381 90 2MB
English Pages [257] Year 2011
ROUTLEDGE ADVANCES IN SOUTH ASIAN STUDIES
Decentralization, Local Governance, and Social Wellbeing in India Do local governments matter? Rani D. Mullen
Decentralization, Local Governance, and Social Wellbeing in India
Over the past three decades, decentralization has been seen as the means for allowing local governments to become more accountable, and for encouraging the deepening of democracy and the building of village communities. By drawing on original village-level case studies of six villages in three different Indian states, this book presents a systematic analysis of the impact of decentralization on the delivery of social services at the local level within India. Supplementing national and state-level data and analyzing the different his torical legacies in each state, the book argues that decentralization is not simply a function of the structure of the decentralization program or of the relationship between higher-tiered and local government. Rather, the possibility of decentralization affecting social outcomes depends on several interacting factors, including the distribution of power among local elites, the dynamics of political competition, and the level of civil society mobilization. By examining constitu tionally mandated political decentralization across India, this book identifies the circumstances under which local government structures can lead to improved social services and societal wellbeing, as well as presenting substantial contribu tion to studies on South Asian politics and local government. Rani D. Mullen is Assistant Professor of Government at the College of William & Mary in Virginia, USA. She is currently a Visiting Fellow at the Centre for Policy Research in New Delhi, India. She has written articles on Indian politics and current developments in Afghanistan.
Routledge advances in South Asian studies Edited by Subrata K. Mitra
South Asia Institute, University of Heidelberg, Germany
South Asia, with its burgeoning, ethnically diverse population, soaring econom ies, and nuclear weapons, is an increasingly important region in the global con text. The series, which builds on this complex, dynamic and volatile area, features innovative and original research on the region as a whole or on the countries. Its scope extends to scholarly works drawing on the history, politics, development studies, sociology and economics of individual countries from the region as well those that take an interdisciplinary and comparative approach to the area as a whole or to a comparison of two or more countries from this region. In terms of theory and method, rather than basing itself on any one orthodoxy, the series draws broadly on the insights germane to area studies, as well as the tool kit of the social sciences in general, emphasizing comparison, the analysis of the structure and processes, and the application of qualitative and quantitative methods. The series welcomes submissions from established authors in the field as well as from young authors who have recently completed their doctoral dissertations. 1 Perception, Politics and Security in South Asia The compound crisis of 1990 P. R. Chari, Pervaiz Iqbal Cheema and Stephen Philip Cohen 2 Coalition Politics and Hindu Nationalism Edited by Katharine Adeney and Lawrence Saez 3 The Puzzle of India’s Governance Culture, context and comparative theory Subrata K. Mitra 4 India’s Nuclear Bomb and National Security Karsten Frey 5 Starvation and India’s Democracy Dan Banik
6 Parliamentary Control and Government Accountability in South Asia A comparative analysis of Bangladesh, India and Sri Lanka Taiabur Rahman 7 Political Mobilisation and Democracy in India States of emergency Vernon Hewitt 8 Military Control in Pakistan The parallel state Mazhar Aziz 9 Sikh Nationalism and Identity in a Global Age Giorgio Shani 10 The Tibetan Government-in-Exile Politics at large Stephanie Roemer 11 Trade Policy, Inequality and Performance in Indian Manufacturing Kunal Sen 12 Democracy and Party Systems in Developing Countries A comparative study Clemens Spiess 13 War and Nationalism in South Asia The Indian state and the Nagas Marcus Franke 14 The Politics of Social Exclusion in India Democracy at the crossroads Edited by Harihar Bhattacharyya, Partha Sarka and Angshuman Kar 15 Party System Change in South India Political entrepreneurs, patterns and processes Andrew Wyatt 16 Dispossession and Resistance in India The river and the rage Alf Gunvald Nilsen 17 The Construction of History and Nationalism in India Textbooks, controversies and politics Sylvie Guichard
18 Political Survival in Pakistan Beyond ideology Anas Malik 19 New Cultural Identitarian Political Movements in Developing Societies The Bharatiya Janata party Sebastian Schwecke 20 Sufism and Saint Veneration in Contemporary Bangladesh The Maijbhandaris of Chittagong Hans Harder 21 New Dimensions of Politics in India The united progressive alliance in power Lawrence Saez and Gurhapal Singh 22 Vision and Strategy in Indian Politics Jawaharlal Nehru’s policy choices and the designing of political institutions Jivanta Schoettli 23 Decentralization, Local Governance, and Social Wellbeing in India Do local governments matter? Rani D. Mullen
Decentralization, Local Governance, and Social Wellbeing in India Do local governments matter? Rani D. Mullen
First published 2012 by Routledge 2 Park Square, Milton Park, Abingdon, Oxon OX14 4RN Simultaneously published in the USA and Canada by Routledge 711 Third Avenue, New York, NY 10017 Routledge is an imprint of the Taylor & Francis Group, an informa business © 2012 Rani D. Mullen The right of Rani D. Mullen to be identified as author of this work has been asserted by her in accordance with sections 77 and 78 of the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988. All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reprinted or reproduced or utilized in any form or by any electronic, mechanical, or other means, now known or hereafter invented, including photocopying and recording, or in any information storage or retrieval system, without permission in writing from the publishers. Trademark notice: Product or corporate names may be trademarks or registered trademarks, and are used only for identification and explanation without intent to infringe. British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data Mullen, Rani D., 1967– Decentralization, local governance, and social wellbeing in India: do local governments matter?/Rani D. Mullen. p. cm. – (Routledge advances in South Asian studies; 23) Based on the author’s thesis (doctoral–Princeton University, 2007) under the title, Do local governments matter? Includes bibliographical references and index. 1. Local government–India–Case studies. 2. Decentralization in government–India–Case studies. 3. Central-local government relations– India–Case studies. 4. Human services–India–Case studies. I. Title. JS7011.M85 2011 320.80954–dc22 2011017347 ISBN: 978-0-415-67065-4 (hbk) ISBN: 978-0-203-35730-9 (ebk) Typeset in Times by Wearset Ltd, Boldon, Tyne and Wear
This book is dedicated to my husband Patrick, for his unwavering support, and to our children, awesome Tara and cool Kiran. It is also written with great appreciation of the numerous villagers who gave so unselfishly of their time and hospitality during my fieldwork.
Contents
List of figures List of tables Acknowledgements List of abbreviations
1 The promise of decentralization
x xi xii xv 1
2 Decentralization in India – rooting the state
20
3 Karnataka – advances with the help of competitive local governments
52
4 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost
91
5 Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power and local governments
140
6 Political power, local governments, and social welfare
172
Appendix A. Powers to be delegated to Panchayats by state governments
192
Appendix B. Methodology
194
Appendix C. Field research questionnaire
204
Glossary Notes Bibliography Index
209 211 215 229
Figures
2.1 Number of national versus total (national, state and independent) parties competing in parliamentary elections, 1951–2009 2.2 The three-tiered panchayat structure 2.3 Key provisions of the 73rd Amendment mandating rural decentralization 2.4 Center–state financial transfers as a percentage of central government GDP, at market prices during the respective Finance Commission (FC) periods 2.5 Local government revenue, 2002–2008 (million rupees) 4.1 The structure of decentralized governments in West Bengal 4.2 Electoral outcomes in West Bengal elections, 1977–2001 (percentage of vote) 6.1 Factors that enable local governments to contribute to improved social wellbeing
26 32 34 37 38 94 98 174
Tables
2.1 Status of devolution of departments/subjects with funds, functions and functionaries to Panchayat Raj Institutions, by state, 2000 40–41 2.2 Poverty rates for selected states and all-India average 48 2.3 Interstate and all-India comparison of key indicators in research states 50 3.1 Social indicators in Bangalore Rural District, 1990/1991 and 2000/2001 66 3.2 Breakdown of election results in Karnataka for 5,675 Gram Panchayats, by social background of elected representative (percentages) 68 3.3 Karnataka: results of selected questions from sample survey in each village in 2000, number responding positively 89 4.1 Share of expenditure on education and public health in West Bengal versus all-India averages, 2005 100 4.2 Selected socioeconomic indicators, Birbhum District versus West Bengal averages 101 4.3 Percentage of seats won by parties of the Left Front Government (LFG) and Opposition in Gram Panchayat Elections, 1978–2008 114 4.4 West Bengal: results of selected questions from sample survey in each village, 2000, numbers responding positively 138 5.1 Selected socioeconomic indicators, Moradabad District versus Uttar Pradesh averages 146 5.2 Funds released versus received for selected programs for Palanpur and Pipli, Chandausi Block, Uttar Pradesh, 2000 (rupees) 155 5.3 Uttar Pradesh: results of selected questions from sample survey in each village, 2000, numbers responding positively 170 6.1 Enabling conditions in the three case study states 184 B.1 Population and geographic location of Indian states 195 B.2 Village case study surveys: quota categories, percentage of quotas in selected district, and percentage of quotas in sample 201 B.3 Selected results of village surveys, number responding positively, percentages, and 95% confidence intervals (CI) 202–203
Acknowledgments
This book would not have come to fruition without the help of many advisors, friends and family members. Three main advisors provided the intellectual and personal guidance, which enabled me to produce this work. Jean Drèze provided me not only with the ideas and contacts that enabled my field research, particu larly in Uttar Pradesh and West Bengal, he is also a moral inspiration to me to research issues that matter for the underprivileged in India and other developing countries. Deborah Yashar’s insights on the linkages between political institutions and social change have guided me in my research. And finally, this research would not have happened had it not been for my dissertation advisor Atul Kohli, whose intellectual and professional advice has carried me through graduate study and work – for which I am immensely grateful. It was his question to me, on a sunny afternoon in Princeton, whether local governments really mattered for social outcomes that provided the seed that grew into this book. Other Princeton faculty members also supported me at various stages of this research endeavor: Marta Tienda, Stan Katz, and Wolfgang Danspeckgruber provided invaluable feedback on the big picture of my research. I also learned much and received advice from many other wonderful Princeton faculty, including Michael Doyle, John Waterbury, Peter Kenen, Angus Deaton, Kathryn Stoner-Weiss, Jonathan Murdoch, Miguel Centeno, Robert Finn, and Kent Eaton. Many graduate school colleagues provided intellectual support, in par ticular Steve Tibbets, Anne Tully, Estela Rivero, Ann Morning, Marty Stein, Jakub Grygiel, and Tyler Dickovick. Several programs were also central to funding this undertaking. As a student at Princeton’s Woodrow Wilson School, the four fully funded first years were important, as were all the other aspects of support the School provided. Summer research funding through the Graduate School, as well as the Center for Regional Studies and Center for International Studies (now the Princeton Institute for International and Regional Studies), enabled my pre-dissertation research in India. The Fellowship of Woodrow Wilson Scholars not only gave funding during my dissertation-writing phase, it also provided a wonderful forum for interdisciplinary intellectual exchange. The Liechtenstein Institute on Self- Determination at Princeton University under the guidance of Wolfgang Danspeckgruber offered me a professional home for a few years and a fellowship
Acknowledgments xiii during 2008–2009, and gave me the opportunity to explore the issue of decentralization in Afghanistan. And finally the Government Department at the College of William and Mary provided me with funding to conduct my followup research during December 2007–January 2008 and also with the space and support to finish this book. Other colleagues at the College, in particular Jim Axtell and Arnab Basu, provided great mentorship and support. My fieldwork in India would not have been possible without the help of many generous individuals and institutions. The Centre for Policy Research provided me with an institutional affiliation and research base during my pre-dissertation research, as well as an intellectual home while I finalized this book during 2010–2011. The Institute of Social Sciences (ISS) was my research base during my field research and many colleagues at ISS provided background data and advice for my fieldwork. I was introduced to villages I selected for study in Uttar Pradesh and West Bengal through the invaluable support of Jean Drèze. In Amarpurkashi, Uttar Pradesh, Mukat Singh’s help and friendship in getting us settled into Palanpur was essential. Rakesh Poddar was a great translator and colleague during our stay in Palanpur and Pipli. In West Bengal, Madangopal Ghosh and Sunil Sengupta at Visva-Bharati, Santinikentan generously provided access to findings from their research of Kuchli and Shahajapur, and helped arrange all the logistics of the village studies, while Surajit Adhikary’s translation and research help was invaluable. And in Bangalore, Karnataka, G. K. Karanth at the Institute for Social and Economic Change (ISEC) kindly provided open access to his prior research of Gavi Nagamangala and Mudabal as well as the crucial introductions to people in the villages, while Avinash Samal helped me with all of the logistics that enabled the field work. My stay in Karnataka would not have been possible without a home base with Mickey and Ilse Shenoy. I owe the greatest debt, however, to the numerous women and men in the case study villages who had so little and gave me so much in terms of their time and hospitality. There were many whose help over the years enabled me to write this book. Research and data inputting help from Matt Michenfelder was much appreciated. It is an honor to be able to publish in this Routledge series, whose editor, Subrata Mitra, is one of the leading thinkers on the issue of decentralization in India. No one could ask for better editors than the ones I had at Routledge – Leanne Hinves and Dorothea Schaefter. I could not have finished this book had it not been for the support and help of my friend, colleague, and wonderful sister Maya Tudor. It is above all my family that I have to thank for believing in me, nudging me and helping me stay anchored during the long research and writing process. My father, Indira, and sister Aarti provided me with a great and welcome base of support during my fieldwork in India. My brothers Kim and Jan have provided me with the quiet brotherly support that made me plough on. My in-laws Lynne and Phil (we miss you) provided great support throughout. I could not have made it this far had it not been for the faith in me by mother and Harpal – and particularly the nudging and baby-sitting help from my mother at crucial times. The all-around help from my aunt Dagmar, who managed the home front and
xiv Acknowledgments looked after my children so that I could focus on my work, was invaluable. And finally this book is dedicated to my children Tara and Kiran who provided the sun, love, and laughter, which was always the light at the end of the tunnel and to my husband Patrick, whose steadfast support since my very first day at Prince ton helped me bring this research to print.
Abbreviations
ADO AITC BDO BJP BLD BPL BSP CPI(M) DRDA EAS FC GC GP GS HDI IAS IAY IMR INC IRDP ISEC JD JD(S) JGSY JRY KP LEB LFG MLA MLC MMR MP NGO
Assistant District Officer Trinamul Congress Party Block Development Office/Officer Bharatiya Janata Party Bharatiya Lok Dal below the poverty line Bahujan Samaj Party Communist Party of India (Marxist) District Rural Development Agency Employment Assurance Scheme Finance Commission General Caste Gram Panchayat Gram Sabha Human Development Index Indian Administrative Service Indira Awaas Yojana program infant mortality rate Indian National Congress Integrated Rural Development Program Institute for Social and Economic Change Janata Dal Party Janata Dal Secular Party Jawahar Gram Samridhi Yojana program Jawahar Rozgar Yojana program Kshetra Panchayat life expectancy at birth Left Front Government member of state legislative assembly member of state legislative council maternal mortality rate Mandal Panchayats Nongovernmental organization
xvi Abbreviations NSDP NSSO OBC PDS PPP PRI RTI SC SC/ST SFC SGSY SP ST TB TFR TP UF UN UP US$ WB ZP
net state domestic product National Sample Survey Organisation other backward castes Public Distribution System purchasing power parity Panchayat Raj Institutions Right to Information Scheduled Caste Scheduled Caste/Scheduled Tribe State Finance Commission Swarnjayanti Gram Swarozgar Yojana program Samajwadi Party Scheduled Tribe Tuberculosis total fertility rate Taluk Panchayat United Front United Nations Uttar Pradesh United States dollar West Bengal Zilla Panchayat
1 The promise of decentralization
Fifty years of development planning, anti-poverty programs, and education and health programs have brought few welfare improvements to the village of Palanpur in the northern Indian state of Uttar Pradesh. Despite being located close to railroad tracks and only a couple hundred kilometers east of Delhi in a relat ively rich agricultural area, most inhabitants of Palanpur are not significantly better off than they were several decades ago, and the poor continue to barely make a living. Central government programs aimed at rural development and the provision of a safety net for the poor through public works projects are virtually unseen in this village of nearly 2,000 inhabitants. The Public Distribution System (PDS) has been in place for decades and is intended to give indigent populations monthly rations of subsidized goods including wheat, rice, oil, and kerosene. When PDS goods are distributed in Palanpur (thrice a year at most), only a fraction of the goods are actually given out. The poor, who are also gen erally illiterate, often do not know their entitlements. They do not realize that their PDS ration booklets have been stamped to indicate that they have received the full monthly PDS allowance. And even if they did know, to whom would they complain without fear of losing the meager rations they do get? Officials in the district capital 20 kilometers away? Government, for most of Palanpur’s residents in the early 1990s, was an entity physically and socially far removed. Over the past three decades, decentralization – defined as the transfer of political power to citizens and/or their elected representatives at lower levels of govern ment – has been attempted by developed and developing countries alike. Decen tralization has been touted as the means for shifting power away from the inefficient, corrupt, and rent-seeking central states towards more accountable local governments and for encouraging the deepening of democracy and the building of village communities. It has also been a way of addressing the ineffi ciencies of central states in reducing poverty by enabling better local targeting and delivery of social services. Scholars from different ideological backgrounds, from neoliberal economists to civil society organizers, have viewed the increased power given to local governments through decentralization as holding great promise for changing the efficacy of government. Advocates of decentralization argue that local
2 The promise of decentralization governments would help democracy take root and be more effective at improv ing the wellbeing of their citizens. Yet critics countered that decentralization might lead to widening disparities between localities – mainly, that lack of local capacity among illiterate and poor population groups might lead to local elite capture of public resources and an inability to implement central government programs. Three decades into the political decentralization of power, it is appro priate to ask whether the shift towards local governments has actually mattered in average citizens’ lives. Few in rich countries who have not spent time in a developing country can imagine the absolute poverty in which one-sixth of the world’s population lived at the beginning of the twenty-first century. Not only do the world’s absolute poor generally lack access to basic education, health services, and safe water, they often do not have enough resources to get the three meals a day that would prevent chronic hunger. But the dynamics of poverty are not static and vary by time and place. While the twentieth century saw large gains in living standards in some coun tries, poverty and other indicators of social wellbeing continued to remain poor in much of the developing world. Some countries, such as South Korea, which were considered “developing” countries 50 years ago, are now in the middle- income league with low poverty rates. Others, like India, have seen high eco nomic growth rates over the last few decades, but these growth rates have not “trickled down” enough to pull over 300 million poor people out of poverty.1 Development theorists have hypothesized that the solution to decreasing poverty lay in open markets, social-democratic regime types, and pro-poor policies. Yet in a developing country like India one finds that pursuit of all three development policies at different times has not radically reduced poverty. Nor has pursuit of these policies alone been able to explain the variance in social outcomes between different regions in India. In a country that is home to more than one-fourth of the world’s poor (Deaton 2002) it is important to understand why some Indian states have improved indicators of social wellbeing more rapidly than others. It is also important to better understand whether functioning local governments are at least partly responsible for more rapidly improving social wellbeing in some states, along with making government more accountable and bringing govern ment closer to the people. This research’s findings show that a state’s history of decentralization, political competition, and social mobilization are key ingredi ents in determining the ability of village governments to deepen democracy and have an impact their citizens’ wellbeing. Different combinations of these key ingredients have led to varying degrees of democratic rooting and efficacy of local governments in implementing decentralization in India. Findings from this study also explain the mixed results of decentralization pro grams across the globe. From Mexico to Uganda and India to Indonesia, the promise of greater accountability, efficacy, and citizen-wellbeing has brought dif ferent results in different places (Blair 2000; Oxhorn et al. 2004; Bardhan and Mookherjee 2005). In seeking to explain decentralization’s differential outcomes, most studies have been macro-level, inter-country studies of decentralization with
The promise of decentralization 3 a focus on the implementation of decentralization programs by central govern ment. Many of these studies therefore tend to locate the causes of differential effectiveness within the underlying structure and process of decentralization. Such studies fail to consider the arena where political power has been relocated as a result of decentralization – the local level – and thereby fail to account for in- country variations in the effectiveness of political decentralization, particularly with regard to local government implementation of social welfare programs. Decentralization is about redistribution of political power, yet the reallocation of power does not happen in a political vacuum. If decentralization occurs in a context where political power is concentrated among a narrow group of village elites and in an area with little history of local governments and political com petition, local governments’ ability to enact change leading to enhanced social outcomes is circumscribed; at least, results are likely to be delayed. Conversely, when local governments are not captured by dominant local elites, when there is a politically competitive environment, and when there has been some experience with local government, then decentralization is likely to lead more expeditiously to improved delivery of social services, thereby resulting in better social indic ators and enhanced social wellbeing. Historical context matters. For the inhabitants of Indian villages, having a his tory of already functioning local governments is a significant factor influencing their awareness of how local governments should function and how they might ensure access to social services particularly for disenfranchised groups. The overall nature of social cleavages, particularly caste and religious differences, and dynamics of local political mobilization are also factors that influence the effectiveness of local governments and in turn are determined by the interactions with local governments. I argue that a focus on national-level factors fails to account for variation within countries. There is, furthermore, little analysis of the wide variance – either between or within countries – of effective social-service delivery after decentralization or of citizens’ perceptions of these services. This book examines constitutionally mandated political decentralization across India to identify the circumstances under which local government structures can lead to improved social services and societal wellbeing. It offers a countrywide analysis of the decentralization process in India with village-level case studies in three Indian states. It demonstrates that contextual differences, particularly the distribution of power among local elites, political competition, and the nature of civil society activism, seriously affect the ability of decentralized local governments not only to function democratically, but also to pursue their mandate of alleviating pov erty and improving the health and education of their citizens. Over the next few chapters I grapple with an under-studied issue in the field of decentralization, namely why the implementation of the same political decentralization program leads to differing degrees of success in subnational states. While political decentralization has been heralded by some as the cure for the inability of large, bureaucratic states to target social services to the poor, others have argued that it is more likely to lead to the capture of power by local vested
4 The promise of decentralization interests. Nevertheless, the efforts of the international community to help root democracy and improve social-service delivery throughout the developing world have been focused on supporting decentralization with billions of dollars of tech nical assistance and development aid. After three decades of decentralization programs, the record of improvements in the social wellbeing (poverty, health, and education indicators) of people in the developing world is decidedly mixed. Identifying the context in which political decentralization is likely to succeed is key both to understanding the theoretical question of why decentralization brings about social change in some situations but not in others, and also to devising policy tools to support effective decentralization. As the first systematic analysis of the impact of decentralization on the deliv ery of social services at the local level within one country, this volume draws on case studies and national data to argue that decentralization is not simply a func tion of the structure of the decentralization program or of the relationship between higher-tiered and local governments. Rather, the possibility of decentralization affecting social phenomenon depends on several interacting factors: how broadly political power is distributed at the village level, dynamics of polit ical competition, and the level of social capital. This book builds on the work of economists and political scientists who argue that decentralized governments can deliver greater benefits than “statist” govern ments. While economists base their advocacy of decentralization on ideas of better information flow and enhanced efficiency, political scientists marshal arguments dating back to de Tocqueville, Montesquieu, and Jefferson on the benefits of decentralization for deepening democracy and bettering social out comes. I draw on the work of political scientists who argue that the corruption and ineffectiveness of the centralized state has discredited the statist structure (Rondinelli et al. 1989). I also build on the work of scholars who have argued that greater pluralism and competitiveness among state structures would give voice to more citizens, thereby deepening democracy (Lieten 1996a; Schoenwal der 1997; Crook and Manor 1998, 2001; Aziz 2000; Johnson 2001; Bhattach aryya 2002). As such, the book speaks to the question posed by a recent World Bank study, Does Decentralization Enhance Service Delivery and Poverty Reduction? (2010). Yet this book differs from the World Bank study by focusing on a single country, teasing out why a single nationwide system of decentraliza tion might lead to differential outcomes within that state. By revealing local political dynamics that condition the differential impact of decentralization for social wellbeing, this study complements recent work – such as Merilee Grin dle’s on Mexico (Grindle 2007) – that explains why the theoretical benefits of decentralization are not inevitable in practice. While Grindle focuses on factors such as public sector modernization to explain decentralization’s differing results, this book highlights the unfolding of decentralization in unique local contexts. As my case studies illustrate, the degree of concentrated political power, the extent of political competition, and the mobilization of civil society all come to bear on the ability of local governments to function democratically and translate their local knowledge into better delivery of social services.
The promise of decentralization 5 This research contributes to the theory and practice of governance in three main ways. First, it broadens our understanding of decentralization and the factors contributing to its efficacy. By holding the structure of decentralization constant by focusing on one country, I illustrate that judgments about the effi cacy of decentralization need to take local contexts, including cultural and insti tutional legacies, into account. Second, this work contributes to our understanding of democracy and its depth. This research builds on Amartya Sen’s idea that democracy should be thought of as being intrinsically valuable to a person’s wellbeing, instrumentally important in providing political incentives for greater government accountability, and providing a constructive framework that forms societal values and helps prevent economic disasters – all of which improve socioeconomic wellbeing (Sen 1999). The following chapters on each state case study illustrate how decentralization can help democracy take root and improve social outcomes at the local level – and how the local context of exist ing allocation of power, political competition, and lack of political and social mobilization might prevent it from doing so. Finally, this work argues that schol ars of decentralization and democracy, as well as policy makers and development aid specialists, should pay closer attention to the local setting in which top-down political decentralization takes place. Complexity of political and institutional factors might lead the designers and implementers of decentralization to rein force clientalistic mechanisms, thereby disabling decentralization from affecting people’s social wellbeing. Overall, these findings can be used to assess decen tralization’s merits generally and to better understand the barriers to decentrali zation in countries from Mexico to Ghana and Pakistan to Indonesia. If the wave of decentralization that has swept the developing world is to really matter for its most vulnerable citizens, we need to understand the main local contextual factors that drive successful decentralization programs.
Decentralization as a tool for reforming the state The past three decades have seen a global wave of efforts to reform the state in order to make it more effective and accountable. In the literature on transform ing the efficacy of the state, decentralization has become a dominant theme (Bardhan and Mookherjee 2005). It has been considered or implemented in a large array of developed and developing countries, since “out of 75 developing and transitional countries with populations greater than five million, all but 12 claim to be embarked on some form of transfer of political power to local units of government” (Dillinger 1994). As states are increasingly pressured by outside international agencies and greater pluralist policies from above, as well as from domestic forces from below, leading scholars in political science focus their research on the interactions between the state and subnational governments. This newer focus is both the result of political events and an increasingly global development paradigm, which posits that subnational governments are more effi cient and capable than formerly assumed. The disillusionment with state capa city and the decrease in state legitimacy owing to its many failures (Bardhan
6 The promise of decentralization 2002), together with the fact that an improvement of an individual’s social well being requires local structures that are focused on and effective at delivering social welfare programs, has over the past decades ushered in a trend towards decentralizing political power to local governments. Centralized states have been attacked in the development paradigm advocated by aid agencies and development institutions (Parker 1995; Manor 1999; Parker and Serrano 2000; Work 2002a, 2002b; World Bank 2003), as well as the political structures that are de facto advocated by the United States government through their public pol icies in post-conflict countries such as Afghanistan (Mullen 2006). These critics of state planning assert that centrally administered bureaucracies are inefficient at allocating resources (Lal 2000; World Bank 2000a). Besides being heralded as the cure to governance problems in a variety of states (Tanzi and Ahmad 2002), decentralization has been promoted by a variety of interest groups, including multilateral development banks. This case for decentralization is based on the assertion that a more decentralized state would be closer to citizens and thus more responsive to local needs (Crook and Sverris son 2001). And by being closer to the people, government would be more accountable to them and more effective for the local population (Crook and Manor 1998; Manor 1999; Blair 2000). The economic argument for decentrali zation is often expressed in terms of reducing information and transaction costs (Marschak 1959) and improving allocation (Cohen and Peterson 2000). While decentralization has been implemented in many countries, it has meant different things in different places, and the results have rarely been analyzed sys tematically through comparative, intra-country case studies. Decentralization is more than mere delegation of power to lower levels of government; it implies more than the de-concentration of power to lower levels of administrative agen cies (Crook and Manor 1998); and it goes beyond devolution, where subnational units of government are created or strengthened (Crook and Manor 1998; Blair 2000). Decentralization has been interpreted as meaning fiscal decentralization, administrative decentralization and/or democratic decentralization or devolution (Rondinelli 1990; Crook and Manor 1998; Manor 1999; World Bank 2000b; Johnson 2003). Clearly local governments, even if democratically elected and representative of their constituents, will fail in the longer term without adminis trative, and some financial, decentralization. Administrative decentralization provides local government with specific responsibilities and bureaucratic resources for implementing these new tasks, while fiscal decentralization enables local governments to have the financial wherewithal (Manor 1999) to undertake more autonomous projects. Yet political and administrative decentralization on their own also change the locus of power, empower people at lower levels of political engagement, and lead to a more accountable and effective local government. During the late 1980s and early 1990s, in the wake of the dissolution of the Soviet Union, many countries decentralized state powers to subnational govern ments. Much of the impetus behind changing the nature of the state and decen tralization has been based on an understanding of the state, which locates the state
The promise of decentralization 7 at the center and attempts to improve its efficiency and accountability by shifting some of its power to the periphery. Although most advocates of this shift agree on a general understanding of the state, not all come from the same background. Decentralization has found support among a wide political spectrum. Neoliberal thinkers have seen decentralization as a means of moving power away from ineffective, overbloated, and often corrupt central states who are responsible for market failures to subnational governments where the transaction costs are lower and public service delivery can be better targeted (Manor 1999; Bardhan 2002). Civil society and social welfare advocates and researchers have viewed decentralization as a possible means for decreasing poverty and enhancing social wellbeing due to local governments having greater information to better target social and anti-poverty programs to the poor. And some democracy advocates have promoted decentralization as a means for deepening the roots of demo cracy. Decentralization, according to this line of argument, brings government closer to the people, thereby fostering greater citizen participation, civic virtue, protection of civil liberties and government accountability. On the other hand, critics of decentralization have pointed out that the formal process of decentrali zation matters less than the underlying power relationships in rural societies (Slater 1989; Peterson 1997; Cross and Kutengule 2001; Harriss 2001; James et al. 2001). Other critics have pointed out that the net effect of increasing local governments’ share in revenue-raising and fiscal autonomy is indeterminate; that greater local participation in government could lead to greater civic engagement or greater corruption; that it was unclear why voters would necessarily be better informed about local versus central government performance; that local govern ments that succeed in obstructing central government interventions are as likely to protect individual freedom as they are to protect local corruption (Treisman 2007). Scholars have argued that in India there needs to be a genuine change in power relations of disadvantaged groups through land reform (among other pro grams), before these groups can benefit from decentralization (Kohli 1987; Echeverri-Gent 1992). Yet despite decentralization being ever-present in much of the world and advocated by a diverse group of people, systematic comparative within-country studies of decentralization are rare, and studies of decentraliza tion and its links with social wellbeing are rarer still.
Decentralization and development Greater democratic depth (and breadth) and increased efficiency in state services and programs have been the two major arguments for decentralization. Some more recent literature has also advocated decentralization as leading to better development outcomes – from higher economic growth rates to better social indicators. This study contributes to the literature on democracy, decentralization and development, and the links between these three. Its findings show that one needs to broaden development paradigms to include local governments as a factor influencing overall wellbeing and that local-level studies are needed to understand the specific factors that enable local governments to function most
8 The promise of decentralization effectively and contribute to improved wellbeing. Decentralization has been her alded as a means to reform the state in developing countries in order to improve effectiveness of development programs and thereby speed up development. The original source of support for decentralization comes from liberal democratic political theory, particularly the work of John Stuart Mill. Mill and other classi cal thinkers advocate decentralization as leading to both national and local bene fits through greater local participation in political structures. In the early 1980s Rondinelli cited 14 possible benefits arising from decentralization, including increased efficiency and speed in carrying out development programs by cutting through “red tape” (Rondinelli 1981). Indeed, the idea that decentralization leads to more effective and efficient development through more accountable and responsive local government struc tures is a main thread underlying the decentralization and development literature (Crook and Sverrisson 2001; Cross and Kutengule 2001; Bardhan 2002; Braun and Grote 2002). Governance, defined as the “traditions and institutions by which authority in a country is exercised,” includes (1) the process of selecting, monitoring, and replacing governments, (2) the government’s capacity to formu late and implement sound policies, and (3) the state’s and citizen’s respect for the institutions that govern economic and social interactions among them (Kaufmann et al. 2002). It is this link between effective village-level local gov ernments in India, known as Gram Panchayats, and social wellbeing that this research will analyze. The decentralization literature can be divided into three broad categories in terms of its main benefits for development: (1) political stability, (2) enhanced participation and democracy, and (3) increased accountability and responsive ness (loosely based on ideas presented in Turner and Hulme 1997). The literat ure advocating decentralization as a means for increasing political stability and thus development effectiveness is largely focused on post-conflict countries, nascent democracies, and countries experiencing separatist movements. In these settings decentralization has been regarded as a way of diffusing tensions. The third category is the largest and most frequently used by politicians as a justifica tion for decentralization. This literature broadly argues that decentralization leads to elected government representatives who are closer – both physically and through better relationships – to their constituents and thus are more responsive and accountable (Rondinelli et al. 1983; Smith 1985). This argument links closely with the local democracy literature mentioned above. Common to both is the notion that local governments provide greater responsiveness and account ability. Local governments lead to quicker and more effective implementation of development projects (among other things), thereby improving development outcomes. There are several theoretical frameworks that fall under this third broad cat egory of decentralization literature. One structure is that of the public adminis tration and management frameworks. This method analyzes the management of development programs at the local level and finds that project plans can better adjust to local conditions, coordination at the local level is enhanced, project
The promise of decentralization 9 implementers are more motivated to perform due to the greater responsibility they have, and the workload is reduced for central agencies, allowing them more time to improve the project policy framework (Rondinelli et al. 1983; Turner and Hulme 1997). Essentially this literature argues that the transfer from central to local agencies improves the management of projects by enabling a better delivery of service resulting in better development outcomes. Economists have used public choice theories to reach similar conclusions, arguing that under democratic conditions, defined as “conditions of reasonably free choice,” competition of agencies, and close proximity of providers to recipi ents of programs results in greater efficiency (Rondinelli et al. 1989). Essentially the supply-and-demand benefit from greater competition promotes efficiency in government services, including the delivery of social and anti-poverty programs (Smith 1985). Greater efficiency in turn improves development. This standard political-economy argument for decentralization is argued as widely applicable in developing countries. Some of the few studies that analyze decentralization’s efficacy have found that decentralization tends to help decrease poverty in subregions, but has little impact on inequalities within subregions; that it can help minorities, but only if they are in the majority locally; and that it tends to enable development of pro jects viewed as important by the localities (Manor 1999; Bardhan and Mookher jee 2005). Most studies of the developmental benefits of decentralization analyze at the macro level, without studying specific localities, with little attention to the potential shortcomings of decentralization; alternatively, such studies may focus on specific case studies without drawing larger lessons from these studies. The few researchers who have analyzed country studies of decentralization have found a positive relationship between decentralized governance and better deliv ery of social welfare programs (Work 2002b; Oxhorn et al. 2004; Bardhan and Mookherjee 2005). Yet warnings of elite capture of local governance, frag mentation of responsibilities and other potential dangers still surface (Prud’homme 1995; Tanzi 1995; Tanzi and Ahmad 2002), indicating that this field requires further study in general and a deeper understanding of the local context in particular, to better judge the benefits of decentralization and contexts in which it is more likely to yield intended results. With so many arguments for decentralization’s benefits, and with countries restructuring administration and political power based on these claims, there should also be more local studies that investigate whether decentralization can enhance the development outcomes that its supporters have promised, and under which circumstances such outcomes are more likely.
Understanding the decentralization process The importance of better understanding the decentralization process and its benefits and costs is imperative because of the billions of dollars of technical assistance and development aid spent by the international community on supporting decentralization programs. Multilateral and bilateral aid organizations
10 The promise of decentralization have been enthusiastic supporters of decentralization for years. The World Bank annually committed between $300 and $500 million for projects that contained decentralization components during a six-year period between 1997 and 2003 (World Bank 2004). Various UN agencies also supported decentralization pro grams with similarly large commitments. With billions of dollars annually given by development agencies to countries in support of decentralization programs, it is important to consider whether the largely unquestioning support of decentrali zation is warranted. Moreover, if there is village-level evidence supporting decentralization’s benefits, how might these large sums of development aid be fine-tuned to enable better support for the desired outcome?
What explains the mixed outcomes of decentralization? This book emphasizes the importance of historical antecedents and sociopolitical context in explaining decentralization’s varied impact in delivering social ser vices by studying the decentralization process in one country and analyzing its varying success in villages in different parts of the country. History clearly mat ters, with states that have experienced working local governments in the past being more likely to have functioning local governments in the future. However, other aspects of the local context are also important. In the relevant literature, three theories are advanced to explain why the reality and actual practice of local governance might differ even when the same decentralized governance structure is implemented within one country. These theories, which center on the extent of democratic depth and political competition, the mobilization of civil society, and elite buy-in, highlight different aspects of local conditions into which decentral ized governance structures are placed, and which affect their impact. This research builds on all three explanatory frameworks. By focusing on the unfold ing process of decentralization in different villages in India, it highlights why and under what conditions these different explanations might be more salient for explaining the better functioning of decentralized government structures, which in turn enable better delivery of services that matter for social wellbeing. Democracy and competition The idea that implementing decentralized governance structures leads to the rooting of democracy is a common theme in the decentralization literature. This literature has pointed to the causal linkages working in the opposite direction, namely that the reason political decentralization might be more effective in some areas compared to others is that these areas might have preexisting structures, which are more egalitarian and democratic. This literature takes the notion of competition among businesses (leading to innovation, lower costs, and more sat isfied customers) and applies it to the political realm. Taking their cue from political philosophers as far back as Immanuel Kant, proponents of this view argue that if decentralized governance structures are placed in a more democratic environment where there is competition to represent constituents, where those
The promise of decentralization 11 who are seeking to represent constituents in local governments are allowed to compete on the basis of political parties which all have a chance of winning, and where elections result in turnover of elected representatives, then increased com petition will yield better functioning local governance structures (Rodriquez 1997; Crook and Manor 1998). While these ideas about democracy and competition have been largely applied to national level analyses (Besley et al. 2005), their logic should similarly hold true at subnational levels. As at the national level, political decentralization and the institutionalization of democratic local elections should yield better function ing local governments. Local elections should force candidates to compete on the basis of political platforms and force accountability of local government rep resentatives by having them submit their record in office to periodic electoral scrutiny. Moreover, the involvement of political parties at local levels of govern ment helps focus political debate on issues rather than on personalities, helps link decentralized governance structures with higher levels of government and party structures, and provides a basis for communication and conflict resolution through the use of party machinery (Gibson and Hanson 1996). By corollary, decentralized local governments, where elections do not take place in an environment of political competition and where representatives are not periodically subject to electoral scrutiny and loss of office, are more likely to rely on existing and often more traditional forms of political mobilization. These would include patron–client and familial relationships in addition to the empow erment of local, traditional elites. Advocates of the democracy and competition literature have argued that in more democratic and politically competitive envir onments, there are likely to be more local governments that follow their mandate and deliver public goods such as targeted social services. Civil society mobilization A second type of explanation that seeks to elucidate why political decentraliza tion of power might lead to differential functioning of local governments and therefore disparate ability to deliver social services hinges on the nature of civil society and the extent to which local citizens are politically aware and mobi lized. Building on insights by de Tocqueville (de Toqueville 1848) and, more recently, Robert Putnam (Putnam 1993, 2000), this literature argues that local governments function better in environments where citizens actively participate in the larger community life across ethnic, gender, socioeconomic, and even caste differences, forming networks that bridge social cleavages and engender norms of trust and reciprocity. In such environments of high “social capital,” cit izens are generally more politically mobilized, with social networks acting as conduits of information and awareness-raising. The norms within these types of social networks are also more likely to yield responsive local governments and better delivery of social services. In these types of environments, citizens are more likely to participate in local governments and actively lobby local govern ments to be more responsive and provide public goods.
12 The promise of decentralization When political decentralization takes place in this type of environment of active social capital and engaged civil society, proponents of this strain of liter ature argue, local governments are more likely to flourish, be responsive, and provide social services. Varied proponents of this view, ranging from academics, community and nongovernmental organizations, and multilateral institutions such as the World Bank, have argued that higher levels of social capital lead to a range of economic and social benefits, as engaged citizenry puts pressure on local governments and bureaucrats to deliver more effective social services. By corollary again, local communities with low levels of social capital, where cit izens are less politically and socially mobilized and aware, are less likely to see citizen groups engage with local government representatives and exert pressure on their representatives to deliver public goods. Elites and the degree of concentrated political power One theory in the comparative political science and sociology literature that seeks to explain diverse outcomes hinges on analyses of local power relation ships. This theory argues that political elites wield power within a community that is independent of the institutionalization of new political structures. These elites might be the traditional governing elites within the community, or non governing elites who derive their political power from their social standing. Scholars of political elites have employed a loose definition of “elites” as groups that are privileged and powerful for any reason (Higley and Burton 2006), in order to highlight the functional imperatives of organizations and movements that give rise to this group. The different strategies used by these elites are key to democracy and democratization (Collier 1999). Without the formation of a “con sensually united elite,” liberal democracy is not able to emerge (Higley and Burton 2006). This strand of literature analyzes the degree of concentration of political power within a given community, arguing that democratically function ing local governments are a function of the distribution of political power which is often concentrated among a few individuals who are not necessarily elected officials and who hold disproportionate power in political decisions (Hunter 1969). These proponents posit that when elite interaction is such that conflicts are restrained, partisan interests are moderated to a degree where they do not prevent compromise, and there is tacit agreement on protecting existing or new political institutions (Higley and Burton 2006). Building on earlier literature on political elites and waves of democratization (Huntington 1991) and applying it to the case of decentralization, this study highlights that the local context of the distribution of political power matters for the likelihood that decentralized local government structures are able to function as true representative structures. When local political power is distributed among a small socioeconomic group with historically significant political leverage, and when there is no consensus among elites that it is in their interest to yield polit ical power, then decentralization is less likely to result in local government offi cials that represent their constituents and deliver social goods. A consensual
The promise of decentralization 13 relationship among the elite and elites who buy-in to the process of political change is, according to this theory, the key to determining whether elite behavior is cooperative or antagonistic; this behavior in turn is the key to enabling polit ical changes, including the decentralization of political power.
Relating theories of local government to its practice These three theories for explaining why the political institutions of decentralized governance might thrive in some areas and languish in others provide the intel lectual lenses with which this book examines constitutionally mandated political decentralization across India. Each of these discrete explanations has advanced the understanding of different decentralization processes. However, by them selves, they do not explain the range of outcomes of decentralization. This study finds that these seemingly distinct theories explaining decentralization’s efficacy are interrelated, with a combination of these theories explaining outcomes in divergent settings. For example, both the Indian states of Uttar Pradesh and Kar nataka have politically competitive elections and yet decentralization has been more effective in Karnataka. Similarly, social cleavages and elites are less dis tinct in West Bengal (WB) and Karnataka compared to Uttar Pradesh, and yet decentralization has been more effectively able to target the poor in Karnataka than in West Bengal. Different local conditions make the issue of political com petition more salient to understanding decentralization in West Bengal compared to Karnataka or Uttar Pradesh. The combination of all three explanatory frame works is important to comparing and understanding the overall efficacy of decentralization. This is a comparative study within one country, which is rare in the literature. Many studies have documented transnational variation in decentralization’s out comes (Blair 2000; Crook and Manor 1998; Eaton 2004), but few have included intra-country analyses. This research is among the first systematic analyses of the impact of decentralization on the delivery of social services at the local level within one country. The research draws on national data and state- and village- level case studies to argue that decentralization is not simply a function of the structure of the decentralization program or of the relationship between higher- tiered and local governments. Rather, the possibility of decentralization affecting social phenomena depends on several interacting factors: the nature of elite interactions at the village level, the dynamics of political competition, and the level of social capital. A case study approach to this research has enabled collection of a wealth of qualitative and quantitative data at the national, state, and local levels, providing a nuanced answer to why decentralized local government has not uniformly translated into improved delivery of social services and thereby an advancement in social wellbeing. This research employed open-ended interviews, informal conversations, and participant observation to analyze the micro-logic of larger, macro phenomena in order to obtain first hand insights into the motives of polit ical actors. Both qualitative and quantitative information was collected by a
14 The promise of decentralization small sample survey that captured views on decentralization and governance at the village level. By examining the political decentralization program of a single country, India, this investigation holds the structure of decentralization and the national policies surrounding it constant. National- and state-level data on gov ernance and social indicators provide an understanding of the differing levels of development among Indian states before and after constitutionally mandated decentralization in 1993. Yet in a country the size of a continent, with a popula tion to match, the range of state-level socioeconomic indicators and policy dif ferences is large. Many Indian states are indeed the size of countries, with 19 of the 28 states having a population of at least ten million. If it were a country, the state of Uttar Pradesh, with a population of over 166 million according to the 2001 census (Government of India 2001), would rank among the world’s ten most populous countries. Analyses of decentralization in Indian states are com parable to studies of medium-to-large sized countries. The case study selection method sought to account for differences in size of states, as well remove states that were outliers in terms of their socioeconomic levels and governance. The list of 28 Indian states was narrowed down to an initial 21, in order to exclude states with populations under two million, which were permitted a two-tiered decentralized structure by the constitution instead of the three-tiered structure for larger states. The list of 21 states was then further narrowed to large states with populations over 50 million in the year 2001. This left a pool of ten large states that shared the same decentralization structure (see Appendix B). It also eliminated the southern state of Kerala, a well-analyzed state and an outlier in terms of consistently having outperformed all other Indian states in social indicators of wellbeing. Bihar, a state that has consistently ranked at the bottom of social indicators was also eliminated as an outlier. Since polit ical devolution of power throughout India was mandated by a 1993 constitu tional amendment that established the “Panchayati Raj Institutions” of local government, West Bengal, a state in eastern India and the only state that had consistent democratically functioning local governance prior to 1993, was chosen as one of the case studies. Uttar Pradesh, a state in northern India, and Karnataka, a state in southern India, were the other two states chosen for ana lysis. Social indicators in these three states were close to the Indian average in the early 1990s, with indicators in Uttar Pradesh generally slightly below average and indicators in West Bengal and Karnataka mostly average. Twenty years later, social indicators in Karnataka had pulled ahead of the other two states, with West Bengal lagging behind Indian averages, particularly in educa tion, and Uttar Pradesh failing to transform its economic growth rates into signi ficant social advances. The history and politics of decentralization in the three Indian states were ana lyzed and village-level studies were conducted in districts that mirrored the respective state’s averages in terms of socioeconomic indicators prior to 1993. Two case study villages were selected within the chosen district in each of the three states. It would be mistaken to hope that a pair of villages in, for example, Uttar Pradesh – with a population of 131 million – could hope to be characteristic
The promise of decentralization 15 of the whole range of socioeconomic conditions in the state. However, two vil lages in each state were chosen to most closely approximate statewide average social indicators. Village representativeness was enhanced by excluding villages for study if they deviated from state averages in terms of demographic indicators, such as female to male ratios and percentage of ethnic and caste minorities. They were also not selected if they were located in regions that were significantly dif ferent agro-economic environments (coastal, suburban or mountainous areas, for example) than the rural norm in the state. All selected villages were located away from urban centers and were predominantly dependent on agriculture for income. Moreover, in all three states at least one of the two case study villages was chosen because it had been studied prior to the passage of the law mandating decentrali zation in order to provide a baseline for comparison of governance and social indicators. Each state was studied for about six weeks in 2000. Follow-up research and interviews during a couple of weeks in each state in 2007/2008 was carried out to ensure that the findings were not driven by the political or socioeconomic idiosyncrasies of a particular year and that temporal changes in social, political, and economic dynamics at the village level could be analyzed. Focus-group dis cussions with different caste and religious communities, group discussions and individual interviews in each village supplemented around forty in-depth survey responses of a random sample of ordinary citizens in each village in 2000. (The term “respondent” is used to refer to those who responded to the small surveys, while the term “informant” is used for others who were interviewed using qualitative methods. Note that, along with discreet yes/no questions, application of the survey questionnaire included in-depth interviews on the various issues covered by the questionnaire (so that survey “respondents” were also “inform ants”). The survey questionnaire (see Appendix C) was based on the instru ments used by Crook and Manor in their study of the panchayat system in Karnataka during the late 1980s and sought to capture citizen perception of governance, social wellbeing, civil mobilization and the possible links between them (Crook and Manor 1998). The information collected from these village studies enabled my overall assessment of the level of decentralized governance and the factors that influ ence it, as well as how it translates into the delivery of social welfare programs. The personally-conducted, in-depth village studies provided an on-the-ground view of how decentralization affected people’s lives, capturing the interaction of diverse variables and providing a rich account of factors driving decentraliza tion’s impact. During the past six decades, India has been ruled by a variety of central gov ernments that have all highlighted the need to address poverty through different programs but have done little to ensure that local structures and political con ditions exist to deliver the programs to the people. The political focus on top- down programs and the intellectual focus on macroeconomic and political structures, have prevented greater understanding of why local structures have often been inadequate to enabling improved welfare. Moreover, macro-level
16 The promise of decentralization approaches are good for looking at economic growth, but not necessarily for analyzing poverty alleviation and social welfare. The politics of redistribution is about effective empowerment of people, which cannot be studied from the top down. It is important to study the context in which welfare changes occur, and doing so requires a view from the bottom up. Large-scale surveys are by their nature fixed in structure and often do not capture variety in local perception and the complexity of interaction among factors influencing outcomes. This study includes local surveys as well as capturing local opinions through free-ranging interviews and discussions. Village studies are important for capturing a holistic understanding of the factors that enable efficacious government. Data gathered by the Indian census and other large-scale surveys are very good, yet these data are usually only gath ered at the district or, at best, the block level. Large-scale quantitative surveys, while providing broad overviews and trends, depend entirely on asking the right questions, thereby often missing causal insights which living in the villages and having open-ended conversations with a large cross-section of village residents can more readily provide. Previous studies of the villages conducted by other researchers were also village-based, often over extended periods of time. The research villages were chosen because of access to previous studies, since they provide an important pre-decentralization baseline on social wellbeing in the villages that large-scale datasets do not include. In my project, data were gathered in two villages in each state and by conducting interviews with villagers of different social backgrounds. The structured interviews asked for people’s perception of changes in their well being, village governance, and civic mobilization. I also asked about their per ception of links between these factors and the presence of local governments. This more qualitative information was supplemented by data collected at the village level and from the panchayat and block offices about the actual function ing of Gram Panchayats (GPs) and the social welfare programs that they were responsible for implementing. All of the case study states are large Indian states, but each differs from the others with regard to the local governance conditions at the time when the Pan chayat Act was implemented in 1993, as well as the level of social wellbeing in the early 1990s. Uttar Pradesh (UP), in northern India, did not have a history of democratic local governance prior to 1993 and only held panchayat elections in 1995. Its social indicators place UP second lowest among the large Indian states. Karnataka, in southern India, also had a history of panchayat governments prior to 1993, though a briefer one than in UP, with average to above-average social indicators in the early 1990s. West Bengal, in eastern India, had a long history of functioning panchayats prior to 1993 and thus is a valuable case study in its own right. Social indicators in West Bengal have made considerable progress since the late 1970s, though in terms of overall social indicators, including poverty rates, West Bengal still fared around the Indian average in the early 1990s.2 The three case study states represent the combinations of different extremes of panchayat government implementation. The advantage of a comparative study
The promise of decentralization 17 that focuses on large Indian states, rather than on multiple countries, is that the Indian states are all part of one federal system subject to the same laws, includ ing the 73rd Amendment mandating decentralization, and receiving the same centrally administered programs, including all anti-poverty and social welfare programs. Ruled by the same federal system, yet each with varying degrees of histories of panchayat rule and local conditions, these three states provide the ideal setting for a comparative study of local governments and the role govern ance can play in changing social welfare. The range of social outcomes possible with differing levels of functioning local governments is illustrated by these three states. Prior to the passage of the 73rd amendment, Uttar Pradesh did not have a history of democratically elected local governments or other structures providing local control over social program implementation. The lack of local governance in Uttar Pradesh’s extremely unequal society, ridden with strong caste, gender, and religious differentiation, resulted in a reaping of social program benefits by local elites. However, the election of new local panchayats in Uttar Pradesh has set in motion a cycle where elite dominance and theft of social welfare coffers is no longer as easy to maintain and indeed involves distribution of payoffs to the new local govern ment representatives. Increasing local awareness that monies allocated to pan chayats are not reaching the intended programs is causing resentment and has found an outlet in subsequent panchayat elections. West Bengal, on the other hand, has had a nearly 30-year history of demo cratic panchayats instituted by a pro-poor, communist government. The pancha yats in West Bengal have had great autonomy to help carry through redistributive measures and oversee local social program implementation. This has enhanced local participation in decision-making, helped to increase awareness, and ulti mately helped to improve social indicators. Over the years, however, the lack of effective political competition has resulted in capture of local power structures and resources by Communist Party members. Leakage of social resources and anti-poverty programs to better-off Communist Party members has decreased the efficacy of local governance and constrained West Bengal’s social welfare improvements. Karnataka also had powerful local panchayats during the 1980s. Though the system was dismantled in the late 1980s due to political and bureaucratic pres sure, people, particularly more vulnerable groups in rural areas, retained strong memories of the great effectiveness of panchayats in enhancing their social wel fare by giving them greater control over local implementation of social welfare programs. The history of effective local panchayats and the re-implementation of the panchayat system in the early 1990s have created a positive cycle of enhanced understanding of the powers and possibilities of panchayats. More over, local political competition in an environment of an increasingly mobilized, educated citizenry has resulted in increased local awareness and demand for social rights, thereby resulting in more democratic local governance and better functioning social welfare programs.
18 The promise of decentralization
Overview of the book This research addresses a current shortcoming in the field of decentralization analysis. It considers how elite power, social stratification, civil society mobil ization, and political competition might interact to enable local governance that improves social welfare. Different combinations of these key ingredients have led to varying degrees of democratic rooting and efficacy of local governments in implementing the decentralization program in India. I contend that local governments can make a difference in local wellbeing if the governments are politically competitive – and thus not captured by elites – if they are held accountable by a mobilized civil society, and if they have a history of functioning local governments. Having a history of already functioning gov ernment increases awareness of social rights, thereby engendering a more active civil society. Three mechanisms in particular enable democratically functioning and accountable local governments to improve social welfare. First, in line with the decentralization literature, the presence of local government brings govern ment closer to the people, decreasing physical, as well as social, barriers to accessing government and therefore directly improving social welfare. Second, the presence of democratic local governments creates more competitive politics. As long as no particular social or political elite captures the local governments, the increased competition between parties will lead to more accountable and transparent local conditions. Under these more competitive conditions, social benefits will be disbursed on the basis of need rather than caste, ethnic, or polit ical affiliation. Under more competitive conditions, local governments are more service- and results-oriented, which causes improved social outcomes for the poor and more vulnerable populations. Third, having a democratically function ing local government, including participatory and democratic village assembly meetings, helps to build and root democratic practices at the local village level. Seeing democracy in action also helps raise and reinforce awareness of one’s rights; as awareness of these rights grows, individuals are more likely to demand their rights through petition-signing and other social actions that also help improve social wellbeing. These three mechanisms through which local govern ments can help improve social outcome tend to reinforce each other, building more accountable and democratic governments and thus enabling better improvements in social wellbeing. Chapter 2 describes the history of decentralization in India, explains the struc ture of decentralization and the range of responsibilities that were devolved to local governments in 1993, and frames the research by introducing the case studies. This chapter indicates that while the impetus for decentralization was not a desire for deepening democracy, the decision to decentralize reflected increased political competition and an increasingly vibrant democracy at the national level, which was reflected to varying degrees at the local level. The same decentralized structure was implemented in various political contexts in the Indian States, leading to differing results in decentralization’s effectiveness for social wellbeing.
The promise of decentralization 19 Chapter 3 focuses on the state of Karnataka and explains the history of local governments, power politics, and socioeconomic distribution prior to the national program of decentralization. It illustrates how Karnataka’s innovative experience with accountable and effective local governments during the 1980s provided for a politically competitive environment. In addition, an aware and mobilized civil society and consensually united elites provided a fertile ground for the imple mentation and flourishing of local governments after 1993. Findings from the village studies illustrate awareness of local governments’ rights and responsibil ities, the democratic functioning of local government structures, rising account ability of local representatives, and the ability of local governance to enhance social service delivery, thereby enhancing citizens’ wellbeing. Chapter 4 explores decentralization in the state of West Bengal and argues that significant past experience with local governance is not enough to guarantee that decentralized village governments will more effectively deliver social services to their constituents. In West Bengal, three decades of Communist Party rule changed the political power structures in Bengali villages from a system based on caste and religion to one based on party membership and hierarchy. While village elites in West Bengal are now more broad-based and consensual, and village cit izens more politically aware and socially mobilized (forming an engaged civil society), party domination has become the major barrier to further rooting of democracy. Findings from village studies clearly indicate that in West Bengal one of the long-term costs of virtual single-party rule for over three decades has been the inefficiency of local government delivery of social services and the conse quent impact on the poorest and politically disenfranchised villagers. In Chapter 5 the study of political decentralization in Uttar Pradesh illustrates that decentralizing political power, in an environment of strong social cleavages and in the absence of an active civil society, leads to further cooption of social services by the existing elite. In this context, democratic decentralization is largely on paper only, with local governance only slowly taking root as aware ness of political rights grows and as political competition increases. In this vicious circle of coopted political power, the implementation of social programs aimed at decreasing poverty and providing a social welfare net is likely to be weak, and improvements to social wellbeing incremental. The final chapter summarizes the overall findings of the case studies with regard to the larger issue of the efficacy of decentralization for social wellbeing in India. Local contextual factors determine the ability of local governments to thrive or not, and therefore need to be understood if we are to gain a holistic understanding of the barriers to effective decentralization. Decentralized local government structures have been planted in various political soils, some rich in democratic governance with little elite capture, more vibrant civil societies and politically competitive environments, and others with less fertile soil for decentralization to flourish. Local dispersion of political power and consensual elites, together with a history of demo cratic local governments and the mobilization of political and civil society, is a more fertile ground for the flourishing of democratic, local governance; and better local governance is more likely to lead to improved social wellbeing.
2 Decentralization in India – rooting the state
As with many countries at the end of the twentieth century, India moved from a centralized political structure toward decentralization of political powers. Political decentralization to local governments in rural areas was legally mandated throughout India with the passage of the 73rd Constitutional Amendment in 1993. This law delineated a list of responsibilities that were to be transferred to subnational government institutions, including the implementation of poverty- alleviation, health, and sanitation programs, as well as primary and secondary education. The rationale for transferring these responsibilities to local govern ments was that decentralized governance structures at the village level would enable greater local oversight of resources and thereby less corruption and more resources for better targeting of social programs. Nearly two decades after mandated decentralization in India, it is time to ask whether local governments in India have been able to impact social wellbeing.1
The importance of decentralization in the Indian context The theory that decentralized regimes are more effective at improving social wellbeing is important to examine in any context but it is particularly important in a country like India. Any change that promises improved social wellbeing for a country with the largest concentration of the world’s poor is worth studying (Chelliah and Sudarshan 1999; Deaton 2003). Over half a century after its inde pendence, India’s development policies have failed to bring significant social welfare improvements to many of India’s citizens. Admittedly, the 1990s saw some significant progress, with poverty rates declining between 1991 and 2001 (Deaton and Kozel 2005), and most social indicators at the national level have improved over the past two decades. Yet much remains to be done. A third of Indians still live below the poverty line and the same percentage is illiterate (Government of Uttar Pradesh 2001). Moreover, there are indicators of widening inequality since some states have seen greater decreases in poverty than other states and urban poverty has increased in mid-sized towns. Furthermore, quality of life for the Indian poor is abysmal. Lack of access to public education inhibits Indians’ chances of upward mobility, and lack of access to good quality public health care facilities impairs their health and thereby their
Decentralization in India – rooting the state 21 ability to earn a living. Often non-functioning safety-net programs, such as the former food-for-work program or the widows’ pension program, subject the poor and vulnerable to further hardships. A cultural preference for the male child and dowries paid to the groom’s family at the time of marriage reduce the quality of life for girls. The continued grip of the caste system – and upper-caste rule (par ticularly in rural areas) – subjects the lower-caste poor to the double indignity of poverty and disrespect. India’s health indicators, such as maternal and infant mortality rates (MMR and IMR), rank among the worst in Asia. Two-thirds of Indian children under five years of age suffer from malnourishment, with the percentage of children who are underweight being one of the highest in the world and nearly double the rates in sub-Saharan Africa (Granolati et al. 2005). The ratio of females to males, at 940 females per 1,000 males according to the 2011 census, also continues to be one of the worst in the world. Moreover, spiraling population growth has created a situation where the number of Indians living below the official poverty line today, which Planning Commission figures estimate to be around 28 percent of the population in 2005, or approximately 300 million people (Planning Commission March 2007), is greater than the entire population of India at the time of independence. India today has the dubious distinction of being the country with the largest concentration of poor, malnourished and illiterate people in the world. This lack of progress in social wellbeing is a manifestation of the shortcomings of more than 60 years of “pro-poor” social and economic policies on the part of the Indian government. Furthermore, aggregate figures mask vast regional differences. Faster-growing states like Gujarat or Maharashtra have not seen the expected accompanying large improvements of social indicators. On the other hand, decreasing poverty and improved social indicators (despite low growth rates) in states like West Bengal and Kerala – states which have had a commit ment to improving the lives of the poor, and which in West Bengal’s case have elected local governments for over 30 years to ensure the delivery of social programs at a local level – proves that relying on the trickle-down effect of eco nomic growth alone will not solve Indian poverty. It also shows that the long-standing decentralization experiment in a state like West Bengal deserves greater scrutiny, particularly in light of West Bengal’s unique history of continu ously elected local governments stretching back 15 years before the passage of the amendment mandating decentralization. Moreover, despite more than six decades of democracy, guided economic development, and central government programs to increase social wellbeing, improvements have been well below the targets set by the government for itself, and repeated promises of poverty alleviation and basic education for all have gone unfulfilled. The higher growth rates India has experienced since the late 1980s and particularly during the past two decades have resulted in improvements in social welfare. Yet these improvements have not been significant or uniform throughout India. Among large states, Haryana, for example, had the highest per capita net state domestic product in 2008–2009, yet also had India’s most skewed ratio of females to males in 2011. Inter- and intrastate social
22 Decentralization in India – rooting the state indicators have in fact been widening since the early 1990s, with social indic ators stagnating in Bihar and to some extent in Uttar Pradesh, while showing greater improvements in states like Kerala, and Karnataka. In fact Kerala, a his torically low-growth state, has the highest social indicators of any Indian state, while states with higher economic growth rates, such as Haryana or Gujarat, have not registered the commensurate growth in social indicators. The lack of significant correlation between high-growth states and states that have shown greater improvements in social indicators indicates that political-economy explanations alone lack explanatory power. Other promising explanations of the differential changes in social indicators between Indian states need to be explored. Some prominent economic and political theories fail to explain the different rates of improvement in social wellbeing between Indian states. Trickle-down of economic growth and centrally sponsored development schemes have failed to significantly reduce poverty and improve social indicators across the board. Although some evidence has shown that strong, pro-poor state governments have been more effective at implementing policies to help the poor (Kohli 1987, 1997), in the longer term even some pro-poor state governments such as West Bengal have failed to ensure continued rapid improvements in social wellbeing, particularly for the poorest segment of the population. Simply having good eco nomic growth rates, anti-poverty programs, or a pro-poor state policy is not enough. What is needed is a system that enables the delivery of social services on the ground and that ensures accountability for public programs at the local level. India’s foray into decentralization has been heralded as the solution to this problem. Over a decade into the decentralization experiment it is appropriate to ask whether these local governments actually matter for improving social wellbeing. And, if local governments do matter for social wellbeing, what types of local governments are more likely to ensure accountability2 and deliver social services?
Democratic political space enabling decentralization Elected village governments were not new to India in the early 1990s. Political decentralization, when it did take place in India in the early 1990s, was the culmination of years of debate and a series of committees tasked to outline the necessary steps. What enabled a constitutional amendment mandating political decentralization throughout India in 1992–1993, however, was a changed polit ical environment within India, which also reflected the changing nature of pol itics globally at the end of the twentieth century. Rarely do states give up power without being pushed to do so by political circumstances or demands from their citizenry. Moreover, political decentralization of power away from central gov ernments during times of increased civil society activism and demands for decentralization might mask attempts by political parties to use local govern ments as a source of patronage in order to serve their financial needs (Mitra 2001). In India, as in other decentralizing states, the mandating and imple menting of decentralization in the early 1990s reflected the growing nature of
Decentralization in India – rooting the state 23 democratic institutions and an increasingly inclusive politics in India. This evolving political environment put pressure on political institutions and govern ment to move beyond the procedural aspects of democracy toward embracing substantive democracy. The turn toward substantive democracy in the late 1990s built upon 45 years of broadening political space and a growing understanding of and demand for political rights. After independence in 1947 and the adoption of a constitution in 1949, India became one of the first decolonized countries to adopt British-style parliamentary democracy and institutions, including full adult franchise. Debates during the Constituent Assembly and within the Indian parliament subsequent to independence grappled with the issue of structuring the newly independent state. Discussion focused on whether political power should be decentralized and vested at the village level, as envisioned by the father of the independence movement, Mahatma Gandhi, or whether the requirements of a newly independent country and the need to modernize and foster development by the state required a centralized government. Where the balance should lie within a federal system – with the central government or the individual states – was debated in the Constituent Assembly. The majority view of the necessity of a federal structure with a strong center prevailed (Government of India Friday, November 25, 1949). This debate reflected the tenuous relationship between a newly emerging demo cracy built on the Gandhian notions of individual and village empowerment, on the one hand, and the quest for modernization with its accompanying drive toward centralization, on the other (Rodriques 2009). Debate in the Constituent Assembly focused on the location of political power in a newly independent federal republic while also reflecting the inevitable gulf separating the procedures and institutions of democracy from equality and substantive democracy. Recognition of this gulf was exemplified by one of the main architects of the Indian constitution, B. R. Ambedkar, in his concluding speech to the Constituent Assembly on the eve of passing the Indian constitution: On the 26th of January 1950, we are going to enter into a life of contradic tions. In politics we will have equality and in social and economic life we will have inequality. In politics we will be recognizing the principle of one man, one vote and one vote, one value. In our social and economic life, we shall, by reason of our social and economic structures, continue to deny the principle of one man, one value. How long shall we continue to live this life of contradictions? How long shall we continue to deny equality in our social and economic life? If we continue to deny it for long, we will do so only by putting our political democracy in peril. [emphasis added] (Government of India Friday, November 25, 1949) The foundational debates of the nascent Indian democracy thus reflected recog nition that attainment of independence and enshrinement of electoral democracy did not mean that substantive democracy had been achieved. These debates also highlighted the existential questions Indian politicians were struggling with,
24 Decentralization in India – rooting the state particularly whether India would be a centralized or decentralized state and what institutional mechanisms would best help the spread of democracy. The often- heated debates during India’s three-year-long Constitutional Assembly (1946–1949) reflected divergent approaches to building the new state and institutionalizing its nascent democracy. While some followers of the Gandhian approach advocated a bottom-up approach to building democracy through decentralized “village republics,” others criticized this approach as likely leading to the undermining of democracy. Addressing a view within the Constitutional Assembly that the new constitution should incorporate “the ancient Hindu model of a State” based on village and district-level governments rather than following a strictly Western approach, B. R. Ambedkar reflected: That [village communties] have survived through all vicissitudes may be a fact. But mere survival has no value. The question is on what plane they have survived. Surely on a low, on a selfish level. I hold that these village republics have been the ruination of India. I am therefore surprised that those who condemn Provincialism and communalism should come forward as champions of the village. What is the village but a sink of localism, a den of ignorance, narrow-mindedness and communalism? I am glad that the Draft Constitution has discarded the village and adopted the individual as its unit. (Government of India 1948a) Eventually, India was established as a federal republic in 1950 with the framers of the constitution intending a central, national government but also self- governing sub-national units. Yet despite the federal framework, the transfer of power from the center to the states and sub-state level, and with it the broadening of political space, proceeded only gradually. The slow transfer of power to Indian states is evidenced by the misuse of central government power with regard to Article 356 of the Indian constitution. This article, which governs relations between the union and state governments, is located in the part of the constitution dealing with “Emergency Provisions.” Also known as the President’s Rule or Central Rule, Article 356 allows the pres ident to dismiss the government of a state (based on the advice of the governor of that state) if the president is convinced that the administration of the state can no longer be carried out in accordance with the provisions of the constitution. Once the government is dismissed, the president of India becomes the executive of the state. However, since Indian presidents have no discretionary powers, they have to act in accordance with the advice of the central government, de facto enabling the ruling party or coalition to rule the state’s affairs – hence Central Rule. Between 1950 and the early 1990s, Central Rule was invoked more than 100 times to dismiss state governments. In the majority of these cases, parties or coalitions in opposition to the central government headed the state. While the purpose of the constitutional article was to address political instability and maintain national unity, the frequent abuse of this article exposed how the balance of
Decentralization in India – rooting the state 25 power tilted toward the central government. It was not until the 1994 Supreme Court ruling in Bommai v. Union of India that abuse of Article 356 was reined in, thereby strengthening the federal nature of the Indian state and rebalancing the relationship between the central government and the states. The unitary nature of the Indian state during the first few decades after inde pendence was also evident in the percentage of votes won by the main party. After independence, the movement that had spearheaded Indian independence, the Indian National Congress (INC), transformed itself into India’s governing political party, the Congress Party, with Jawaharlal Nehru as prime minister. The legitimacy bestowed on the Congress Party by virtue of it inheriting the mantle of freedom fighters and the charismatic rule of its first prime minister enabled the Congress Party to firmly entrench itself in national as well as subnational politics in India. While a variety of political parties representing national and subnational constituencies competed for power in parliamentary elections, the Congress Party repeatedly received the largest number of votes in the 50 years post-independence and thus formed India’s governments until 1999, with the notable exception of 1977–1980, when post-emergency rule elections ushered in a brief Janata Party government. In parliamentary elections from 1951 to 1991 the Congress Party continually received 35 to 50 percent of votes, typically 20 percentage points more than the second most popular party. Moreover, from 1951 to 1989, again with the exception of 1977–1980, the Congress Party won an absolute majority of seats in parliament. The continual governance of the Congress party for the first five decades of independence firmly entrenched Congress as the singular governing political party. It ruled through its network of party structures and system of political patronage down to the village level, and was dominated by wealthy landowners, entrepreneurs and social elites. The procedural and centralized nature of Indian democracy was reflected in the solid grip on Indian politics by the Congress party and its leaders up until the early 1990s. The Congress Party dominated the political landscape not only in terms of the percentage of votes it received nearly continuously for 40 post- independence years, but also in terms of their virtual monopoly on representa tion of an extremely heterogeneous population, with social cleavages ranging from ethnic, linguistic, and regional, to caste and religious. As seen in Figure 2.1, the number of national parties (having constituencies and a political base in more than one state) remained relatively constant, at around seven. However, when tallying the total number of political parties competing in national parlia mentary elections in the post-independence period, the combined number of national parties as well as state parties that only had a base in one state remained at 50 or below until 1989 when the number increased dramatically, tripling from 34 parties competing in 1984 to 114 parties in the parliamentary elections of 1989 and rising further subsequently. The entrance of increased numbers of political parties representing diverse constituencies represented a loosening of the hold of the Congress Party and the widening of representation of diverse groups in India’s national politics towards the end of the 1980s. Moreover, since the elections of 1989, every Indian government, regardless of whether it was led
26 Decentralization in India – rooting the state 400
Number of parties
350 300 250
Number of national parties in general elections Total number of parties (national, state and independant) in general elections
200 150 100 50 0
1951 1957 1962 1967 1971 1977 1980 1984 1989 1991 1996 1998 1999 2004 2009 Election year
Figure 2.1 Number of national versus total (national, state and independent) parties competing in parliamentary elections, 1951–2009 (source: Election Commission of India. Various years).
by the Congress Party, has been a coalition government and has not been able to form without the help of several subnational parties. The consequence has been greater interdependency between national parties and state governments, and in turn a less dismissive attitude toward state governments by the national parties. Since the late 1980s, political space at the national level in India has widened to include a greater representation of India’s diverse population. As these diverse interests increasingly found representation and voice at the national level, they contributed to a deepening of democracy and leveraged greater rights and repres entation for subnational governments. The broadening of political space at the national level in India during the late 1980s and early 1990s was reflected as well in an opening of India’s formerly closed economy, a gradual shift in the balance of power from the central govern ments to the states, and resulting changes to India’s federal system. Yet, while conventional wisdom has focused on the rise of political parties in India as reflecting a change in locus of power to the subnational level (Chhibber and Kollman 2004), the dynamics of the increasing number of subnational political parties and the increased political power of Indian states from the late 1980s were reflective of a fluid and cyclical process. After 1989, states attained greater bargaining power through coalition governments, where state-level political par ties were increasingly key partners in forming national coalitions (Nikolenyi 2010). The demise of majoritarian national governments led by the Congress Party, a concomitant rise in the number of state-level political parties, and their increased power in national coalition governments, led to growing pressures for decentralization of political power to the states. The dynamics of increasingly consolidated coalitional politics (Chakrabarty 2008) in turn empowered nascent
Decentralization in India – rooting the state 27 subnational political parties, leading to a shift in the balance of power in the center–state relationship from centralized government toward the states. The constitutional assignment of some statutory powers to the states, while retaining other powers at the center, is the essence of Indian federalism. Yet while the balance within this federal system favored the central government up to the late 1980s, a rising participation of parties representing increasingly diverse constituents (Rao 2009) and demanding greater political rights for states changed this balance so that the center–state relationship became one of interdependence of equals. Moreover, an economic crisis in 1991 and the government’s subsequent response ushered in the liberalization of the Indian economy. Economic lib eralization restored some economic decision-making powers to the states, powers that had remained in the hands of the central government since independ ence. Increasing demands for state autonomy in economic and political decision- making were countered by the significant leverage the central government maintained through the transfer of revenues to states. Thus, in the economic as well as the political sphere the relationship between the central government and states was, by the early 1990s, increasingly characterized by growing demands and increased leverage of the states, thereby turning center–state relations into a more pluralistic federal system. This opening of political space and strengthening of federal structures by the early 1990s in turn created an environment friendly to political decentralization.
Historical background of decentralization in India India has a long history of local governments dating back to pre-colonial times, with evidence of panchayats (assemblies of five elders who adjudicated village affairs) well before the advent of British India. Members of these village panchayats were almost exclusively from economically and socially privileged backgrounds and almost exclusively male and upper-caste. During the British period, local self-governments were formalized and given greater weight. In 1882 under the Viceroy of India, Lord Ripon, the Ripon Resolution called for institutionalization of elected local governments, from municipal governments in urban areas to the block level (administratively just above the village level and below the district level) in rural areas. Despite the fact that the Ripon Resolution is today con sidered the “Magna Carta of local democracy in India,” implementation of its recommendations at the turn of the previous century proceeded slowly (Mathew and Mathew 2003). However, the ideal of local self-governance was incorporated by India’s independence movement, and particularly its chief champion, Mahatma Gandhi (Mathew and Mathew 2003). The idea of decentralized govern ments in the form of Gram Panchayats (village governments) was central to the ideological framework of the nationalist movement in India. Mahatma Gandhi’s vision of an independent India focused on the notion of village self-rule (“Panchayat Swaraj”) as the basic building block of democracy. His vision of local self-governance focused not only on the structures and institutions of government,
28 Decentralization in India – rooting the state but also on egalitarian community building (Parel 1997). India’s first prime min ister, Jawaharlal Nehru, wrote an entire book on the subject of community development and coined the term “panchayat raj,” stating that local governments were the foundation of government institutions and that unless local government structures were “sound[,] the upper structure would be weak” (Nehru 1965). After independence, the drafters of the constitution engaged in lively debate about local governance. Those who advocated enshrining Gandhi’s ideas about decentralized power to Indian villages were countered by those who insisted that Indian villages were the strongholds of conservative caste-ridden social mores and therefore, could not be entrusted as agents of sociopolitical change. Local governments were finally included in Part IV, Article 40 of the constitution (which forms part of the Directive Principles of State Policy): “The state should take steps to organise village panchayats and endow them with such power and authority as may be necessary to enable them to function as units of self- government” (Government of India 1948b). In fact, local panchayats were estab lished by most state governments in India after independence. Yet without support at the national level, the implementation of panchayats languished. During the four intervening decades between the writing of the constitution and the 1993 amendment enshrining decentralization, the discussion on decentralization was punctuated by a series of committees on the issue. The debates surround ing decentralization and lack of concrete action up to 1993 reflected the greater power of the central government in the federal relationship until the early 1990s. Recognition that utilization of local government structures was not progressing led in 1957 to the establishment of the Balwantrai Mehta Committee. Charged with evaluating the extent to which the national program of community development projects had worked together with decentralized government structures, the committee pointed to a greater need to involve rural communities, and recommended the organization of “statutory representative bodies” by the states (Government of India 1957). It also made a range of recommendations to strengthen local govern ments, including programs to develop local agriculture and the delivery of services such as drinking water (Singh 1994). However, the Balwantrai Mehta Committee’s suggestions did not have the power of law, which left it up to individual states to enact legislation to institutionalize local governments. Over the next two years all states passed panchayat legislation and by the early 1960s, local governments had been elected in most parts of India. In 1963 another committee, under the leadership of K. Santhanam, was appointed to investigate how to provide greater financial autonomy to local governments. The committee provided recommendations a few months later, yet the government did not institutionalize any of them. Due to elite domination of village politics, local elections turned out local governments that were democratic in name only. As with politics at the national level, where the Congress Party ruled with hege monic power, the same elites who had traditionally governed India were elected. Furthermore, without any enforcement of local elections by the central government and opposition to decentralization by vested interests ranging from state governments and civil servants to local political party bosses, the
Decentralization in India – rooting the state 29 subsequent elections were dropped in most states and local governance structures soon reverted to the previous rule by patriarchical caste-based elites. By the early 1970s panchayat elections were basically defunct in all Indian states, while the virtual one-party rule of the Congress Party under Prime Minister Indira Gandhi appeared to have solidified Congress’ hold at the national and state level. However, by the mid-1970s the calculus between the states and the federal government started to change. Prime Minister Gandhi’s strong-arm tactics, which were aimed at bypassing the old-guard-dominated, clientalistic structure of the Congress Party to directly appeal to voters, started to backfire. The context of the 1975–1977 Emergency Rule declared by Indira Gandhi and the groundswell of anti-Indira Gandhi and anti-Congress sentiment in the wake of the Emergency, led to the first national electoral defeat for the Congress Party in 1977 by the Janata Party. The Emergency Period not only led to the ousting of the Congress Party at the national level, it also changed the federal bargain between the states and the center. Henceforth any attempt by the center to consolidate or even expand power at the expense of the states was going to be perceived as an illegitimate undermining of state authority. When the Janata Party briefly came to power it sought to establish itself at the state and local levels as well as nationally. It is likely that it was Janata’s need to break the political patronage network that was so firmly controlled by the entrenched Congress Party that led to its focus on decentralization. Under the national Janata government, the Ashok Mehta Committee was appointed in 1977 to suggest avenues for rekindling local government structures and thereby eliciting greater grassroots participation in development (Singh 1994). The Ashok Mehta Committee suggested a two-tiered local government structure, with one sub-state government at the district level and another at the block level below the district. The Committee was also notable for linking local governments and development efforts. In its 1978 report on local governments, or Panchayat Raj Institutions (PRIs), it suggested ways of strengthening local governments in order to make them agents for furthering social development, recommending that they participate in the fields of agriculture, forestry, cottage industries, and welfare activities (Singh 1994). Many of the suggestions made by the Ashok Mehta Committee, from repres entation of lower castes in local government elections (on the basis of their population) and participation of political parties in PRI elections to devolution of development functions to local governments, would later become institutionalized in the 1993 constitutional amendment. At the time, however, the Ashok Mehta Committee’s recommendations were accepted and implemented only by the four non-Congress state governments of Andhra Pradesh, Karnataka, West Bengal, and Jammu and Kashmir. These states took the committee’s recom mendations as a mandate to change their state laws to strengthen their panchayat system, thereby also enabling their ruling party’s ability to build a patronage network down to the village level. However, as the power of the Janata government at the national level started to wane, leading to a return of the Congress Party in 1980, central government support for decentralization ebbed
30 Decentralization in India – rooting the state again. This left the impetus for decentralization with the individual states. The states, other than Karnataka for a brief period in the late 1980s and West Bengal under Communist Party rule since 1977, had little incentive to give away polit ical power to local governments. The recommendations of the Ashok Mehta Committee thus languished, as those of such committees had before. During the 1980s the Congress Party appointed various commissions and studies that reaffirmed the Ashok Mehta Committee recommendations, but without any political incentive to decentralize, no recommendations were implemented. In 1985 yet another committee, the G. V. K. Rao Committee, recom mended revitalizing the local government system in order to enhance rural development, but its recommendations were also not enacted. A year later the L. M. Singhvi Committee and subsequently a committee under the chairmanship of P. K. Thungon again studied the panchayat system and recommended that local governments be institutionalized through a constitutional amendment. During the late 1980s Prime Minister Rajiv Gandhi championed the idea of a constitutional amendment to strengthen local governments. The 1989 L. M. Singhvi Committee advocated for enshrinement of political decentralization. In May 1989 the 64th Amendment Bill, based largely on the Ashok Mehta Committee’s recommendations but also seeking to bypass state governments and establish a direct link between the central and local governments, was introduced to parliament. While the bill received the required two-thirds majority in the lower house of parliament, it fell two votes shy of the required numbers in the upper house. At the same time the government of Rajiv Gandhi was defeated in 1989 and a coalition government under the banner of the “National Front” came to power. In 1990 the National Front government introduced a revamped 64th Amendment, known as the 74th Amendment, which included urban and rural local governments. This amendment also languished in parliament, while the National Front focused on trying to keep together its coalition. The National Front government was short-lived and soon replaced by the Congress Party in 1991. Yet despite the inability of the National Front to push adoption of the 74th Amendment through parliament, both the incoming Congress Party as well as opposition leaders publicly voiced support for legally enshrining elected local governments. The increased commitment of all political parties to decentralization was a reflection of the changing nature of politics in India by the early 1990s, especially the demise of Congress Party hegemony and the entrance of a variety of new political parties, many with regional, linguistic and caste-based constituencies. Decentralization presented the perfect vehicle for these newer parties to establish links at the grassroots level and thereby counter the entrenched Congress Party machinery. For the Congress Party, the increased challenges to its authority at the national, as well as the state and subnational levels, presented by the increasingly crowded field of political parties, necessitated a reigniting of its political base and party machinery at the subnational levels. Decentralization of power to subnational institutions similarly presented an opportunity for the Congress Party to use its established subnational party structures to ward off the challenges presented by the increased competition.
Decentralization in India – rooting the state 31 By the early 1990s the political environment at the national level had therefore changed to one where the political parties that were new entrants to national rule as well as the formerly dominant Congress Party saw support for subnational political institutions to be in their long-term interest. The stage was thus set for passage of decentralization.
The 73rd Constitutional Amendment With increased support in parliament for political decentralization, the Congressled government of Prime Minister Narasimha Rao introduced two bills seeking constitutional amendments to enshrine rural and urban panchayats in 1991. A year later, in late 1992, both amendments were passed by the Indian parliament, and in early 1993 the required two-thirds majority of state assemblies ratified the amendments, thereby legally mandating decentralization in rural and municipal areas throughout India. These constitutional amendments, the 73rd Amendment for rural panchayats and the 74th for urban ones, made India one of the most politically decentralized countries in the world (World Bank 2004). The final impetus for decentralization among India’s main political parties was a response to pressure from an increasingly competitive array of political parties at the national and subnational levels. Democratic pressure to bring gov ernment closer to citizens, including poorer and marginal groups, and to create more accountable and transparent political institutions at the local level, finally pushed legislators to pass the constitutional amendment. After 45 years of sover eignty, years of parliamentary debate, and a series of special commissions, the Indian parliament finally passed a constitutional amendment to decentralize that was far-reaching in its potential implications for participatory democracy and improvements in peoples’ social wellbeing. The 73rd Constitutional Amendment set the framework for the structure of local government and required every state to enact legislation or amend its own panchayat laws by April 1994 in conformity with the constitution, to delegate political powers to local governments in rural areas, and to hold local govern ment elections by April 1995. Political powers as well as fiscal transfers were intended to make up the decentralization package. The wording of the amend ment also clearly conveyed its intent: local governments were to become institutions of self-government, where the participation of citizens in direct and representational democracy at the village level would lead to greater citizen involvement in the process of planning for development as well as greater social justice. Direct citizen participation in the selection of beneficiaries for anti- poverty programs was to ground democracy at the village level. The 73rd Amendment, known as the Panchayat Raj Amendment, was envisioned as a means for establishing democracy at the village level (Thomas Isaac and Franke 2002). By ordering local government elections in every village, the amendment represented a top-down approach to instilling local governance in the hopes of deepening democracy, furthering local government accountability through village-level social audit, and enabling better delivery of public social
32 Decentralization in India – rooting the state services to improve citizen’s social wellbeing. It mandated a uniform, three- tiered structure of subnational governments throughout India’s large states (see Figure 2.2), a two-tiered structure in small states, and left to state governments the changing of state laws in order to conform to the constitutional amendment as well as the implementation of these structures. The uniform three-tiered local government structure in all states was to include elected representatives at the district level (the level right below each Indian state in rural areas), village or Gram Panchayat level (or a group of villages if so specified by the governor of the respective state), and an intermediate level “between the village and district levels specified by the Governor of a State by public notification to be the inter mediate level” (Government of India 1992). All local governments were to have uniform five-year terms, with direct elections to constitute new panchayats to be held before the expiry of the five-year term. An independent Election Commission was mandated for each state to supervise and direct local government elections. Of particular note was the 73rd Amendment’s defining of the Gram Sabha as constituting all registered voters within the Gram Panchayat. These Gram Sabhas were to meet regularly and were seen as the main mechanism for providing accountability and citizen feedback in the local government system. By being entrusted with reviewing Gram Panchayat accounts and reports, the Gram Sabha was essentially given an auditing function. Importantly, the Gram Sabha meetings were to identify the village beneficiaries of anti-poverty programs. Though some researchers of decentralization in India have argued that the wording of the 73rd Amendment was vague and did not devolve substantial powers to local governments (Oommen 1995; Jha 1999; Manor 2004), the polit ical powers entrusted to village governments and the quotas to ensure the parti cipation of disadvantaged groups represented a decisive break from the past District-level Panchayat Representatives are directly elected. Chairpersons of block-level panchayats, as well as members of parliament, MLAs, and MLCs, can be representatives.
Taluk/Block-level Panchayat Representatives are directly elected. Chairpersons of Gram Panchayats, as well as members of parliament, MLAs, and MLCs, can be representatives of this intermediate panchayat.
Village/Gram-level Panchayat Gram Panchayat representatives, including the head of the Gram Panchayat, are directly elected by voters within the panchayat’s jurisdiction.
Figure 2.2 The three-tiered panchayat structure.
Decentralization in India – rooting the state 33 top-down approach to government in India. Prior to the passage of the amend ment, the election of local governments had been at the discretion of the indi vidual state governments. This meant that with a few exceptions, local government elections had not taken place for several decades and that rural development was managed by state government-appointed officials charged with implementing the various public rural development and anti-poverty programs. Political and administrative power, oversight and accountability rested at the district or state level. Before implementation of the PRIs there was also no institutional mechanism for citizens of a village to communicate with the govern ment, nor any mechanism for holding accountable the civil servants who managed rural development programs. The passing of the 73rd Amendment changed this, providing village residents with a direct role in managing rural development programs, ranging from anti-poverty schemes to education and health service delivery, and institutionalized channels of communication from the villages up through the block and district and state levels. It also encouraged fiscal decentralization to increase the resources available at the village level for social and economic development. One of the most path-breaking aspects of the 73rd Amendment was its attempt at social engineering by mandating quotas or “reserved seats” for formerly disenfranchised groups. One-third of all panchayat seats, urban and rural, at all tiers of local government, including the seats for the chairperson of the respective panchayats, were reserved for women. Moreover, among these positions reserved for women, there was to be a rotation of caste backgrounds in the reserved seats. Furthermore, a percentage of panchayat seats that reflected the percentage of Scheduled Castes (SC) and Scheduled Tribes (ST) in the local district’s popula tion were reserved for SC and ST, including seats for the chairperson of the panchayats. Of the seats reserved for the SC/ST population, one-third had to be reserved for SC/ST women (Government of India 1992). The reserved position of chairperson of the panchayats was also to be rotated among different panchayats within a district. State legislatures were given additional powers to further reserve panchayat seats for vulnerable or “backward groups” within their state. Moreover, in 1996 the Panchayat Act was extended to cover tribal areas of states, designated as “Scheduled Areas.” The Provisions of the Panchayats (Extension to the Scheduled Areas) Act, 1996, was added to ensure that local gov ernment structures would respect the customary law, social and religious practices, and traditional community resources management of the respective tribal communities. This Act also took the opportunity to more specifically define the duties of the local governments across India, the Gram Panchayat in particular. The Act stated that in Scheduled Areas, the Gram Sabha was to function as a cultural storehouse in order “to safeguard and preserve the traditions and customs of the people, their cultural identity, community resources and the customary mode of disputes resolution” (Government of India 1996). Yet this Act also further defined the role of the Gram Sabha as being the key institution through which participatory democracy would be enabled. The Gram Sabha was given the responsibility of approving all public socioeconomic development programs and
34 Decentralization in India – rooting the state projects for their village before they were implemented. Gram Sabhas were also to identify or select the beneficiaries of these development programs. By reiterating that the power to give final approval to social and anti-poverty programs and select beneficiaries for these programs rested not with Gram Panchayat representatives, but instead with the village electorate, this Act further clarified that the local village electorate were to play an integral part in the delivery and targeting of public programs aimed at improving social wellbeing. The linking of local governments and public programs aimed at improving development in rural areas was for the first time legally enshrined in the 73rd Amendment. Article 243G of the 73rd Amendment stated that states should transfer “powers and authority” in order to enable panchayats “to function as institutions of self-governance” (Government of India 1992). The same Article also suggested the devolution of responsibilities and powers to local govern ments for the preparation of plans and implementation of programs with regards to two overall responsibilities, economic development and social justice. Article 243G further stated that the broad category of economic development and social justice is specified in the 11th Schedule to the 73rd Amendment. This schedule devolved a wide-ranging list of 29 subject areas to the village panchayats (see Appendix A), from implementation of land reforms and poverty and social wel fare programs, to delivery of education and health services, and investment in physical infrastructure (Government of India 1992). This transfer of responsib ility to local governments in such a wide range of areas was significant because the central government had had extensive anti-poverty programs in place for • Panchayats, or local governments, were to be institutions of self-government. • A three-tiered structure of local governments at the sub-state levels of district, block and village levels for all states with populations over two million. States with smaller populations were to have a two-tiered structure of local governments. • One-third of seats at all levels of local governments were to be reserved for women, including the seat of the chairperson. • Seats at all levels of local government were to be reserved for members of the Scheduled Castes and Scheduled Tribes in proportion to their percentage of the local population, including the seat of the chairperson. • Direct elections every five years of local government representatives at all levels. • The village electorate, or Gram Sabha, was to deliberate and approve socioeconomic development programs of the Gram Panchayat, or village government, and be responsible for the selection of beneficiaries of anti-poverty programs. • A State Finance Commission was to be created in each state to review panchayat finances every five years and to decide on allocation of State funds to the different layers of the panchayats. • A State Electoral Commission was to be created to prepare for and conduct all panchayat elections.
Figure 2.3 Key provisions of the 73rd Amendment mandating rural decentralization (source: Government of India 1992). Note Emphasis added.
Decentralization in India – rooting the state 35 several decades, yet the efficiency and effectiveness of these programs had been low. The 1993 Panchayat Act was a conscious move to anchor at the local level a wide range of central government-funded programs aimed at decreasing pov erty, which included a rural employment guarantee program, a food-for-work program, a rural housing program, and a national microenterprise program. Statutory recognition of local governments was a vehicle for furthering self- governance at the village level (Jha 2000a) and ensuring that self-governance would help improve social welfare. By involving local citizens in the planning, targeting, monitoring, and evaluation of public social programs and policies, this decentralization of political powers to village citizens had an explicit focus on improving social wellbeing. In addition to laying out the transfer of powers and functions to the lower tiers of government as part of the overall decentralization process, the Amendment included a vague statement about local governments receiving adequate funds in order to carry out their responsibilities. Thus, the transfer of funds to panchayat institutions, though suggested, was not mandated, making the Indian decentralization program one of political, not fiscal, decentralization. All states were to pass legislation in order to conform with the 73rd Amendment and schedule elections to panchayats every five years. Since the passage of the 73rd Amendment and its implementation throughout India, there have been various studies on the panchayat system (Webster 1992a, 1992b; Singh 1999; World Bank 2000b, 2000c, 2000d; Crook and Manor 2001; Bhattacharya 2002). Other studies focus on specific aspects of decentralization (Blair 2000; Besley et al. 2004a, 2004b; Chattopadhyay and Duflo 2004). Though most of the studies of decentralization in India focus on a particular state or issue, there are emerging data and research on how individual local govern ments and aspects of governance have fared during the nearly two decades since the passage of the decentralization law. The larger debate on the impact of Panchayat Raj Institutions in India since the constitutional changes of 1992/1993 mirrors the general debate about the nature and extent of decentralization. In India as in most decentralizing countries, political decentralization has been legally mandated, though administrative and financial decentralization to local governments have lagged behind. Political decentralization was accomplished through the legal institutionalization of three tiers of elected local governments in all rural areas of large Indian states and the transfer of responsibilities of socioeconomic development to village governments.
Administrative decentralization Administrative decentralization aims to redistribute responsibility, authority, and financial resources for the provision of public services to subnational, and in the Indian case sub-state, levels of government. It involves the transfer of respons ibility of specified public functions from central governments, ministries, and agencies to field units of these agencies, so that local civil servants come under the jurisdiction of local governments. The 73rd Amendment did not entail any
36 Decentralization in India – rooting the state specific measures for administrative decentralization, and subsequent attention to this aspect of decentralization has been minimal. Yet the 73rd Amendment implied that decentralization should include the transfer of jurisdiction over local civil servants to local governments. Article 243G of the Amendment states that state legislatures may endow panchayats with the power to enable their functioning as “institutions of self-government” and that the devolution of powers to panchayats would include the preparation and implementation of programs to address economic development and social justice (Government of India 1992). Public programs to address socioeconomic development and justice were all adminis tered by civil servants, and if local governments were to act as institutions of self- government and be responsible for socioeconomic development in their area, they would need authority over those civil servants. Thus, administrative decentralization was implied, but remained a weak aspect of decentralization in the Indian context. A series of World Bank studies commend India for being among the top performers among developing countries in terms of political decentralization, though in terms of administrative decentralization – the delegation of “agents of higher levels of governments into lower level arenas” (Manor 1999) – India is found to perform poorly (World Bank 2000b, 2000c, 2000d).
Fiscal decentralization In contrast to the weak focus on administrative decentralization in the 73rd Amendment, the law did entail some guidelines on fiscal decentralization and subsequent measures have tried to deepen it. Overall, compared to other developing countries, India has a greater degree of fiscal decentralization due to its federal structure. The new nature of Indian fiscal decentralization, or the transfer of responsibility for expenditure and/or revenues to subnational govern ments, was laid out in Article 243H of the 73rd Amendment. It states that “. . . the Legislature of a State may, by law, a) authorize a Panchayat to levy, collect and appropriate such taxes, duties, tolls and fees . . . b) assign to a Panchayat such taxes, duties, tolls and fees levied and collected by the State Government . . .” and “provide for making such grants-in-aid to the Panchayats . . .” (Government of India 1992). The areas crucial to fiscal decentralization – autonomy to determine allocation of expenditures and ability to raise revenue – are mentioned, but sub- state delegation of these authorities is not mandatory. However, Article 243I of the Amendment required the creation of State Finance Commissions within a year of passage of the 73rd Amendment, and every five years thereafter, in order to review the financial allocations to and financial positions of panchayats. Fiscal decentralization also needs to be viewed in the context of market-oriented reforms that were adopted in 1991 in the wake of India’s economic crisis. The post-1991 opening of the Indian economy redefined the role of government in the economy and the fiscal relationship between the central government and the states. Opposing forces have since been at work with the transition from a relatively closed economy with centralized planning to resource allocation increasingly based on market signals. On the one hand this economic transition and parallel
Decentralization in India – rooting the state 37 political decentralization have led to greater flexibility and opportunities for states and local governments to allocate resources and deliver social services according to their priorities; on the other hand increasing inequalities between regions and states requires a greater role for the center (Rao, Shand et al. 1998). Transfers from central to state governments and on to local governments increased in the post-1993 period, in both relative and absolute terms. With the country’s increased prosperity, and as the states and local political leaders became more vocal and the participation of political parties became more pluralistic, greater demands for subnational and local resources were met with increased resource flows. The past two decades since the 73rd Amendment con tinued to see an increased transfer of resources from central to local govern ments, though resource mobilization by local governments continued to be limited and many decisions about allocations of funds continue to remain within the purview of the district and state governments (Vinod Vyasulu 2007). Fiscal transfers between the central government and the states, as a percentage of central government GDP at market prices during the respective Finance Commission periods, saw an overall rise over the past 60 years, with a decrease in transfers during the financial crisis of 1989–1995, and a rise since then (see Figure 2.4). Data on fiscal transfers from the central and state governments to 6
5
Percentage
4
3
Center–state transfers as a percentage of central government GDP (at market prices) during different Finance Commission (FC) periods
2
1
3r
d
FC
2n d
1s t
FC
(1 95 2
–1
95 (1 7) 95 7 FC –1 96 (1 2) 4t 96 h 2 FC –1 96 (1 6) 5t 96 h 6 FC –1 96 (1 9) 6t 96 h 9 FC –1 97 (1 4) 7t 97 h 4– FC 19 (1 79 8t 97 ) h 9 FC –1 9 (1 84 9t 98 ) h 4 FC –1 9 (1 89 10 98 ) th 9– FC 19 (1 95 11 99 ) th 5– FC 20 (2 00 12 00 ) th 0– FC 20 (2 05 00 ) 5– 20 10 )
0
Figure 2.4 Center–state financial transfers as a percentage of central government GDP, at market prices during the respective Finance Commission (FC) periods (source: Srivastava and Rao 2009).
38 Decentralization in India – rooting the state 10,000 9,000 8,000
Other revenue Grants-in-aid from state government Transfers from central government
Rupees (million)
7,000 6,000 5,000 4,000 3,000 2,000 1,000 0
2002–2003 2003–2004 2004–2005 2005–2006 2006–2007 2007–2008 Period
Figure 2.5 Local government revenue, 2002–2008 (million rupees) (source: Finance Commission of India 2010).
local governments has only been collected since 2002. However, as highlighted in Figure 2.5, transfers from central and state governments to local governments have increased during the period 2002–2008, while the total revenue of local governments has also increased. Fiscal decentralization, in terms of local gov ernments receiving increased funds at their disposal, has clearly occurred over the past two decades in India. Yet the increased flow of grants and overall trans fers of funds to local bodies are largely earmarked for particular activities or targeted to particular groups. The autonomy of the panchayats over allocation of this increased flow of money remains low (Jha 2000b). With an increase in resources flowing to local governments but little autonomy of local governments over allocation of these resources, the Indian government made attempts to ensure that Gram Panchayats, and Gram Sabhas in particular, played an increased role in resource management. While the federal structure left it up to each state to determine the extent and pace of decentralization, within the framework of the 73rd Amendment, the central gov ernment sought to provide guidelines and increased incentives to state govern ments to deepen decentralization. Various committees were established, particularly since the late 1990s, to recommend strategies for ensuring local
Decentralization in India – rooting the state 39 government input into the channeling and implementation of central governmentsponsored programs. Policy makers have encouraged states to transfer greater resources to the panchayats. For example, the 11th Finance Commission was constituted in 1998 to make recommendations, among other tasks, on transforming panchayats into “functionally, financially, and administratively viable institutions” (Pal 2000). Incentives were provided to encourage the states to follow up with the central government recommendations. In a 1999/2000 budget speech, the Finance Minister announced that in order to ensure that resources of the central govern ment’s wage employment programs were spent with the “active involvement of the elected PRIs,” the central government would only release the discretionary 20 percent of these funds if the state government had legislated “elected and empowered PRIs” (Task Force on Panchayati Raj Institutions 2001). In order to determine the extent to which states had devolved powers and empowered local governments, a Panchayat Raj Devolution Index was constructed, based on five indicators: (1) constitutional and political devolution; (2) administrative devolution; (3) financial devolution; (4) functional devolution; and (5) devolution of funds, functionaries and functions to Gram Sabhas (Task Force on Panchayati Raj Institutions 2001). While rankings of states based on this Devolution Index had not been done ten years later, the Indian government continued its attempts to cajole the states to further transfer funds, to devolve the 29 functions listed in the 11th Schedule to the 73rd Amendment, and to institute functionaries at the Gram Panchayat level charged with overseeing specific functions. The central government also turned to publishing available information on the degree of state compliance with the 11th Schedule. As seen in Table 2.1, states varied in their speed of delegating resources and transferring specific tasks to panchayat-level functionaries, with very few states following the spirit of the 73rd Amendment by delegating responsibility and funding for all 29 subject areas. The 73rd Amendment left it up to States to decide the extent of revenue collection they would delegate to panchayat institutions. The Amendment also mandated the setting up of State Finance Commissions (SFCs). All states complied and set up SFCs, yet most left the revenue-raising abilities of local governments unchanged. Local government institutions were assigned increased responsibil ities under the 73rd Amendment for social and economic development, but there was no corresponding increase in their revenue-raising powers to match these increased responsibilities (Government of India: Ministry of Rural Development 2001). The central government raises two-thirds of total public revenue, but controls and spends only one-third, while the state governments raise about one- third, yet control two-thirds of overall revenues (Rao 2000). The asymmetry in revenue raising is much more pronounced at the local government level. Financial powers of Gram Panchayats have increased in terms of the tied resources allotted to them, but are constrained in terms of their ability to raise taxes. Gram Panchayats have some powers to directly levy taxes, but they rarely impose taxes. International experience has shown that the capacity to raise local
Andhra Pradesh Arunachal Pradesh Assam Bihar Jharkhand Goa Gujarat Haryana Himachal Pradesh Karnataka Kerala Madhya Pradesh Chattisgarh Maharashtra Manipur Orissa
States/UTs
5 – – – – – – – 2 29 15 10 10 18 – 5
13 – – – – – – 16 23 29 29 23 23 18 22 25
2 – – – – – – – 7 29 15 9 9 18 4 3
24 29 29 29 29 29 29 29 27 – 14 19 19 11 29 24
16 29 29 29 29 29 29 13 6 – – 6 6 11 7 4
Function
27 29 29 29 29 29 29 29 22 – 14 20 20 11 25 26
Functionary
Fund
Functionary
Fund
Function
Nr. of departments/subjects yet to be transferred to Panchayats
Nr. of departments/subjects transferred to Panchayats
Table 2.1 Status of devolution of departments/subjects with funds, functions and functionaries to Panchayat Raj Institutions, by state, 2000 (research states in bold)
– 7 – 29 29 29 – 29 – 12 12 13 12 13 12 29 – – – – – 3 – 29 Panchayat system yet to be revived – 6 – –
Source: Task Force on Panchayati Raj Institutions 2001.
Punjab Rajasthan Sikkim Tamil Nadu Tripura Uttar Pradesh Uttaranchal West Bengal A&N Islands Chandigarh D&N Haveli Daman & Diu Delhi Lakshadweep Pondicherry
29 29 – 29 29 17 17 17 29 29 29 29 29 29
– – 29 – – 9 9 12 – – 3 – – –
23 29
22 – – – 17 16 16 – 29 29 26 –
29 29
29 29 – 29 29 20 20 17 29 29 26 29
42 Decentralization in India – rooting the state resources is greatly constrained by the local revenue base as well as the willingness to impose taxes on local constituents (Jha 2000b). In the Indian context, the issue of revenue-raising by Gram Panchayats is controversial. While some have argued that fiscal autonomy cannot be based on transfers alone (Oommen and Datta 1995), others have argued that local governments do not necessarily need their own revenues to operate effectively, as long as they have some autonomy over how they spend the transfers (Johnson 2003). The degree of actual auto nomy and financial needs at the village level, however, remains largely unknown, reflecting the dearth of village-level studies of panchayat functioning.
Political decentralization Beyond these general observations on administrative and fiscal decentralization, research findings on Indian political decentralization can be characterized as dichotomous, with both lines of argument found amongst policy makers, civil society, economists as well as political scientists. There is general agreement that since compliance with the 73rd Amendment in 1995, at least two rounds of panchayat elections have taken place, and reservations for SC/ST, as well as women, have been respected. All data, including the findings from this study, indicate that voter participation rates, which at around 60 percent in national elections are already high, are even higher in local elections, in some areas over 90 percent (Oommen 1995; Alsop and Kurey 2005). Yet general assessments of decentralization vary, largely based on ideology. One branch of findings, which is more firmly based in the liberal democratic tradition, argues that the measures taken by Indian states to conform to the 73rd Amendment have led towards effective decentralization and that the changes that have come in the wake of local government elections have had an overall posit ive effect. While there are differences within this branch of analysis of Indian decentralization with regard to the extent of political, administrative, and fiscal decentralization, as well as with regard to the democratic depth of the reform and degree to which different aspects of the 73rd Amendment have been implemented, the literature is unified in arguing that the passage of the Panchayat Raj Amendment was overall a positive development. The other branch of research is more critical of the 73rd Amendment and the outcomes of decentralization in India. While divided on why they find decentralization in India to be prob lematic, those advancing this line of argument stress that while all Indian states have passed legislation to conform to the 73rd Amendment and now have legally mandated elected local governments, these changes have been largely superficial and have not led to substantial changes in local powers over bureaucrats, social hierarchy, elite capture, or mechanisms that allow for greater accountability and democratic deepening. The findings of this book illustrate that the impact of the panchayat legislation has not been uniform. While the overall result has been positive, even in states like Uttar Pradesh where panchayats largely are not empowered, the efficacy of local governments ranges widely from state to state. A state’s history of
Decentralization in India – rooting the state 43 decentralization, political competition, and social mobilization are key factors in determining the ability of village governments to improve their citizens’ wellbeing. Three areas that have the potential for changing local governance in India are the impact of reservations of seats for SC/ST and women, the interaction between panchayats and the bureaucracy, and the issue of social hierarchy and elite capture. Quantitative studies of the effect of quotas for socioeconomically vulnerable groups on their social wellbeing are encouraging. For example, Chattopadhaya and Duflo have studied the impact of quotas for women and SC panchayat leaders in village governments in West Bengal and Rajasthan. Their study finds that both women and SC heads of Gram Panchayats were more likely to make decisions that benefited women and the SC population, and that the panchayat system, with its quotas, represents an important vehicle for women’s empowerment in rural India (Chattopadhyay and Duflo 2004). Their findings underscore the important potential social implications of the 73rd Amendment, with its measures to provide access to representation and political power for groups generally disenfranchised in the Indian political system. Their findings that quotas may improve targeting of social services suggest that the correction of imbalanced political agency might also help correct inequities in other areas (Sen 1999; Chattopadhyay and Duflo 2004). Though reservations for women and SC/ST might only be enabling conditions for the larger project of empowerment (Hust 2007), and outcomes might not be uniform, guaranteed or immediate, these initial studies nevertheless point to their potential for improving the social impact of the local government system. Nevertheless, studies of the impact of reservations in India are few and the causal mechanisms that account for greater impact of reservations in some areas compared to others remain poorly understood. Many critics of the local government reform have pointed to the Indian civil service system and the hold it retains on local distribution of resources and polit ical power as a barrier to functioning local governments (Jha 1999; Mukarji 1999; World Bank 2000b, 2000d). The Indian administrative structure has played an important role since independence – a role it is not keen to relinquish. With independence, the roles of the civil service changed from collecting local revenue and maintaining law and order for the British Empire, to contributing toward India’s extensive planning requirements as well as implementing poverty reduction and development plans (Jha 1999). While the post-independence constitution paid lip-service to the importance of local governments in furthering development, the merit-based and prestigious Indian Administrative Service (IAS) was charged with managing the bureaucracy and implementing central and state government programs at the subnational levels. As the powers entrusted to the IAS grew, its size grew exponentially (Frankel 1990) and with it also the incentives to retain powers for program implementation rather than devolve these to local governments. The tension was evident between the rhetoric of local governments as agents of self-governance and development and the reality of non-elected district and
44 Decentralization in India – rooting the state block-level civil servants charged with administering anti-poverty and other rural development programs. When in the 1970s, under the tenure of Prime Minister Indira Gandhi, the District Rural Development Agency (DRDA) was created to administer national poverty reduction programs in rural areas, rural development came under the administrative control of state governments and was generally administered by District Collectors (Jha 1999; Johnson 2003). From the 1970s until the passage of the 73rd Amendment, the official locus of revenue and rural development program distribution and thereby political power was largely in the hands of district-level administrators (who are Indian Administrative Service officers). In response to the 73rd Amendment, the central government in 1995 decided to bring the DRDA under the purview of the district-level panchayat system (Jha 2000b), but the tensions between the civil service and panchayats remained. Most importantly, the idea that decentralization would lead to increased local transparency in the financing and implementation of rural development programs and an overall increase in accountability stood in contradiction to the kind of institution the Indian bureaucracy had become by the early 1990s. As several observers of the Indian civil service have pointed out, the incentive structure within the service had led to widespread charges of corruption, lack of transparency, and little accountability to the citizens whom they were supposed to serve (Wade 1994; Crook and Manor 1998; Johnson 2003). This bureaucracy was obviously likely to resist decentralization of powers to local governments. This tension between the ideals behind the 73rd Amendment and the local structures and institutions likely to resist its implementation was recognized by a 2001 government task force report on panchayats. This task force recommended greater autonomy and a greater role for panchayats in furthering local development and encouraged closer cooperation between local, state, and central government and the civil service system (Government of India: Ministry of Rural Development 2001). Another main issue that recurs in the decentralization literature, and particu larly the debate about decentralization in India, is whether decentralization of political and financial authority to local governments can lead to new opportun ities for local elite capture of these new resources and powers (Echeverri-Gent 1992; Jha 1999; Government of India: Ministry of Rural Development 2001; Johnson 2003; Krishna 2003; Mathew and Mathew 2003). In the Indian context, particularly in village settings where caste, class, gender, and religious cleavages still dominate, Gram Panchayats and their new political powers and resources presented an opportunity for locally dominant groups to capture the resources at the local government’s disposal. Decentralization, with its focus on empowerment, democratization, and social improvement, might be hijacked in situations where social and cultural hierarchies enable local capture of political power structures. A series of World Bank studies of decentralization in India have pointed out that instead of furthering equity, decentralization can actually “bolster the power of elites” (World Bank 2000b, 2000c, 2000d). The 73rd Amendment aimed at increased accountability by reserving the seats of representatives and panchayat heads for women and SC/ST, endowing the
Decentralization in India – rooting the state 45 village electorate in the Gram Sabha with deliberative and audit powers, and instituting mandatory elections every five years. These measures represented an attempt to bring greater democratic depth into village politics, by bringing in groups formerly largely excluded from village politics and building in safeguards to ensure that elected representatives fulfilled their obligations to represent their communities. In the past, studies of attempted decentralization in India have consistently shown that elites, largely men from upper-caste backgrounds, continued to capture political offices and the resources associated with those offices (Slater 1989; Echeverri-Gent 1992; Singh 1993; Jha 1999; World Bank 2000b, 2000c, 2000d; T. N. Srivastava 2002). Post-1993, with the quotas and the Gram Sabha in place to increase accountability, initial reports highlight a persistent lack of accountability and a failure to decisively break elite stranglehold on local power. Observers have pointed to the persistence of “informal patterns of domination and power” at the village level where, for example, reservations for women are usurped by male relatives, and reservations for SC/ST are coopted by local elites (Johnson 2003). Yet the causal mechanisms that enable persistence of elite capture in some areas while allowing other local governments to be more inclusive and democratic remain under-studied. There is increased recognition that the ability of women and SC/ST to participate in local governments depends on the underlying power structures in the village. However, whether the inter action of local power structures with elected and formal local political institutions in turn changes those power structures, and whether top-down mandated decentralization has the ability to change local social hierarchies and systems of domination and exclusion in the Indian context, remain questions. Some recent research (Chattopadhyay and Duflo 2004) points out that democratic empowerment of groups traditionally excluded from local political power can lead to Gram Panchayats acting as agents of change and undermining traditional hierarchies of power. While supporters of Indian decentralization have focused on the potential for local governments to root democracy, to include groups traditionally excluded from social and political power, and to improve local social development, detractors have pointed to the remaining barriers to decentralization and development such as bureaucratic unwillingness to share power and elite capture. Initial assessments of decentralization in India have pointed to both successes and failures, highlighting the complexity with which a uniformly mandated local gov ernment structure interacts with local conditions to produce differing outcomes. Unequivocal changes to the democratic nature, power structure, and local resources of local governments have taken place in the wake of the 1993 ratification of India’s 73rd Amendment. This study sets out to highlight the complex interactions with local government of Gram Panchayat structures having differing state-level histories, social mobilization, and political competition, to bring about diverse outcomes in social wellbeing.
46 Decentralization in India – rooting the state
Village studies in three states: the local nature of Gram Panchayats This study will examine decentralization in six villages across three Indian states over the nearly two decades since the 73rd Amendment. The findings highlight how the combination of state and local factors enable good local governance and more effective delivery of social welfare programs through local governments. Decentralization was intended to go beyond the mere election of local govern ment representatives to manage local affairs and help implement central and state government programs. Decentralization in India was to provide an institutionalized arena where the local population could participate in local government decision-making. Through increased participation in the selection of welfare program beneficiaries and allocation of local government resources, local popu lations were to exert greater direct influence on their development. Nearly two decades after legally mandating decentralization in India, the emerging results are mixed, with panchayats in some states functioning more in the spirit of the 73rd Amendment than panchayats in other states. The history of decentralization within a state, political competition, social cleavages (including whether socio economic elites capture government institutions), and social mobilization, are key ingredients in determining the ability of village governments to deepen democracy and have an impact on their citizens’ wellbeing. Different combinations of these factors have led to varying degrees of democratic rooting and efficacy of local governments. Using the literal definition of democracy as “rule of the people,” this study analyzes whether decentralized local governments do function as set out in India’s 73rd Constitutional Amendment, thereby “rooting” democracy at the village level. The study is a comparative analysis of decentralization focusing on local, village-level governments’ ability to matter for the social wellbeing of individuals in rural India. Decentralization is defined in this case to be the polit ical transfer of power down to the local, village level as set forth in the 73rd Amendment to India’s constitution. At the same time, the definition of decentralization used here goes beyond the delegation of powers set forth in the 73rd Amendment to include the qualitative nature of democracy. Decentralization is taken to mean democratic decentralization where the functioning of local gov ernments matters – for example, in terms of elite capture versus competitive democracy, or deliberative aspects of village electorate meetings. The case studies look at the arguments behind decentralization relating to enhancing democracy and improving the functioning of government. Looking at democratic depth as an indicator for successful decentralization follows Amartya Sen’s notion that democracy should be thought of as having direct, instrumental and constructive roles in improving socioeconomic wellbeing (Sen 1999). Social wellbeing in this research context is defined to include not only poverty status, but also other social indicators such education and health.
Decentralization in India – rooting the state 47
The argument The main argument of this study is that democratically functioning local govern ments are able to effectively oversee the equitable implementation of social programs, thereby contributing to citizen welfare. The key determinants of their capacity to have an impact on social wellbeing, besides the history of decentralization in the state, are the extent of local political competition, and the presence of a mobilized civil society that engages with local governments and holds them accountable, thereby preventing capture of panchayats by local social or political elites. When these governments are genuinely representative, accountable, and democratic, they function as they were intended by the 73rd Amendment. They are able to achieve the intended goal of local implementation of social programs, particularly anti-poverty and social welfare schemes (see Figure 2.3). Yet the specific conditions and local dynamics that enable panchayats to function as agents of self-government and bring about improvements in social wellbeing are complex and dynamic. Local governance exhibits some path-dependent tendencies that can be overcome with significant political realignment. Governance outcomes also depend on local factors, from local distribution of social and polit ical power to mobilization of civil society – both of which are partially path- dependent but are also driven by dynamic interactions and processes at the village level. Understanding the local contexts in which local governments are more likely to function as agents of change is crucial to understanding decentralization’s likely impact on and the mechanisms by which it affects the rooting of demo cracy and improvement of social wellbeing. Moreover, key to understanding why local governments work better in some contexts are the perceptions of cit izens. Findings from this research’s surveys qualitative interviews and focus group discussions conducted during months living in the case study villages yielded that panchayats can contribute towards better-functioning schools, targeting of poverty programs to those in need, and delivery of health care services by local health care workers. When local governments select beneficiaries for social programs based on need and are able to implement these social welfare programs, they are able to boost social welfare through raising awareness, bringing government closer to the people, cementing social capital, and improving accountability. Recent economic growth has led to a growing middle class in India, but overall the socioeconomic welfare of the poor has not improved greatly. Moreover, the conventional wisdom advocating increasing economic growth rates under strong central and state governments has not always provided the answer in India, where higher growth-rate states have not done better than others in improving the welfare of the poor. For example, as seen in Table 2.2, poverty rates decreased most dramatically in Karnataka during the period from 1993/1994 to 1999/2000, as well as between 1993/1994 and 2004/2005.3 Moreover, the rates of poverty decrease for Karnataka over both time periods were significantly higher than the Indian average. By contrast, reductions in poverty
48 Decentralization in India – rooting the state Table 2.2 Poverty rates for selected states and all-India average Poverty rate Poverty rate Poverty rate 1993/1994 1999/2000 2004/2005 (% population) (% population) (% population; mixed recall period)
% change between 1993/1994 and 1999/2000
% change between 1993/1994 and 2004/2005
Karnataka 33 Uttar Pradesh 41 West Bengal 36
20 31 27
17 26 21
39 24 25
48 37 42
All-India
26
22
28
39
36
Source: Planning Commission 2011.
rates in Uttar Pradesh and West Bengal for the same time periods were at or below the Indian average. These lower than average poverty rate reductions in West Bengal during the earlier time period (1993/1994 to 1999/2000) came despite the fact that per capita growth in net state domestic product (NSDP) was comparable to Karnataka (both around 5.5 percent) and was above the Indian average of 4.6 percent (see Table 2.3) (Bhandari and Kale 2007a). Above average economic growth rates in West Bengal during the 1990s therefore did not lead to above average poverty rate reductions. Similar patterns are found in other Indian states. States with high economic growth rates have not always been able to translate the growth into better social wellbeing for their citizens. Increased inequalities between Indian states over the past two decades since economic liberalization are evident in the widening of inter-state economic disparities (Ahluwalia 2000) as well as disparities in social indicators. The last two decades of increased economic growth and market-oriented reforms, along with India’s democratic structure and history, have buttressed the legitimacy of the economic and political structure while providing rewards largely to the upper and middle classes. Pro-poor governments in individual states have not provided the answer, since some of these states – notably West Bengal – have not achieved the large improvements in social outcomes that were expected. Moreover, increased social inequalities have led to a rise in social tensions. States, such as communist-ruled West Bengal, have witnessed the rebirth of an increasingly violent Maoist insurgency, which has now spread to 20 states and a third of the country’s districts (Ghosh and Das 2010). Furthermore, another line of reasoning has argued that Indian states with a high degree of subnational cohesive community have better social service provision (Singh 2008). Yet a large Indian state with arguably the highest level of subnational cohesion, West Bengal, is not among the leading states in social service provision or indicators. Conventional theories do not explain the range of social welfare outcomes among Indian states. Since a top-down focus on federal and state structures and policies has not yielded the anticipated improvements in poverty, it is necessary to evaluate the delivery of social programs to intended beneficiaries at the local level. Key to
Decentralization in India – rooting the state 49 understanding why economic growth and top-down policies have not provided adequate solutions to poverty alleviation is the fact that those left out by the pro cess of socioeconomic development have often not had a vehicle for expressing their grievances. Existing political institutions provide the poor with few choices for participation or dissent. The history of centralized governance in India, combined with deep inequalities, has resulted in a shortage of accountable local political structures in most Indian states. Lack of participatory local democracy has meant that large parts of redistributive schemes have been captured by local bureaucracies, often in conjunction with local elites. The following chapters illustrate that decentralization is a complex process. In the long run, as literacy and awareness of rights in India increases, top-down decentralization will lead to better targeted social and anti-poverty programs and enhanced social wellbeing. Over the shorter term, however, state-level differ ences matter. A state’s history of decentralization and empowerment of local governments matters, yet it is not a sufficient condition on its own. As seen with a comparison of West Bengal and Karnataka, a longer history of functioning local governments in the case of West Bengal does not equate with better social outcomes. Beyond having a history of decentralization, political competition in local elections, a mobilized and aware civil society, as well as the nature and dominance of local elites, will influence the structure, process, and pace of local government efficacy. Social services in the pre-1993 period were often marginally functional at best in Indian villages because control over these services was located in far- away district, state or central government administrations. At great distance from administering agencies and without any local structures to provide for feedback mechanisms and accountability, the delivery of social programs often becomes coopted by local elites in conjunction with administering bureaucrats. Without local structures of authority, the poor who cannot access the social services to which they are entitled are left without recourse. They are forced to accept a situation in which local elites and bureaucrats absorb social sector resources intended for them, and where political competition, which might provide them with access to power (or at least representation), is circumscribed. Since this has been the status quo for decades in the majority of Indian states, the most disempowered are left without an avenue for expressing their needs and grievances. It is the lack of effective social service delivery mechanisms in many regions in India, along with widening social disparities, that lends urgency to explora tions of new government structures, such as decentralization, which might counter this trend. Advocates believe that a democratically functioning panchayat system allows people to voice their grievances (Mathew 1994b). Through neighborhood representation and village meetings, these democratic local gov ernments increase awareness of rights, which in turn augment the likelihood of people demanding delivery of services. It also leads to greater awareness and pride through enhanced social interaction within the community and greater awareness of the needs and concerns of more vulnerable groups such as women (Cadwell 1986; Drèze et al. 1995). Moreover, one of the most innovative aspects
42 41 31 33 26 16.2 0.314
Poverty Headcount ratio, 1987/1988 (e) Headcount ratio, 1993/1994 (e) Headcount ratio, 1999/2000 (e) Headcount ratio, 2004/2005 based on uniform recall period (e) Headcount ratio, 2004/2005 based on mixed recall period (e) Sen’s Welfare Index, rural areas, 1987/1988 (c) Human Development Index, 2001 (d)
45 36 27 25 21 20.1 0.404
917 934 947 58 69 77 55 48 0.404 0.472
20 66
6,756 36,322 2.5 5.5 5.1
West Bengal
38 33 20 25 17 15.3 0.412
960 965 968 56 67 76 53 43 0.412 0.478
72 57
7,838 40,998 3.7 5.7 5.2
Karnataka
39 36 26 28 22 15.5 0.381
927 933 940 52 65 74 71 – 0.381 –
– –
7,690 37,490 – 4.6 5.4
All-India
Sources: (a) Reserve Bank of India 2011a; (b) Government of India 2001; (c) Drèze and Sen 2002; (d) Government of Karnataka 1999; (e) Planning Commission 2011; (f) Centre for Economic and Social Studies 2008; (g) Roy and Bhattacharjee 2009; (h) Government of India 2011.
876 898 908 42 56 70 85 73 0.314 0.388
20 78
Physical infrastructure % rural households with electricity, 2001 (b) % rural households with any assets listed by census (TV, radio, telephone, bike, etc.), 2001 (b)
Human development Sex ratio (females/1,000 males), 1991 (c) Sex ratio (females/1,000 males), 2001 (b) Sex ratio (females/1,000 males), 2011 provisional (j) Adult literacy rate, 1991 (d) Adult literacy rate, 2001 (b) Adult literacy rate, 2011, provisional (h) Infant mortality rate (IMR), 1995 (d) IMR, 2005 (f) Human Development Index (HDI), 1991 (b) HDI, 2001 (g)
5,066 18,214 1.9 2.0 2.8
Uttar Pradesh
Per capita net state domestic product (NSDP), 1993/1994 (in current prices) (rupees) (a) Per capita NSDP, 2008/2009 (in current prices) (rupees) (a) Average annual per capita NSDP growth, 1980/1981 to 1993/1994 (at constant prices) (%) (a) Average annual per capita NSDP growth, 1993/1994 to 1999/2000 (at constant prices) (%) (a) Average annual per capita NSDP growth, 1999/2000 to 2008/2009 (at constant prices) (%) (a)
Table 2.3 Interstate and all-India comparison of key indicators in research states
Decentralization in India – rooting the state 51 of the panchayat system in India today is that it reserves a third of all panchayat seats for women and a further percentage for scheduled castes and tribes. The panchayat system gives voice and representation to poorer and generally more vulnerable groups, thereby instituting a system of affirmative action that is intended to improve the welfare of more vulnerable groups over the long term. The analysis set forth in subsequent chapters will illustrate that if poverty in India is to be substantially reduced, and social indicators greatly improved, policy must improve the institutionalization of local governments, while recognizing that structural conditions at the village level will determine the pace at which local governments are empowered and able to function as catalysts for improving social wellbeing. These local governments should be encouraged to function in a democratic manner that allows for participation of all citizens regardless of caste, gender, religion or political background. Moreover, these local governments must be empowered to oversee implementation of social wel fare programs, including anti-poverty schemes, and ensure accountability of local civil servants employed in the delivery of social services, such as schoolteachers. Building up effective local governance systems, which empower disenfranchised groups and increase their control over resources designated to improve their welfare, is essential to improving social welfare in India. The major contribution of this research will be to present a comparative study of decentralization within one country, analyzing the conditions that are conducive towards efficacious local governments that help improve the social wellbeing of their constituents.
3 Karnataka – advances with the help of competitive local governments
Local governments in Karnataka were found to be high-functioning at the time of the research. In May 1993, Karnataka became the first Indian state to enact new legislation in conformity with the 73rd Constitutional Amendment, estab lishing the three-tiered panchayat system. At the end of 1993 it also became the first state to hold new panchayat elections. Since then, Karnataka has held four rounds of local government elections and has amended its panchayat law 15 times, making it in 2011 one of the most progressive local government laws in the country. How did one of the most progressive decentralization laws affect the functioning of local governments on the ground? As seen in Table 2.3, social and poverty indicators in Karnataka prior to the 1993 Panchayat Act compared favorably to indicators in West Bengal and Uttar Pradesh and were in most cases above India’s average around 1990. Twenty years later, average social indicators and poverty rates in particular were even better in Karnataka, having in many cases improved at a higher rate than in the two other states. While many socioeconomic and political changes have taken place in Karnataka since the early 1990s, particularly in urban areas, social indicators also improved in rural areas. These improved social indicators in rural areas raise the question of whether decentralization during the 1990s enabled Gram Panchayats in Karnataka to actively target and implement development programs, contributing to increased social wellbeing in Karnataka. Karnataka, in southern India, is a large Indian state like Uttar Pradesh and West Bengal, with a population of over 60 million. Yet that is where, for the most part, similarities end. At the turn of the twenty-first century Karnataka’s socioeconomic indicators, such as literacy and infant mortality rates (IMRs), were better than those in Uttar Pradesh and equal to or better than indicators in West Bengal, as seen in Table 2.3. With regards to poverty rates in particular by 2011, Karnataka’s rates as well as improvement of these rates since the early 1990s were among the lowest of states in the country. Overall social indicators were not as impressive as those found in the well-studied state of Kerala, Karnataka’s southern neighbor, though by 2011 they were above the national average. The late 1980s and the 1990s brought improvements in socioeconomic indicators in Karnataka, improvements that generally have been ascribed to the growth of the service sector in urban areas and the state capital of Bangalore in particular.
Karnataka – competitive local governments 53 However, Karnataka’s net state domestic product growth rates, averaging 5.7 percent annually between 1993/1994 and 1999/2000 and 5.2 percent between 1999/2000 and 2008/2009, were comparable to those of West Bengal (see Table 2.3). While economic growth in urban areas has certainly helped to improve social wellbeing, it alone cannot explain Karnataka’s improving social indicators since other high-growth states such as Punjab, Haryana, and Gujarat have not seen the same rates of improvement. This research investigates an explanation for improving social wellbeing in Karnataka that has not been explored; namely, the state’s more competitive and functioning local governments compared to Uttar Pradesh and West Bengal. While economic growth in the state has undoubtedly helped Karnataka’s fortunes, increased revenues alone do not improve the implementation and targeting of anti-poverty programs. Karnataka had favorable economic conditions and competitive politics in the state capital that were complemented by dynamic and competitive local governments in rural areas to promote socioeconomic development. Local government structures were placed in an environment more conducive to enabling social improvements – a rural fabric of more competitive politics where village elites did not obstruct or undermine local governance while civil society was largely self-aware. Karnataka differs from both of the other two case study states in that it has a history of experimenting with one of the most innovative forms of local govern ment in the 1980s – although only for one election term. It experienced functioning and innovative local governments, in contrast to Uttar Pradesh, and yet this experiment only lasted for a five-year period, in contrast to the three decades of functioning local governments in West Bengal. However, Karnataka’s panchayat system of the 1980s and its current panchayat system differ from the system in West Bengal in one important aspect: in Karnataka, local governments have functioned in an environment of competitive party politics and elections. Local governments in Karnataka, though far from the ideal set forth by local govern ment proponents and not fully in line with the spirit of the Karnataka Panchayat Amendment Act of 1993, are functioning and competitive. No single leading group or party dominates state or local politics. Local governments implement social welfare programs in a way that is less likely to be driven by local elites or party politics.
Socioeconomic and political context Before investigating the local government system that Karnataka pioneered in the 1980s, it is important to understand the socioeconomic as well as the polit ical context. Social inequalities between people of different caste backgrounds in Karnataka have not been as extreme or oppressive, which in turn makes caste in Karnataka more resilient, but also more legitimate in the perspective of those who are dominated (as quoted in Manor 1997). Key to understanding the less divisive socioeconomic divisions in Karnataka is the fact that numerically large and dominant groups are not at the top of the caste hierarchy and that much of
54 Karnataka – competitive local governments the population of agricultural laborers have at least some access to land (Manor 1989). Unlike many other states, particularly in northern India, Karnataka has experienced extensive agricultural reforms, including land reforms, which like those in the neighboring state of Kerala have followed the more radical “land to the tiller” legislation, though they were slow in the implementation (Herring in Kadekodi et al. 2007). Most of those who belong to the socioeconomically most disadvantaged groups are therefore not landless and are able to eke out a living. Unlike Uttar Pradesh – where politics at the local level have been dominated by socioeconomic elites – and unlike West Bengal – where local politics have for three decades been dominated by political elites – local and state-level pol itics in Karnataka have been more competitive for the last two decades. The Congress party, under the power of Devraj Urs, dominated much of Karnataka state politics during the 1970s, with politics working largely through on a patron–client system rather than competitive elections.1 Yet even during the 1970s, politics were dominated not by one large sociopolitical elite, as in Uttar Pradesh or West Bengal, but rather by three groups: the upper-caste Brahmins and two non-Brahmin caste groups, the Vokkaligas of mostly southern Karnataka and the Lingayats of northern Karnataka. These latter two caste groups, though they make up roughly only a quarter of the state’s population, own much of the cultivated land and thus have great influence over state politics (Thimmaiah and Aziz 1983). Although the Vokkaligas and Lingayats have regional bases, at the state level they compete for power, creating a situation that necessitates power sharing within larger coalitions, making for more stable and demo cratic power politics in Karnataka. The political competition between the Vokkaligas and Lingayats has created an environment where personalities are less important than group alliances and institutions, so that despite the cycling of power between different caste groups and political parties, no single individual, caste-group, or political party has been able to dominate politics in Karnataka over the last three decades. The competition among social groups is mirrored in the competition among political parties. Since 1983, when the Janata Dal Party (JD) came to power in Karnataka, breaking the Congress Party’s hold on power and introducing an innovative new panchayat system, alternation of ruling parties in state elections has become the norm. Since parties alternate in power, no politician or party has been able to dominate state politics or preside over an entrenched patron–client network. Though at times politicians have been powerful political actors – H. D. Deve Gowda was Chief Minister of Karnataka (1994–1996), went on to become Prime Minister of India, and then presided as head of the Janata Dal Secular Party (JD(S)) – the nearly continuous change of parties at state elections acts as a brake on any individual’s, and indeed any party’s, consolidation of power. The lack of a dominant party over the past two decades of state politics in Karnataka, along with the lack of dominant politicians and the preference for “rainbow coalitions,” has changed politics in Karnataka to where institutions matter more than individuals and the shifting political landscape displays remarkable policy continuity (Manor 2006), despite at times volatile state-level politics.
Karnataka – competitive local governments 55 Policy continuity and institutional stability through political alteration are key ingredients for understanding political and social developments in Karnataka. In contrast to Uttar Pradesh, where personalized patronage networks still dominate and local governments have little autonomy and in contrast to West Bengal, where three decades of virtual one-party rule largely dominated by a party leader have subordinated all politics and bureaucracy to party rule – the bureaucracy in Karnataka has been able to retain greater continuity and capacity. This has enabled successive state governments in Karnataka to produce more well- designed policies than in most other governments (along with the institutional capacity for implementing these policies), though it has also made them more reluctant to give up power, as seen in the late 1980s.2 The ability to retain policy and institutional continuity in an environment of frequently changing state gov ernments needs to be understood against the background of a tendency of the ruling political parties to appeal to the same social base (Wood 1984). This has led new governments to retain most of the policies introduced by their predecessors, particularly since the early 1990s (Manor 2006). By the early 1990s the statewide increase in political competition (discussed below) was starting to bear fruit in increased investments in social and anti- poverty programs. Karnataka since the early 1990s invested above national average expenditures on development: the state’s disbursements to the education sector as well as health and family welfare throughout the 1990s (and up to 2010) consistently ranked among the highest of Indian states (Reserve Bank of India 2011b). While previous studies of the 1990s found Karnataka to have made only average progress in the poverty and social sectors (Herring in Kadekodi et al. 2006; Kohli 1987) this state of affairs clearly began to change by the turn of the century, with Karnataka making particular progress in reducing the poverty rate from 30 percent in 1993/1994 to 17 percent in 1999/2000, as seen in Table 2.3 (Planning Commission 2011). Moreover, in 2001 Karnataka’s ratio of females per 1,000 males improved to 965 compared to the national average of 933, literacy rates were at 67 percent compared to the national average of 65, and 88 percent of households had electricity in 2006 compared to the national average of 64 percent (Bhandari and Kale 2007c). By 2011 Karnataka’s social indicators were above the national average and significantly ahead of those in Uttar Pradesh.
Karnataka’s innovative Panchayat system of the 1980s: a product of national and state politics The Janata Party came to power in Karnataka in 1983, breaking the Congress Party’s hold over state politics since independence for the first time. However, by the time the Janata Party won in Karnataka in 1983, internal bickering had torn the fragile Janata-led coalition apart at the national level and the Congress Party was again in power at the center. The national Janata Party was organized by Jayprakash Narayan to unite all anti-Congress parties for the 1977 national elections, at the end of Indira
56 Karnataka – competitive local governments Gandhi’s imposition of martial law. In 1977 it presented a unified front as the main opposition to Emergency rule and to the Congress Party led by Indira Gandhi. After succeeding in ousting Indira Gandhi in a landslide victory, from 1977 to 1980, it headed national politics under the leadership of Prime Minister Morarji Desai. It was a populist, leftist party that was an amalgamation of a variety of personalities and political movements. To demonstrate that it was the true Gandhian party of democracy and anti-poverty, the Janata Party, upon coming to power in 1977, appointed a committee on Panchayat Raj institutions under the chairmanship of Ashok Mehta. The Ashok Mehta Committee, as it became known, submitted a report a year later. The findings included 132 recom mendations aimed at reviving the declining Panchayat Raj system in the country. Specific recommendations included enabling official participation of political parties at all levels of panchayat elections and setting quotas for panchayat seats for SC and ST members, based on their percentage in the respective population. The Committee’s recommendations led to revision of panchayat legislation in the three states of Karnataka, Andhra Pradesh, and West Bengal, with many of the Committee’s recommendations later incorporated into the 73rd Amendment. Though it can be credited with preventing the corrosion of democracy at the national level, significant ideological and political divisions soon emerged within the Janata Party, hampering its ability to rule. When its key charismatic and pop ular leader Jayaprakash Narayan died in 1979, the glue that helped unify the party weakened further. By 1980, the Janata Party’s inability to rule effectively led to its ousting at the national level and the triumphant return of an Indira Gandhi-ruled Congress Party. The Janata Party’s brief foray onto the national political stage and its quick fall from power a few years later laid bare its lack of political reach at the subnational and particularly substate levels. Mindful that they did not have the same party structure as the Congress Party (which had networks reaching down to the village level), upon coming to power in Karnataka in 1983 the Janata Party introduced a radically new decentralization. A report issued by the Ashok Mehta Committee while the Janata Party was in power at the national level, which provided recommendations for making panchayats part of the democratic fabric of the country, also provided the basis for the Janata Party’s new decentralization program in Karnataka. The Karnataka “Zilla Parishads, Taluk Panchayat Samitis, Mandal Panchayats and Nyaya Panchayats Act” was drafted by the new government in 1983 and came into effect in 1987 (Karnataka 1987). The new decentralized government mandated by the Act had a two-tiered structure with local government structures known as Zilla Parishads (ZP) at the district level, block-level Taluk Panchayats (TP) as coordinating bodies, and Mandal Panchayats (MP) covering groups of villages with population sizes between 8,000 and 12,000 at the local level (Institute of Social Sciences 1995). The local governments at the Zilla and Mandal Panchayat levels were both directly elected, with most of the political power residing with the Zilla Panchayats, the district level. This landmark panchayat legislation in Karnataka helped form the basis for the 73rd Constitutional Amendment (Besley et al. 2004a). The new act in
Karnataka – competitive local governments 57 Karnataka was revolutionary because it devolved real powers and resources to local governments with the district-level governments supervising and even controlling bureaucrats deputed to the district level (Crook and Manor 1998). This transfer of power and resources to the Zilla Panchayats in Karnataka was much more radical than in any other Indian state, including West Bengal, because the district-level local governments were given control over de-concentrated state ministries. This meant that the elected presidents of Zilla Panchayats, who were given the status of junior ministers in the state government, were in charge of more than half of the state’s civil servants, controlled nearly 40 percent of the state budget, and were responsible for most of the main development functions (Crook and Sverrisson 1999). Moreover, Karnataka’s decentralization act also built on its history of reservations for women, which had been in place since 1959, by continuing to promote affirmative action and reserving 25 percent of local government seats at the Zilla and Mandal Panchayat level for women and 18 percent of seats for SCs/STs (Pur 2006). The Gram Sabha, the meeting of all eligible voters in the village, was seen as the basic tier of the decentralized system and was mandated by law to meet twice a year to review development plans submitted by the Mandal Panchayats and select beneficiaries for social welfare programs (Raghavulu and Narayana 1999). Karnataka’s new local government system did not last long. In 1988, a year after implementation of the newly decentralized system, factions within the Janata Party and the bureaucracy started fighting about the powers of the local governments, leading to a decrease in the powers and functions of the Zilla Parishad level (Mathew 2000). The following year, in 1989, the national govern ment imposed President’s rule on Karnataka and started further curtailing the powers of local governments. At the end of 1989 the Congress Party came back to power by winning the Karnataka state elections and right away started undermining the panchayat system through financial cuts and the recentralization of power. With support from many in the bureaucracy who had seen their power undermined through decentralization, the Congress party chipped away at local government power to the point that when the next round of local elections were due in 1992 the government did not hold them and instead appointed administrators. With these final steps, Karnataka’s short-lived experiment in decentralization was over. Before the 73rd Amendment and the subsequent new system that arose in Karnataka, it is important to understand how innovative Karnataka’s 1980s experiment in decentralization was. James Manor, in his comparisons of decentralization in Karnataka, other Indian states, and other developing countries, has argued that the 1980s decentralization in Karnataka was one of the most intensive in the world (Crook and Manor 1998; Manor 1999). Not only did the decentralized structure transfer significant power, functions, and finances to local governments, but local governments also attained some control over civil service administrators charged with implementing development projects at the local level. The state government did not reserve any powers of control or supervision for itself. In addition, poorer and more vulnerable groups such as the landless
58 Karnataka – competitive local governments were represented in local governments. The results included improvement in the provision of social services and local governments that were more responsive than before to their constituents’ demands (Institute of Social Sciences 1995; Crook and Manor 1998). There are also some negative observations about the earlier panchayat sys tem, such as village meetings rarely taking place, over-representation of dominant groups, and lack of active participation of female local government officeholders. Gram Sabha meetings were held when they were initially introduced, but within a couple of years such meetings became rare despite a legal requirement that they be held twice a year. Moreover, the politically dominant groups, the Vokkaliga and Linggayat castes, were found to occupy 51 percent of Panchayat seats after the 1987 Panchayat elections, despite only accounting for 27 percent of the population (Crook and Sverrisson 1999). At the district level, richer land-owning individuals were over-represented. Overall assessments of the decentralization program in Karnataka during the late 1980s, however, are highly positive. The system provided local governments the power and resources to implement development programs at the local level and influence development planning at the state level. It created positive spillover effects such as catalyzing decreased corruption, more timely warnings of potential disasters, and more proactive participation among villagers once they realized their improved access to government and their ability to bring about change (Crook and Manor 1998). Even though the panchayat system in Karnataka was dismantled by the end of its first term, it set the precedent for the local government system that was to follow and illustrated the power of local govern ments to improve government functioning and service delivery at the local level.
The 1993 Karnataka Panchayat Act The political winds had shifted toward the end of 1992 in Karnataka and at the central government level. For much of 1992 Karnataka was under direct rule, with civil servants and political appointees in charge rather than elected politicians. At the end of 1992, state elections brought in a Congress Party govern ment. Meanwhile a Congress-led government had also come to power at the national level a year earlier. The new Congress government in Karnataka was composed of new leaders and stated its commitment to revive the panchayat system once in office, coinciding with pro-panchayat moves at the national level. After decades of talk about commitment to local governance, the 73rd and 74th constitutional amendment bills came into force in April 1993. In order to conform to these constitutional amendments, Karnataka instituted several changes, most notably revising the local governance structure to a three- tiered system, which included the Gram Panchayats (GP) at the village level. Instead of passing amendments to the Karnataka Panchayat law, the state gov ernment crafted a new “Karnataka Panchayat Raj Act.” In May 1993, only a month after the national-level 73rd Amendment, Karnataka’s new act was in force, making it the first state to comply with the new national legal framework.
Karnataka – competitive local governments 59 The Act required the establishment of Gram Panchayats to cover a group of villages with a total population ranging from five to seven thousand and one representative for approximately every 400 constituents (Government of Karnataka 2007). The Act also mandated the devolution of all 29 subjects listed in the schedule to the 73rd Constitutional Amendment. Until 2005, Karnataka was the only state to have devolved all 29 subjects to panchayats (Ghorpade 2002); and by 2010 it was still one of only two states. Since 1993 the state legislation has been amended numerous times, most recently in 2006. After the passage of the Karnataka Panchayat Raj Act of 1993 the renamed Janata Dal party came to power again in 1994 and set up a committee known as the Nayak Committee. The Committee recommended changes to the Act in order to make it more accountable to the people. Several amendments implemented since then have improved the potential impact of the panchayat legislation. These include transferring panchayat supervision powers from civil servants to district-level or block-level panchayat officers and spelling out the obligatory functions of the Gram Panchayats, including maintaining water supply infrastructure, achieving universal immunization and primary school enrollment, and providing latrines to the community (Mathew 2000). They have also given more financial clout to the Gram Panchayats, particularly since 2005, by increasing the amount of tied and untied money they receive directly from the state government and through increasing their taxation powers. The Gram Panchayats have been given increased authority to manage implementation of social welfare schemes in the villages, and training has been provided to all panchayat members (Government of Karnataka 2006). By 2008 the average annual resources transferred to Gram Panchayats in Karnataka was about 3.8 million rupees (approximately US$86,000 in 2010 dollars), a significant sum in the Indian context (Government of Karnataka 2007). Karnataka has been at the forefront of Indian states in devolving political, finan cial, and managerial powers to local governments. Unlike local governments at the district and block levels, Karnataka’s Gram Panchayats were given the right to raise revenue, including the ability to raise taxes on buildings, markets, and water, in addition to transfers from the state and central governments. However, the Gram Panchayats in Karnataka have not been proactive in raising local resources in order to supplement fiscal transfers, as has been the case elsewhere in India. Local resource mobilization was low throughout the 1990s and continued to remain low at the turn of the century. In 2000/2001, the revenues raised by Gram Panchayats in Karnataka on average constituted only 22 percent of their total revenue (Government of Karnataka 2006), which was comparable to the percentage of revenues raised by the GPs in the 1990s. This is similar to other states. Gram Panchayats in Karnataka con tinued to be reluctant to raise their own revenue, so that the amount of resources available to GPs was similar across the state. Karnataka was quick to act in implementing a local government system that has been revised several times to make it more democratic, powerful, and accountable. The system set up in Karnataka was in congruence with the 73rd Amendment (Government of Karnataka 1993), with the Karnataka Panchayat
60 Karnataka – competitive local governments Raj Act of 1993 instituting a three-tiered local government structure. The Gram Sabha forms the backbone of the local government structure and elects the members of the Gram Panchayat. It is required to meet at least twice a year by law in order to enable villagers to identify beneficiaries for social welfare programs and enable accountability of the Gram Panchayat (Subha 1996). The Taluk Panchayat (TP) is at the block level and the Zilla Panchayat (ZP) is at the district level. The Karnataka Act also conforms with the national constitution in reserving seats at all three levels, with one-third of all seats reserved for women and reserved seats for SC/ST in proportion to population. The Karnataka Panchayat Raj Act went beyond national legal requirements by mandating a minimum of 15 percent of seats for Scheduled Castes and 3 percent for Scheduled Tribes. Later, a reservation of one-third of all seats for members of other backward castes (OBC) was added (Mathew 2000). Furthermore, the new legislation included reservations for the head of the Gram Panchayat as well as the deputy-head of the GP and mandated that these two positions be held for 30 months, in order to enable a rotation of reserved seats once during the five-year term of the GP (Government of Karnataka 2007). Karnataka Gram Panchayats also include administrative staff headed by a Secretary, and these staff are civil servants paid by the government. Moreover, the state law mandated all Gram Panchayats to have three standing committees with reserved seats in each committee: a production committee to oversee agricultural and rural development, including poverty alleviation programs; a social justice committee tasked with managing village education programs and furthering the inter ests of minority groups such as SC/STs; and an amenities committee to cover health, education and public work activities (Government of Karnataka 2007). Some observers of local governments in Karnataka have criticized the depth of the panchayat system, saying that the basic structure of the new system as set forth in 1993 was less innovative than the 1987 version where much of the bur eaucracy at the local level was under the control of the panchayats (Aziz 2000). However, soon after the elections of new panchayat members, local government representatives started lobbying for increased powers. The Karnataka Panchayat Raj Act of 1993 was then amended several times. For example, in October 2003, 47 amendments to the Panchayat Raj Act were unanimously adopted by the legislature. The objective of these amendments was to facilitate people’s parti cipation and make the panchayats more accountable to them, through the inclusion of innovative mechanisms such as social audits of local governments. The amendments passed despite some wrangling between politicians, local govern ments, and civil servants on how much power and resources should be devolved to the local governments. The 2005 Right to Information Act (RTI), which guaranteed every citizen the right to request information from public institutions, which were required to answer the request within 30 days, was also legislated with instructions being issued to all Karnataka panchayats, including Gram Panchayats, that information pertaining to the areas devolved to them, including details of works undertaken, estimates, and the like, should be made clearly available to all citizens through the maintenance of display boards.
Karnataka – competitive local governments 61 The end result of the evolving innovations was that despite political attempts to roll back the power of local governments, of Gram Panchayats in particular, by 2011 most of the innovations of the 1987 decentralization system were back in state law. For example, the District Rural Development Agency, charged with implementing anti-poverty programs of the Ministry of Rural Development, was merged with the Zilla Panchayats, putting its civil servants under the control of the ZP (World Bank 2000b). Thirty percent of state revenues are now regularly released to the panchayats (Rao et al. 2004); the Karnataka state government in 2005 legislated disbursements of 30 billion rupees of untied money directly to the Gram Panchayat (Government of Karnataka 2006); and Karnataka became the first state to provide training for its panchayat members in 2006. Furthermore, in 2006 the World Bank provided a concessional loan to the Karnataka government to fund a “Karnataka Panchayat Strengthening Project,” which further increased the unmarked funds at the disposal of Gram Panchayats (World Bank 2006). The Government of Karnataka was at the forefront of not only devolving responsibilities for socioeconomic development to the Gram Panchayats, but also in transferring funding and personnel to village level governments. Karnataka was the first state to enact an amendment in order to bring its law in line with the 73rd Amendment, the first state to hold local government elections on the basis of the rules set forth in the 73rd Amendment, and the only state for over a decade that legally transferred the responsibility for and financing of all 29 subjects mentioned in the 73rd Amendment (see Appendix A and Table 2.1). Since 1993 Karnataka has been at the vanguard of Indian states in decentralizing powers to local governments. This has created an environment conducive to further innovations in decentralization and recognition at the grassroots of the increasing power of local governments. For example, in 2006 the government of India along with the National Commission for Women started organizing a series of state conferences for women panchayat members to share their experiences and lessons learned (Ministry of Panchayats, Government of India 2007). Known as Panchayat Mahila Shakti Abhiyan, one of the first such conferences was held in Karnataka and similar conferences were subsequently held in other states. Also, in 2007 the Karnataka Panchayat Ministry initiated a program to provide every Gram Panchayat with a computer, to train a computer operator for Gram Panchayats throughout the state, and to mandate the public posting at the GP office of a monthly computer printout of revenue and expenses. In early 2008 each Gram Panchayat was directed to open a bank account, and with the aid of computers, funding from the state government was, “at the stroke of a key,” directly transfered each month to Gram Panchayats throughout the state (inter view with Director of Panchayat Raj, Ashraful Hasan, January 3, 2008). These efforts to empower local governments did not go unnoticed. The government of India recognized Karnataka for paving the path to empowering panchayats while increasing their accountability and effectiveness. In April 2010, the states of Karnataka and Kerala shared the 2009–2010 top prize given by the government of India for “Panchayat Empowerment and Accountability” (DHNS 2010).
62 Karnataka – competitive local governments In contrast to panchayat elections in both West Bengal and Uttar Pradesh, the Karnataka Act explicitly states that Gram Panchayat elections are not to be contested on the basis of political parties, though in local government elections above the village level, electoral candidates are allowed to officially disclose their party affiliation and compete on a party basis (Government of Karnataka 1993). According to Karnataka’s Panchayat law, elections to the state’s 5,476 Gram Panchayats are to be conducted strictly on apolitical lines. Yet as the village studies below highlight, politically competitive elections are less a result of legislation and instead have more to do with the actual workings of elections in the respective state. Gram Panchayat elections in Karnataka are de facto waged on a party basis. Though no party symbols are printed on the ballots, the local electorate knows the party affiliation of candidates, and major parties often invest substantial resources to back their candidates. The fact that political parties bankroll the elections of Gram Panchayat members, and an increase in expenditure on Gram Panchayat election campaigns generally, reflect how Gram Panchayat members wield considerable political, and increasingly economic, power in Karnataka. Gram Panchayat members play a significant role in electing block- and district-level panchayats, as well as electing members to the state legislative assembly (MLAs) where elections are contested on a party basis. As the central and state governments have continued to increase transfers to Gram Panchayats, the power exercised by Gram Panchayat representatives has also increased. For example, the funds distributed through the Mahatma Gandhi Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme, a central govern ment program started in 2008 that guarantees 100 days of work paid at a min imum wage to every family, are directly transferred to local governments for selection of beneficiaries and distribution. In 2010, the funds to be transferred to local governments in Karnataka under this scheme alone are estimated at 3.5 billion rupees. Gram Panchayat members increasingly hold politically and eco nomically important positions, leading to de facto campaigning on a political party basis and competitive politics in local governance. By 2010, the decentralized government system in Karnataka was once again one of the more innovative and politically and financially devolved local govern ment systems in India. In order to investigate how the state’s local government legislation translated into the functioning of village-level local governments and the processes that enabled local governments to target and deliver social and anti-poverty programs, village-level studies were conducted in Karnataka. The following section sets forth the village studies and findings from these studies.
Overview and choice of village case studies in Karnataka Karnataka’s socioeconomic background and history of local government is quite different from both Uttar Pradesh and West Bengal. Karnataka citizens on average experienced less inequality, both socially and economically, during the 1980s than did their counterparts in Uttar Pradesh and West Bengal. Since this study compares how villagers in these three states fared before and after the
Karnataka – competitive local governments 63 introduction of the 1993 Panchayat Amendment to understand whether the exist ence of local governments improved their socioeconomic wellbeing, it is import ant to note that Karnataka residents had a slightly better starting point in the early 1990s. There was also more political volatility at the state level, with par ties alternating in office particularly since the 1980s. Karnataka, unlike West Bengal, was not ruled by a party with a pro-poor orientation that had been in charge since 1977, with an organization that reached down to the village level. As discussed in the next chapter, this rule by a coalition of leftist parties in West Bengal has been heralded by some researchers as the key to that state’s successful improvements in social welfare of the past decades. However, less social welfare-oriented state governments in Karnataka have nevertheless overseen improvements in socioeconomic indicators that exceed those in West Bengal, particularly in recent years. Nor are other macro or state-level factors sufficient by themselves to explain improvements in social indicators in the state. For example, spectacular growth of the service sector in and around the city of Bangalore has not led to significantly greater social improvements in Bangalore Rural District. State-level studies explain state-level economic or political factors, but do not provide an understanding of the dynamics at the local level, where the delivery of public social and economic services matters most for people’s wellbeing. This study of two villages in Karnataka aims to understand local dynamics and analyze whether having elected local governments for most of the 1990s mattered for people’s wellbeing. To this end, Bangalore Rural District was chosen because it does not have the geographic and socioeconomic anomalies of the coastal or hilly regions, and because it most closely approximates average socioeconomic indicators for Karnataka. For example, in 2001 literacy rates for Bangalore Rural District were 65 percent compared to a 67 percent state average, the ratio of females to 1,000 males was 956 for the district compared to 965 for the state, and 90 percent of the district’s households had electricity compared to 88 percent in the state (Bhandari and Kale 2007c). The obvious difference between Bangalore Rural District and the districts chosen for study in Uttar Pradesh and West Bengal is that it borders the large metropolitan area of Bangalore. The city of Bangalore is the state capital and the center of economic growth in the state (due in large measure to the services sector boom from multinational corporations moving their “back-offices” to Bangalore city). To minimize comparability problems arising from a district being close to a thriving metropolis, the block or taluk chosen for study and the two villages within it were located a three-hour bus and scooter drive from Bangalore city. As with the village studies in Uttar Pradesh and West Bengal, the two villages here, Gavi Nagamangala and Mudabal (both located in the Magadi Taluk), were also selected because they had been studied prior to the passage of the 73rd Amendment. Though not as formal a study as those that provided the baseline in the other two case studies, and despite little socioeconomic data being collected, Dr. G. K. Karanth’s studies of the villages in the late 1980s and again in the early 1990s provide an understanding of socioeconomic wellbeing in both villages (Karanth 1987,
64 Karnataka – competitive local governments 1994). There is therefore a baseline for comparison of social wellbeing before and after implementation of the Panchayat Raj Amendment in these villages.
Gavi Nagamangala and Mudabal in the early 1990s While the villages of Gavi Nagamangala and Mudabal in the Bangalore Rural District of Karnataka are both in closer proximity to a large metropolitan area than are the villages in Uttar Pradesh and West Bengal, both Karnataka villages are less accessible and appear more remote. No scheduled public transport runs by either of these villages, making the time needed to cover the distance to Bangalore too long to enable commuting into the metropolis. The high fuel cost of driving into Bangalore (for the one person in the village who owned a car in 1990–2000) did not make commuting to Bangalore city a viable option. Gavi Nagamangala and Mudabal in 1990 were essentially rural villages where the majority of the population was engaged in agriculture and agriculture-related work. In the late 1980s most households in Gavi Nagamangala owned some land, with the average per household ranging from less than an acre for an SC Kumbara family to over six acres for a dominant Vokkaliga family (Karanth 1987). According to the 1991 census, Gavi Nagamangala had a population of 1,066 persons, and the caste with the largest number of people was the Vokkoligas (Karanth 1994). Only 51 percent of the land was arable, with most of the land being used to grow “ragi” (a crop frequently grown in dry areas), while only a few dozen farmers with access to irrigation facilities cultivated rice, mostly for their own household consumption (Karanth 1994). During the 1980s poor and landless households saw a gradual improvement in their livelihoods, due to increased availability of anti-poverty programs, increased access to salar ied jobs through affirmative action programs, and increased demand for labor within the village. Unlike the villages studied in West Bengal and Uttar Pradesh, even in 1991 there was not much evidence of underemployment in the village of Gavi Nagamangala. The demand for labor and shortage of workers had by the early 1990s resulted in an improved livelihood situation for the agricultural laborer in Gavi Nagamangala and had also led to mutual labor exchange arrange ments. In order to lure wage labor to work agricultural land, land owners had begun to restart a practice which had virtually disappeared during the 1970s: sharecropping and land tenancy, albeit under much better financial conditions for the laborer (Karanth 1994). Some new economic opportunities were arising by the early 1990s in the villages – mainly sericulture (silk-farming) – but most villagers remained agriculturalists. Both villages had primary schools, which were functioning in the early 1990s and where most children in both villages were enrolled. Yet the proximity to Bangalore and its educational facilities had not spilled over into literacy rates, which, at 65 percent for the Bangalore Rural District, were slightly below the Karnataka average of 67 in 2001 (Bhandari and Kale 2007c). Overall, the socio economic picture of Gavi Nagamangala in the early 1990s was one of slowly
Karnataka – competitive local governments 65 improving socioeconomic indicators that were close to the district and state averages. Changes on the economic front mirrored changes on the political front. The frequent changes in parties in power at the state government level during the late 1980s and early 1990s were also reflected at the village level, where social cleavages ran not only along caste lines, but also along political ones. The tumultuous state power struggle between the Congress Party and Janata Party during the 1980s was palpable in the villages studied, where most people knew who was affiliated with which party (interview with G. K. Karanth 2000). Echoing the lack of continuity on the political front was the change in local government structures that took place in Karnataka (and in these villages) in 1987. The new and innovative local government system enacted in 1987 was starting to be dismantled in the early 1990s. In-depth interviews conducted in both villages about whether village residents had felt a sense of empowerment and voice with the 1987 Karnataka Panchayat Act yielded no straightforward answers. On the one hand, people were aware that they had elected representatives at the Mandal Panchayat level under the 1987 system, which represented a group of villages in their area with a population of 8,000 to 12,000. Interviewees were aware that these GP representatives brought government closer to the village level, reporting that they were more likely by the early 1990s to contact their local representatives than in the early 1980s – and in some cases they indeed did contact their representative if they had a concern. Having elected representatives at the national level for several decades, villagers had an awareness of what it meant to have an elected representative for a grouping of villages. Many informants also reported a sense that increased developmental resources were flowing to the villages by the early 1990s, especially for anti-poverty programs. This feedback on life in these villages around 1990 compared to the previous decade mirrors findings in other village-level studies of the panchayat system in Karnataka of that time (Crook and Manor 2001). On the other hand, several people interviewed in both Gavi Nagamangala and Mudabal recounted incidents where they had tried, albeit in some cases for the first time in their lives, to contact their Mandal Panchayat representatives in Mudabal in the early 1990s, only to face difficulty in getting responses from them. This also makes sense if one takes into account that under the panchayat system of the late 1980s, most of the power resided at the district-level Zilla Panchayat. The residents of Gavi Nagamangala and Mudabal were aware that by the late 1980s a shift in power had occurred at the state level with government representatives now being closer to the village level and a noticeable improvement in access to anti-poverty programs. People recounted that “it seemed like almost everyone turned out for the first panchayat elections in 1987” and that there was excitement about this first round of elections. A few years later, there was disappointment when direct rule was imposed by the central government and panchayat elections were postponed. It is also clear both from discussions with villagers in Gavi Nagamangala and Mudabal, as well as from other village- and state-level studies of Karnataka
66 Karnataka – competitive local governments during its late 1980s experiment with local governments, that while the previous panchayat system empowered the Zilla Panchayat level, the base of local gov ernment, the Gram Sabha, did not function as envisioned (Aziz 1993; Crook and Manor 1998; Umapathy 1998; Mathew 2000). The Gram Sabha of the pre-1993 era, by all accounts, rarely met in Gavi Nagamangala, Mudabal or any other village in Karnataka (interview with G. K. Karanth 2000; Crook and Manor 1998). It was not able to provide the kind of village level check on the actions of panchayat members that the 1987 legislation on panchayats required. While that legislation had enabled greater accountability of bureaucrats at the district level with commensurate improvements in accountability and flow of funds to the local level (Crook and Manor 1998), interviews from these village studies indicate that most people at the village level were not empowered and involved in local governance before 1993.
Gavi Nagamangala and Mudabal in 2000 and 2008 The passage of the 1993 national Panchayat Act once again changed the pro spects for local governance in Karnataka. The basic two-tiered system from 1987 was changed to three tiers, including Gram Panchayats at the village level. Since passage of the Karnataka Act, Gram Panchayat elections have taken place four times, in 1993, 2000, 2005, and 2010. The village studies in Karnataka were conducted in 2000 with a follow-up visit in 2008. During the 1990s social indicators in the two study villages, like in Bangalore Rural District and in Karnataka as a whole, continued to improve (see Table 3.1), and this trend continued in the decade after the turn of the century. The largest improvements were seen in the poverty rate, where Karnataka was a leader among Indian states. These large social gains throughout the 1990s and up to 2008 were evident in the villages studied, despite growth in economic opportunities that was not obviously greater than in the villages studied in West Bengal or Uttar Pradesh. Annual growth in Karnataka’s per capita net state domestic product between 1993/1994 and 2008/2009 was comparable to the growth registered over the same time period in West Bengal. However, poverty rates decreased more substantially in Karnataka (see Table 2.3). As with the other empirical chapters, the following analysis of the village studies is based largely on qualitative data, namely interviews with key Table 3.1 Social indicators in Bangalore Rural District, 1990/1991 and 2000/2001 Indicators
Bangalore Rural District, 1990/1991
Bangalore Rural District, 2000/2001
Sex ratio (females/1,000 males) Infant mortality rate (per 1,000 live births) Life expectancy (years) Adult literacy rate (%)
945 67 65.8 73.5
955 43 70.2 89.1
Source: Bhandari and Kale 2007c.
Karnataka – competitive local governments 67 informants and survey respondents, focus group discussions, and cross- referencing, both in 2000 and in 2008. Quantitative data (from yes/no questions) and qualitative information from in-depth interviews were collected by a small survey of a random sample in each village. Results for selected survey questions are provided in Table 3.3 at the end of the chapter. The rest of the chapter is structured as follows. First is an analysis of popular participation in Gram Panchayat elections and Gram Sabha meetings, and responsiveness of local government representatives. Next is an examination of whether the quality of government has changed according to the villagers and whether there is any link to be made between changes in governance and the new Gram Panchayat system. The analysis then turns to the overarching question of whether there is evidence, in terms of feedback from villagers and also from other sources, that wellbeing has improved in the villages, and whether such changes can be attributed to the existence of local Gram Panchayats. By providing information on these changes in two villages in Karnataka the chapter details how increased power transferred to local governments, and the functioning of these local governments in a politically competitive environment, have helped to further root democracy in Karnataka and have improved the social wellbeing of village residents, despite imperfect implementation of the Karnataka Panchayat Act.
Perception of the new Panchayat system: high participation, low agency Since institutionalization of local governments in 1994 and until 2011, state elections took place in Karnataka in 1994, 1999, 2004, and 2008, while Gram Panchayat elections were held in 1993, 2000, 2005, and 2010. Over 80,000 Gram Panchayat representatives were elected to 5,675 Gram Panchayats throughout the state. Statewide breakdowns of the backgrounds of Gram Panchayat representatives from the first two Gram Panchayat elections show that more Scheduled Caste, Scheduled Tribe, and female Gram Panchayat representatives were elected than the percentage of seats reserved for them in both elections (see Table 3.2). Similarly, in Bangalore Rural District, the percentage of women, Scheduled Caste and Scheduled Tribes elected to GP office in 2000, as well as in 2005, was higher than their quota of reserved seats. Interviews in 2000 and again in 2008 with female Gram Panchayat members in both villages showed an awareness of the functioning of local governments and their rights and responsibilities as representatives that stood in marked contrast to their counterparts in the villages of Uttar Pradesh. Furthermore, in both the Gram Panchayats to which the villages belonged, the women who were elected to office in non-reserved seats in 2000 and 2005 were young, literate individuals who were witnessed talking to female teachers and local female healthcare workers to find out their concerns with the social services in the com munity. These women had not been elected to rubber-stamp local government decisions as token female representatives. They were actively engaged in
68 Karnataka – competitive local governments Table 3.2 Breakdown of election results in Karnataka for 5,675 Gram Panchayats, by social background of elected representative (percentages)
% seats reserved for respective population in Karnataka’s GP elections(a) Gram Panchayats, 1993(b) Gram Panchayats, 2000(b) Gram Panchayats, 2005(b) GP for the village of Gavi Nagamangala, 2005(c) GP for the village of Madabal, 2005(c)
SC (%)
ST (%)
Women (%)
16.2
5
33
22.2 – 19 20 (3 out of 15)
9 – 11 13 (2 out of 15)
21 (3 out of 14)
44 44.7 43 40 (6 out of 15) 7 (1 out of 14) 50 (7 out of 14)
Sources: (a) (2006) Government of Karnataka 2005; (b) various news sources; (c) information given by the Panchayat Secretary of Gavi Nagamangala and Madabal during an interview on January 3, 2008.
determining the desires of their constituents and in advancing women’s concerns and requests for physical and social infrastructure during their local government meetings. Similar observations were made of the representative of Scheduled Tribe background from Gavi Nagamangala who was elected to a non-reserved seat by the GP elections in 2000. This individual was a political entrepreneur who knew his ST constituents and had active Congress Party support. His polit ical party affiliation, moreover, gave him a basis for meeting with other Congress Party-affiliated village residents, thus offering a forum for bridging caste cleavages. Interviews with several villagers in 2000 and 2008 in both villages on the question of whether the reservation of seats has encouraged broader and more democratic representation of village residents, yielded an unequivocal yes. While opinions differed on the extent to which female representatives were vocal and active at local government meetings and on the efficacy of their work, there was broad consensus that many who were elected to local govern ment office for the first time, through reserved seats, represented the commun ity well and in some cases were re-elected in their own right. Numerous informants shared the view that women’s position of power had changed by 2008, compared to 1993, through their work in the Gram Panchayats. There was an increased preference for female representatives because they generally did not “drink, smoke or have other bad habits” and were thought to be more likely to be honest. Representation in local governments in Karnataka has become more inclusive and representative of the general population since 1993, which in turn has helped decrease the political power of formerly dominant local caste groups and elites. The entrance of new political actors through Gram Panchayat elections has also mobilized political competition, with increased political party affiliation. Together these factors have helped root democracy at the village level.
Karnataka – competitive local governments 69 Participation in national, state, and panchayat elections in Karnataka is gen erally high. Since Gram Panchayat elections are held separately from upper-level panchayat elections, turnout rates are a direct indication of people’s interest in village-level governments. State-level analysis of Gram Panchayat election turnout shows high participation rates with two-thirds of voters turning out for Gram Panchayat elections in 2000, with voter turnout well over 80 percent in some districts (staff reporter 2005b). Generally, the village studies showed that interest in local elections remained high through 2008, as the small-scale survey, focus group discussions and interviews yielded a perception that the system of Gram Panchayats brought government power much closer to the village. With a higher percentage of seats reserved for SC/ST and women, there was high interest amongst these groups in the local elections. This excitement was palpable in the small survey and inter views conducted in the villages of Gavi Nagamangala and Mudabal. When asked whether they had voted in the last national and Gram Panchayat elections, all 80 respondents of the survey indicated that they had. Though this figure seems high, they point to the fact that voters in these villages, as throughout Karnataka, were enthusiastic at the prospect of electing village governments. All key informants as well as all 80 survey respondents in 2000 thought that the village-level local government elections were fair. Once again these figures seem very high, but they indicate enthusiasm and support for local governments in these villages. If one takes into account that Gram Panchayat elections in Karnataka were not legally to be contested on a party basis, it is clear that vote- rigging and other forms of election corruption through organized party interests were less likely to happen in the early stages of local elections, where the power of the Gram Panchayats was still unclear and resources flowing to these local governments were not as high as they were by 2011. Moreover, the high level of perception of elections as being fair is in line with previous studies by Crook and Manor and others, which found that 95 percent of respondents thought local gov ernment elections were fair (Subha 1997; Crook and Manor 1998). In both Gavi Nagamangala and Mudabal, key informants recounted that some of the contenders for Gram Panchayat seats that were more heavily contested distributed liquor before elections in the hopes of influencing results. Key informants as well as focus groups were unanimous in the view that while some people accepted the liquor, they then voted for whomever they wanted and that balloting was secret, so that this incentive did not influence the outcome of the election. Several respondents also stated that on the day of both the 1993 and 2000 Gram Panchayat elections in the village, police were stationed outside voting booths to prevent fraud and violence. The new Karnataka Panchayat laws engendered high electoral participation rates in Gram Panchayat elections. Not only did all of the 80 villagers surveyed in 2000 vote during the Gram Panchayat elections, 22 of them (27 percent) also campaigned for a person running for a panchayat seat. Similar participation rates were found by previous studies in Karnataka (Crook and Manor 1998). In contrast to the high participation rates in election campaigning and voting, fewer villagers seemed to understand the full functioning of the new panchayat
70 Karnataka – competitive local governments system or know all panchayat members, even though at the time of the 2000 study the new local government system had been in place for seven years. From in-depth interviews conducted in both villages during 2000 and 2008, it was clear that individuals generally knew that the new Gram Panchayats had political powers devolved to them, but not a single person out of the ten interviewed on this question in 2000 and the ten interviewed in 2008 knew the full extent of powers legally devolved to the panchayats. When asked specifically whether they knew the names of their Gram Panchayat members, most responded that they knew the names of at least three members; however, only about half knew the name of the Gram Panchayat president. The most likely explanation for this is the distance between villagers and the Gram Panchayats. Karnataka Gram Panchayats, like those in West Bengal and unlike those in Uttar Pradesh, gen erally represent a grouping of villages rather than an individual village. This greater distance between village residents and the Gram Panchayat might account for the likelihood of knowing the names of representatives from one’s own village but not knowing the head of the Gram Panchayat, who was not from either of the villages studied. Participation rates in Gram Sabha meetings, while higher than in some other studies (Deshpande and Murthy 2002), were also lower than intended. When asked about participating in these village level meetings, 23 out of 80 respondents (29 percent) to the small-scale survey said that they had taken part in one or more of these meetings since the establishment of the new panchayat system in 1993 and none said that they had attended more than one Gram Sabha (GS) meeting every year. Furthermore, according to the respondents, none of the GS meetings was videotaped as stipulated by the Karnataka Panchayat Act. On a more positive note, of the 23 respondents who attended Gram Sabha meetings, 16 (70 percent) said that they were active participants at the meetings. When those survey respondents who said that they had not attended Gram Sabha meetings were asked why not, most said that the meetings are held without informing villagers of the date and the result was that most of those who went to these meetings were Gram Panchayat representatives or people associated with them through family ties or friendship. This might explain why a high proportion of those who did go to meetings were active at the meetings. On the other hand, while participation at first glance might appear low, it is still higher than what was observed in the Uttar Pradesh villages. It is also higher than Gram Sabha participation rates under the previous panchayat system in Karnataka, where it was found that only 17 percent of all villagers attended such meetings (Crook and Manor 1998). The evidence from these two village studies in Bangalore Rural District shows that participation in and awareness of local government, though far from ideal, is nevertheless relatively high. Given this, it was surprising to find that most villagers did not have frequent interactions or show high agency with their panchayat representative. Only 15 survey respondents (19 percent) reported having contacted their local representative for help in 2000. This is less than what was observed in Uttar Pradesh, and seems at odds with the high level of electoral participation. On the
Karnataka – competitive local governments 71 other hand, of the 15 respondents who contacted their representative, 13 (87 percent) found their representative to be responsive. Moreover, several survey respondents who said that they had not had any formal contact with representatives volunteered that local government representatives seem accessible and that they would contact them if they needed to. This overall low level of interaction and agency vis-à-vis Gram Panchayat members in Gavi Nagamangala and Mudabal contrasts unfavorably with the high mobilization of voters in the West Bengal villages, but compares favorably with the villages in Uttar Pradesh in terms of a sense among villagers that local government representatives were accessible. To further understand why in particular poorer village residents and the Scheduled Tribes do not make greater use of the increased availability of gov ernment officers at the village level, several in-depth group discussions and individual interviews were held in both villages. These discussions revealed that despite being visibly the poorest members of the village, the social and economic distance between the ST villagers and other village residents in 2000 was not as great as that found in West Bengal, nor as great as between upper caste and SC or Muslims in the villages studied in Uttar Pradesh. The ST villagers lived together in a separate part of the village, but their residences were not physically located outside the village as in the West Bengali villages, and they lived in better-built and larger houses than their counterparts in the villages in the other two case study states. There was a strong sense of community among the ST villagers in the Karnataka villages, and life was less a matter of survival, since between agricultural work and functioning social welfare programs, villagers managed reasonably well and did not have any grievances against the village or village government. The well from which they drew their water was shared with other, non-ST members of the community; at religious festivals they celebrated with other villagers; and at crop planting and harvesting time they worked the fields alongside other villagers. When asked specifically why they did not lobby the local government for more social programs for their community, the unanimous answer was that they were receiving social benefits and their life in general was better than a decade ago. While the low agency rates are still surprising given the easier access to local governments, and though these findings differ from higher agency findings in village studies conducted on the earlier panchayat system by Crook and Manor, social welfare programs appear to be working in these villages and the village poor do not appear or think of themselves as destitute or disenfranchised. These findings on the short social distance between traditionally marginalized groups in Karnataka (such as the ST) and upper-caste village residents mirror statewide analysis of social groups in Karnataka (interview with G. K. Karanth 2000). In Karnataka, the caste hierarchy is not a deep social cleavage and the frequency of interactions between citizens belonging to different caste backgrounds reflects the more horizontal hierarchy of social interactions. In the two village studies in Karnataka, village elites were not easily identifiable by their high caste background or their political party affiliation. Conversations with groups of villagers in 2000 as well as 2008 to identify village residents with
72 Karnataka – competitive local governments significant political influence repeatedly indicated that the elite in these villages were spread across the spectrum of caste and religious cleavages, as well as across the spectrum of political party affiliation. “Elites” as identified by respondents in these Karnataka villages have a variety of caste and political backgrounds, making caste and political affiliation an important identity marker rather than a hierarchical marker. Also, neither caste nor political affiliation was identified as being a significant factor in determining access to political power or “elite” status, findings that echo other research in Karnataka (Besley et al. 2008; Manor 2008). The wide social distribution of individuals identified as village elites indicates that these elites are not an easily identifiable, cohesive group, making their resistance to democratic deepening and their cooption of local gov ernment resources less likely.
Work of the Gram Panchayats Discussions with vulnerable and poorer groups in both villages highlighted that key government-financed social welfare programs were working in both villages. And while in-depth interviews with key informers in both villages showed that few know the exact extent of devolution of powers to their Gram Panchayats, there was a general understanding that the Gram Panchayats received resources from higher levels of government and were in charge of managing social welfare programs at the village level. One of the most impressive findings of the village studies in Karnataka is the near unanimity about functioning social programs. All 80 survey respondents said that some type of social welfare program was being delivered in their village while 24 (30 percent) said that the Gram Panchayat was the key implementer of these programs. Also, 70 of the 80 respondents (88 percent) thought that there were functioning anti-poverty programs in the village, but only 13 (16 percent) thought that the GP was instrumental in providing these services. These responses as well as follow-up interviews confirm observations in these villages during 2000 and again in 2008: the social programs in these villages were operational and know ledge of social program delivery was widespread. The village-level healthcare worker was observed delivering pre- and postnatal care to women; school teachers show up and teach in the primary schools; distribution of subsidized goods under the public distribution system (PDS)3 takes place; toilets had been built through a central-government grant program; and central government anti-poverty schemes such as the Jawahar Gram Samridhi Yojana (JGSY)4 public works program and the Swarnjayanti Gram Swarozgar Yojana (SGSY)5 self-employment program were also in evidence in both villages. Moreover, perceptions of functioning ser vices are significantly higher than those found in the other two state case studies and point to a relatively high-functioning social welfare system at the village level. Survey respondents perceived that the delivery of central and state government programs aimed at improving social welfare was taking place in their villages, though most did not perceive the Gram Panchayat as the instrumental body in the delivery of these social services.
Karnataka – competitive local governments 73 While programs aimed at improving social wellbeing were clearly functioning in Karnataka, the questions of whether they were targeting their intended beneficiaries or whether powerful interests were able to corrupt the process was more difficult to answer conclusively. Though the social distance between locally powerful socioeconomic groups and poorer groups is not as great in Karnataka as in some northern Indian states such as Uttar Pradesh, some castes nevertheless still dominate the political economy of rural Karnataka, raising concerns about whether beneficiaries tended to be of the dominant caste background. In order to assess whether poverty programs were reaching intended beneficiaries, names of three Indira Awaas Yojana (IAY) beneficiaries and two SGSY beneficiaries in Gavi Nagamangala, as well as two recipients of each program from Mudabal, were obtained from their respective Gram Panchayats, and inter views were conducted with them in 2000. Similar cross-checks were conducted in 2008. In all of the interviews, recipients confirmed receiving the respective anti-poverty scheme during the last five years. None of the recipients was from an OBC or upper-caste background, and visual assessments as well as recipient feedback on assets owned confirmed that these were indeed poorer members of the village. To understand perceptions of corruption in the social welfare allocation pro cess, the survey of 80 villagers in these two villages were asked whether, if two people were equally poor but one of them had some association (caste or polit ical) with the person determining the benefits, this association would determine who would get the benefit. Unlike in West Bengal where the majority of survey respondents said that political background and connections would influence the decision, in the Karnataka villages only 22 of the 80 respondents (28 percent) hought connections would influence beneficiary selection. Moreover, 11 respondents (14 percent) said – without being asked – that one person alone would not be making the decision under the new local government system. There was clearly a group of people in the village who understood the workings of the new local government system well enough to make this type of statement. If these social welfare programs are clearly functioning in the two villages and the Gram Panchayats participate in their implementation (by identifying the beneficiaries and releasing funds to beneficiaries or program implementers), the question remains why so few villagers see the Gram Panchayat as being instrumental in the delivery of these programs. Linked to this question is the general issue of awareness and also agency and involvement of villagers in beneficiary- identification through Gram Sabhas. Villagers are aware that there is a new panchayat system in place and that a local government structure closer to the village has been instituted, yet only 23 of 80 survey respondents (29 percent) reported participating in any Gram Sabha meetings over the past years and those who did participate seemed to be more politically aware and often from the politically connected groups of the village. From the perspective of local government representatives, the amount of development work that they can undertake is limited. Several panchayat members who were interviewed complained about the fact that the funds that are
74 Karnataka – competitive local governments devolved to Gram Panchayats are in large part tied to specific programs. Most of the untied funds are used for salaries and administrative costs, and there is therefore little leeway for Gram Panchayat members to allocate funds toward areas they deem important – findings that have also been echoed by other studies of the Karnataka panchayat system (Besley et al. 2004a; World Bank 2004). Interviews with Gram Panchayat members and review of the logbook of revenues and expenditures of both villages’ Gram Panchayats in 2008 confirmed that the vast majority of funding received by the local governments is intended for specific programs or costs rather than untied. While the new panchayat system appears to have spurred the deepening of democracy through greater electoral participation, this deepening did not extend all the way to the roots of local governments, the Gram Sabha. Moreover, while there was evidence that social welfare programs are working well in the villages and are generally reaching their intended audience, how well these programs are targeted versus what percentage of funds are either pocketed or mis-targeted by locally powerful groups and individuals remains unclear. The influence of dominant groups in these villages in Karnataka is clearly still present, yet most social programs do function at the village level and only a quarter of the survey respondents thought that political or socioeconomic connections influence program targeting, in contrast to the higher perception of political corruption in the West Bengal case study villages.
Overall perception of Gram Panchayats While the new panchayat system was already in place for seven years at the time of the first round of village studies in 2000, the field research and analysis of the changing nature of Gram Panchayats since the turn of the century reveal that the system in Karnataka is still evolving. Since 1993 several amendments have been added to the Panchayat Act, generally to increase the power and financial resources of the Gram Panchayats as outlined above. The Gram Panchayats in Karnataka are increasingly structured to empower villagers and change the power balance at the local level to be more democratic. Information from villagers and observation of the social services provided through the Gram Panchayat make clear that local governments are making a difference in these villages in Karnataka. Villagers were enthusiastic about the Gram Panchayat elections and by all accounts have turned out in record numbers. Social welfare programs, in all of which the Gram Panchayat is now involved in delivering, were visibly working in both villages. Of the 80 villagers surveyed, 45 (56 percent) thought that their Gram Panchayat representatives were good, and involved in satisfying the most import ant needs of the village, with only seven (nine percent) stating that they did not address the village’s needs. However, the majority of survey respondents as well as key informant interviewees who held the GP representatives in high esteem, were literate, older, more affluent and higher-caste villagers. Other village studies in Karnataka have found that the more politically powerful members within each
Karnataka – competitive local governments 75 group benefiting from quotas are the ones who tend to be elected to local govern ments. While this may be so, it is evident that the newly instituted Gram Panchayat system is bringing about changes to the distribution of power. Though the two Gram Panchayat members from Gavi Nagamangala and two from Mudabal who occupied reserved seats in 2000 were all literate, one was a younger woman and one sometimes worked as a laborer in the fields. The GP representatives from these villages are not all from the traditionally powerful groups in the village. Even though many villagers do not attribute the functioning social services to the GP, and even though the GS are not fully functioning as they are mandated, the new panchayat system – with its quotas – has changed power dynamics at the village level. Women and SC/ST groups are being elected in record numbers. In the GPs for the villages studied, over 40 percent of GP members were women, 20 percent were of SC and nearly 15 percent were of ST backgrounds. These proportions are similar to statewide patterns in 2007, where 41 percent of all GP members were women, 18 percent were of SC background and nine percent were of ST background (Government of Karnataka 2007). The overall perception of the Gram Panchayats at the village level is one of support for the GPs, where women and people of SC/ST background are increasingly represented, and one where GP-managed social services are being provided.
Quality of governance This section will analyze the quality and perception of governance in Gavi Nagamangala and Mudabal in order to better understand whether the Gram Panchayats have improved social wellbeing in the villages. As with the other two case study chapters, governance will be analyzed by assessing changes in participa tion, accountability, and political stability; government effectiveness and regu latory quality; and rule of law and control of corruption. Governance, defined as the “traditions and institutions by which authority in a country is exercised” includes (1) the process of selecting, monitoring, and replacing governments, (2) the government’s capacity to formulate and implement sound policies, and (3) the state’s and citizen’s respect for the institutions that govern economic and social interactions among them (Kaufmann et al. 2002). Villagers were asked about the extent to which they perceived others as abiding by the rules of law and society, as well as their perceptions of corruption – defined as the exercise of public power for private gain (Kaufmann et al. 2002: 4). In particular, they were asked whether there was a change in violence, rule of law, and corruption since the implementation of the new panchayat system. Advocates of decentralization have often cited increased voice for formerly disenfranchised groups, increased accountability of local governments and bureaucrats, and greater polit ical stability, as benefic ial outcomes. The village surveys, key informant inter views and focus group discussions, collected information on whether or not villagers in Gavi Nagamangala and Mudabal shared this view. Since implementation of the 73rd Amendment, unequivocal changes in village-level power dynamics have taken place just through the election of more
76 Karnataka – competitive local governments women and lower castes to local government office. Even if some of these are “token representatives” who do not actively engage in local governments, as some studies suggest, there are other studies that show the changing dynamics and empowerment of groups that have arisen as a result of the panchayat reser vations, including implementation of more social projects that are highly prioritized by women and SC/ST as opposed to upper castes (Chattopadhyay and Duflo 2003, 2004). This rise in “voice” of villagers as a result of the new Gram Panchayat system is reflected in the villages studied in Bangalore Rural District. Among 80 villagers in the two communities who were surveyed, 30 (38 percent) said they felt they had more voice since the implementation of the new panchayat system. 24 respondents (30 percent) said that their sense of voice was the same, 8 (10 percent) stated that it was worse, and 18 (23 percent) did not express an opinion. However, when looking at the background of the 30 who said that their voice had increased, 20 (67 percent) were of lower caste background and/or women. Clearly, there was some change in sense of voice, and the change was mostly among groups who had been more disenfranchised under the previous system. This finding is borne out by the fact that in the Gram Panchayat that Mudabal belongs to, one female Gram Panchayat representative won a seat that was not reserved for a woman. Quotas for women encouraged more women to run for office, and in the 2000 as well as the 2005 Gram Panchayat elections in these villages, at least a couple of women contested – and won – seats that were not reserved. Several amendments to the Karnataka Panchayat Act have been passed since 1993 that aimed at improving Gram Panchayat control over the bureaucracy in order to enhance accountability. Gram Panchayat records showing disbursed versus received funds for these villages showed a high disbursement rate. Survey responses on this issue showed a similar pattern to the question about voice, as 32 out of the 80 respondents (40 percent) answered that accountability had increased, 24 (30 percent) said it had decreased, and 24 (30 percent) did not answer or said that they did not know. Interviews with four Gram Panchayat representatives as well a dozen key informants presented a mixed picture. Some said that they now knew better what funds were being allocated to the village and that they had some leverage through feedback to upper-level panchayats to get work done by bureaucrats. Others thought that the panchayat did not have enough power over local-level civil servants such as schoolteachers or those engaged in distributing public rations through the PDS system. Comparisons of accountability perceptions before and after implementation of the 73rd constitutional amendment need to keep in mind that the system that existed in Karnataka up to 1992 was hailed by many for its innovation in empowering panchayats and thereby increasing government and civil servant accountability (Crook and Manor 2001). However, most respondents, when comparing the new system to the system that was in place up to 1992, found that the new system was about the same as the old in enhancing the accountability of governments and civil servants. Moreover, the Karnataka panchayat system was still in flux, with many of the amendments to the state law, which aimed at
Karnataka – competitive local governments 77 empowering Gram Panchayats both in terms of resources and political power, not being implemented until 2004–2005. Since 2001, complaints from panchayats over lack of power over funding and over the bureaucracy also resulted in the state government taking specific measures to improve accountability, including a system of social audits, citizen report cards, and user group monitoring by inde pendent, professional agencies (Government of Karnataka 2005). Measures were also taken by the government of Karnataka to enable feedback from local governments on how to improve the panchayat system. For example, in 2006 the state revived the idea of a State Panchayat Council, which was to meet twice a year to discuss the functioning of Panchayats in Karnataka. This Council consisted of political representatives and appointees from the state level, as well as representatives from each local government level within each district (Government of Karnataka 2007), and met “as a forum for elected representatives to voice their aspirations and offer their suggestions to improve the Panchayat Raj system and make it more responsive to the people’s needs” (Government of Karnataka 1993). Though this Council has only met four times since its resuscitation – which some experts see as an indicator that the state gov ernment is not following the spirit of its decentralization law – the fact that Karnataka has instituted such a council suggests a strengthening of the enabling environment for local government. These measures, together with an increasing focus on linking panchayats and their financial records electronically, are improving the transparency of Gram Panchayat accounts, and will help improve accountability in the longer term. In trying to understand whether Gram Panchayats have mattered for governance and hence social wellbeing in these villages, it is also important to assess government effectiveness and administrative quality. As in the following chapters, government effectiveness is taken to mean the ability of local governments to implement programs they are charged with implementing or overseeing by their mandate, as well as their ability to improve implementation of services by civil servants so as to decrease the administrative burden faced by citizens. When assessing government effectiveness, the results of field research in these villages again provide a mixed picture. On the one hand, social services and programs are evidently functioning in the village with Gram Panchayat sup port. On the other hand, the survey in 2000 found that only 15 of 80 respondents (19 percent) thought that government effectiveness had improved since institutionalization of the Gram Panchayats, while 24 (30 percent) respondents thought that it had worsened, and the rest did not know or did not respond. When asked to discuss why accountability worsened, the most frequent answer was that the representatives under the previous panchayat system were more educated and thus, more aware of notions of governance and also more likely to enforce them. The feedback on changes in administrative burden was even less encouraging. When asked if the administrative burden that villagers faced when trying to get goods or services from the government had increased or decreased since implementation of the new Panchayat system, 38 of the 80 survey respondents (48 percent) in 2000 said that the burden had worsened, while only 21 (26 percent) thought it had
78 Karnataka – competitive local governments improved. Moreover, these opinions did not seem to differ by gender or caste background. Follow-up interviews with key informants and focus groups discussions on why people thought that the regulatory burden might have increased revealed a myriad of answers, including an increase in bribes that must be paid to get work done; a diminished understanding of who should be approached to get something done; more layers of government; and lack of knowledge of some Gram Panchayat members about how to deal with various issues. At the same time, those informants who thought that the administrative burden had worsened, as well as those who thought it had improved, acknowledged that government was closer to them now than under the previous panchayat system. Follow-up interviews and focus group discussions in 2000 and again in 2008 revealed that by having government representatives who now lived in their village, many villagers had a sense that they at least had a person living physically close to them to whom they could turn if they had questions or needed some services from the government. But having local gov ernment representatives did not appear to have improved the transaction costs associated with availing oneself of government services. The feedback from the 2000 survey on violence and rule of law was also not encouraging. Only 23 survey respondents (29 percent) thought that violence had decreased and only five stated that rule of law had improved, while the majority of respondents though there had been no change in the rule of law. Yet in-depth discussions with survey respondents and key informants, both in 2000 and 2007/2008, provided a more detailed understanding of these perceptions of change. The observations of increased violence were largely attributable to intergenerational change and increased party competition. Many survey respondents stated that the younger generation had less respect for elders and were more engaged in party politics, leading to increased political violence. Many of those who stated that violence had increased stated that violence only increased around elections. The entrance of an increased number of political parties vying for votes at elections and the new presence of party politics at the village level led to an increased politicization of local governance. Several key informants stated that newer parties had emerged and these now clashed with the Congress Party – a phenomenon that emerged in the early 1990s The mixed picture of changing governance in the villages of Gavi Nagamangala and Mudabal is also reflected in perceptions of corruption. When asked directly whether corruption had changed over the past decade, respondents were more posit ive. Of the 80 survey respondents, 54 (68 percent) said that corruption had decreased between 1990 (before the Karnataka Panchayat Raj Act had been legislated) and 2000. Furthermore, when these 54 villagers were asked whether the decrease in corruption was due to the Gram Panchayats, 30 (56 percent) thought so, while 10 (19 percent) thought that decreased corruption was due to other factors. However, focus group discussions and individual interviews found that while there was a perception that the rule of law had deteriorated between 1990 and 2000, Gram Panchayats were not seen as being responsible for the change. Follow-up interviews in 2000 and discussions in 2008 to understand why there was such a perception of worsening rule of law, indicated that while violations of the
Karnataka – competitive local governments 79 law in the past were usually dealt with within the village, there has been an increasing move to refer matters to the nearest police station. Operations of justice thus appear now to be more removed than formerly, when village elders and caste panchayats dealt with breaches of the law. The perception of how the rule of law has changed in these villages thus might not be directly related to the presence of the new panchayat system.
The general quality of governance Decentralization in Karnataka has brought government closer to the village level – and while the new local government system is one of the most innovative among Indian states, the previous panchayat system, although it lasted only five years, was more radical and empowering of local governments. When villagers were asked to compare changes in governance in the year 2000 to the system in place before institutionalization of the new panchayat system, they were often comparing it to a system that, according to most studies, was the most decentralized in India, one that assigned much power to local governments. This partially explains why, in the case of Karnataka, the presence of Gram Panchayats has not unequi vocally improved governance from the perspective of most villagers. Rather, the perceived quality of governance has improved in some areas while remaining the same or worsening in others. According to the village surveys results, 30 of the 80 (38 percent) respondents thought that they were more likely to be listened to under the new local government system. Also, 35 survey respondents (44 percent) thought that accountability had improved under the new system, but 26 (33 percent) also thought that the new system was no different in accountability from the old one. Most thought that government was less effective, that the administrative burden had increased, and that there was less visible rule of law in 2000 compared to 1990. Yet 54 of the 80 survey respondents (68 percent) in 2000 thought that corruption had decreased and the majority thought the decrease was attribut able to the Gram Panchayats. Interviews with key informants conducted in 2008 yielded a similarly mixed perception of accountability and governance. There is further evidence about this mixed picture of changes in governance. With the institutionalization of Gram Panchayats more information was made available to villagers on the amounts of funding allocated to their local govern ment for socioeconomic programs. The greater visibility of government transactions at the village level was a direct result of the presence of Gram Panchayats at the local level, as well as the recent innovations to enhance the financial transparency of local governments, for example through social audits. In both the village Gram Panchayats, the ledgers keeping accounts of funds received from the central and state governments and disbursed through different programs were available to the public – which was not the case in any of the villages studied in West Bengal and Uttar Pradesh. It is this increased transparency that has likely had an impact on the perception of decreased corruption in these villages, because when corruption occurs it is likely to be more visible – in itself an effective deterrent. Two panchayat members candidly stated in 2000 that
80 Karnataka – competitive local governments corruption was less likely to occur now, because their families and neighbors would be more likely to know if a Gram Panchayat member were involved in corruption. Group discussion in 2008 yielded similar findings. These findings are backed by other village studies in Karnataka indicating that while the number of people involved in corruption might have increased with decentralization (as quoted in Crook and Manor 1998; Kadekodi et al. 2006) – which in itself might be thought of as “democratization of corruption” – the amount of overall funds misappropriated very likely declined. Corruption was also held in check by the sporadically functioning Gram Sabhas (GS), where representatives are supposed to present and discuss Gram Panchayat ledgers. All respondents to the 2000 survey, as well as those who had attended Gram Sabha meetings who were interviewed in 2000 and 2008, said that panchayat finances and beneficiary selection were discussed, although the extent of these discussions is not clear. Moreover, as more information becomes available through electronic linking of Gram Panchayats to block- and district- level panchayats, as well as to the Department of Rural Development and Panchayat Raj at the state level, and with increased requirements for disseminating these records, corruption is likely to be further averted. The overall findings of the 2000 and 2008 village studies were one of improved governance as a result of having local government officials at the village level. While many complained about the increase in administrative burden during the 1990s, few attributed this to the panchayats. Several respondents, including one panchayat member, pointed to increased transparency and empowerment of formerly marginalized groups and said that these changes exemplified the slowly evolving power dynamics within the village. The majority of respondents, moreover, stated that corruption had decreased since institutionalization of the new system. Many conversations, particularly in 2008, attested to a common perception that the increased resources for development flowing to the Gram Panchayats, together with having local government representatives from their villages, had made corrupt transactions more difficult to hide – thereby decreasing corruption overall. Interviews with village elites also revealed that the formerly dominant caste groups in the villages were realizing that the Gram Panchayat system with its reservations is now a permanent sys tem. Having female and lower-caste representatives in local government, together with greater transparency of local government transactions, are ensuring that not only do social services function, but also that those resources have a greater likelihood of reaching their intended beneficiaries. Together with increasing awareness of local government structures and how they ought to function, including the biannual gathering of the Gram Sabha, these factors are improving democratic inclusion and governance in the villages in Karnataka.
Civil society and elites Key to understanding local government functioning in these two villages was also the social interactions among the villagers and the attitude of social elites
Karnataka – competitive local governments 81 towards the new panchayat system. Understanding relations between different religious and caste groups in a country and state where social norms of inter action are still conservative is essential to understanding the dynamics in the village and within the Gram Panchayat. Building on Robert Putnam’s thesis that civic organizations that bridge social cleavages are key to building social capital, which in turn undergirds the foundations of democracy (Putnam 1993, 2000), the survey in 2000 and focus group discussions in 2000 and again in 2008, asked questions about the presence of religious and caste group bridging associations in the village and about social interactions among villagers. In contrast to both of the other state case studies, 59 of the 80 survey respondents (74 percent) in these villages stated that there were such associations in their village and 31 respondents (39 percent) stated that they had participated in such associations. Examples given included an association to market raw silk, a temple maintenance associ ation (across different caste groups), and a farmers’ association. By 2008 there were many more examples of such associations, including a women’s cooperative in each village that bought and prepared school meals, a government- financed rabbit-raising cooperative, and a group of parents who organized to clean and paint the local elementary school. Not only were there increasing examples of villagers interacting across caste divisions by 2008, but responses given during interviews with key informants in that year showed that increasing public funding distributed through the GP directly led to the formation of some of these organizations, such as the women’s cooperative that cooked lunch for the local elementary school children. Social and economic elites in both villages also furthered the democratic workings of the local Gram Panchayat. Elites in these villages belonged to the dominant castes in Karnataka and were viewed as elites due to their social and economic standing in the village. After identifying such socioeconomic elites in each village with the help of key informants, interviews with three leaders in each village were conducted in 2000, with follow-up interviews in 2008. These interviews backed the information given by other key informants: the elites in these villages are supportive of the new local government system. Two out of the three leaders in each of the villages had run successfully for office either at the local or district level and all talked about the system in posit ive terms.
Did social wellbeing improve? The main question of these village studies is whether the Gram Panchayats have mattered by contributing to improved social wellbeing. General social and eco nomic wellbeing improved in Karnataka between 1990 and 2011 and this section analyzes whether this improvement held true for the villages of Gavi Nagamangala and Mudabal, and whether any of the changes can be linked to the presence of Gram Panchayats. While economic growth rates for Karnataka as a whole since the early 1990s were high, this was largely driven by the very high growth rates of
82 Karnataka – competitive local governments urban areas, Bangalore city in particular. Bangalore Rural District performed better than some other districts, as it moved between 1991 and 2001 from twelfth to sixth in rankings of the state’s districts by gross domestic income (Government of Karnataka 2006). It is also clear from progress in social indicators, from discussions with researchers of changes in socioeconomic wellbeing in Bangalore Rural District,6 and from interviews with villagers on the changing economic opportunities and wage ates within their village and outside, that socioeconomic indicators within the district improved since the early 1990s. Yet these changes were modest and nowhere comparable to the high statewide economic growth rates that were driven by urban Bangalore. Among the 80 survey respondents in the two villages in 2000, 46 (58 percent) stated that socioeconomic wellbeing had improved in Gavi Nagamangala and Mudabal during the 1990s. This perception was confirmed by interviews in 2008. Moreover, village observations in 2008 clearly attested to improved social and physical infrastructure, as well as new economic opportunities, most of which were provided by anti-poverty programs such as micro-loans to women’s groups. However, perceptions of the role that the local government has played in improving that wellbeing are mixed. On the one hand, of the 46 respondents who said in the 2000 survey that they were better off, 29 (63 percent) came from lower caste background – evidence that those of traditionally poorer backgrounds made socioeconomic gains during the 1990s (no difference in answers was found between men and women). On the other hand, of the 46 respondents who said they were better off in the 2000 survey, only 19 (41 percent) thought that the local gov ernment had played any role in improving their social wellbeing. The majority of respondents did not think that their local panchayats had made any difference in their wellbeing. These findings are congruent with the evidence of functioning social welfare programs in the village. Observations in 2000 and again in 2008 revealed that social welfare programs were working in both villages, as were anti-poverty programs, with 70 of the 80 survey respondents (88 percent) attesting to this in 2000. Moreover, selected follow-up of these survey respondents in 2000 indicated that these programs appear to be reaching their targeted beneficiaries. However, despite all 80 survey respondents stating that there were social welfare programs working in their village, only 24 (30 percent) thought that their local governments were responsible for delivering the social services. In sum, although there is a perception that wellbeing has improved, most do not perceive the Gram Panchayat as having played a role in those improvements. Knowledgeable key informants confirmed that wellbeing improved in these villages and in the district during the 1990s.7 Evidence that people living in Gavi Nagamangala and Mudabal were better off at the turn of the century than a decade earlier is also borne out by the earlier studies of these villages, which found that literacy rates and laborer wages had increased between the late 1980s and late 1990s (Karanth 1987, 1994; interview with G. K. Karanth on May 4, 2000). In addition, interviews with selected village-level officials such as village
Karnataka – competitive local governments 83 health workers, schoolteachers, and Gram Panchayat members in 2000 and again in 2008 all attested to these village-level improvements in social wellbeing during the 1990s and up to 2008. Yet, although the Gram Panchayats were instrumental in drawing up the lists of beneficiaries of social welfare programs and in releasing funds, and despite these programs working in both the villages, the majority of respondents did not think that their Gram Panchayat was involved in delivering these programs. This seeming contradiction can be explained by perceptions of the funding of social welfare programs and of the weakly functioning Gram Sabhas. Several rounds of group interviews and in- depth interviews with key informants were conducted in 2000 and again in 2008 to resolve this paradox. They yielded that since the central or state governments have traditionally funded and continue to fund anti-poverty programs, the continuance of their implementation was not credited to Gram Panchayats but rather to higher levels of government. Evidently, many villagers were not aware of the structure and responsibilities of the new panchayat system. The lack of well- functioning Gram Sabhas is closely related to this issue. If Gram Sabhas had taken place at least twice a year as mandated, if villagers had been actively involved in social welfare program beneficiary selection, and if there had been wide dissemination of Gram Panchayat financial accounts, then the beneficiary selection process would have been more democratic, more likely to be targeted, and more illustrative of the Gram Panchayats’ role in social welfare program implementation. In the absence of frequent Gram Sabhas, social program delivery was attributed to upper levels of government, rather than local governments, despite the functioning local governments in these villages.
Have local governments contributed to improved wellbeing? Before turning to an overall assessment of local governments’ role in improving social wellbeing in Karnataka, we should keep in mind that the social and polit ical dynamics in Karnataka are different from those of the other two case study states. Civil society in Karnataka is lively and civic associations that bridge religious and caste cleavages abound, as witnessed by 59 of the 80 survey respondents (74 percent) in 2000 who stated that such associations exist in their village. Interviews and focus group discussions in 2008 confirmed that a rise in such civic associations has occurred in these villages over the past decade. Organized civic associations are not limited to upper caste and other dominant groups, and are not all based on caste or religious cleavages. Moreover, political parties de facto compete in Gram Panchayat elections. Unlike Uttar Pradesh, where the same landed, upper-caste groups have dominated state and local politics, and unlike West Bengal, where one-party dominance has resulted in a situation where access to the state and state-distributed social goods is largely dependent on party membership, Karnataka has been much less marked by socioeconomic and political inequalities. Less inequality, a lively history of multi-party com petition, civic associations that bridge social cleavages, and village elites who work with the local government system, have bolstered the democratic nature of
84 Karnataka – competitive local governments local governments. These were already quite transparent and competitive in the early 1990s, and continued to improve in transparency in the nearly two decades since the passage of the 73rd Amendment. Competition between political parties at the state level increased particularly since the early 1990s, with a more frequent turnover of power between different parties. It was also a system where social forces by the turn of the century were used to working with and through the established political and bureaucratic system. Decentralization in Karnataka was placed in more fertile political soil, increasing the likelihood that functioning local governments would further help improve social welfare. But it was the social dynamics in these villages – where current elites were not a clearly identi fiable group and traditional elites of dominant caste background did not capture the resources distributed by the Gram Panchayat, and where political competi tion in local elections crossed caste and socioeconomic cleavages – that provided for an environment where village-level governments were more likely to function as intended. Residents of Gavi Nagamangala and Mudabal were clearly better off at the turn of the century compared to 1990. Yet can these improvements in social wellbeing be attributed to the newly functioning Gram Panchayats? Or would these villagers have been just as well off if the 1993 Karnataka Panchayat Raj Act had not been passed and village governments had been allowed to remain dysfunctional? Other than West Bengal, Karnataka is the only other example of an Indian state that had innovative and functioning local governments prior to the 73rd constitutional amendment. Yet while West Bengal has had continuously functioning local governments since 1977, the previous local government experiment in Karnataka lasted only five years (from 1987 to 1992) and there was no functioning local government system in place at the time of the passage of the 1993 Karnataka Panchayat Raj Act. This intermission complicates analysis of the Karnataka case. Interviews with key informants in 2000 and again in 2008 were aimed at ascertaining conditions before and after implementation of the new local government system, and yet respondents invariably compared the current system with the previous system – a system that Crook and Manor have already documented as being one of the most innovative and responsible local govern ments (Crook and Manor 1998). Under the 1987 local government system, corruption declined, the responsiveness of government officials improved, and delivery of projects by local governments increased – due in large measure to the large degree of political and financial power given to local governments (Crook and Manor 1998). In comparison, the Karnataka panchayat system implemented in 1993 was at first modest in its devolution of powers, though it went much further than the previous system in reserving seats for SC/ST, women, and later the OBC. The tepid response of many villagers to questions about the role of local government in delivering social services in the late 1990s thus needs to be understood in the historical context of a previous system that was quite revolutionary and had already brought about significant changes in wellbeing at the local level.
Karnataka – competitive local governments 85 Social wellbeing increased in the villages that were studied, and social wel fare programs were helping their poorer beneficiaries to improve their wellbeing. Yet for villagers these improvements were not attributed to the Gram Panchayats, even though Gram Panchayats were evidently involved in program implementation. A lack of awareness of Gram Panchayat functioning and the fact that Gram Sabhas were not functioning as they were mandated, are likely explanations for this incongruence. Recent developments in Karnataka are strengthening the capacity of local governments to help improve social wellbeing. Since implementation of the new local government system in 1993, an outcry among panchayat representatives about their lack of power has led to increasing devolution of political and finan cial powers over the past years. Some of these – for example, reservations for the other backward castes (OBC) and term limits for Gram Panchayat chairpersons – were implemented before the village research was conducted in 2000. Other changes designed to improve the functioning of local governments, such as a doubling of the funds allotted to each Gram Panchayat, an increase of the proportion of untied funds at the Gram Panchayat level, training of all panchayat members, and linking of all Gram Panchayat financial records via electronic databases, are recent changes, many of them implemented between 2004 and 2011. The local government system that was analyzed through village studies in 2000 and again in 2008 has had more political and financial powers devolved to it since then, and the system itself is being made more transparent and account able. This makes the likelihood of Karnataka’s local governments contributing towards better delivery of social services and improved social wellbeing even greater today.
The story emerging from the Karnataka village studies An enabling environment in the early 1990s The emerging story from the village studies in Karnataka is that the environment into which decentralized structures were placed was conducive to functioning local governments, which in turn made them better able to deliver public programs aimed at increasing social wellbeing. The three cases of states in India researched in this book do not provide one specific answer as the key to understanding the link between local governments and the targeted delivery of social services that ultimately help improve social wellbeing. Decentralization is a complicated process, with interlinking local conditions – of elite structure and political buy-in to the decentralization process, political competition, and social mobilization – determining the environment in which local governments function. The process of decentralization and social service delivery in Gavi Nagamangala and Mudabal is a particularly dynamic and multifaceted one. Having a functioning local government system during the late 1980s mattered, especially since local government officials held substantial powers over bureaucrats.
86 Karnataka – competitive local governments As highlighted in Crook and Manor’s study of decentralization in Karnataka in the late 1980s under the previous system, bureaucrats at all levels were made more accountable to elected politicians than ever before (Crook and Manor 1998: 45). Moreover, Crook and Manor found that corruption declined and transparency increased during the previous panchayat system. The examples that these short years of decentralized governance provided were crucial for demonstrating the benefits of local governments to the citizens of Karnataka. However, contrary to Crook and Manor’s findings, discussions with villagers repeatedly yielded a sense that the previous system of local governments was removed from the daily life of villagers. The new Gram Panchayat system, on the other hand, has brought government closer to the village level by decreasing the population size to be covered by the Gram Panchayat. The majority of respondents knew the name of several local representatives in the Gram Panchayat, while few even among the older population could recall the names of representatives under the previous system. At the same time, the previous system only functioned for a few years – not long enough for most villagers to notice a difference in their personal wellbeing. Yet historical antecedents by themselves are not a sufficient guarantee for functioning local governments, as is seen in the following chapter on West Bengal. In Karnataka, the historical legacy of a working system of local governance together with a state government in the early 1990s that was committed to decentralization provided the conditions for successful implementation of decentralized governance. In addition to this enabling framework, an aware and mobilized civil society and a politically competitive environment forestalled “capturing” of local democracy by elites in the villages of Karnataka, in marked contrast to West Bengal and Uttar Pradesh. The village studies provide a microcosm of state-level political and social dynamics that led village elites to work with the local government structures, rather than undermining them. Previous state-level and village-level research indicates that, after a divisive period during the 1980s, sociopolitical cleavages had become less salient. While upper- and middle-caste groups had earlier dominated state and subnational pol itics (Kohli 1987; Crook and Manor 1998), by the early 1990s lower-caste groups had become more organized and assertive, leading to better political representation at each level of state and subnational government. Increased democratic competition between political parties at the national and state levels also meant that all political parties needed to appeal to the numerically important middle- and lower-caste groups. The general increase in political competition in Karnataka was reflected in the villages in the early 1990s, where party affili ations crossed caste cleavages and traditional social elites saw their power diminish. Sociopolitical interaction at the village level was based less on caste hierarchies or political dominance, and more on social or political issues facing the village. Taken together, all these factors made for an environment conducive to the flourishing of local government structures when the first Gram Panchayat elections took place in 1993. Decentralization in turn accelerated political repres entation of women and SC/ST, while political competition increased as parties
Karnataka – competitive local governments 87 sought to establish machineries at the national, state and village levels. All these factors helped root democracy by decreasing the power of traditional caste elites, and those former elites in turn sought to remain influential by joining competit ive political parties. Functioning Gram Panchayats Given the enabling environment for local governance at the state as well as village levels, how did the Gram Panchayats function in these Karnataka villages? First, perceptions of Gram Panchayat elections were virtually unanimous that they were devoid of corruption. Respondents stated that they would have “seen” any corruption occurring, and that they were confident that local elections were free of fraud. In the eyes of the villagers, elections at the village level, with people they knew campaigning for political office, made the whole political pro cess more transparent than before. The 2000 village surveys found that 54 of the 80 respondents (68 percent) perceived corruption to have decreased since 1991. Follow-up research in 2008 indicated that villagers from different social backgrounds were aware of the increased measures mandated to improve transparency of GP workings, such as the newly installed GP computers and the requirement to post their balance sheets, as well as social audits. The changes made by the Karnataka government to improve local government transparency were trickling down to the villages, and village residents were noticing the implementation of these changes. Having Gram Panchayata set aside seats for women and SC/ST also contrib uted to a sense of empowerment and “equalization” of social interaction. In the villages studied, as well as in Karnataka overall, the average percentages of SC/ ST and women elected per GP exceeded the percentages of seats reserved for each group, as seen in Table 3.2. Not only did the quotas directly lead to greater representation for women and SC/ST, but also women as well as members of the SC/ST population were elected to office in their own right in numbers that went beyond the reserved seats. In the 2005 elections, 43 percent of all GP representatives were women, the second highest figure in India (Government of Karnataka 2007). Interviews of women GP members in 2000 and 2008 in the villages studied repeatedly revealed a sense of pride and accomplishment in being able to participate in local politics. Mirroring findings by researchers in other states (Chattopadhyay and Duflo 2003, 2004) as well as in Karnataka (Kadekodi et al. 2007), the reserved seats for women and SC/ST yielded noticeable results. Women and people of SC/ST background stated that they were more likely to contact a GP representative if needed because having women and SC/ST representatives made government more accessible. While women were observed during GP and focus-group meetings to be less assertive than their male counterparts, there was an observable increase in female assertiveness in the Gram Panchayat meetings observed in 2008 compared to 2000. Women representatives in these two Gram Panchayats were increasingly able to act as a conduit of information between the GP and female public employees, such as the female
88 Karnataka – competitive local governments village healthcare workers tasked with mobilizing the village population for immunization drives. They also became advocates for women’s and children’s issues ranging from health care to education. In contrast to findings from the late 1980s (Crook and Manor 1998; Karanth 1987), women representatives in these villages were initiating and contributing to improved policies to benefit their constituents. Improved social wellbeing By the early 1990s the political and social environment in Karnataka had become increasingly dynamic. Social and economic distances between different caste groups were no longer as large as in decades past, and the state government was progressive not only in quickly implementing decentralization in 1993 but also in allocating increasingly larger percentages of expenditure to the social sectors and to primary education and basic health within those respective sectors. The decreasing social distance between different castes changed the social dynamic in villages. Previous studies of these villages in the late 1980s and early 1990s revealed increased political activism among and social interaction between people of different caste backgrounds, as exemplified by a dispute over the site of a new temple, with the two sides in the dispute bridging caste cleavages (Karanth 1994; interview with G. K. Karanth, May 2000). Disputes in these villages were issue-based, rather than motivated by religion, caste, or other social divisions. By the early 1990s, these villages were already exhibiting increased political competition between parties that crossed caste cleavages. By 2000 the decreasing social distance between castes had made for improved interaction between groups of different socioeconomic backgrounds. Coupled with rapidly improving literacy rates, awareness of rights, and political competition, it made for an environment where villagers mobilized around social issues that cut across social and economic cleavages. As the survey results, key informant interviews, focus group discussions, and observation of dynamics between different socio economic groups in the village, all attest, social cleavage-bridging civil associ ations, in an environment of political competition, provided a check on former caste elites capturing local political structures. In this environment, there were increasingly fewer caste, social, or political elites who would have been likely to capture social benefits, a trend that continued through 2008. Decentralization in Karnataka occurred in a competitive and dynamic environment, one that was likely to yield results for social wellbeing. This enabling environment for decentralization was present in Karnataka well into the twenty-first century. Decentralization was guided by state law and the state government in Karnataka through 2011 was at the forefront of implementing decentralization and allocating increased resources to local governments. The residents of the villages studied did not engage extensively in local political life and very few contacted or protested against their GP representatives for any reason. Yet the vast majority of survey respondents and key informants, regard less of caste, religious or gender background, pointed out that they could easily
Karnataka – competitive local governments 89 Table 3.3 Karnataka: Results of selected questions from small sample survey in each village in 2000, number responding positively (percentages in parentheses)
Voted in last national elections Thought last national elections were fair Voted in last GP elections Thought last GP elections were fair Campaigned for the election of a GP member Knew the name of GP representative(s) Have participated in a meeting of the village electorate There are working social welfare programs in the village GP instrumental in delivering these social services There are working anti-poverty programs in village GP instrumental in delivering these antipoverty programs GP been able to satisfy the most important needs in the village If two poor people applied for an antipoverty scheme to the GP and one had political connections while the other did not, the GP would give the scheme to the politically connected person (additional question) More voice under new GP system Less violence in 2000 compared to 1990 Rule of law has improved between 1990 and 2000 Government has become more effective Administrative burden has decreased Accountability has improved Corruption decreased over past ten years Was better off in 2000 compared to 1990 Of those who said they were better off, those who said they were better off due to the GP There are associations (religion and caste bridging) in this village Have participated in associations during last 5 years Have contacted their GP representative in the last 5 years for help
Gavi Nagamangala Mudabal (n = 40) (n = 40)
Total (n = 80)
38 40 40 40 12
40 40 40 40 10
78 (98%) 80 (100%) 80 (100%) 80(100%) 22 (27%)
38 12
38 11
76 (95%) 23 (29%)
40
40
80 (100%)
12
12
24 (30%)
34
36
70 (88%)
7
6
13 (16%)
22
23
45 (56%)
10
12
22 (28%)
15 11 2
15 12 3
30 (38%) 23 (29%) 5 (6%)
9 10 15 26 22 10
6 11 17 28 24 9
15 (19%) 21 (26%) 32 (40%) 54 (68%) 46 (58%) 19 (41%)
31
28
59 (74%)
15
16
31 (39%)
7
8
15 (19%)
90 Karnataka – competitive local governments contact their local government representative should the need arise. Moreover, increased political competition between a greater number of political parties and the decrease in power of caste-based, traditional elites, led Gram Panchayats to be more transparent and held more accountable by the villages of Gavi Nagamangala and Madabal. Decentralization in this politically competitive environment created opportun ities at the village level for greater participation in local governance, particularly among women and people of SC/ST background. This in turn created new opportunities for emerging local politicians from a variety of social backgrounds, and members of an increasing number of political parties to engage in local gov ernments, thereby rooting governments at the village level and launching local bases of support for increasingly dynamic and politically competitive politics in Karnataka. In this environment, the Gram Panchayats for the villages of Gavi Nagamangala and Madabal were notable for the lack of cooption by elites and the perception of decreased corruption. They were able to target and deliver poverty-alleviation programs, ensure that students were taught at local schools, and foster the delivery of basic healthcare. Gram Panchayat representatives in these villages were increasingly functioning as agents of “economic development and social justice” as originally envisioned in the constitutional amendment (Government of India 1992). Into this fertile ground of Gram Panchayats that were helping to improve social wellbeing in Karnataka, recent innovations have further increased the transparency of government. These include computerizing all Gram Panchayats and requiring public posting of financial revenues and expenditures, directly transferring financial resources to GPs from the state through local banks, conducting training programs for GP members, and instituting “Ward Sabhas” for each constituency within the GPs. With such measures, local governments are more likely to be held accountable, graft is likely to decrease, and the Gram Panchayat’s ability to act as an agent of social wellbeing is enhanced. In Karnataka, civil society mobilization, a lack of elite capture of local resources, and a polit ically competitive environment helped enable the growth of well-functioning local governments. This was a virtuous and reinforcing dynamic of factors that were absent in West Bengal and Uttar Pradesh.
4 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost
If (the) Panchayat fails, CPI(M)’s experiment fails. – Dr. Ashok Mitra, former Finance Minister, West Bengal Power tends to corrupt, and absolute power corrupts absolutely. – Lord John Acton
When the 73rd Amendment mandating local governments throughout India was passed in 1993, West Bengal had the distinction of being the only state that made changes to its state constitution in anticipation of the 73rd Amendment (ISS 2000). West Bengal already had elected functioning local governments when the amendment was introduced and thus only had to make changes relating to the percentage of seats reserved for women and people of SC/ST background. West Bengal also has the longest history of functioning local governments in India: Gram Panchayat (GP) elections have been taking place regularly, every five years, for over 30 years. Local governments were mandated by the Communist Party of India (Marxist) (CPI(M)-dominated Left Front Government (LFG)) when they first came to power in 1977 and were seen as the backbone of the government’s efforts to carry through its economic and social reform agenda at the local level. They were essential to the LFG’s famous land reform program and without the panchayats, effective implementation of land reforms would have been unlikely. A study of West Bengal’s local governments and their abil ity to improve social welfare is therefore an ideal case to test the main question of this overall study: Do functioning local governments really matter for improving social wellbeing? The answer is that the historical, social, and political power context in which these local government structures are placed is crucial to understanding the differing functionality and capacity of local governments to implement social programs, thus leading to different social outcomes. West Bengal’s social indicators in 2010 and their improvements over the previous two decades were not as dramatic as supporters of the LFG or advocates of local government reform would have hoped. West Bengal represents a “middling case scenario” of the three cases studied here, because the long history of
92 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost elected local governments and a mobilized civil society have been offset by the lack of effective political competition under 34 years of uninterrupted domination of the LFG. This party domination has created new elites in West Bengal’s villages, elites who have largely captured social benefits intended for the indigent, thereby hampering the ability of the local governments to improve social indicators and overall wellbeing. Social outcomes in West Bengal have lagged behind the advances made since the early 1990s in Karnataka and, in the case of poverty rates, even lagged behind the average for all Indian states. Understanding the nexus between West Bengal’s local governments and changes in social wellbeing will provide insight into the ability of local governments to influence wellbeing and the factors that prevent local governance. The lack of significant social progress in West Bengal is puzzling because the state has ingredients that have been argued (Kohli 1987; Lieten 1996a) to be key to improved social outcomes, such as a pro-poor state government and elected local governments for the past three decades. Indeed, 34 years of a continuously elected communist state government, whose explicit goal has been poverty reduction and social welfare improvement through the election of village-level local governments, led researchers to argue that a pro-poor government, such as that of West Bengal, was the key ingredient for effective service delivery and improved social wellbeing. West Bengal’s social indicators are also not as good as predicted by a theory that posits states with a more highly developed subnational identity, such as West Bengal, are better at delivering social services to their constituents (Singh 2008). By 2010 poverty rates in West Bengal were higher than the Indian average with areas of the state, such as Jamboni block, registering extremely high poverty rates. The case of West Bengal is an enigma and deserving of research in its own right. It is an essential case to better understand why the presence of elected local governments, in a context of a state gov ernment whose stated aim it is to decrease poverty and a state with a strong subnational identity, is by itself insufficient for attaining significant improvements in social wellbeing. The key to understanding local governments in West Bengal is the historical context in which the new local government system was implemented in comparison to the other case study states. Karnataka had a brief, though pivotal, history of democratically elected and powerful local governments during the 1980s, while in Uttar Pradesh there was no significant history of democratically elected and functioning village governments. By contrast, West Bengal in 1993 had more than 15 years of continuously elected and empowered local governments, which had achieved noteworthy accomplishments by the early 1990s, including land reforms. The West Bengali village governments studied here were opera tional and delivering social and anti-poverty services to their constituents at the time of the 73rd Amendment’s passage. While net state domestic product growth rates between 1993/1994 and 2008/2009 were similar in West Bengal and Karnataka, rural poverty rates in 2006/2007, for example, remained higher in West Bengal than in Karnataka,
West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 93 around the national average of 21 percent (see Table 2.3). West Bengal’s improvements in social indicators since the early 1990s has not matched the progress made in Karnataka. The unique political conditions in West Bengal, where the CPI(M)-dominated LFG has been in power for over 30 years, has meant that local governments are also controlled by CPI(M) members and are much more likely to distribute social welfare benefits to party members, who are often not the poorest. Local governments in many instances have been coopted by the CPI(M) with the party becoming the new patronage network in both the villages studied. It is the lack of competition with CPI(M)-dominated local governments that leads to allocation of anti-poverty and social welfare programs often being made on the basis of party affiliation rather than greatest need. Local governments in these West Bengali villages are not fully “democratic” in the sense that they do not practice the pursuit of one of their mandates: that of improving social equality through directing anti-poverty and social welfare programs to the poorest. Decentralizing political power to village governments in West Bengal has not led to the anticipated better targeting and delivery of social programs for the most indigent. By studying two villages in a Bengali district with near state average indicators, this study will delve into the links between presence of functioning local governments and changes in social wellbeing, as well as exploring whether it is only the pres ence of local democracy that matters or also the quality and nature of the government. This chapter is structured as follows: After providing background informa tion, the first section gives an overview of the rise of the LFG during the late 1970s and social reforms achieved under their tenure, including the implementation of functioning Gram Panchayats as a tool for social reform. It then details the structure and workings of local governments and social indicators in West Bengal and in the district where the two village studies are located before implementation of the 73rd Amendment in the early 1990s. Subsequently, findings from the village studies are presented, including changes in social wellbeing and local government’s actions to improve social welfare. The chapter then concludes with an analysis of whether the Gram Panchayats in the village studies and in West Bengal in general can be shown to have improved social wellbeing, whether this has changed with implementation of 73rd Amendment, and what conditions would contribute towards greater improvements in social wellbeing.
Decentralized government in West Bengal Decentralization in West Bengal in the early 1990s took place in an environment that already had experience with local governments. Indeed the extent of land reforms and decentralization carried out in West Bengal were the highest of any Indian states with several studies linking the degree of land reform in West Bengal with the presence and effectiveness of local governments (Lieten 1996a, 1996b; Bhattacharya 2002). The experience with and perceived success
94 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost of political decentralization in West Bengal created an environment for implementing the 73rd Amendment that was quite different from that in Uttar Pradesh or Karnataka. Major amendments to the West Bengal Panchayat Act were undertaken in 1992 and 1994 in order to bring the act in congruity with the 73rd Constitutional Amendment, including increasing the representation of women, who were also among the chairpersons of panchayats, and mandating representa tion of SC and ST groups. The decentralized structure in West Bengal is now similar to that in Uttar Pradesh and Karnataka in that it is a three-tiered structure as mandated by the constitution. Unlike in Uttar Pradesh, however, the lowest level of decentralized government, the Gram Panchayat, represents a group of villages rather than one village, with the average Gram Panchayat representing a population of 15,000 (Mathew 2000). Since periodic meetings of the entire voting constituency of a Gram Panchayat would be too unwieldy to reach decisions such as village-level selection of social program beneficiaries, the West Bengali government decided to create biannual meetings of a village’s voting population, called Gram Sansad (literally meaning village parliament), along with the annual meetings of voters of a Gram Panchayat, called Gram Sabha (GS). This structure of decentralized government, as laid out in Figure 4.1, was devised in order to be congruent with the constitutional amendment while also enabling village-level issues to be addressed in a two- way feedback loop. Zilla Parishad � district-level government
Panchayat Samiti � block-level government
Gram Panchayat � local government for a group of villages
Gram Sansad � village voters
Gram Sansad � village voters
Gram Sabha � all voters within a Gram Panchayat
Gram Sansad � village voters
Figure 4.1 The structure of decentralized governments in West Bengal.
West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 95 The new village government structures provided greater potential for transparent local governance. Proposals and questions brought up at the Gram Sabha meetings were to be taken up and answered by the Gram Panchayat. Moreover, as envisioned in the 73rd Amendment, the meetings of the GS were institutionalized as the forum for identifying anti-poverty program beneficiaries and prioritizing social welfare works in the village. The GPs were then supposed to draw up lists of social program beneficiaries, based on the discussions and decisions made during the GS meetings. In theory this system had the potential to enable active participation in democratic governance by all villagers and provided signi ficant village control over the functioning of the Gram Panchayats. On the political front, unlike most other Indian states, West Bengal has experienced remarkable political continuity over the past three decades. Since its initial victory in 1977, the coalition comprising the Left Front Government has won every state election in West Bengal. This continuity of power has enabled the state government the time and legitimacy to carry through much of its pro- poor developmental agenda, including the 1978 implementation of local govern ments in order to carry through their reform agenda at the local level. However, despite the long tenure of the LFG and its many notable pro-poor achievements, from land reform to the rapid decrease in poverty rates during the 1980s, the level of social indicators in the state as well as their rate of change over the last three decades has not matched those achieved in Karnataka, and certainly not those achieved in Kerala. As with Uttar Pradesh and Karnataka, social wellbeing in West Bengal, in terms of poverty rate and social indicators, is not simply a function of its eco nomic growth rates or the political party in power – two of the more common explanations given for the level of social improvements in Indian states. Social development in West Bengal is clearly not only a derivative of the state’s growth rate. West Bengal’s overall economic growth rates during the 1980s were below the Indian average and yet improvements in social indicators, including decreasing poverty rates and improving health and educational indicators, were above the Indian average. During the 1990s per capita income and economic growth rates in West Bengal increased, largely as a result of agricultural growth, and were above the Indian average, comparable to those of Karnataka and better than those of Kerala (Ministry of Statistics and Programme Implementation 2008). Nevertheless, West Bengal continued to lag behind Karnataka in some of its social indicators, including poverty incidence, and infant mortality, both in terms of the absolute rates as well as the rate of change of these indicators (see Table 2.3). West Bengal has not exhibited the dramatic improvements in social indic ators that one might have expected given the pro-poor orientation of the LFG, the durability of the party’s power in West Bengal, and the above average eco nomic growth rates in the state since the early 1990s. It remains a conundrum in the political science, economics and development literature: one where conventional explanations do not hold. Yet it is important to understand the ingredients influencing changes in social wellbeing in the third largest state economy in India in 2010 with a population over 80 million in 2001. Why has West Bengal
96 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost not been able to translate its seemingly favorable framework for social progress into significant improvements to social wellbeing? West Bengal presents a par ticular conundrum to the advocates of local government and is therefore crucial to any understanding of local governments and the mechanisms and barriers to their capacity to improve indicators of social wellbeing. Moreover, in the larger history of socioeconomic development, West Bengal has traditionally been known as a rich and progressive state with above national average social indicators such as literacy rates. Over the past two decades, West Bengal has lost this position of preeminence. While economic growth rates in West Bengal as well as in India overall were low during the 1970s and 1980s, social sector improvements exhibited significant gains. Then, in the 1990s, eco nomic growth rates picked up and from 1993/1994 through 2008/2009 the net state domestic product grew at an average rate of over 5 percent (see Table 2.3) (Bhandari and Kale 2007b). Yet improvements in social indicators of wellbeing were mixed. For example, while literacy rates in West Bengal grew from 58 percent in 1991 to 69 percent in 2001, putting the state above the Indian average of 65 percent in 2001, the school dropout rate, at 71 percent in 2002, was substantially higher than the national average of 41 percent (Bhandari and Kale 2007b). Similarly, while West Bengal’s infant mortality rate and maternal mor tality ratio were better than the Indian averages in 2004/2005, an annual household survey by the National Sample Survey Organisation that same year found that West Bengal had the highest prevalence among Indian states of rural households who were not getting enough adequate food during some months of the year (National Sample Survey Organisation 2005). In a state that was the site of the first wave of industrialization in India, the state government in 2005/2006 spent only 1.6 percent of its aggregate disbursement on health and family wel fare, compared to the Indian average of 2.1, and only 5 percent on the education sector, compared to the national average of 7.2 percent (Bhandari and Kale 2007b). Similarly, only 12 percent of rural households in West Bengal have drinking water in their households, compared to the national average of 13 percent and in a state with surplus electricity only 48 percent of households have electricity compared to 64 percent national-wide in 2006 (Bhandari and Kale 2007b). Studying West Bengal is important not only because of its unique history of a stable pro-poor left-wing government over the past three decades, but also because it provides lessons about the state government’s attempt at social reform. Like Uttar Pradesh and Karnataka, West Bengal is one of the more populous Indian states and is the state with the highest population density. As with the other case study states, the size of West Bengal, in terms of area and popula tion, makes it comparable to many other countries and therefore worthy of study in its own right. And as with the other state chapters and country studies, gen eralizations about West Bengal hide large disparities within the state. Agro- climates vary greatly from the southern delta of the Hugli River at Calcutta, to the alluvial tracts of Medinipur, to the undulating, dry terrain of Birbhum dis-
West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 97 trict, and the mountainous terrain of Darjeeling district in the north, as do the social and economic conditions in these areas. While there are large variations between districts, the district where the villages chosen for case study are located most closely approximated average social, economic, and agro-climatic conditions. Previous studies of these villages in the early 1990s provide a baseline for comparison. Moreover, given that the local government structure and history is the same throughout West Bengal, findings from these village studies again provide an insight into the micro-logic undergirding state-level phenomena.
Political context Political and social stability has not always been a hallmark of West Bengal pol itics. At independence, the trauma of the division of Bengal, with the accom panying communal riots, famine, and high poverty rates, caused widespread suffering. In addition to these crises, the state government had to provide relief to the steady influx of Hindu refugees from East Pakistan (formerly East Bengal and now Bangladesh), thereby further straining the economy. The inability of the Congress Party-led West Bengal government to address the widespread misery led to a strengthening of leftist parties throughout the 1950s and 1960s, increasing political radicalization and turbulence. In 1967 a peasant uprising, called the Naxalites, which developed into a radical leftist movement that increased their support among disillusioned youth, broke out in Naxalbari, an area in northern West Bengal (Singh 2006). The Naxalites in West Bengal were violently repressed by a Congress-led government called the United Front (UF ), a coalition in which the Communist Party of India (Marxist) (CPI(M)) was a major ally (Roy 2010). In the midst of these political conflicts within the state, tensions between the central and West Bengal governments increased, thereby furthering political volatility in the state. These rising tensions between the West Bengal state and central government, led to the dismissal of the West Bengal government by the central government in February 1968 and a year of President’s Rule. In February 1969 a short-lived, year-long minority government known as the Bangla-Congress-led United Front government ruled. However, in March 1970, President’s Rule was imposed again, this time for a year, and was then followed by a three-month rule of the Indian National Congress Party-led coalition. In June 1971 President’s rule was imposed again for ten months, followed again by a Congress Party government, which ruled until the election victory and take-over of government by the CPI(M)-led Left Front Government in June 1977. During the late 1960s and early 1970s leftist parties, building on the growing resentment against the Congress Party within the state, made large electoral gains in West Bengal, though splits within the leftist parties led them to be junior partners in Congress-led coalition governments in the late 1960s and early 1970s. The independence movement of East Pakistan in 1971 and its winning of independence with the help of Congress-governed India, helped the fortunes of
98 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost the Congress Party in West Bengal for a few years, with a strengthened Congress government ruling West Bengal from 1972 to 1977. Prime Minister Indira Gandhi’s imposition of emergency laws in 1975 and the West Bengal govern ment’s heavy-handed response toward leftists only served to cause resentment amongst the lower and middle classes in West Bengal. By the time the federal government was forced to withdraw the emergency and call for national elections in 1977, resentment against the Congress Party was high throughout India and West Bengal in particular. In addition to the political turmoil of the 1970s, socioeconomic inequality in rural West Bengal throughout the 1970s was steep, both in terms of the disparity between large landowners and the landless and also in terms of caste rigidities. These larger socioeconomic divisions in West Bengal, as still in Uttar Pradesh today, led to more divisive politics in these states. While in Uttar Pradesh these socioeconomic differences resulted in caste politics and alienation of the poor, in West Bengal they led to the explosive class politics of the early 1970s and the subsequent extreme politicization of West Bengal today. Against this background of social misery and upheaval and the political turmoil of the 1960s and 1970s, it was not surprising that a CPI(M)-led Left Front Government (LFG) coalition emerged the winner of the 1977 West Bengal elections. With Jyoti Basu as chief minister, the leader of the CPI(M), the largest party in the coalition, the LFG ushered in an era of remarkable political stability. As seen in Figure 4.2, the CPI(M)-led LFG coalition continued to win every 45 40 CPM
Percentage of vote
35 30 Trinamul
25 20 15
Congress
10 Forward bloc
5 0
Revolutionary Socialist CPI
1977
1982
1987
1991 1996 Election year
2001
2006
Figure 4.2 Electoral outcomes in West Bengal elections, 1977–2001 (percentage of vote) (source: Electoral Commission of India 1977–2006).
West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 99 election held since 1977 and still forms the ruling coalition in West Bengal in 2011. After their 1977 electoral victory the LFG immediately set out to address the social misery and discontent that fermented during the political volatility of the previous decades. Radical land and tenancy reforms were initiated with the help of newly organized local governments and increased expenditures were devoted to the social sectors. As detailed in other studies, the Left Front Government was able to maintain party unity and implement social change by staffing government bodies with party cadres and setting about an ambitious and much-needed social agenda (Kohli 1987: see particularly chapter 3). Their ability to address some of the problems of widespread poverty and social misery contributed to their elect oral success. The CPI(M)-led Left Front Government’s continual electoral success between 1977 and 2010 provided West Bengal with political stability, but this stability has to be seen against the turbulent and agonizing political upheavals the state experienced during the 1960s and 1970s which wrought havoc on the economy and radicalized the political parties and populace. It is against this background that the LFG’s promises of increased social justice met the expectation and willingness of the people to implement more radical changes, and together enabled real change, particularly during the early years of this government (Lieten 1996b). Land reforms were implemented with zeal by local panchayats during the late 1970s and the 1980s, along with the building of schools and health care infrastructure. While poverty rate estimates differ for the period after 2001, due to a change in data collection and calculation methods, most estimates show a remarkable decrease in poverty rates in West Bengal, from around three-quarters of the population living below the poverty line in the early 1970s to about 35 percent by the early 1990s (Chatterjee 1998). Similarly, in the early 1970s, West Bengal’s growth rate for agricultural production was one of the slowest in the country, while by the late 1980s its rates were among the fastest, with an annual growth rate of 6.5 percent for food-grains production (Banerjee et al. 2002). By the 1980s West Bengal’s CPI(M)-led government was registering improved social indicators and social welfare in the state. Yet while the improvements in social indicators were good in most areas and dramatic in some sectors during the tenure of the LFG, they were not uniformly so throughout the sectors or over the 30 years of LFG tenure. In particular, pov erty rates over the past decade appear to have stagnated at best. Table 4.1 illus trates that the LFG’s anti-poverty rhetoric in the early part of the twenty-first century was certainly not matched by the actual share of expenditures accounted for by the social sectors, which remained below Indian averages.
Overview and choice of case studies in West Bengal This study of local governments in West Bengal analyzes the link between the long tenure of local governments in West Bengal and improvements in social outcomes, as well as assessing what might account for the social improvements
100 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost Table 4.1 Share of expenditure on education and public health in West Bengal versus allIndia averages, 2005 West Bengal
All-India average
Share of expenditure on education to total disbursements, 2005
5.0
7.2
Share of expenditure on medical, public health and family welfare as ratio to total disbursements, 2005/2006
1.6
2.1
Source: Bhandari and Kale 2007a.
not being as spectacular as anticipated. The theory and empirical studies of decentralization suggest that if decentralization is carried out so as to shift control over political and financial resources to the local level, and if it is done in a manner to enable increased accountability, voice, and responsiveness, then the functioning of local social welfare programs can improve. Additionally, some authors have posited that in order for local governments to really decrease pov erty and improve social welfare of the poorer and most vulnerable groups, the whole decentralized system needs to be dominated by a leftist party that has pov erty alleviation as a central goal of its political agenda (Kohli 1987; Crook and Manor 2001). Since West Bengal is the only Indian state that has been dominated by a leftist coalition for a significant length of time, as well as being the only one with long-functioning local governments, it is an ideal state to study whether local governments can make a significant difference in improving social wellbeing. West Bengal, unlike Uttar Pradesh and Karnataka, has had a state-supported and state-implemented panchayat system since 1977. Thus, it is a different type of case study from the other two states in that the local government system has been supported by the state government from its inception and in fact was seen as a critical tool for implementing the state government’s political agenda at the local level. Another factor that sets the panchayat system in West Bengal apart is the close nexus between the Left Front Government and the panchayat system at every level. Since 1977, the West Bengal panchayat law has allowed for local government candidates to campaign on a party basis. Moreover, it is likely that when the CPI(M)-led government was elected in 1977, it set about implementing local government structures as a way of building a rural base for its party (Bandyopadhyay 2008). The strategy worked, leading to a close, sometimes indistinguishable, nexus between the party and local government. State-level party politics and priorities continue to play a large role in Bengali local government, making it difficult to distinguish what role the Gram Panchayats play in implementing social programs versus what role the party plays. Furthermore, West Bengal is also a test of the state-centered argument that all meaningful improvements in social wellbeing of the population, from decreasing poverty to increasing literacy, can and should only be brought about from the top, through a state government that is ideologically committed to poverty
West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 101 eradication and social change. The LFG’s rhetoric and actions particularly during the first decade and a half of its rule portrayed a commitment to poverty reduction, and the LFG’s class and power alliances are with the poor and lower castes. As the coalition LFG’s main party, the CPI(M)’s party structure and organization with the help of local governments now allow it to reach down from the state capital to the village level to implement these anti-poverty programs. The West Bengal case study represents a “middling” scenario in that improvements in social welfare have slowed since the turn of the century and because current social indicators place it in the middle or slightly above the middle rank of Indian states. For example, West Bengal has high literacy rates, low infant mortality rates, and above average life expectancy, and its rate of rural poverty and primary school dropout rates are below the Indian average (see Table 2.3). (Government of West Bengal – Development and Planning Department 2005). Gains in social welfare since the 1990s have not been spectacular, yet it is the state with the longest history of functioning local governments. As with the other two states studied in this research, in the case study of West Bengal’s panchayats, the selected research district was chosen because it was closest to the state’s average indicators for social welfare (see Table 4.2), as this allowed for village findings to be more representative of decentralization within the state. Birbhum district, one of West Bengal’s 18 districts and located in the center of the state, met this criterion. Moreover, this district does not have the unusual geographical setting of some of the northern districts, which include economies based on hill stations and tea plantations. Nor is Birbhum district overshadowed by any large metropolitan area or the uniqueness of coastal eco nomies, like the districts in the southern part of the state around Kolkata. Within Birbhum district, two villages in the same administrative block were selected. These villages were studied in the late 1980s and early 1990s by the United Nations-sponsored WIDER study.1 The WIDER study provides insight into social and economic development in these villages after 13 years of functioning local governments and prior to the implementation of the Panchayat Raj Amendment in 1993. Kuchli and Sahahajapur, the two villages studied in West Bengal, are each about ten kilometers from Santiniketan, the block headquarters. The mainstay of the village population was agriculture, with 86 percent of the Kuchli households and 63 percent of the households in Sahahajapur working in agriculture in Table 4.2 Selected socioeconomic indicators, Birbhum District versus West Bengal averages
Population growth, 1991–2001 (%) Sex ratio, 2001 (females per 1,000 males) Adult literacy rate, 2001 (%) Household access to electricity, 2006 (%) Source: www. Indiastat.com. Accessed February 2007.
West Bengal
Birbhum District
17.8 934 69.2 48
17.9 950 63.2 42
102 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 1987–1989 (Sunil Sengupta et al. 1991). Poverty rates in these villages in the late 1980s were 40 and 52 percent respectively, compared to the West Bengal rural poverty rate at that time of 48 percent (Sunil Sengupta et al. 1991). Over 50 percent of villagers were literate in both villages in the early 1990s and the sex ratio was around 95 females per 100 males, similar to the average for Birbhum district (Government of India 1991). In general indicators for both villages around 1990 indicate continued social deprivation, though government anti-poverty programs appeared to be reaching a large percentage of their target beneficiaries according to earlier studies (Sunil Sengupta et al. 1991).
Kuchli and Sahahajapur around 1990 By 1990, West Bengal’s Gram Panchayats had already been functioning for 13 years, going through three rounds of elections. And in contrast to village govern ments elsewhere in India, elections were contested on the basis of parties. In Kuchli and Sahahajapur, as in most of West Bengal villages, leftist parties led by the CPI(M) swept to power, forming the backbone of the CPI(M)-led LFG at the state level. In 1990, 89.5 percent of the panchayat seats in Kuchli and 100 percent of the seats in Sahahajapur were held by members of the CPI(M) and other Left Front parties (Sengupta 1991). The LFG’s establishment of the new panchayat system along with the massive land distribution and tenancy cam paign of the 1980s paid electoral dividends in local as well as state elections. Revitalizing the panchayat system was one of the first initiatives undertaken by the Left Front Government after it was elected in 1977. Panchayats were given the power to carry out local government planning and 50 percent of all rural development funds were marked for spending and distribution through the panchayats. The panchayat system and particularly the Gram Panchayats were essential to the land reform program. In the villages of Kuchli and Sahahajapur, land reforms were undertaken as the major focus of the newly constituted panchayats, starting in the late 1970s and picking up speed in the 1980s. Land reforms in these two villages as in most others focused on land redistribution and tenancy reform. While no official record was available for the total amount of land and number of beneficiaries in these villages, interviews indicated that in each of the villages at least a dozen households (out of 142 in Kuchli and 227 in Sahahajapur) were beneficiaries of the land redistribution programs of the 1980s (Sunil Sengupta et al. 1991). In addition to land redistribution, land reforms included tenancy reform. All tenancy agreements were recorded by the local governments. Here again there were no village-specific data available, but inter views indicated that of those who were sharecroppers in 2000 and 2007/2008, most did receive the mandated two-thirds share of harvested crops, though there were a few incidents of people not getting their entitled share.2 A positive byproduct of the land reforms and grass-roots organization of the Left Front Government through the panchayats was that agricultural laborers became more unified and organized, thereby increasing their bargaining power. In Kuchli and Sahahajapur, the rice equivalent in kilograms of labor wages went up from a
West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 103 stagnant 2.6 in the 1960s through early 1980s to 3.42 for Kuchli and 3.3 for Sahahajapur in 1988 (Sengupta 1991). By 1990, landless and agricultural laborers were noticeably better off in terms of income than before the 1977 election of the LFG and the revitalization of the panchayats. Although the WIDER study of these villages did not analyze causal linkages between the presence of panchayats and improvements in economic wellbeing of the poor in West Bengal, other studies have pointed to the general benefits accrued to the poor under LFG rule particularly through land reform (Westergaard 1986; Lieten 1992; Webster 1992b; Datta 1993). During the 1980s great improvements were made in Kuchli and Sahahajapur, as well as most other West Bengali villages, in terms of breaking the power of the Zamindari (landlord) system and implementing general land reforms. However, given that one of the main aims of the Left Front Government had been to decrease poverty and improve the general wellbeing of the impoverished, it is noticeable that social indicators for these two villages, as for West Bengal in general, did not improve greatly. By 1990 the literacy rate was 47.2 percent for Kuchli and 40.8 percent for Sahahajapur, slightly below the West Bengal average and around the Indian average (Sengupta 1991). While both villages had access to electricity for those who could afford it, neither had an Anganwadi worker (female health care worker who provides pre- and post-natal advice and care), only Kuchli had a public tubewell for potable water, both villages were located more than four kilometers from the nearest primary health care center, and distribution of subsidized goods under the Public Distribution System actually declined during the 1980s (Sengupta 1991). By the 1990s, these social indicators were noticeably lower than those achieved in Maharashtra, Tamil Nadu, and Kerala – even though West Bengal’s social indicators in the 1950s and 1960s had been higher than in these other states. Thus, the picture of social wellbeing of the villagers of Kuchli and Sahahajapur that emerges by 1990 is mixed, reflecting West Bengal’s middling performance compared to other large Indian states. On the one hand, social indicators for the villages of Kuchli and Sahahajapur, like the indicators for West Bengal in general, had fallen behind states it had surpassed a few decades earlier. These figures are particularly noticeable with regard to literacy and primary education rates, where West Bengal fell behind its ranking of the 1980s. On the other hand, poverty rates had gone down (though still not as dramatically as expected), social indicators had improved, and land reforms, including those affecting the farmers’ organizations that resulted in higher agricultural labor wages, helped improve the lives of the poorer and more vulnerable landless and marginal farmers.
Findings from the West Bengal village studies in 2000 Having had a functioning local government system in place for well over a decade, the government of West Bengal only had to make few adjustments to its Panchayat Act to bring it in line with the Constitutional Amendment in 1993. These adjustments can be divided into two categories: those of a cosmetic or
104 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost technical nature and those that had more substantial implications. On the more technical end, changes to the West Bengal Panchayat (Amendment) Act of 1994 included changes such as an increase in the maximum number of Gram Panchayat members from 25 to 30. Of the more substantive changes made, one-third of all panchayat seats at every level was reserved for women and the percentage of seats reserved for members of the SC/ST population was equivalent to their percentage in the given district. One-third of the seats of chairpersons and vice- chairpersons from the local-level Gram Panchayat to the district-level Zilla Parishad Panchayat was also reserved for women, and similarly the position of chairpersons and vice-chairpersons were reserved for SC and ST in the same proportion as their population within the given district. The changes to the West Bengal Panchayat Act brought it in line with the 73rd amendment, and in the context of an already functioning panchayat system, this new structure made the Gram Panchayat potentially more democratic, transparent, and accountable to the electorate. West Bengal’s Gram Panchayats have been able to accomplish much in improving social welfare during the past decades. Due to the general state-level support for social programs and the actual functioning of Gram Panchayats at the local level at the time of implementation of the new Gram Panchayat system in 1992/1993, benefits from these programs largely flowed to more vulnerable groups. On the other hand, West Bengal’s progress in social welfare has not been nearly as large as expected and the village studies show that the reasons for this are the “undemocratic” elements of panchayat functioning – the new village elites and lack of effective party competition in particular. Three decades of the LFG and control of the bureaucracy from the state level to the villages has had an effect on the efficacy of democratic functioning. Despite elections and other institutions designed to ensure plurality, most West Bengal villages in particular have become one-party run. This has enabled corruption and reduced the effectiveness of the Gram Panchayat in improving social wellbeing because allocation of social welfare benefits – one of the main powers entrusted to Gram Panchayats under the 73rd Constitutional Amendment – is conducted according to party affiliation rather than poverty and the needs of the recipient. The 1992 changes to West Bengal’s Gram Panchayat system increased the representation of vulnerable groups, but did nothing to change the corruption of one-party rule. The following section first explores how villagers in the case studies viewed the panchayat system – in this case both the pre-1992 system and the system that has been in place since then. Next, the issue of whether perceptions of the quality of governance have changed since the introduction of the new panchayat law is analyzed. The third section explores whether having associations in the village has led to better functioning of the Gram Panchayat. The final section details villagers’ perceptions of changes in wellbeing, both since the initial implementation of the panchayat system, and since the 73rd Amendment-induced changes to the panchayat system in 1993. It also explores their perception of links between changes in wellbeing and changes in welfare. The findings illustrate that any
West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 105 analysis of panchayats in West Bengal has to involve discussion of the influence of the CPI(M). It was through the 1977 election of the CPI(M)-led Left-Front Government that state support for decentralization of political power in rural areas first emerged. It was also the CPI(M)-dominated government that instituted the PRI system in West Bengal and organized the first PRI elections, along with a variety of other reforms such as government-organized land reform, various mass organizations of the party such as Kisan Sabhas (party-organized peasant associations), and district cooperative movements. It was indeed through the party’s simultaneous domination of these various reforms that the CPI(M) was able to penetrate deep into rural society, as argued by many scholars of West Bengal and CPI(M) politics (Mallick 1993; Lieten 1996a). As with the other case studies, the village research was mainly based on qualitative data, including a small, stratified sample survey in both villages conducted in 2000 that collected both quantitative and qualitative information. A total of 80 villagers were interviewed in the two villages of Kuchli and Shahajapur. See Table 4.4 at the end of the chapter for results on selected survey questions. Interviews with key informants and focus group discussions were held in 2000 and again in 2007/2008.
How is the Panchayat system perceived? Effective democratic institutions are central to governance and legitimacy in a democracy. However altruistic the democratic ideals, principles, and aims of a government may be, it is only through the democratic and operational functioning of governments in pursuit of social goals at the local level that serious and sustained change is possible. From de Tocqueville to Anthony Giddens, writers have emphasized the importance of strong local governments and functioning deliberative institutions for strengthening democracy. Assessing the perceived and actual functioning of local democracy is the first step towards analyzing whether the West Bengal Gram Panchayats were delivering on their goals of improving local social welfare. The following section analyzes how villagers in the villages of Kuchli and Shahajapur perceive the functioning of their Gram Panchayats. Only when local governments function as mandated – by holding Gram Sabha and Gram Sansad meetings to democratically identify the indigent population for benefit distribution, and by overseeing and facilitating the delivery of social welfare programs to those most in need – can local governments hope to improve indicators of poverty and social wellbeing. For villagers to assess whether the local govern ments have changed their social welfare, they need not only to have witnessed implementation of the social welfare programs, or to have been a passive recipient of a program, but they need to have an active understanding of the local gov ernment system and its functioning. They need to be able to make informed and free decisions on who will best represent their interests, participate in the functioning of the local government (at village assembly meetings for example), have approachable and responsive local representatives, and have the ability to hold
106 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost them accountable. Villagers also need to perceive allocation of social benefits by the local government as targeted and equitable, free from undue extraneous influences.
Popular participation in local elections Since the 1978 panchayat elections, elections have been held regularly every five years throughout the West Bengal, including in the villages of Kuchli and Shahajapur. In 2000, villagers in Kuchli and Shahajapur had already experienced two rounds of Gram Panchayat elections and nearly ten years of local govern ment functioning under the revised Gram Panchayat system. Election turnout was high throughout the state in 1993 and 1998, with a turnout of over 85 percent in 1993 (Kumar and Ghosh 1996). Turnout was at least as high in Kuchli and Shahajapur, with all but two of the 80 survey respondents to a small sample survey in 2000 saying that they voted in the last national elections and all but three stating that they had voted in the last Gram Panchayat elections. Though these voter turnout rates seem high, they are in line with other studies on voter participation in West Bengal, which indicate rates of around 90 percent in local government elections (Westergaard 1986; Webster 1992a; Kumar and Ghosh 1996). For the first time, the Gram Panchayat elections in 1993 had seats reserved for women and Scheduled Castes and Scheduled Tribes, including reserving for a woman the position of head of the Kuchli Gram Panachayat. This led to an even greater than usual turnout. During the 1993 and 1998 elections voter participation was high amongst women and Scheduled Tribes – those groups that had had lower rates of representation prior to the passage of the 73rd Amendment. Furthermore, a greater percentage of traditionally disadvantaged groups were elected to Gram Panchayat offices. During the 1990s, participation in and election to local government offices was high amongst groups who traditionally were also poorer and more vulnerable, and thus, were more likely to be beneficiaries of social welfare programs. However, follow-up interviews in 2007/2008, as well as correspondence with key informers between 2008 and 2010 suggest that turnout rates at subsequent panchayat elections in 2003 and 2008 were lower overall, particularly lower among the Scheduled Tribes. In interviews and focus group discussions in 2000 on why voter turnout was so high during the 1990s, responses indicated that politics also played a dominant role. Candidates of the Left Front Government and the CPI(M) in particular had the majority of seats in both villages’ Gram Panchayats in both the 1993 and 1998 local elections. These findings are in line with the previous studies of these villages, which found that the CPI(M) and other LFG parties held 89.5 percent of the seats in the Gram Panchayat to which Kuchli belonged and 100 percent of the seats in Shahajapur in the late 1980s (Sengupta 1991). Moreover, this trend continued in subsequent elections with 16 out of the 17 Gram Panchayat members of the GP to which the village of Kuchli belonged being CPI(M) members in 2008. Responses from key informants and focus group discussions
West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 107 indicated a high degree of participation in the local government elections despite a belief among some that elections were not fairly conducted. The residents of these two villages were highly mobilized along political lines. Wanting to represent or see the implementation of a particular party agenda was one of the main explanations given by key informants for the high electoral participation rates. Informants who were ideologically close to the Left Front Government often stated that they wanted to see more party programs implemented. Those ideologically aligned with opposition parties largely criticized the efficacy of the Left Front-dominated Gram Panchayats in their village. Several also gave the aim of routing the Left Front-dominated Gram Panchayats from local government as their main motivation for voting in the elections. Rarely did informants give personalized politics, i.e., the wish to remove or elect a particular person from or to office, as their reason for voting. Over 30 years of local elections based on party representation and politics have changed the nature of local politics in these West Bengali villages. Unlike local politics in Uttar Pradesh, and most other Indian states, politics based on religion, caste, communal, or feudal interests have been replaced by party-based politics. This has enabled greater interaction of groups across socioeconomic, religious, and ethnic cleavages through the vehicle of local government. However, while the LFG is a coalition of leftist parties aimed at representing and benefiting more disadvantaged groups, studies show that people of ST background and landless agricultural workers, who historically have the lowest social indicators of any social group in West Bengal, are underrepresented in both the parties that constitute the LFG, as well as in local governments (Bandyopadhyay 2008). The dominance of the Left Front has seeped into all aspects of government functioning, to the point that those who are not party members find it difficult to get govern ment jobs, even at the local level. Being a party member has become an entry ticket to the more lucrative public sector jobs. In addition, the opportunism of those who were not part of the LFG’s initial base of supporters has attracted people of all backgrounds to the party. For example, during a conversation with a general caste citizen of Shahajapur village in 2000 the person confided that neither he nor any members of his family were CPI(M) members. Moreover, his family refused to join the party both because their caste had suffered under LFG tenure in the village by having land expropriated during land reform and because they had witnessed the corruption associated with CPI(M)-dominated Gram Panchayats. Particularly where access to social programs such as subsidized loans or the location of new tubewells and the legal punishment of criminals, was based on party membership rather than actual need or crimes committed. In a conversation with the same individual eight years later he and his brother confided that they had now joined the CPI(M) not due to ideological conviction, but because some of their family land had been identified as being above the land holding ceiling and therefore eligible for land seizure and redistribution by the Gram Panchayat. In a move designed to prevent the seizure of their lands, both brothers joined the CPI(M) party in 2003. Seven other citizens of Shahajapur and Kuchli villages, all of
108 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost whom were general caste members, stated in 2008 that they had joined the CPI(M) party over the past decade for instrumental reasons ranging from wanting to avoid land seizure to needing help with administrative issues from the Gram Panchayat and its CPI(M) members. CPI(M) party membership enabled access to services that were controlled by the local governments, including social services. However, when key informants were asked why people voted and why the electoral turnout in the late 1990s was so high even by West Bengal’s high average standards, the explanations given point to a faith in the electoral and local govern ment system to represent people’s aspirations, despite allegations of corruption. Similarly, while 77 out of 80 survey respondents (96 percent) said they voted in the 1998 Gram Panchayat elections, only 50 respondents (62 percent) thought that the elections were fair. These responses were corroborated through key informant interviews and are consistent with other empirical studies conducted over the past two decades in West Bengal which show that villagers believed that there was some electoral corruption even at the local government level, but are nevertheless motivated to continue to participate in high numbers in local government workings (Westergaard 1986; Webster 1992a; Wiley 2000). In Kuchli and Shahajapur, several informants gave concrete details of corrupt or rigged local elections, including distribution of alcohol or other “presents” on the day before elections by parties in order to “buy votes,” election booths being manned by CPI(M) party supporters, and cases where the police, who were known to be partial to the Left Front Government, intimidated political candidates of non-LFG parties. However, belief in the fairness of elections was related to characteristics generally associated with the LFG. Of the 50 survey respondents who thought that local government elections (which elected mostly LFG-associated candidates) were fair in the 2000 survey, 28 (56 percent) came from a SC/ST/OBC background, 18 (36 percent) were laborers as opposed to landowners or salaried employees, and 33 (66 percent) were categorized as not having many assets – all traits traditionally associated with the base of support for the Left Front Government. Despite the belief of some respondents to the 2000 survey that the Gram Panchayat elections were not fairly conducted, even these skeptical respondents turned out to vote in the elections. In follow-up interviews in 2000 and again in 2007/2008 on why they voted if they thought that elections were not going to be fair, several stated that voting was still the main avenue for influencing change. Over three decades of voting and seeing change brought about through elections, even if the changes were not to the extent or of the type wanted by the voter, has given the villagers in Kuchli and Shahajapur a faith in the basic efficacy of local government as an instrument of change. It has also mobilized civil society by rallying groups around political parties, primarily the CPI(M). Interestingly, the increased presence of female and Scheduled Caste and Tribe Gram Panchayat candidates after 1993 was not given as a motivation for voting by any respondent, although several people offered the view that having more women in the Gram Panchayats is helping combat corruption. A couple of decades of local elections and some improvements in social and economic infrastructure in the
West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 109 villages have helped deepen the villagers’ understanding of elections as an instrument of change. Not only did the vast majority of respondents in these villages portray an underlying faith in the democratic workings of local democracy, they also showed a higher level of awareness of the political structure and greater participation in the workings of their Gram Panchayat than either of their counter-part case studies in Uttar Pradesh or Karnataka. The 2000 survey of the two villages found that 16 out of 80 respondents (20 percent) attested to having campaigned for a member of the local government and ten out of 80 (13 percent) had campaigned for a local government candidate at the block or district level. When questioned about the village electorate meeting, 26 of the 80 respondents (33 percent) said that they attended and actively participated in Gram Sabha or Gram Sansad meetings. And 65 of the 80 survey respondents (81 percent) knew the name of their local panchayat representative and the name of the head of the panchayat and therefore knew who to turn to in order to represent their interests, or who was responsible if their interests were not well represented in the local government. Such high awareness and social and political mobilization rates were corroborated through key informant interviews in 2000 and again in 2007/2008. The rates of attendance and participation in Gram Sabha meetings are high by any standard of participation in local politics, but may be misleading without closer inspection. In 2000, 26 out of 80 of survey respondents (33 percent) said that they had attended one or more meetings within the last few years. This figure represents an increase over the late 1980s where 22 out of 114 respondents (20 percent) in the same villages stated that they had attended a Gram Sabha meeting in these villages (Sengupta 1991). When those survey respondents (20 percent) who said that they did not attend local electorate meetings were asked why, 25 percent said that they did not attend because the outcome of the meetings were pre-determined by the CPI(M) party, and that only party members were active participants in these meetings (Sengupta 1991). In 2000, of the 54 survey respondents who did not attend meetings, 26 (48 percent) said that they did not know about the meetings and/or that they were not invited to the meetings. Follow-up conversations with key informants and focus group discussions in 2000 and 2007/2008 confirmed that voter apathy was related to perceptions that outcomes of village electorate meetings were pre-determined by the CPI(M). The low percentage of the electorate attending Gram Sabha and Gram Sansad meetings was corroborated by observation of the panchayat meetings for 2000 and 2007/2008 in both villages. It is also in line with the previous study of these two villages (Sengupta 1991), and others that point to a low level of citizen parti cipation in the workings of village democracy. The main arena in which villagers are able to participate and contribute towards direct democracy appears not to be functioning in the manner in which it was envisioned. Studies of the 1993 changes to the panchayat law, requiring mandatory Gram Sansad village constituency meetings, have been critical of the ability of this new law to address the problem of perceived lack of control among villagers over Gram Panchayat decisions (Narayana 2005). The lack of attendance at these village electorate
110 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost meetings indicates that one of the few avenues for citizen participation and input into local governments, and the method mandated for determining social welfare program beneficiaries, was largely not functioning. The village studies point to a prevailing perception of a lack of control over the panchayat institutions – that despite democratic elections, functioning of their local government is not democratic, but rather pre-determined by CPI(M) party members. These findings mirror those of other studies, which have found that a prominent feature of these village constituency meetings is that those who are active at the meetings are largely members, or at least supporters, of the dominant political party – which are the Left Front parties in a majority of the cases (Ghatak and Ghatak 2002). Moreover, of 26 survey respondents who said that they do attend the Gram Sabha meetings, 7 (27 percent) said that they attend because they were told they must go by CPI(M) members. In addition, of those 26 who said they attended Gram Sabha meetings, 10 (38 percent) voluntarily proclaimed their political affinity with the Left Front Government. These findings point to some degree of alienation from local government institutions among villagers, particularly those who are not party members. Nonetheless, the results also attest to a high level of citizen awareness about the local governments in these villages as well as a high degree of participation in the workings of the local governments, albeit more among those who are LFG party members. Awareness of local government functioning is a significant indic ator of a working local government. In contrast to the lack of awareness and parti cipation in the Uttar Pradesh case studies and similar to awareness in Karnataka, respondents in these West Bengal villages were clearly aware of not only the structural set-up of the local governments, but also of their rights and obligations in making local government work in their interest. Certainly, having 26 out of 80 eligible voters (33 percent) participate in local government meetings are rates that any well-functioning local government in any part of the world could only hope to achieve, even if many of those attending are members of the ruling party. These findings of high citizen awareness and participation rates in West Bengal are documented in other case studies of local governments in rural West Bengal and indicate that the Gram Panchayat system has led to high participa tion rates in the elections of local government and to increased citizen awareness of their political rights under local government. Of the 80 survey respondents in Kuchli and Shahajapur, 77 (96 percent) continued to vote in the elections for their local governments and 50 out of 80 of them (62 percent) believe these elections to be fair. As we will see later, they also believe that the Gram Panchayats have improved the quality of life in their villages. Yet, at the same time, two-thirds of the respondents do not attend local government meetings and many who do not attend, do so out of a belief that their presence and vote at these meetings does not matter because most decisions have been pre-determined by the ruling CPI(M) party. The CPI(M) and other parties of the Left Front Government largely influence the agenda and outcomes, thereby undermining the demo cratic process of local governance. On the other hand, the importance of citizenry awareness of their local government structure and functioning cannot be
West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 111 overstated. Three decades of functioning and active governments in West Bengal have yielded an important increase in awareness of democracy and rights. This mobilization of civil society has spilled over into a general increased awareness of rights and demand for one’s rights, including the ability to vote out of office Gram Panchayat members who do not perform as expected.
Responsiveness of local government The high awareness of and participation in local government functioning, measured by survey responses and follow-up interviews in 2000 and 2007/2008, was also a result of a high level of interaction with Gram Panchayat representatives. Belief in the local government system, as seen in the high level of voter turnout and relat ively high belief in the fairness of elections, was based not only on an understanding of the system but also on personal interaction with panchayat members. Of the 80 survey respondents in 2000, 38 (48 percent) said that they had interacted with their local panchayat representative over the course of the past couple of years in their capacity as a panchayat member and 43 of the respondents (54 percent) said that they had contacted their local representative at some point for help in dealing with an issue. More significantly, over half of those who had not contacted their Gram Panchayat for help, volunteered that they would if they needed to, despite this not being a question on the questionnaire! And this included respondents who had identified themselves as having political affiliations that were not part of the LFG coalition. Clearly, most villagers feel comfortable contacting their local representatives for help when they need it. Furthermore, of those 43 survey respondents who contacted their local panchayat representative, 22 (51 percent) said that the representative was responsive and helpful. Examples of issues that panchayat members were helpful with included securing government documents such as birth certificates and ration cards for accessing goods from the Public Distribution System (PDS), helping access government-subsidized programs, such as loans and health care, and resolving disputes with government officials. Compared with villagers in Uttar Pradesh and Karnataka, residents in these West Bengali villages in general showed much greater engagement with panchayat members in 2000 and this remained evident in 2008. A surprisingly high number of survey respondents, 38 out of 80 (48 percent), said that between 1995 and 2000 they had participated in some activity directed at their local govern ment such as signing a petition to give to a panchayat member on some issue or requested holding a formal meeting with a Gram Panchayat member on a par ticular issue. The high level of interaction with local panchayat members con tinued through 2008 and underscores the belief of most respondents that when they need to get something done that involves interaction with government officials or accessing government programs, Gram Panchayat members are usually their first point of contact. These positive experiences with local representatives over several decades have cemented people’s appreciation of the Gram Panchayat system. Older informants with memories of the government before 1977, particularly those of
112 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost less privileged backgrounds, recounted numerous stories attesting to the difficulty in accessing government services and officials in the pre-panchayat days. Informants of lower caste backgrounds told stories of trying to insist on rights as sharecroppers or farm workers and being humiliated, subjected to punishments such as withholding of wages and food, and in some severe cases even beatings and loss of employment. Now, people in these West Bengali villages depend on their local panchayat representatives to access government services and officials. The Gram Panchayats are viewed as an essential aspect of village life: delivering social services and facilitating villagers’ access to their rights. The village studies suggest that Gram Panchayats have taken deep roots in these West Bengali villages, leading to institutionalization of local governments over the past decades, even if questions regarding equitable treatment of their constituents remain.
Work done by Gram Panchayats When asked specifically about different public projects aimed at social welfare improvements and whether their Gram Panchayat had been instrumental the functioning of these projects, all 80 survey respondents in 2000 thought that there had been some public projects in their village during the last year, ranging from physical construction on classrooms to water supply and sanitation pro jects. Moreover, 66 out of 80 survey respondents (82 percent) thought that the Gram Panchayat was the implementing force behind these projects, with a small minority thinking that upper levels of the panchayat system and different inter national aid organizations were the main implementing forces. Opinions on this issue did not vary much by village. Similarly in 2008, during qualitative inter views many informants stated that their local government was behind social wel fare programs in their village. Appreciation of the role that Gram Panchayats have played in villagers’ lives is based not only on personal experiences, but also on evidence of panchayat work in the village. In stark contrast to the social infrastructure of the villages studied in Uttar Pradesh and similar to Karnataka, these West Bengali villages in 2000 had functioning primary schools and a village health care worker who regularly held meetings with mothers and dispensed pre- and ante-natal care. Much of village infrastructure, such as wells, ponds and roads, had been built using village labor and public work funds, and the villages had a working public distribution system. All of these services were managed by or with the assistance of the local Gram Panchayat. During research visits in 2000 and again in 2008 the village primary schools were always functioning: teachers showed up every school day and classes were held. However, in 2008 at repeated visits to both village primary schools, the nutritional scheme providing free midday meals to all school children was only functioning sporadically, despite funds allocated to this scheme at the block level. Moreover, teachers confirmed in 2000 and again in 2008 that student absenteeism was high and that not a single child of Scheduled Tribe background – which in the case of both these villages largely
West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 113 represented the economically poorest group – was in attendance at the time of visits. Also, adult education classes organized by a Gram Panchayat subgroup were held in one of the villages, though not in the other in 2000, and by 2008, such classes had ceased in both villages. Health care provision functioned better in both villages. The female village health worker (Anganwadi) kept records of which village women were pregnant or had recently had a child, whom she had met with and when, and what types of goods, such as vitamins, she had dispensed, or referrals she had given in 2000. Follow-up with some of the pregnant or lactating mothers in 2000 and again in 2008 confirmed that the Anganwadi had indeed met with these women, offered advice, dispensed vitamins or medications, and/or given referrals to the district hospital. Furthermore, there were visible signs in both villages of infrastructure projects, funded by central government programs and implemented or monitored by the Gram Panchayat. Shahajapur even has functioning a two-room, brick- construction village library with four shelves of books and young and older readers present on the five random visits made to the library in 2000 and the two visits during 2008. This type of daily evidence of the local panchayats in action was evident throughout the village. There is, however, a caveat to these signs of a high level of Gram Panchayat involvement in village governance and social project management: in 2000, many survey respondents as well as key informants used the terms “Gram Panchayat” and “the party” (meaning CPI(M)) interchangeably. When the 66 out of 80 respondents (82 percent) who stated that the Gram Panchayat is instrumental in the delivery of social services were asked who specifically was responsible for implementing social programs in the village, the Party or the Gram Panchayat, 62 (94 percent) said that they were one and the same, including those who had identified themselves as CPI(M) members as well as both the Gram Panchayat representatives from these villages. Similar questioning of key informants in 2007/2008 yielded comparable answers. These findings are similar to those of earlier studies of these two villages, which found that the most villagers did not appear to distinguish between the CPI(M) and the Gram Panchayats (Sengupta 1991). The feedback from these villages underscores how entrenched the CPI(M) party is in West Bengal after nearly three decades in power and that any analysis of panchayats in West Bengal is incomplete without discussion of the nexus between the panchayat system and the CPI(M).
Local government accountability The idea that local populations are more likely to hold local governments accountable, as opposed to a distantly located district or state government, has been cited as one of the main rationales for decentralization of power to the local level. It also was one of the main reasons the Left Front Government cited for the creation of local governments in West Bengal in 1977. Whether the village governments of Shahjapur and Kuchli have been held accountable by the villagers needs to be understood against the background of
114 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost village governments that have been ruled for over three decades by the pro-poor Left Front Government parties, including the Communist Party of India (Marxist) in particular. In the past decade other parties, particularly the All-India Trinamul Congress Party (AITC), a party formed largely by defectors from the Congress Party in West Bengal, and to a lesser extent the Bharatiya Janata Party (BJP), have started to challenge the stronghold of the CPI(M) in West Bengal. This introduction of political competition in a de facto one-party state was vis ible in Kuchli and Shahajapur in 2007/2008, though the CPI(M) still continued to dominate the political landscape. Thus, the Gram Panchayat officials elected, often running unopposed, have overwhelmingly been CPI(M) members, reflecting a statewide trend as seen in Table 4.3. This did not change with the implementation of quotas for women and SC/ST members mandated by the 73rd Amendment. Most of the candidates fielded at local government elections were CPI(M) members, as were virtually all of those who won Gram Panchayat positions in the 1998, 2003, and 2008 village government elections in Kuchli and Shahajapur (Adhikary 2009). Moreover, while the percentage of statewide Gram Panchayat seats won by the LFG in 2008 dropped dramatically as a result of several highly publicized land-evictions by the state government, it remained questionable whether the 2008 local election results indicated a significant threat to the LFG’s dominance of politics in West Bengal. The problem of local government accountability in West Bengali villages is different from that in Uttar Pradesh or Karnataka. Monies sent from the district and block offices to the villages of Kuchli and Shahajapur were recorded at the village panchayat level as having arrived and been disbursed. The record of funds allocated and disbursed was clear in district, block, and village-level docu ments in 2000 and 2008. In addition, talks with Gram Panchayat members and key informants in both villages as well as focus group discussions (with villagers from different social backgrounds and political leanings) on size and allocations of individual social and anti-poverty programs disbursed by the Gram Panchayat, confirm that the monies allocated to villages generally flow to the villages. Moreover, the amount and percentage of resources flowing to local governments has increased markedly since the turn of the century. Corruption and leakages of public funds from the center down to the village level is less of a problem in these West Bengali villages than in Uttar Pradesh. The more important questions are whether local government representatives are disbursing the funds received in accordance with the guidelines for distribution of these funds and whether, if Table 4.3 Percentage of seats won by parties of the Left Front Government (LFG) and opposition in Gram Panchayat elections, 1978–2008 Party
1978
1983
1988
1993
1998
2003
2008
LFG Opposition
69 31
60 40
73 27
64 36
56 44
72 28
51 49
Sources: Ghatak and Ghatak 2002; Government of West Bengal 2011.
West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 115 the process was corrupted, representatives were being held accountable for it. To try to address these politically sensitive issues, survey interviewees were asked to answer a more general question on their sense of Gram Panchayat members’ accountability. Specifically, they were asked whether, if there were problems of corruption within the Gram Panchayat, local government representatives were more likely to be held accountable in the year 2000 compared to 1990, only 16 out of 80 survey respondents thought that accountability had improved by 2000. This compared with 26 who thought that they would be less likely to be held accountable in 2000 and 38 of the survey respondents who stated that they were not sure or did not give an answer to this question. Interviews with key informants in 2000 and again in 2007/2008 yielded a similar perception of deteriorating accountability in the villages of Kuchli and Shahajapur. It appears puzzling that there is a perception of decreased accountability of local governments while at the same time the local governments in these villages are functioning and producing visible improvement in social infrastructure and services. Closer exploration of this issue, mainly through focus group discussions and with key informants in 2000 and again in 2008, yielded a more complete picture. Importantly, unlike with other Indian states, the changes in state law in compliance with the 73rd Amendment did not change the internal workings of the Gram Panchayats in West Bengal. The only noticeable difference was the increase in female and Scheduled Tribe representatives. Overall, respondents stated that while the Gram Panchayats have continued to function and perform, accountability of the Gram Panchayats, mostly composed of CPI(M) members, has decreased since the early 1990s. An exception to this overall sense was the case of the pradhan or head of the panchayat in Shahajapur in 2000. Some informants suggested that because the Shahjapur pradhan was a woman, she was less corrupt and more likely to be empathetic. This qualitative finding is in line with a quantitative study of the district within which both the villages are located. This study finds that women and SC pradhans are more likely to invest in goods and services that are more relevant to the needs of women and SC respectively, such as water for women and goods and services for SC-populated areas, and that in general having a female pradhan makes a difference to service delivery (Chattopadhyay and Duflo 2004). If, during the 1990s, goods and services continued to be effectively delivered within the villages through the Gram Panchayats and yet the overall perception of villagers was one of deterioration in accountability of local government representatives, then something in the nature and functioning of the Gram Panchayats must explain this inconsistency. Interviews with key informants during 2000 and follow-ups in 2008 provided much of the basis for providing an answer to this question. After the changes made to the West Bengal panchayat system in line with the 73rd Amendment, the Gram Panchayats in both Kuchli and Shahajapur continued to function as before. Since local government elections at all pan chayat levels in West Bengal were held on the basis of political parties, there continued to be close linkage between the panchayats and CPI(M), with party members (and often the same party member) generally being elected to
116 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost panchayat positions. In fact after the 1998 panchayat elections, three out of the four Gram Panchayat representatives from Kuchli and Shahajapur were CPI(M) party members. And the one representative who was not a member of the CPI(M) party, the female pradhan, had a husband who was a party member and active in the CPI(M). After hearing much qualitative evidence that the close linkage between the CPI(M) party and panchayat members over two decades was at the root of the overall perception of decreased accountability of Gram Panchayat members, a new question was added to the West Bengal questionnaire in 2000, before the survey was implemented. In this question, the inter viewee was told to imagine a hypothetical scenario in their village where the panchayat had received money for an anti-poverty scheme that they could only give to one person. However, two people applied for this scheme. Both appeared to be equally poor, but one was a CPI(M) and the other was not. The interviewee was asked who would receive the benefit scheme. Out of the 80 survey respondents, 59 stated that the CPI(M) member would receive the benefits. All panchayat members interviewed also stated that the party member would more likely receive benefits. That nearly three-fourths of survey respondents found a positive correlation between party affiliation and receipt of social welfare programs by local govern ments is one of the most telling findings from the 2000 survey of these West Bengal villages. It captures the fact that social service programs do function and benefits are distributed by the panchayats in the villages, but that the process of distributing social service benefits is perceived to be corrupt, due to CPI(M) members having a greater likelihood of receiving these schemes. Moreover, the fact that such a large percentage of survey respondents said that the Communist Party member would be more likely to benefit from the anti-poverty scheme indicates not only that the beneficiary allocation system is corrupt, but also that the corruption is widely accepted as a matter of fact and is not something requiring concealment. Key informant interviews conducted in the villages in 2007/2008 yielded similar results. The fact that some panchayat members themselves admitted to a preference for party members in the allocation of anti-poverty schemes is evidence that this preference is socially accepted and is indicative of the power relationships in the Kuchli and Shahajapur. It is also confirms the findings of recent household surveys in rural West Bengal (Bardhan et al. 2008). To investigate this widespread perception of corruption in the Gram Pancha yat’s allocation of social welfare benefits, interviews were conducted in 2007/2008 with five people who had participated in public infrastructure projects under the Jawahar Gram Samridhi Yojana (JGSY) and five recipients of the microfinance program Swarnjayanti Gram Swarozgar Yojana (SGSY) in both villages. In none of these cases were the beneficiaries ST or females (which are the more vulnerable groups in these two villages) and visual assessments of the homes of these beneficiaries indicated that while they were not well-off, they were also not amongst the poorest. Moreover, five of the eight social welfare program recipients interviewed in 2000, and all of the recipients interviewed eight years later, reported that they were CPI(M) party members.
West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 117 In holding power in West Bengal for more than three decades, the CPI(M) has become the dominant political player and through the process it has also become corrupted. There was widespread perception among villagers both in 2000 and in 2007/2008 that poorer CPI(M) party members were more likely to get access to pro-poor public programs than non-members who were equally poor. In this case, accountability problems derive from capture not by a socio economic elite, but by a new political elite. These findings are somewhat at odds with a quantitative study of local governments in West Bengal that finds that accountability problems stem from political discretion at higher levels of the panchayat system, concerning inter- rather than intra-village targeting (Bardhan and Mookherjee 2004a). Several stories shared by informants indicate that the perception that local government members are less accountable derives not only from their official work as Gram Panchayat representatives, but also the influence that the representatives who are also party members exert in other village happenings. In Kuchli in 2000 one informant told of an incident that he thought exemplified how the CPI(M) works in the village. His brother had a house in the village that he wanted to sell since he had gained employment outside the village. The pro spective buyer was a CPI(M) member who offered half the market value, which his brother did not want to accept. However, CPI(M) members, two of whom were Gram Panchayat members, then started blocking other potential buyers and forced his brother into accepting the low offer by telling him that they would not otherwise allow the land transfer registration. In the end his brother accepted the low offer for his house because he had no other choice. Another informant who lived alone with her mother in Shahajapur in 2000 told of getting beaten in her home by CPI(M) party members after she publicly complained at a village meeting about corruption among the CPI(M) and said that people should vote for the Congress Party. Several other villagers corroborated this incident, as well as two other similar accounts of political violence. Numerous villagers recounted incidents of applying for social or anti-poverty programs but not receiving them, they thought, because they were not CPI(M) party members, since others who were party members received these benefits. Similar stories were recounted by key informants in 2007/2008. Other accounts of corruption within the Gram Panchayat in 2007/2008 included the redistribution of a government collection of surplus land through the Gram Panchayat to Scheduled Caste members, but not the poorest among them or the generally poorer Scheduled Tribe members; not getting government jobs in the village owing to not being a party member; many accounts of distribution of larger quantities of goods under the Public Distribution System (PDS) to influential party members; distribution of anti-poverty micro-loans through the Gram Panchayat only to party members; public wells being built by the panchayat with foreign donor money not being located as prescribed among the poorest and most neediest residential area, such as that of the Scheduled Tribes, but among the Scheduled Caste neighborhoods, close to houses of party members.
118 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost These types of accounts were numerous and though not all could be corroborated, there were enough of them to support the view that there was a general sense of corruption among CPI(M) members who have dominated politics in these villages for over three decades. More specifically with regard to this study, corruption among Gram Panchayat members in Kuchli and Shahajapur was associated with corruption of the CPI(M), since panchayat members in these villages have overwhelmingly been CPI(M) members. Overall the sense of preferential treatment given by CPI(M) members to others who are also members of their party in Kuchli and Shahajapur is intrinsically linked with a lower ability to hold Gram Panchayat members accountable. Nevertheless, in these West Bengali villages, and in West Bengal in general, introducing the local government system in the late 1970s helped improve social welfare and social indicators. This is clear when looking at the land reform and tenancy reform programs known as “Operation Bargha,” both of which were implemented by the local village panchayats and generally benefited the poorer and more vulnerable populations. Previous studies of Kuchli and Shahajapur also indicate an improvement in socioeconomic indicators between 1983 and 1990, including daily wage rates for male agricultural laborers, general literacy rates, infant mortality rates, nutritional status of children, and the proportion of households below the poverty line (Sengupta and Gazdar 1996). Gram Panchayats have contributed substantially towards the wellbeing of people living in rural West Bengal. Social programs reached the village and by having a local govern ment, the government in general became more accessible and more accountable to local people. Yet 30 years of CPI(M)-dominated local governments has led to an increased perception of corruption among Gram Panchayat members. An important finding of these villages studies in West Bengal is that the lack of political competition in these villages has led to worsened targeting of social welfare programs – a finding that is similar to a quantitative study which found improved poverty alleviation efforts in West Bengali villages that had more contested local elections between 1979 and 1998 (Bardhan and Mookherjee 2004b). The accountability of government to its citizens, which was one of the main stated reasons behind the implementation of the panchayat system in West Bengal in the late 1970s, declined between 1990 and 2008. The lack of checks and balances on the dominant political party in Bengali villages such as Shahajapur and Kuchli has created a situation where local government representatives, who are also Communist Party members, are increasingly seen as favoring party members and in some cases, putting themselves beyond the reach of law.
Overall perception of local government Despite issues of accountability, however, most respondents still viewed the Gram Panachayats in a positive light overall. The majority of residents of Kuchli and Shahajapur in West Bengal are content with their local government members and the services that they have rendered. Functioning local government-managed
West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 119 social programs have instilled general confidence in the Gram Panchayat system in these West Bengal villages. Villagers regarded their local government as providing them with much needed social and anti-poverty programs despite prob lems of Communist Party-associated corruption. In the post-73rd Amendment elections, villagers have witnessed greater numbers of women and SC/ST members elected to the village government, reinforcing their view that GP members were now more accessible than under the pre-1993 panchayat system. Moreover, with the panchayat system now a national phenomenon, rather than only a West Bengali one, there was a sense of permanence to the local govern ment system. With the system enshrined in the national constitution and nearly two decades of subsequent panchayat elections, the residents of Kuchli and Shahajapur view local panchayats as part of their daily village life and institutions that they can depend on when needed. In 2000, 66 out of 80 survey respondents thought that their Gram Panchayat played an active role in implementing social programs in their village while 73 stated that their panchayat played an active role in implementing anti-poverty programs. Moreover, 48 out of 80 survey respondents thought that their local government had tried to satisfy what they thought were the most important needs within the village, despite problems of corruption. Responses from interviews and focus group discussions both in 2000 and 2007/2008 confirmed these views, though confidential interviews with seven key informants in 2007/2008 yielded increasingly critical views of their local governments. Since 1993, general satisfaction with the performance of the local panchayat is extremely high when compared with the dashed high hopes for Gram Panchayats in Uttar Pradesh and even higher than perceptions of local panchayats in Karnataka. In these West Bengali villages the Gram Panchayat implements and oversees social programs, anti-poverty programs, and most of the other import ant economic or infrastructure needs of the village. Despite 59 out of 80 survey respondents stating that Gram Panchayat members privilege CPI(M) party members in their targeting of beneficiaries of social welfare programs, respondents nevertheless thought that they were generally good and tried to do their best to improve the overall welfare of the villagers.
Quality of governance Accountability matters greatly for the quality of governance, but governance is not influenced by accountability alone. This section begins by addressing the overall issue of local governance and its links with social welfare within these two Bengali villages. As in the previous chapter, Kaufmann and Kraay’s definition of governance is used and applied to the local level. Governance is defined as the “traditions and institutions by which authority in a country is exercised” including (1) the process of selecting, monitoring and replacing governments, (2) the government’s capacity to formulate and implement sound policies, and (3) the state’s and citizens’ respect for the institutions that govern economic and social interactions among them (Kaufmann et al. 2002). To better understand the
120 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost quality of governance in Kuchli and Shahajapur this section analyzes the issues of voice and accountability, as well as political stability in these villages. The second section applies the second part of Kaufmann and Kraay’s definition and builds on the discussion of accountability above to look at panchayat effect iveness and administrative quality. The third section uses the third part of the definition by looking at the rule of law and control of corruption under the Gram Panchayats in Kuchli and Shahajapur. Voice, accountability, and political stability: the changing locus of power Local government elections in West Bengal since 1978 have been contested on a political party basis. According to a previous study of these villages (Sengupta 1991) and accounts from survey respondents and focus group members in 2000 as well as 2007/2008, the majority of the Gram Panchayat positions in both villages were filled by CPI(M) members both before and after the 1993 elections. These findings are in line with statewide trends in West Bengal where the CPI(M)-led LFG has won the majority seats in GP governments since the late 1970s. Another unique feature of West Bengal panchayats is that since the first elections in 1978, people from the lower and middle classes of rural society, such as sharecroppers, agricultural laborers, and poorer peasants, have been elected as Gram Panchayat representatives. Sample surveys conducted after the 1978 elections found that three-quarters of Gram Panchayat representatives came from households owning less than two acres of land (Ghatak and Ghatak 2002). An analysis of caste background of Gram Panchayat members in Kuchli and Shahajapur prior to the 1993 elections found that a large majority were of SC background (Sunil Sengupta et al. 1991). However, prior to 1993, none of the Gram Panchayat representatives from these two villages were of ST background and there was only one female representative in the Gram Panchayat to which Shahajapur belonged, and none in the Gram Panchayat to which the village of Kuchli belonged. Before the introduction of the 73rd Amendment, these West Bengali Gram Panchayats, like most of the state, were male-dominated institutions, with women holding less than 2 percent of all Gram Panchayat seats (Ghatak and Ghatak 2002). Male domination of Gram Panchayats changed drastically after 1993. The change in West Bengal’s panchayat law resulted in one-third of all seats in the Gram Panchayats for Kuchli and Shahajapur being filled by women, and several Gram Panchayat seats being reserved for and filled by ST members, with the seat of pradhan (head of the Gram Panchayat) in Kuchli reserved for a woman. By virtue of these quotas, the voices of people previously less involved in local politics were now at least present in the Gram Panchayat. Moreover, during the 1998, 2003, and 2008 local government elections were competitive in the sense that more than one candidate contested three out of four seats for the Gram Panchayats of these two villages, including the position reserved for a female head of the Gram Panchayat. However, the elections were not politically competitive
West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 121 since the four local governments seats for these two villages were largely contested and consistently won by CPI(M) party members until 2008, when two of the contestants and one of the elected representatives was a member of an opposition party. Focus group discussions also highlighted that, unlike other states with less experience with functioning local governments such as Uttar Pradesh, West Bengal has seen active participation of formerly powerless groups since 1977. Scheduled Castes and agricultural laborers, sharecroppers, small peasants, and artisans, have played active parts in local politics. The 1994 changes to West Bengal’s Panchayat law and the subsequent increased number of women and ST members elected to the Gram Panchayats has only heightened this sense of increased voice for people who had historically been excluded from local governing of villages. Yet the increase in voices of formerly disenfranchised groups through the Gram Panchayats needs to be qualified. As documented by several studies of West Bengal, males of SC background who were generally excluded from power before the LFG came to power, have now been part of the local power and gov ernment structure for several decades and can no longer be seen as a disenfranch ised group (Westergaard 1986; Kumar and Ghosh 1996; Lieten 1996a; Ghatak and Ghatak 2002). This point was repeatedly made in focus group meetings in 2000 and in 2007/2008 particularly by ST members who still are the poorest in both the villages studied. While the ST population is now represented in their Gram Panchayats, almost all interviewees of ST background spoke of their inability to be heard at local electorate meetings or of discrimination in getting access to social welfare programs. Political power in these villages, which prior to 1977 was held by upper castes and large land-owning families, shifted in the subsequent decades to lower castes and agricultural labor. By the 1990s political power in these villages was firmly in the hands of male, CPI(M) party members, largely of SC background. Upper caste and larger landowners were conspicuously missing from the local political life of these villages in 2000. By 2007/2008, however, key informant interviews provided evidence that some larger landowners and upper-caste members were seeking to retain or regain political and economic power by joining the CPI(M) party. The elites in these villages by 2008 were not village elites based on traditional socioeconomic cat egories of caste or wealth. Instead their power derived from their affiliation with the party that dominated the political landscape. Another measure of voice under the new system was people’s perception of whether they were more likely to be heard by the new Gram Panchayat. When asked this question, an overwhelming 73 out of the 80 survey respondents said that they were more likely to be heard in 2000, compared to under the pre-1993 panchayat system. And of those 73 who felt that their voice was more likely to be heard under the system, 66 thought that their increased voice was due to the structure of the panchayat, rather than other factors such as increased literacy rates or an increased demand for representation. Overall, the newly revised local government system unequivocally led to an increase in representation and
122 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost perception of increased voice of people less likely to be heard under the pre- 1977 local government system. Moroever, while the panchayat system instituted in 1977 brought formerly disenfranchised groups and people of SC background in particular into politics and power, the post-1993 panchayat system was notable for increasing the representation of women and people of ST backgrounds. Feedback from respondents in these two Bengali villages indicated a general sense that representation of all village residents had indeed improved since the changes laid out by the 73rd amendment were enacted, particularly for women. In West Bengal alleged electoral fraud was associated with representatives of parties rather than with individuals and, like in Karnataka but unlike in Uttar Pradesh, it spanned the caste and class divide. Accounts from qualitative inter views in 2000 and 2008 tell of the parties providing gifts and liquor to villagers on the eve of panchayat elections (a practice in which all contesting parties purportedly engage), party members rounding up and escorting individuals to the booths, and a few accounts of known CPI(M) party members being in the voting room and being seen with election officials when ballot boxes were taken away for counting. While these individual accounts could not be verified, they point to a widespread belief of some fraud in the local government electoral process associated with political parties, the CPI(M) in particular. Yet electoral turnout in the 1993, 1998, 2003, and 2008 Gram Panchayat elections was extremely high in Kuchli and Shahajapur, with 50 out of 80 survey respondents in both villages in 2000 stating that the 1998 local elections were fair. Of the 20 survey respondents who reported the 1998 elections to be unfair, all of them stated that corruption was related to political parties trying to influence election outcome. Most incidents recounted in 2000 related to fraud by the CPI(M), but reported incidents also included Congress/Trinamul and BJP party members. By 2007/2008 the perception of electoral fraud had changed. In inter views with key informants all specific incidents of fraud involved CPI(M) members, while those key informants who were CPI(M) members refrained from comment on the issue. The respondents’ overall sense of Gram Panachayat accountability, however, is not based only on specific incidents of alleged electoral fraud, but also on the broader fact that local government elections regularly take place. In contrast to Karnataka and Uttar Pradesh, where local government elections have been irregular, West Bengal has held panchayat elections regularly since 1978 and villagers have had a chance to observe the effectiveness and benefits of working local governments. These differences in history and functioning of local govern ments are also reflected in the different overall perceptions of whether local gov ernment members are good and likely to be held accountable. While the vast majority of local government representatives were CPI(M) members, the occasional win of local government seats by a member of one of the opposition par ties was repeatedly brought up by informants as an illustration of electoral competition. Regular elections with some change in Gram Panchayat member ship after each election have given the majority of villagers a sense that, despite
West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 123 some fraud mostly associated with the CPI(M), local elections are largely fair and that they can vote for other candidates if the local government’s workings are not to their liking – thereby exercising their greatest tool for holding local representatives accountable. Government effectiveness and administrative burden The ability of local governments to improve social wellbeing is largely determined by their effectiveness in terms of planning and carrying through sound anti-poverty and social policies. If local panchayats function well their constituents can use them to enable improved access to government services. If this happens then the administrative burden that the individual faces in accessing these services will have decreased for that individual, adding to the benefits of having a functioning local government. When survey respondents were asked whether they thought that government was more effective in 2000 compared to the pre-1993 panchayat system, 48 out of 80 respondents (60 percent) answered in the affirmative. Of those 48 survey respondents who thought the new panchayat system was more effective, 34 (71 percent) thought it was due to the existence of their local panchayat. These sentiments were echoed in the focus group meetings during 2000 and again in 2007/2008. For the majority of citizens in Kuchli and Shahajapur, having a representative and elected local government has meant that the central and state govern ments are more present in their village. Most social services and infrastructure programs, particularly in education and health, are central or state government schemes. Those employed in these programs are civil servants receiving a regular government salary. However, the local panchayats exert some control over these government employees in order to ensure their effectiveness in delivering services. Seeing successfully operating central and state government programs in the villages, from basic health care services to the public distribution system for subsidized goods, has meant that villagers have a generally favorable image of the local, state, and central governments and their general effectiveness. The majority view that government and its services are more effective under the newer Gram Panchayat system in West Bengal is based not only on the supply and delivery of these services, but also on the ease of accessing these ser vices. When survey respondents were asked in 2000 how bureaucratic hurdles to getting paperwork completed (from food ration cards to birth certificates) or to accessing government services and benefits (from health care to food-for-work programs) had changed over the past decade, 33 out of 80 respondents (41 percent) thought that such hurdles had decreased, with the rest not being sure either way. Of the 33 who thought there was less red tape, 22 (67 percent) thought that the decrease in bureaucratic hurdles was due to the existence of their Gram Panchayat. These findings were again supported by interviews with key informants in 2000 and again in 2007/2008. Having a local government representative in their village, and often in their neighborhood, meant that villagers could ask the representative for advice and
124 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost help on government services. In addition to going directly to a representative, both villages had functioning Gram Panchayat subcommittees which villagers could access for help in areas ranging from education to a farmers’ association, Informants old enough to remember the 1970s and the pre-panchayat days recounted how they had to make the journey to government offices at the district headquarters to get simple government documents such as birth certificates or ration cards. For people living in Indian villages, particularly the less educated and vulnerable groups, such as women and people of lower-caste background, this was often a hurdle too difficult to overcome, resulting in non-access to these services. In the decades since the election of the first Gram Panchayats in 1978, with functioning local governments and their subcommittees, the bureaucratic hurdles faced by the villagers have decreased. In follow-up qualitative interviews conducted in 2000 and 2007/2008 on why some respondents did not think the government was any more effective than previously, key informants and two focus group discussions in 2007/2008 pointed to corruption by CPI(M) members, particularly with regard to access to social services and physical infrastructure by the Scheduled Tribe members. Those citizens whose political allegiances were not with parties of the LFG or who were of either socioeconomically marginalized or more affluent backgrounds, reported difficulties in accessing services managed by their local governments. Rule of law and control of corruption Effective and somewhat accountable Gram Panchayats have coexisted with deterioration in the rule of law and stagnation in the fight against corruption. In 2000, although 64 of 80 survey respondents (80 percent) thought that violence had decreased between 1990 and 2000, only 18 (23 percent) thought that rule of law had improved between 1990 and 2000. This seemingly contradictory picture was further elucidated in several interviews, focus groups meetings, and in personal conversations with some villagers, again both in 2000 and 2007/2008. According to this feedback, there was some violence in the community during the 1990s, but the incidence of violence was low and not as extreme as the violence that characterized the decade before the Left Front Government came to power. In follow-up interviews in 2007/2008, however, informants noted an increase in violence associated with political events such as elections, a further deterioration of the rule of law, and an increase in corruption in comparison to the 1990s. The village studies point to little change in the general level of corruption in the 1990s and an increase in corruption since 2000, which many informants associated with members of the CPI(M)-dominated LFG. Many anecdotes were recounted in both 2000 and 2007/2008 of transgressions of the law remaining unpunished if the perpetrator was a member of the LFG. Other informants corroborated many of these incidents. Despite functioning and accountable Gram Panchayats, violence, the rule of law, and corruption have become increasingly salient issues in these West Bengali villages.
West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 125 When asked in 2000 whether changes in violence, rule of law or corruption were in any way linked to the local Gram Panchayats, only 19 of the 80 survey respondents (24 percent) thought that the panchayat was responsible for the increase in corruption while 31 (39 percent) thought that the Gram Panchayats were responsible for deterioration in the rule of law. Qualitative interviews in 2000 and 2008 revealed that informants associated changes in violence, rule of law or corruption more frequently with the local CPI(M) members rather than the local government, though in most cases they were the same people and many informants did use the terms interchangeably. In individual conversations non- CPI(M) members pointed out that the main cause behind the decline in the rule of law was the dominant political party, the CPI(M), but most informants were not willing to provide an answer to this question when anyone other than family members were around. Many eyewitness accounts of CPI(M) party obstructing the rule of law or abiding corruption made it clear that the long reign of power enjoyed by the LFG in West Bengal has created an environment where their party members can obstruct the democratic workings of local governments in Kuchli and Shahajapur. Rather than encouraging local governments to work together with police to combat corruption and improve the rule of law, the LFG and its members in these two villages often interfered and in some cases obstructed the workings of democratic government and the rule of law. When a conflict arose between the interests of the CPI(M) party in the village and the local panchayat or law enforcement, the CPI(M) party prevailed. Moreover, between 2000 and 2008, the problem of corruption, rule of law and violence appeared on the increase. By 2011 it was clear that local governments in these two villages no longer functioned as independent, democratic organizations of governance, but as an extension of the LFG (Adhikary 2009).
General quality of governance Perceptions of the overall quality of governance and its links with the local gov ernment in these two West Bengali villages are mixed – with a general perception of improved governance during the 1990s and a decrease in governance since the turn of the century. One of the main reasons for slow progress on local governance in the past decade is that the LFG parties have coopted the Gram Panchayat structures in Kuchli and Shahajapur. The CPI(M)-led LFG deserves credit for virtually eliminating the system of patronage and clientelism based on religion, caste, and communal interests which existed in West Bengal prior to 1977. The grassroots nature of the CPI(M) party structure (Kohli 1987) and its close linkage with the panchayats, have meant that respondents often used the terms Gram Panchayat and CPI(M) party interchangeably. It is also this dominance that has affected whose voice is heard within the Gram Panchayat and the Gram Sabha meetings and which members of the panchayat are more likely to be held accountable. It even extends to who is more likely to evade the rule of law in Kuchli and Shahajapur. The system of patronage of the past has now been replaced with one based along party lines in West Bengal. The political parties
126 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost that have formed the Left Front Government and ruled West Bengal for the past three decades are so entrenched and have dominated the villages for so long, that it is difficult to separate out the local Gram Panchayat’s quality of governance from that of the parties in the LFG. Kuchli and Shahajapur’s Gram Panchayats have achieved improvements in social welfare over the past decades, but their independence and thus their capacity to function as impartial bodies of governance, have been compromised by the dominance of the CPI(M) party. Particularly following the 2003 and 2008 panchayat elections with the level of violence and reports of corruption that they entailed, local governance hit a low point in the three-decade reign of the LFG.
Did social wellbeing change? The main impetus behind the 73rd Amendment and panchayat system implementation in West Bengal was to apply the notions that self-government at the village level strengthens democracy, functioning local governments are better able to judge the needs of people in their communities, and they are thus better able to decrease local poverty and improve social wellbeing. Since West Bengal has often been touted as the role model for decentralization, local democracy and governance-building, it is particularly vital to assess whether social wellbeing did indeed improve in villages such as Kuchli and Shahajapur and if so, whether this can be attributed to functioning Gram Panchayats. General trends in social indicators for West Bengal as a whole show improvement from the early 1990s into the twenty-first century (see in Table 2.3). These improvements were mirrored in the self-reported changes in wellbeing in both the small-sample survey of 2000 and qualitative key informant interviews in 2007/2008. Furthermore, 32 out of 80 survey respondents (40 percent) inter viewed in 2000 and a majority of the key informants interviewed in 2000 and again in 2007/2008 thought that the local governments generally contributed towards improved social welfare. However, these overall perceptions mask complicated links between local governments and social wellbeing in these West Bengali villages. Over the course of their existence, Gram Panchayats have much to show in terms of improvement in the lives of the communities they represented and served. From land reforms to recording of sharecroppers’ rights and 30 years of implementing the central government’s social and anti-poverty programs, these changes could not have been brought about without functioning local govern ments on the ground. As many studies of West Bengal since the 1970s have pointed out (Kohli 1987; Mallick 1993; Lieten 1996a), these changes have led to a quantitatively and qualitatively better quality of life for most people in West Bengal. The majority of West Bengalis lead a life that is no longer dominated by the caste-based patronage system and the feudal interests that dominated life prior to the reign of the LFG. However, since 1993 West Bengal has been less progressive in empowering local governments with the functions, funding and institutional support to carry
West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 127 out their responsibilities, including those of improving local social wellbeing. As discussed in Chapter 2 (see Table 2.1), as of 2010 West Bengal had not fully empowered their Gram Panchayats by devolving the funding of all 29 subjects listed in the schedule to the 73rd Constitutional Amendment, while in contrast Karnataka had. Furthermore, while life today is better for most West Bengalis compared to the mid-1970s, the results from the two village studies indicate that general improvements in social wellbeing have not benefited all socioeconomic groups equally. Those groups reporting in 2000 that they had not benefited from local government-managed social welfare programs were even more likely to report lack of access to social services eight years later. Perception of changed wellbeing One way to assess whether people are better off, and whether the improvement in wellbeing is due to the help they have received from their local government, is to ask them. When 80 villagers in Kuchli and Shahajapur were asked whether they were better off in the year 2000 compared to a decade earlier, 54 out of 80 (68 percent) stated that they were better off. Of the 54 who said that their wellbeing had improved over the 1990s, 32 (59 percent) said that it was due to interventions from their respective Gram Panchayat. This proportion is high when considering the relatively small amounts of funding for social programs that were allocated to each village during the 1990s. For example, over the 1990s, less than two dozen people in each of the villages had been the recipient of Integrated Rural Development Program (IRDP) loans, which were small government-subsidized loans to poor families to help them become self-employed. Similarly, in 1999 the Jawahar Gram Samridhi Youjana (JGSY), which paid a daily wage to below-the-poverty- line (BPL) beneficiaries to work on Gram Sabha-determined village infrastructure projects, provided less than a dozen people in each of the respective villages with ten or less days of daily wages per person. And between 1995 and 2000 there was no recipient of Indira Awaas Yojana (IAY), the rural housing program, which provides significant subsidies for housing for the rural poor. Focus group discussions and interviews with key informants in 2007/2008 yielded similar findings of improved social wellbeing but with only a minority of informants attributing improved wellbeing to their local governments. Qualitative discussions were conducted in 2000 and again in 2007/2008 to understand why some informants thought that the Gram Panchayats had contrib uted to their social wellbeing when the actual number of programs and funds disbursed through the programs were not high. These discussions revealed three reasons for the high attribution of improved welfare to local governments. First, informants pointed out that since many villagers in Kuchli and Shahajapur used the terms Gram Panchayat and CPI(M) interchangeably, many had therefore included work done CPI(M)-backed organizations such as the farmers’ coop erative that provides subsidized seeds to its members. A second reason was that while the questionnaire conducted in 2000 asked about improvements over the ten-year period between 1990 and 2000, people also referred to local
128 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost government actions prior to 1990, including land reforms and institution of better sharecropping rights. A third reason was that the local governments had indeed helped some residents to improve their social wellbeing during that decade. Follow-up discussions and visits in 2007/2008 with a total of 15 people in both villages identified as being beneficiaries of anti-poverty programs since 2000 yielded further insights. Fourteen out of the 15 social welfare program beneficiaries were of lower-caste background. However, only two out of these 14 beneficiaries were of ST background, while all others were of SC background. Furthermore, while none of the recipients was an owner of large tracts of land or had regular non-agricultural employment, none of the anti-poverty program beneficiaries was among the most destitute citizens of the village. This was confirmed visually by visiting the informants in their homes and seeing that none of the poverty program recipients lived in the poorest part of the village and most of them had some assets such as a bicycle. Thus, while the beneficiaries of the social welfare programs were not the richest members of the village communit ies in 2000 or in 2008, they were also not the poorest. Another way of assessing perceptions of changed social wellbeing was to ask whether anti-poverty and social welfare programs were functioning in the villages and what role the Gram Panchayat played in delivering these services. In 2000 all 80 survey respondents in both villages stated that some social welfare programs had been implemented in the village during the late 1990s and 77 out of 80 respondents (96 percent) reported functioning anti-poverty programs. Interviews, focus-group discussions and observations in 2008 yielded similar findings. The vast majority of Kuchli and Shahajapur’s residents felt that the Gram Panchayats were directly involved in the delivery of programs aimed at improving social wellbeing. However, a majority stated that there was corruption in the delivery of anti-poverty programs in terms of how the beneficiaries were selected and whether the targeted audience received the benefits. One of the most significant findings of the 2007/2008 follow-up research visit was that of the 15 social welfare recipients, every single recipient was a self- identified member of the CPI(M) party. Moreover, interviews in 2008 with three households in each village that were identified as the poorest residents of the village by village informants (a couple of whom were CPI(M) members), found that none of the six poorest household heads was a CPI(M) party member! Moreover, in addition to the problem of inadequate targeting of social welfare programs to the most indigent, checks on specific programs found evidence that the allocated funding was not being fully disbursed. For example, in an interview in 2008 with the Block Development Officer (BDO) responsible for releasing development expenditures to the Gram Panchayats for both villages, she stated that Kuchli village had received funds over the past year for building dugout toilets for poorer residents at the cost of 500 rupees per toilet (Arundhati Bhaumik 2008). Follow-up at the village level brought to light that out of the 25 toilets built, only ten had been for families below the poverty line and only 300 rupees were allotted for the construction of each toilet. When asked, neither of
West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 129 the GP members knew what had happened to the remaining 200 rupees or why only ten poorer families had been the beneficiaries of this program. Due to the politicized nature of panchayats in West Bengal and the fact that in both these villages the CPI(M) continued to dominate the Gram Panchayats, party priorities and party membership determined what types of anti-poverty programs are distributed, in what amounts, and to whom. Evidence of changed wellbeing State-level data show that social indicators for West Bengal improved throughout the 1980s and 1990s, up to 2010, and other studies of Gram Panchayats in West Bengal have shown the GPs to have been essential in the delivery of social programs and improvement in social wellbeing (Dasgupta 1995; Roy 1995). The findings of this research in Kuchli and Shahajapur were similar. The previous study of both these villages in 1991 found that social indicators in general, from undernourishment to literacy rates, improved from 1981 to 1991 (Sengupta 1991). This general trend continued into the 1990s and the first decade of the twenty-first century. Interviews conducted in 2000 and 2007/2008 with a cross-section of people, ranging from farm laborers and village health care workers to schoolteachers and revenue inspectors in each village (a civil servant in charge of overseeing development and finances in the respective village), all attested to an improvement in social wellbeing. These interviews were followed-up with unannounced visits to the local primary school and visits during the local health workers’ working hours. As in Karnataka but unlike in the village studies of Uttar Pradesh, these visits in Kuchli and Shahajapur found functioning schools and health services. In general most residents in these two villages were better off at the beginning of the twenty-first century than they had been in the early 1990s. However, reported perceptions of changes in wellbeing indicated that while respondents thought that social wellbeing in general had improved, they also thought that there was some corruption in the allocation of social programs. It is therefore important to analyze how political preferences in the allocation of social services might have had an impact on social welfare in these villages. Here again it is useful to refer back to the previous WIDER study of these two villages. The study conducted during the late 1980s analyzed the effectiveness and targeting of different anti-poverty programs in Kuchli and Shahajapur, including the IRDP in particular. It found that during the 1980s the panchayats were actively involved in implementing the IRDP scheme and that the benefits “mostly went to the intended beneficiaries” (Sengupta 1991). However, the WIDER study also found that 7.5 percent of those who were not eligible for the IRDP loans due to not being poor nevertheless received loans and that these ineligible receipts constituted 22 percent of total loan disbursements (Sengupta 1991). In other words, those who were not eligible for these loans actually received larger loan amounts. The findings of significant leakage in anti-poverty programs continued into the twenty-first century. While this study did not do a systematic review of all
130 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost IRDP loan recipients in these villages, interviews and follow-up with people who were identified as IRDP loan recipients in 2000 indicated that the proportion of ineligible people receiving IRDP loans during the 1990s was at least as high as during the 1980s. Moreover, as stated above, random follow-up visits to social welfare program recipients in 2008 found that none of the recipients was amongst the poorest in the village. Well into the twenty-first century there is discretion in the allocation of anti- poverty funds used by Gram Panchayat members who are also members of the CPI(M) party. In both villages party membership was rewarded through disbursement of anti-poverty and other social programs to party loyalists. These findings are slightly at odds with the study of West Bengal by Bardhan and Mookherjee, which finds that pro-poor programs are well targeted toward the poor in general and that any distortions are due to political discretion used to determine inter-village allocation of resources rather than to elite capture (Bardhan and Mookherjee 2004b). In contrast, this study found that there was some elite capture of social welfare programs, but the definition of elites in these villages no longer refers to the traditional landowning class, but rather to a polit ical elite of largely SC and OBC members of the CPI(M) party. The lack of serious competition in local government elections in Kuchli and Shahajapur, as in the rest of West Bengal, has affected the quality of social ser vice delivery. While anti-poverty and social service delivery programs generally function well, the influence on targeting by Gram Panchayat members who belong to the CPI(M) party has meant that the programs are not as effective as they could have been under more politically competitive conditions. For example, in the village of Shahajapur, the poorest residents are from the Scheduled Tribe category, who live in a separate part of the village. In this part of the village the soil is less well suited to agriculture, the houses and courtyards are smaller, with fewer windows, each house has fewer visible assets, and the residents are dressed more poorly. None of the residents here owns enough land to be self-sufficient and most are agricultural laborers. The poverty in this part of the village is evident also in its infrastructure – no pond, public well, or electricity reaches this part of the village. When asked about this lack of infrastructure, residents agreed that they are not as well off as most other parts of the village. Several recounted in 2000 that in 1999 a German development agency announced it would fund the building of a public water well in the village. The funding for this well came to the panchayat in 1999 and its location was supposed to be discussed in the Gram Sabha. But one ST member who had been to all the Gram Sabha meetings noted in 2000 that the location of the well had never been discussed at these meetings and the well was being built in the center of the village, close to the house of an SC Gram Panchayat member who was also a CPI(M) member. Cross-checking found this account to be true. These and other similar accounts during 2000 and 2007/2008 showed that the ST population in Shahajapur is still disadvantaged compared to the rest of the village population, with higher poverty and lower literacy rates among this popu lation. Moreover, while many among the ST population had received the title to
West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 131 their homestead during the land reforms undertaken by their panchayat during the late 1970s and early 1980s, few had received agricultural land, and none had received enough agricultural land or land that was rich enough to support a livelihood. These findings echo another study on West Bengal, which finds that the allocation of resources for poverty alleviation varied greatly between villages and tended to be higher when there was a more equal distribution of land, when the people were more literate, when there were fewer SC/ST households in the village, and when local elections were more contested (Bardhan and Mookherjee 2004b). Social wellbeing under the Gram Panchayat system generally improved in both villages during the 1980s and through the turn of the century, thereby mirroring trends in other rural areas of West Bengal. However, these improvements were not as good as they might have been if the local government had functioned fully democratically, free from political capture and the political pressures of the LFG-affiliated parties. By the twenty-first century the domination by CPI(M) of the Gram Panchayats serving the villages of Kuchli and Shahajapur has resulted in inefficiencies in targeting of the poor. Despite the 1993/1994 changes to the West Bengal panchayat system to improve representation and voice of the most disadvantaged groups, there were no significant changes in the welfare of women and ST attributable to local government efforts. The new village elites – those with access to upper levels of political power through their membership in the CPI(M) – have been able to solidify their power and social standing in the village due to the lack of political competition and to their control over the distribution of public benefits. Moreover, since these new village elites derive their power and social standing from the very lack of political competition, they have no incentive to support improvements to the system of democratic local governance, thereby undermining the rooting of local governments in these villages of West Bengal.
The changing political landscape in West Bengal By the early part of the twenty-first century the political landscape in West Bengal became increasingly volatile, with negative consequences for social indicators. After declining winning margins over several elections, the LFG won an apparent landslide victory in the 2003 Gram Panchayat elections. These elections also saw a record 80 percent voter turnout (Chaudhuri 2003) but also high levels of violence. Violence in the 2003 elections included accounts of intimidation and coercion and the killing of dozens of individuals. These panchayat elections were also notable for having 11 percent of all panchayat seats at the three levels of panchayats not being contested (Ghosh 2003). Members of the LFG parties won most of these uncontested seats. Moreover, there were allegations that as many as 80 percent of the nomination papers filed by the CPI(M) on the last day for filing nominations were false candidates (Ghosh 2003). Given that the LFG had seen a decrease of 17 percent of the number of local government seats won between 1993 and 1998 and given that feedback from villagers in
132 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost Kuchli and Shahajapur indicated that in these and other villages the CPI(M) knew that people were increasingly less likely to vote for LFG party members, the large increase in votes for LFG parties in the 2003 panchayat elections is suspicious. Editorials on this issue in the wake of the 2003 panchayat election results, including ones by authors known to have politically leftist leanings, questioned the veracity of these elections and pondered what this depth of fraud heralded for local governments in West Bengal. Changes in the nature of political competition and functioning of Gram Panchayats witnessed over the past decades in both Kuchli and Shahajapur are a microcosm of the changes in local governance and political stability in West Bengal. Responses from the 80 survey interviews in 2000 differed from informa tion collected through qualitative means in 2007/2008. When asked in 2000 whether violence had increased or decreased since the 1994 institutionalization of local governments in their village up to the year 2000, 64 of 80 survey respondents (80 percent) said that it had decreased. Though only 13 of these 64 respondents (20 percent) attributed the decreased violence to the Gram Panchayats, most, when asked what they thought might have led to the decrease, answered that it was the overall political stability, including the long tenure of the CPI(M) in West Bengal of the past decades, that had permeated down to their villages. The increased voice of people and improved delivery of social services in the villages during the 1990s, combined with a party that had been in power for several decades and had provided continuity and order, creating a general sense of stability in 2000. This sense of stability in 2000 contrasted greatly with West Bengal’s tumultuous history and social and political instability of the 1970s. However, the sense of political stability changed during the decade up to 2011. In 2000, Jyoti Basu, the charismatic leader of the West Bengal CPI(M) party and Chief Minister of West Bengal since 1977, resigned his post. This created turmoil in party leadership at the same time that it enabled space for greater political competition. Though fellow CPI(M) politician Buddhadeb Bhattacharya quickly took over the reins, this change of leadership occurred at a time when the party was grappling with its ideological response to the economic lib eralization India had embarked upon in the early 1990s. The political platform of the LFG was keenly debated at the state and sub-national levels as it struggled with decisions on the degree of market-oriented reforms it was willing to initiate. At the state level, several CPI(M) party leaders were suspended from the party due to their opposition to market-oriented reforms initiated by Chief Minister Bhattacharya in the middle of the decade. At the same time, the economic reforms and change in political leadership at the state level as well as within the CPI(M) reinvigorated the grassroots base of the LFG by providing hope for increased economic growth and social welfare improvements. The 2003 panchayat elections took place in the midst of this identity crisis of the LFG and were accompanied by the highest degree of election-related viol ence seen in West Bengal since the late 1970s. Political space initially narrowed in the wake of these elections. According to local accounts, local poll violence in 2003 was largely associated with CPI(M) party members determined to retain
West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 133 their hold on power (Jagdish Chatterjee 2007; Sudipto Bhattacharya 2008). In Kuchli and Shahajapur, several upper-caste citizens who belonged to the polit ical opposition interpreted the strong-arm tactics of the CPI(M) during the 2003 election as leaving them little choice for official political contestation against the CPI(M). When political contestation, which for the first time since 1977 might have unseated the LFG, was met with violence in 2003 village residents switched allegiance to the CPI(M) party (Sudipto Bhattacharya 2008; Adhikary 2009), leading to the largest LFG win in panchayat elections since 1988 (see Table 4.3). Public attention to the 2003 election violence and the changing LFG economic platform spotlighted the turmoil within the CPI(M) and increasing opposition to its changing platform. For example, the LFG decision in 2007 to actively court large industries by, for example, forcibly buying up land from farmers in the town of Nandigram and offering special tax concessions in order to attract private capital to set up a chemical manufacturing plant, spotlighted the local as well as state-level CPI(M)’s disregard for local democracy and human rights. Opposition parties took Nandigram as an opportunity to rally and organize the farmers who were about to be dispossessed, eventually prevailing. Another well-publicized attempt by the LFG to offer confiscated land in Singur at a concessional rate to Tata automobile manufacturing in 2006 backfired in the face of large-scale organ ized demonstration. The fight within the LFG for a new ideological identity and cases such as Nandigram and Singur galvanized the political opposition. The 2008 panchayat elections were conducted against this politically polarized and volatile background. The parties of the LFG lost East Midnapore and South 24-Parganas districts, both centers of opposition to the LFG’s new industrialization policy, in addition to two other districts. Of the 18 districts in West Bengal, the Left Front retained 13 district-level Zilla Panchayats, and the opposi tion, including the Congress and Trinamul Congress, won five. At the block and Gram Panchayat levels, the losses for the Left were even higher. In response to the large local election loss the LFG decided to reevaluate its industrial policy and approach to luring large industries to West Bengal. However, it is doubtful that the 2008 local government election spells the end of the era of LFG-dominated state politics, even though the parties of the LFG won with the lowest margin since 1978 The Trinamul Congress Party increased the number of district-level local government seats that it won from 38 in 1998 to 122 in the 2008 election, making it the largest opposition party to gain seats, ahead of the 97 district-level seats gained by the Congress Party (which also tripled its representation compared to the 1998 elections), and well ahead of the third-largest opposition party, the Bharatiya Janata Party (BJP), which won two seats at the same local government level (Government of West Bengal 2011). The AITC and the Congress Party made large gains during the 2008 elections, particularly at the village level, yet at the district level the LFG parties retained almost 70 percent of local government seats (Chattopadhyay 2008). Whether the Trinamul Congress and the Congress Party will continue to wrest votes away from the parties of the LFG over the longer term, however, will depend on their ability to build a party network down from the state level to the
134 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost villages and Gram Panchayats. While the Congress Party has been the traditional opposition party in West Bengal, the Trinamul Congress was able to ascend rapidly during the 2008 panchayat elections by effectively capitalizing on the popular discontent surrounding the Nandigram and Singur cases. However, unlike the Congress Party, which has a grassroots political structure down to the village levels dating back to the freedom movement, and unlike the CPI(M) and other parties of the LFG, which in many villages of West Bengal are viewed as synonymous with local government structures, the AITC by 2011 still lacked the grassroots presence and network needed for longer-term electoral gains. A key lesson from the three decades of LFG rule in the villages of West Bengal is that a strong party presence at the grassroots, along with visible results such as the delivery of social services and land reform, matters for a party’s electoral gains, from the village to the state level. While the 2008 electoral gains at the panchayat level for opposition parties in West Bengal do not yet point to the demise of the LFG, West Bengal politics by 2011 was increasingly characterized by political turmoil. This is also evident by the growth of the Maoist guerilla movement in the state. That the ranks of the growing Maoist movement were largely filled with the poor and ST in particular is evident from their high presence in West Bengal’s tribal and heavily forested areas of West Midnapore, Bankura and Purulia districts. Some areas of these districts also have extraordinarily high poverty rates – in West Midnapore’s Jamboni block for example over 90 percent of the population live below the official poverty line (Ghosh 1998). Moreover, the West Bengali Maoists have repeatedly stated that they represent the rights of landless laborers and tribal communities. Researchers of this movement conclude that the grievances of the Maoists in Birbhum District and other parts of West Bengal center on their mar ginalized social and economic status, including lack of adequate access to social programs and the fact that they were allotted unfertile lands during land reforms (Sudipto Bhattacharya 2008). Despite the increasingly politicized nature of local government politics, the overall analysis of the revamped local government institutions in Kuchli and Shahajapur by 2011 is a mixed yet positive one. According to the respondents, the local governments have generally helped improve the lives of most citizens and this in turn has brought some prosperity and stability compared to the pre- 1978 period. Yet the positive view of the CPI(M)-dominated Gram Panchayats was in flux after the 2008 local government elections. Villagers are now more aware of their rights, from their right to vote with a secret ballot for a person of their choosing to the right to have access to locally delivered central government services. The increased awareness of rights is leading to an increased insistence on those rights, even if it leads to increased violence and political instability.
Conclusion: the cost of long-term domination Has the presence of Gram Panchayats in these West Bengali villages mattered for the social wellbeing of their residents? Or would the residents of Kuchli and
West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 135 Shahajapur be just as well off if there had not been any functioning local govern ments over the past decades or if no changes to the panchayat system had been made in the wake of the 73rd amendment? Analyzing case studies in West Bengal is crucial to understanding the differ ence that Gram Panchayats make in improving social wellbeing in rural India. It is the only state that had functioning panchayats before the passage of the 73rd amendment and is important to understanding whether the quotas for women and SC/ST groups that were introduced after the amendment can make a longer-term difference in further improving social welfare. This research suggests four findings. First, the Gram Panchayats have provided a forum which cuts across social cleavages and since 1993 also across gender divides, thereby decreasing these cleavages and making interactions with local government more democratic. However, since panchayat members in West Bengal campaign and are elected based on party membership, the cleavages in these villages are now along party lines. The political as well as socioeconomic polarization between party and nonparty members is high and significantly higher than in the villages studied in Karnataka. Second, having functioning local governments in these villages for nearly three decades has resulted in a greater awareness of rights and increased willingness to act to ensure these rights. Citizens in these villages reported a high awareness of panchayat functioning and petitioning of local governments, even higher than in the study villages in Karnataka. Third, greater politicization and growing awareness of rights together with functioning local governments have helped improve social wellbeing between 1993 and 2010. And fourth, the domination of local governments by one party has decreased democratic efficiency of these Gram Panchayats and worsened the targeting and impact of programs aimed at improving social wellbeing. West Bengal in the 1960s and 1970s was a state polarized along social cleavages. With the election of the CPI(M)-led LFG in 1977 and each subsequent election, the social cleavages have decreased. The long tenure in West Bengal of the CPI(M), a party founded on a class-based ideology, has helped reduce the social space between the landowners and the sharecroppers, the higher and lower castes, between the poorer and richer, by working through local governments to implement pro-poor reforms (particularly land reform) and improve social ser vice delivery. Functioning Gram Panchayats and the twice-yearly meetings of the village electorate through the Gram Sabha (when they do take place) have meant that people who would not previously have interacted, now have to work together to run the local governments. Moreover, since 1993 the increased pres ence of women and ST groups in local governments has further enhanced the democratic representation of disenfranchised groups, and to a lesser extent access to social services. Studies of increased female and SC/ST representation in local governments (Chattopadhyay and Duflo 2004), as well as feedback from respondents to this research, indicate that increased representation of these groups in the Gram Panchayats has improved social wellbeing in general. Thus Gram Panchayats in West Bengal have helped local communities to overcome
136 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost social cleavages, increase social mobilization, and thereby improve social wellbeing. The domination of politics by the CPI(M), however, has come at a cost. Since Gram Panchayat members in West Bengal are elected based on political parties, social cleavages have been replaced with political cleavages. By the turn of the century, the CPI(M)-dominated Left Front Government faced little competition and continued to dominate most village governments in West Bengal. This domination led to allegations of corruption, election fraud, and a general sense that those who are LFG-affiliated party members are above the law and not subject to democratic competition. After experiencing the smallest margin of electoral victory since West Bengal’s local government election of 1978, an increased spotlight on charges of corruption within the LFG, a more organized political opposition, and a reinvigorated Maoist guerilla movement were challenging the Left Front on its own ideological turf. This might have increased political com petition at the panchayat level. However, despite these challenges, by the end of 2011 the LFG still controlled a majority of Gram Panchayats, though their lead was no longer as commanding as in the past. One of the key contributions of 30 years of functioning local governments has been to increase local citizens’ awareness of their rights. As those who were formerly disenfranchised started to participate in local governments and become more literate, their awareness of their rights – for example, to access social ser vices or receive the official daily wage for laborers – has also increased. This growing awareness is evident not only in the increased percentage of laborers receiving the official minimum daily rate (Sunil Sengupta et al. 1991), but also in the increased willingness to act in order to demand one’s rights, the incidence of collective actions, the diminished electoral majorities of the LFG, and the growth of the Maoist movement. When Gram Panchayats were first elected in 1978, they were given the responsibility of carrying out land reform and sharecropper registration by the newly elected LFG. Over the subsequent decades, additional responsibilities for implementing social programs were given to the panchayats. Local panchayats who are periodically elected and who implement social welfare programs, together with the growing awareness of rights and demands of citizens, have helped root democracy in West Bengali villages and changed people’s lives by improving social wellbeing. Many of the improvements in welfare are directly attributable to local governments in the respective villages. The Gram Panchayats carried out land reforms, which registered the homesteads of many landless people and registered tenancy rights. They implemented central government- funded anti-poverty programs in the villages. After the 73rd Amendment they have increasingly been charged with forming subgroups to oversee the implementation of social sector programs, from delivering primary education and adult-literacy services to building local infrastructure. Without local govern ments responsible for each village and without local government representatives who were family, neighbors, and fellow village residents, there would not have been a “face” that villagers could associate with the State. When state programs
West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 137 did or did not deliver, residents knew who was to praise or blame. Having a local face to associate with the State has meant that local residents have been more likely to hold local governments accountable and in turn the local governments, unlike in Uttar Pradesh, have been more likely to deliver the goods and services aimed at improving social welfare. Overall, having had functioning local governments in Kuchli and Shahajapur has made a difference in people’s lives, improving their social welfare directly through implementation of anti-poverty programs, and indirectly through decreasing the socioeconomic cleavages between people of different religions, caste, and gender, thereby, increasing people’s sense of their self-worth. But there is a caveat to the positive relationship between functioning local govern ments in West Bengal and improving social welfare. The domination of the Gram Panchayats in most of West Bengal by CPI(M) and other LFG associated parties initially had a large positive impact on fighting poverty, as pointed out by Kohli and Lieten (Kohli 1987; Lieten 1996a). However, the lack of competition in CPI(M)-dominated Gram Panchayat elections over the past three decades has decreased the reformist capacities of local governments in West Bengal, including the targeting of anti-poverty programs. Furthermore, domination of the polit ical landscape by LFG-affiliated parties has by 2011 nurtured a new village elite that has little incentive to nurture democratic panchayat institutions, thereby leading to a weakening of local democracy’s roots. Despite an engaged and active civil society, the lack of competitive local governments and new village elites whose base of political power is contingent on their undemocratic control of Gram Panchayats, undermine local democracy in West Bengal, in particular preventing the targeting of social services to the most indigent. Active CPI(M) members are generally not the poorest in both villages, but rather, are now the political elite in both villages – an elite that has captured many of the social welfare programs and resources meant for the indigent popu lation. As the follow-up with past recipients of some social welfare programs allocated through the GP in 2000 and 2008 indicated, most recipients of social welfare programs in recent years were not the poorest, but CPI(M) members who had received social benefits based on their party affiliation. Corruption, leakages, and a general loss of zeal in carrying out land reforms and in targeting anti-poverty programs to the most vulnerable populations in these West Bengali villages, have undermined the very premise by which the LFG first rose to power in the 1970s. Low turnout rates at Gram Sabha meetings attest to the increasing sense among villagers in Kuchli and Shahajapur that their opinions matter less than those of CPI(M) party leaders and GP members, who are usually the same people. The anti-poverty successes of CPI(M)-led local governments during the 1980s, the very reason that Gram Panchayat members of the CPI(M) have been continuously reelected over the past decades, has led local governments to lose their zeal in carrying out these programs thereby decreasing their impact on improving social welfare. West Bengal is the middling case in this research because the lack of political competition, the accompanying strong social cleavages between party members and those who are not CPI(M) party
138 West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost Table 4.4 West Bengal: results of selected questions from sample survey in each village, 2000, numbers responding positively (percentages in parentheses)
Voted in last national elections Thought last national elections were fair Voted in last GP elections Thought last GP elections were fair Campaigned for the election of a GP member Knew the name of GP representative(s) Have participated in a meeting of the village electorate There are working social welfare programs in the village GP is instrumental in delivering these social services There are working anti-poverty programs in village GP is instrumental in delivering these anti-poverty programs GP been able to satisfy the most important needs in the village If two poor people applied for an anti-poverty scheme to the GP and one was a CPI(M) member and the other not, and the panchayat could only give the scheme to one person, the GP would give it to the CPI(M) member (additional question) More voice under new GP system Less violence in 2000 compared to 1990 Rule of law has improved between 1990 and 2000 Government has become more effective Administrative burden has decreased Accountability has improved Corruption decreased over past 10 years (comparing 2000 to 1990) Were better off in 2000 compared to 1990 Of those who were better off, those who said they were better off due to the GP There are associations (bridging religion and caste) in this village Have participated in associations in last five years Have had contact with their GP member Have contacted their GP representative for help in the last five years
Kuchli (n = 41)
Shahajapur (n = 39)
Total (n = 80)
40 25 38 26 8 33 14
38 26 39 24 8 32 12
78 (97%) 51 (64%) 77 (96%) 50 (62%) 16 (20%) 65 (81%) 26 (33%)
41
39
80 (100%)
31
35
66 (82%)
40 37
37 36
77 (96%) 73 (91%)
24
24
48 (60%)
32
27
59 (74%)
37 31 9 25 17 8 14
36 33 9 23 16 8 14
73 (91%) 64 (80%) 18 (23%) 48 (60%) 33 (41%) 16 (20%) 28 (35%)
26 18
28 14
54 (68%) 32(40%)
41
39
80 (100%)
21 20 23
17 18 20
38 (48%) 38 (48%) 43 (54%)
members, and elite capture of socioeconomic benefits intended for the indigent, have offset the effects of a socially aware and mobilized population, diminising local government efficacy in delivering public programs intended to improve the wellbeing of the poorest. Promoting greater resource allocation to Gram Panchayats or greater manpower to implement panchayat programs, as advocated by a
West Bengal – continuity and domination at a cost 139 conference report devoted to the lessons of decentralization in West Bengal (Ghosh 2008) therefore misunderstands the causal underpinnings of the panchayats’ middling performance. The inefficiency of West Bengal’s panchayats is not due to lack of resources, but rather to the lack of political competition and the resulting elite capture of social programs. Channeling additional resources to Gram Panchayats under the current structural conditions is therefore unlikely to yield better results in terms of efficiency and improvements in social wellbeing. These village studies in West Bengal indicate that there is not a straight forward positive correlation between decentralized local government and improving social welfare. Functioning local governments actively implementing social welfare programs are a necessary, but not sufficient, condition for success in reducing poverty and improving social wellbeing. The extent to which local governments are democratic and accountable matters greatly. The impact of decentralized governments on social wellbeing depends on the nature of local governance and how well people are able to actively participate and demand their social rights. Periodic local government elections, diverse socioeconomic representation and local government implementation of social welfare programs, are not sufficient in themselves to guarantee accountable local governments that target the poorest. In West Bengal the majority of local governments have been dominated by LFG-affiliated parties for over three decades. This has led to local governments that are not fully politically representative of and thus less account able to their constituents, thereby weakening the efficacy of Gram Panchayats in improving social wellbeing.
5 Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power and local governments
Since 1950, a constitutional right to education and decades of central govern ment funding for primary education has meant that the village of Palanpur today has a cement, two-room primary school; the building has a recently added out house and three government-employed, full-time teachers for the nearly 140 enrolled students. On those rare days when the school is in session and at least one of the teachers shows up to teach all children grades one through five, at most a dozen children are present, sitting down on the verandah, without a black board, books, or any other type of school supplies often whiling the time away while the teacher attends to “other duties.” Parents, who long ago gave up pushing their kids to go to a school that is rarely in session, nevertheless keep their children enrolled in the school in the hope that they might have access to the free “midday meals.” The Integrated Child Development Program (ICDS), which among other responsibilities, is supposed to provide pre- and post-natal care to pregnant women and infants through the local Anganwadi (village health worker), has not been heard of by most women interviewed in Palanpur. In addition, the absence of access to national health programs such as the tuberculosis (TB) program, which is supposed to provide a full treatment course at no charge, or the anti- malaria program, which is supposed to distribute heavily subsidized insecticide- impregnated bednets, has resulted in at least six confirmed cases of tuberculosis in 2008 in Palanpur and dozens of cases of malaria annually. A nine-year old boy, Viresh, suffers from TB. His parents barely earn enough to feed their small family of four, let alone buy the expensive TB medication that their child requires. Life would be easier if they would receive their monthly allotment of publicly distributed goods, thereby freeing up money to cover other basic needs. Viresh is enrolled in the local primary school, but does not know how to read or write because the main teacher seldom shows up and even when he is there, he rarely teaches. Because he is not able to regularly get the medication to cure his TB, his small body is not strong enough to help contribute to the family earnings. Viresh is a boy – his chances of improved welfare are much better than that of most girls his age. Viresh’s mother is atypical because she is literate and
Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power 141 understands what the officer distributing public goods stamps in her booklet when rations are distributed. What can she do to complain about the total ineffectiveness of anti-poverty programs in Palanpur? From whom can she demand the health care to cure her son? To whom could she go and who would listen to her? (Notes from field research in Palanpur 2000) Viresh died in 2005 of suspected TB. He was 14 years old and could neither read or write. Nor was he able to demand access to the free government health care that might have saved his life. When Viresh’s mother asked the local government representatives for help, they did not respond. (Notes from field research in Palanpur 2008) Of the three case studies in this book, the north Indian state of Uttar Pradesh (UP) represents the low-functioning case. Unlike both Karnataka and West Bengal, Uttar Pradesh had no history of democratically functioning local gov ernments prior to the passage of the 73rd Amendment. Moreover, despite large socioeconomic potential, social indicators before and after mandatory decentrali zation remain well below the Indian average (see Table 2.3). The inability to effectively deliver public social services in Uttar Pradesh, ranging from health care to anti-poverty programs, is due to virtually defunct local governments in many parts of the state. Local governments are captured by old and new local elites, while the lack of a mobilized civil society in the presence of political par ties that appeal to and reinforce stark social cleavages, hamper sporadic local efforts at increasing Gram Panchayat (GP) governance and accountability. In this infertile soil for democratic local government structures, Gram Panchayats do not function as envisioned by the Indian constitution and do not help deliver social services that would improve the social wellbeing of their constituents. As seen in the villages studied, Uttar Pradesh’s decentralized governance structures do not select the poorest as beneficiaries of anti-poverty programs, nor do they effectively deliver social welfare programs to the targeted beneficiaries – both key aspects of local governments’ ability to influence social wellbeing. In 2011, the situation in UP remains dire, with little commitment by the state government to decentralization and social change. The innovations to the pan chayat system that were implemented by the state were only those that were mandated by the federal law. The panchayat system in UP continues to delegate responsibilities to the panchayat, without the necessary political and legal means nor the financial wherewithal to enable real social improvements. The govern ment of UP had no prior history of effective decentralization prior to 1993, nor a state-level commitment to social improvement. Indeed, social indicators are only slowly improving. Without a functioning local government system, social well being in Uttar Pradesh is likely to fall further behind states with high-functioning local governance like Karnataka, thereby also exacerbating inequality. However, despite this dismal situation, there are some indications that having directly elected local representatives, even if they are corrupt and unaccountable, is
142 Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power helping increase awareness of rights – the first step towards demanding rights and access to government programs and improving social conditions.
Background Uttar Pradesh, like the other two case study states of West Bengal and Karna taka, is a large Indian state. Beyond this categorization, however, there are few similarities. Even after the northern part of the state separated to form the new state of Uttaranchal in 2001, Uttar Pradesh was still the most populous Indian state with over 166 million inhabitants (UP Government 2001). Its size and population have given it the distinction of being the most populous subnational division in the world. UP’s population is larger than that of many of India’s neighbors, including Bangladesh, Nepal, and Sri Lanka. Uttar Pradesh is an important case study because it is an enigma to theories of socioeconomic development. At the time of independence, and indeed into the 1970s, UP was thought to have the potential to lead India in social and economic development. Much of the state lies in the fertile Indo-Gangetic Plain and has naturally high soil fertility that allows for triple-cropping in many parts of the state, enabling UP to be one of the leading states in India’s Green Revolution of the 1960s and 1970s. New technology and increased irrigation have translated into higher grain yields per hectare than in most of the other Indian states; this region is part of India’s breadbasket. Despite these advantages, the state of UP has remained one of India’s most backward areas in terms of social indicators. By 1993 when the 73rd Amend ment was enacted, social and economic indicators in UP were well behind West Bengal and Karnataka, as well as most other Indian states. The proportion of people living below the poverty line in rural UP in the early 1990s was 42 percent – significantly higher than the Indian average of 37 percent. Moreover, over the past decades, UP’s poverty rates have shown only slow improvements. In 2005 nearly a third of UP’s population was still living below the poverty line, only half the population was literate, and there were still under 900 females per 1,000 males (Bhandari and Kale 2007b) – which put Uttar Pradesh behind Kar nataka and West Bengal, as well as the national average, in terms of social indic ators (see Table 2.3). Uttar Pradesh contradicts the conventional wisdom that economic, and particularly agricultural, growth should translate into greatly improving social indicators. Advances in agriculture, the mainstay occupation and income source in rural UP, have not translated into improved social wellbe ing, raising the question “why not?” This case study of Uttar Pradesh investigates what happens when decentrali zation of administrative and political powers down to the village level is man dated in a state that, despite economic potential, has been unable to show commensurate improvements in social and poverty indicators. It is the test case for staunch supporters of decentralization who argue that having local govern ments is likely to produce better socioeconomic results in any socioeconomic context. In contrast to the findings on West Bengal and Karnataka, constituting
Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power 143 village-level local governments seems to have made little difference to the indic ators of social wellbeing. Nearly two decades after the implementation of local governments in the wake of the 73rd Amendment, poverty rates and social indic ators in UP remained among the worst of Indian states, with the gap between UP and Karnataka’s social indicators growing by 2011.
Socioeconomic and political context Neglect of UP’s political, economic, and social nexus at the local level in the literature is glaring because, politically, Uttar Pradesh has been an important state for national politics – more so than either West Bengal or Karnataka. Several Indian prime ministers started their careers in this state. Until 1977 all three prime ministers of India came from UP and of the 14 prime ministers to date, eight have come from UP. Of the 540 members of the Indian parliament, 85 come from UP, making it the largest group of state representatives in the par liament. Trying to understand the linkages between local governments and indic ators of social wellbeing in such a large and important state is important in its own right as well as for the impact it has on India. At the same time, any study aiming to generalize about an area this size faces many difficulties. Uttar Pradesh is not only a large and populous state, its average indicators mask great diversity from the generally more prosperous western part to the less well-off eastern part. Different castes dominate different parts of the state, while the state’s sizable Muslim population is concentrated in the western region. Western Uttar Pradesh is also agriculturally more prosper ous, more industrialized and is more urbanized than the eastern part of the state. The eastern section of the state is characterized by lower agricultural growth and a lower level of industrial activity. However, it is important to bear in mind that all parts of the state, as with West Bengal and Karnataka, have had the same political history over the past half-century and all districts are governed by the same administrative structure, covered by the same public programs. Moreover, while the villages analyzed in this study are located in the more affluent western part of the state, social indic ators in this area are comparable to state averages. Given some general baseline indicators, it is therefore possible to understand and make generalizations about the processes through which local governments interact (or fail to interact) with their respective populations in order to change social welfare. It is important to understand the larger statewide political context in which local governments in UP function. From independence through the late 1960s UP politics was dominated by the Congress Party and the socioeconomic elite: the upper castes and Ashraf Muslims. The Brahmins, in particular, dominated the state’s political landscape, and by implication also Indian politics, into the early 1990s. The formation of the Bharatiya Lok Dal (BLD) in 1967 and the short-lived Janata Party government of 1977 signified the entrance of rich and middle-class peasants as a new contending force in UP politics. The refurbish ment of the Janata Party in 1990 as the Janata Dal and the swearing in of
144 Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power Mayawati, Uttar Pradesh’s first Dalit (scheduled caste) chief minister and head of the Bahujan Samaj Party (BSP), a party standing largely for the rights of sched uled castes (SC), in April of 1995 further changed the political landscape (Pai 2002). Increasingly greater numbers of SCs and other backward castes (OBCs) entered the center-stage of UP politics and political leadership. The expectations built up by the ‘garibi hatao’ (remove poverty) campaign of the Congress Party, the social improvement slogans of the Janata Dal, and the political entrance of parties claiming to represent the interests of the lower castes led to increased mobilization around questions of identity and empowerment (Hasan 1996). By the 1990s, new identity-based parties were capturing votes of distinct castes and Muslims, leading to a more developed form of cleavage politics in UP than in any other state (Heath and Yadav 2002). The traditional dominance of the Congress Party and the new national party, the BJP, was by the 1990s, being replaced with the BSP. In addition, the Samajwadi Party (SP; literally Socialist Party), a state-based rather than national party whose main base of support lies with the OBCs, also made electoral gains in Uttar Pradesh. This combination of increased mobilization around religious and caste identity and identity-based parties making electoral gains, together with constantly shifting alliances between the main political parties, has led to increased volatility in UP politics since the late 1980s. While UP politics at the turn to the twenty-first century were characterized by identity-based politics and political parties that appealed directly to the numeri cally large lower castes, social issues continued to receive scarce attention and resources. Successive governments did not focus on poverty alleviation, inequal ity, or empowerment of the poor. Only in the past decade has the state govern ment increased funding to the social sectors. Taken together, the state’s history of not actively pursuing pro-poor policies and the presence of strong caste and class cleavages since the 1970s (Kohli 1987; Lerche 1999) have resulted in low social mobility in an environment of slowly growing awareness and slowly rising expectations. In addition to a society divided along caste lines and strong cleavage politics, failure of the Uttar Pradesh state government to actively pursue land reforms and the low priority accorded to improving the welfare of the rural poor in what is a largely rural, agricultural state has contributed to the failure to produce pro-poor change (Kohli 1987). The dominance of conservative social structures in the state has also inhibited inter-caste and class alliances aimed at improving social wellbeing at both the national and local levels. This was the case in the 1980s, before the implementation of the nation-wide decentralized system, and it was still the case well into the twenty-first century. Mandating the elections of local governments in this statewide and local environment was unlikely to achieve the desired results of improved social indicators at the local level. This research finds that the presence of a new local government structure with increased representation of women and SC/ST is slowly leading to increased awareness of rights and questioning of engrained social cleavages. However, in an environ ment where state politics and political mobilization still revolve around religious
Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power 145 and caste-based politics, local governments are unable to supersede established social hierarchies and patronage networks in the villages of UP. In this political environment, newly emerging and traditional local elites stymie the ability of local governments to help improve poverty rates and social indicators.
1994 amended acts in UP in response to the 73rd Amendment Before the introduction of the 73rd Constitutional Amendment Act in 1993, there were local governments in Uttar Pradesh, but they were largely in name only and elections to the Gram Panchayat were sporadic in the 47 years between the initial Panchayat Raj Act of 1947 and its amendment in UP in 1994. More over, despite a Gram Panchayat structure which on paper had all the ingredients to deliver the fruits of village democracy and social development, panchayats formed in the wake of the 1947 Act failed to deliver. Instead, local power- holders and caste elites occupied panchayat positions and acted as the local contact persons for the government. By the early 1990s, democratically elected and democratically functioning Gram Panchayats in the study villages of Palan pur and Pipli, as in most of Uttar Pradesh, were rare. Panchayats were de facto understood to mean an informal gathering of village elders, usually headed by a person recognized as the “pradhan” (headman), convened for the purpose of resolving a specific village dispute.1 These village elders were the traditional landowning upper castes with their established patronage networks, which oper ated in an environment of deep social cleavages amongst people of different caste, religious, gender and ethnic backgrounds. It is in this environment of a largely patriarchal society with deep social cleavages and firmly rooted patronage structures that Uttar Pradesh changed its laws to be in congruence with the 73rd Amendment. Rather than enacting new local government legislation as in Karnataka, the Government of Uttar Pradesh chose to amend the two existing acts on local governments, the United Provinces Panchayat Raj Act of 1947 and the Uttar Pradesh Kshetra Pan chayat and Zilla Panchayat Adhiniyam of 1961. The amended acts, which con tinued the three-tiered local government system that UP had until then had on paper, came into force in April 1994. Innovations to the old local government system were the mandating of one-third of local government seats in all three tiers for women, and seats reserved for other backward castes (OBC) and the SC/ST population according to their proportion in the population of the district (with a limit of 27 percent for the OBC). This decentralized system has a Zilla Panchayat at the district level, a Kshetra Panchayat at the block level, and a Gram Panchayat at the village level. A Gram Panchayat is formed for each village or group of villages with a population of about 1,000 people, with the stipulation that no revenue village is to be divided for the purposes of forming a Gram Panchayat. Since the panchayat amendment acts in UP provided for a wide range of activities that were to be devolved to the local governments, the state appointed a commission to suggest changes required at the state level to plan and
146 Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power implement development programs in conjunction with the local governments. This commission suggested sharing functions between 32 departments of the state government and the different levels of panchayats. These recommendations were reviewed by the state government with orders for 28 departments to trans fer some power and functions to local governments (Mathew 2000). Ultimately, however, most important decision-making continued to remain in the hands of the bureaucrats at the state level. Gram Panchayats in UP have nevertheless had the resources and the power to implement development programs. Moreover, the control over works that fell under the jurisdiction of the departments of primary education, non-formal edu cation, rural drinking water, social welfare, youth affairs, women’s welfare and child development, agriculture, medical and health, animal husbandry, sugar cane, land development and water resources, village development and farming, was given to Gram Panchayats (Mathew 2000). The Gram Panchayats were to carry out the works related to these areas, including management of Gram Pan chayat funds – for example, to ensure the repair of hand-pumps, maintain pri mary schools and sub-health centers, and implement anti-poverty programs. While Gram Panchayats in UP had fewer financial powers devolved to them than in either West Bengal or Karnataka, they had similar levels of responsibility for implementing and managing socioeconomic programs and similar jurisdiction to target programs aimed at improving social indicators.
Case studies The two villages studied, Palanpur and Pipli, are located in the northwestern region of Uttar Pradesh. This part of the state has social indicators that are around the state average and agro-climatic conditions that are similar to most parts of the state. The region also exemplifies the conundrum of UP: owing to the quality of land, irrigation facilities, and available agricultural technology, it is considered to be part of the breadbasket area of India. Yet, despite these advantages, economic and social indicators for UP’s Moradabad District were around UP state averages (see Table 5.1). The ratio of females to males in
Table 5.1 Selected socioeconomic indicators, Moradabad District versus Uttar Pradesh averages Moradabad District Uttar Pradesh Population growth rate, 1991–2001 (%) Households with electricity connection, 2006 (%) Sex ratio, 2001 (females/1,000 males) Adult literacy rate, 2001 Infant mortality rate, 1998–1999 (per 1,000) % Scheduled Castes, 2001
27 39 875 45 95 19
26 35 898 56 87 21
Sources: Government of Uttar Pradesh 2001; Government of India 2001; Bhandari and Kale 2007b.
Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power 147 Moradabad was 875 compared to the state average of 898 in 2001 and 39 percent of households had access to electricity in the Moradabad District, compared to a 35 percent average in Uttar Pradesh (Bhandari and Kale 2007b). Each case study village is small, with a population under 2,000 according to the 1991 and 2001 census. They are only a couple of kilometers from each other, and about 30 kilometers south of Moradabad, the district headquarters. In 1993, the number of females to 100 males in Palanpur was 85, compared to the state rural average of 88, population growth rate was estimated at 1.9 percent, the same as the average for rural UP, while the estimated infant mortality rate at 160 was higher than the state average of 139 (Lanjouw and Stern 1998). In the case study villages, as in Moradabad District and statewide averages, poverty remained a persistent problem with at least 20 percent of the population barely making ends meet during the mid 1990s (Lanjouw and Stern 1998). Within this region of the state, the two villages of Palanpur and Pipli were chosen for study because of data availability and because their socioeconomic indicators are similar to those of northwestern UP. In particular, these villages were good cases for study because one of the villages, Palanpur, has been exten sively studied over the past five decades and its development has been docu mented in two major research works (Bliss and Stern 1982; Lanjouw and Stern 1998; Bandyopadhyay 2002). These previous studies of Palanpur provide insights into village life, social, and economic development, and local govern ment structures prior to the implementation of the Gram Panchayats. As such they provide a basis for comparing life before and after institution of the new panchayat system.
Palanpur and Pipli in the early 1990s: village self-government in name only2 The lack of democratically functioning local governments prior to implementa tion of the 73rd Amendment meant that the reach of the state did not extend to the majority of the village population. Government-sponsored social programs, such as the Public Distribution System (PDS), which aims to distribute subsi dized essential goods like wheat and cooking oil to indigent people, as well as food-for-work programs, reached the villagers through government bureaucrats at the block or district level. However, many of these programs functioned only minimally. The villagers’ only recourse, if indeed they were aware of the fact that something they were entitled to was not given to them, was to physically go to the Block Development Officer (BDO) or Chief Development Officer (CDO) at the district headquarters in order to lodge a complaint. Going to the district offices was something which, given the distance of travel and lack of experience in dealing with these matters, was unimaginable to most villagers. This meant that the state, and with it its social development programs, only minimally affected the lives of villagers in Palanpur and Pipli. What progress individuals in these villages had achieved was usually entirely of their own doing, rather than through state provision of education, safety nets, and economic opportunities.
148 Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power The absence of elected and representative village governments meant that the state did not reach down to the village level and, conversely, that village citizens could not access government-sponsored programs, much less make their own decisions on how to best distribute government programs to the needy. There was no democratically functioning local government in the villages of UP in the early 1990s.
Social and economic wellbeing in the early 1990s In the early 1990s, both Palanpur and Pipli were still largely agriculture-based villages, with a small but increasing percentage of the labor force having non-agricultural jobs as their main source of income. Agricultural innovations brought about through the Green Revolution, together with the region’s fertile soil and increased irrigation, meant that agricultural productivity was relatively high by Indian standards. Although increased productivity was also accompanied by large decreases in real prices of the main agricultural outputs, it nevertheless contributed to overall economic growth in these villages. Yet the increase in economic welfare was not accompanied by similar gains in the social sectors, as education and health indicators in the early 1990s had not kept pace with economic improvements. In fact, some indicators, such as a decreasing female-to-male ratio and little upward mobility among the lowest caste residents, highlight the failure of government sponsored health, education, and anti-poverty programs to reach the most vulnerable members of the society.
No forum for overcoming social cleavages and inequalities Caste dominated interaction between individuals and groups in Palanpur and Pipli in the early 1990s. It also determined the norms of social interaction, par ticularly for women, and cooperation (or the lack thereof ) between individuals. Women from one caste might see women from other castes at religious festivals or temples, but would be unlikely to interact. Accounts from the early 1990s, as well as maps drawn of Palanpur showing residential segregation of different castes, demonstrate that these were not tranquil rural societies (Lanjouw and Stern 1998). Both villages were structured according to rigid norms of caste and class and also according to gender, degree of education, and kinship. Interactions occurred along these familial and socioeconomic divisions. There were no clubs, associations, or informal groups of any kind that provided a venue for people from different castes or class to interact. This was despite the fact that, for example, Muslim and Jatab (the lowest in Palanpur’s caste hierarchy) agricul tural workers had similar socioeconomic characteristics and would have bene fited from cooperating with each other in lobbying for better labor conditions. These great social inequalities between people and the deep cleavages they produced among the villagers, along with the lack of any formal or informal associations, were not an environment conducive to collective action. Indeed
Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power 149 villagers and the researchers who had previously studied these villages could remember very few instances of collective action. This meant a perpetuation of the status quo of a highly unequal and divided society in Palanpur and Pipli in the 1990s. The resultant social cleavages, coupled with the lack of a history of democratically functioning local govern ment, and the largely ineffective reach of public social programs, made for a situation in which the already abysmally low social indicators and poor general social welfare were unlikely to improve rapidly. Palanpur and Pipli were caught up in a situation where improved economic welfare had only slowly trickled down into gains in social welfare. Life for the most vulnerable people in Palan pur and Pipli – the lowest caste, many of the Muslim families particularly in Pal anpur, poorer girls and women – had not improved significantly.
Findings from the village studies a decade later The following section explores the perception of the new panchayat system among the villagers. By analyzing popular participation in elections, the work of the Gram Panchayat, accountability in the new panchayat system and the overall perception of the panchayat system, the subtle ways in which having an elected village government might have changed the villagers’ lives are explored. Second, whether the quality of governance changed since 1993 and whether the Gram Panchayat played any role is analyzed. Third, the villagers’ own percep tion of changes in wellbeing and its links with the panchayat system are evalu ated. As with the other case studies, the village research presented is mainly based on qualitative information, supplemented with a small, stratified sample survey in both villages conducted in 2000 that collected both qualitative and quantitative data. A total of 80 villagers were interviewed in the two villages of Palanpur and Pipli, 40 in each village. See Table 5.3 at the end of the chapter for results on selected survey questions. Interviews with key informants and focus group discussions were held in 2000 and again in 2007/2008.
Perceptions of the new Panchayat system The first statewide panchayat elections in Uttar Pradesh were held on April 1995. Over 50,000 Gram Panchayats were elected and turnout was high throughout the state. People also turned out to vote in high numbers in Palanpur and Pipli. In Palanpur, the position of the pradhan (head of the Gram Panchayat) was for the first time reserved for a person from an OBC background, while in Pipli it was the first time that the position was reserved for a woman of SC background.3 Many villagers who were not part of the village elite and who had traditionally been excluded from positions of government now had a chance to stand for elec tion and be represented in the local government for the first time. In response to questions about whether they participated in the last national and village elections, an overwhelming majority of people surveyed in 2000 answered that they had voted. Of the total of 80 people interviewed in Palanpur
150 Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power and Pipli, 70 (88 percent) stated that they voted in the national elections, while 78 (98 percent) stated that they had voted in the last Gram Panchayat elections – similar to the high proportion found in the village studies in Karnataka and West Bengal. High voter turnout continued into the twenty-first century with the 2005 local government elections leading to a 85 percent voter turnout in Uttar Pradesh, which was also reflected in discussions in follow-up research in the villages in 2007/2008 (PTI 2010). Voting was an action that was perceived by most villagers as a duty, even when people were sure that there was some fraud in the elections such as “booth capturing,” miscounting of the votes, or intimidation of voters. The most frequent rationale given by survey respondents as well as by key informants in 2000 for the extremely high turnout at the Gram Panchayat elec tions of 1995 and 2000 (and during follow-up research about the 2005 elections in 2007/2008) was that many were excited about being able to directly elect their panchayat members, from the pradhan (head of the Gram Panchayat) to their ward representatives. Some genuinely hoped that having a panchayat representa tive from their own caste, religion, class, or gender would help improve their lives. When pressed further for how specifically they envisioned that the election of Gram Panchayat members would help improve their lives, the answers given ranged from general hopes of better roads, schools, and water access in the village, to specifics such as hoping to get the widow’s pension that they had not been receiving. Many key informants who voted stated that they did so because by having people they knew as their elected representatives and their interlocu tors with the government officials in charge of dispensing social programs and benefits, they would gain access to these programs. Several key informants shared that by becoming themselves or having someone they knew become part of the upward chain in government bureaucracy, they would gain access to resources they knew were being allocated to the village but not being disbursed.4 In addition to a high voter turnout for the first post-1993 Gram Panchayat elec tions, 58 out of 80 of those surveyed in 2000 (73 percent) felt the elections were fair, compared to 41 of the respondents (51 percent) who thought that national elections were fair. Several people insisted that the elections were rigged, but this was not the opinion of the majority of those surveyed in 2000, nor of the key informants interviewed in 2007/2008.5 In striking contrast to the high voter participation rates in the elections and the widespread sense of these elections being fair, a lower proportion of the 80 individuals who were surveyed in 2000 and interviewed in 2007/2008 was aware of the structure and workings of their Gram Panchayat. Almost everyone knew the name of their pradhan and 51 out of 80 surveyed (64 percent) could supply the names of their panchayat representative. Yet only 24 out of those surveyed in 2000 (30 percent) had attended any meeting held by the panchayat and of those who said that they had attended a meeting, the majority were panchayat members or close relatives of members.6 When the survey respondents in 2000 who stated that they did not attend Gram Sabha meetings were asked why they did not attend, most of them replied that these meetings did not actually take place.7
Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power 151 None of those who stated that they did not attend the Gram Sabhas or any other Gram Panchayat meeting was aware that these meetings were a requirement under the new panchayat law, much less that Gram Sabhas were the forum for determining the beneficiaries of government development programs.8 Most of those who did not attend these meetings also did not know that the Gram Pan chayat was supposed to form committees on social justice, development, village education and public interest to help it perform its functions.9 Thus, most of the villagers surveyed and the key informants interviewed in 2000 did not know how the Gram Panchayat was structured, how decisions regarding development pro jects were arrived at, or that they were supposed to be an integral part of the decision-making process.10 This lack of knowledge about the local government systems was mirrored in key informant interviews and focus group discussions conducted in 2007/2008. In addition, most voters in Palanpur and Pipli did not have frequent interaction with their panchayat representative. This was despite the fact that most castes, both religious groups in the two villages (Hindus and Muslims), and both genders were represented in each Gram Panchayat. In the 2000 survey, only 16 of the 80 survey respondents in both villages (20 percent) said that they had had contact with their GP member. While 20 out of 80 (25 percent) had contacted a panchayat member for help, for example, in resolving a bureaucratic matter or getting access to government services, only 9 of these 20 (45 percent) felt that the member was helpful in any way. Not only was the quantity of responses from panchayat members low, the quality of responses was usually also low. Follow-up inter views with survey respondents who indicated that they had contacted a member and received a response, found that the issue had not been resolved expeditiously. Interviews nearly eight years later with the same individuals as well as with key informants yielded similar feedback. This lack of local government responsive ness differs markedly from the village findings in Karnataka and West Bengal. Not only were panchayat members largely unresponsive when contacted by their constituents, one should also note the lack of agency among many villag ers in contacting, lobbying, or protesting actions of members of the Gram Pan chayat. The responses among the villagers clearly showed that very few villagers actually took some individual or collective action on behalf of or against their Gram Panchayat, again in contrast especially with the findings in West Bengal but also with those in Karnataka. Moreover, only 14 of the 80 survey respondents (18 percent) stated had participated in different types of actions with the GP, from signing petitions, requesting to meet with the pan chayat on an issue of concern, or protesting or thanking the panchayat for its actions. The number of survey respondents who stated that they had engaged in such activities with Gram Panchayat members was significantly higher in the village of Palanpur compared to Pipli, since there had been a collective action in 1999 to try to remove the head of the GP through petition signing. However, interviews with key informants in both villages in 2007/2008 found that in general there was no difference in level of activism and engagement between the residents of Palanpur and Pipli.
152 Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power In general, interviews with key informants in 2007/2008 revealed that the cit izens of Palanapur and Pipli overwhelmingly did not resort to their local govern ments. This is striking when considering the geography and structure of the village: the residential area of Palanpur consists of a tight cluster of about two hundred houses sitting on approximately 20 acres, with households of the same caste tending to live close to each other, and an overall population of about 2,000 (Lanjouw and Stern 1998). The density of the village population and dwelling construction in these villages in UP was higher than in the villages studies in West Bengal and Karnataka. Given the physically close construction of the village and the largely caste-segregated neighborhoods, it is difficult for resi dents going about their daily work activities not to at least see a panchayat member in their village. However, despite deep caste and religious cleavages in these villages as in the rest of Uttar Pradesh, there were some attempts at social engagement and civic action. While conducting the village studies in 2000 several examples of civic engagement across caste lines were evident. In Palanpur in 2000, some of the poorer or lower-caste residents were troubled by what they perceived as an inactive and corrupt pradhan of OBC background, who channeled social wel fare benefits to himself and his extended family and some traditional village power-holders of upper-caste background. Several Gram Panchayat members and a young Scheduled Caste man, who had initially supported the pradhan and campaigned on his behalf in the village, had heard that one needed a written petition of 20 residents to ask district officials for the removal of a pan chayat member. They drew up a statement asking for the removal of the pradhan due to corruption charges and at least two dozen villagers signed the document, before taking it to the Chief Development Officer’s office. There they were told that they needed a majority of the panchayat representatives to sign the complaint before it could officially be accepted – something they were unable to do because not enough representatives were willing to sign it. While the attempt to remove the pradhan in 2000 was ultimately not successful, it nevertheless represented a visible attempt of civic action that crossed social cleavages. Ironically, this same Scheduled Caste man was elected as pradhan of the Palanpur Gram Panchayat in 2005 (when the office of the pradhan was reserved for a person of SC background) and, according to more than a dozen different sources, was similarly pilfering the local government’s resources for the benefit of his extended family. While a civic action to remove this pradhan succeeded in 2010, incidents such as this furthered the perception among vil lagers that election to local government office was a new venue for self- enrichment and, in some cases, provision of kickbacks to others within the candidate’s respective caste or religious community.11 At the same time there were a few other instances of benevolent civic interaction in these villages. In one instance a former teacher’s mobilization of villagers facilitated a meeting with the pradhani (female pradhan) to discuss the construction of a new pri mary school in the village. In another instance, when the drainage in one dirt road alley of the village became particularly bad, people living along that alley
Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power 153 got the panchayat to allocate some money towards its cleaning and they came up with the funds to build a drainage system. These three instances were, how ever, among the few examples of collective action by villagers towards their panchayats between 2000 and 2011. Despite high voter participation rates in the Gram Panchayat elections and despite high hopes and expectations among the inhabitants of Palanpur and Pipli, the survey responses and follow-up interviews indicate that there was little knowledge of the functioning of the panchayat system among the villagers, infrequent contact between the members and their constituents, and a low level of agency among villagers with regard to protesting or supporting Gram Pancha yat actions. Several key informants in 2000 and in 2007/2008 indicated that there was little information available on the resources available to the panchayats or what kinds of assistance different groups of indigent were eligible for. Without transparency on the functioning of the Gram Panchayat and on the resources available to it for different programs, it was difficult for people to know how to inquire, protest, or support panchayat members. Yet, detailed knowledge of the panchayat and its workings were not required to judge whether the Gram Panchayat had played a role in delivering key government-financed programs. While the majority of key informants in 2000 and again in 2007/2008 did not know that Gram Panchayats were vested with the responsibility of implementing all government-financed social and anti- poverty programs, most appeared to have a general sense that the Gram Pancha yat was meant to be “somehow” involved in the process and whether they had in fact been involved. Yet when asked whether there were functioning anti-poverty programs in the village, only 19 out of 80 survey respondents (24 percent) stated that there were such programs in the village and of those 19 only 5 (26 percent) thought that their Gram Panchayats were responsible for targeting and delivering those anti-poverty programs. Similarly, only 16 of the survey respondents (20 percent) stated that there were functioning social welfare programs in the village. Moreover, only 21 out of 80 survey respondents (26 percent) thought that the Gram Panchayat had been involved in delivering any of the most important social and infrastructure needs of the village.12 In fact one panchayat member in Palanpur stated that she thought government was no more effective now than earlier – thereby implicating herself. While a lower number of survey respond ents from Palanpur thought that the GP was involved in addressing these needs than from Pipli (6 versus 15), such a divergence in perception of survey respond ents was not found on other questions relating to service delivery. Moreover, responses from key informants and focus group discussions in 2007/2008 yielded a similarly dismal picture of the delivery of social programs through the Gram Panchayat of both villages. Overall, the majority of the villagers questioned in the 2000 survey, and in focus group meetings and key informant interviews in 2000 and 2007/2008, thought that most anti-poverty and social projects were not functioning in their village and a majority believed that their Gram Panchayat was not active in implementing such projects. In contrast to the time before the implementation of
154 Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power the 1994 UP Constitutional Amendment Act when the disbursement of funds for most social programs rested with bureaucrats such as the block development officer, key informant interviews in 2000 and again in 2007/2008 found that there was a general sense that some funds now went to the Gram Panchayat for disbursement. Even those residents of Palanpur and Pipli who were not part of the literate social elite, and were not aware of how exactly the panchayat func tioned, knew that after 1995 most of the funds for social programs came to the Gram Panchayat. They knew who was responsible for implementing various developmental programs and disbursing the funds to the intended beneficiaries. Villagers knew whom they could praise or blame for the implementation of rural development programs, or the lack thereof.
Changes in accountability? The accountability of the Gram Panchayats in these villages was low. By spring of 2000, Uttar Pradesh had held only one round of local panchayat elections, with two further elections by the spring of 2008. Focus group sessions in 2000 and 2008 yielded similar information: informants stated that they knew that their panchayat representative and their pradhan in particular had not disbursed the developmental funds that they were supposed to. Many stated that they were not going to vote for these members. A few informants in both villages also stated that the members knew that they were not performing their job properly and that they would not be reelected. As a result, the members had even less incentive to perform effectively and more incentive to enrich themselves while they could. Several informants in 2008 pointed out that very few Gram Panchayat seats at any one election were not reserved for a person of a particular gender or caste background. Moreover, they explained that due to the rotational system of reserved seats, where the powerful position of the pradhan was rotated amongst people of different caste and gender at each local government election, the indi vidual elected as pradhan was unlikely to be able to run for reelection – no matter what her or his record might be. Individuals elected to that office know this and in the elections in 1995, 2000, and 2005 enriched themselves and their family members. The perception of disadvantages to the system of reserved seats was also shared by illiterate and lower-caste members in both villages in 2008 and indicates a perception that there are built-in disincentives in the GP structure for those representatives who might otherwise be interested in doing a good job in order to get reelected. These perceptions mirror the local history of the GP leaders. In both these villages where for the first time a female pradhan and a pradhan from an OBC background were elected in the 1995 election, both prad hans were corrupt in 2000. As seen in Table 5.2, a large portion of central gov ernment funds, which had been released to the local panchayats for several social programs, did not reach the intended beneficiaries. Stories of the extent of the pradhan’s corruption in 2000, particularly in Palanpur, abounded in formal inter views as well and individual discussions and focus-group meetings. The same responses were given about the pradhan in 2008 in both villages. A system that
10,000 10,000 N/A N/A N/A N/A
10,000 10,000 13,500 (9 × 1,500) 10,000 12,000 (2 × 6,000) 10,000
Support for pregnant women (Rs.500 for each pregnant woman below Funds released the poverty line) Funds received c Funds released Funds received c Funds released Funds received c
Old age pension for indigent people (Rs.1,500 for each person above 60 years of age living below the poverty line)
Money for marriage of daughter (Rs.6,000 for families living below the poverty line and where there is no father)
Notes a From the 10th Finance Commission, JRY, and the State Finance Commission b For SC/ST households only c Funds received by eligible beneficiaries.
Sources: From the Chandausi Block Development Office Records and Moradabad District Welfare Office Records, 2000. Figures cross-checked at village level.
10,000 10,000
10,000 10,000
Funds released Funds received c
Birth of female baby to parents below poverty line (Rs.500 for each female child)
Pipli 84,146 Approx. 55,000
Funds released Funds received c
General fundingsa for roads, drainage, school building repairsa, grain storageb, and household handpumpsb
Palanpur 61,365 Approx. 20,000
Funds (rupees)
Type of social program
Table 5.2 Funds released versus received for selected programs for Palanpur and Pipli, Chandausi Block, Uttar Pradesh, 2000 (rupees)
156 Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power was designed as a system of affirmative action for disadvantaged groups has had the negative impact of lowering incentives for accountability. Reserving the positions of the local government head for women or people of lower caste back grounds had not changed the main structures of accountability or reduced cor ruption. Moreover, in contrast to the findings from the village studies in Karnataka and West Bengal, findings from these village studies in UP yielded a perception that reserving local government seats by caste in an environment of strong caste cleavages resulted in GP members appropriating GP funds for them selves or channeling funds to their respective religious or caste groups. Corruption in the Gram Panchayats of both villages appeared pervasive through the early part of the twenty-first century, particularly among the heads of the local governments. However, what has changed in these local govern ments is that the people formerly excluded from patronage and kickbacks were now, through the reservation system, able to partake in the corruption. Towards the end of a long interview in the fields of Palanpur in 2000 with an illiterate female Muslim Gram Panchayat member about the lack of social funds reaching the target audience, the interviewee stopped her work of making cow-dung patties and exasperatedly stated “The upper-class men of this village and upper levels of government have been eating up the government money for centuries. So what if I now take my share too?” Similar comments in 2008 from several informants of SC background about the corrupt GP pradhan of SC background yielded the perception that while levels of corruption continued to remain high the reservation of local government seats has led to a “democratization of local government corruption” in these UP villages since 1993. Most of the villagers surveyed in 2000 were unsure if corrupt Gram Pancha yat members under the new panchayat system were more likely to be held accountable than under the previous panchayat system. In 2000 the vast majority of survey respondents in both villages thought that accountability of the pancha yat members had not changed or were unsure whether it had changed when com paring the new system to the pre-73rd Amendment system, with only seven out of 80 respondents (9 percent) thinking that Gram Panchayat members were more likely to be held accountable under the new system. When key informants were asked in 2000 why panchayat members were not held accountable under the new system, they recounted the instance where a group of people tried unsuccessfully to have the pradhan of Palanpur removed. Focus group discussions and interviews with key informants in 2007/2008 yielded similar responses. Key informants cited the corrupt pradhan in 2007 and the previous corrupt pradhan, indicating that there was no system for directly holding panchayat members, and the pradhan in particular, accountable. The only “tool” available to citizens for rewarding or punishing the members was their vote at election time, and even that was usually limited in the case of the election of the pradhan due to that position being reserved for people of different backgrounds on an rotational basis. The procedures put in place by the UP Con stitutional Amendment Act to remove a pradhan required a high percentage of panchayat members to sign a petition, something many were unwilling to do.
Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power 157 Other than trying to remove the pradhan or waiting until the next elections, the voters have no way of ensuring accountability. Moreover, there is no legal requirement for panchayat members to report the panchayat’s budget expendi tures to the village community in a systematic way. The Gram Sabha, the village council meetings which the UP Act states should be called by the pradhan twice a year to consider development programs, accounts and audit reports, programs for adult education, mobilization of voluntary labor, and identification of benefi ciaries for government-funded social programs, rarely took place in 2000 and almost never took place by 2008. Focus group meetings yielded that there was no disclosure of Gram Panchayat accounts at any Gram Sabha meetings and vil lagers did not know how to get definitive information about resources allocated to their village. With no required, regular mechanism for informing villagers of panchayat finances, villagers have no concrete proof of corruption, just hearsay and suspicions. The lack of meetings added to government dysfunction and inability to hold panchayat members accountable. On the other hand, villagers knew under the post-1993 system who was involved in the corruption. Under the earlier system, villagers also knew that corruption took place, but they could only assume that the bureaucrats involved in delivering services to their village were corrupt and that perhaps some of the “village elders” who constituted the Gram Panchayat were involved in malfea sance. Under the new panchayat system, most villagers were aware that many development funds came directly to the village pradhan and that if the funds did not reach the beneficiaries, then their own representatives, people who were their neighbors and community members, were to blame. While this meant a growth in the number of people engaged in corruption, it also suggested that even the poorest and least educated villager was now able to put a face to the corruption. The dispersion of power to Gram Panchayats had led to an increase of the number of people with influence to peddle; it had also given a face to those involved in corrupt practices. Overall, the survey results, along with the focus group discussions and key informant interviews in 2000, revealed that many hoped the new Gram Pancha yat system would improve their social welfare, through the direct election of panchayat representatives from different caste, class, and gender backgrounds. They had also hoped to improve their welfare through increased accountability in delivering social programs. Few key informants knew exactly how the pan chayat was going to be structured or what their rights were with regard to the Gram Panchayat. But they did know what the Gram Panchayat was supposed to do and that representatives of all different communities were now elected as local government members. By 2008 the villagers were even less optimistic about the ability of the GP to help improve their lives. Key informant interviews and focus group discussions found that villagers had seen what the Gram Panchayat had done or had failed to do since 1995. Disillusionment with the various pradhans in Palanpur and the failure of an effort to remove the pradhan in 1999 meant that many villagers were not sure that the new system was much different from the previous panchayat
158 Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power system. The structure of the panchayat system, with the regularity of elections and formerly excluded groups accessing panchayat positions, had changed. The overall sense that leaders were corrupt and that the system was unable to deliver social programs remained largely unchanged.
Quality of governance The environment in which local governments operate was assessed by several Indian government officials as being a key issue in determining the effective implementation of central government funded anti-poverty and social development programs.13 A measure of participation under the new system was people’s own perception of whether they were more likely to be heard by the new Gram Panchayat. When asked this question in 2000, 18 of the 80 survey respondents in Palanpur and Pipli (23 percent) replied that, if they directed a question or complaint to the village Gram Panchayat, they felt that their voice was more likely to be heard today than before the implementation of the new panchayat system. Five years after the first Gram Panchayat elections under the new local government system, the vast majority of survey respondents in both villages thought that there was no difference between the likelihood of being heard under the previous Gram Panchayat system versus the new system. This widespread perception of the local government system not making a large differ ence in whether an individual was going to be heard by the local government continued through 2007/2008 as evidenced by focus group discussions and key informant interviews. At the same time the attempt to remove the Palanpur pradhan in 2000 was an indication of increased awareness and hope among some villagers that the new system had created the possibility of their voice being heard. While the failure to remove the pradhan left some of those involved feeling despondent about their ability to affect change under the new system, others involved noted that the very process of trying to have a pradhan removed was unthinkable under the previous system. Having a local government system in place where villagers could attempt to remove the pradhan meant an increasing awareness of among villagers of their rights and abilities under the new system, even if this had not translated into a perception of increased voice. Resorting to petition-signing in order to attempt removal of the Palanpur pradhan was an indication of the belief that under the new system there might be legal alternatives to unconstitutional or even violent means of local government change. The fact that Gram Panchayat members are now elected, and might not be reelected, contributed to an increasing awareness that under the new system one had the ability to peacefully select and replace those in power at the local level. Most villagers understood that the days where the same families domi nated local government are on the wane, particularly because an institutional mechanism for changing the people at the helm of local governments now exists, even if in practice it is still difficult to do. At the same time, examples of attempts to hold local government representatives accountable were few,
Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power 159 combined with a widespread perception that there were few mechanisms for holding local governments accountable. Accountability of civil servants also did not appear to have improved with the advent of the new Gram Panchayat system. Feedback from several villagers and observation of the work of civil servants in the village in 2000 and 2007/2008 indicated that the Gram Panchayat had not used its powers to enhance account ability of these civil servants. For example, the targeted Public Distribution System (PDS) is supposed to ensure food security through monthly distribution of goods at a subsidized cost to indigent people, as well as several other related programs. In Palanpur and Pipli, however, the distributors of PDS goods in 2000 as well as in 2008 only came a few times a year and did not even distribute a fraction of what they were supposed to. Similarly, the “Anganwadi worker” (female health worker for a village) was not performing her duties in either one of the villages in 2000 or 2008. None of the people interviewed had heard of the worker distributing vitamin biscuits as part of a post-natal care program spon sored by the government.14 Moreover, the “Midday Meals Scheme” which was to provide free lunch to all children attending elementary school was rarely func tioning in 2008. Civil servants were not performing their duties in these villages and yet the Gram Panchayats had made no attempt to call them to account for their performance. Another aspect of the quality of local governance, and thereby its capacity to improve wellbeing, is its effectiveness – its ability to plan and implement sound policies. This includes the ability of the local government to implement pro grams entrusted to it by the central and state governments, to devise and imple ment its own policies, and to interact with and oversee the local implementation of social programs by civil servants. The ability to implement policies also includes an awareness of regulatory quality – the perception by the villagers of whether local government and its policies have led to a decrease in regulatory burden, thereby improving access to government programs and the bureaucrats responsible for implementing them. Survey respondents were asked whether they thought that the administrative burden they faced when they needed to obtain services or goods from the gov ernment in 2000 had decreased since the implementation of the new panchayat system. Again, only 10 out of 80 respondents (13 percent) thought that the administrative burden had decreased since the election of the new Gram Pancha yat. Excluding responses from panchayat representatives and their immediate families, there was only one respondent who thought that the administrative burden had improved. For the vast majority of villagers, having an elected local government that often included local government representatives who were from their own caste, class, or gender background, did not translate into less bureau cracy in their daily lives. Focus group discussions and key informant interviews in 2000 as well as 2007/2008 yielded similar results. On the whole, Gram Panchayat effectiveness and ability to ease the adminis trative burden faced by villagers in their interactions with government officials did not improve with the implementation of the new local government system.
160 Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power When asked in focus group discussions why this was the case, villagers replied that panchayat members did not have any incentive to be effective in their imple mentation of policies and in their oversight with civil servants. Despite a provi sion in the 73rd Constitutional Amendment that encourages the formation of committees in order to help Gram Panchayats perform their social development duties, not a single committee had been formed in either village. This lack of panchayat oversight of social service delivery meant that there was no enforce ment mechanism to ensure the performance of civil servants. Similarly, pancha yat members themselves had no incentive to perform since, other than their reelection and a distant possibility of removal by panchayat majority consensus, there was no mechanism for oversight and accountability. Two female panchayat members from Palanpur stated in 2000, and three members from each of both villages stated in 2007/2008, that it was very diffi cult for them to find out the exact amount of funds received by the pradhan for various programs, let alone try to enforce service provision by civil servants. They indicated that there was little communication amongst Gram Panchayat members on what their rights and obligations were. They also stated that there was a general sense that committees were not set up because the panchayat had no enforcement mechanism vis-à-vis the bureaucracy. In neither Palanpur nor Pipli were there mechanisms and incentives to ensure local government effect iveness or quality service delivery by civil servants. Villagers, however, placed some of the blame for lack of improvements in governance on the representatives themselves. In particular, when the small- scale survey respondents were asked in the 2000 whether there was a change in violence, rule of law, and corruption, since the implementation of the new pan chayat system, few gave positive answers. Only ten of the 80 survey respondents in 2000 (13 percent) believed that there was less general violence in their village; 12 out of 80 (15 percent) believed that there had been an improvement in the rule of law; 10 (13 percent) believed that there had been an improvement in the administrative burden they faced; 7 (9 percent) believed that accountability had improved; and only two out of 80 (3 percent) believed that corruption had decreased. Several focus group discussions on the issue of governance in 2000 (3 percent) as well as in 2007/2008 confirmed a widespread view that govern ance throughout the 1990s and up through 2008 had not improved. Significantly, only two of the small-scale survey respondents in 2000 believed that any improvements in governance had been achieved through the panchayat system. In fact the opposite was true: four respondents shared that the Gram Panchayat might have been responsible for an increase in corruption and decrease in the rule of law, even though this was not a direct question asked by the survey.15 Corruption and poor governance have been widespread and there have been well-documented problems in Uttar Pradesh (Mishra 1997). Yet with decentrali zation of power and responsibility for implementation of rural development pro grams to the village level, the ability to organize sub-committees under the Gram Panchayat to oversee the functioning of social services in the village, and with some financial resources available to accomplish these tasks, there was hope that
Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power 161 increased local oversight would improve governance. Several villagers indicated that they had shared these hopes. However, as seen in the above sections, this was not the case. For the most part, villagers did not experience an increase in voice, government effectiveness, regulation, rule of law or corruption in their village. In addition to the survey responses in 2000, several individual accounts in 2000 and 2007/2008 corroborated that corruption was still rampant and the overall quality of governance low. Information obtained in 2000 from the Block Development Office (BDO) in Chandausi, UP, showed that in 2000, the Palan pur Gram Panchayat had distributed – on paper – 500 rupees to each of 20 preg nant women who were living below the poverty line and to 20 families below the poverty line who had had a female baby born within the last year.16 Yet only one of the six pregnant or recently pregnant women questioned had received 100 rupees through the pradhan and none of the five families questioned who had had a female baby born in the past year had received any money. Of the funds allocated towards beneficiaries under four specific social programs at the block level, virtually none had reached the beneficiaries through the Gram Panchayat in 2000. The Gram Panchayat was party to the corruption in the system. Further more, there were indications that bribery was not only rampant at the Gram Pan chayat level, but also at the block level and above.17 Follow-up interviews with people listed as social welfare program recipients at the block level in 2007/2008 yielded similar results. Overall, the evidence indicates that implementation of the new Gram Pancha yat government in Uttar Pradesh and subsequent election of Gram Panchayats in Palanpur and Pipli did not change the real incentive structure. People who for merly were excluded from the realms of village government were elected as Gram Panchayat representatives. Yet without functioning village assemblies, sub-committees to oversee social service delivery, or Gram Panchayat meetings, and without a system that provided transparent accounting of receipts and expen ditures by the Gram Panchayat to the villagers, there was no credible threat to panchayat members to dissuade them from partaking in the system of corruption. Similar to the findings in West Bengal and in contrast to the village findings in Karnataka, local governments in these villages of UP were unlikely to be held accountable for pilfering of social funds intended for the indigent and there are no mechanisms in place for the village population to gain information on the flow of public funds to the village in order to hold their local representatives accountable.
Enduring social inequality What is striking when comparing the social settings and interactions in the vil lages studied in UP with those of the villages studied in West Bengal and Karna taka is the lack of social change and the persistence of social cleavages. One of the main innovations of the new panchayat system in 1993 was the reservation of seats for women and people of SC/ST background, thereby providing them
162 Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power access to political and perhaps social power. In UP it was hoped that this reser vation system could enable women and SC/ST people to gain greater access to government and provide the basis for social change. However, in the two vil lages studied in UP, the panchayat reservation system has not provided a basis for social change. In Pipli the pradhan elected in 1995 was a women for the first time in village history, but she appeared to be in the position largely on paper. In 2000, most key informants stated that her late husband had been the pradhan and that her brother-in-law had now taken over the position. When she was inter viewed, her brother-in-law sat next to her and, since she was unable to, answered most of the detailed questions regarding the functioning of the Gram Panchayat and its budget receipts and allocations. In Palanpur informants who were of the same OBC caste background as the pradhan elected in 1995, attested that they had voted for him because they thought that he would advance their caste com munity’s cause, only to find that he was corrupt and intent on enriching himself and some of his kin. In both villages female Gram Panchayat members and members of scheduled caste background appeared to be members largely on paper. While some admitted to now also having access to the system of kick backs, these members have been largely unable to assert their rights as repre sentatives. Relationships between people of different castes, class, and gender continued to remain inequitable in Palanpur and Pipli through 2008. Social inequalities are so stark in this part of India that they are physically and geographically visible. When walking through Palanpur or Pipli one is struck by the narrow alleyways, bordered on both sides by high walls. Even the poorest resident of Palanpur, with an entire family living together in a one room, windowless mud hut, is protected by a mud wall and a small door demarcating the homestead from the alley and from the neighbors. When dusk falls on the village, families convene in their homes, behind closed doors, and seldom venture out into the darkness of the night. Rarely are large groups of children seen playing together at the few public spaces in the villages, and even more rarely do children of different social or religious backgrounds play together. Men are sometimes seen sitting on charpoys in front of their homes or in public places chatting with relatives, but rarely with people outside their caste, class, or gender. Women are usually only seen in groups at religious holidays or births, marriages, or deaths, but again, very rarely with women outside their caste, while women of upper castes continue to remain largely within the confines of their homes. These impressions are symptomatic of the structure of social interaction in Palanpur and Pipli. As amply documented elsewhere, the dominance of the upper castes in UP society has remained largely unchanged over the past decades (Kohli 1987; Hasan 1989, 2000; Hasan et al. 1989). Caste and class continue to be the dominant cleavages determining political and social interaction. Electoral campaigning by political parties that appeal to the ascriptive identity of caste and class has further cemented these social cleavages. That people should get together with relatives for holidays or at informal social occasions is not surpris ing. What is surprising is that this appears to be largely the only forum of social
Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power 163 interaction and that these forms of interaction in these villages are largely intra- caste instead of inter-caste gatherings. Observations from walking around the villages create an impression of people whose social interaction is largely limited to people from their own caste and class background. For example, access to drinking water is just as difficult for the poor Muslims who live on an alley in the southwestern part of Palanpur, as it is for the disadvantaged Jatabs, a group of scheduled castes living on the north ern edge of the village. Yet people from these two communities have not been able to bridge their religious–caste division and mobilize to ensure better drink ing water access, despite their obvious common need. It is this enduring struc ture of social cleavages despite the election of local governments, its perpetuation by the major political parties which have been elected over the past two decades in UP, and a lack of inter-caste and religious group based civil soci ety, which enable the traditional caste elite and new temporary local government elite to continue siphoning off local government funds. When individuals from both villages were asked in focus group sessions, and further discussions with key informants in 2000 and 2007/2008, whether they thought that the lack of informal and formal associations in the villages was in any way linked with Gram Panchayat functioning, none of the informants thought so. Inter-caste and inter-class interactions were so far removed from the daily lives of most villagers that the idea that their structure of social interactions might be related to their social wellbeing had not occurred to them. None saw a direct link between the ingrained social cleavages and the failure of the Gram Panchayat to help improve their wellbeing. The rigid social structure in Palanpur and Pipli is mirrored in the many needs for collective action and the very few instances where such action takes place. Collective action occurs when people of different backgrounds come together for the purpose of accomplishing something for the good of all involved and sometimes even the greater public good. There were only few examples of col lective action in either village. Before the implementation of the 73rd amend ment, the previous study of Palanpur illustrated that there was plenty of need but virtually no collective action (Lanjouw and Stern 1998). Since the implementa tion of the amendment in UP in the early 1990s, a few instances of collective action occurred, but they remain the exception rather than the rule. In one example, under the guidance of a local man but with support from several high- caste families, a private primary school was set up in Palanpur in 1997, yet by 2008 this school was disbanded. The public school in both villages had teachers who only come sporadically. Moreover, despite over one hundred children being enrolled at each school, on any given day no more than a dozen children are actually to be found. In contrast, the private school teachers came every day during the field research stay in 2000 and at least three-dozen children usually attend, dressed in uniforms and with school supplies. While the teaching methods at the private school certainly could have been improved, the school functioned every day until mid-2007. On the other hand, since parents had to pay tuition in addition to uniform and school supply costs, only the children of
164 Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power better-off families were able attend the private school. Initially the private school seemed open to all until the upper-caste families exerted pressure until a teacher who was a Scheduled Caste member was dismissed from the school. Further more, no Muslim children attended the private school, Hindu religion was taught at the school, and Hindu festivals were celebrated there. What initially appeared as a collective action for the greater good of providing functioning primary edu cation for all children, turned out to be a school for middle- and upper-caste Hindu children. In another example, after years of unsuccessfully trying to tap into a main electrical grid line running close to the village, several affluent families in Palan pur contributed to a pool of money that was used to officially pay for an electric ity line to the village. At the end of 1998 electricity finally arrived at the village and those families who had contributed money towards the fund for the electric ity line could now avail themselves of electricity. Electricity could have been brought to the village many years ago but in previous years there was little sense that this kind of collective action was possible. A third example of recent col lective action was the 1999 incident mentioned earlier where, after frustration with how corrupt the pradhan had been over the last years, a group of young village men collected signatures on a petition to have the pradhan removed by district-level officials. Muslims and Hindus, Scheduled Caste members as well as a few upper castes signed the initial petition. While this action was ultimately unsuccessful, it was the clearest example of villagers overcoming their caste dif ferences in order to perform an action they believed would benefit the entire village. Organizations that could help bridge the tremendous social inequality and lack of trust between groups, including local governments, do not function suffi ciently in the villages of Palanpur and Pipli. Social interaction generally still occurs along the exclusionary lines of caste, class, and gender. Despite ample opportunities for participating in collective action that would benefit all, few vil lagers do in fact participate. While villagers admit that, for example, the lack of a drainage system in the village creates difficulties for all villagers trying to walk anywhere in the village during the monsoon season, none sees the feasibility of getting even the people living in their alley to cooperate in order to dig a drain age system. With only a few examples of successful cooperation among villag ers, most villagers do not even try to initiate collective actions. In both the villages studied in UP, the villagers were caught in a vicious cycle of lack of trust and rare examples of cooperation reinforcing non-cooperation in the villages. Moreover, none of the villagers surveyed in 2000 or interviewed in 2000 and 2007/2008 saw any relationship between social cleavages, the presence of the new Gram Panchayat, and their social welfare. Having a Gram Panchayat that is largely perceived as not functioning as mandated by law, ineffective at the work with which it is charged, and lacking governance, has not provided the cit izens of Palanpur and Pipli with an example of how collective action by elected officials could help improve their welfare or provide a forum for organizing col lective action. In addition, the electoral campaigning for GP elections by parties
Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power 165 that largely appealed to the ascriptive identity of caste furthered these social cleavages. The hope that local governments would provide an avenue for helping to decrease social inequalities through increased interaction and collective action among groups of differing social backgrounds has not materialized in the case of Palanpur and Pipli in Uttar Pradesh. However, the prognosis is not entirely bleak. The one incident where a couple of young men of different caste back grounds collected signatures for a petition to have the pradhan of Palanpur removed gives some hope. Tenuous as these links between Gram Panchayat, social cleavages, and improved social welfare might be, this incident helped increase awareness among those who participated, and in the village in general, of the possibilities and pitfalls of collective action. It was a reminder that in order to succeed, these types of actions require broad-based support. It illustrated that there are legal, democratic, and nonviolent avenues for removing corrupt panchayat members, of which even the least educated and lowest-caste villager can avail him or herself. It also demonstrated that by reaching across religious, caste, and gender cleavages, one could potentially accomplish goals that would not be possible in smaller groups. The experience taught the participants about democracy in action and increased their awareness of their rights and potential to use these rights to effect change. It was an example of increased awareness of rights being used to question established patterns of corruption and domination. In doing so, it provided hope to some villagers that growing awareness of their rights would enable villagers to press panchayat members to implement social programs more effectively and thus help improve social welfare of the villagers. However, even these weak hopes were largely dashed by 2008 when three GP elections had taken place without changes in the GP’s delivery of social welfare programs and a continuously abysmal rate of social service delivery in these villages.
Slowly improving social wellbeing – no thanks to the Gram Panchayats Between 1993 and 2011 the overall social wellbeing of Palanpur and Pipli resi dents improved slightly, largely due to new economic opportunities. There was overwhelming consensus among respondents that local governments had not helped in any way to deliver social services that would have improved their social wellbeing. These findings are mirrored in the previous study of Palanpur which documented a few improvements seen in 1997, such as the new private school and a better functioning government school, yet found that overall there was little indication of improved welfare (Lanjouw and Stern 1998). However, by most villagers’ accounts, residents of Palanpur and Pipli were slightly better off in 2008 compared to 1995 – before the election of the new Gram Panchayat. When asked in the 2000 survey whether their overall wellbeing – in terms of such tangibles as the health and education services they can afford, the food they eat, and the housing they can afford – was better in 2000 than in the early 1990s,
166 Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power 50 out of 80 surveyed (63 percent) said that they were better off due to the better quality of their housing, better and greater variety of educational facilities, the arrival of electricity in Palanpur, more hand-pumps for accessing drinking water, and better quality and variety of food in both villages. These views were sup ported by interviews with key informants and focus group discussions in 2000 and again in 2007/2008. Yet while most citizens of Palanpur and Pipli perceived themselves as being better off, only two out of 80 survey respondents in 2000 (3 percent) thought that the Gram Panchayat contributed in any direct or measurable way to their change in wellbeing. The rest, 78 out of 80 survey respondents (98 percent), including Gram Panchayat members themselves, did not think that the Gram Panchayat had helped improve their lives, or were not sure. Almost all the key informants in 2000 and again in 2007/2008 stated that if there had been a change in their wellbeing, it was entirely due to their own work and their own fortunes or misfortunes. While there is some indication of social welfare improvements in Palanpur and Pipli, the progress has not been great nor nearly what it could have been had the government’s social programs functioned in the manner intended. Government-provided health services were virtually non-existent. The in-village Anganwadi (female health care worker) did not provide services in either village, government immunization programs in the villages were sporadic, and referrals to government health care services, such as the anti-malaria and TB programs, were non-existent. Untrained private “doctors” provided health care and the tra ditional village midwife did not use any sterilization methods during deliveries. The public distribution system delivered only a few of the goods and then for only about a fourth of the time it was scheduled to deliver. The public education program was doing little to teach children in either village, had high teacher absenteeism, and a low attendance rate. Moreover, the government’s Midday Meals Scheme for children at public primary schools was also essentially defunct in 2007/2008.18 Most of the public programs aimed at protecting and improving the lives of indigent citizens were not functioning. The responsibility for overseeing the implementation and efficiency of these programs rested with the Gram Panchayat, which was blamed by the villagers for non-delivery of these services. It is this lack of tangible improvement in the delivery of social services meant for the poor of Palanpur and Pipli’s that is the local Gram Panchayat’s biggest failure. There was no perceived difference between the implementation of development projects before versus after the institutionalization of the new Gram Panchayats in both villages. While the local presence of those responsible for project implementation in the aftermath of the 1995 elections made the absence of functioning social development projects more noticeable, this did not affect survey respondents’, key informants’, or focus groups’ perceptions – most pro jects were simply not implemented before or after 1993. Contrary to what one might expect, the few programs that were sporadically functioning were no more focused on beneficiary needs than they were prior to elections. The types of pro jects implemented, for example under the former Integrated Rural Development
Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power 167 Program (IRDP), did not change in nature, similarly to what was found by other case studies in UP (Crook and Manor 1998) and in contrast to the village studies in Karnataka. The stagnation in social development projects in these villages occurred despite a real increase in funding for many of these programs at the national level and slight increased allocations for the villages at the district and block levels. Development funds continued to be pocketed by government and local officials before and after the implementation of the new panchayat system.
The vicious circle of nonfunctioning local governments and stagnating wellbeing Nearly two decades after the passage of the Panchayat Raj Amendment and 16 years after the first constitutionally mandated Gram Panchayat elections were held in Uttar Pradesh, there is little indication that the Gram Panchayats have helped to improve social wellbeing in Palanpur and Pipli. Stark social cleavages and an environment where political parties appeal to caste and religious identi ties have made for local elections, which – though competitive because elections are contested by multiple parties and multiple individuals running for the same seat – reinforce caste and religious cleavages (Pai 2001). A local government seat won in the villages is used as a mechanism for enriching the elected repre sentatives and their caste or religious constituents, hampering the targeted deliv ery of social services in these communities. Popular participation in local elections continued to remain high, but there were indications of fraud in the selection of the pradhan, and once elected, democratic GPs were essentially defunct in both villages. The village councils (Gram Sabhas) and GP meetings rarely took place. Most panchayat members were unaware of Gram Panchayat budgets or allocations and none had convened any of the social development committees they were urged to do by law. While groups formerly excluded from the realm of local government now had panchayat seats reserved for them and thereby gained access to the domain of local power, these newly included groups did not wield any real power. In some instances they gained access to the kick backs within the system, but formally they did not participate in the management of local government in any democratic sense. The already low quality of governance was essentially unchanged among local government representatives as well as civil servants delivering social ser vices to the villages. From public school teachers to village health workers and distributors of PDS goods, no one became more accountable as a result of the elected Gram Panchayat. Virtually no associational activity or examples of col lective action existed in these villages before the election of the new Gram Pan chayats and this did not change after the elections. When survey respondents were asked if there were associations in the village where people of different caste and religious backgrounds would meet, none of the 80 respondents answered affirmatively. The lack of associations that could have provided a meeting forum for villagers of different caste backgrounds meant that there was little interaction between members of different religious groups or caste
168 Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power backgrounds, even if they had common socioeconomic interests. Political parties did not have any village-level presence in either village studied. Moreover, the absence of associations in these UP villages in addition to the deep and persist ent social cleavages meant there were no coalitions that formed around social welfare issues, which could have provided a check against the dominance of tra ditional upper-caste village elites. While women and people of SC/ST background in Palanpur and Pipli can now participate in local government that was formerly the realm of the upper castes, there is little evidence that this access to positions of power has changed the dynamics of power and corruption or general social interactions in the village. There is no indication that Gram Panchayats have improved social infra structure or implementation of social programs. Moreover, since the findings in these two villages in western UP mirror findings about the overall functioning of local governments in UP (Lieten and Srivastava 1999), there is little hope that the mere existence of Gram Panchayats will improve social wellbeing in this part of India. A clear lesson which emerges from these village studies is that mandating the election and formation of local governments per se does not lead to improved social wellbeing, particularly not when it takes place in an environment of deep social cleavages, political parties and social mobilization along religious and caste lines rather than across social cleavages. In this environment there is no sociopolitical counterweight to traditional and newly emerging village elites such as local government leaders. Without structural, social or political incen tives to cooperate with elected local governments, the village elite continued to dominate public resource allocation and pilfer public funds. Even having a pro gressive composition of local government representatives through the implemen tation of quotas, does not by itself led to improved social indicators. As seen in Pipli and Palanpur, implementation of the 73rd Amendment has changed the fea tures of local government, but not how it functions. Local governments in these villages are essentially nominal. They do not function in the democratic and par ticipatory manner mandated and have therefore do not lead to increasing social wellbeing. Moreover, in the traditional social environment of UP with enduring social cleavages and a civil society that is unlikely to hold the local government accountable, just mandating the elections of local governments at the village level, without commensurate awareness-raising of how the Gram Panchayats are to function and what their powers are, is unlikely to lead to local governments that are able to function and ensure better social wellbeing of the poorer villagers. However, while the overall findings are pessimistic regarding the ability of local governments to improve social welfare in these villages, even in such a highly inequitable and socially stagnant situation, there is nevertheless some indication that local governments may in the longer run contribute to general social welfare in a number of subtle ways. First, decentralization of power to local governments can help “root” democracy. The extent to which the imple mentation of the panchayat raj amendment results in the actual practice of local
Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power 169 democracy depends on existing social structures, the local village elites, and associational life in the village. Even in villages such as Palanpur and Pipli, with a highly structured caste and class system, no history of democratic local gov ernments, and little associational life, villagers turned out in record numbers to vote in the Gram Panchayat elections. For the first time, seats were reserved for women and members of SC/ST/OBC backgrounds. Groups often excluded from the realm of power now practiced democracy by voting and, at least nominally, by being Gram Panchayat members. Although participation by vulnerable groups is still far from ideal, the very process of selecting, campaigning, and voting for local representatives was democracy in action, as was the attempt to remove the pradhan. Ironically, cor ruption was “democratized” by providing social groups and women who had been formerly excluded from power, access to public funds previously pocketed by upper caste men. Leakages of funds from the anti-poverty and social policy programs were obviously taking place since many of the programs investigated were at best only minimally operational, yet some of these funds were now flowing into the pockets of local government officials who were formerly excluded from local power: women, Muslims, or people of OBC/SC/ST background. Second, while the new Gram Panchayat system has provided a base for improving accountability of local governments and local delivery of public ser vices, there were no responsible local governments in place in these villages in 2000 or 2007/2008. The findings indicate that local government’s ability to bring about improvements in social welfare in these UP villages is not evident. However, enforcing accountability of government and social services can best be accomplished by those who interact with these officials and by the beneficiar ies of these services. When residents of Palanpur and Pipli elected local govern ment representatives who were neighbors as well as members of their caste, gender, or religious group, they were able to “put a face” on government. When these members did not perform the duties they were elected to, or were dishon est, villagers knew who was involved in the corruption and who was to blame. Similarly, when the primary public school teacher did not come to school, when children did not get food through the Midday Meals Scheme, when goods were not distributed through the PDS system, or the village health care worker did not provide any health services, villagers knew, at a minimum, that the delivery of these public social services could have been improved by the Gram Panchayat. This slowly increasing awareness is the first step towards demanding greater accountability. One of the few examples of collective action in these villages – the petition to have the pradhan of Palanpur removed – failed, but attempting his removal would have been impossible before 1993. This was a small step taken towards increasing accountability Finally, the new local government system has started to change social inter actions among villagers living in a highly structured community, albeit very slowly. The reservation of seats in the new Gram Panchayat system gave often- excluded groups nominal access to a domain of power that was historically the
170 Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power realm of upper caste members. Voting for panchayat members who were of SC background, Muslims or women, even if they were only token representatives, provided younger people from disadvantaged backgrounds with new role models. Because the traditional elite now had to campaign for the vote of for merly excluded citizens and also had to vote for representatives who were from disadvantaged backgrounds, interactions are slowly changing between the tradi tional elite, the newly emerging elites in the form of GP members and the pradhan in particular, and members of disadvantaged communities. The tradi tional village elites can no longer regard village government as their inherited domain. Changing caste, class, and gender perceptions provide opportunities for collective mobilization and action. Very slowly, the groundwork for demo cratizing social interactions and thereby improving social welfare is being laid. Table 5.3 Uttar Pradesh: results of selected questions from sample survey in each village, 2000, numbers responding positively (percentages in parentheses)
Voted in last national elections Thought last national elections were fair Voted in last GP elections Thought last GP elections were fair Campaigned for the election of a GP member Knew the name of GP representative(s) Have participated in a meeting of the village electorate There are working social welfare programs in village GP is instrumental in delivering these social services There are working anti-poverty programs in village GP is instrumental in delivering these anti-poverty programs GP has been able to satisfy the most important needs in the village More voice under new GP system Less violence in 2000 compared to 1990 Rule of law has improved between 1990 and 2000 Government has become more effective Administrative burden has decreased Accountability has improved Corruption has decreased Was better off in 2000 compared to 1990 Of those who were better off, those who said they were better off due to the GP There are associations (bridging religion and caste) in this village Have participated in associations in last five years Have had any contact with their GP member Have contacted their GP representative for help in the last five years
Palanpur (n = 40)
Pipli (n = 40)
Total (n = 80)
34 20 40 28 9 26 11
36 21 38 30 4 25 13
70 (88%) 41 (51%) 78 (98%) 58 (73%) 13 (16%) 51 (64%) 24 (30%)
8 4 9 3
8 7 10 10
16 (20%) 11 (14%) 19 (24%) 13 (16%)
6
15
21 (26%)
6 7 7 2 3 2 0 25 2
12 3 5 2 7 5 2 25 0
18 (23%) 10 (13%) 12 (15%) 4 (5%) 10 (13%) 7 (9%) 2 (3%) 50 (63%) 2 (2%)
0
0
0 (0%)
0 6 7
0 10 13
0 (0%) 16 (20%) 20 (25%)
Uttar Pradesh – fractionalized power 171 Despite these few glimmers of hope, the overall lesson on decentralization in an environment of deep and enduring social cleavages is evident: Decentraliza tion of administrative and political power in settings such as those found in the villages of Uttar Palanpur and Pipli in Uttar Pradesh is unlikely to bring about better targeting and decreased corruption in the distribution of social programs in the short or even medium term. In this type of environment of locally domi nant groups and rigid social cleavages, it is only in the long term that the elec tion of village governments will be able to break through established patronage and power networks.
6 Political power, local governments, and social welfare
In India, the extension of democratic politics and electoral participation to village governments in 1993 broadened the scope and depth of Indian demo cracy. Village-level democratic structures rooted and flourished in some states of the country, engaging women and lower castes, delivering social services and anti-poverty programs to those in need, and contributing to the improved wellbe ing of their constituents. In other Indian states, however, the very same local government structure is only nominally democratic. In these states, socio economic or political elites capture services intended for the indigent while a disengaged civil society is unable to demand accountability from their local gov ernments. These differing depths of local governance in each Indian state are due to the unique state-level political soil in which each decentralized local govern ment structure has been planted. Some have a history of functioning local gov ernments, rich in bridging social cleavages, and politically competitive environments that in turn prevent the capture of public services by local elites, and a mobilized civil society that holds their government more accountable. Other states have less fertile soil for decentralization to grow. State-level factors determine the ability of local governments to thrive or not, and therefore need to be understood if we are to gain a holistic understanding of the barriers to effective decentralization and improved targeting of public ser vices. Sole reliance on top-down, central government-funded anti-poverty inter ventions alone will not help lift the masses out of poverty. India has a plethora of anti-poverty programs, public education, and health care initiatives, yet the actual amount of these programs reaching their intended beneficiaries is often quite low, with some studies finding that malpractice amongst local government administrators led to no more than 25 percent of the entitlement actually reach ing the poor (Nayak et al. 2002). Rajiv Gandhi, a former Indian prime minister, is supposed to have said that only 15 percent of public spending on the poor actually reached them, with the rest being siphoned off (Polgreen 2010). Targeting of resources to indigent groups is particularly low in states like Bihar and Uttar Pradesh and conventional explanations of differential economic growth or reformist state-level governments are insufficient for explaining diver gent social outcomes. Economic growth creates the resources for financing social welfare programs and there is some evidence showing that strong and pro-poor
Political power, local governments, social welfare 173 state governments have been more effective at implementing pro-poor policies (Kohli 1987). Yet in the longer term even a number of Indian states that have high growth rates, such as Uttaranchal between 2001 and 2005, or have pro-poor governments, such as West Bengal, have failed to ensure equitable and success ful implementation of social programs at the local level. Just having the resources and/or a pro-poor political orientation is not enough. What is needed in addition to an economic and politically advantageous environment are accountable local governments that are engaged in the targeted delivery of social services at the local level – the level where interventions matter for changing people’s lives. Decentralization advocates have heralded the devolution of powers to the local level as enabling more efficient implementation of local programs. It is this promise of decentralization’s ability to influence changes in indicators of social wellbeing – from poverty rates to education and health indicators – that lends urgency to research aimed at understanding the remaining barriers to effective local governments. India’s constitutionally mandated system of local govern ment, the panchayat system, was heralded as a means for furthering social well being. The 73rd Constitutional Amendment, which directed the uniform institutionalization of panchayats throughout the country, instructs: . . . devolution by the State Legislature of powers and responsibilities upon the Panchayats with respect to the preparation of plans for economic developments and social justice and for the implementation of development schemes . . . (Government of India 1992) Nearly two decades after the 1993 passage of the 73rd Amendment, this village- level research in three Indian states has provided evidence that local govern ments matter for improving wellbeing. As represented by Figure 6.1, having a politically competitive local environment, a mobilized civil society that is able to hold local governments accountable, and local elites who work within the demo cratic framework rather than coopting public benefits for themselves, are three factors crucial to the successful functioning of Gram Panchayats. When these sociopolitical elements are in place, local governments function according to their mandate. They are also able to better target anti-poverty programs and ensure the functioning of social programs such as health and education services at the village level, as seen in the study villages in Karnataka. Village studies in West Bengal, where elected local governments have been operating for over three decades, are particularly illustrative of the necessity of a politically com petitive environment for ensuring that social welfare programs reach the targeted audience. In the case of West Bengal, the new village elite are those who belong to the CPI(M) and other parties of the LFG, which has ruled the state since 1977. As seen in the villages studies in Uttar Pradesh, the absence of all these factors led to local governments which, although elected and inclusive of more social groups, were used as vehicles for self-enrichment of elected local officials.
174 Political power, local governments, social welfare These studies highlight that the nature of sociopolitical conditions under which local governments function matter to social wellbeing. When Gram Pan chayats function as the 73rd Constitutional Amendment intended, they enable better targeting and delivery of public services and this in turn leads to increased social wellbeing. This occurs through three overlapping paths. First, a function ing local government puts a “face” on governments, making contact with gov ernment and the bureaucracy more accessible and improving accountability and governance within local governments. Second, the process of having local elec tions, village-level meetings to determine beneficiaries of social welfare pro grams, and a functioning local government with its sub-committees on different aspects of village welfare, makes for a more representative local government. This government is more likely to target social welfare programs to those in greatest need if the local governments are not captured by local political, social or economic elites. Finally, a functioning local government helps to “root demo cracy” by increasing democratic behavior and democratic expectations, height ening awareness of individual rights and increasing the demand for and accessibility of social services.
Specific findings from the village studies How is the local Panchayat system perceived? By the mid-1990s panchayat elections had been held in all three case study states and by 2011 all case study states had held at least three panchayat elections. Voter turnout in the first round of elections was extremely high in all three states, as in the six villages studied. In West Bengal the population was accustomed to voting in regular panchayat elections and the turnout was slightly lower than in
Politically competitive local environment, including elections
Mobilized civil society
Local elites who are constrained by cleavagebridging political competition and an active civil society to “buy into” the local government system
Democratically functioning and accountable local governments
Improved social wellbeing
Figure 6.1 Factors that enable local governments to contribute to improved social wellbeing.
Political power, local governments, social welfare 175 the other two states, while in Karnataka the population had some experience with voting for local governments, yet nevertheless turned out in high numbers. The post-1993 elections were the first time in all three states that one-third of all panchayat seats were reserved for female representatives and a percentage of seats were reserved for SC/ST members. Many villagers who were not part of the village social or political elite and who had traditionally been excluded from positions of local power now had a chance to stand for election for the first time. The most frequent rationale given by interviewees and survey respondents for the extremely high turnout at the first local elections after adoption of the 73rd Amendment was that many were excited to directly elect their panchayat members. This was particularly the case in the two villages in Uttar Pradesh where voting in local elections for women or SC/ST was a novelty. Some informants genuinely hoped that having a panchayat representative from their own caste, religion, class, or gender would help improve their lives. When pressed further on how specifically they envisioned the election of Gram Pan chayat members improving their lives, the answers ranged from general hopes of better schools and primary health care provision in the village to specifics such as hoping to get the widow’s pension that they had not been receiving. Villagers explained that the excitement of being able to vote for female repre sentatives or representatives of their religious or caste community galvanized voters to turn out in large numbers. They believed that having people they know represent them and be their interlocutors with government officials in charge of dispensing social programs would gain them access to resources that they knew were being allocated to the village but either were not being distributed or were not being distributed to the correct demographic. Moreover, after more than six decades of functioning democracy, most informants perceived voting as a duty, even when people were sure that there was some fraud in the elections. In addition, local government elections in India are held in the respective vil lages or in a neighboring village, which increased election booth accessibility and decreased security concerns, furthering panchayat election turnout. Research at the block and district level for all three states yielded information that local elections in all six villages in the mid-1990s were peaceful. High voter turnout for Gram Panchayat elections in the mid-1990s is corroborated by other studies (Kumar and Ghosh 1996; Subha 1997). By 2011 the novelty of local government elections started to wear off, although electoral turnout for these elections remained about 60 percent in all three states. Electoral participation in local government elections still continued to be high, despite increasing disillusionment with the possibility that local gov ernment representatives would change their wellbeing, particularly in Uttar Pradesh and West Bengal. While at the turn of the century the vast majority of respondents in all case studies thought that the local elections had been fair, by 2007/2008 differential trends in perceptions of local government election fraud were found between the three states. In West Bengal in particular the majority of key informants interviewed in 2008 thought that the local elections had been rigged by local political elites.
176 Political power, local governments, social welfare In Karnataka most of those interviewed in 2008 responded with examples of the local government in action. Villagers in Karnataka saw their panchayat’s involvement in nutritious Midday Meals, the local health worker center that pro vided a crêche, and the microfinance programs that enabled a women’s group to start a rabbit- and poultry-raising business. By contrast, in the West Bengali vil lages those affiliated with the CPI(M) party were likely to dominate the local government and pass out benefits to people based on party affiliation rather than need. In private interviews, some informants even talked about their instrumen tal joining of the CPI(M) party, in order to access public resources, or fend off land seizure for redistribution. In sharp contrast to the uniformly high rates of voter participation in villages in all three states and the widespread sense of these elections being fair, a signi ficantly lower percentage of those interviewed were aware of their local pancha yat structure and its workings in 2000 and in 2007/2008. As expected, the understanding of local governments was highest in West Bengal and lowest in Uttar Pradesh. While many knew the name of their pradhan (head of local gov ernment) and the majority of the survey respondents in all six villages could name some of their panchayat members, the percentage of people attending village assembly meetings was low in all three states.1 Most respondents seemed unaware that these meetings were a requirement under the new panchayat law or that participation in the selection of beneficiaries for government-sponsored development programs was their right. The majority of respondents in all three states were also not aware that their Gram Panchayats were supposed to form committees on issues such as social justice, development and village edu cation. In Uttar Pradesh the majority of respondents were not aware of the law mandating these committees, while in West Bengal most respondents thought that these committees were something that the local Communist Party members organized. Interaction with panchayat members also differed by state. Most voters in the Uttar Pradesh villages did not have interactions with their own panchayat repre sentative, in contrast to voters in West Bengal and Karnataka. Of those people who contacted their representative for help, the majority of survey respondents in West Bengal and Karnataka expressed that they had received a response, again in contrast to Uttar Pradesh. However, in West Bengal many of the respondents thought that the speed and outcome of responses from local govern ment representatives were dependent upon whether or not the person asking for help was a Communist Party member. Civil society engagement also clearly differed by state, with villagers in Uttar Pradesh being least engaged in contacting, lobbying, or protesting actions of panchayat members, compared to villagers in West Bengal and in Karnataka, which by 2008 showed the most engagement of villagers with their local govern ments. Villagers in West Bengal and Karnataka also showed a greater under standing of the workings of local government, which was not the norm in the Uttar Pradesh villages. Moreover, while at the turn of the century there were a few examples of collective action detailed in the UP chapter, there were no such
Political power, local governments, social welfare 177 examples a decade later, providing less hope that the local government in UP would lead to social welfare improvements. The villages in the three states also differed greatly in terms of popular parti cipation in local governments. In West Bengal, which has had functioning Gram Panchayats for over two decades, the understanding of and interaction with local governments was highest, while it was lowest in Uttar Pradesh. Yet popular participation and responsiveness of local governments were not only a function of the length of their existence. Of those who did contact their local government representative for help, villagers in Karnataka were most likely to receive help regardless of their personal background or affiliation. By contrast, in West Bengal Communist Party membership influenced local government responsive ness and in Uttar Pradesh there was little interaction between the panchayat members and villagers and few distributed social benefits. Work done by Gram Panchayats In Uttar Pradesh the perception and evidence of work done by the Gram Pancha yats were minimal in 2000 and almost non-existent in 2008. This contrasts greatly with West Bengal and particularly Karnataka, where there is widespread evidence that Gram Panchayats are active in the delivery of social welfare program to the villagers. However, in the West Bengali villages there was a per vasive perception that Communist Party members were more likely to be program beneficiaries than the poor. In UP the lack of functioning local govern ments was evidenced everywhere, while in West Bengal follow-up with the recipients of social welfare projects showed not only clear linkages between those who were CPI(M) party members and project recipients but also that the project recipients, while poor, were not the neediest in the village. In Karnataka, by contrast, social welfare projects were functioning and targeted to the indigent with little evidence of any other sociopolitical group capturing these benefits. Moreover, unlike in the Uttar Pradesh and West Bengali villages, there was little evidence in the villages studied in Karnataka that GP representatives who were members of a particular social or political background had captured benefits. Whether local governments were functioning and were captured by local elites clearly mattered for the implementation and targeting of social welfare projects to the village indigent. Local government elections have helped increase a sense of inclusion in all three states studied. In all three states, no group had a sense of being excluded from the Gram Panchayat candidate selection and election process. This is par ticularly noteworthy since one would have expected the village elites (social elites in the Uttar Pradesh villages, political elites in the West Bengali villages and socioeconomic elites in the villages in Karnataka) to have been resentful of the encroachment on their traditional realm of power and therefore be more likely to be involved in fraudulent elections. The feedback from the villagers indicates that if the elections were unfair, the corruption was not due to village elites or a particular caste, but rather due to individuals keen on securing their
178 Political power, local governments, social welfare position in the local government or, in the case of West Bengal, the Communist Party using its well-established local patronage networks to retain power. The local government system had the most “democratizing” impact in Karnataka, where women and lower castes were actively participating in local governments. The overall changes in governance as a result of Gram Panchayats present mixed results. In Uttar Pradesh there has been little change in voice, accountabil ity, or political stability since 1993. In West Bengal the dominance of the Com munist Party with its commitment to poverty alleviation and local governance has shown tangible results in helping improve the voice of groups formerly disenfranchised. At the same time, the absolute power that the parties of the LFG wield in many areas of West Bengal after decades of setting up patronage net works at the village level, has resulted in panchayat members who are also party members and are perceived as being less accountable than non-party members. Another aspect of the quality of local governance, and thereby its capacity to improve wellbeing, is its ability to plan and implement sound policies. This includes the ability of local government to implement programs entrusted to it by the central and state governments, to devise and implement its own policies, and to interact with and oversee the local implementation of social programs by civil servants. Local government effectiveness, in terms of quality of services provided and the ability to do the things that they were mandated to do, did not change in the Uttar Pradesh or West Bengal villages, but improved in the Karna taka villages. The quality and frequency of social service delivery in Uttar Pradesh continued to be low in 2010. In West Bengal and Karnataka these same social programs are functioning, though only in Karnataka did they appear to have improved from the early 1990s. The absence of Gram Panchayat accountability and effectiveness in the two Uttar Pradesh and two West Bengali villages and their presence in the two Kar nataka villages can be largely traceable to the existence of enforcement measures and the level of political corruption in the system. The interviews conducted in the villages abound with examples of socioeconomic status (caste in particular) being associated with the degree of exemption under the law in Uttar Pradesh, while in West Bengal it is membership in a LFG party that correlated with the degree of exemption from the law. Social cleavages in UP remain strong, and caste cleavages particularly so. Similarly in the West Bengali villages, those who were CPI(M) members and part of the well-established political patronage network were more likely to receive social and material benefits through govern ment programs, get government jobs, and have criminal cases against them waived. Entrenched patronage networks, whether caste-based or political, meant that those who were part of that network were less likely to be subject to the rule of law. General quality of governance The overall quality of village governance differed greatly by state. In Uttar Pradesh, there were low levels of governance before the implementation of the
Political power, local governments, social welfare 179 73rd Amendment, along with persistent social cleavages and a political system that focused on patronage. Institutionalizing local governments in this environ ment did not result in an overall improvement in governance quality. There was a lack of transparency with regard to how Gram Panchayats functioned and little sense of institutional recourse to hold the panchayats accountable. Most respond ents did not experience an improvement in voice, government effectiveness, level of regulation, rule of law or corruption in their village. Information obtained at the block and district level in each of the states corroborated that leakages from anti-poverty programs were highest in UP. It was unclear whether most of these leakages of funds occurred at the state, district, block, or village level. All accounts, perceptions, anecdotal evidence, as well as specific findings from this and other studies (Lieten and Srivastava 1999; P. Srivastava 2002), show that the general quality of governance did not change in villages studied in UP as a result of the election of new local governments. In West Bengal there was a significant sense of increased voice, particularly among formerly disenfranchised groups throughout the 1990s. Local govern ments were seen as being effective and the regulatory burden appeared to have decreased over the past decades with functioning local governments. Nearly 30 years of working local government systems had changed the way villagers inter acted with government. Gram Panchayats were now usually the first stop for help on bureaucratic issues. However, Gram Panchayat members who were also CPI(M) members were often seen as being above the law by informants. Find ings in Karnataka show that there was no one group that was seen as being above the law or responsible for the change in corruption. By contrast, implementation of the new Gram Panchayat government in Uttar Pradesh and the subsequent election of local governments in the villages did not change the incentive structure to decrease corruption and implement social ser vices. But it did change the access to power. People who formerly were excluded from the realms of village government were elected as local government repre sentatives. Yet without functioning village assemblies, sub-committees to oversee social service delivery, or Gram Panchayat meetings, and without a system that provided transparent accounting of receipts and expenditures by the Gram Panchayat to the villagers, there was no credible threat to panchayat members to dissuade them from partaking in the system of corruption. In West Bengal over two decades of functioning Gram Panchayats has led to formerly disenfranchised groups becoming actively involved in local govern ments. Yet, the very same dominance of the Left Front Government for over three decades, which enabled a focus on poverty and other social programs, also meant a concentration of power. Increasingly this one-party rule means that local government members who are also LFG coalition party members are seen as being above the law and engaged in corrupt practices. In Karnataka the short but positive experience with local governments during the 1980s increased the per ception that village governments could bring about great change. Not only are the formerly disenfranchised included in the village government but they actively participate in the functioning of their local governments. Moreover,
180 Political power, local governments, social welfare competition among various groups in running the village governments also con tributes to an environment in which corruption is less likely to happen. Overall, the findings indicate that the presence of the new panchayat system at the local level did not deter panchayat members or citizens directly from engaging in corrupt practices. Corruption, practices that led to personal enrich ment or the enrichment of people affiliated with Gram Panchayat members by being members of the same familial or political background, did not disappear because there were locally elected governments in any of the three states. However, since local representatives were directly involved in management and distribution of social welfare programs, villagers could link a “face” to who is responsible for a certain program’s functioning, or lack thereof. ‘Putting this face’ on government and governance meant that praise as well as dissatisfaction with local government representatives could be channeled towards specific people, as in fact it was in a couple of instances in the villages studied in UP. Local government ability to cut across social cleavages Differential development and social interaction in the three states are also due to differing functioning of local governments and their ability to organize meeting fora that cut across social cleavages. There are two ways in which this can take place. One is through more institutionalized meeting space. Gram Panchayats are mandated to have meetings of the representatives to run the local government. In addition, sub-committees are supposed to be formed to more closely analyze how to improve various aspects of village life, and twice a year all villagers of voting age are supposed to gather to discuss priorities for the local government’s development agenda. In all three types of institutionalized meeting fora, groups of different caste, class, gender, and religion meet and work together. The other way in which greater interaction amongst people of different social backgrounds can take place is more informal, but the Gram Panchayat can also facilitate it. The very existence of local governments can lead to formations of social cleavage- bridging groups and aids the interactions among people of different backgrounds. In the Uttar Pradesh villages, where the panchayats themselves rarely met, sub-committees did not form and village-level meetings of the voting population rarely took place; there was no institutionalized meeting space that provided a forum for interaction that cut across social cleavages. The local governments also did not facilitate the creation of informal meeting space for people of differ ent backgrounds and examples of collective action across social groups were few. Established patterns of interaction were not broken and interactions among people of different caste, religion, gender, or class remained limited, resulting in less general understanding of poverty and social problems among the villagers and less resolve across groups to work collectively to improve general social welfare. Village civil society was also less likely to gather across caste divides to hold their local governments accountable. In West Bengal, Gram Panchayat and Sabha meetings took place regularly and most Gram Panchayat sub-committees were functioning. People of different
Political power, local governments, social welfare 181 socioeconomic backgrounds had venues for interacting across religious and caste divides, in turn encouraging more civic and democratic behavior, including a greater willingness to improve social welfare for all villagers. However, the increasing dominance of the LFG over the last decades and the associated increase in corruption and lack of accountability has eroded some of these gains. Groups who have not benefited as much as others and who continue to be amongst the poorest groups in the villages, such as the scheduled tribes in par ticular, continue to benefit less from social welfare programs. This has led to increased resentment, straining the more positive vehicles of cross-cleavage interaction and exacerbating political volatility and extremism. In both the vil lages studied in West Bengal, CPI(M) members dominated the local government with little political contestation in Gram Panchayat elections and a leakage of social welfare programs to CPI(M) members, who were not the poorest. These findings mirror similar findings in a recent quantitative study of local govern ments and the targeting of social welfare programs in West Bengal (Bardhan and Mokherjee 2006). In Karnataka, Gram Panchayat and Sabha meetings did take place. Villagers there had a brief recent history of well-functioning Gram Panchayats, which were able to accomplish many improvements in social welfare in the short time they were functioning during the 1980s (Crook and Manor 1998; Manor 2006). After implementing the new local government system in 1993, respondents expressed an awareness of the advantages of functioning local governments and institutionalized meetings that cut across social cleavages. The results from the villages studied in Karnataka differed notably from the findings in UP and West Bengal in that no one particular political or social group was seen as dispropor tionately reaping the gains from social welfare programs. In Karnataka, villagers attend village-level meetings without a sense that meeting outcomes were prede termined. Social welfare programs were functioning as in West Bengal, but with the difference that the programs in Karnataka appeared to be better targeted to the poorest, rather than to those who had a particular party affiliation.
Did social wellbeing change as a result of Panchayats? Changes in the local political structure through the election of Gram Panchayats set in motion the possibility for improving social wellbeing through increased opportunities for oversight, implementation, and accountability of social pro grams. The new system also brought the possibility of oversight of these pro grams closer to their intended beneficiaries. In the village studies in Uttar Pradesh, there was no direct evidence of improved social wellbeing as a result of local governments’ interventions. The previous study of one of the villages in Uttar Pradesh documents a few improve ments in the village seen in 1997, such as the new private school and a better functioning government school, yet finds that overall there was little indication of improved welfare (Lanjouw and Stern 1998). The vast majority of villagers interviewed for the UP case studies said that they were better off in 2000 and
182 Political power, local governments, social welfare better again in 2008. Moreover, visual assessment of interviewees’ homes and the village overall supported these findings: more houses were built out of bricks as opposed to mud, more people owned televisions, bicycles, and radios. Yet there was no change in the provision of public services such as primary educa tion or basic health care and the poorest residents of both villages still lived in mud huts, received a fraction of the subsidized grains that they were entitled to, and had not had access to most anti-poverty programs. Significantly, virtually none of them thought that the Gram Panchayat contributed to changes in their wellbeing. Almost no respondents in 2000, or key informants in 2008 (including Gram Panchayat members themselves), thought that their local government had helped improve their lives. Most of the informants stated that if there was a change in their wellbeing, it was entirely due to their own work or misfortune. Respondents in West Bengal, in 2000 and again in 2008, also thought they were better off, but in contrast to Uttar Pradesh, many attributed the changes in wellbeing directly to the work done by local governments. The historical evid ence for local governments improving wellbeing is abundant in studies in West Bengal, where the Gram Panchayats were the implementers of land reforms as well as the driving force behind the distribution of social welfare benefits since their institutionalization in 1977 (Lieten 1992; Harriss 1993). Gram Panchayats in the two villages studied started adult literacy programs, hired poorer residents to build public dirt roads and dig wells, and built up a good primary health care system. The presence of functioning local governments in West Bengal was directly responsible for helping to improve social wellbeing in the villages. However, those who were clearly identifiable as the poorest in both villages, people of ST background in particular, were not the main beneficiaries of these programs. In Karnataka the majority of people interviewed in both village studies reported being better off in 2000 and again in 2008. Moreover, in 2000, while the proportion of respondents attributing their changed welfare to local govern ment work was not as high as in West Bengal, this changed markedly only eight years later. In the Karnataka villages local governments were functioning and the social welfare programs they managed showed greater evidence of targeting than in the other two case study states. Functioning local governments were active in improving the social wellbeing of their constituents, the poor in par ticular. By 2008 the poorer residents in both villages in Karnataka were sending their children to the local public school where the teachers were present and the Midday Meals program provided the children with nutritious meals. A women’s group in the poorer part of one village received a public micro-finance loan through their local panchayat and was raising poultry and rabbits. Several indi gent residents in one of the villages had built one-room brick houses with public funds received through their local governments and many people of Scheduled Tribe background had been able to build toilets in their homes with public funding distributed through their local panchayat. A decade after their reinstitu tion, the panchayats in Karnataka were able to improve the social welfare of some people in their villages.
Political power, local governments, social welfare 183
What enables functioning local governments? Local governments can enable better functioning public services and target anti- poverty programs to improve social wellbeing especially of the indigent – or local governments can prevent public programs from being delivered. These are two divergent outcomes and yet they were the result of the same decentralized structure mandated in India in 1993. As seen in the case studies of villages in Karnataka, West Bengal, and Uttar Pradesh, the outcomes predicted by conven tional political science and economic growth theories are in reality not uniform. Conventional theories of decentralization and the causal linkages they imply are not as robust as earlier, national-level studies imply. Decentralization can result in enhanced governance, delivery of social services and improved social wellbe ing – but it need not. The theoretical models that explain divergent social outcomes at subnational levels are contested. Scholars of political science have argued that poverty reduc tion and social improvements have been most successful in states run by govern ments with a pro-poor orientation and a strong subnational identity, while economists have argued that states with a higher economic growth rate should see greater reductions in poverty and improvements in social wellbeing. In India, none of these theories explains divergent social outcomes. Pro-poor state gov ernments with strong subnational identities in West Bengal have not led to large reductions in poverty or improvements in social indicators, while medium- growth states like Karnataka have surpassed some higher growth states like Punjab over the past two decades. This tension between the promise of decen tralization and conventional explanations of divergent social outcomes on the one hand, and the reality in different parts of India on the other hand, is evident in this study. Constitutionally mandated decentralization became the law with the adoption of the 73rd Amendment in India in 1993. The responsibility for socioeconomic development had been given to local governments who received increased public resources from their states and the central government, and the implementation of anti-poverty and social welfare programs came under the purview of local governments. Increased powers and financial wherewithal in a democratic frame work provided local governments in India with the basis for more targeted deliv ery of social programs. Moreover, a uniform structure of decentralized governments in large states, mandated quotas for inclusion of women, tribal groups and lower castes, and local government responsibility for the social and economic advancement of their constituents, had raised hopes that decentralized local governments would not only help deepen democracy, but also improve social wellbeing, particularly of the poorest. Yet social indicators in 2011 dif fered widely between Indian states, as did the rate of changes in these indicators between 1993 and 2011. Village studies in the states of Karnataka, West Bengal, and Uttar Pradesh found that local governments varied in their efficacy and therefore delivery of social services and anti-poverty programs. Specifically, the extent of political
184 Political power, local governments, social welfare competition, the mobilization of civil society, and elite buy-in enabled varying degrees of functioning of these decentralized structures. These three explanatory frameworks for understanding differential outcomes presented in the introduc tory chapter and in Table 6.1, when taken together, provide a holistic framework for understanding the varying impact of decentralization on social wellbeing. Political competition is important . . . Decentralized governance structures that function in an environment of com petitive local elections, where the people who are seeking to represent constitu ents in local governments are allowed to compete on the basis of political parties which all have a chance of winning, and where elections result in a turnover of elected representatives, should yield better functioning local governance struc tures, according to the theory outlined in Chapter 1. At the subnational level in India, states with more competitive elections that resulted in a turnover of parties at the state and local levels would see larger improvements in social wellbeing. Village studies in the three states indicate that this hypothesis best explains the middling case of West Bengal’s panchayats. In West Bengal, where the CPI(M) party-led Left Front Government (LFG) has ruled the state and has won the vast majority of local government elections since 1977, the lack of political competi tion over three decades has counteracted the Left Front Government’s pro-poor political platform. While poverty reduction, land reform, and social improve ments for the indigent were the platform that catapulted them to power, the lack of political parties that have been able to pose a credible challenge to the Left Front Government decreased the party-dominated local governments’ account ability and impetus for delivering on electoral promises. Public programs intended for the poor and vulnerable are being distributed by CPI(M)-run local governments based on party affiliation rather than need. Under these circum stances, the new West Bengal panchayat law did not lead to significant improve ments in social wellbeing, with public resources intended for the indigent leaking to those belonging to the party in power. In contrast to West Bengal, politically competitive elections took place in Karnataka and to a large degree in Uttar Pradesh. However, efficacy of local governments in these two states differed greatly, highlighting that political com petition on its own lacked explanatory power in causing these differential out comes. Local government elections that were ostensibly fought on a non-party Table 6.1 Enabling conditions in the three case study states History of democratically elected PRIs Yes Yes No
Karnataka West Bengal Uttar Pradesh
Politically competitive environment
Mobilized Civil Society
Socio-political elites, which are able to capture benefits
Yes No Somewhat
Yes Yes No
No Yes Yes
Political power, local governments, social welfare 185 basis in Karnataka, but where village residents knew the candidate’s political views through their campaign platform, led to issue-focused local electoral cam paigns, mirroring statewide election campaigns and results. In Uttar Pradesh, where political parties appealed to the numerically large Scheduled Castes, local government elections were competitive yet electoral platforms were often dominated by divisive social cleavages rather than a focus on political issues and social cleavage-bridging social issues, with consequences for social wellbeing. A mobilized civil society can improve local government accountability . . . There was a greater level of civil society mobilization among residents of the Karnataka and West Bengali villages compared to the village residents in Uttar Pradesh. Citizens in the villages in Karnataka were more knowledgeable about their governments, more likely to contact their local government representatives when needed, and more likely to work across religious and caste lines to rally for a cause. Residents of the villages in Karnataka and West Bengal were also more likely to participate in their local government meetings. The more engaged civil society had led to a mobilized electorate in West Bengal, especially in the early 1980s. However, while in Karnataka civil society functioned in an environ ment of political competition and the combination of these two factors produced more accountable local governments, the mobilized civil society in West Bengal had very few avenues for dissent or complaint. Local governments in West Bengal were less accountable than their counterparts in Karnataka, since local as well as upper levels of government in West Bengal were captured by CPI(M) party members, leaving civil society little recourse for complaint. Many civil society organizations in the West Bengali villages studied, ranging from farmers’ associations to women’s associations, were in fact set up by the CPI(M). The highly engaged civil society in West Bengal was mobilized by the dominant party and was not differentiated from the new political elites in these West Bengal villages. The civil society organizations in these villages were therefore also not able to provide an independent counterweight to village elites. By con trast, in Karnataka an active social capital and engaged civil society, in an envir onment of political competition, led local governments to be more responsive and to effectively provide public programs and social services. A more aware citizenry put pressure on local governments and bureaucrats to deliver more effective social services or face the significant threat of loss at the next local government elections. . . . And the buy-in of sociopolitical elites matters Sociopolitical elites, particularly upper castes, have historically wielded signific ant power within India’s villages and this continued to be the case in Uttar Pradesh, despite the implementation of elected local governments in 1993. With
186 Political power, local governments, social welfare the advent of elected local governments and the access to power of women and lower castes, upper castes in the villages of Uttar Pradesh saw their traditional sociopolitical power and dominance over public resources threatened. They fought to retain their access to public resources by continued dominance in access to government resources, including employment opportunities ranging from schoolteacher to the local distributor of subsidized grains in the Public Dis tribution System, and tried to use their privileged background of literacy and social standing to continue to retain access to public programs distributed by the elected local governments. Moreover, Gram Panchayat elections brought for merly disenfranchised individuals to power, which had no model of governance except for the elite-capture of public funds that they had witnessed over the pre vious decades. When these new local government representatives accessed polit ical power, traditional elites were forced to share some of their captured public resources with them as bribes for acquiescence. Though this has led to a “demo cratization of corruption” in the villages studied in Uttar Pradesh, it has also hampered the efficacy of local governments. Furthermore, in the Uttar Pradesh environment, where political platforms continue to be focused on social cleav ages and civil society does not organize across social divisions to pressure local government accountability, traditional elites are able to retain some of their his toric power and capture public resources. In Uttar Pradesh the lack of traditional elite buy-in to the panchayat structures has further exacerbated cleavages in a civil society already fraught with religious and caste divisions and local elections that focus on socials cleavages rather than political issues. The lack of any of the three factors shown in Table 6.1 that support the formation of democratic and efficacious local governments has created an environment that has not been con ducive to the rooting of democratic local governance, and has hampered the abil ity of Gram Panchayats to improve social wellbeing. By contrast, the traditional upper-caste, large landowning social elites of West Bengal have given way during three decades of LFG rule to new elites who are LFG coalition party members. Party membership provides access to positions of local power and public resources, since LFG-dominated Gram Panchayats provide public resources meant for the indigent to their party comrades. In West Bengal, as in Uttar Pradesh, there is no elite buy-in to the new democratic pan chayat structures – instead, the new local elites capture benefits to distribute amongst themselves. In Karnataka, a virtuous circle has been created by the combination of a polit ically competitive local environment, an aware and mobilized civil society that keeps its local governments more accountable, and traditional elites who buy-in and support their local governments rather than seeking to capture them. The three factors reinforce each other, creating an environment in Karnataka that is more conducive to the flourishing of effective local governments, which in turn is better able to deliver social services and public anti-poverty programs. In con trast, in Uttar Pradesh, traditional social elites connive to retain their hold on power, working against the local governments and in some instances bribing newly elected officials in order to continue to pilfer public resources.
Political power, local governments, social welfare 187 In villages in Karnataka, citizens had an enabling environment, which led to quicker “rooting” of local governance structures as local government representa tives actively engaged with their constituents and citizens demanded the public services and programs to which they were entitled. With greater resources flowing to local governments and the state government taking measures to increase transparency and accountability of Gram Panchayats, more resources were available for investments in social and economic infrastructure. As citizens interacted with local public officials, they became more aware of the growing resources and powers now located in the village governments, which provided further incentives to interact with local government representatives in order to access public resources. The lack of effective Gram Panchayats in Uttar Pradesh, however, did not mean that electing local government representatives was for naught. Once the decision to decentralize had been legislated by the Indian federal government and Uttar Pradesh had to change its laws to conform to the decentralization amendment, a process of access to local power by formerly disenfranchised groups was set in motion. Even though the traditional elite still tried to pilfer public resources, they were not able to bypass local government representatives, which gave local representatives unprecedented power and access to patronage networks. Even in states like Uttar Pradesh, which have a weak history of local governance and deep social cleavages that deter collective action, the process of electing local governments has changed social interaction at the village level. Village citizens now know who is stealing public resources and are more likely to protest. The links between local governments, public services, and improve ments in social wellbeing, are much more tenuous in Uttar Pradesh than in Kar nataka, but the barriers to more efficacious local governments in Uttar Pradesh may be surmountable.
Enhancing local government’s capacity to improve social wellbeing Having a history of elected local governments provided for an enabling environ ment in which elected local governments, after 1993, were more likely to flour ish. Yet as the historical case of West Bengal during the early 1970s illustrates, deep social cleavages, traditional elites who capture public resources and are not interested in furthering local democracy, and a civil society wracked by dissen sion and antagonism are not insurmountable barriers to democratic local govern ments that can help improve social wellbeing. With the institutionalization of local governments in West Bengal in 1977, great improvements in poverty reduction and social wellbeing were made during the 1980s. Decentralization can contribute towards more accountable local governments; it can provide avenues for increasing interaction between citizens and govern ment representatives; and it can lead to more targeted delivery of social welfare programs that improve the lives of poor and vulnerable groups. Yet, in some cases it does not lead to these desirable outcomes. Decentralization’s impact on
188 Political power, local governments, social welfare social wellbeing is variable. Having a past history of functioning local govern ments matters, since it provides citizens with a basis for understanding the pos sible benefits and engaging local governments. However, past legacies are not a guarantee for future success, since local government structures can be coopted by traditional or newly emerging elites, especially in an environment lacking in political competition. How then can the promises of decentralization predicted by the political scientists, economists, public management experts and realized in places like the Indian state of Karnataka become more likely than the failure of local governments in Uttar Pradesh? Improving awareness of rights Throughout the village studies, a glaringly reoccurring theme was the lack of cit izens’ knowledge of decentralized structures and their local governments’ responsibilities, as well as citizens’ rights. This is perhaps surprising in a country that has had elected national governments for over 60 years. However, low levels of literacy and deep social and gender cleavages have perpetuated tradi tional social mores in rural India that have inhibited accountable local govern ments in some parts of the country. The Indian constitution guarantees a right to education, but very few villagers interviewed were aware of this right and fewer still knew that they had legal avenues for demanding it from their government. The Indian central government has a plethora of anti-poverty and social welfare programs, but only a few of those interviewed knew specifics of the programs or that they were entitled to help the village government select the program beneficiaries. A large barrier to the effective institutionalization of democratic local govern ments is that citizens are not aware of their rights and how to demand these rights, and do not know the extent of rights and obligations of decentralized gov ernments. Improving awareness of citizens’ rights and what they can expect from their local governments is key to breaking the vicious cycle of non- functioning local governments that do not deliver social services. Methods of increasing awareness of rights could include disseminating local government functions and obligations at election time and other public gatherings, govern ment broadcasting of its obligations via radio and television, public posting of the decentralization law at local government offices, and a national drive to educate citizens about the obligations of their local governments. Understanding the functioning, rights, and obligations of local governments is the starting point for increasing local government functioning, yet to date no public campaign to educate citizens in India has been undertaken. When citizens are aware of the obligations of local governments, they are more likely to demand these rights and hold governments accountable when they trespass on these rights. Building better awareness of citizens’ rights vis-à-vis local governments – as West Bengal did in the late 1970s and early 1980s – will increase civil society interactions, improve local government accountability, and lead to better delivery of social services and programs.
Political power, local governments, social welfare 189 Institutionalizing accountability mechanisms Well-functioning local governments are governments that are answerable to their citizens. They have institutionalized accountability mechanisms that require elected representatives to provide explanations on the workings of local govern ments. In places like Uttar Pradesh, where local governments do not function as laid out by the law and do not contribute towards improving their constituents’ wellbeing, institutionalizing mechanisms to increase accountability would jump-start the building of more responsive local governments. The state govern ment of Karnataka has been at the forefront in trying to increase local government transparency through mechanisms such as the electronic transfer of public funds directly to Gram Panchayats and posting of panchayat finances at the local government offices. There are other possible avenues for institutional izing responsive and accountable local governments, including requiring village- level campaigning even for reserved seats, institutionalizing mechanisms for citizen auditing of local government finances, mandating public posting of all local government finances as well as social program beneficiaries, providing local government majorities with powers to hire and fire village-level civil ser vants such as teachers and local health care workers, and facilitating opportun ities for regular and open dialogue between government representatives and citizens. A significant breakthrough in building government accountability at all levels of government has been the Right to Information (RTI) campaign in India, which resulted in the Right to Information Act of 2005. This Act gives all citizens the right to request information from any public authority, which then has a max imum of 30 days to respond. Moreover, the act requires computerization of public records in order to increase public access, and requires government authorities to be proactive in publishing important information. Though RTI is now the law of the country most interviewees had never heard of it – again high lighting the need for a public campaign to disseminate information on citizens rights. Increasing local resources When decentralization leads to an engaged civil society and accountable govern ments, local governments can more effectively target social services and pro grams to those most in need. India has many central government-financed programs aimed at improving social and economic wellbeing, yet effective deliv ery of these programs has been weak in large parts of the country. Moreover, transfers of resources to local governments for these various social programs have increased since the mid-1990s, as discussed in Chapter 2. Decentralization of power and resources in India was in part driven by the premise that the elected local governments with more wherewithal would be better able to deliver these social programs to their intended beneficiaries. However, the majority of local government resources is earmarked for use in specific programs. Only a small
190 Political power, local governments, social welfare fraction of local governments resources in India today is given to or raised by local governments to use for projects requested by their citizens. Clearly, transferring large amounts of resources to local governments that are corrupt would further exacerbate accountability problems. However, channeling greater “untied” resources to local governments that have functioning account ability mechanisms and where civil society is mobilized and aware of its rights would help better target public funds to local needs and the indigent. Further resources to allocate according to needs in the village would in turn increase the likelihood of local governments improving social wellbeing. Greater resources at the village level are necessary, but should only be allocated in environments where there are structures of accountability and where civil society is mobilized and aware of its rights. Another important and related issue is the need to improve local revenue raising. There is little incentive for local governments to tax their citizens in order to increase their resource base in rural India, since all public services are paid for by the central or state governments. It is easier to continue to rely on federal and state resources, rather than make locally unpopular moves to imple ment their legal powers of taxation. Yet since emerging literature on taxation and accountability in developing countries suggests that government account ability is more likely to occur when states tax their citizens particularly through progressive tax systems (Brautigam 2002; Moore and Rakner 2002), more avenues for progressive, local resource raising should be explored by states. Interlinkages between a mobilized and aware civil society, functioning struc tures of accountability, and increased resources at the local level so as to better select and target social programs, further point to the need to holistically analyze the determinants of decentralization’s successes and failures. With a better understanding of different factors influencing successful decentralization pro grams, better policies can be designed to root democracy and improve citizen wellbeing. Improving awareness of citizens’ rights and institutionalizing mech anisms to hold governments more accountable are two main ways to help quicken the ability of local governments to improve social wellbeing. When local governments are likely to be accountable, increasing the resources avail able to them through increased federal and state transfers, as local revenue raising, will further improve local government functioning. While political com petition, civil society mobilization, and elite reactions to local governments determine the ability of village governments to matter for the wellbeing for their citizens, decentralization is not a one-time event. Decentralization can be fine- tuned, or in the more severe cases, jump-started. Decentralization in Karnataka lagged behind West Bengal in the early 1990s, but by 2010 local governments in Karnataka had surpassed West Bengal in its ability to deliver targeted social pro grams and help improve social wellbeing. The high-functioning local govern ments in Karnataka were a function of state-level conditions, but also of attempts since 1993 by the Government of Karnataka to increase the accountability and financial means of local governments. Local conditions in Karnataka were more conducive to local government functioning than in Uttar Pradesh, but steps taken
Political power, local governments, social welfare 191 to increase accountability within the system also led to higher functioning local governments in Karnataka than in West Bengal. Understanding remaining local barriers to effective decentralization should be the first step towards fine-tuning of public policies in order to increase the efficacy of local governments and their delivery of social services in India.
Appendix A Powers to be delegated to Panchayats by state governments
The writers of the 73rd Amendment envisioned local governments as agents of socioeconomic development and enabled Indian states to devolve significant responsibilities to local governments as the following sections of the Amendment highlight.
Powers, authority and responsibilities of Panchayats “Subject to the provisions of this Constitution, the Legislature of a State may, by law, endow the Panchayats with such powers and authority as may be necessary to enable them to function as institutions of self-government and such law may contain provisions for the devolution of powers and responsibilities upon Panchayats at the appropriate level, subject to such conditions as may be specified therein, with respect to – a b
the preparation of plans for economic development and social justice, the implementation of schemes for economic development and social justice as may be entrusted to them including those in relation to the matters listed in the Eleventh Schedule.”
Eleventh Schedule (Article 243g) 1 Agriculture, including agricultural extension. 2 Land improvement, implementation of land reforms, land consolidation and soil conservation. 3 Minor irrigation, water management and watershed development. 4 Animal husbandry, dairying and poultry. 5 Fisheries. 6 Social forestry and farm forestry. 7 Minor forest produce. 8 Small scale industries, including food processing industries. 9 Khadi, village and cotton industries. 10 Rural housing. 11 Drinking water.
Appendix A 193 12 Fuel and fooder. 13 Roads, culverts, bridges, ferries, waterways and other means of communi cation. 14 Rural electrification, including distribution of electricity. 15 Non-conventional energy sources. 16 Poverty alleviation programme. 17 Education including primary and secondary schools. 18 Technical training and vocational education. 19 Adult and non-formal education. 20 Libraries. 21 Cultural activities. 22 Markets and fairs. 23 Health and sanitation, including hospitals, primary health centers and dispensaries. 24 Family welfare. 25 Women and child development. 26 Social welfare, include welfare of the handicapped and mentally retarded. 27 Welfare of the weaker sections, and in particular, of the Scheduled Castes and Scheduled Tribes. 28 Public distribution system. 29 Maintenance of community assets. Source: Government of India 1992: Constitution (73rd Amendment) Act.
Appendix B Methodology
This is primarily a qualitative study. Faced with an ambitious research question in a challenging context, there were essentially two basic methodological choices: (1) quantitative: try to answer the question using quantitative data from large- sample representative surveys in the states; or (2) qualitative: use purposive selection of state and village cases along with qualitative data collection methods. The first option was not possible because population-representative data on the relev ant issues were not available, it was far beyond the available means to attempt to collect it, and the complex processes to be measured were in any case unlikely to be adequately captured by discrete quantitative survey questions. Qualitative methods were applied, starting with purposive selection of states on the basis of several criteria (i.e., state size and importance as well as differing experiences with decentralization), and then purposive selection of village case studies on the basis of similarly clear criteria (i.e., located in a district that approximates state averages in socioeconomic indicators, villages that approximate district averages, and at least one village with a study previous to the decentralization reform). I spent substantial time doing field research in each village in both 2000 and 2008, applying qualitative methods (i.e., interviews of informants and focus groups). In addition, in 2000 I did small quantitative surveys (with sample sizes of around 40 in each village) that are representative of each village (respondents were randomly selected from a list of all households, stratified by caste and religious group). Along with yes/no questions, survey respondents were also interviewed in-depth in a qualitative fashion. Both the qualitative methods and quantitative surveys provide evidence about conditions and perceptions in each village, and the main use of this evidence is to support conclusions about decentralization in each of the states as a whole. For each state, conclusions are based on: (1) secondary analysis of the literature as well as available data that are representative of the state as a whole; (2) qualitative information-gathering from key informants at the national, state and district levels; (3) qualitative information-gathering in the two villages; and (4) small quantitative surveys in each village. Quantitative data derived from discrete (yes/no) questions asked during the village surveys essentially supplement the qualitative methods – any statistical analysis beyond numbers and proportions would not have been useful to my analysis as there was no intention for these surveys to be representative of the states as a whole.
Appendix B 195
Case selection The initial list of 28 states was narrowed down by excluding small and medium- sized states (those with populations under 50 million). Among the final ten large states, Karnataka, West Bengal and Uttar Pradesh were selected for study with the objective of contrasting different experiences with the presence and duration of functioning local governments prior to the adoption of the 73rd constitutional amendment at the beginning of 1994. In the case of Uttar Pradesh, there were no continuously elected local governments. Karnataka had a brief experience with democratically elected and innovative local governments prior to 1993. And West Bengal has had elected local governments since 1977. In order to construct the background history and baseline for each state from the early 1990s to 2010, I drew on socioeconomic surveys conducted by the National Sample Survey Organisation in India (http://mospi.gov.in/nsso_4aug 2008/web/nsso.htm), census reports (http://www.censusindia.gov.in) and other socioeconomic surveys conducted by the Indian government such as the National Table B.1 Population and geographic location of Indian states (ten large states in bold) Indian State
Population (2001)
Geographic region
1 Andhra Pradesh 2 Arunachal Pradesh 3 Assam 4 Bihar 5 Chhattisgarh 6 Goa 7 Gujarat 8 Haryana 9 Himachal Pradesh 10 Jammu and Kashmir 11 Jharkhand 12 Karnataka 13 Kerala 14 Madhya Pradesh 15 Maharashtra 16 Manipur 17 Meghalaya 18 Mizoram 19 Nagaland 20 Orissa 21 Punjab 22 Rajasthan 23 Sikkim 24 amil Nadu 25 Tripura 26 Uttar Pradesh 27 Uttaranchal 28 West Bengal
76,210,007 1,097,968 26,655,528 82,998,509 20,833,803 1,347,668 50,671,017 21,144,564 6,077,900 10,143,700 26,945,829 52,850,562 31,841,374 60,348,023 96,878,627 2,293,896 2,318,822 888,573 1,990,036 36,804,660 24,358,999 56,507,188 540,851 62,405,679 3,199,203 166,197,921 8,489,349 80,176,197
S NE NE N N S NW N N N N S S N S NE NE NE NE N N NW NE S NE N N NE
Source: Census information in Government of India 2001.
196 Appendix B Family Health Survey (www.nfhsindia.org/). Together these data provided a wealth of population-representative data on indicators of social and economic wellbeing in these three states, down to the district level, and over the period studied, from pre-1993 to 2010.
Selection of villages within states For each selected state, census as well as social and economic data were ana lyzed to build a profile of the state around 1990, before the passage of the 73rd amendment, and at the end of the 1990s, near the time of the first round of research. Within each state, the district that most closely approximated average statewide socioeconomic indicators was chosen. Within each selected district, villages were chosen based on whether there had been a study of the village around 1990. In each of these districts, at least one village was found that had been studied extensively prior to passage of the 73rd Amendment. Prior village studies in different districts of the state were available in all three of the states. Selection of the villages could therefore be made based on district-level socioeconomic indicators most closely approximating state-level averages. While it would be illusionary to expect that a pair of villages in Uttar Pradesh for example – a state with a population of 166 million – could hope to be characteristic of the whole range of socioeconomic conditions in the state, the selection criteria were intended to minimize the possibility of selecting cases that were obvious outliers on important socioeconomic characteristics. Villages were excluded if they significantly deviated from state averages in terms of demographic indicators, such as female-to-male ratio and proportions of castes and religious groups. Villages were also excluded if they were located in regions that presented significantly different agro-economic environments than the rural norm in the state, such as coastal, suburban or mountainous areas. All selected villages were at least ten kilometers away from towns and were predominantly dependent on agriculture for their incomes.
Previous village research and initial key informants In the case of Karnataka, Professor G. K. Karanth from the Institute of Social and Economic Change in Bangalore, Karnataka, had studied the villages of Madbal and Gavi Nagamangala in Bangalore Rural District yearly between 1987 and 1994. He had also been involved in James Manor’s study of decentralization in Karnataka (Crook and Manor 1998). While G. K. Karanth studied labor organization, agricultural changes and rural development more generally in these two selected villages, he also published information on numbers of households in each village as well as their caste and socioeconomic backgrounds. In addition, during his years of studying these two villages, he learned the political affiliation of every household and the political history of the villages, informa tion he generously shared with me. G. K. Karanth was my main initial key informant for the study of the villages of Madbal and Gavi Nagamangala and
Appendix B 197 shared his insights into the local political history of the villages during several background discussions. He also suggested people in the villages who could be potential key informants on the ground. Once I had been living in the villages for ten days, I supplemented his list with my own list of key informants. Information on the types of castes and minority religious groups within both villages and number of households within each caste was obtained with the assistance of my initial list of local informants and double-checked with members of the respective groups. The local key informants in the villages studied in Karnataka as well as those in West Bengal and Uttar Pradesh were and remain my “sounding board” for understanding the processes and relationships that undergird social, economic and political developments in their respective villages. In the case of West Bengal, both villages of Shahajapur and Kuchli in the selected district of Birbhum had been studied in the late 1980s by Professor Sunil Sengupta of the World Institute for Development Economic Research (WIDER), based at the Visva Barathi University in Shantiniketan, Birbhum District. Professor Sengupta published a summary analysis of his research on socio economic development in these villages in a volume edited by Amartya Sen and Jean Drèze (Drèze and Sen 1996). He also studied health and economic indic ators in these two villages in the early 1980s with Amartya Sen and was a research collaborator for over 30 years. Sunil Sengupta made all data from his studies of the two villages available to me, thereby providing me with a wealth of insight into the social, economic and political development of the selected villages up to the early 1990s. Extensive discussions with him and his research collaborators provided me with detailed background on local political history. Sunil Sengupta was my main initial key informant for the study of these villages. He and his collaborators provided me with a list of potential key informants in the villages and here too I supplemented their list with my own key informants after having spent about ten days of research in the villages. In the case of Uttar Pradesh, one of my research advisors, Jean Drèze, had studied one village in the selected district of Moradabad with several other well- respected scholars. Their findings were published in Economic Development in Palanpur Over Five Decades (Lanjouw and Stern 1998). This book describes socioeconomic changes in the village of Palanpur from 1957 to 1993, and provides an abundance of background information for my study, including detailed village-level data on demographic and social indicators such as the number of households in each caste, infant mortality and literacy rates. In addition to Palanpur, I chose the neighboring village of Pipli, which is of about the same size as Palanpur and therefore has the same structure of Gram Panchayat (local village government). Jean Drèze was my initial key informant for the study of Palanpur and Pipli in Uttar Pradesh and provided me with invaluable background informa tion on Palanpur as well as introductions to the director of a non-governmental organization living close to the village and a potential list of local key informants, which I later supplemented after an initial period of living in the village. Once two villages for study had been selected in each state, the initial key informants provided me with introductions to non-governmental organizations
198 Appendix B or a university (in the case of West Bengal) located close to the villages to use as an initial base until I found accommodation in the villages. My key informants helped identify the political, social, and economic elites in the villages.
Data collection While care was taken in village selection to maximize their proximity to statewide averages in socioeconomic characteristics, it is important to emphasize that the purpose of data collection in the villages was not to make generalizations about the state as a whole, but to illuminate phenomena and processes evident at both the village and state levels. An example is the question of why local gov ernments in West Bengal have been less successful than those in Karnataka at delivering social services such as primary education and anti-poverty programs to those most in need, despite what many leading academics have argued are more favorable state-level conditions in West Bengal. Population-representative surveys depend heavily on asking the right questions and can miss out on the social processes in action that influence outcomes. For example, quantitative census and large-scale survey data, as well as other larger state-level surveys (Drèze and De 1999) in Uttar Pradesh, indicate weak delivery of primary education in both villages studied, as well as at the overall state-level in Uttar Pradesh, but do not illuminate the processes that prevent more efficient delivery of basic education. However, living in the village of Palanpur and seeing the head teacher of the primary school, who rarely came to the school to teach and when he came rarely taught, and finding out that he was related to one of the politically most powerful families in the village, provided understanding of why village residents were powerless to speak out about this specific corruption. Similarly, living in the villages studied in West Bengal provided me with a keen understanding of the deep-rooted power of the Communist Party and enabled me to follow up with poverty program recipients to better understand the relationship between political affiliation and receipt of social benefits. Interviews and participant observations were thus the most integral and important aspect of this research, enabling a deeper understanding of the political, social, economic and cultural underpinnings of local governance in three Indian states. The aim of this study was to understand the complex processes set in motion by the 1993 constitutional amendment on decentralization in India and its impact on the social and economic wellbeing of rural communities. Qualitative research was required to provide insights into the processes and causal interactions between factors such as state-level histories of functioning local governments, social mobil ization, and political parties. Understanding political and social interactions and processes, such as the links between local elites and local governments that enable governance, required qualitative information. My main method of qualitative research was participant observation, a standard method used by a variety of fieldwork-based comparative politics scholars. Among the virtues of this method is that it allows one to assess the micro-logic of macro phenomena, contributing to understanding the motives of political actors first hand.
Appendix B 199
Qualitative data collection The bulk of my research was based on qualitative data collection. Two villages within each of the three states were studied for about six weeks in 2000. I was based in or close to each village. Data collection methods included interviews with village elites, which involved identifying local opinion-makers of both genders, within all castes, and among the minority religious communities with the help of the initial and local key informants. I conducted interviews with other key informants identified by previous researchers as well as from information I obtained while living in the villages. I convened focus group discussions (which were conducted with all major caste groups and religious minorities). Additional qualitative data included informal interviews when villagers asked to be inter viewed or stopped by my village living quarters for tea and to chat. In addition, as elaborated below, a random sample of villagers (stratified by caste and religious group) was selected for a structured interview following the questionnaire provided in Appendix B. Along with yes/no questions, in-depth interviews with each survey respondent were done, along with open discussion of issues as they came up. The main topics of the qualitative interviews included structures of local government, patterns of interaction between the panchayats and local social forces, and the interactions associated with improved social welfare outcomes. For each village study, I engaged a translator who accompanied me on all interviews. I gained information from direct observation (i.e., of the functioning of social services, village conditions, etc.) while living in the villages. I also conducted interviews at the district and state levels with government officials charged with different aspects of administrating local governments as well with local researchers on this subject in each state. In 2008, I returned to the six villages for a week in each one and conducted interviews with a number of key informants from the social and economic leadership/elites and from the various caste and religious groups. I also inter viewed individuals that I had known during the previous round of research and had numerous informal discussions with village residents.
Small village surveys to collect both qualitative and quantitative data Small sample surveys in each village were done to both collect quantitative data (from yes/no questions) and qualitative information from structured interviews. The quantitative data supplements the information collected through qualitative methods. Although random sample selection meant that survey findings could be considered representative of each village population, as noted above the focus was on understanding patterns and processes within each village that could illuminate larger state-level patterns. Census data, cross-referenced with data collected by previous researchers and information from local key informants, were used to construct district- and village-level demographic profiles. Village profiles included the population and total number of households, as well as the
200 Appendix B percentage of population by caste and religious group. These “quota” groups were defined by the categories with reserved seats in local governments. The sampling frame was a list of households that I had compiled from local leaders and from mapping. Households were randomly selected from mutually exclusive caste and religious groups, with the proportion of the sample selected from each group the same as their proportion of the village population. This was to ensure representation in the sample from each caste and religious group. Systematic random sampling from the list (i.e., selection of households at a randomly- determined interval on the list within each stratum) was used to select the sample. This self-weighted sample provided estimates that are considered representative of the village population as a whole. All villages studied contained 100–200 households, with an overall popula tion size of approximately 1,000. The sample size for each village in all three states was approximately 40 respondents, for a total of 240 individuals. Table B.2 provides details on the village populations and sample sizes by caste and religious group. All interviews were conducted using a questionnaire based on the instrument used by Richard Crook and James Manor in their seminal study of decentralization in South Asia and West Africa (Crook and Manor 1998) (see Appendix C). The questionnaire was modified on the basis of input from previous researchers and a pre-test in the first studied village. The questionnaire was supplemented by open-ended discussions with each respondent, adding to the qualitative information collected in each village. Results for the yes/no questions, as well as summaries of the qualitative discussions were input into a database. Table B.3 presents results for selected yes/no questions posed by the survey.
1,027
685 0 186 123 0 33 1,062
40
40
28 0 7 3 2 0
743 0 186 80 53 0
27 0 7 5 0 1 823
345 51 330 97 0 0
Sample Pop.
41
17 3 16 5 0 0 899
248 107 286 245 13 0 39
11 5 12 11 0 0
1,133
576 171 195 0 141 50
40
20 6 7 0 5 2
1,195
595 135 211 0 209 45
Sample Pop.
40
20 5 7 0 7 1
Sample
Uttar Pradesh Uttar Pradesh: Palanpur village Pipli village
Sample Pop.
West Bengal: Shahajapur village
Sample Pop.
West Bengal: Kuchli village
Sample Pop.
Karnataka: Madabal village
Note The village population is based on the 1991 census data. Demographic data for each village was cross-checked with previous researchers of the case studies, local government officials, and local key informants.
Total
General Caste (GC) Other Backward Castes (OBC) Scheduled Castes (SC) Scheduled Tribes (ST) Muslims Other
Pop.
Karnataka: Nagamangala village
Table B.2 Village case study surveys: quota categories, percentage of quotas in selected district, and percentage of quotas in sample
Voted in last national elections Thought last national elections were fair Voted in last GP elections Thought last GP elections were fair Campaigned for the election of a GP member Knew the name of GP representative(s) Have participated in a meeting of the village electorate There are working social welfare programs in the village GP is instrumental in delivering these social services There are working anti-poverty programs in village GP is instrumental in delivering these anti-poverty programs GP been able to satisfy the most important needs in the village If two poor people applied for an anti-poverty scheme to the GP and one had political connections while the other did not, the GP would give the scheme to the politically connected persona 30 (21%, 41%) 88 (78%, 93%) 16 (10%, 26%) 56 (45%, 67%) 28 (19%, 38%)
24 70 13 45 22
59
48
66 77 73
100 (95%, 100%) 80
78 51 77 50 16 65 26
80
(91%, 99%) (95%, 100%) (95%, 100%) (95%, 100%) (19%, 38%) (88%, 98%) (20%, 39%)
98 100 100 100 28 95 29
78 80 80 80 22 76 23
(91%, 99%) (53%, 73%) (90%, 99%) (52%, 72%) (13%, 30%) (71%, 88%) (23%, 43%)
95% CI 70 41 78 58 13 51 24
74 (63%, 82%)
60 (49%, 70%)
83 (73%, 89%) 96 (90%, 99%) 91 (83%, 96%)
21
11 19 13
–
Number
26
14 24 16
20
88 51 98 73 16 64 30
%
–
–
(18%, 37%)
(8%, 23%) (16%, 34%) (10%, 26%)
(13%, 30%)
(78%, 93%) (40%, 62%) (91%, 99%) (62%, 81%) (10%, 26%) (53%, 73%) (21%, 41%)
95% CI
2 villages in Uttar Pradesh (n = 80)
100 (95%, 100%) 16
98 64 96 63 20 81 33
%
Number
95% CI
Number
%
2 villages in West Bengal (n = 80)
2 villages in Karnataka (n = 80)
Table B.3 Selected results of village surveys, number responding positively, percentages, and 95% confidence intervals (CI)
74 (63%, 82%) 39 (29%, 50%) – – 19 (12%, 29%)
59 31 – 15
(28%, 48%) (20%, 39%) (3%, 14%) (12%, 29%) (18%, 37%) (30%, 51%) (57%, 77%) (47%, 68%) (16%, 34%)
38 29 6 19 26 40 68 58 24
30 23 5 15 21 32 54 46 19
38 38 43
80
73 64 18 48 33 16 28 54 32
(83%, 96%) (70%, 87%) (15%, 33%) (49%, 70%) (31%, 52%) (13%, 30%) (25%, 40%) (57%, 77%) (30%, 51%)
48 (37%, 58%) 48 (37%, 58%) 54 (43%, 64%)
100 (95%, 100%)
91 80 23 60 41 20 35 68 40
0 16 20
0
18 10 12 4 10 7 2 50 2
0 20 25
0
23 13 15 5 13 9 3 63 3
(0%, 5%) (13%, 30%) (17%, 35%)
(0%, 5%)
(15%, 33%) (7%, 22%) (9%, 24%) (2%, 12%) (7%, 22%) (4%, 17%) (1%, 9%) (52%, 72%) (1%, 9%)
Note a For West Bengal “had political connections” is replaced with “was a CPI(M) member.” Confidence intervals of the proportions are estimated using Stata SE 10.1 for Windows (2008), assuming a binomial distribution and applying the Wilson method, which is appropriate for extreme proportions (i.e. less than or equal to 5% or greater than or equal to 95%). (This calculation does not take in account stratification of the sample, which would be expected to reduce the variance and thus narrow the confidence interval.)
More voice under new GP system Less violence in 2000 compared to 1990 Rule of law has improved between 1990 and 2000 Government has become more effective Administrative burden has decreased Accountability has improved Corruption decreased over past ten years Was better off in 2000 compared to 1990 Of those who said they were better off, those who said they were better off due to the GP There are associations (bridging religion and caste) in this village Participated in associations during last five years Have had contact with their GP member Have contacted their GP representative in the last five years for help
Appendix C Field research questionnaire
Introduction: Explain the nature of this research and that answering any and all parts of this questionnaire are voluntary. If they agree to answer the questionnaire, explain that they are welcome to stop at any time.
Section A: General background 1 2 3
Name: Gender: (Male/Female) How old are you? a b
4
What is your level of education? a b c d e f g
5 6 7 8
35 years old or less or over 35 years old specific age None Some primary Completed primary Completed junior secondary Completed senior secondary or technical school College, university or polytechnic Other professional
What is your main occupation? Where were you born? How long have you lived here? (Last ten years?). How many people are in your household? a b c d e
Person Age Gender Education Health
Appendix C 205
Section B-1: Wellbeing today 9 Describe what life is like today in terms of your wellbeing: a b c d e f
Assets: What do you own in terms of assets (house, land, savings, jewelry, animals, etc.)? Luxury Goods: Do you own things that you consider luxury goods (tv, radio, bike, etc.)? Nutrition: Do you and your family have at least three full meals a day? Education: Do you and your family have enough money so that you have been able to afford and will be able to afford the education you wanted/want for all your family members? Health: Do you and your family have enough money so that in the past and future, if someone falls sick, you will be able to get medical help? Other: Are there other examples that illustrate what your life is like today?
10 What was your life like ten years ago in terms of wellbeing: a b c d e f
Assets: What did you own in terms of assets (house, land, savings, jewelry, animals, etc.)? Luxury Goods: Did you own things that you consider luxury goods (tv, radio, bike, etc.)? Nutrition: Did you and your family have at least three full meals a day? Education: Did you and your family have enough money so that you were able to afford the education you wanted for all your family members? Health: Did you and your family have enough money so that if someone fell sick you were able to get medical help? Other: Are there other examples that illustrate what your life was like?
11 Do you think that you are better or worse off today than ten years ago? Why?
Section C: Perception of PRIs 12 Did you vote in the last national elections? Were they fair? (Completely fair; fair but with some problems; very unfair; do not know) 13 Did you vote in the last gram panchayat elections? Were they fair? (Completely fair; fair but with some problems; very unfair; do not know) 14 Did you campaign or work for the election of any particular panchayat member in your village? Did you campaign or work for the election of any particular panchayat member at the block or district level? 15 Have you ever attended a GS meeting? If so, did you speak at the meeting? Why or why not? 16 What are the names of your present panchayat members? 17 Who is the pradhan/sarpanch?
206 Appendix C 18 Do you think that the panchayat members are good representatives of their communities (SC, ST, OBC, or women)? 19 Can you tell me about any project or services that have been provided for your village or locality during the past five years, including those that have stopped functioning or have been abandoned? a b c d e f g h i j k l
Schools/classrooms Health clinic Water (piped, well, etc.) Latrines Sanitary Communal lands Roads Transportation Agricultural projects Any other (specify) None Do not know
20 Do you know who brought the projects or services that you mentioned to your village? (GS, GP, nongovernmental organizations (NGOs), social groups within village, etc.). If not from the gram panchayat, was any help received from them? 21 Are there any other programs (anti-poverty programs such as JRY, IRDP, etc.) that you are aware of, where the panchayat played a role (i.e., helping target groups, select beneficiaries, etc.). 22 Since the GP elections, have you noticed any changes in the attendance of government employees in the village (teachers, health workers, revenue collectors, etc.)? 23 If there was a change in attendance, why do you think this happened? 24 Since the GP elections, have you noticed any changes in the number of transfers or dismissals of the government employees we have been talking about? 25 If there was a change, why do you think this happened? 26 In general, what do you think are the most important needs of the people in this area? What are the projects that you think are most needed in order to improve people’s wellbeing? 27 In your view, has the GP been able to satisfy any of these needs with its pro jects or services? If yes, in what way? 28 In your view, has this GP done any better than what village government did here before these last local government elections? 29 What do you think needs to be done with regard to the powers of the GP so that they could help you make your life better? 30 If there were some problems in the GP (did something illegal or incorrect), do you think that someone would be likely to hold them accountable? Do you think that the accountability has changed as compared to before the elections?
Appendix C 207
Section D: Quality of governance 31 Do you think that your voice is more likely to be heard now as compared to before the GP elections? If so, why? 32 Do you think that instability/violence in the village has changed? 33 Do you think that government effectiveness has changed? If so, why? 34 Do you think that the regulatory burden (for example, in terms of number of people who have to agree before a project can go ahead) has changed? If so, why? 35 Do you think that the rule of law (in terms of the likelihood that someone who has done something wrong/illegal will be punished by law) has changed any? If so, why? 36 Do you think that corruption, bribery, etc. has changed any? If so, why?
Section E: Social capital 37 Are there any associations in this village? 38 If yes, have you taken part in the activities of any association in the past five years (for example village development association, youth association, women’s association, farmer’s association, cultural associations)? 39 If yes, were you active in this association before the last GP elections? 40 During the last five years, have you engaged in any of the following kinds of activities either on behalf of your village or through your association? a b
c d e
Have you signed any kind of petition, raised an issue, or sent a letter/ taken an issue to the GP? Or to the next level of panchayat? Or district or state government? Have you held a meeting to raise an issue or take action about an issue with the GP, next level of panchayat or state government? If yes, what kind of issue was it and would you have done anything like this before the GP elections? Have you taken part in a protest or demonstration over an issue affecting your community or association? If yes, what kind and would you have done anything like this before the GP elections? Have you met with the GP or its members to thank them for their work? If yes, what kind of work were you thanking them for and would you have done anything like this before the GP elections? Have you organized any refusals to cooperate with the GP or other types of government? If yes, what kind of work were you thanking them for and would you have done anything like this before the GP elections?
41 Have you personally participated in any officially organized local GP or GS meetings, committees, or consultative groups since the GP elections? If yes, were you able to say anything at the meeting? Did you participate in any similar meeting before the elections? If so, did you speak up at the meeting?
208 Appendix A 42 How frequently does your GP representative come to meet you and your constituency now? How does that differ from ten years ago? 43 Have you personally ever contacted any GP representative about any prob lem in your community in the last four years? If yes, what kind of problem was it? Did you find the representative helpful? And would it have been the same ten years ago? Thank you very much for your time and cooperation!
Glossary
Below the poverty line (BPL) A designation of poverty set by the central Government of India. Individuals meeting the definition are issued BPL cards, which make them eligible to access social welfare programs. Corruption The abuse of public, political power for personal gain or for the gain of people who are affiliated through political or familial networks. Employment Assurance Scheme (EAS) A former program for the creation of additional employment opportunities for the rural poor during times of acute shortage of manual wage employment, now replaced by the Mahatma Gandhi National Rural Employment Guarantee Act (MGNREGA). Gram Panchayat (GP) Local government institutions at the village or villagecluster level (depending on state law). Gram Sabha (GS) A meeting of all voting-eligible members of a village. Human Development Index (HDI) A summary composite index measuring a country’s average achievements in three basic aspects of human development longevity, knowledge, and standard of living. Longevity is measured by life expectancy at birth (LEB); knowledge is measured by a combination of the adult literacy rate and the combined primary, secondary, and tertiary gross enrolment ratio; and standard of living by GDP per capita (PPP US$). Indira Awaas Yojana program (IAY) A program for the rural poor providing grants to assist in the construction and upgrading of housing. Integrated Rural Development Program (IRDP) A former program that provides assistance to rural poor in the form of subsidy and bank credit for productive employment opportunities. Jawahar Gram Samridhi Yojana program (JGSY) Program launched in April 1999 to replace the former Jawahar Rozgar Yojana program (JRY) and now replaced by MGNREGA. It was essentially a public works program where demand-driven village infrastructure was built by laborers selected by the Gram Sabha and Gram Panchayat. Laborers were supposed to be people living below the poverty line, with a preference given to SC/ST fam ilies, and were paid through the Gram Panchayats. The program intended to improve the quality of life for the rural poor and provide employment opportunities in times of need.
210 Glossary Jawahar Rozgar Yojana program (JRY) A former rural development program which aimed to generate employment opportunities in rural areas. Kshetra Panchayat (KP) Block-level Panchayats in the state of Uttar Pradesh. Mandal Panchayats (MP) Block-level Panchayats under the 1987 Panchayat system in the state of Karnataka. Public Distribution System (PDS) A program that distributes essential items such as sugar, cereals, and kerosene at subsidized prices to those who have a ration card identifying them as living below the official poverty line. Panchayat Raj Institutions (PRI) The decentralized system of local govern ments set up by the 73rd and 74th amendments to the Indian constitution. Scheduled Caste (SC) The lowest caste group in India, previously known as untouchables. Scheduled castes are accorded special status by the Constitution of India. Swarnjayanti Gram Swarozagar Yojana program (SGSY) A self- employment program for the rural poor, which replaced the former IRDP in April 1999. This program is for the rural poor, with at least 50 percent of its beneficiaries being SC/ST, 40 percent being women and 3 percent disabled. While the selection of activities under this program takes place at the district-level Panchayat, the Gram Sabha of each village is responsible for providing a list of beneficiaries taken from the list of people living under the poverty line. Though this was the program in operation in 2000, most people continued to refer to the program as “IRDP,” and therefore this convention is used in this research. Scheduled Tribe (ST) Original inhabitants or indigenous peoples in India who are accorded special status by the Constitution of India. Taluk Panchayat (TP) Block-level local government institution. Zilla Panchayat (ZP) District-level local government institution.
Notes
Chapter 1 1 Poverty rates refer to the head-count ratio: the proportion of the population living below the official Indian poverty line. The official poverty line is based on a nutritional norm of 2,400 calories per person per day and is defined as the level of average per capita expenditure at which this norm is typically attained. It is set at a per capita monthly expenditure of Rs.49 at October 1973–June 1974 all-India prices. 2 There is much controversy surrounding the exact percentage of people living below the official poverty line in India in 1999–2000, as well as the percentage of poor in the individual Indian states. Estimates of the overall poverty rate in India vary from between 23 to 28 percent, depending on which survey and institute are being quoted. The official incidence of poverty at the national and state levels has been estimated by the Planning Commission based on the large sample surveys on consumer expenditure conducted periodically by the National Sample Survey Organization (NSSO). The 55th round of the NSS was conducted between July 1999 and June 2000. Earlier surveys had calculated monthly per capita consumption based on responses utilizing a 30-day recall period for all items. In this round of the NSS, all consumption expenditures on clothing, footwear, medical and durable goods were measured using a 365-day recall period, while the 30-day recall period was used for all other non-food items. Data on food consumption were collected using a 30-day recall period as well as a seven-day recall. Poverty rates calculated using these different recall periods naturally yielded different poverty rates. Moreover, while the new methods of estimating expenditures on non-food items were introduced to improve the quality of the data, since the method of calculation changed, the latest round of poverty estimates are not strictly comparable to poverty estimates for previous years. This needs to be kept in mind when considering poverty estimates. Chapter 2 1 Social wellbeing is defined as the rate of poverty and basic health and education indicators. 2 Accountability in the context of local governments in India is defined as the willingness to take responsibility for initiating, planning, implementing and delivering on those tasks entrusted to local governments by the 73rd Constitutional Amendment. 3 The methods of collecting and calculating poverty data were changed in 2002/2003, making comparisons with previous estimates difficult. Nevertheless, the same trends in poverty rate reductions continued to hold for the three states of Karnataka, Uttar Pradesh, and West Bengal up to 2010.
212 Notes Chapter 3 1 See for example Kohli (1987) pp. 145–187 for a more complete discussion of state- level politics in Karnataka during the 1970s. 2 See Manor (2006) pp. 10–17 on this analysis, as well as his description of interaction between the Karnataka government and World Bank officials in 2002. I also worked for the World Bank in the mid-1990s and had similar experiences when working on state health projects in Karnataka, West Bengal, Andhra Pradesh, Maharashtra, and Punjab. My experiences echo those found by Manor seven years later: compared to West Bengal and other states, the bureaucracy in Karnataka displayed more continuity and capacity – with obvious benefits for development in the state. 3 The Public Distribution System (PDS) in India is a public program managed jointly by the central and state governments to distribute essential commodities (wheat, rice, sugar, and kerosene) to the poor in order to ensure food security and provide a mechan ism for poverty alleviation. 4 Jawahar Gram Samridhi Yojana (JGSY) is a central government program initiated in April 1999 (replacing two similar previous programs) dedicated to the development of rural infrastructure at the village level. 5 The Swarnjayanti Gram Swarozgar Yojana (SGSY) is also a central government program started in 1999 (replacing the previous IRDP program) targeting the rural poor for self-employment activities through a subsidized micro-credit. The program aims to establish a large number of micro-enterprises in rural areas. Within this target group of rural poor, special safeguards have been provided to vulnerable sections, by reserving 50 percent benefits for SCs/STs, 40 percent for women and 3 percent for disabled persons. The Employment Assurance Scheme (EAS) was launched in 1993 for certain areas of the country, and then extended to the entire country in 1999. It was sub sequently replaced by the National Rural Employment Guarantee Act (NREGA) in 2008, which guarantees 100 days of wage employment in a fiscal year to a rural household whose adult members are willing to work as unskilled laborers at a minimum wage. The selection of people eligible to work under this program is supposed to be decided by the Gram Sabha of each village. The Indira Awaas Yojana (IAY) program is a housing subsidy for the rural poor. 6 Interview with Professor Abdul Aziz on May 3, 2000, ISEC campus, Bangalore and Dr. G. K. Karanth on May 4, 2000, ISEC campus, Bangalore. 7 Interview with Dr. G. K. Karanth on May 4, 2000, ISEC campus, Bangalore; interview with M. Rangaswamaiah, retired teacher, on May 16, 2000 in Mudabal; interview with Mr. Shivanna, Panchayat Extension Officer, Magadi Taluk, on May 16, 2000. Chapter 4 1 The World Institute for Development Economics Research (WIDER) conducted a research project between 1987 and 1990 based at the Visva-Bharati University at Santiniketan, West Bengal. This project on “Rural Poverty, Social Change and Public Policy” was started at the behest of Dr. Amartya Sen. It collected and analyzed data on a wide range of social and economic issues in six West Bengal villages. Two of these villages, Kuchli and Sahahajapur, are the ones selected for my research work. Since the detailed findings from this research project were not published, I am very grateful to Dr. Sunil Sengupta, one of the key planners, implementers and director of this project for giving me access to the findings of their research work. 2 One sharecropper interviewed in Sahahajapur said that despite having his sharecropping registered during the early 1980s, he still continued to sharecrop on a 50–50 basis in order to “keep good relations with the landlord” since he had several members of his household working for the landlord and his household “wellbeing” depended on the good relations with the landlord. The persistence of these original sharecropping ratios has been noted by other researchers (Lieten 1994).
Notes 213 Chapter 5 1 Information on the historical overview was gathered through several conversations with key informants in Palanpur. Similar impressions were noted by Jean Drèze in Lanjouw and Stern (1998). 2 Unless otherwise noted, information in this section is largely based on the previous studies of Palanpur and information received through conversations with Jean Drèze. 3 When seats are reserved for people from a particular background (SC/ST, OBC or female) in UP as well as West Bengal and Karnataka, this is made known before the GP elections by the government officials overseeing the election and at each election the officials ensure that at a minimum the required number of people from each reserved category are standing for elections. 4 Some of those interviewed were quite frank in expressing their views that the village elite had been corrupt and taken much of the money that was to be disbursed for specific social programs during the past for their own pockets and that now it was their turn to get access to these government monies and do the same. 5 For example, a resident of Palanpur, who had even campaigned for the eventual winner of the election for pradhan of Palanpur, recounted that he found out a month after the elections that they had indeed been unfair. He recounted how he had found out from the Assistant District Officer (ADO) that the counting of votes at the Block headquarters in Chandausi was not going in favor of the eventual winner. When he heard of this, he apparently bribed the Block Development Officers to change the vote tally in his favor. The ADO apparently shared this information since he was disgruntled with the fact that he had not received a bribe! 6 The UP Panchayat Act states that each village (defined as either a revenue village or a group of villages) will have these Gram Sabha (village assembly of all eligible voters) meetings twice a year. Meetings are called by the pradhan and require a one-fifth quorum. The Gram Sabha considers development programs, accounts and audit reports, and programs for adult education presented by the Gram Panchayat, the mobilization of voluntary labor, and the identification of beneficiaries for the implementation of development schemes. 7 This information regarding Gram Sabha meetings not actually taking place was higher among the responses for Palanpur than for Pipli. 8 In fact most of those interviewed did not understand the difference between Gram Sabha meetings (village assembly) and Gram Panchayat meetings (meeting of the elected panchayat officials), including some of the panchayat members themselves! 9 The UP Panchayati Raj Act of 1994 “encourages” each GP to form committees on: social justice, development, village education, and public interest in order to help it perform its functions. It also states that the social justice and village education committees should each have at least one female member and one SC/ST member. 10 One of the female, SC panchayat members in Palanpur did not know anything about the structure of Gram Sabha meetings or even the panchayat meetings and had never attended a meeting. She stated that she was illiterate and that she put her thumbprint on documents whenever the pradhan asked her to do so. 11 Of the 16 private interviews conducted in 2008 with key informants of different caste backgrounds in both villages, all informants confirmed that this was the accepted view among local representatives. 12 These figures hardly differed between Palanpur and Pipli, with 27 of the 40 respondents in Palanpur and 23 of the 40 respondents in Pipli stating that social infrastructure was the most important need in the village, while only three respondents in Palanpur and two in Pipli stated that the Gram Panchayat had attempted to address these needs. 13 For example, interviews with Dr. Rohini Nayyar, (Advisor on Rural Development, Planning Commission of India) on March 2, 2000 and Dr. S. P. Gupta (Member, Planning Commission of India), June 24, 1999.
214 Notes 14 Yet when I visited one of these Anganwadi workers in Pipli in March 2000, I was offered these clearly marked biscuits along with tea! 15 My findings support Crook and Manor’s assertion that when power is dispersed into the hands of more people through decentralization, the number of people with influence to peddle rises, though its overall scale might decline (Crook and Manor 1998: 61). 16 Information obtained from accounting records kept by the Block Development Officer Chandausi on March 23, 2000. 17 In an example of the pervasiveness of corruption from the top levels of government down to the Gram Panchayat level, during an interview with the BDO in Chandausi, an assistant came in asking the BDO to sign some documents for the inspection of the District Magistrate’s visit the next day. The BDO looked through the papers and told the assistant to change a figure on spending in one Gram Panchayat from 9,000 to 11,000 “because it would not look good to have such a low figure.” (Interview with Block Development Officer in Chandausi, UP on March 23, 2000). 18 The National Programme of Nutritional Support to Primary Education is commonly called the Midday Meals Scheme. It was launched in August 1995 with the aim of increasing enrollment, attendance, and retention at primary schools, while also improving the nutritional status of students. The program provides cooked meals for children in classes one to four in all government schools. When provisions for cooked meals have not been made, three kilograms of foodgrains (rice and wheat) per child per month are to be given to the child. Chapter 6 1 While the specifics of the Panchayat Act in each of the three states differs slightly, all have in common that they mandate that the Gram Sabha meet twice a year to consider development programs, accounts and audit reports, identification of beneficiaries for development schemes, etc.
Bibliography
Adhikary, S. (2009). Recent Gram Panchayat elections in Kuchli and Shahajapur. R. D. Mullen. Adler, P. A. and P. Adler (1998). Observational techniques. Collecting and Interpreting Qualitative Materials. N. Denzin and Y. S. Lincoln. London, Sage: 79–110. Agrawal, A. and J. Ribot (1999). Accountability in decentralization: A framework with South Asian and West African Cases, Yale University & World Resources Institute. Ahluwalia, M. S. (2000). Economic performance of states in post-reforms period. Economic and Political Weekly. Allan, G. and C. Skinner, Eds. (1991). Handbook for Research Students in the Social Sciences. London, Falmer Press. Alreck, P. L. and R. B. Settle (1995). The Survey Research Handbook: Guidelines and Strategies for Conducting a Survey (2nd). Burr Ridge, IL, Irwin. Alsop, R. and B. Kurey (2005). Local Organizations in Decentralized Development: Their Functions and Performance in India. Washington, D.C., World Bank. Altheide, D. L. and J. M. Johnson (1998). Criteria for assessing interpretive validity in qualitative research. Collecting and Interpreting Qualitative Materials. N. Denzin and Y. S. Lincoln. London, SAGE: 293–312. Andrews, M. and A. Shah (2002). Voice and Local Governance in the Developing World: What is Done, to What Effect, and Why? Washington, D.C., World Bank. Arundhati Bhaumik (2008). Interview. Rani D. Mullen. Shantiniketan, West Bengal. Atteslander, P. (1996). Auf dem Wege zur lokalen Kultur. Einfuehrende Gedanken. Die Street Corner Society. Die Sozialstruktur eines Italienviertels. W. F. Whyte. Berlin, de Gruyter: ix–xiv. Aziz, A. (1993). Decentralised Planning: The Karnataka Experiment. New Delhi, Sage Publications. Aziz, A. (2000). Democratic decentralisation: Experience of Karnataka. Economic and Political Weekly: 3521–3526. Babbie, E. R. (1995). The Practice of Social Research (7th). Belmont, CA, Wadsworth. Bandyopadhyay, D. (2002). Panchayats in Karnataka: Two steps back. Economic and Political Weekly 37(3): 3572–3574. Bandyopadhyay, D. (2008). Panchayats in West Bengal: Unrealized potential. Three Decades of Rural Decentralization in West Bengal: Lessons and Future Options. B. Ghosh. Kolkata, Kalpana Printing House: 154. Banerjee, A., P. Bardhan, K. Basu, M. D. Chaudhuri, M. Ghatak, A. S. Guha, M. Mazumdar, D. Mookherjee, and D. Ray (2002). Strategy for economic reform in West Bengal. Economic and Political Weekly 37(41): 1–34..
216 Bibliography Bangura, A. K. (1992). The limitations of survey research methods in assessing the problem of minority student retention in higher education. San Francisco, Mellon Research UP. Barber, B. (1984). Strong Democracy: Participatory Politics for a New Age. Berkeley and Los Angeles, University of California Press. Bardhan, P. (2002). Decentralization of governance and development. Journal of Economic Perspectives 16(4): 185–205. Bardhan, P., S. Mitra, D. Mookherjee, and A. Sarkar (2008). Political participation, clientelism and targetings of local government programs: Analysis of survey results from rural West Bengal, India. Discussion Paper ERU/2008–0. Kolkata: 57. Bardhan, P. and D. Mookherjee (2004a). Pro-poor targeting and accountability of local governments in West Bengal: 1–62. Bardhan, P. and D. Mookherjee (2004b). Poverty alleviation efforts of Panchayats in West Bengal. Economic and Political Weekly: 965–986. Bardhan, P. and D. Mookherjee (2005). Decentralization and Local Governance in Developing Countries: A Comparative Perspective. Cambridge, MA, MIT Press. Bardhan, P. and D. Mookherjee, Eds. (2006a). Decentralization and Local Governance in Developing Countries – A Comparative Perspective. Cambridge, MA, MIT Press. Bardhan, P. and D. Mookherjee (2006). Land reform, decentralized governance and rural development in West Bengal. Conference on “Challenges of Economic Policy Reform in Asia.” Stanford Center for International Development. Belson, W. A. (1986). Validity in Survey Research. Brookvield, VT, Gower. Bennett, R. J., Ed. (1994). Local Government and Market Decentralization: Experiences in Industrial, Developing and Former East Bloc Countries. Tokyo, United Nations University Press. Bery, D. N. and K. K. Smith, Eds. (1988). The Self in Social Inquiry: Researching Methods. Newbury Park, Sage Publications. Besley, T., R. Pande, L. Rahman, and V. Rao (2004a). The politics of public goods provi sion: Evidence from Indian local governments. Journal of the European Economic Association 2(2–3): 416–426. Besley, T., R. Pande, V. Rao, and R. Ban (2004b). Tokenism or agency? The impact of women’s reservations on Panchayats in South India. Background paper for the World Bank. Washington, D.C., World Bank. Besley, T., T. Persson, R. Pande, and V. Rao (2005). Political competition and economic performance: Theory and evidence from the United States. NBER Working Paper Seroes. Cambridge, MA, National Bureau of Economic Research: 1–53. Besley, T., R. Pande, and V. Rao (2008). The political economy of Gram Panchayats in South India. In Development in Karnataka: Challenges of Governance, Equity and Empowerment. G. K. Kadekodi, R. Kanbur, and V. Rao. New Delhi, Academic Foundation: 243–264. Bhagwati, J. (1998). The design of Indian development. India’s Economic Reforms and Development. I. J. Ahluwalia and I. M. D. Little, Oxford University Press. Bhandari, L. and S. Kale, Eds. (2007a). West Bengal. Indian States at a Glance 2006–07. New Delhi, Pearson Education for Indicus Analytics. Bhandari, L. and S. Kale, Eds. (2007b). Uttar Pradesh. Indian States at a Glance 2006–07. New Delhi, Pearson Education for Indicus Analytics. Bhandari, L. and S. Kale, Eds. (2007c). Karnataka. Indian States at a Glance 2006–07. New Delhi, Pearson Education for Indicus Analytics. Bhattacharya, M. (2002). Panchayat Raj in West Bengal: Democratic Decentralisation or Democratic Centralism? New Delhi, Manak Publications.
Bibliography 217 Bhattacharyya, H. (2002). Making Local Democracy Work in India: Social Capital, Politics and Governance in West Bengal. New Delhi, Vedams. Blair, H. (2000). Participation and accountability in the periphery: Democratic local governance in six countries. World Development 28(1): 21–39. Bliss, C. and N. Stern (1982). Palanpur: The Economy of an Indian Village, Oxford University Press. Braun, J. v. and U. Grote (2002). Does decentralisation serve the poor? Managing Fiscal Decentralisation. A. Ehtisham and V. Tanzi. London, Routledge. Brautigam, D. (2002). Building leviathan: Revenue, state capacity and governance. The New Politics of Taxation and Accountability. M. Moore and L. Rakner. London, IDS Bulletin. 33(3). Braverman, M. (1996). Sources of survey error: Implications for evaluation studies. New Directions for Evaluation: Advances in Survey Research 70: 17–28. Bryman, A. (1992). Quantitative and qualitative research: further reflections on their integration. Mixing Methods: Quantitative and Qualitative Research. J. Brannen. Aldershot, Avebury: 57–80. Buehler-Niederberger, D. (1985). Analytische Induktion als Verfahren qualitativer Methodologie. Zeitschrift fuer Soziologie 14: 475–485. Cadwell, J. C. (1986). Routes to low mortality in poor countries. Population Development Review 12: 171–220. Centre for Economic and Social Studies (2008). Human Development Report 2007: Andhra Pradesh. Hyderabad, Government of Andhra Pradesh Chakrabarty, B. (2008). Indian Politics and Society since Independence. Oxon and New York, Routledge. Chatterjee, B. (1998). Poverty in West Bengal: What have we learnt? Economic and Political Weekly. 33: 3,003–3,014. Chattopadhyay, R. and E. Duflo (2003). The impact of reservations in the Panchayati Raj: Evidence from a nationwide randomized experiment. Economic and Political Weekly. 39: 979–986. Chattopadhyay, R. and E. Duflo (2004). Women as policy makers: Evidence from a ran domized policy experiment in India. Econometrica 72(5): 1,409–1,443. Chattopadhyay, S. S. (2008). Wake-up call. Frontline. New Delhi, The Hindu. 25. Chaudhuri, K. (2003). An emphatic victory. Frontline. New Delhi, The Hindu. 20. Chelliah, R. and R. Sudarshan (1999). Income Poverty and Beyond. New Delhi, Social Science Press. Chhibber, P. and K. Kollman (2004). The Formation of National Party Systems: Federalism and Party Competition in Canada, Great Britain, India, and the United States. Princeton, Princeton University Press. Cohen, J. M. and S. B. Peterson (2000). Administrative Decentralization: Strategies for Developing Countries. Kumarian Press, Inc. Collier, R. B. (1999). Paths Toward Democracy: The Working Class and Elites in Western Europe and South America. Cambridge, UK, Cambridge University Press. Creswell, J. W. (1998). Qualitative Inquiry and Research Design: Choosing Among Five Traditions. Thousand Oaks, CA, SAGE. Crook, R. C. and J. Manor (1998). Democracy and Decentralization in South Asia and West Africa: Participation, Accountability and Performance. Cambridge, UK, Cam bridge University Press. Crook, R. C. and J. Manor (2001). Democracy and decentralization in India. Democracy in India. N. G. Jayal.
218 Bibliography Crook, R. C. and A. S. Sverrisson (1999). To what extent can decentralised forms of gov ernment enhance the development of pro-poor policies and improve poverty-alleviation outcomes? Background Paper for the 2000 World Development Report. Washington, D.C., World Bank. Crook, R. C. and A. S. Sverrisson (2001). Decentralization and poverty-alleviation in developing countries: a comparative analysis or, is West Bengal unique? Brighton, Institute of Development Studies. Cross, S. and M. Kutengule (2001). Decentralisation and rural livelihoods in Malawi. LADDER. Norwich, University of East Anglia. Dahl, R. A. (1971). Polyarchies. New Haven, Yale University Press. Dasgupta, B. (1995). Institutional reforms and poverty alleviation in West Bengal. Economic and Political Weekly: 2691–2708. Datta, P. (1993). The Second Generation Panchayats in India. Calcutta, Calcutta Book House Pvt. Ltd. de Tocqueville, A. (1848). Democracy in America. New York, Perennial Library. de Tocqueville, A. (2001). Democracy in America. New York, Signet Classics. Deaton, A. (2002). Is world poverty falling? Finance & Development 39(2). Deaton, A. (2003). Prices and poverty in India, 1987–2000. Economic and Political Weekly: 362–368. Deaton, A. and V. Kozel (2005). Data and dogma: The great Indian poverty debate. World Bank Research Observer 20(2): 177–199. Deshpande, S. V. and G. B. V. Murthy (2002). Pressures from below: Decentralised governance in Karnataka. Economic and Political Weekly 37(18): 1766–1770. deSouza, P. R. and E. Sridharan, Eds. (2006). India’s Political Parties. Readings in Indian Government and Politics series. New Delhi, Thousand Oaks, and London, Sage. DHNS (2010). Good panchayats can help fight Naxals. Dillinger, W. (1994). Decentralization and its implications for urban service delivery. Urban Management Program Discussion Paper. Washington, D.C., World Bank. Doner, R. and E. Hershberg (1999). Flexible production and political decentralization in the developing world: Elective affinities in the pursuit of competitiveness? Studies in Comparative International Development 34(1): 45–82. Drèze, J. and A. De (1999). Public Report on Basic Education in India. New Delhi, Oxford University Press. Drèze, J., A.-C. Guio, and M. Murthi (1995). Demographic outcomes, economic development and women’s agency – Working Paper No. 28. New Delhi, Centre for Development Economics, Delhi School of Economics. Drèze, J. and A. Sen, Eds. (1996). Indian Development: Selected Regional Perspectives. Oxford and Delhi, Oxford University Press. Drèze, J. and A. Sen (2002). India: Development and Participation. Oxford and New Delhi, Oxford University Press. Eaton, K. (2004). Politics Beyond the Capital: The Design of Subnational Institutions in South America. Stanford, Stanford University Press. Echeverri-Gent, J. (1992). Public participation and poverty alleviation: The experience of reform communists in India’s West Bengal. World Development 20(10): 1401–1422. Election Commission of India (1977–2006). Statistical Reports of Assembly Elections. Retrieved March 1, 2010, from http://eci.nic.in/eci_main/StatisticalReports/ElectionStatistics.asp. Election Commission of India (various years). Statistical Reports of Lok Sabha Elections.
Bibliography 219 Retrieved March 10, 2010, from http://eci.nic.in/eci_main/StatisticalReports/ElectionStatistics.asp. Evans, P. B., D. Reuschmeyer, and T. Skocpol (1985). Bringing the State Back In. Cam bridge, UK, Cambridge University Press. Fielding, N. and R. M. Lee (1998). Computer Analysis and Qualitative Research. London, SAGE. Finance Commission of India (2010). Data collected by the Commission relating to local bodies. New Delhi, Finance Commission of India. Fisman, R. and R. Gatti (2002). Decentralization and corruption: Evidence across coun tries. Journal of Public Economics 83: 325–345. Flick, U. (1994). Social representations and the social construction of everyday know ledge: Theoretical and methodological queries. Social Science Information 2: 179–197. Foster, A. and M. Rosenzweig (2001). Democratization, decentralization and the distribution of local public goods in a poor rural economy, Brown University. Frankel, F. R. (1990). Decline of a social order. Dominance and State Power in Modern India. F. Frankel and M. S. A. Rao. Delhi, Oxford University Press. 2: 482–517. Fukuyama, F. (1991). Liberal democracy as a global phenomenon. PS: Political Science and Politics 1991(4): 659–664. Fukuyama, F. (1992). The End of History and the Last Man. New York, Free Press. Ghatak, M. and M. Ghatak (2002). Recent reforms in the Panchayat system in West Bengal: Towards greater participatory governance. Economic and Political Weekly, January 5. Ghorpade, M. Y. (2002). Karnataka: Strengthening Gram Panchayats. Economic and Political Weekly 37(38): 3,889–3,891. Ghosh, B. (2008). Three decades of rural decentralization in West Bengal: Lessons and future options. Kolkata, Institute of Social Sciences: 154. Ghosh, M. (1998). Agricultural development, agrarian structure and rural poverty in West Bengal. Economic and Political Weekly 33(7/48): 2987–2995. Ghosh, P. (2003). Murder of democracy at the grassroots. Liberation. Ghosh, S. and S. Das (2010). Spatial point process analysis of Maoist insurgency in India. Technical Report #2010–3. Research Triangle Park, NC, Statistical and Applied Mathematical Sciences Institute. Gibson, J. and P. Hanson, Eds. (1996). Transformation from Below: Local Power and the Political Economy of Post-Communist Transitions. Cheltham, UK, Edward Elgar. Gould, H. A. and S. Ganguly, Eds. (1993). India Votes: The Quest for Consensus, 1989 and 1991. Boulder, Westview. Government of India (1948a). Constituent Assembly of India. New Delhi, Government of India. Government of India (1948b). Constitution of India, Article 40. Government of India (Friday, November 25, 1949). Constituent Assembly Debates, XI: 11. Government of India (1957). Report of the Team for the Study of Community Projects and National Extension Service. New Delhi, Government of India. Government of India (1991). 1991 Census, Government of India. Government of India (1992). The Constitution (73rd Amendment) Act, 1992. New Delhi, India. From http://indiacode.nic.in/coiweb/amend/amend73.htm. Accessed January 23, 2010). Government of India (1996). The provision of the Panchayats (Extension to the Scheduled Areas) Act, 1996. Government of India. 40 of 1996.
220 Bibliography Government of India (2001). Census of India. New Delhi, Government of India, Ministry of Home Affairs, Office of the Registrar General & Census Commissioner, India; http://www.censusindia.gov.in/2011-common/censusdataonline.html. Accessed Octo ber 12, 2010 Government of India (2008). Selected socio-economic statistics, India, 2008. Ministry of Statistics and Program. Implementation. New Delhi, Central Statistical Organisation. Government of India (2010). Twenty point programme, 2006 – Progress Report for April–September, 2010. M. o. S. a. P. Implementation. New Delhi, Government of India: 73. Government of India (2011). Provisional population tables and annexes. Census of India. New Delhi, Government of India, Ministry of Home Affairs, Office of the Registrar General & Census Commissioner; www.censusindia.gov.in/2011-prov_rep_tables. html. Accessed April 1, 2011. Government of India: Ministry of Rural Development (2001). Report of the Task Force on Devolution of Powers & Functions Upon Panchayati Raj Institutions New Delhi, Department of Rural Development: 1–93. Government of Karnataka (1987). The Karnataka Zilla Parishads, Taluk Panchayat Samithis, Mandal Panchayats and Nyaya Panchayats Act 1985. Bangalore, Karnataka, Government Press. Government of Karnataka (1993). The Karnataka Panchayat Raj Act 1993. Bangalore, Karnataka, Government Press. Government of Karnataka (1999). Human development in Karnataka 1999. Planning Department. Bangalore, Karnataka, Government Press. Government of Karnataka (2005). Karnataka Human Development Report 2005. Bangalore. Government of Karnataka (2006). Karnataka: Human Development Report 2005. Planning and Statistics Department. Bangalore, Government of Karnataka. Government of Karnataka (2007). Panchayat Raj institutions in Karnataka: Empowering villages. Bangalore, Department of Rural Development and Panchayat Raj. Government of Uttar Pradesh (2001). Government of India. Indian Census, provisional population totals 2001. Retrieved October 15, 2010, from http://www.upgov.nic.in/ upinfo/census01/cen01-6.htm. Government of West Bengal – Development and Planning Department (2005). West Bengal Human Development Report 2004. Human Development Report. Kolkatta: 232. Government of West Bengal (2011). West Bengal State Election Commission. Retrieved March 3, 2011, 2011, from www.wbsec.gov.in/(S(mxpzufifrbk4y145qjmxjauh))/Home. aspx. Accessed March 3, 2011. Granolati, M., M. Shekar, M. Das Gupta, C. Bredenkamp, and Y.-K. Lee (2005). India’s undernourished children: A call for reform and action. HNP Discussion Paper. Washington, D.C., World Bank: 1–93. Grindle, M. S. (2007). Going Local: Decentralization, Democratization, and the Promise of Good Governance. Princeton, NJ, Princeton University Press. Haggard, S. (1990). Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries. Ithaca, NY, Cornell University Press. Hagopian, F. (1994). Traditional politics against state transformation in Brazil. State Power and Social Forces. J. S. Migdal, A. Kohli, and V. Shue. New York, Cambridge University Press. Harriss, J. (1993). What is happening in rural West Bengal?: Agrarian reform, growth, and distribution. Economic and Political Weekly.
Bibliography 221 Harriss, J. (2001). Social capital construction and the consolidation of civil society in rural areas. London, Development Studies Institute, London School of Economics. Hasan, Z. (1989). Dominance and Mobilisation: Rural Politics in Western Uttar Pradesh 1930–1980. New Delhi, Sage Publications. Hasan, Z. (1996). Uttar Pradesh, Persistence of polarization. Frontline: 36–38. Hasan, Z., Ed. (2002). Parties and Party Politics in India. New Delhi, Oxford University Press. Hasan, Z., S. N. Jha, and R. Khan (1989). Class and caste: The dynamics of political change in Uttar Pradesh. The State, Political Processes, and Identity: Reflections on Modern India. New Delhi, Sage Publications. Have, P. T. (1999). Doing Conversation Analysis: A Practical Guide. London, SAGE. Heath, A. and Y. Yadav (2002). The united colors of Congress: Social profile of Congress voters, 1996 and 1998. Parties and Party Politics in India. Z. Hasan. New Delhi, Oxford University Press: 107–149. Heller, P. (2000). Degrees of democracy: Some comparative lessons from India. World Politics 52(July): 484–519. Heller, P. (2006). Building local democracy: Lessons from Kerala. Workshop on Poverty and Democracy. Duke University. Herring, R. (1983). Land to the Tiller. New Haven, Yale University Press. Herring, R. (2007). Agrarian reform for a liberal pattern of society? In Development in Karnataka: Challenges of Governance, Equity and Empowerment. G. Kadekodi, R. Kanbur, and V. Rao. New Delhi, Academic Foundation. Higley, J. and M. Burton (2006). Elite Foundations of Liberal Democracy. New York, Rowman Littlefield Publishers, Inc. Hunter, F. (1969). Community Power Structure: A Study of Decision Makers. Chapel Hill, NC, University of North Carolina. Huntington, S. P. (1991). The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late Twentieth Century. Norman, University of Oklahoma Press. Hust, E. (2007). Political representation and empowerment: Women in the institutions of local government. Decentralization: Institutions and Politics in Rural India. S. Singh and P. K. Sharma. New Delhi, Oxford University Press: 245–277. IndiaStat (2008). Selected state-wise estimates of poverty line and ratio of poverty by Planning Commission in India, (1993–1994 and 1999–2000). New Delhi, Planning Commission of India. Institute of Social Sciences (1995). Status of the Panchayati Raj in the States of India, 1994. New Delhi, Concept Publishing. ISS (2000). Update on the status of the Panchayat Raj. New Delhi, Concept Publishing Co for ISS. Jagdish Chatterjee (2007). Interview. Rani D. Mullen. Sahahajapur, West Bengal. James, R., P. Francis, and G. A. Pereza (2001). The institutional context of rural poverty reductions in Uganda: Decentralisation’s dual nature. Norwich, University of East Anglia. Jha, R. (2000a). Growth, inequality and poverty in India. Spatial and temporal character istics. Economic and Political Weekly. Jha, S. (2000b). Fiscal decentralization in India: Strengths, limitations and prospects for Panchayati Raj Institutions. Overview of Rural Decentralization in India, Volume 3. Washington, D.C., World Bank. Jha, S. N. (1999). Introduction. Decentralisation and Local Politics: Readings in Indian Government and Politics (2). S. N. Jha and P. C. Mathur. London, Sage: 13–44.
222 Bibliography Jha, S. N. and Mathur, P. C. Eds. (1999). Decentralization and Local Politics. New Delhi, Sage Publications. Johnson, C. (2001). Local democracy, democratic decentralisation and rural development: Theories, challenges and options for policy. Development Policy Review 19(4): 521–532. Johnson, C. (2003). Decentralisation in India: Poverty, politics and Panchayati Raj. London, Overseas Development Institute: 1–60. Jones, G. W. and S. Humes (1992). Local governance and national power: A worldwide comparison of tradition and change in local government. Government and Opposition 27(4): 532–537. Kadekodi, G., R. Kanbur, and V. Rao (2006). Governance and development in Karnataka. Bangalore, Karnataka, Symposium in Economic and Political Weekly: 1–112. Karanth, G. K. (1987). Cooperative enterprises and rural development in India: Primary agricultural credit cooperatives in Karnataka – A case study. Mangalore, Mangalore University: 1–90. Karanth, G. K. (1994). Mutual exchange labour in agriculture in a changing rural eco nomy. Bangalore, Institute for Social and Economic Change. Kaufmann, D., A. Kraay, and P. Zoido-Lobaton (2002). Governance matters II: Updated indicators for 2000/2001, World Bank and Stanford University: 1–55. Khanna, B. S. (1999). Rural Local Government in India and South Asia. New Delhi, Deep & Deep. Khemani, S. (July 2000). Decentralization and accountability: Are voters more vigilant in local versus national elections? (working paper), Development Research Group, World Bank. King, R. (1986). The State in Modern Society: New Direction in Political Sociology. Chatham, NJ, Chatham House. Kochanek, S. A. (1968). The Congress Party of India: The Dynamics of One-Party Democracy. Princeton, Princeton University Press. Kohli, A. (1987). The State and Poverty in India – The Politics of Reform. New York, Cambridge University Press. Kohli, A. (1988). India’s Democracy: An Analysis of Changing State-Society Relations. Princeton, Princeton University Press. Kohli, A. (1990). Democracy and Discontent: India’s Growing Crisis of Governability. New York, Cambridge University Press. Kohli, A. (1997). From Breakdown to Order: West Bengal. State and Politics in India. P. Chatterjee. Oxford, Oxford University Press: 336–366. Krishna, A. (2003). Do poor people benefit less from decentralization? American Political Science Association Annual Meeting. Philadelphia. Kumar, G. and B. Ghosh (1996). West Bengal: Panchayat Elections 1993: A study in participation. New Delhi, Institute of Social Sciences. Kvale, S. (1996). Interviews: An Introduction to Qualitative Research Interviewing. London, SAGE. Lal, D. (2000). The Poverty of Development Economics. New Delhi, Oxford University Press. Lanjouw, P. and N. Stern (1998). Economic Development in Palanpur Over Five Decades Oxford University Press. Lerche, J. (1999). Politics of the poor: Agricultural labourers and political transforma tions in Uttar Pradesh. Rural Labour Relations in India. T. J. Byres, K. Kapadia, and J. Lerche. London, Frank Cass Publishers: 182–241.
Bibliography 223 Lieten, G. K. (1992). Continuity and Change in West Bengal. New Delhi, Sage Publications. Lieten, G. K. (1994). What has really happened in West Bengal: Land reforms at the centre stage. Amsterdam, Centre for Asian Studies. Lieten, G. K. (1996a). Development, Devolution and Democracy: Village Discourse in West Bengal. New Delhi, Sage Publications. Lieten, G. K. (1996b). Land reform at centre stage: The evidence on West Bengal. Development and Change 27(1): 111–130. Lieten, G. K. and R. Srivastava (1999). Unequal Partners: Power Relations, Devolution and Development in Uttar Pradesh. New Delhi, Sage Publications. Lijphart, A. (1971). Comparative politics and the comparative method. The American Political Science Review 65(3): 682–693. Lijphart, A. (1996). The puzzle of Indian democracy. American Political Science Review 90(2): 258–268. Mallick, R. (1993). Development Policy of a Communist Government: West Bengal since 1977. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. Manor, J. (1989). Karnataka: Caste, class, dominance and politics in a cohesive society. Dominance and State Power in Modern India. F. R. Frankel and M. S. A. Rao. Delhi, Oxford University Press. I: 322–361. Manor, J. (1997). Karnataka: caste, class, dominance and politics in a cohesive society. Politics in India. S. Kaviraj. New Delhi, Oxford University Press: 262–273. Manor, J. (1999). The political economy of democratic decentralization. Directions in Development. Washington, D.C., World Bank. Manor, J. (2004). Democratization with inclusion: Political reforms and people’s empowerment at the grassroots. Journal of Human Development 5(1): 5–29. Manor, J. (2006). Change in Karnataka over the last generation: Villages and the wider context. Governance and Development in Karnataka. Bangalore: 10–27. Manor, J. (2008). Change in Karnataka over the last generation: Villages and the wider con text. Development in Karnataka: Challenges of Governance, Equity and Empowerment. G. K. Kadekodi, R. Kanbur, and V. Rao. New Delhi, Academic Foundation: 37–62. Marschak, T. (1959). Centralization and Decentralization in Economic Organizations. Econometrica 27(3): 399–430. Mathew, G., Ed. (1994a). Status of the Panchayati Raj in the States of India. New Delhi, Concept Publishing Co. for the Institute of Social Sciences. Mathew, G. (1994b). Panchayati Raj: From Legislation to Movement. New Delhi, Concept Publishing Company. Mathew, G., Ed. (2000). Status of the Panchayat Raj in the States and Union Territories of India. New Delhi, Concept Publishing Co. for Institute of Social Sciences. Mathew, G. and A. Mathew (2003). India: decentralisation and local governance. How clientelism and accountability work. Decentralisation and Democratic Governance: Experiences from India, Bolivia and South Africa. A. Hadenius. Stockholm, Almqvist & Wiksell International: 13–62. Maywood, P. (1987). Decentralisation and the Third World in the 1980s. Planning and Administration 14(1): 10–22. Migdal, J. S., A. Kohli, and V. Shue, Eds. (1994). State Power and Social Forces: Domination and Transformation in the Third World. Cambridge Studies in Comparative Politics. New York, Cambridge University Press. Ministry of Panchayats, Government of India (2007, May 3). Women, representation and empowerment in Panchayats. Retrieved June 10, 2011, from http://pib.nic.in/release/ rel_print_page.asp?relid=27452.
224 Bibliography Ministry of Statistics and Programme Implementation (2008). Statement: Gross state domestic product at current prices. New Delhi, Ministry of Statistics and Programme Implementation. Mishra, R. K. (1997). Paper on the Indian Civil Service. Civil service systems in comparative perspective, Bloomington, Indiana. Mitra, S. (2001). Making local governments work: Local elites, panchayati raj and governance in India. The Success of India’s Democracy. A. Kohli. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 103–126. Moore, M. and J. Putzel (1999). Politics and poverty: A background paper for the World Development Report 2000/1. Brighton, Institute of Development Studies. Moore, M. and L. Rakner (2002). Introduction: The new politics of taxation and account ability in developing countries. IDS Bulletin 33(3). Mukarji, N. (1999). The Third Stratum. Decentralisation and Local Politics: Readings in Indian Government and Politics (2). S. N. Jha and P. C. Mathur. London, Sage: 70–82. Mullen, R. D. (2010). Centralization versus decentralization in Afghanistan: The import ance of sequencing and timing. Building State and Security in Afghanistan, W. Danspeckgruber and R. Finn. Boulder, Lynne Rienner Press: 89–99. Narayana, D. (2005). Local governance without capacity building: Ten years of Panchayati Raj. Economic and Political Weekly: 2822–2832. National Sample Survey Organisation (2005). Perceived adequacy of food consumption in Indian households 2004–2005. New Delhi, Government of India. Nayak, R., N. Saxena, and J. Farrington (2002). Reaching the poor: The influence of policy and administrative processes on the implementation of government poverty schemes in India. Working Paper 175. London, Overseas Development Institute. Nehru, J. (1965). Jawaharlal Nehru on Community Development, Panchayati Raj, and Co-Operation. Delhi, Government of India. Nikolenyi, C. (2010). Minority Governments in India: The Puzzle of Elusive Majorities. New York & Oxon, Routledge. O’Donnell, G., J. V. Cullell, and O. M. Iazzetta, Eds. (2004). The Quality of Democracy: Theory and Applications. Notre Dame, University of Notre Dame. Olson, M. (1982). The Rise and Decline of Nations. New Haven, Yale University Press. Oommen, M. A. (1995). Devolution of resources from the state to the Panchayati Raj institutions: Search for a normative approach. New Delhi, Institute of Social Sciences. Oommen, M. A. and A. Datta (1995). Panchayats and Their Finance. New Delhi, Institute of Social Sciences. Oxhorn, P., J. S. Tulchin, and A. D. Selee, Eds. (2004). Decentralization, Democratic Governance, and Civil Society in Comparative Perspective – Africa, Asia and Latin America. Washington, D.C., Woodrow Wilson Center Press. Pai, S. (2001). Social capital, panchayats, and grassroots democracy: Politics of Dalit Assertion in Uttar Pradesh. Economic and Political Weekly 36(8): 645–654. Pai, S. (2002). Dalit assertion and the unfinished democratic revolution: The Bahujan Samaj Party in Uttar Pradesh. Cultural subordination and the dalit challenge. New Delhi, Sage. Pal, M. (2000). 11th Finance Commission: Transforming panchayats. Economic and Political Weekly. 35: 4379–4382. Palys, T. (1997). Research Decisions: Quantitative and Qualitative Perspectives. Toronto, Ontario, Canada, Harcourt Brace Jovanovich. Parel, A. (1997). Hind Swaraj and Other Writings of M. K. Gandhi. Cambridge, Cam bridge University Press.
Bibliography 225 Parikh, S. (1996). Politics of Preference: Democratic Institutions and Affirmative Action in the United States and India. Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press. Parker, A. N. (1995). Decentralization: The way forward for rural development. Washington, D.C., Agriculture and Natural Resources Department, World Bank. Parker, A. N. and R. Serrano (2000). Promoting good governance through social funds and decentralization. S. P. D. P. Series. Washington, D.C., World Bank. Peterson, G. E. (1997). Decentralization in Latin America: Learning through Experiences. Washington, D.C., World Bank. Pinkney, R. (2003). Democracy in the Third World. Boulder, CO, Lynne Rienner. Planning Commission (March 2007). Poverty estimates for 2004–05. New Delhi, Government of India, Press Information Bureau. Planning Commission (2011). Data tables, #32, percentage of population below poverty line by states & UTs for 61st (2004–05) Rounds. Government of India. Retrieved June 10, 2011, from http://planningcommission.gov.in/data/datatable/1705/final_40.pdf. Polgreen, L. (2010). Right-to-know law gives India’s poor a lever. New York Times. New York. Prud’homme, R. (1995). The dangers of decentralization. World Bank Research Observer 10(2): 201–220. Przeworski, A., M. E. Alvarez, J. A. Cheibub, and F. Limongi, Fernando (2000). Democracy and Development. New York, Cambridge University Press. PTI (2010). 90% polling in Panchayat elections. Outlook India. Lucknow. Pur, K. A. (2006). Selection by custom and election by statute: Interfaces in local governance in Karnataka. Local Governmance in India: Decentralization and Beyond. N. G. Jayal, A. Prakash, and P. K. Sharma. New Delhi, Oxford University Press: 27–46. Putnam, R. D. (1993). Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton University Press. Putnam, R. D. (2000). Bowling Alone. New York, Simon & Schuster. Raghavulu, C. V. and Narayana, E. A. (1999). Reforms in Panchayati Raj: A comparative analysis of Andhra Pradesh, Karnataka and West Bengal. Decentralisation and Local Politics. S. N. Jha and P.C. Mathur. New Delhi, Sage Publications, Ltd. Ragin, C. C. (2000). Fuzzy-Set Social Science. Chicago, University Chicago Press. Ragin, C. C. and H. S. Becker, Eds. (1992). What is a case? Exploring the foundations of social inquiry. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. Rao, A. (2009). The Caste Question: Dalits and the Politics of Modern India. Ranikhet, Permanent Black; co-published with University of California, Berkeley. Rao, G. M., R. Shand, and K. P. Kalirajan (1998). Convergence of incomes in Indian States: A divergent view. IIPF conference. Cordoba, Argentina. Rao, M. G. (2000). Fiscal decentralization in Indian federalism. Bangalore, Institute for Social and Economic Change. Rao, M. G. (2007). Rural fiscal decentralization in India: Problems and reform issues. Decentralization: Institutions and Politics in Rural India. S. Singh and P. K. Sharma. New Delhi, Oxford University Press: 135–153. Rao, M. G., H. K. A. Nath, and B. P. Vani (2004). Rural fiscal decentralisation in Karnataka. Fiscal Decentralization to Local Governments. G. Seethi. New Delhi, Oxford University Press. Reserve Bank of India (2011a). Handbook of Statistics on Indian Economy. Table 4: Net state domestic product at factor cost – state-wise (at current prices) and Table 5: Net state domestic product at factor cost – state-wise (at constant prices). Retrieved June 10, 2011, from http://rbidocs.rbi.org.in/rdocs/Publications/PDFs/4T_HBSE200910.pdf.
226 Bibliography Reserve Bank of India (2011b). State Finances: A Study of Budgets of 2010–11. Mumbai, Reserve Bank of India: 402. Rodriques, V. (2009). Two discourses on democracy in India. Challenges to Democracy in India. R. M. Basrur. New Delhi, Oxford University Press. Rodriquez, V. E. (1997). Decentralization in Mexico: From Reforma Municipal to Solidaridad to Nuevo Federalismo. Boulder, CO, Westview Press. Rondinelli, D. A. (1981). Government decentralisation in comparative Perspective. International Review of Administrative Sciences 47(2): 133–145. Rondinelli, D. A. (1990). Decentralization, territiorial power, and the state: A critical response. Development and Change 21: 491–500. Rondinelli, D. A., J. S. McCullogh, and R. W. Johnson (1989). Analysing decentralisation policies in developing countries: A political-economy framework. Development and Change 20(1): 57–87. Rondinelli, D. A., J. R. Nellis, and G. S. Cheema (1983). Decentralization in developing countries: A review of recent experiences. Washington, D.C., World Bank. Roy, H. and K. Bhattacharjee (2009). Convergence of Human Development across Indian States. Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research. Roy, M. N., Joint Secretary, Rural Development Department, Raj Bhawan (1995). Panchayats as development delivery system – The case of West Bengal. The Administrator 40(2): 95–106. Roy, M. S. (2010). Gender and Radical Politics in India: Magic Moments of Naxalbari (1967–1975). Oxon and New York, Routledge. Rudolph, L. I. and S. H. Rudolph (1987). In Pursuit of Lakshmi: The Political Economy of the Indian State. Chicago, University of Chicago Press. Sandbrook, R., M. Edelman, P. Heller, and J. Teichman (2007). Social Democracy in the Global Periphery: Origins, Challenges, Prospects. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. Schmitter, P. C. and T. L. Karl (1991). What democracy is . . . and is not. Journal of Democracy 2: 75–87. Schoenwalder, G. (1997). New democratic spaces at the grassroots? Popular participation in Latin American local governments. Development and Change 32: 753–770. Scholz, R. W. and O. Tietje (2002). Embedded Case Study Methods. Integrating Quantitative and Qualitative Knowledge. Thousand Oaks, CA, Sage. Scott, J. (1998). Seeing Like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition Have Failed. New Haven, Yale University Press. Sen, A. (1999). Development as Freedom. New York, Alfred A. Knopf. Sengupta, S. (1991). Rural economy and poverty in West Bengal and the public policy intervention: A report of the ‘WIDER’ project on rural poverty, social change and public policy at Santiniketan. Visva-Bharati, Santiniketan. Sengupta, S. and H. Gazdar (1996). Agrarian politics and rural development in West Bengal. Indian Development: Selected Regional Perspectives. J. Drèze and A. Sen. New Delhi, Oxford University Press: 129–204. Sengupta, Sunil et al. (1991). Rural economy and poverty in West Bengal and poverty intervention, the WIDER project on “Rural poverty, social change and public policy,” at Santiniketan: 1–114. Shue, V. (1994). State power and social organization in China. State Power and Social Forces. J. S. Migdal, A. Kohli, and V. Shue. New York, Cambridge University Press. Sibley, G. N. (2002). The enduring left in West Bengal. Princeton, NJ, Princeton University: 22.
Bibliography 227 Singh, H. (1994). Constitutional base for panchayat raj in India. Asian Survey 34(9): 818–827. Singh, H. N. (1993). Social background and role performance of village Pradhans. Occasional Paper Series. New Delhi, Institute of Social Sciences. Singh, P. (2006). The Naxalite Movement in India. New Delhi, Rupa & Co. Singh, P. (2008). Subnationalism and social development: A comparative analysis of Indian states Rethinking Ethnicity and Ethnic Strife: Multidisciplinary Perspectives. Budapest. Singh, S. K. (1999). Panchayati raj finances in Uttar Pradesh. Occasional Paper. Hyderabad, National Institute of Rural Development. Slater, D. (1989). Territorial power and the peripheral state: The issue of decentralization. Development and Change 20: 501–531. Smith, B. C. (1985). Decentralization: the Territorial Diversion of the State. London, George Allen & Unwin. Srivastava, D. K., and C. B. Rao (2009). Review of Trends in Fiscal Transfers in India. Report commissioned by the Finance Commission of India. Chennai, Madras School of Economics. Srivastava, P. (2002). Panchayats, bureaucracy and poverty alleviation in Uttar Pradesh. New Delhi, Jawaharlal Nehru University. Srivastava, T. N. (2002). Local “self ” government and the constitution. Economic and Political Weekly 37(30): 3,190–3,199. Staff reporter (2005a). Karnataka devolves maximum power to its panchayats. Outlook. Staff reporter (2005b). Highest voter turnout in Chikkodi taluk The Hindu. New Delhi. Stake, R. E. (1995). The art of case study research. Thousand Oaks, CA, Sage. Stepan, A. (1978). The State and Society: Peru in Comparative Perspective. Princeton, Princeton University Press. Subha, K. (1996). Karnataka: Panchayat Elections 1995: Process, Issues and Membership Profile. New Delhi, Institute of Social Sciences. Subha, K. (1997). Karnataka: Panchayat Elections 1995: Process, Issues and Membership Profile. New Delhi, Institute of Social Sciences. Sudipto Bhattacharya (2008). Interview. R. D. Mullen. Shantiniketan. Tanzi, V. (1995). Fiscal federalism and decentralisation: A review of efficiency and macro-economic aspects. Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics. Washington, D.C., World Bank. Tanzi, V. and E. Ahmad, Eds. (2002). Managing Fiscal Decentralization. New York, Routledge. Tarrow, S. (1994). Power in Movement: Social Movement and Contentious Politics. Cam bridge, Cambridge University Press. Task Force on Panchayati Raj Institutions (2001). Report of the Task Force on Panchayati Raj Institutions (PRIs) New Delhi, Planning Commission, Government of India: 1–135. Thimmaiah, G. and A. Aziz (1983). The political economy of land reforms in Karnataka, A South Indian state. Asian Survey 23(7): 810–829. Thomas Isaac, T. M. and R. W. Franke (2002). Local Democracy and Development: The Kerala People’s Campaign for Decentralized Planning. Lanham, MD, Rowman & Littlefield. Treisman, D., Ed. (2007). The Architecture of Government: Rethinking Political Decentralization. New York, Cambridge University Press. Turner, M. and D. Hulme (1997). Governance, Administration and Development: Making the State Work. West Hartford, CT, Kumarian Press.
228 Bibliography Umapathy, M. (1998). Rural self-governance in Karnataka. Mysore, Karnataka, Mysore University. Vinod Vyasulu (2007). Local finances after the 73rd amendment. Decentralization: Institutions and Politics in Rural India. S. Singh and P. K. Sharma. New Delhi, Oxford University Press. Wade, R. (1994). Village republics: Economic conditions for collective action in South Asia, Institute for Contemporary Studies. Wallerstein, I. (1976). The Modern World System: Capitalist Agriculture and the Origins of the European World Economy in the Sixteenth Century. New York, Academic Press. Weber, M. (1968). Economy and Society. New York, Bedminster Press. Webster, N. (1992a). Panchayat Raj in West Bengal: Popular participation for the people or the Party? Development and Change 23(4): 160–182. Webster, N. (1992b). Panchayati Raj and the Decentralisation of Development Planning in West Bengal: A Case Study. Calcutta, K. P. Bagchi & Co. Weiner, M. (1989). The Indian Paradox: Essays in Indian Politics. New Delhi, Sage. Westergaard, K. (1986). People’s participation, local government and rural development: The case of West Bengal, India. Copenhagen, Centre for Development Research. Wiley, J. (2000). Democracy, Development and the Institutionalised Participation of the Poor in Poverty Eradication. London. Wood, J. R. (1984). State Politics in Contemporary India: Crisis of Continuity? Boulder, Westview Press. Work, R. (2002a). Overview of decentralization worldwide: as stepping-stone to improved governance and human development. New York, United Nations Development Programme. Work, R. (2002b). The role of participation and partnership in decentralized governance: A brief synthesis of policy lessons and recommendations of nine country case studies on service delivery for the poor. New York, United Nations Development Programme. World Bank (2000a). World Development Report: Attacking poverty. Washington, D.C., World Bank. World Bank (2000b). Overview of rural decentralization in India: Volume I. Washington, D.C., World Bank. World Bank (2000c). Overview of rural decentralization in India. Volume II: Approaches to Rural Decentralization in Seven States. Washington, D.C., World Bank. World Bank (2000d). Overview of rural decentralization in India. Volume III: Background papers. Washington, D.C., World Bank. World Bank (2003). Module A: Decentralization policies and practices – Participant’s manual. Washington, D.C., World Bank, June. World Bank (2004). India: Fiscal decentralization to rural governments. Washington, D.C., Rural Development Unit, South Asia Region, World Bank. World Bank (2005). Decentralization & subnational regional economics – Bank opera tions. Retrieved February 20, 2011, from http://www1.worldbank.org/publicsector/ decentralization/operations.htm. World Bank (2006). Project agreement (Karnataka Panchayats Strengthening Project) between International Development Association and State of Karnataka. Washington, D.C., World Bank: 12. Wunsch, J. S. and D. Olowu, Eds. (1995). The Failure of the Centralized State: Institutions and Self-governance in Africa. San Francisco, ICS Press. Yin, R. K. (1994). Case Study Research: Design and Methods. Thousand Oaks, CA, Sage.
Index
Page numbers in italics denote tables, those in bold denote figures. 11th Finance Commission 39 11th Schedule 34 64th Amendment Bill 30 73rd Constitutional Amendment 20, 31–6, 43, 56–7, 173, 192–3 74th Constitutional Amendment 30, 31 2003 elections 131, 133 2008 elections 133 absolute poverty 2 accountability: comparison 178; and decentralization 8, 44; Karnataka Panchayat Act 76–7; and local elections 11; of local governments 18; and local taxation 190; Uttar Pradesh 154–8, 159, 169; West Bengal 113–18, 122–3 accountability mechanisms 189 administrative burden 77–8, 79, 123, 159–60 administrative decentralization 35–6 administrative quality 77–8, 123–4 adult education 113 agency 151 agricultural laborers 102–3 agricultural reforms 54 agriculture 143 AITC (All-India Trinamul Congress Party) 114, 133, 134 Ambedkar, B. R. 23, 24 Andhra Pradesh 29 anti-malaria program 140, 166 anti-poverty program beneficiaries 128–9, 130 anti-poverty programs 72, 129–30, 153–4, 172 Article 243G 34, 36, 192 Article 243H 36
Article 243I 36 Article 356 24–5 Ashok Mehta Committee 29, 30, 56 Ashraf Muslims 143 associations 81, 83 Bahujan Samaj Party (BSP) see BSP Balwantrai Mehta Committee 28 Bangalore Rural District 63, 64–6, 66–74, 82 Bangla-Congress-led United Front government 97 Bankura 134 Bardhan, P. 130 Basu, Jyoti 98, 132 below the poverty line (BPL) 209 Bhattacharya, Buddhadeb 132 Bihar 14, 22, 172 Birbhum District 101, 134 BJP (Bharatiya Janata Party) 133 BLD (Bharatiya Lok Dal) 143 book overview 18–19 Brahmins 143 “bridging” associations 81, 83 British period 27 BSP (Bahujan Samaj Party) 144 bureaucracy 55, 123–4 case study: argument 47–51; and decentralization 46; methodology 15, 194–200, 201–3; selection method 14, 195–6; village selection 14–15, 16 caste system 21, 53, 71, 148, 162–3 center–state relationship 27 Central Rule 24–5 Chattopadhyay, R. 43 citizen participation 109
230 Index civic action 152–3 civil service system 43 civil society: and elites 80–1; Karnataka 83; West Bengal 137; Uttar Pradesh 141 civil society advocates 7 civil society engagement 176 civil society mobilization 11–12, 18, 185 class 162–3 class politics 98 clientelism 125 coalition politics 26–7 collective action 148–9, 151–2, 163–5, 176–7 committees 60, 124, 151, 160, 167, 176, 213n9 Communist Party of India (Marxist) see CPI(M) competition 10–11, 137, 139 competitive politics 54, 55–7 conferences: Panchayat Mahila Shakti Abhiyan 61 Congress Party 25, 28, 29, 30, 54, 56, 97–8, 133–4, 143 Constituent Assembly 23, 24 context, historical 3 corruption 209; and civil service 44; comparison 179–80; decreased 58; Gram Panchayat elections 87; Karnataka 73, 78; local elections 108; perceptions of 73, 78; and transparency 79–80; Uttar Pradesh 154–8, 161, 167, 186; West Bengal 114–18 CPI(M) (Communist Party of India (Marxist)) 91, 93, 97, 105, 110, 113, 131, 133 CPI(M) (Communist Party of India (Marxist)) members 114, 115–16, 120, 121, 125, 128–9, 130 Crook, Richard C. 84 data collection: methodology 198–9 de Tocqueville, A. 11 decentralization: 73rd Constitutional Amendment 31–5; administrative 35–6; background 1–2; benefits 4, 8–9; case study 46; definition 46; and development 7–9; fiscal 36–42; historical background 27–31; implementation 22–7; importance 20–2; literature 8–9; meaning of 6; mixed outcomes 10–13; political 42–5; rationale 20; and state reform 5–7; supporters 7, 173
decentralization process: understanding 9–10 decentralization programs: studies on 2–3 democracy 8, 10–11, 12, 18, 22–7, 46, 74, 168–9 democratization 12 Desai, Morarji 56 development: and decentralization 7–9 District Rural Development Agency (DRDA) see DRDA domestic product growth rates: Karnataka 53; West Bengal 93 DRDA (District Rural Development Agency) 44 Duflo, E. 43 economic crisis (1991) 27 economic growth rates 47, 53, 172–3, 183 economic liberalization 27 education 163–4 elections 11, 67, 68, 69, 106–11, 131–4, 149–51, 175 electoral fraud 131–2, 150 elite capture 43, 46, 47, 49, 130, 138–9, 186 elite power 3, 11, 12–13, 18 elites 12–13, 28, 80–1, 145, 185–7; see also village elites emergency laws 98 Emergency Rule 29 Employment Assurance Scheme (EAS) 209 enhanced participation 8 familial relationships 11 federal structure 23, 24, 27 female to male ratios 21, 55, 63, 102, 146–7, 196 field research questionnaire 204–8 fiscal decentralization 36–42 food-for-work program 35 G. V. K. Rao Committee 30 Gandhi, Indira 29, 44, 56, 98 Gandhi, Mahatma 23, 27 Gandhi, Rajiv 30, 172 Gavi Nagamangala 63, 64–6, 66–74, 81–5, 88–90; see also Karnataka gender divides 135 gender inequality 21 girls: quality of life 21 governance: quality of 75–83, 167
Index 231 government effectiveness 77, 123–4, 159–60, 178, 183–7 government structure 94–5 Gowda, H. D. Deve 54 Gram Panchayat elections 67, 69, 106–11 Gram Panchayat representatives 67, 120, 151 Gram Panchayats 209; functions of 59; Karnataka 59–62, 87–8, 90; nationalist movement 27; and social wellbeing 181–3; structure 32; successful functioning 173–4; Uttar Pradesh 145, 149–51; West Bengal 94; work done 177–8 Gram Sabha meetings 109–10, 137, 150–1 Gram Sabhas 32, 33–4, 57, 70, 83, 209 Gram Sansad meetings 109–10 Green Revolution 142 Grindle, Merilee 4 growth rates: and social indicators 21–2 Gujarat 21, 22 Haryana 21, 22 health care provision 112, 113 health indicators 21 health services 166 historical context 3 Human Development Index (HDI) 209 IAS (Indian Administrative Service) 43, 44 IAY (Indira Awaas Yojana) see Indira Awaas Yojana ICDS (Integrated Child Development Program) 140 illiteracy 1, 20, 21, 188; see also literacy IMRs (infant mortality rates) 21, 52, 96, 147 independence movement 27 Indian Administrative Service (IAS) see IAS Indian National Congress (INC) 25 Indira Awaas Yojana (IAY) 73, 127, 209 inequality 20, 48 infant mortality rates (IMRs) see IMRs “informants” 15 infrastructure 112 Integrated Child Development Program (ICDS) see ICDS Integrated Rural Development Program (IRDP) loans see IRDP (Integrated Rural Development Program) loans intra-country analyses 13–14 IRDP (Integrated Rural Development
Program) loans 127, 129–30, 166–7, 209 Jamboni block 134 Jammu 29 Janata Dal Party (JD) 54, 55–6, 59, 143, 144 Janata Party government 25, 29 Jatabs 148, 163 Jawahar Gram Samridhi Yojana (JGSY) 72, 127, 209 Jawahar Rozgar Yojana program (JRY) 210 JD (Janata Dal Party) see Janata Dal Party JGSY (Jawahar Gram Samridhi Yojana) see Jawahar Gram Samridhi Yojana Karanth, G. K. 63 Karnataka: administrative burden 77–8, 79; Ashok Mehta Committee’s recommendations 29; background 52–3; bureaucracy 55; caste hierarchy 71; civil society 83; civil society mobilization 185; government quality 179–80; Gram Panchayats 72–5; improved wellbeing 83–5; local elites 186–7; new panchayat system 67–72; panchayat governments 16, 17, 55–8; participation 69; political competition 17, 184–5; political context 53–5; poverty reduction rates 47, 48; quality of governance 75–9; selection for case study 14; social indicators 16, 22, 55; social wellbeing 182; social wellbeing improvement 81–5, 88–90; socioeconomic context 53–5; village case studies 62–7, 85–90 Karnataka Panchayat Raj Act 58–62 Kashmir 29 Kerala 14, 21, 22, 52, 103 key indicators: in research states 50, 52 Kohli, Atul 137 Kshetra Panchayat (KP) 210 Kuchli 101–3, 105–6; see also West Bengal L. M. Singhvi Committee 30 land redistribution 102, 117 land reforms 102, 137, 144 large-scale studies 15–16 Left Front Government (LFG) see LFG legitimacy 5–6 LFG (Left Front Government) 91, 93, 95, 98–9, 100–1, 102–3, 125, 131–2, 133, 178 Lieten, G. K. 137
232 Index Lingayats 54, 58 literacy 49, 52, 100; see also illiteracy literacy rates: Bangalore Rural District 63, 64; Birbhum District 101; Gavi Nagamangala 82; Karnataka 52, 55, 88; Kuchli 103; Moradabad District 146; Mudabal 82; Sahahajapur 103; Uttar Pradesh 142; West Bengal 96, 101, 103, 118 literature: on decentralization 8–9 local democracy 105 local elections see elections local elite capture 44, 49 local elites: and political power 3, 11, 12–13; see also village elites local governance: differing depths of 172; history 27–31; path dependency 47; quality of 178–80; theories 10–13 local governments: and competition 18; effectiveness 3, 178, 183–7; enabling factors 183–7; and improved wellbeing 83–5; perception of 118–19; responsiveness 111–12; revenue 36–42; and social wellbeing 47, 83–5, 187–91; sociopolitical factors 173–4 local revenue raising 190 Maharashtra 21, 103 Mahatma Gandhi Rural Employment Guarantee Act 62 malaria 140 malnourishment 21 management frameworks 8–9 Mandal Panchayats (MP) 56, 210 Manor, James 57, 84 Maoist guerilla movement 134, 136 market-oriented reforms 36 maternal mortality rates (MMRs) see MMRs meetings 109, 137, 150–1, 180–1 methodology: case selection 195–6; data collection 198–9; overview 15, 194; previous village research 196–8; village selection 196; village surveys 199–200, 201–3 “Midday Meals Scheme” 159, 166, 214n18 MMRs (maternal mortality rates) 21, 96 Mookherjee, D. 130 Moradabad District 146 MP (Mandal Panchayats) see Mandal Panchayats Mudabal: 2000 and 2008 66–74; early 1990s 64–6; selection 63; social
wellbeing improvement 81–5, 88–90; see also Karnataka Muslims 143, 144, 148, 163 Nandigram 133 Narayan, Jayaprakash 55 National Front government 30 national health programs 140 national microenterprise program 35 national parties 25–7 National Programme of Nutritional Support to Primary Education see “Midday Meals Scheme” Naxalites 97 Nehru, Jawaharlal 25, 28 neoliberalism 7 OBCs (other backward castes) 60, 85, 144, 145, 149, 162, 169 “Operation Bargha” 118 other backward castes (OBCs) see OBCs overview of book 18–19 Palanpur 1, 140, 146, 147; see also Uttar Pradesh Panchayat Act 16 panchayat elections 28–9, 42 panchayat government implementation 16–17 Panchayat Mahila Shakti Abhiyan 61 panchayat members 111–12, 176 “panchayat raj” 28 Panchayat Raj Amendment see 73rd Constitutional Amendment Panchayat Raj Devolution Index 39 Panchayat Raj Institutions (PRIs) see PRIs Panchayat Raj system 56 panchayat structure 32; awareness of 150–1, 176 panchayat system: perception of 174–7 panchayats 27–8, 181–3; see also Gram Panchayats parliamentary elections 25 participation: enhanced 8, 69; in local elections 106–11; in local government 177 participation rates 70 Party (BJP (Bharatiya Janat) see BJP party affiliation: and welfare programs 115–17 party competition 104 party politics 107–9, 125–6 path dependency: local governance 18, 47 patriarchical caste-based elites 27, 28
Index 233 patronage 22, 29, 125, 178 patronage networks 145, 178 patron–client relationships 11 PDS (Public Distribution System) 1, 72, 159, 210 Pipli 146, 147; see also Uttar Pradesh political competition 17, 18, 46, 54, 55–7, 120–1, 130, 137, 139, 184–5 political decentralization 42–5 political elite 130 political landscape: Karnataka 53–5; Uttar Pradesh 143–5; West Bengal 131–4 political mobilization 11 political parties 25–7, 62, 83, 125–6 political power: and elites 12–13; location of 23; redistribution 3; West Bengal 121 political stability 8, 97, 98, 178 poverty line 21 poverty rates: decline of 20; definition 211n1.2; India 2; Karnataka 52; Uttar Pradesh 142–3, 147; West Bengal 99, 103 poverty reduction 183 poverty reduction programs 15–16, 35, 44, 48–9 poverty reduction rates 47–8 power relationships 12–13 President’s Rule 24–5 primary schools 112–13 prime ministers: and Uttar Pradesh 143 PRIs (Panchayat Raj Institutions) 29, 35, 39, 40–1, 210 pro-poor governments 48, 172–3, 183 pro-poor policies 21 pro-poor programs 130 Provisions of the Panchayats (Extension to the Scheduled Areas) Act, 1996 33–4 public administration 8–9 public choice theories 9 Public Distribution System (PDS) see PDS public projects 112 Putnam, Robert 11, 81 quality of life 20–1 questionnaire, field research 204–8 Rao, Narasimha 30 regional differences: social wellbeing 21, 22 research contribution 5 reserved seats: 73rd Amendment 33, 44–5; and accountability 156; and corruption 156; Karnataka 68–9, 87; Karnataka Act 60; panchayat system 51; studies of 43;
Uttar Pradesh 154, 161–2, 213n3; West Bengal 120 resource management 38–9 resources: at local level 189–90 “respondents” 15 responsiveness 8 Right to Information Act (RTI) 60, 189 Right to Information (RTI) campaign 189 rights: awareness of 134, 135, 136, 142, 158, 188 Ripon Resolution 27 RTI (Right to Information Act) see Right to Information Act rule of law: Karnataka 78–9; Uttar Pradesh 160; West Bengal 124–5 rural employment guarantee program 35 rural housing program 35 rural poverty 20 safety-net programs 21 Samajwadi Party (SP) see SP Santhanam, K. 28 “Scheduled Areas” 33 Scheduled Castes (SCs) see SCs Scheduled Tribes (STs) see STs schools 163–4 SCs (Scheduled Castes) 210; 73rd Amendment 33, 44–5; Gram Panchayat representatives 120; Karnataka 57, 67, 87, 121; Karnataka Panchayat Raj Act 60; panchayat system 51; Pipli 149; studies 43; Uttar Pradesh 144, 161–2; West Bengal 106 Sen, Amartya 5, 46 sex ratio see female to male ratios SFCs (State Finance Commissions) 39 SGSY (Swarnjayanti Gram Swarozgar Yojana) see Swarnjayanti Gram Swarozgar Yojana Shahajapur 101–3, 105–6; see also West Bengal sharecroppers 102 Singur 133 social capital 11–12 social cleavages 46, 135, 145, 148–9, 162–3, 178, 180–1 social elites 80–1 social engineering 33 social hierarchy 43 social indicators 14, 20, 21–2, 52, 66, 95, 99, 118, 142–3 social inequality 161–5 social interaction 162–3, 169–70, 180–1 social mobilization 46
234 Index social programs 153–4, 189 social reform 96 social services: delivery mechanisms 49; pre-1993 49 social stratification 18 social welfare 119–20 social welfare advocates 7 social welfare programs 71, 72–3 social welfare recipients 128–9, 130 social wellbeing: definition 46, 211n2.1; factors for improvement 174; impact of panchayats 181–3; improvements 2, 4, 88–90; in Karnataka 81–5; lack of progress 21; and local government 187–91; regional differences 21; Uttar Pradesh 165–71; West Bengal 126–31 socioeconomic indicators 146 socioeconomic welfare 47 sociopolitical conditions: importance of 173–4 sociopolitical elites 185–7 SP (Samajwadi Party) 144 state elections 67 State Finance Commissions (SFCs) see SFCs state parties 25–7 state reform: and decentralization 5–7 STs (Scheduled Tribes) 210; 73rd Amendment 33, 44–5; disadvantaged 130–1; Gram Panchayat representatives 120; Karnataka 57, 67, 68, 87, 121; Karnataka Panchayat Act 60; panchayat system 51; studies 43; Uttar Pradesh 161–2; West Bengal 106 studies: on decentralization programs 2–3, 35; on panchayat system 35; STs and SCs 43 subnational cohesion 48 subnational parties 26–7 substantive democracy 23 survey results 67 Swarnjayanti Gram Swarozgar Yojana (SGSY) 72, 210 Taluk Panchayats (TP) 56, 210 Tamil Nadu 103 Tata automobile manufacturing 133 taxation, local 190 tenancy reform 102 Thungon, P. K. 30 Tocqueville, A. de 11 top-down interventions 172 TP (Taluk Panchayats) see Taluk Panchayats
transparency 44, 79, 90 Trinamul Congress Party 133–4 tuberculosis (TB) program 140, 166 UF (United Front) 97 United Provinces Panchayat Raj Act of 194 145 urban poverty 20 Urs, Devraj 54 Uttar Pradesh: 1994 amendment acts 145–6; accountability 154–8, 159, 169; administrative burden 159–60; agency 151; anti-poverty programs 153–4; background 142–3; civic action 152–3; collective action 148–9, 151–2, 163–5; corruption 154–8, 161, 167; decentralization amendment 187; early 1990s 147–8; education 140, 163–4, 166; elections 149–51; government quality 167, 178–9; Gram Panchayats 149–51; Gram Sabha meetings 150–1; health services 166; identity-based parties 144; land reforms 144; literacy 142; local elites 145, 170, 185–6, 187; local governance conditions 16, 17; low-functioning case 141; new panchayat system 149–54; panchayat system 141; panchayats 42, 145; political competition 185; population 14, 142; poverty 147; poverty rates 142–3; poverty reduction rates 48; quality of governance 158–61; reserved seats 154, 161–2; resource targeting 172; rule of law 160; schools 163–4; SCs (Scheduled Castes) 161–2; selection for case study 14; selection of villages 146–7; social engagement 152–3; social indicators 16, 22, 142–3, 146–7; social inequality 161–5; social interaction 169–70; social issues before 2000 144; social programs 153–4; social wellbeing 165–71, 181–2; socioeconomic and political context 143–5; socioeconomic indicators 146; STs (Scheduled Tribes) 161–2; survey question results 170; violence 160; voice 161 Uttar Pradesh Kshetra Panchayat and Zilla Panchayat Adhiniyam of 1961 145 Uttaranchal 173 village elites 71–2, 104, 130, 131, 170, 177–8; see also local elites village governments 22 village research, previous: methodology 196–8
Index 235 village selection: case study 14–15, 16; methodology 196 village studies: value of 15–16 village surveys: methodology 199–200, 201–3 violence: 2003 elections 131, 132–3; Karnataka 78; perception of 78, 124–5; Uttar Pradesh 160; West Bengal 117, 124–6, 131–4, 138 voice 76, 120–2, 161, 178 Vokkaligas 54, 57, 64 voter participation 106–11, 149–50 voter turnout 106–7, 149–50, 174–5 West Bengal: 73rd Amendment 91; accountability 113–18, 122–3; administrative burden 123; Ashok Mehta Committee’s recommendations 29; case studies 102–5; case studies overview 99–101; case studies selection 101–2; civil society 91–2; civil society mobilization 185; class politics 98; corruption 114–18, 124–6; decentralized government 93–7; elections 98–9, 131–4; functioning local government 91–2; government quality 179; government structure 94–5; Gram Panchayat elections 106–11; Gram Panchayats 104, 105–6, 112–13; historical context 92; infrastructure 112; land reform program 102; leftist parties 97–8; local elections 106–11; local elites 186; panchayat governments 16,
17; participation in local elections 106–11; party competition 104; perception of local government 118–19; perception of Panchayat system 105–6; political competition 17, 184; political context 97–9; political landscape 131–4; poverty rates 99; poverty reduction rates 48; public projects 112; quality of governance 119–26; responsiveness of local governments 111–12; selection for case study 14; size 96–7; social improvements 99, 137; social indicators 16, 21, 92–3, 95, 99, 103, 118, 126, 129; social reform 96; social wellbeing 126–31, 134–9, 182; stability 132; survey question results 138; village elites 104; voter participation 106–11 West Bengal Panchayat Act 94 West Bengal Panchayat (Amendment) Act 104 West Midnapore 134 WIDER study 101, 103, 129 women: Gram Panchayat representatives 67–8; Karnataka 87–8; reserved seats 33, 43, 44–5, 51, 57, 60, 106, 120 World Bank studies 4, 44 Zilla Panchayats 57, 210 Zilla Parishads (ZP) 56 “Zilla Parishads, Taluk Panchayat Samitis, Mandal Panchayats and Nyaya Panchayats Act” 56 ZP (Zilla Parishads) see Zilla Parishads