245 13 8MB
English Pages 242 [253] Year 2018
I5EA5 Institute of Southeast Asian Studies The Institute of Southeast Asian Studies was established as an autonomous organization in May 1968. It is a regional research centre for scholars and other specialists concerned with modern Southeast Asia, particularly the multi-faceted problems of stability and security, economic development, and political and social change. The Institute is governed by a twenty-two-member Board of Trustees comprising nominees from the Singapore Government, the National University of Singapore, the various Chambers of Commerce, and professional and civic organizations. A ten-man Executive Committee oversees day-to-day operations; it is chaired by the Director, the Institute's chief academic and administrative officer. The ASEAN Economic Research Unit is an integral part of the Institute, coming under the overall supervision of the Director who is also the Chairman of its Management Committee. The Unit was formed in 1979 in response to the need to deepen understanding of economic change and political developments in ASEAN. The day-to-day operations of the Unit are the responsibility of the Co-ordinator. A Regional Advisory Committee, consisting of a senior economist from each of the ASEAN countries, guides the work of the Unit.
Growth and Spatial Equity in West Malaysia
edited by
Ludwig H. Schatzl translated by
Verna Freeman
Research Notes and Discussions Paper No. 63 ASEAN Economic Research Unit INSTITUTE OF SOUTHEAST ASIAN STUDIES
1988
Published by Institute of Southeast Asian Studies Heng Mui Keng Terrace Pasir Panjang Singapore 0511 All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise, without the prior permission of the Institute of Southeast Asian Studies.
© 1988 Institute of Southeast Asian Studies
The responsibility for facts and opinions expressed in this publication rests exclusively with the author and his interpretations do not necessarily reflect the views or the policy of the Institute or its supporters. Cataloguing in Publication Data Growth and spatial equity in West Malaysia I edited by Ludwig Schatzl. (Research notes and discussions paper I Institute of Southeast Asian Studies; no. 63) 1. Malaysia --Economic conditions. 2. Malaysia-- Economic conditions-- Regional disparities. 3. Malaysia-- Economic policy. 4. Malaysia-- Industries. I. Schatzl, Ludwig. 11. Institute of Southeast Asian Studies. Ill. Series. DS501 I596 no. 63 1988 ISBN 9971-988-79-8 ISSN 0129-8828 Printed in Singapore by General Printing & Publishing Services Pte Ltd
CONTENTS
List of Tables List of Figures Foreword I II
IV Vll
1
Polarization Reversal in Developing Countries? Ludwig Schiitzl Economic Development and Economic Policy in Malaysia Ludwig Schatzl
3
27
Ill Spatial Disparities in West Malaysia Heidrun Frohloff-Kulke
53
IV Development of Industrial Systems in West Malaysia Knut Koschatzky
96
V
Limiting Factors in Industrialization: A Case Study of Kelantan Elmar Kulke
Ill
169
LIST OF TABLES
Il.1
Indicators of Socio-Economic Development in Malaysia (1960, 1982)
33
Il.2
Public Development Expenditure in Malaysia 1956-85 (in%)
37
11.3
Structural Differences between West and East Malaysia
50
III.1
Indicators used in the Study
58/59
111.2
Population, Rank, and Average Annual Growth Rate of the 50 Largest Settlements in West Malaysia
62/63
III.3
III.4
111.5
111.6
Factor Loadings for the First Factor (factor of socio-economic development) for 1970 and 1980 for the Federal States of West Malaysia
77
Factor Scores for the Federal States of West Malaysia in 1970 and 1980 ranked according to 1980 Scores
80
Factor Loadings for the First Factor (factor of socio-economic development) for 1970 and 1980 for the Districts of West Malaysia
81
Factor Scores for the Districts of West Malaysia 1970 and 1980 lV
83/84
List of Tables v Distribution of Industrial Employment in the Federal States, 1959-81
100/101
IV.2
Distribution of Industrial Value Added in the Federal States 1963-81
104
IV.3
Industrial Growth Rates in the Federal States, 1962-81
106
IV.4
Shift-Share Analysis between the Federal States, 1963-81
111
IV.5
Measures of Concentration, 1959-81
116
IV.6
Weighted Coefficient of Variation between the Districts, 1968-81
121
IV.1
IV. 7 IV.8
Industrial Growth Rates in the Districts of West Malaysia, 1973-81
130/131
Distribution of Industrial Employment in the Districts, 1973 and 1981
132/133
IV.9
Growth Rates according to Size of District, 1973-81
148
V.1
Data on Labour in West Malaysia
188
V.2
Evaluation of Location Factors: Labour
189
V.3
Evaluation of Location Factors: Enterpriserelated Infrastructure
191
V.4
Evaluation of Location Factors: Natural Resources and Suppliers
195
Evaluation of Location Factors: Contacts with Service Enterprises and Administrative Bodies
198
V.5
vi List of Tables V.6
Evaluation of Location Factors: Regional Demand Supraregional Contacts
200
V. 7
Evaluation of Location Factors: Regional Policy
200
V.8
Incentives Granted according to Type and Size of Enterprise
203
V.9
Evaluation of Location Factors: Other Factors
205
V.l 0
Locational Profile
208
LIST OF FIGURES
Balancing of Factor Prices by Factor Mobility according to Neoclassical Theory
8
1.2
Mechanism of Cumulative Causation according to Polarization Theory
9
I.3
Sequence of Stages in Spatial Organization
12
I.4
Relationship between Level of Development and Regional Economic Growth (cross-sectional analysis of 24 countries)
19
Relationship between Level of Development and City Size Distribution (cross-sectional analysis of 38 countries)
20
1.6
Model showing Demographic Transition, Natural Population Growth and Rural-Urban Migration
21
1.7
Relationship between Level of Development and Personal Income Distribution (cross-sectional analysis of 66 countries)
23
Spatial Economic Policy in West Malaysia (1982}
40
II.2 Spatial Economic Policy in East Malaysia ( 1982)
44
III.l Relationship between Rank and Population
57
1.1
1.5
II.1
Vll
vm List of Figures 111.2 Rank-Size Distribution of the 50 Largest Settlements in West Malaysia 1957, 1970, 1980
64
III.3 Spatial Distribution of Settlements in West Malaysia
67/68
III.4 Average Annual Growth Rate of Settlements in West Malaysia
69/70
III.5 Factor of Socio-Economic Development for West Malaysia according to States
78f79
III.6 Factor of Socio-Economic Development for West Malaysia according to Districts
85/86
Ill. 7 Factor of Socio-Economic Development in West Malaysia 1970/80. Changes in Factor Scores 1970/80
89
IV.1 Shift-Share Analysis 1973-81 (Employment)
109
IV.2 Weighted Coefficients of Variation 1959-81 (State Level)
117
IV.3 Gini-Coefficients 1959-81 (State Level)
118
IV.4 Weighted Coefficients of Variation, 1968-81 (District Level)
120
IV.5 Industrial Locations, 1968, 1973
124
IV.6 Industrial Locations, 1973, 1981
125
IV. 7 Level of Industrialization, 1973
128
IV.8 Regional Growth Pattern, 1973-81
134
IV.9 Level of Industrialization, 1981
139
List of Figures IV.lO Sectoral Growth Pattern 1973-81 (Employment, Value Added) IV.ll
Locations of Manufacturing Industries, 1981
IX
140 142
IV.12 Location-Oriented Industries
144
V.1
Mode of Spatial Development
174
V.2
Diagram of Regional Disparities in West Malaysia 1971,1980
178
V.3
Location and Spatial Elements
180
V.4
Agricultural Land and Population according to Location
183
V.5
Kelantan -- Industrial Structure 1981
185
V.6
Locational Profile
208
V.7
Model of Industrial Effects
213
V.8
Spatial Linkages: Input
216
V.9
Spatial Linkages: Output
217
V.10
Spatial Linkages: Services
220
V.ll
Spatial Linkages: Labour
224
V.12
Spatial Linkages: Income
225
V.13
Spatial Linkages: Locations of the Headquarters
228
V.14
Spatial Linkages: Means of Production
229
FOREWORD
The collection of papers in this volume present the initial findings of a research project undertaken by members of the Department of Economic Geography of the University of Hanover and financed by the Volkswagen Foundation. The research was supervised by Paul Chan (Kuala Lumpur) and Ludwig Schatzl (Hanover). The main objective of the project was the empirical testing of H.W. Richardson's polarization reversal hypothesis, using Malaysia as a case study. According to Richardson's hypothesis, a reversal in the process of spatial concentration, that is, intra- and interregional decentralization, also occurs in developing countries. Chapter I presents the concept of polarization reversal. The basic features of economic development and economic policy in Malaysia are examined in Chapter II. Chapters III and IV are devoted to the analysis of long-term changes in spatial disparities and of industrial location patterns. In the final chapter an attempt is made to identify the factors limiting industrialization in Kelantan, a federal state in Malaysia with a peripheral location. The main results of the investigations completed in November 1985 may be summarized as follows:
2 1.
Foreword Following independence, Malaysia has succeeded in reducing the deve 1opi ng gap between tries.
itself and the
industria 1i zed coun-
The country is progressively overcoming the economic
structure inherited from the colonial period. 2.
In West Malaysia it was possible to identify initial indications of a reversal in the process of spatial concentration. As far as manufacturing industry is concerned, however, intraand
interregional
decentralization
is confined to the west
coast of peninsular Malaysia. The results of the analysis of long-term spatial development in West Malaysia do not support the view frequently expressed in the 1 iterature, at least in this
general
form,
that
spatial
disparities
in developing
countries are increasing. 3.
These positive results, compared with other developing countries, were achieved by pursuing an economic policy geared to integration into the world market. By promoting dynamic economic
growth,
the
government
is
attempting
to
create
the
material preconditions necessary for the achievement of major goals of social and spatial policy, such as eradication of poverty, reduction of interethnic dichotomies, and removal of spatial disparities. L. Schatzl
I
POLARIZATION REVERSAL IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES?
Ludwi g Sch'atzl
Research into developing countries raises the following controversial issues of debate: 1.
Does the integration of developing countries into the world economy intensify or reduce North-South disparities in socioeconomic development?
2.
Does integration into the world market result in the deformation and disintegration of economic and social structures within developing countries, or does international division of labour promote integration of the domestic economy by forcing efficient utilization of scarce resources?
3.
Within developing countries exposed to world market forces, is there a tendency for intra- and interregional disparities to increase and towards the emergence of a monocentric settlement system, or does, in the long term, the market mechanism, in association with spatial economic policy, lead to a turning point (polarization reversal) in the spatial concentration process?
3
4
Ludwig Schatzl
Issues of development theory and development policy can be discussed
at
various
spatial
scales,
for
example,
global
or
national. The following remarks relate to the national scale, that is,
they are concerned with the exp 1 ana t ion of i nterreg ion a l and
intraregional
differences in development within countries. An in-
troductory review of the possible impact of international economic relations on national spatial development is followed by a comparative assessment of the principles of neoclassical and polarization theories and a summary of the various theories of polarization reversal.
The final
section presents the results of empirical
re-
search wh i eh can be interpreted as providing confirmation of the polarization reversal hypothesis.
International Economic Relations and National Spatial Development There is general agreement in the literature that the structure and intensity of developing countries' involvement in the world economic system affects spatial development within the developing countries themselves. international
There
economic
is,
however,
relations
considerable debate whether
serve
to
intensify
or
reduce
intra- and interregional disparities. There are two basically different theoretical approaches to this question, from each of which conceptual strategies can be derived. According to the dissociation approach, based on dependencia theories, underdevelopment and North-South disparities derive from the
developing countries' enforced incorporation into an unequal
international neocolonial thereby
division pressures.
rendered
of
labour
as
The developing
a
result
of
countries
structurally dependent upon
the
colonial
and
(periphery)
are
industrialized
Polarization Reversal in Developing Countries?
5
countries' world centres. Whereas in the centres there evolved a production structure adapted to the needs of society, the periphery, as early as the colonial period, was forced to adopt a production structure oriented not to its own requirements, but to those of the centres. The domestic market was neglected in the interest of production of primary goods for export. This form of incorporation of the developing countries into a world economy based on division of labour causes a net outflow of resources,
as well
deformation
social
and
disintegration
of
their
economic,
as and
spatial system, creating, for example, sectoral disparities, imbalances in personal income distribution, metropolization, and intraand
interregional
firstly,
disparities.
Two
strategies
are
demanded:
dissociation of the developing countries from the world
market in order to overcome the North-South dichotomy, and secondly,
selective
national
core
spatial
closure of less
regions,
in
order
to
developed areas from the reduce
spatial
disparities
within developing countries. According to the integration approach, based on neoclassical theories, disparities in income levels between industrialized and developing countries are the result of
1.
uneven
availability
and
mobilization
of
internal
growth
determinants, for example, inventive and innovative potential, human capital, material resource endowment; 2.
the
inadequate participation of the developing countries in
the
i nterna ti on a l exchange of goods, capital
and technology
because of the monopolistic behaviour of multinational companies, protectionist measures (trade restrictions, subsidies) imposed by the governments of the industrialized countries, and misguided economic policies pursued by the governments of developing countries, insofar as
they
establish
inefficient
6 Ludwig Schatzl industries protected by high tariff barriers geared to import substitution; and 3.
deficiencies in the present organization of the world economy, for example, the absence of a law regulating international competition.
In terms of the above analysis of the causes of international imbalances in income levels, the strategy proposed is one of intensified integration of developing countries into the world economy. The aim of this strategy is the creation of a substitutive division of labour by the systematic application of comparative cost advantages in developing and industrialized countries, that is, the transformation of international economic relations from their present state of unilateral dependence into one of interdependence by means of a gradual process of adaptation of production structures. The key element of the integration strategy is the fact that the developing countries also have to establish an export industry able to compete on the world market. Integration into the world economy would thereby compel developing countries to use scarce resources more efficiently and not on 1y generate over a 11 economic growth but also accelerate essential structural change, leading in the long term to a polarization reversal in the process of spatial concentration.
Theories of National Spatial Development
Neoclassical versus Polarization Models The regional growth theories of the neoclassical school are based on a series of simplified assumptions, including, for example,
Polarization Reversal in Developing Countries?
7
polypolistic market structures, free interregional mobility of the factors of production and comparability between individual regions in
terms
of their available internal
growth determinants. Using
these assumptions, the basic hypothesis of the neoclassical theory states
that each disturbance
in a system of equilibrium in its
initial stage generates countervailing forces which operate in such a way as to create a new state of equilibrium in the system, that is,
the
market
differentials, differences balanced
mechanism
contributes
for example,
in
towards
per capita
erasing
income.
regional
Interregional
in factor remuneration (wages, profits) are counter-
by
factor
migration
and
also
trade
(Heckscher-Ohlin
Theorem). Figure !.1 shows a two-region model in which both regions possess
the
same capital assets, although in situation (a) wage
levels in Region 2 are lower than in Region 1, on account of the greater 1abour supp 1y in the former. The wage differentia 1 induces labour migration from Region 2 to Region 1 until
a situation of
equilibrium is attained in (b), in which both regions have the same wage levels. If more realistic assumptions are taken into account, however, the tendency for factor prices to be compensated for becomes weakened and complete adjustment in the prices of production factors is negated. The decisive weakness of neoclassical regional growth theories
rests
deserve
in
their
consideration
underlying restrictions. since,
compared
with
They nevertheless other
theories
of
regional growth and development, not only do they possess inherent unity, but also essential elements of these theories are applied in location and polarization theories, and the neoclassical doctrine has influenced, and continues to determine regional policy in many market economies. Polarization theories were formulated subsequently as a critical
reaction
to
the
deductive
theories
of
equilibrium
which
8
Ludwig Schatzl FIGURE I. l Balancing of Factor Prices by Factor MObility according to Neoclassical Theory
(a)
Region 1
Region 2
0 1 Labour
02
Labour
(b)
SOURCE: Siebert 1970, p. 64 ff.
include not only the neoclassical growth theories, but also location theories elaborated by von Thunen, Losch, and Christaller. In contrast to the restrictive assumptions embodied in the theories of equilibrium, they emphasize the existence, for example, of oligopolistic
and
monopolistic market structures,
partially immobile
factors of production and structural differences between regions as far
as
internal
growth
determinants
are
concerned.
The
basic
hypothesis of the polarization theories states that the emergence of
regional
imbalances
under market economy conditions
sets
in
motion a circular and cumulative causation process of growth or decline which heightens the imbalances. Cumulative growth processes are predicted for the region which takes the lead in development. Figure
I.2
shows
the
mechanism contributing
economic growth within a region.
to self-sustaining
In the backward region, a corres-
Polarization Reversal in Developing Countries?
9
FIGURE I. 2 Mechanism of Cumulative Causation according to Polarization Theory
p
y
y p
w p
w
p
Growth rate of output Growth rate of productivity Wage level Index of productivity Efficiency wages
SOURCE: Richardson 1973, P• 32,
ponding process of cumulative decline sets in. Fundamental structural
differences between regions in conjunction with asymmetric-
ally operating periphery
interregional
spatial
closed spatial
structures.
interactions gives rise Centre
to centre-
and periphery represent a
system and are linked together in a relationship
characterized by ties of authority and dependence.
10
Ludwig Schatzl
Polarization Reversal Models Theories of polarization reversal explain the nature of the spatial differentiation process (regional
development, spatial structure)
in the context of the level of development of a country. The basic hypothesis states that during the long-term development process of a national economy, phases of spatial equilibrium alternate with phases of imbalance. In order to illustrate changes and variations in the formulation of the theory, brief reference wi 11 be made to the work of A.O. Hirschman, E. v. Boventer and J. Friedmann as well as to a new contribution by H.W. Richardson. A.O.
Hirschman
(1958) explains long-term regional economic
growth liy means of a two-region model. Negative polarization effects and positive trickling down effects are transmitted from a progressive northern region to a depressed southern region. In an initial phase of development, centripetal polarization effects are stronger than the centrifuga 1 trick 1 i ng down effects, resulting in intensification
of
regional
imbalances.
The
concentration
of
economic activities in the northern region generates countervailing economic forces
(for example, negative effects of agglomeration)
and political countermeasures (for example, regional policy). In a second phase of development, the trickling down effects constantly gain momentum until they exceed the polarization effects and bring about regional balance. E.
v.
Boventer
(1962,
1964) examines long-term changes in
location structure. The dependence of the economy on the production factor land, on transport costs and on agglomeration factors are regarded as the major economic determinants of location structure. The dynamism of the spatial system is a product of the interactions between
these
factors
of
spatial
differentiation
and of their
changing significance during the long-term development of the econ-
Polarization Reversal in Developing Countries? omy.
In
the
pre-industrial
development
phase,characterized by
significance of agriculture, relatively high transport sence of agglomerations, v.
11
costs,
ab-
Bi:iventer expects a location structure
in which the primary sector corresponds with a von Thunen system, the secondary sector with a modified Li:isch system, and the tertiary sector with a Christaller system. With advancing industrialization there
is a shift of emphasis
differentiation.
The
in the factors
decentralizing factors,
governing spatial land and transport
costs, decline in significance in favour of agglomeration advantages which promote concentration. The concentration of economic activity in agglomerations offering locational advantages creates increasing imbalance in the spatial system. Once an optimal density value has been exceeded, decentralizing tendencies resulting from agglomeration disadvantages in the centres, in conjunction with regional policy, are expected to contribute to a reduction in spatial disparities. J. Friedmann (1966) in his stage theory attempts to combine elements of both the regional growth and location theories. As an economy develops,
changes
in
spatial organization are viewed in
terms of evolutionary development to higher levels. In each of the four
developmental
stages,
representing
degrees
industrialization in pre-industrial, transitional, industrial post-industrial
economies,
a
characteristic
spatial
of and
structure
emerges. Figure I.3 shows development from a situation of spatial equilibrium (independent local spatial librium
settlements) through two stages of
instability (centre-periphery structures) to a new equi(interdependent
spatial
system
of
a
high
hierarchical
order). H.W. Richardson (1977, 1980) formulated the hypothesis that in developing countries,
too,
the
long-term spatial development
process experiences a phase of increasing polarization and reaches
12
Ludwig Schatzl FIGURE 1.3 Sequence of Stages in Spatial Organization
Po~ c Q)
E
Q_
0
a; >
Q)
"0
Industrial
"'"' Q) (J
0
If_
Transitional
88888
Pre - industrial
SOURCE: Friedmann, 1966, p. 36.
a turning point, which he terms "polarization reversal", and that subsequently
there
is
a strengthening of forces
which
produces
intra- and interregional decentralization. The following phases
in
Polarization Reversal in Developing Countries?
13
the process of spatial differentiation are distinguished: The urban-industrial process of national development originates in one or two favourably located regions (for example, resource
endowment,
port,
market
scarcity of investment resources.
size) Here,
because
of
the
a cumulative cau-
sation process is set in motion by internal and external economies and by the in-migration of mobile factors of production (for example, skilled labour and capital) from other parts of the country. Agglomeration advantages in the centre, in conjunction with the polarization of production potential from the remainder of the space economy, result creation of a centre-periphery spatial structure.
in the
As development proceeds, a process of spatial transformation begins which originates within the core region (centre and its hinterland). The high rate of growth of economic activitY and inward migration of labour in excess of available employment opportunities cause agglomeration disadvantages in the centre (slums, temporary collapse of public infrastructure, rising land prices, etc.). In the economic sphere, they cause production costs to rise and render profitable the relocation of existing enterprises and the establishment of nev1 enterprises in satellite towns in the hinterland of the centre. The result is intraregional decentralization within the core region. At an advanced stage of development, Richardson expects intraregional decentralization to be accompanied by interregional dispersion, that is, the emergence of national subcentres. At a few selected locations in the periphery, for the most part in larger towns, conditions emerge which enable self-sustaining growth. The emergence of agglomeration ad-
14
Ludwig Schatzl vantages may be associated with
improvements
in material,
human and institutional infrastructure, exploitation of local natural
resources,
low input costs,
increases
in incomes,
population and market size induced by investment activity, diffusion of technical know-how and urban attitudes from the core region, and so forth. The agglomeration advantages in the subcentres associated with increasing agglomeration disadvantages in the core region cause investment to be diverted from
the
core
region
into
the
subcentres
(by means
of
enterprise relocation, establishment of new branches). This, in turn, stimulates labour migration out of the core region and the remaining periphery into the new subcentres. This interregional
dispersion of economic activity and associated
migratory movements constitutes
the fundamental
feature of
the polarization reversal hypothesis. At a later stage of development there occurs a renewed process of intraregional decentralization of economic activities from
the new subcentres
into their hinterland.
The whole
process of intraregional decentralization and interregional dispersion results in stable hierarchical settlement systems distributed throughout the space economy. Richardson's polarization reversal interest within the regional
hypothesis has attracted
sciences not least for two reasons.
Firstly,
it constitutes a praiseworthy attempt to incorporate es-
sential
elements of both the polarization theory and neoclassi-
cal
thought, as well as to combine regional growth with location
theories. Secondly, it appears to provide theoreti ea l arguments to support the view that the market mechanism is also able to lead to spatial equilibrium, at least in the long term, in developing countries.
Polarization Reversal in Developing Countries?
15
From the point of view of economic and social geography, however, the following questions still require adequate explanation. The model of a long-term spatial development process was originally formulated from empirical observations in some industrialized countries with a market economy,
and applied by Richard son
to
the
present-day situation in developing countries. This procedure is only acceptable if the laws used to explain the process of spatial concentration and decentralization have universal validity. There are, however,
fundamental
differences
between
industrialized and
developing countries, for example, in terms of the availability of internal growth determinants (such as population growth, social and economic structure) or of the resulting international interactions. In view of this, it would appear necessary to at least modify the theory in order to render it applicable to the specific problems of the
developing
countries
and
to
their
individual
stage
of
development. Furthermore, there exist considerable variations in dynamism and in the nature of the spatial development process even between countries
with
account for
a
comparable
level
these differences,
of development.
it is essential
In order
to
to identify the
basic conditions underlying the mechanisms of polarization and decentralization. What role is played by external factors (such as the intensity and structure of world market relations) or internal determinants (such as natural resource endowment, regional distribution of resources,
population dynamics,
sectoral
of
structure
know-how)?
the
economy,
For the developing countries
the level
settlement system, of
technological
it is particularly im-
portant to identify the specific conditions which favour a reversal of
the
polarization
process.
The
decentralization
mechanisms
formulated in the polarization reversal theory (agglomeration disadvantages in the centres, locational advantages in the periphery) cover
only a
few of the economic and political factors which
are
16
Ludwig Schatzl
regarded as essential for the removal of spatial imbalances. The question remaining basically unexplained is which regional policy strategies for developing countries can be inferred from the statements remarks
on
on
polarization
regional
reversal"
Richardson concentrates his
policy action in the phase of interregional
dispersion. In order to overcome the development problems resulting from
a
monocentric
spatial
structure,
Richardson
proposes
influencing the spatial process by active encouragement of agglomeration advantages in the larger subcentres,
in such a way as to
accelerate the attainment of the turning point. State intervention of this kind, however, is regarded as being likely to succeed only if it occurs when the po l ari za ti on forces have weakened, that is, if regional policy measures are implemented near the turning point. This argument raises questions regarding the timing of intervention and which subcentres should be selected. Richardson's arguments neglect the fact that in the polarization
phase
and
in
both phases of intraregional
decentralization
state intervention is required to promote regional development and spatial
structure on economic,
social
and political grounds, and
that strategies specific to these phases have to be developed.
In
the polarization phase, regional policy strategies should contribute towards tration
counteracting the process of extreme spatial
experienced
in
many
developing
countries.
concenPossible
measures, derived from polarization and dependencia theories, would be mobilization of the production potential available in peripheral regions, basic
temporary protection and adaptation of production to the
needs
necessary,
of
broad
sections
of the
population,
combined,
with the selective dissociation of peripheral
if
regions
from global and national metropolitan centres with the aim of overcoming existing authority-dependence relationships.
In the phases
of dispersion and decentralization, on the other hand, public pro-
Polarization Reversal in Developing Countries? motion
of
agglomeration
advantages
in
new
17
subcentres could be
coupled with a strategy aimed at intensifying intra- and interregional
interaction along neoclassical
in order to ac-
lines,
celerate the removal of spatial imbalances. By this are meant, for example, measures aimed at reducing existing obstacles to mobility involving
expansion
of
interregional
infrastructure
and
active
promotion of trade and transfer of capital and techn i ea l know- how into peripheral regions. A theory which claims to explain spatial development processes and which is to provide a basis
for
regional
and
spatial
policy
must be subjected to testing in the real world, that is, empirical investigation
by
means
of
cross-sectional
and
intertemporal
analyses.
Empirical Investigation of the Polarization Reversal Hypothesis Comprehensive empirical reversal
hypothesis
by
examination of Richardson's polarization means
of
international
cross-sectional
analysis is impossible, given the present state of research, since a precondition would be case studies of a sufficient number of countries with differing levels of development, using a unified theoret i ea l concept and a comparable methodo log i ea l approach. The research
results
presented
below
examine
long-term changes
in
regional development, city size distribution, sectoral structure, population growth and personal
income d is tri but ion. They are not
only of significance for the general evaluation of the polarization reversal hyothesis, but can also be utilized in the testing of individual elements of the theory. The relationship between stage of development and regional development was exan11ned ernp1ncally by J.G.
W1lllarn~un
1n 1965.
18
Ludwig Schatzl
From a cross-sectional
analysis
of
24 countries with differing
levels of development he concludes that, as an economy develops, interregional income
-
initially
development studies,
disparities - measured stage,
then
of
reach
decline
(cf.
a
peak
at
Figure
of
per
an
intermediate
1.4).
More
capita recent
such as by B. Renaud, reach similar conclusions. There is
considerable debate value
increase,
in terms
these
in the
findings,
literature concerning the predictive particularly
on
account
of
proven
methodological inadequacies. In 1970, B.J.L. Berry examined the relationship between level of development and city size distribution. From an analysis of 38 countries he predicted that in the course of long-term development there is a transition from primacy to lognormality in accordance with the rank-size rule (cf. Figure 1.5). As the study does not take into account the actual
location of towns within a country,
the question remains unanswered whether this spatial development process merely describes intraregional decentralization within the core region or a reversal of the polarization process, that is, interregional dispersion associated with the creation of hierarchical settlement systems distributed throughout the country. According to the sector theory (C. Clark, J. Fourastie) longterm economic growth of a country is accompanied by a shift of emphasis secondary
in to
economic the
activity
tertiary
from
sector.
the
primary
Structural
through
change
can
the be
explained in terms of changes in income elasticity of demand, and, on the supply side, in terms of differences in the sectoral growth rates of productivity. This long-term shift in production and employment structure has been empirically demonstrated for a series of
countries with differing
levels of development.
The spatial
development process is without doubt influenced by sectoral change. The polarization reversal hypothesis can be regarded as one attempt
Polarization Reversal in Developing Countries?
19
FIGURE 1.4 Relationship between Level of Devel~t and Regional Econo.ic Gro.th (cross-sectional analysis of 24 countries)
c Q)
E
c. 0
a;
..,> Q)
"'"' a: Q) ()
0
Regional disparities
SOURCE: Wi11iamson 1965, p. 10.
to clarify these interrelationships which have so far been the subject of little research. The long-term process of economic and social transformation is accompanied by a demographic transition from a state of equilibrium with high birth and mortality rates, through a stage of imbalance characterized by rapid natural population growth, to a new state of equ i 1 i bri urn with 1ow birth and mort a1 ity rates. From time-series and cross-sectional analyses it can be concluded that the model of demographic transition is applicable not only to industrial countries but also, in modified form, to developing countries. In 1982,
20
Ludwig
Sch~tzl
FIGURE I. 5 Relationship between level of Developaent and City Size Distribution (cross-sectional analysis of 38 countries)
c
"'c.
E 0
a; >
"'
1:l
"' "'"' ()
0
a:
City - size distribution
SOURCE: Berry and Horton 1970, p. 73.
J. Ledent formulated the hypothesis which he tested empirically by
means of time-series and cross-sectional analyses, according to which, during the transition from traditional to modern society, the rate of rural-urban migration at first increases, reaches a peak and then falls once more (cf. Figure 1.6). Finally, the Kuznets hypothesis (1955) deserves mention. It states that during the transition from an agrarian to an industrial and post-industrial society, increasing inequality of personal income distribution occurs in the early stages of industrialization, whereas during more advanced stages in development, compensatory
Polarization Reversal in Developing Countries? FIGURE I. 6 MOdel sho.ing Demographic Transition, Natural Population Growth and Rural-Urban Migration
Natural increase rate
Rural net outmigration rate
Process of development
SOURCE: Ledent 1982, p. 103.
21
22
Ludwig Schatzl
forces
lead to stabil ization and subsequently to a reduction in
income
differentials.
This
relationship
between
economic
development and secular change in income structure was derived from time-series section a 1
analyses ana 1yses
of Western industrialized countries. of
countries
with
differing
Cross-
1eve 1s
of
development have meanwhile become available, which can be interpreted as confirming this hypothesis. As Figure I.? shows, as per capita income increases, the share of income of the lowest 40 % of income earners initially undergoes a drastic fall before beginning a steady c 1 i mb as development progresses. On the other hand, the share of total income of the upper 20 % of income earners rises in the early phase of the development process and then dec 1 i nes once higher per capita values have been attained. Time-series
analyses
are
available for
some
industrialized
countries, which can be interpreted as confirming the polarization reversal hypothesis. These countries exhibit a pattern of development characterized by convergence of regional income differentials, followed by a phase of divergence, and, finally a new phase of convergence at a more advanced stage of development; similarly, they illustrate a transition in the city size distribution from primacy to lognormality. F. Lo, K. Salih, and M. Douglass, for example, who investigated period
the
1956-70,
spatial
development
utilized a variety of
process
in
indicators
Japan
for
the
(regional
and
personal income distribution, urban primacy) to demonstrate empirically that at the beginning of the sixties spatial polarization was
reversed and followed by decentralization.
After identifying
the conditions in Japan which effected the reversal in spatial development (full employment, facturing
in
the
core
complex organizational cluded
that
a
agglomeration disadvantages for manu-
region,
interregional
linkage
effects,
structure of the economy) the authors con-
spontaneous
polarization
reversal
process
unlikely in developing countries in the foreseeable future.
was
Polarization Reversal in Developing Countries?
23
FIGURE I. 7 Relationship between Level of Development and Personal Income Distribution {cross-sectional analysis of 66 countries)
% 60
----------------t~o~p~2~0~%~------50 (
Q)
~
"'
---
40
Q)
E
0
()
£
10
lowest 40% 200
1000
2000
3000
4000
GNP per capita, US- dollar
SOURCE: Ah1uwa1ia 1974, p. 15.
The process tries, described follows: small
of spatial in
differentiation
in
developing coun-
numerous case studies, can be summarized as
Modern economic
activity remains largely confined to a
number of centres
with favourable locations. This spatial
concentration of productive forces leads to imbalances in income between
the
largely
industrial
centres
and
the
predominantly
agrarian periphery (that is, interregional disparities). One of the consequences of this from the
periphery
type into
of development is increased migration the
industrial
centres.
The
1 imited
employment impact of predominantly capital-intensive industries and the
fact
that rural-urban migration
is generated by perceived,
rather than actual prospects of employment and income, results in deterioration in the material living conditions of a greater part
24
Ludwig Schatzl
of the population, even v1ithin the core regions (that is, intraregional disparities). For the decisive question of whether in developing
countries
industrial term,
the
growth
impulses
emanating
from the urban-
centres contribute towards reducing, and in the long
overcoming existing inter- and intraregional
disparities,
there is no clear empirical evidence in most country case studies. Research results are nevertheless available for some developing countries
(mainly newly industrializing countries) which can be
regarded as providing the first indications of a reversal in the spatial concentration process in terms of Richardson's hypothesis. K. Mera, for example, demonstrated for South Korea that regional disparities
in
incomes
declined as a result of rapid economic
growth and public subsidies for agriculture. Studies by B. Renaud and M.C.
Hwang also confirm the convergence of regional gr01vth
indicators. The following chapters examine Malaysia, a developing country where intra- and interregional decentralization, at least in their initial stages, can be empirically identified.
REFERENCES Ahluwalia, M.S. "Income Inequality: Some Dimensions of the Problem". In H. Chenery et al., Redistribution with Growth. Oxford, 1974. Berry, B.J.L., and F.E. Horton. Geographic Perspectives on Urban Systems. Englewood Cliffs (New Jersey), 1970. Boventer, E.v. "Die Struktur der Landschaft. Versuch einer Synthese und Weiterentwicklung der ~lodelle J.H. van Thi.inens, W. Christallers und A. Loschs". In QQ_timales Wachstum und optima le Standortverteilung, pp. 77-133. Schriften des Vereins fur Soc1al-pol1t1k 27. Berlin, 1962.
Polarisation Reversal in Developing Countries?
25
. Raumwirtschaftstheorie, pp. 704-28. Handworterbuch der So--zialwissenschaften 8. Stuttgart, Tubingen, Gottingen, 1964 . . Standortentscheidung und Raumstruktur. Veroffentlichung der --Akademie fur Raumforschung und Landespl anung. Bd. 76. Hannover, 1979. Friedmann, J. Regional Development Policy: A Case Study of Venezuela. Cambridge, London, 1966 . . "A Theory of Polarized Development". In J. Friedmann, Urbanization, Planning and National Development, pp. 41-64. Beverly Hi 11 s, London, 1973. Hirschman, A.O. The Strategy of Economic Development. New Haven, London, 1958. Hwang, M.C. "A Search for a Development Strategy for the Capital Region of Korea". In Metropolitan Planning: Issues and Politics, edited by Y.H. Rho and M.C. Hwang, pp. 3-32. Seoul, 1979. Krebs, G. "Regional Inequalities during the Process of National Economic Development: A Critical Approach". Geoforum 13 (1982): 1-81. Kuznets, S. "Economic Growth and Income Inequality". American Economic Review (1955): 1-28. Ledent, J. "The Factors of Urban Population Growth: Net Immigration Versus Natural Increase". International Regional Science Review 7, No. 2 (1982): 99-125. Lo, F., K. Salih, and M. Douglass. Uneven Development, Rural-Urban Transformation and Regional Development Alternatives in Asia. Nagoya, 1978. Lo,
F. and K. Salih. "Growth Poles, Agropolitan Development and Polarization Reversal: The Debate and Search for Alternatives". In Development from Above or Below? The Dialectics of Regional Planning in Developing Countries, edited by W.B. Stohr and D.R.F. Taylor, pp. 123-52. Chichester, 1981.
~1era,
K. "Population Concentration and Regional Income Disparities: A Comparative Analysis of Japan and Korea". In Human Settlement Systems, edited by N.M. Hansen, pp. 155-75. Cambridge, 1978.
Renaud, Ne1~
B. National Urbanization Policy in Developing Countries. York, 1981.
26
Ludwig Schatzl
Richardson, H.W. Regional Growth Theory. London, 1973. _ _ . City Size and National Spatial Strategies in Developing Countries. World Staff Working Paper No. 252. Washington, D. C. ,1977 .
. "Polarization Reversal in Developing. Countries". Papers of the Regional Science Association 45 (1980): 67-85. Schatzl, L. "Oberlegungen zum langfristigen regionalen Wirtschaftswachstum". Die Erde 109 (1978a): 445-55. Wi rtschaftsgeograph i e, 1978b.
1.
Theori e.
Paderborn:
UTB
782,
Wirtschaftsgeographie 2. Empirie. Paderborn: UTB 152, 1981. Wirtschaftsgeographie 3. Politik. Paderborn: UTB 1383, 1986. Siebert, H. Regionales Wirtschaftswachstum und interregionale Mobilitat. Tubingen, 1970. Williamson, J.G. "Regional Inequality and the Process of National Development. A Description of the Patterns". Economic Development and Cultural Change 13 (1965): 3-84.
11
ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AND ECONOMIC POLICY IN MALAYSIA
Ludwi g Sch.atzl
Colonial Development The colonial with
the
period in Malayan history may be said to have begun
British
occupation
of
the
following
territories:
the
island of Penang (1786), the trading post of Malacca (1795), which had been a Portuguese possession since 1571 and a Dutch possession since
1641,
and
the island of Singapore (1819). The aim of the
British in these Straits Settlements was initially to control the sea route from India to China. From the mid-nineteenth century onwards, economic exploitation of the Malay peninsula as a supplier of raw materials for Western i ndus trial i zed countries was undertaken from Penang, Malacca and Singapore. At the outset, the economy of the British colony of Malaya was characterized by rich deposits of tin-ore and vast untouched areas suitable for tropical lation
in
agriculture.
With an estimated total popu-
1833 of a quarter of a million Malays and indigenous
inhabitants,
the region lacked the manpower necessary for the ex-
ploitation of its natural resources (Newbold 1839).
27
28
Ludwig Schatzl From 1850 onwards tin mining on the west coast of the pen-
insula was actively pursued by Chinese and later also by British companies, with immigrant labour from China providing the main part of the work- force. The influx of Chinese was accompanied by the growth of urban settlements, notably Kuala Lumpur, Ipoh and Taiping in the tin-mining centres. After 1890 the British colonial administration established a railway network to link the tin mines with the exporting ports. Growing demand for natural rubber, reflecting the expansion of the automobile industry in Western Europe and North America, led to the introduction at the end of the nineteenth century of Hevea brasiliensis into the hinterland of the Straits Settlements. Natural rubber was produced on European plantations and, after 1911, to a limited extent on Malay smallholdings. The plantation workers were predominantly Tamils from southern India and Ceylon. Cultivation of natural rubber became concentrated on the west coast of the Mal ay peninsula
where
the
infrastructure
provided for the tin mining
operations was available. From the beginning of the twentieth century onwards,
the British colonial
administration established a
road network on the west coast, serving the needs of the export trade. By 1911 the population of Malaya had risen to 2.6 million, of which 35 % were Chinese, 10 % Indian and 55 % Malay and other ethnic groups. Economic
expansion
continued
throughout
the
following
two
decades. Development was characterized by the progressive expansion of tin production and of the rubber plantations in the tin and rubber belt on the west coast and by improvements in material infrastructure,
primarily along the west coast but also including
initial efforts to open up the east coast by constructing a railway line. There was also continued influx of Chinese and Indian labour. The world economic crisis (1929-32) and the associated fall in de-
Economic Development and Economic Policy in Malaysia
29
mand for industrial raw materials caused economic stagnation. The outbreak of World War II halted the flow of Chinese and Indian immigrants. In 1941 Malaya had a total population of 5.5 million, of which 44 % were Chinese, 14 % Indian and only 42 % Malay. From
the
end
of World War II
until
independence in 1957
economic development was mainly characterized by reconstruction of the economy, particularly recovery from the war damage caused by the Japanese occupation and communist guerilla activities, and by further expansion of the export-oriented sector of the economy. Major political events included the founding of the Federation of Malaya (excluding Singapore) in 1948, the establishment of ethnically-based parties and, in 1955, the holding of general elections. A constitution, which had been drawn up before the end of colonial rule, came into force on Independence Day. This constitution confers de facto political power on the Malay population and establishes Malay as the official language and Islam as the official state religion. The constitution also contains provisions aimed at safeguarding the rights of the Chinese and Indian minorities, for example, the right to ·practise religion freely and to engage in economic activity. In summary, the Malay peninsula successfully developed into a major world producer of tin and rubber during the colonial period. At the same time, however, there emerged fundamental imbalances in sectoral economic structure, in regional development and in personal
income
distribution.
After
one
and
a half
centuries of
British colonial rule the economic situation was as follows: 1.
The country's economy lacked diversification, being dominated exclusively by the exploitation of two raw materials for export.
The
nature
and
intensity
of
primary production was
dependent on de,nand for raw materials in Western Europe and NurLh Amer1cct.
30 2.
Ludwig Schatzl In socio-economic terms there were marked
disparitie~
between
the west coast of the Malay peninsula, where exploitation of raw
materia 1s
for
export
and
most
infrastructure were concentrated, underdeveloped east coast. 3.
and
of
the
the
deve 1oped
economically
Deve 1opment of the export trade had encouraged immigration of Chi ne se and Indian 1abour and created a multi raci a 1 society. During the colonial period considerable interethnic disparities in income emerged between the Chinese on the one hand, and the Malays and Indians on the other. The total population of the Federation of Malaya in 1957 was 6.3 million, of which 50 % were Ma 1ay, 37% Chi ne se, 12% Indian and 1% other ethnic groups. 1 The majority of the Chinese worked initially in the tin mines. Due in some measure to the British colonial administration imposing restrictions on the Chinese population's right to acquire land and to obtain employment in public administration, the Chinese soon began to concentrate on urban-commercial activities. Particularly in the towns along the west coast, they successfully established enterprises in craft trades, manufacturing and the service sector. In contrast the Malays, most of whom lived in rural areas, engaged in subsistence activities (rice cultivation, fishing) and, though less significantly, in rubber cultivation on small and medium-sized holdings.
Although
some
employment in public administration, workers with poor prospects.
of the Indians found most were
plantation
The legacy of a one-sided economy, regional disparities, separation of political and economic power and the British colonial administration's policy of division of labour among the ethnic groups, which the Federation of Malaya inherited at the end of the
Economic Development and Economic Policy in Malaysia
31
colonial era, constituted a situation of potential conflict. (Cf. Ooi 1976, KUhne 1980, KrUger 1985 on precolonial and colonial development).
Economic Development after Independence The Federation of Malaya became independent on 31 August 1957. The early post-independence years were dominated by the struggle to achieve national unity and territorial integration. By 1960 the activities of the communist guerilla movement had been successfully brought under control. In 1963 the Federation of Malaysia was established which united the Federation of Malaya (that is, West Malaysia or peninsular Malaysia), the thinly populated territories of Sarawak and Sabah in Borneo (that is, East Malaysia) and Singapore. Singapore left the Federation in 1965. Following independence, economic growth in Malaysia was satisfactory and there were marked improvements in living conditions. This is illustrated by changes in selected economic and social indicators (cf. Table II.1). 2 During the period 1960-82 real annual growth in gross national product (GNP) averaged 7 % and in per capita GNP 4.3 %. With a per capita income of US$ 1860 in 1982, Malaysia belongs to the upper category of the middle-income countries. Table II.2 presents social indicators which show positive trends in areas such as demography, nutrition, and education. Between 1960 and 1982 birth and death rates fell markedly. Although natural population increase is still high, it is gradually falling. There has been a consistent fall in infant and child mortality.
32
Ludwig Schatzl
There have also been improvements in life expectancy, daily per capita calory supply and in secondary-school enrolment. Malaysia has on the whole succeeded in reducing the socio-economic development gap between itself and the industrialized countries. Sectoral economic structure in Malaysia underwent far-reaching transformation after independence; the country experienced a process of dynamic industrialization. Between 1960 and 1982 the share of agriculture in gross domestic product (GDP) fell from 36% to 23 %. The share of the industrial sector (mining, manufacturing, construction, electricity, gas and water supplies) on the other hand rose from 18 % to 30 %, the contribution of manufacturing alone to GDP doubled from 9 % to 18 %. The service sector accounted for 46 and 47 % of GDP for 1960 and 1982, respectively (World Bank, World Development Report 1984). Data relating to long-term change in sectoral employment structure are available for peninsular Malaysia. The share of employment in agriculture fell from 58 % in 1957 to 50 % in 1970 and 37 % in 1980. Over the same period the percentage of the economically active population in the industrial sector rose from 3 % to 14 % and 22 %, respectively. A major driving force behind economic growth and sector a1 change in Ma1ays i a has been the export economy. In the years fo 11owing independence exports accounted for approximate 1y 50 % of GDP. The structure of foreign trade has, however, undergone fundamental change. Two development trends can be identified: 1.
Raw material exports maintained their leading position but their contribution to the total value of exports fell from 94 % in 1960 to 79 % in 1980. At the same time primary goods exports underwent diversification. The share of traditional
Economic Development and Economic Policy in Malaysia
33
TABLE II.l Indicators of Socio-Economic Development in Malaysia (1960, 1982)
Indicators
1960
GNP (real) in US$ (thousand m.)
ea.
GNP per capita in US $
ea. 740
Population (m.)
Average annual growth rate
1982 6
27
7.0
1,860
4.3
ea.
8.1
14.5
Birth rate (?o)
44
29
Death rate (%)
15
6
Natural population increase (%)
29
23
Infant mortality rate (?0 0
72
29
8
2
52
65
Child death rate (?o 0
,
,
under 1 yr.)
age 1-4)
2.7
Life expectancy in yrs. - male - female
56
Daily calorie supply per capita
69
ea. 2,200
2,662*
19
53*
Number enrolled in secondary schools as percentage of age group
1.0 1.0
0.9
* 1981 SOURCE: World Bank, World Development Report 1984.
export items, tin and rubber, which accounted for over 80 % of total
exports
at
the
end
of
the
col on i a l
period,
declined
steadily to 53 % in 1970, and 26 % in 1980. In 1980 the chief raw material exports were crude oil ( 25 % of exports in terms of value), followed by rubber (17 %), timber (13 %), palm oil (9 %),
and
tin
(9 %)
(cf.
Government
of
Malaysia
1981,
p. 18 ff.). 2.
Malaysia has been able to establish a competitive export industry. Manuf ac tu red goods accounted for 6 % of total exports
34
Ludwig Schatzl in 1960 and 21 % in 1980. The most successful export items were machinery and transport equipment, electronic components, textiles and clothing. At the beginning of the 1980s, roughly two
thirds
of manufactured goods exported went to Western
industrial countries and one third to developing countries. Disparities in personal
income distribution remain consider-
able and have shown some reduction only since 1970. According to estimates available for West Malaysia in the 1960s about half the households were living below a poverty line defined in terms of a basic needs concept (M$180 at 1970 prices); by 1980, the percentage of households below the poverty line had fallen to 30 %. There was also a decline, albeit small, in interethnic differences in income. In terms of average income,
the ratio between Malay, Indian, and
Chinese households was 1:1.8:2.3 in 1970 and 1:1.5:2.1 in 1980; in other words,
the average income of Chinese households was still
double that of Malay households (cf. Government of Malaysia 1981, p. 56).
Economic Policy after Independence
Basic Features of the Economic Policy The economic and social aims, strategies, and policy instruments of the
Malaysian
government
are
embodied
in
Five-Year Plans.
Six
development plans have been drawn up since independence. The first two
plans
(1956-65)
relate
to West Malaysia
(First and Second
Mal ay a Plans) and the four subsequent plans ( 1966-85) to West and East Malaysia (First to Fourth Malaysia Plans). In principle, all development plans are directed towards overcoming the inherited eo-
Economic Development and Economic Policy in Malaysia
35
lonial structure including the one-sided production structure, interethnic income differences and spatial disparities. They also seek to achieve maximum possible economic growth and integration into the world market. Conceptual differences are, however, identifiable in terms of economic policy pursued between the plan periods 1956-70 and after 1970. Between 1956 and 1970 economic policy reflected recommendations made by the World Bank. A market economy with laissez-faire liberal characteristics was introduced. The state was given the task of creating a favourable climate for private investment originating both from within the country and from abroad, and of making available in all parts of the country the material infrastructure essential for the growth of the private sector. Investment in infrastructure (transport, energy, communications) accounted for half of total public development expenditure in the First and Second Malaya Plans and for a third in the First Malaysia Plan (cf. Table II.2). Sectoral economic policy gave priority to agricultural development with the aim of diversifying agricultural exports. Secondary emphasis was placed on the development of manufacturing, protected by tariffs to substitute imports. Whereas the first three plan periods were successful in achieving global economic and sectoral aims, no progress was made in alleviating poverty among broad sections of the population, nor in reducing interethnic and spatial disparities in incomes. In May 1969, Malaysia suffered racial unrest, whereupon a state of emergency was imposed throughout the country until February 1971; during this period, governmental power was transferred to a "National Operations Council". Racial unrest also caused conceptual changes to be made in economic policy. The New Economic Policy proclaimed in 1971 pursued the following long-term development objectives which are contained in the Outline Perspective Plan 1971-90 (cf. Young et al. 1980, p. 60 ff.):
36 l.
Ludwig Schatzl Dynamic economic growth. In contrast to the preceding years, export-oriented manufacturing is regarded as the key growth sector. This kind of industrialization strategy reflects the view that, in the long term, because of the 1imited domestic market, industry based on import substitution cannot generate sufficient impetus for development.
High rates of economic
growth and intensified industrialization are to create the necessary preconditions for achieving the essential social objectives of the New Economic Policy. 2.
Eradication of poverty.
It is
intended to reduce the per-
centage of households below the poverty line from about 50 % (1970) to 34 % (1980) and to 17 % by 1990. As already stated above, the objective for 1980 had been achieved. 3.
Reorganization of society. The basic underlying principle here is that in the long term, participation of the ethnic groups in economic activity should correspond with their population share. In concrete terms this means, in the case of peninsular Malaysia, for example, increasing the proportion of Malays emr l oyed in the secondary sec tor from 31 % ( 1970) to 52 % (1990) or, during the same period, raising the percentage of Malays exercising senior administrative and management func-
tions from 22 % to 49 %. In addition to reorganizing sectoral employment structure and occupational structure, a fundamental change in ownership of the share capital of limited companies is planned. During the course of the perspective plan, it is intended to increase Malay ownership of the share capital of limited companies from 2.4% (1970) to 30% (1990) and the involvement of the remaining Malaysians (Chinese, Indians) from 34 % to 40 %.
The ownership of share capital of overseas investors is to be correspondingly reduced from 63 % to 30 %. As Malay private investment capital is not available on the
TABLE II.2 Public Development Expenditure in Malaysia 1956-85 (in \1:) fTl
First Malaya Plan l 1956-60 Agriculture - irrigation and drainage - new land development
Second Malaya Plan 1 1961-65
First Malaysia Plan 1 1966-70
Second Malaysia Plan 1 1971-75
Third Malaysia Plan 1 1976-80
Fourth Malaysia Plan 2 1981-85·
23 4 2
18 4 5
26 8 9
18 2
19 2
11
11
20 2 9
3
15
13
13
34
18
23
22
1
2
Material infrastructure (transport, communications, energy)
52
47
Social services
14
16
lA
22
18
0
Other expenditure (e.g., administration, internal security, defence, state funds)
10
17
19
27
27
25
Industry and commerce
-in M$ (thousand m.)
0
::::l
0
3
~.
n
Cl
ro ro
< 0
1-o 3
ro
::::l
r+
0> ::::l
0. fTl
n 0
::::l
0
3
~.
n -o 0
n
Total expenditure - in %
n
'
actual expenditure 2
planned
SOURCE: Rao 1980; Government of Malaysia 1976, 1981.
0>
'< (/) 0>
w
---J
38
Ludwig Schatzl scale required, prov1s1on is made for a transitional period during
whi eh government agencies
are to acquire
the share
capital. This explains the substantial public expenditure in the commerce and industry sectors in the Five-Year Plans since
1971 (cf. Table II.2). 4.
Reduction
of spatial
disparities.
In order to achieve
the
priority objective of the New Economic Po 1icy out 1i ned above, state control of spatial development is regarded as imperative in Malaysia. The reasons for this lie, firstly, in economic growth goals aimed at exploiting development potential in all regions of the country and, secondly, in social policy goals aimed at removing disparities in interethnic development by improving the living conditions of the Malay population. Since the Malays live predominantly in the less developed, agricultura 1 and peri phera 1 parts of the country, pub 1 i c subsidies and development efforts for such areas primarily benefit the Malay ethnic group. The strategies and instruments of spatial policy
pursued in Malaysia are discussed
in
the
following
chapter.
Spatial Economic Policy The concepts of spatial planning applied in Malaysia fall into two categories: a strategy of rural development (in-situ new
land
tralization.
development)
and
a
strategy
of
development,
industrial
decen-
Economic Development and Economic Policy in Malaysia
39
Rural Development Strategy In-situ Development. This involves state-supported structural improvement in traditional agricultural areas. The objective is to improve productivity and increase production in order to raise farmers' incomes and thereby contribute to the fight against poverty. Hitherto,
development efforts were concentrated in the densely populated areas of rice cultivation in the northwest (Muda Project) and the northeast (Kemubu Project) of the Malay peninsula (cf. Fig-
ure II.1}. The high priority accorded to rice cultivation particu1arly reflects the fact that in 1970 88 % of the farmers sti n lived below the poverty line and domestic production of rice, the basic foodstuff, met only part of national requirements. In-situ development is the responsibility of the Federal Ministry of Agriculture and regional public sector agencies, for example, the Muda Agricultural Development Authority (MADA) and the Kemubu Agri cu ltura 1 Deve 1opment Authority ( KADA) . Within an i ntegrated development framev10rk, they utilize a great number of instruments. Development measures range from irrigation and drainage, the introduction of higher yielding varieties, mechanization of agriculture, subsidized fertilizer prices,all of which are intended to enable double cropping, that is, two rice harvests annually, to an improved marketing system and diversification of production, for example, by introducing poultry raising. Between
1971 and 1980, over 100,000 rice farmers received state assistance within the framework of in-situ development. By 1980, Malaysia had succeeded in reducing the proportion of padi farmers living in poverty to 55% and in increasing national selfsufficiency in rice from below 60 % in 1967 to over 90 %. During the nineteen seventies, the development gap between the densely populated rice cultivation areas and the country in general at
40
Ludwig Schatzl FIGURE II.l
Spatial Economic Policy in West Malaysia (1982)
ala Trengganu
[
m
G
j
in-situ Development New Land Development Locational Incentive Area
•
Metropolitan Centres
0
Growth Centres
•
Free Trade Zones
o
Industrial Estates
0
100 km
t----=::F=-------+~
Economic Development and Economic Policy in Malaysia
41
least did not widen. Decisive factors in this success were not only the development measures implemented in selected regions, but also the nationwide price subsidies for rice through the Guaranteed Minimum Price Scheme introduced in 1971 (cf. Government of Malaysia 1981, pp. 38 f., 265 ff.). New Land Development: The large-scale development of new land for agricultural
purposes
is
intended
areas,
accelerate
reduce
regional disparities.
to create employment in rural
diversification
of
agricultural
exports
and
The largest development projects in
West Malaysia are shown in Figure II.1. The main
body responsible
for
new
land development is the
Federal Land Development Authority (FELDA), set up in 1956. In addition to land development (forest clearance, irrigation and drainage, soil improvement, planting) its tasks also extend to the construction
of
houses
and
villages,
selection
and
training
of
settlers, processing and marketing of agricultural produce, and so forth. By the end of 1981 FELDA had developed 0.6 million hectares of new land, of which 60 % was planted with oil palms and a third with rubber. As a result of these development measures Malaysia is today the world's leading producer of palm oil, as well as of tin and rubber. for
FELDA projects have provided settlement opportunities
70,000 families
Household
(about 360,000 people), predominantly Malay.
incomes of the
settlers
average incomes in the traditional
are markedly
higher than the
agricultural
areas (cf. Uhlig
1984, p. 54 ff.). In spite of this impressive record, new land development projects reveal several weaknesses: State development of new
land has proved rather expensive,
accounting for between 5% and 11% of Malaysian total public
42
Ludwig Schatzl development expenditure in the plan periods from 1961 onwards. The cost of settling one family averaged around M$60,000 in the past, part of which has to be repaid by the settler in the 1ong term.
Planning.errors (such as selection of unsuitable areas, imposition of rigid quotas relating to the regional origin of the settlers), resulted in the failure of some projects. In 1966, the Federa 1 Land Con so 1 i dation and Rehabi 1 i tati on Authority (FELCRA) was established in order to provide structural improvements for these projects. The new 1and deve 1opment po 1 icy, as it was ori gi na 11 y conceived, second
overlooked the need to pro vi de emp 1oyment for the generation
of
settlers.
The projects were oriented
solely towards agriculture, with small settlements dispersed throughout
the
countryside.
More
recent
projects,
in
accordance with the strategy of intermediate cities, provide for small, multifunctional towns offering a wider range of employment (agro-industry, services). Large-scale clearance of tropical rain forest has resulted in environmental problems (soil erosion and soil degradation).
Industrial Decentralization Strategy The main purpose of Malaysia's industrial policy was and is to accelerate the growth of, initially, import substituting industries and, later,
export-oriented industries. The earliest evidence of
a policy of industrial decentralization dates from the end of the sixties and became more apparent after the introduction of the New Economic
Policy.
The
sections
below briefly outline the grmvth
Economic Development and Economic Policy in Malaysia centre strategy attempted in Malaysia and examine the range of
43 in-
struments so far employed to encourage industrial development and dispersal. The growth centre strategy was conceived at the beginning of the
seventies.
It was envisaged at that time that towns with a
population of between 40,000 and 75,000 in 1970 should assume the role of growth centres.
In West Malaysia
such
towns were Kota
Bharu, Kuala Trengganu and Kuantan, all situated on the east coast, Alar Star in the northwest, and Taiping, Telok Anson, Muar and Batu Pahat on the west coast. Special priority in industrial development was
to
be given
north~vest,
to the locations on the east coast and in the
in the interests of achieving interregional decentrali-
zation. In East t4alaysia the capital cities of Sarawak and Sabah, Kuching and Kota Kinabalu were selected as growth centres (cf. Figures II.1 and II.2). Towns with a population of over 75,000 (Kuala Lumpur,
including
the
satellite
Georgetown/Butterworth, Johor Bahru,
towns
in
the
Klang
Valley,
I poh, Malacca and Seremban),
which in Malaysian Planning are termed 'Metropolitan Centres', were to receive no special assistance, as they were expected to generate their own economic growth dynamics. The
gro~1th
centre concept also
accorded low priority to assistance for towns with a population belovJ 40,000, which were considered to possess too little potential for industrial development. The extent to which the policy instruments used to promote industrial
growth in Malaysia contributed towards fulfilling de-
centralization goals is examined below. Several instruments can be used to influence the locational behaviour of private
enterprises.
They range from infrastructural measures, in this context in particular, zones,
the establishment of information
services,
industrial estates and free trade and
incentives,
to
compulsory
instruments (cf. Spinanger 1980, Kruger 1982, Kohler 1982).
44
Ludwig Schatzl FIGURE I 1.2
Spatial Economic Policy in East Malaysia (1982)
ommm
New Land Development
~ Industrial Incentive Area D
Growth Centres
o
Industrial Estates
lndones1a
0
200km
~----±---=--=t==----=l
The first industrial estate was established in Petaling Jaya near Kuala Lumpur in the mid-fifties. By 1970, a further nine industrial estates had been created on the west coast of peninsular Malaya at favourable locations, with the aim of initiating the process of industrialization in Malaysia. In subsequent years, however, the industrial estates were used as instruments of spatial economic policy. Their number i ne reased to 70 in 1980 and exceeded 100 by 1983. As Figures 11.1 and 11.2 show, today almost every town in West and East Malaysia possesses an area designated for industrial use and equipped 1vith the necessary infrastructure. There is
Economic Development and Economic Policy in Malaysia
45
no doubt that the provision of such industrial estates stimulates the industrialization process in developing countries. Where they are ubiquitous, as in Malaysia, industrial estates do, however, make only a minor contribution to decentralization. In the seventies,
ten industrial estates were accorded the
status of Free Trade Zones in order to stimulate the exportoriented industrialization called for in the New Economic Policy. Enterprises
in
these
zones whi eh produce goods for export are
all owed to import and export goods free of duty. So far, all the free trade zones in existence are located on the west eo as t of peninsular Malaysia close to the industrialized metropolitan centres ( Kua la Lumpur, Penang, Mal ace a and Johor Bahru) , whi eh possess international airports and ports. In addition, Malaysia offers export-oriented enterprises outside the free trade zones the opportunity to produce in so-ea ll ed Licensed Manufacturing Warehouses free of duty. Viewed as a whole, the provision of free trade zones has accelerated the development of export industries in the country and encouraged decentralization on the west coast of peninsular Malaysia. These planning instruments cannot, however, be expected to encourage industrial development in peripheral areas. The major institutions with responsibility for industrial decentralization policy, that is, at federal level, the Malaysian Industrial Development Authority (MIDA), and at state level, the State Economic Development Corporation (SEDC), provide potential investors with information relating to, for example, the services provided on the industrial estates or to the regionally differentiated incentives. These information services provide assistance in particular to small and medium-sized enterprises in locational decision-making. Development aid to industry by the provision of incentives
is
46
Ludwig Schatzl
regulated by legislation in Malaysia. The aim of this legislation and the essential instruments it provides are summarized below. Development assistance for the establishment of new manufacturing industries is provided by the Pioneer Industries Ordinance of 1958 and the Pioneer Industries Variation Act of 1965. Pioneer industries are those which produce goods not previously manufactured in Malaysia, which possess favourable future potential and which are in the public interest. They are exempt from tax for a period varying from two years in the case of initial fixed capital investments below M$ 250,000, to up to five years in the case of investments over one million Malaysian dollars. Under the Investment Incentives Act of 1968, tax exemption for pioneer industries can be extended for a further one to three years, if they produce priority goods, use a specified amount of local inputs, or if the enterprise is situated in a designated development area. The year 1968 saw, therefore, the first example of a direct link between development assistance and choice of location. The main objective of this legislation is, however, encouragement of the export activities of enterprises already in existence by means of special depreciation terms and tax concessions. The Investment Incentives (Amendment) Act of 1971 pursues objectives concerned primarily with labour market policy. Enterprises the establishment of which is in the interest of industrial development are exempt from tax for a period varying, according to the number of jobs created, from two years (51-100 employees) to five years (over 350 employees). The Investment Incentives (Amendment) Act of 1973 fully endorses the policy of industrial decentralization. Enterprises which locate in a "locational incentive area" are exempt from tax for a
Economic Development and Economic Policy in Malaysia
47
period of five to eight years. As the accompanying tabulation shows, the period of tax exemption depends on the amount invested and the number of jobs created:
Fixed capital investment in M$ 1,000
Number of new jobs created
or
below 750
Tax exemption (in years)
below lOO
5
Z50 - 500
lOO - ZOO
6
501-1,000
ZOl - 350
7
above 1,000
above 350
B
The period of tax exemption is extended by increments of a year to a maximum of ten years, if priority goods are produced or if enterprises derive more than half their inputs from within Malaysia. As measures designed to promote the decentralization of the manufacturing industry, these locational incentives were relatively ineffective for the following reasons: The locational incentive areas designated for industry were too large.
As Figures
II.l
and
II.2 show,
large parts of West
Malaysia and the whole of East Malaysia constitute incentive areas.
If development aid were concentrated into fewer growth
centres, this would foster the generation of localization economies.
A questionnaire
survey
of industrial
enterprises
in
Kelantan showed that public development aid measures had been influential in the decision to locate in this peripheral state in the case of only one quarter Chapter V. ) .
of the
enterprises
(cf.
48
Ludwig Schatzl There is
very
little
incentives
offered
development
areas
to and
difference industrial those
between
the
enterprises
incentives which
to
financial locate
apply
to
in all
parts of the country. In
terms of development policy,
the
preferential
treatment
extended to large enterprises is open to question. Empirical studies show that it is the small and medium-sized enterprises which are able to generate intensive linkages with the local economy. Apart from the prov1s1on of information and incentives, the locational behaviour of private enterprises in Malaysia can be influenced by compulsory measures. The legislative basis is provided by the Industrial Coordination Act of 1975, according to which the establishment of an industrial enterprise representing investments in excess of M$ 250,000 requires a manufacturing licence granted by the Ministry of Trade and Industry, in conjunction with MIDA. MIDA is attempting to make the granting of a licence dependent upon an enterprise locating in a development area. Initial results of this scheme have been disappointing. According to Chi Seck Choo (1981), fewer than one third of the licences granted for a development area actually resulted in the establishment of an industrial enterprise. There is unanimity of opinion in the literature that the policy of industrial decentralization as practised so far has yielded little success. Possible reasons for this are, on the one hand, the fact
that
regions
location
factors
operating within the industrial
core
of the west coast of peninsular Malaysia clearly remain
attractive
and,
on
the
other
hand,
conceptual
weaknesses
and
inadequacies inherent in the policy itself. There is, for example, inadequate coordination between the instruments used to implement the
policy
and
the
intended
aim of
creating
growth centres:
Economic Development and Economic Policy in Malaysia territorially-based
development
assistance
must
be
49
replaced
by
measures relating more closely to specific locations. Furthermore, industrial policy in general and the policy of decentralization in particular, are pursued by a large number of public institutions at both state and federal level. Lack of adequate coordinatiQn between these activities considerably reduces their effectiveness. Since
achieving
independence,
Malaysia
has
succeeded
in
reducing the development gap with the industrialized countries, and it
is
progressively
structure. economic
overcoming
the
inherited colonial
economic
Noteworthy success has been achieved in the fields of growth and sectoral
differences
are
still
change.
Although interethnic income
considerable,
success, which
bears
positive
countries, was
achieved
by
comparison
means
oriented to the world market.
they
of
a
are
decreasing.
with
other
liberal
This
developing
economic
policy
The common underlying principle of
policy which was directed ·initially towards economic growth and, after 1970, more strongly towards distribution, is the attainment of dynamic economic growth in order to create the material basis for fulfilling
fundamental
goals
of social
and
spatial
economic
policy. Chapters socio-economic oping
III
and
IV examine whether spatial
development
have
increased
disparities in
in Malaysia,
a devel-
country oriented towards the world market, or whether the
market mechanism in association with Malaysia's spatial economic policy has led to a trend reversal
in the spatial
concentration
process. The Federation of Malaysia comprises West Malaysia (peninsular Malaysia) and East Malaysia (Sarawak, Sabah). The polarization reversal
hypothesis will
study. The choice of study
be tested using West area can be
~1alaysia
as a case
justified not only
on ac-
50
Ludwig Schatzl
count of the substantial spatial separation of the two parts of the country, but also in view of the fact that, as Table II.3 shows, West Malaysia accounts for 83 % of the population, 85% of the GDP and 93 % of employment in the manufacturing industry. A quarter of the population of West Malaysia live
in eleven cities of over
100,000 inhabitants. East Malaysia, on the other hand, exhibits a low degree of urbanization and industrial development is still at an early stage. potential and
In
the
for industrial
Sabah,
based
on
long
term,
however,
and agricultural
their
rich
natural
there
is excellent
development in Sarawak resources
(crude oil,
natura 1 gas, hydra-e 1ectri c power) and extensive areas of as yet untouched land suitable for agriculture.
TABLE II.3 Structural Differences between West and East Kalaysia
Area - in 1000 km - in
2
~~
Population (1980) - in mill. - in
Population per km
~~
2
Population share in large cities (1980)' in % GDP (1980) - in M$ thousand mill. - in
~0
West Malaysia
East Malaysia
132
198
330
40
60
lOO
11.2
2.3
Malaysia as a whole
13.5
83
17
lOO
85
12
41
26
0
22
22.4
3.8
26.2
85
15
lOO
515
41
556
93
7
100
Employment in manufacturing industry (1981) - in 1,000 - in ?0
Economic Development and Economic Policy in Malaysia
51
NOTES 1
Singapore, which was not part of the Federation of Malaya, of about 1.2 million, mostly Chinese in origin.
had a
population
2
In the interests of international comparability, the data used for Table II.l are derived from the World Development Report (1984) of the World Bank. These data may differ slightly from the official statistics of the Government of Malaysia.
REFERENCES Chi Seck Choo. "The Industrial Estate Program and Industrial Development Strategies in Malaysia: An Appraisal". Malaysian Geographers 3 (1981): 12-20. Government of Malaysia. Lumpur, 1976 .
Third
Malaysia
Plan
1976-1980.
Kuala
. Fourth Malaysia Plan 1981-1985. Kuala Lumpur, 1981. Kohler, 0. Malaysia. Investitionsfuhrer. Deutsche Gesellschaft fur wirtschaftliche Zusammenarbeit; and Bundesstelle fur AuBenhandelsinformation, Koln, 1982. Kruger, K. "Regional ( 1982): 133-49.
Policy
in
Malaysia".
Geoforum 13,
No.
2
_ _ . Regionale Entwicklung in Malaysia. Ph.D. dissertation. Hannover, 1985. Kuhne, D. Ma 1ays i a. Tropen 1and i m Wi derspi e 1 von Mensch und Na tur. Stuttgart, 1980. Newbold, T.J. Political and Statistical Account of the British Settlements in the Straits of Malacca. 2 vols. Kuala Lumpur, 1839. (Reprint 1971). Ooi, J.-B. Peninsular Malaysia. London, 1976. Rao,
V.V.B. Malaysia. Singapore, 1980.
Development Pattern and Policy 1947-1971.
52
Ludwig Schatzl
Spinanger, D. Regional Industrialization Policies in a Small Developing Country. A Case Study of West Malaysia. Kiel: Institut fur Weltwirtschaft, 1980. Uhlig, H., ed. "Spontaneous and Planned Settlement in Southeast Asia". Giessener Geographische Schriften, Vol. 58. Hamburg:
Institute of Asian Affairs, 1984.
World Bank. World Development Report. Washington, D.C., 1984. Young, K., et al. Malaysia. Growth and Equity in a Multiracial Society. Baltimore, London, 1980.
Ill
SPATIAL DISPARITIES IN WEST MALAYSIA
Heidrun Frohloff-Kulke
Introduction The identification of regional disparities within a defined territorial unit and their interregional comparison are of great interest
in
regional
research
for
both
theoretical
and
practical
reasons. The success of regional policy essentially depends on the establishment of a system of regions using standardized criteria and on the selection of appropriate methods for the purposeful delimitation and subdivision of the regions. Regional differences within
disparities are defined here as social and economic in development between
West
Malaysia.
measured directly, In
regional
pressed
in
As
the
individual
socio-economic
statistical
spatial
development
units
cannot
be
indicators have to be substituted.
science literature socio-economic development is exthe form of single
indicators,
such as
GDP,
or of
groupings of indicators aggregated, using various statistical procedures.
Such procedures include, for example,
index compilation
(cf. UNRISD 1974, p. 244), scalogram analysis (cf. M.M. El-Kammash 1963), catalogues of indices, factor analysis (cf. Berry 1960) and cluster
analysis
(cf.
Bratzel
and
1982b, 1984) ·-
53
Muller
1979a,
1979b,
1982a,
54
Heidrun Frohloff-Kulke The aim of this study is to establish the extent of regional
disparities in West Malaysia and to demonstrate development trends in these disparities. Investigations were undertaken at three different spatial states,
in
levels, namely, urban units, districts and federal
order
both
to
determine
interurban
differences
in
development and to illustrate imbalances between the larger spatial units of West Malaysia. Spatial intensity of regional disparities varies with scale. The development process in the regions will be illustrated by comparative analysis of disparities at the census dates 1957, 1970, and 1980. Differences in spatial structure are analysed using two specific
statistical
methods.
1 The
Rank-Size
Rule
is
used
to
examine the city size distribution in West Malaysia. Time series analysis is used to indicate whether the population of West Malaysia is becoming concentrated into fewer settlements or whether a process
of dispersal
expressed by the values of the
is occurring. Socio-economic development is
patterns
indicators.
produced by· the
positive or negative
By means of factor analysis,
a large
number of indicators representing the regions of West Malaysia can be aggregated into a few complex groupings without loss of essential information. This procedure helps to clarify the complex interrelationships between the individual indicators, thereby facilitating interregional comparison. The following analysis of West cate whether
polarization
reversal
~1alaysia
is
is intended to indi-
taking
place,
that
is,
whether a phase of increasing concentration is followed first by intraregional dispersal and subsequently by interregional dispersal processes.
Spatial Disparities in West Malaysia
55
Methodological and Statistical Problems Lack of alternative data necessitated the almost exclusive use in the
following
study
of
statistics
published
by
the
Malaysian
Department of Stati sties which, on account of their availability and the delimitation of the spatial units, posed inherent problems. These problems are discussed below. The
Ran~-Size
Rule was applied using population data for the
50 larg~st urban units in West Malaysia from the Population Census 2 of Malaysia for the years 1957, 1970, and 1980. In the statistics, no differentiation is made between high density settlements occupying small areal units on the one hand, and, on the other, rel atively large settlement units - in terms of population numbers which are, however, areally extensive and low density and include dispersed settlements and isolated farmsteads (for example, Pangkal Kalong in Kelantan). Both types are classified administratively as town council
or
local
council
and as
such are included in the
study. The factor analysis uses data at district and federal state levels.
Each federal state includes a number of unsubdivided dis-
tricts. Between 1970 and 1980 there were territorial reforms in the federal states of Kedah, Kelantan, Negeri Sembilan, Pahang, Perak, and Selangor, as a result of which the boundaries of some districts were readjusted and a new federal state and, in some cases, new 3 districts were created. Consequently, comparability of the spatial units between 1970 and 1980 is limited and the conclusions which can
be
drawn
relating
inevitably limited. differentiation
to
regional
development
dynamics
are
It was necessary to either forego a study of
within
a
state
or
to
exclude
the
respective
districts from the investigation. Availability of data also imposed limitations. Factor analysis
56
Heidrun Frohloff-Kulke
could not be carried out for 1957, since for that year only population data were available.
Although the Census of Manufacturing
Industries and the Population and Housing Census were held in dif4 ferent years, the time inconsistencies were accepted, since industrial data were indispensable for the study. In the case of several significant economic and social indicators, for example, GDP, employment rate, productivity in economic sectors,
teachers
population,
per
patients
either completely
1,000
population,
per doctor,
lacking,
is
and
telephones
so forth,
based only upon
per
a data
1,000
base
is
or
is
estimates,
available only at federal state level. The incomplete nature of the spatial data meant that the following study could in part be undertaken only at the federal state level in
\~est
Malaysia.
The indicators included in the study are listed in Table III.1 which also shows the census date,
level
of territorial
unit for
which the data are available, and the statistical sources.
Rank-Size Rule
~let hod
Based on the observation that there are in a country (or region) a large number of sma 11 , fewer medi urn-si zed, and a sma 11 number of large settlements as well as only one metropolitan centre, Auerbach (1913)
formulated
his
"Law
of
Population
Concentration"
which
created the basis of the Rank-Size Rule. The latter was developed further by Zipf (1941).
Spatial Disparities in West Malaysia
57
The law formulated by Zipf states that, if the urban units in a region are ranked by their population in decreasing order of size (that
is,
so
that
the
largest urban unit is given rank 1, the
second largest is given rank 2, and so forth), the product of population
(Pr)
and rank (r)
remains constant and has a value very
close to the population size of the largest city (P ): 1
pr · r
= pl ·
This relationship can be alternatively expressed as a linear equation: log Pr = log P - log r. 1 When this expression is plotted on daub le logarithmic paper with the logarithm of population on the ordinate and logarithm of rank
on
the
abscissa,
the
points
should form
an approximately
straight line with a slope of -1. This is shown in Figure III.1.
FIGURE III.l
Relationship bet.een Rank and Population
Population (log. scale)
Population
0
L
rank
rank (log. scale)
TABLE III.l
I~
Indicators used in the Study
::J: (1)
~.
Indicator
Year
Level of ref.
Source
Population
1957, 1970, 1980
sll ,ozl
a, b, c, 1
Population density
1957, 1970, 1980
s,
0
a, b, c, d
Malays in population
1970' 1980
s,
0
b, c
~6
Chinese in population
1970, 1980
s,
0
b, c
~6
Indians in population
1970, 1980
s,
0
b, c
Number of motor vehicles per 1000 people
1970, 1980
s,
0
b, c, e, f
0
b, c, e, f
Number of motor cycles/scooters per 1000 people
1970, 1980
s,
% of living quarters with electricity
1970, 1980
s,
0
e, f
% of living quarters with piped water
1970, 1980
s,
0
e, f
% of living quarters without toilet facilities
1970, 1980
s,
0
e, f
% of living quarters without special cooking facilities
1970, 1980
s,
0
e, f
Average number of rooms per living quarter
1970' 1980
s,
0
e, f
Average number of persons per room
1970, 1980
s,
0
b, c, e, f
1973, 1981 3 1970 ) ,1980
s,
Gross domestic product per capita Infant mortality rate
1970' 1980
Persons per registered doctor
0 s
g, h b, c, i,
s
1970, 1980
s
population in towns 'llD. ODD people
1970, 1980
s
Manufacturing employees per 1000 people
1970, 1980
s
~6
,
~
~~
Salaries and wages paid per paid worker
c..
"'5
District
Factor
Factor
'"Factor
Factor
va I ue
value
value
value
1970
1980
1970
1980
District
Kuala Langat *
• 5282
.2716
Kota Bahru
. 7437
.6141
Kuala Muda
.1264
.2394
Yan
• 7952
• 7094
Kuala Selangor *
.0641
.1923
Kuala Trengganu
- 1.2223
.8249
Perak Hilir *
.1750
.1870
Perak Tengah *
la rut dan Matang, Se lama
.2685
.1599
Kuala Krai *
Kota Setar *
.1056
.1478
Baling
• 7472
- 1.0549
Kuala P1lah
.0447
.0672
Dun gun
.8674
- 1.0923
Pontian
.1495
.0477
Machang
- l. 3996
- 1.1709
Temerloh
.0712
.0210
Tanah Merah
- 1.1689
- l. 2805
Kat a Tinggi
.3141
Kuala Kangsar *
.0798
-
.8856 .9858
.0361
Tumpat
- l. 5809
- l. 3183
.0472
Ulu Trengganu
- l. 3287
- 1.3419
Perlis
.4810
.0524
Pendang *
Mersing
.2663
.1462
Ulu Kelantan
Jerantut
.6377
.2844
Sik
- l. 3838
*
• 7902
l. 3937
- 1.0996
- l. 4898
Ker ian
.3821
.3800
Pasir Puteh
- l. 3684
- l. 5299
Sabak Bernam *
.3000
.3805
Padang Terap
- l. 3540
- l. 5997
.9957
.3923
Besut
- 1.5573
- 1.6649
. 7004
.4540
Pas.1r Mas
- l. 2246
- l. 6693
Pekan
*
Kubang Pasu Perak Hulu
.1574
.5226
Pulau Langkaw.1
- 1.1097
- 1.6706
Lip is
.5386
.5466
Bachok
- l. 9395
- l. 8329
- l. 5420
- 2.0084
Bandar Bahru
.3364
.5521
Marang
Kemaman
. 7455
.5697
Kuala Lumpur
.6110
*
Rompin *
*
2.1696
Distr1cts under reform
I~ c
:=s
..., ~
0
:::>""
_.,
~
0
-+> I
""~
"' ro
Spatial Disparities in West Malaysia FIGURE I I I. 6
Factor of Socio-Economic Developaent for West Malaysia according to Districts
1970
Va
Pulau
THAI LAND
factor scores
2 1, 0
0,3 - < 1, 0 0,0 - < 0,3 0,3 - < 0,0 1,0 -
3. 71
48.25
1.64
3.86
68.66
1.56
r+
0.11
3.13
0.11
0.74
36.97
0.84
0.22
5.53
0.19
0.42
15.15 175.55
19.68
0.45
0 ....., ......
5.97 14.63 197.83
4.51
c:
r+
0.12
3.36
0.11
0.08
4.17
0.10
0.04
2.79
0.09
0.05
5.50
0.13
1.42
31.02
1.06
2.94
81.27
1.85
0.16
5.88
0.20
0.12
7.44
0.17
0. 25
8. 27
0. 28
0. 41
20.71
0. 47
:::>
0.. (/)
-s
~ (./)
'< (/)
r+
ro
3
(/)
0.18
9.17
0.31
0.17
14.50
0.33
Keranan
0.16
9.04
0. 31
0. 35
26.50
0.60
K. Trengganu
0.79
11.57
0.39
1.10
23.73
0.54
Marang
0.05
6.34
0.22
0.06
12.31
0.28
0.20
15.57
0.53
0.25
28.75
0.65
OJ
13.53
51.46
1.75 11.75
59.50
1.36
'< (/)
W. Malaysia 100.00
29.39
1.00 100.00
43.91
1.00
OJ
:::>
::E:
ro
(/)
r+ 3: OJ
~
>---'
~ Share of the district in total errplo}1Tent In
cc
!; :;> 300,000 West Malaysia
of size-class in total growth 1973 - 1981 in % annual growth rate
RF = regional factor
41.54
33.65
25.33
5.86
0.810
100.00
100.00
100.00
8.69
1.000
Development of Industrial Systems in West Malaysia
149
The complex growth patterns and relationships between the subcentre and the tertiary centres described above, arise from the fact that a high share of employment does not necessarily mean a high contribution to value added. In terms of employment, for example, Tengah (Melaka) and Ulu Langat are tertiary centres, whereas in terms of value added they fall into the category of subcentres. The main features can be summarized as follows: districts with 10,000-20,000 employees made the greatest relative contribution to growth, and districts in the category of M$ 100-300 million achieved both the highest relative and absolute contribution to growth. The core region suffered absolute decline in its share of value added, whereas it retained its leading position in terms of employment growth.
Summary The spatial patterns resulting from industrialization in West Malaysia were analysed in order to establish the presence or otherwise of decentralization processes in terms of a polarization reversal. The analysis which was carried out at district and federal state level yielded the following results in terms of the objectives of the study: 1
Up to 1968, industry became increasingly concentrated in the federal state of Selangor. At federal state and district levels, the period after 1968 saw the emergence of decentralization trends which were expressed in terms of below-average growth rates and falling shares of employment and value added in the industrial core regions (Selangor; Petaling and W.P.), with simultaneous disproportionate growth in other regions.
150
Knut Koschatzky indications
Further
this
of
were
process
the
widespread
reductions in the weighted coefficients of variation and the Gini coefficients after 1968. 2.
Although the industrial core regions declined in relative importance,
they remain the main locations of employment and
production potential by virtue of their absolute growth. 3.
From the spatial distribution of growth-intensive districts, it is possible to identify a pattern of intraregional decentralization Petaling/W.P.
the
in
preliminary
of
the
core
region
of
(towards Ulu Langat and Kuala Langat) and the (towards Kuala Muda and Kulim).
state of Penang intraregional
hinterland
decentralization interregional
does
not
decentralization:
Increasing
constitute both
a
processes
operate concurrently. 4.
Colonial and economic influences (the free ports of Penang and Singapore) had caused the spatial industrial structure of West Malaysia at the beginning of the period under investigation to be characterized by a polycentric system with subcentres possessing internal growth dynamics. Further inverstigation was necessary in order to establish whether growth processes in other
subcentres
and
tertiary
centres
had
influenced
the
spatial development process. Two phases were identified after 1968: a) 1968-73: above- average growth in Ti mor La ut and Utara and the growing economic power of Penang as an industrial counter-magnet to Se l angor ( Kua la Lumpur), accompanied by reduced rates of growth in Selangor. b) 1973-81: increasing industrial significance of Penang, due
Development of Industrial Systems in West Malaysia
151
to the shift of growth to Barat Daya and Tengah; further decentralization in Selangor (with Kelang and Ulu Langat) and more widespread spatial diversification within the west coast states, reflecting dynamic industrial growth in Seremban, Tengah (Melaka), Batu Pahat, and Kuala Muda; more intensive growth in Pahang (Pekan/Rompin), Trengganu (Kuala Trengganu, Kemaman) and in some of the smaller centres (for example, Kota Tinggi, Kuala Kerai, Kulim); and persistence of below-average growth rates in Petaling and, particularly, in W.P. In other words, growth impetus emanated not only from the subcentres present in 1968, but also from districts in the category of 10,000-20,000 employees which between 1973 and 1981 made a decisive contribution to a reduction in spatial polarization. 5.
Decisive influences on the interregional decentralization process among the districts on the west coast were exerted by the locational behaviour of foreign, world-market-oriented enterprises in the fields of electronics and textiles. After 1973, more enterprises belonging to these branches began to locate in the less industrialized regions of West Malaysia.
6.
The turning point in spatial development began to emerge between 1968 and 1973 and became more influential after 1973. The absolute loss of significance of the industrial core region expected by Richardson at a late stage in the process, was not observable.in Petaling and Kuala Lumpur up to 1981, although a decline in relative significance was demonstrable.
In conclusion, evaluation of the data for West Malaysia between 1968 and 1981 reveals tv10 significant features: reduced in-
152
Knut Koschatzky
dustrial
concentration
accompanied
by
intra-
and
interregional
decentralization, particularly between districts in the west coast states
and,
reduction
secondly,
in
the
polarization
relative
reversal
significance of
in
the
sense of
a
the major centres of
manufacturing industry, that is, Petaling and W.P.
Major Determinants of Spatial Differentiation This part of the study seeks to identify those factors which have encouraged reduced spatial concentration trends. Since industrial data classified according to branches is available only for 1981 at district level, shift analysis could not be used to establish the causes of growth (structural and locational influences).
In terms
of the polarization reversal hypothesis, the most important causes of spatial
differentiation are agglomeration disadvantages in the
central region, locational advantages in the subcentres and spatial policy measures implemented by the government. The significance of these determinants for spatial development in West Malaysia is discussed
belmv,
based
on
the
results
of
locational
surveys
of
manufacturing firms.
Agglomeration Factors Locational
Surveys of Enterprises in West Malaysia.
Bet1veen 1981
and 1982, the Socio-Economic Research Unit of the Prime
~linister's
Department carried out a survey of manufacturing enterprises in the 27 Klang Valley (KV) and other regions (OR) of West Malaysia. Within the KV,
140 enterprises 1vere surveyed,
accounting for 18.4% of
enterprises in the following locations: W.P., the towns of Petaling Jaya and Shah Alam (Petaling), Kelang, Port Kelang (Kelang), Rawang
153
Development of Industrial Systems in West Malaysia ( Gombak),
and Kaj ang/Bang i
( Ul u Langa t) . The survey also i ne l uded
districts defined in the present study as subcentres or tertiary centres, and which were not classified as part of the core region. Since the places
mentioned
are
located
within
the
vicinity
of
Petaling and W.P., this justified using the survey to shed light on location factors within the central region. The
OR
(Selangor),
regions
cover
locations
in
the
Outer Klang
Valley
in Pahang, Kelantan, Kedah, and Perlis, comprising 72
enterprises in the survey. The results of this survey were supplemented by the present author's ovm interviews held in March/April
1984 and 1985
in
the Johor
Bahru
area and in kua la ~1uda/Kul i m
(Kedah) comprising a total of 50 enterprises (cf. Koschatzky 1986).
Location Factors and Evaluation of Locations in the Central Region. A major West
feature of the spatial
~lalaysia
pattern of industrialization in
between 1973 and 1981 was the decline in relative
importance of the central region, that is, Petaling and W.P. On the other
hand,
occurred
in
fundamental tricts,
greatest
absolute
Petal ing,
which
growth
(employment,
raises
the
question
value
added)
of
whether
agglomerative disadvantages have emerged in these dis-
or vJhether
high
ab so 1 ute
growth
reflects
the
continued
presence of positive locational influences. The most important criteria determining the choice of location in the KV was the population and industrial potential of the region and the available infrastructure. Proximity to market \vas named as the decisive location factor by 47.1 % of the 140 enterprises, followed by access to Port Kelang (27.1 %),
(19.3 %), and ( 18.6 %) .
availability
of
availability of labour
fully-serviced
industrial
sites
154
Knut Koschatzky Once enterprises had begun production, the major locational
advantages quoted were the substantial marketing opportunities in the
KV
(78.4 %),
(64.7 %),
availability
proximity to the port
of
infrastructural
(58.3 %),
and
facilities
labour
supply
%).
(49.6
Apart from factors relating to agglomeration advantages, only 98 enterprises mentioned locational disadvantages of which the most important were lab our shortages ( 60.2 %),
inadequate i nfrastruc-
ture, especially disruption of electricity supplies (30.6 %), lack of space for expansion (28.6 %) , and telecommunications problems ( 13.3 %) . On balance, it appears that production facilities in the Klang Valley are still regarded as positive despite the small number of enterprises which were critical of their location. Problems were, nevertheless, apparent, particularly relating to the availability of labour. The long established industrial process and diversity of branches
in
this
region
have
demanding relatively high wages; labour 28
(particularly female
created
a
skilled
labour
force
the demand for cheap, unskilled
labour)
can no longer be adequately
met.
Although the agglomeration problems referred to by Richardson (lack of industrial space, inadequate infrastructure) are also observable,
they have
not yet resulted in relocations out of the
Klang Valley. Of the 140 enterprises, 30.7% would choose the same industrial estate and 45 % the same location for expansion, while 24.3 % of the enterprises were prepared to consider other federal states (4.3% Negeri Sembilan and Pahang and 3.6% Johor), an attitude which has grown in recent years and which is reflected in the 29 trend towards spatial decentralization already observed.
Development of Industrial Systems in West Malaysia
155
Two different determinants of spatial differentiation emerge from the perception of 1ocati on noted above. For enterprises producing mainly for the domestic market the importance of proximity to market renders the concentration of industry and population in the
KV
an
agglomerative
unskilled
labour
producing
for
could
export
advantage.
In
stimulate
to
relocate
contrast,
shortages
labour-intensive outside
the
of
enterprises
central
region,
particularly if the alternative locations were able to offer satisfactory infrastructure.
Location Factors outside the Central Region. The Socio-Economic Research Unit's survey was confined to the less developed parts of Selangor and the states of Pahang, Kelantan, Kedah, and Perlis. Of the 72 enterprises questioned in these regions (OR), 36.1% stated proximity to rav1 materials as the most important location factor, reflecting
the
influence
of
Pahang
and
Kelantan
(timber
processing). The second most important factor influencing location after 1975 was availability of labour (26.9 %). Proximity to the investor's home and to markets were also significant factors. Once production had begun, the most significant location factor named was availability of labour (72.5 %), followed by infrastructure facilities and access to raw materials (40.6
%). Whereas
in the KV there were no responses to the question relating to low wage costs, this factor ranked seventh (11.1 %) in the OR. The labour
highest number of negative responses availability,
together
with
again related to
inadequate
infrastructure
(38.7 % of 62 enterprises). Nevertheless, no less than 60.2% of the enterprises surveyed in the KV quoted inadequate labour supply as a locational disadvantage. Telecommunications problems and poor market
prospects
(22.6% and 17.7 %, respectively)
were also re-
156
Knut Koschatzky
garded as locational drawbacks. In contrast to the situation in the KV, labour problems in OR were mostly related to the inadequate supply of skilled workers, 30 However, not all less derather than lack of unskilled workers. veloped regions in West Malaysia possess an unlimited supply of unskilled labour. According to the author's own survey conducted in Kedah there were, for example, severe shortages of unskilled female workers in the electronics industry, especially in Kulim which is not far from Bayan Lepas Industrial
Estate and Free Trade Zone.
This is partly due to the more attractive wage levels in Penang and partly a reflection of the dominance of Islam which confines the available female labour force to the more "Westernized" families. These shortages are not, however, regarded as an insoluble problem, because there are still adequate labour reserves in the rural hi nterlands therefore,
of
the with
industrial supplies
locations. of
Less
unskilled
developed
labour
and
regions, low
wages
constitute attractive locations for enterprises seeking to minimize 31 wage costs. Infrastructural shortcomings, stated as a problem by only 40.6 % of the sample, do not appear to be very significant. Two
factors
influencing
spatial
patterns
in
West Malaysia
emerged from the locational surveys: proximity to market which encourages
concentration,
and
availability
levels which encourage decentralization.
of labour and low wage Since the survey by the
Socio-Economic Research Unit showed that fundamental agglomeration disadvantages have not yet emerged in the central region, the decentralization process observed cannot have been triggered by them. The distinctive locational advantages offered by other regions in the country must be regarded as causing the decentralization observed.
Development of Industrial Systems in West Malaysia
157
Spatial Economic Policy Since 1973, when the Mid-term Review of the Second Malaysia Plan 1971-1975 was published, and more particularly since 1976 (Third Malaysia Plan), industrialization policy has, through its emphasis on
regional
Malaysian
policy
objectives,
Government's
become
an
integral
regional
policy measures component of the New Economic Policy. 32
part of the
and,
thereby,
a
Starting in 1952, industrial estates were established to attract
industry,
pioneer status, estates
were
complementing locational
located
investment
incentives,
near
large
incentives,
etc.
cities
such
as
The first industrial on
the
west
coast,
reflecting the policy of encouraging import-substituting industries implemented up to 1968. When export diversification was attempted after 1968, corresponding facilities had to be provided. Free trade zones 1vere attractive
set up
from 1971
preferential
producing for export. Economic
Policy,
onwards which offered particularly
customs
regulations
to
enterprises
In the wake of the formulation of the Ne1v
provision of
industrial
estates and free trade
zones 1vas used increasingly as an instrument of spatial economic . 33 po l 1cy. In 1983 there were 101 industrial estates and free trade zones throughout the federal states of Malaysia. Of the industrial space already allocated, 25% is in Selangor and 1-J.P., 54.5% in Johor, Helaka, Negeri Sembilan, Perak and Penang, 6.7% in Kedah and Perlis, and 13.8% in Kelantan, Trengganu, and Pahang. With the exception of Perak, the greater part of this industrial space is located in the growth-intensive west coast states, although the east coast states
account
for
an
employment (Table IV.l).
above-average
proportion
in
terms
of
158
Knut Koschatzky The significance of the industrial estates and the free trade
zones in influencing spatial patterns is reflected in the following: 1.
Reference to "fully serviced sites" (18.6 % in the KV) as a location factor in the survey;
2.
the number of enterprises giving preference to an industrial estate
in
average
their choice of
of
51.8
% of
location.
In 1978 and 1982,
investment projects
an
approved by the
Malaysian Industrial Development Authority were to be located in an industrial estate (FIDA 1979, p. 36; MIDA 1983, p. 23); 3.
industrial oriented
development
to
date.
industrialization
and
In
the
against
course of exportthe
background
of
growth in a few districts with a high percentage of employment in the electronics industry (cf. sectoral change 1973-81) two trends are apparent. The spatial distribution of free trade zones has, on the one hand, further encouraged concentration in the Kl ang Valley ( S!.mga i Way /Subang FTZ, Ampang/Ul u Ke l ang FTZ) and, on the other hand, lent impetus to decentralization trends. For example, the high growth of employment and value added in Barat Daya (Penang) is almost entirely attributable to
the electronics 34 Free Trade Zone. The
free
enhance
trade the
industry established in the Bayan Lepas
zones
of
locational
Tanjong
Kling
attraction
of
and
Batu Berendam 35 Tengah (Melaka).
Although there is no free trade zone in Seremban, the early establishment of the Senawang Industrial Estate (1966) and the possession
of
some
vJarehouse
status
enterprises (with
of
preferential
Licensed customs
Manufacturing regulations 36
similar to those in the FTZ) provided attractive locations.
Development of Industrial Systems in West Malaysia
159
The quasi-FTZ in Senai (Johor) is to be extended (seven enterprises in spring 1984) and a free trade zone is to be deve loped in the port area of Pasir Gudang by 1985. In
addition
to
the
indirect
locational
guidance
outlined
above, the Industrial Coordination Act of 1975 also gives the Mal ays i an
Industrial Development Authority, an advisory body asso-
ciated with
the granting of manufacturing licences required for
investment in excess of M$ 250,000 (from December 1985 of M$ 1 million and over), the opportunity to actively influence individual location decisions, as the granting of licence may be tied to the cl oice of location (cf. Government of Malaysia 1983). Government spatial policy, through industrial estates and free trade zones, therefore, constitutes the third major determinant of spatial differentiation in Malaysia. Other
regionally
influential
factors
have
also
served
to
counteract the process of industrial concentration. These include the new land development policy (for example, Pahang Tenggara and industrial growth in Pekan/Rompin), integrated development projects (for
example,
Seremban
of
Kuala
Muda
in Kedah),
proximity
to
Singapore
(port)
proximity
to
intensive 37 Melaka.
branches
of
the
the positive influence on
Klang and
production
Valley,
efforts from
and
on
Johor
to transfer
Singapore
to
of
labour-
Johor
and
Conclusion For the period after 1968 it is possible to identify decentralization trends average
in the manufacturing industry in terms of above-
growth
in
selected
districts,
particularly
in
the
160
Knut Koschatzky
industrial subcentres (10,000-20,000 employees). This growth pattern corresponds with the spatial process described in the polarization reversal hypothesis. These developments were
stimulated
region.
by
locational
advantages
The most significant factors
in
outside
the
central
spatial differentiation
processes were the availability of low-wage labour and infrastructural investment on the part of the Malaysian Government in industrial
estates
and
free
trade
zones.
Contrary
to
Richardson's
hypothesis, major agglomeration disadvantages have not yet become apparent in the central region (Klang Valley). The final
point to consider is the extent to which general
conclusions can be derived from the regional development process as observed in West Malaysia. In
contrast
to
many
other
countries
in
the
Third
World
Malaysia had a polycentric settlement structure at a very early stage which subsequently prevented a process of extreme concentration. Johor Bahru/Singapore in the south, Ipoh and Penang in the northwest were both centres of population counterbalancing Kuala Lumpur and the industrial locations. In West Malaysia, therefore, the phase of interregional decentralization and associated development of subcentres, as described by Richardson, was able to be the decentra 1 i za t ion process was further encouraged by
bypassed;
the infrastructure already present in these regions. Strict limitations are therefore placed on the transferability of
the generalizations obtained from
the Malaysian case.
It is
evident that a balanced settlement structure is able to influence efforts
to
reduce
industrial
concentration.
Appropriate natural
conditions (ports, natural resources) and a policy of industrialization which explicitly emphasizes and actively pursues the goal of
Development of Industrial Systems in West Malaysia
161
regional balance are also basic requirements for a polarization reversal. Alongside this, however, there must also exist an appropriate investment climate, since the investors (state and private) are the driving force underlying industrial development and therefore influence the spatial dimension of the industrialization process.
In viev1 of its central
Southeast Asia, other
developing
location in the growth market of
Malaysia possesses indisputable advantages over countries
(cf.
Laumer 1984) and has used the
growth opportunities of the world market to create a more balanced regional industrial structure.
NOTES "Manufacturing is defined as the mechanical or chemical transformation of inorganic substances into new products whether the work is performed by power-driven machines or by hand, whether it is done in a factory or in the worker's home, and whether the products are sold at wholesale or retail" (Department of Statistics,Malaysie,l972, p. 20). 2
In spatial economic theory the most important factors of spatial di fferentiation are agglomeration factors (internal and external savings), transport costs and the economy's dependence on the factor land. Cf. summary in Schatzl (1978), p. 81 ff.
3
The polarization reversal hypothesis is discussed in chapter I. Cf. the study of Japan by Lo, Salih, and Douglass (1978). Although the authors find evidence of a process of decentralization, they conclude that the balancing mechanisms identified do not apply to developing countries on account of Japan's high level of advancement (ibid., pp. 65-70). A study by Linn of Colombia concluded that no decentralization trends were observable there (Linn 1978).
4
The manufacturing industry was selected for detailed analysis as it decisively influences the spatial development and its impact on job creation and incomes causatively affects the development of spatial disparities. The strategic rule of manufacturing industry in the rwtional development process is emph~si7Prl in M~l~ysian de11Plopment pl~nninq: "In line wHh the New lconumic Policy (NEP), the matlufacturinq c;ector ••• is expected to generate
162
Knut Koschatzky significant opportunities in employment and participation of the poorer section of the community, in particular the Bumiputera. In addition, the sector is viewed to have considerable potential for securing a balanced industrial growth among regions" (Government of Malaysia 1984, p. 249).
5
Department of Statistics, Malaysia (1968). The 1981 census was published as a survey. The complete data were kindly made available by the Department of Statistics, Manufacturing Division.
6
Value-added data were not published for 1959; only the largest enterprises were classified according to branch.
7
The 70 districts in West Malaysia which existed until about 1973 were gradually reorganized into 78 districts. In Johor, Melaka, Penang and Trengganu there were no changes; in Kedah, Kelantan, Negeri Sembilan, and Pahang district reform did not involve boundary changes; reforms in Perak and Selangor resulted in boundary changes. On 1 February 1974, Selangor lost Kuala Lumpur as an independent state and district, Wilayah Persekutuan. In the 1973 statistics, Padang Terap and Sik (Kedah), and Pekan and Rompin (Pahang) constituted two districts, respectively, and these combinations were also retained in the calculations for 1968 and 1981.
8
The problem of selecting methods is also stressed by Richardson who points out that there is still no standardized set of indicators available for measuring a polarization reversal in different countries (cross-section analysis). Cf. Richardson (1980), pp. 81 ff.
9
The indices are explained when they are used for the first time.
10
Employees in this study include both full-time and part-time paid workers.
ll
No source is given for the following tables and maps; they represent the results of the author's calculations based on the census data as indicated.
12
Cf. Cheong and Fong (1979); German Development Institute (1978); Lim (1976); Singh (1976); and Spinanger (1980).
13
A major reason is probably the establishment of labour-intensive industries. This is also suggested in the case of Penang by the varying shares of employment and value added (1973: 17.1 ~o and 13.1 ~o, resp. ). Cf. Werner (1982).
14
The growth registered by Pahang reflects essentially regional policy aid to the growth pole of Kuantan as well as the effects of new land development in the regions of Jengka Triangle and Pahang Tenggara.
15
For example, despite a lower average annual growth rate, absolute growth in employment between 1973 and 1981 was 59.1 ~o above that for the period 1968-73.
Development of Industrial Systems in West Malaysia
163 oc-
16
In terms of industrial employment ratio and LQ of employment,Penang has cupied first place since 1973.
17
Branch structure in 1981 is examined in more detail in chapter 3. locational advantages are discussed on pp. 138 ff., 153 ff.
18
The variables value added/employees, value added per capita and industrial employment per capita each received a weighting of 1.0; wages per employee and employment per enterprise a weighting of 0.25; and the shares of employment and value added 2.0 each. These weightings were obtained from comparisons with different weighted variables and produced the best approximation to a regionalization based on factor analysis for the period 1957-70 on 45 socio-economic indicators. Cf. Singh (1976), pp. 323 ff.
19
The growth process in Kuala Langat is not expressed in the RF of the index value because of the high level of value added per employee in 1973 in this district. Whereas all other indices have grown disproportionately, average value added/employees declined from M$ 25,484.6 to M$ 8,030.3 because of the strong growth in employment of 37.8 ~~ (per annum) and thereby resulted in an RF less than l.
20
The deviations in the case of Kuala Langat have been referred to above.
21
Detailed reference to the influence of Singapore lies beyond the scope of the present study. Cf. p. 159.
22
It can only be presumed that the reason for the decline in employment in Timur Laut lies in Barat Daya 's specialist function as a location for the electronics industry with corresponding loss of labour in this branch in Timur Laut. This cannot, however, be regarded as intraregional decentralization, since Bay an Lepas is, in fact, only the industrial estate of Georgetown which lies in a different district.
23
In 1983, Trengganu accounted for 44.2 % of Malaysia's crude oil production. Enterprises associated with the oil industry are to be established in this state as part of the creation of heavy industry in Malaysia. Cf. Government of Malaysia (1984), pp. 20, 169, 179. "The first signs are vast earthworks and coastal development in preparation for a new urban industrial complex in Kemaman district~ Far Eastern Economic Review, 28 August 1981, "Focus: Malaysia '81", p. 48.
24
Whereas in 1981/82 an average of 20.8 ~~ of industrial production was exported (industrial exports in relation to gross production), the export quota in the electronics industry reached 82 %; this industry's volume of exports (M$ 3.71 billion) accounted for 49.8 % of total industrial exports (calculated from Dept. of Statistics of Malaysia l983b, l983c).
25
Cf. the case study of Kelantan by E. Kulke in this volume.
Specific
164 26
Knut Koschatzky This
different
compilation of
weighting
of
the
indices classes,
variables produces, in contrast to the differences in the regional allocation to
the individual classes. 27
Socio-Economic Research Unit, Prime Minister's Department, 1982. We are indebted to the Socio-Economic Research Unit and the Klang Valley Secretariat for access to this study. Unless otherwise indicated, all following data are derived from this study.
28
This also applies to Penang and Johor. Cf. Asia Finance (198~, pp. 78 ff. In contrast to the KV and to Penang, emerging shortages in this section of the labour market in Johor are a result not only of rising wages but also of the demand for Malaysian labour in Singapore.
29
" ••• Data
from
the
study
investors have begun
to
have
indicated
that
over
time more
seriously consider alternatives in OR,
and more i.e.,
less
developed regions" (Socio-Economic Research Unit 1982, p. xxxv). 30
disadvantages faced by OR investors in the limited supply of skilled workers" (Socio-Economic Research Unit 1982, p. 174).
31
"K.V. had a relatively larger proportion of semi-skilled and skilled workers who were paid higher wages as compared to the unskilled pool of labour in OR where generally lower levels of wages were paid ••. Data have indicated that OR has a slight advantage over K.V. in terms of the availability of unskilled labour" (Socio-Economic Research Unit 1982, p. 173).
32
"Thus the (manufacturing) sector will provide large scope for redistributing economic activity away from the established manufacturing regions, especially the Klang Valley, towards the less developed states" (Government of Malaysia 1976, p. 211). For terminology relating to spatial economic policy, cf. Schatzl (1986), p. 13-29.
33
"The maJor objectives of the strategies included disperse industries away from the urban centres to through the development of industrial estates and facilities with the aim of achieving a balanced regions" (Government of Malaysia 1984, p. 250).
34
Cf. Penang Development Corporation (1979), p. ll. The free trade zones have, at the same time, influenced the government's aim of increasing the share of Malays (bumiputeras) in industrial employment. Bumiputeras account for over 50 % of employment in the free trade zones of Penang and in the Sungai Way FTZ; the majority are presumably women. Cf. Leinbach (1982).
35
Cf.
v.
viewed
Naerssen (1980).
In Melaka too,
the following: ••• b) to the less developed areas related infrastructural industrial growth among
the employment effects have to be
in
context: 11 In the Free TrndP Zones lorated in Malacca, it is reported that 99 % of the new jobs created are taken up by both local women
and migrant women from as far as Terengganu, whilst male labour from the
Development of Industrial Systems in West Malaysia
165
local areas remains unemployed~ Chi (1982), p. 14. 36
Cf. Leinbach (1982), p. 463; v. Naerssen (1980), p. 6; and Lim (1979).
37
The locational survey carried out by the author in the districts of Johor Bahru and Batu Pahat in Johor state comprising 20 industrial establishments showed that proximity to Singapore (port and infrastructure) is the most important locational factor (75 ?~ of the responses), followed by fully serviced industrial sites (60 %) and the low wage level (50 %)(cf. Koschatzky 1986). The Singapore Government's policy until 1984 of encouraging the establishment ~f capital-intensive and technologically oriented production by raising wage costs and of relocating labour-intensive sections of production could have stimulated further development, particularly in the form of job creation, in the southern part of West Malaysia which is within easy reach of Singapore. Cf. Star, 24 March 1984: "Singapore firm moves factory to Malacca" (Chen 1983, pp. 12 ff., 112).
REFERENCES Asia Finance. "Amidst the virgin forests, a ne11 awakening". file: Malaysia 7, No. 10 (1981): 60-87. Chen,
P.S.J., ed. Singapore, 1983.
~
Singapore. Development Policies and Trends.
Cheong Kee Cheok, and Fong Chan Onn. "Regional Development in Malaysia". In Regional Development in Southeast Asian Countries, edited by Regional Developoment Research Institute of Developing Economies, pp. 157-259. Tokyo, 1979. Chi Seck Choo. "Accelerated Industrialization and Employment Opportunities in Malaysia". Geoforum 13, No. 1 (1982): 11-18. Corvinus, F. Probleme der Energieversorgung eines tropischen Entwicklungslandes Das Beispiel Malaysia. Jahrbuch der Geographischen Gesellschaft zu Hannover. Hannover, 1984. Department of Statistics, Federation of Malaya. 1957 Population Census of the Federation of Malaya. Kuala Lumpur, 1960. Department of Statistics Malaysia. Census of Manufacturing Industries in theFede_!"at_i()_l1___()_fMalata__l_959. Kuala Lumpur, 1961.
166 Knut Koschatzky Census of Manufacturing Industries. --Malaya 1963. Kuala Lumpur, 1965 . . Malaysian --1972.
Industrial
III: The States of
Classification 1972. Kuala Lumpur,
Census of Manufacturing Industries, Peninsular Malaysia 1968, Vol. 1. Kuala Lumpur, undated. 1970 Population and Housing Census. Basic --Tables, Vol. 1. Kuala Lumpur, different years.
Population
Census of Manufacturing Industries. Peninsular Malaysia 1973, Vol. 1. Kuala Lumpur, undated . . Population and Housin Census of Malaysia 1980. Mukims: Population, Households and Living Quarters based on preliminary field count summaries). Kuala Lumpur, 1982. _ _ . Population and Housing Census of Malaysia 1980. General Report of the Population Census, Vol. 2. Kuala Lumpur, 1983a . . Industrial Surveys 1981, Malaysia. Kuala Lumpur, 1983b . . Malaysia: Annual Statistics of External Trade 1982. Vol. 1, Part 1. Kuala Lumpur, 1983c. Far Eastern Economic Review: Focus: Malaysia '81. 28 August 1981, pp. 38-70. Federal Industrial Development Authority 1978. Kuala Lumpur, 1979.
(FIDA). Annual Report
German Development Institute, ed. Industrial Location Behaviour of Malaysian and Foreign Investors- The Effectiveness of the Malaysian Decentralization Policy. Berlin, 1978. Government of Malaysia. Lumpur, 1971.
Second Malaysia Plan 1971-1975. Kuala
Third Malaysia Plan 1976-1980. Kuala Lumpur, 1976. Fourth Malaysia Plan 1981-1985. Kuala Lumpur, 1981. Laws of Malaysia. Act 156. Industrial Co-ordination Act. Reprint No. 2. Kuala Lumpur, 1983. Mid-term Review of the Kuala Lumpur, 1984.
Fourth____t-1~laysia_flan_19~1~1