General Average and Risk Management in Medieval and Early Modern Maritime Business 3031041178, 9783031041174

This open access book explores the history of risk management in medieval and early modern European maritime business, f

144 61 9MB

English Pages 525 [510] Year 2023

Report DMCA / Copyright

DOWNLOAD PDF FILE

Table of contents :
Acknowledgements
About This Book
Conventions and Word Usage
Contents
Notes on Contributors
List of Figures
List of Tables
Why and How Risk Is Shared
Sharing Risks, on Averages and Why They Matter
Risk-Sharing and Risk-Shifting
The Theory and Practice of Risk Management: Silent Partnerships, Moral Hazards and (the Impossibility of) Correct Procedures
Lex Maritima, Lex Mercatoria and Early Modern States
Conclusion
General Average and All the Rest: The Law and Economics of Early Modern Maritime Risk Mitigation
Frank Knight on Uncertainty and Risk
Douglass North on Transaction Costs and Risk Spreading
Robert Scott on Contracts Under Uncertainty
Knight, North, Scott and the Origins of Marine Insurance
Before Marine Insurance—General Average
Applying the Theoretical Framework for Other Maritime Institutions
The Sea Loan
Commenda
The Business Corporation
Conclusion
Risky Narratives: Framing General Average into Risk-Management Strategies (Thirteenth–Sixteenth Centuries)
Appendix
Origins and Variants of Mutual Protection
General Average in Byzantium
General Average, the Rhodian Law of Jettison and the Roman Jurists: The Digest (6th c. AD)
General Average in the Byzantine Collection Entitled “The Rhodian Sea-Law” (7–8th C. AD)
General Average in the Basilica (ca. 900 AD)
Conclusion
Rules and Practices of General Average in the Islamic Mediterranean on the Eve of the Emergence of the Italian Communes
Rules and Criteria of Jettison
Commercial Commodities and Personal Belongings
Assessment of General Average
Shipping Charges
Valuation of the Vessel for Contribution
Summary and Conclusion
Principles and Developments of General Average: Statutory and Contractual Loss Allowances from the Lex Rhodia to the Early Modern Mediterranean
Average and Contribution: An Etymological Question
The Only Greek Law Handed Down to Us in Living Form?
Voluntary, Involuntary, and Mixed Acts
The Scandal of Νόμος Ροδίων Ναυτικός
The Catalan Germinamento
Conclusion
The Iberian Experience
The ‘Mutualisation’ of Maritime Risk in the Crown of Castile, 1300–1550
The Origin of Mutual Aid in Maritime Traffic
The Mutualist Geography of Medieval Atlantic Castile
Mutualisation of Maritime Risk ‘según la costumbre castellana’
General Average and Jettison
Conclusion
General Average, Compulsory Contributions and Castilian Normative Practice in the Southern Low Countries (Sixteenth Century)
Averages in the Low Countries: Types and Varieties
General Average in the Low Countries and Castilian Normative Practice
The Spanish Compulsory Contributions and the Issue of Protection Costs
Conclusion
The Nautical Republic of the Carrera de Indias: Commerce, Navigation, Casos Fortuitos and Avería Gruesa in the Sixteenth Century
The Carrera De Indias as a Space of Interaction for Navigation and Commerce
Merchants v Seamen: Two Professional Groups and One Enterprise
The Scene of Conflict: Lawsuits Regarding Casus Fortuitus and avería gruesa Between Merchants and Seamen
Suits for Avería Gruesa Before the Royal Court at the Casa de la Contratación in Seville
Sailors’ Wages and Freight Payment in Cases of Casus Fortuitus
Shipwrecks and Fleet Captains General: The Peculiarities of the Indies
Conclusion
The Genoese Experience
General Average in Genoa: Between Statutes and Customs
GA Rules from Roman Law to the Consolat de Mar: premises for the Evolution of a GA Genoese Policy
The Genoese Statute as a Source for the Study of Maritime Law
GA Rules in Genoa According to the Statutes: Jettison and Calculators
The Legislative and Procedural Changes of the XVII Century
The Economic Structure of Maritime Trade Calling at the Port of Genoa Through the Analysis of General Average Data (Sixteenth–Seventeenth Centuries)
Introduction
New Data for Genoese Maritime Historiography: Average Procedures
The Structure of Shipping Traffic at the End of the Sixteenth Century, Between Old and New Actors
Characteristics of the Ships Arriving in Genoa (1600–1608)
Consolidation of the Northerners’ Presence and the Subsidiary Function of Genoese Shipping in the Period of Crisis
The Port of Genoa and Its Network (1640–1641)
Financing and Risk in Genoese Maritime Trade During the Eighteenth Century: Strategies and Practices
Credit and Maritime Business
The Genoese Eighteenth Century Context
The Structure of Bottomry Contracts
Bottomries, Average (Avaria) and Risk Management
The Genoese Bottomry Market and  Its Protagonists
Mature Systems
Divide and Rule: Risk Sharing and Political Economy in the Free Port of Livorno
The Free Port of Livorno and Its International Competition
To the Benefit of the Shipmaster?
The French Cottimo
Tuscany’s ‘Northern’ Policy
Conclusion
GA Adjustments in Amsterdam: Reinforcing Authority Through Transparency and Accountability (Late Sixteenth–Early Seventeenth Century)
Introduction
GA and the Amsterdam Chamber of Insurance and Average
The Statute Book of the Chamber
Reinforcing the Authority of the Chamber
Concluding Remarks
‘The Honour of Giving My Opinion’: General Average, Insurance and the Compilation of the Ordonnance de la marine of 1681
Contextualising the Ordonnance: Custom, Positive Law and the French State
The Chambre and the Compilation of the Ordonnance
Conclusion
Bibliography
Index
Recommend Papers

General Average and Risk Management in Medieval and Early Modern Maritime Business
 3031041178, 9783031041174

  • 0 0 0
  • Like this paper and download? You can publish your own PDF file online for free in a few minutes! Sign Up
File loading please wait...
Citation preview

General Average and Risk Management in Medieval and Early Modern Maritime Business Edited by Maria Fusaro · Andrea Addobbati · Luisa Piccinno

General Average and Risk Management in Medieval and Early Modern Maritime Business

Maria Fusaro · Andrea Addobbati · Luisa Piccinno Editors

General Average and Risk Management in Medieval and Early Modern Maritime Business

Editors Maria Fusaro University of Exeter Exeter, UK

Andrea Addobbati University of Pisa Pisa, Italy

Luisa Piccinno University of Genoa Genoa, Italy

ISBN 978-3-031-04117-4 ISBN 978-3-031-04118-1 (eBook) https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-04118-1 © The Editor(s) (if applicable) and The Author(s) 2023. This book is an open access publication. Open Access This book is licensed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this book are included in the book’s Creative Commons license, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the book’s Creative Commons license and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. The use of general descriptive names, registered names, trademarks, service marks, etc. in this publication does not imply, even in the absence of a specific statement, that such names are exempt from the relevant protective laws and regulations and therefore free for general use. The publisher, the authors, and the editors are safe to assume that the advice and information in this book are believed to be true and accurate at the date of publication. Neither the publisher nor the authors or the editors give a warranty, expressed or implied, with respect to the material contained herein or for any errors or omissions that may have been made. The publisher remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. Cover illustration: The History Collection/Alamy Stock Photo This Palgrave Macmillan imprint is published by the registered company Springer Nature Switzerland AG The registered company address is: Gewerbestrasse 11, 6330 Cham, Switzerland

This volume is published in Open Access thanks to funding from the European Research Council (ERC) under the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research and Innovation Programme ERC Grant agreement No. 724544: AveTransRisk—Average—Transaction Costs and Risk Management during the First Globalization (Sixteenth-Eighteenth Centuries).

Acknowledgements

First and foremost we would like to thank the European Research Council, which has provided funding the whole AveTransRisk project. The essays published here are a selection of those originally presented at a conference which took place in May 2019 in Genoa. The conference was generously hosted by the State Archive of Genoa, and we thank the then Director Francesca Imperiale for her help and support. Giustina Olgiati’s outstanding support and enthusiasm for the conference since the very beginning, and the splendid documentary exhibition which she organised to accompany the conference have been essential also for the development of the project at large. Before and during the conference the help and support provided by the whole staff of the Archive has been crucial, and we would like to particularly thank Fausto Amalberti, Gabriella Balestra, Teresa Coloru, Valter Grimaldi, Liliana Piscioneri, Giuliana Ricciardi, Alberto Saitta, Daniele Tinterri and Francesco Tripodi for their contribution. The city of Genoa showed us an incredibly warm institutional and personal welcome, and for this we thank the Comune di Genova and the Camera di Commercio. We are thankful for the financial support provided to the conference by the Association Mondiale de Dispacheurs and the Italian Associazione dei Liquidatori di Avarie Marittime, associations represented at the conference by Joern M. Groninger (then AMD president) and by Paola Gatti. We also would like to acknowledge the formal endorsement we received from the Associazione Italiana di Diritto

vii

viii

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

Marittimo, whose president—Giorgio Berlingieri—was an active member of the audience. The traditional strengths of Genoese international enterprise shone for us thanks to the enthusiastic support of the St. George’s Club, whose aim is to strengthen economic and cultural links between Genoa and England, and its soul Francesca Centurione Scotto. Amongst our hosts we would like to thank especially Manfredo Leteo, Annaluisa Cameli, Dina Kotelnikova and Elena Manara who made us feel truly welcome. The University of Genoa, through his then Rettore Paolo Comanducci, and the Department of Economics and Business Studies, and its director Alberto Quagli, and that of History of the University of Exeter, and its then director Henry French, provided further essential support through Orietta Bertonasco in Genoa and Susan Lee in Exeter. We also wish to thinks those participants in the conference who, for various reasons, are not present in this volume: Nick Foster, Jolien Kruit, Nadia Matringe, Walter Panciera, Simon Schaffer, Francesco Siccardi and Jonathan Spencer. Alfredo Dani, Marco Doria, Paola Massa and Vito Piergiovanni participation as chairs of our sessions greatly enhanced the conversations. Genoa was chosen as the conference venue to recognise the intellectual contribution of Giuseppe Felloni, once professor of Economic History at the University of Genoa, and author of a pioneering study on the potential of General Average data for the study of maritime entrepreneurship. His generous donation of his own research material to the Department of Economics and Business Studies provided us with a helpful starting template for the creation of our Database. We are thankful to Guido Laura for his conference contribution sketching Felloni’s intellectual heritage, and to Valeria Polonio for the generosity with which she continues to support her husband’s intellectual heritage. Since its beginning the project has substantially widened the scope of its investigation beyond the economic element, and taking into account the legal and political implications which underpinned Averages as a fundamental pillar of maritime trade and transport. We are especially grateful to Jolien Kruit and Nick Foster who have been exceedingly generous with their time and expertise in providing us with critical feedback and helpful suggestions along the way. We are also grateful to Ruth MacKay and Monica Chojnacka for their translations of those contribution which were originally written in Spanish and Italian.

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

ix

Essential for the project, and for the volume, has been the technical IT contribution of Ian Wellaway, who has been a true intellectual partner in transforming our ideas—and Felloni’s original cards—into a Database capable of displaying not just the Genoese material, but a far wider array of diverse documentation pertaining to Averages all across Europe. The Database development has been a true team effort, and a splendid example of productive collaboration, for this we are grateful to Jake Dyble, Marta García Garralón, Antonio Iodice and Lewis Wade. Their joint work will allow scholars to use Averages data and thus opening new avenues for further investigation not just in maritime risk management but in pre-modern economic history at large. Nearly three years have passed since then, and what years have these been… the issue of risk management and of an equitable redistribution of its related costs has taken an unprecedented visibility all across the globe, which makes the contributions in this volume particularly topical. Maria Fusaro Andrea Addobbati Luisa Piccinno

About This Book

The volume is divided into five parts. The first one—Why and How Risk is Shared—starts with Maria Fusaro’s introduction and analytical description of the concept of General Average [GA] at large, highlighting some of its peculiarities and importance regarding both its historical development and future policy. This is followed by essays by Ron Harris and Giovanni Ceccarelli that, from two different perspectives, contextualise GA’s importance within the development of medieval and early modern risk management tools and business strategies. The second part—Origins and Variants of Mutual Protection—traces the development of GA from Byzantium to Early Modern Italy. It starts with Daphne Penna detailing the complex transition of GA from Roman law to the Digest, the Byzantine collection known as the Rhodian SeaLaw and their transmission in the Basilica. The focus then shifts to Hassan Khalilieh’s discussion of how GA rules and practices evolved in the Islamic Mediterranean. This section ends with Andrea Addobbati’s analysis of how this complex genealogy was received in early modern Italy. The third part—The Iberian Experience—is dedicated to the multifaceted articulation of Averages within the Hispanic world. Ana María Rivera Medina argues for the medieval roots of maritime risk mutualisation in northern Spain, and the second essay—by Gijs Dreijer—analyses the transplantation of these usages in the Spanish Low Countries in the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries. The section concludes with Marta García

xi

xii

ABOUT THIS BOOK

Garralón discussing the peculiarities of GA as practiced within the Carrera de Indias. The next part—The Genoese Experience—focuses on the extremely rich documentary evidence regarding GA in Genoa. It starts with Antonio Iodice’s discussion of local early modern normative developments. Then—in the essay by Luisa Piccinno—the focus shifts to the importance of GA data for the analysis of maritime trade passing through the port of Genoa. Andrea Zanini completes this section discussing the intersection between financing the maritime sector and risk-sharing strategies in the eighteenth century. The fifth and last part—Mature Systems —presents three cases in which GA was used as a tool of political economy by states with a strong maritime sector. Jake Dyble analyses the free port of Livorno, Sabine Go discusses developments in Amsterdam, and Lewis Wade the effects of the Ordonnance de la Marine in the French case.

Conventions and Word Usage

We refer to ships using the female pronoun (she/her), fully aware this is now a contentious choice. But it is in accordance with the usage in the primary evidence. Natio/nationes are the Latin terms we consistently use to refer to established mercantile communities away from the home country. It is preferred to ‘nations’ to avoid confusion with the contemporary understanding of the term and its tight connection with the concept of nation-state, which originated in the period after our analysis but which now dominates regardless of the historical period under examination. The terminology we use to define roles on board mercantile ships follows the conventions and translations described in: http://humani ties.exeter.ac.uk/history/research/centres/maritime/research/modern ity/roles/. For some terms whose translation proved to be particularly problematic, the original has been kept in the text. A detailed explanation of its meanings and associated problems is provided in the footnote with all the relevant bibliographical references. All dates have been normalised to the Gregorian calendar; when necessary, further details have been provided in the footnotes. Dates are following the Common Era format, when relevant we also provide the A. H. (Anno Hegirae) details. Transliteration from Arabic uses the conventions employed by the International Journal of Middle East Studies (IJMES).

xiii

Contents

Why and How Risk Is Shared Sharing Risks, on Averages and Why They Matter Maria Fusaro General Average and All the Rest: The Law and Economics of Early Modern Maritime Risk Mitigation Ron Harris Risky Narratives: Framing General Average into Risk-Management Strategies (Thirteenth–Sixteenth Centuries) Giovanni Ceccarelli

3

33

61

Origins and Variants of Mutual Protection General Average in Byzantium Daphne Penna Rules and Practices of General Average in the Islamic Mediterranean on the Eve of the Emergence of the Italian Communes Hassan Khalilieh

95

121

xv

xvi

CONTENTS

Principles and Developments of General Average: Statutory and Contractual Loss Allowances from the Lex Rhodia to the Early Modern Mediterranean Andrea Addobbati

145

The Iberian Experience The ‘Mutualisation’ of Maritime Risk in the Crown of Castile, 1300–1550 Ana María Rivera Medina General Average, Compulsory Contributions and Castilian Normative Practice in the Southern Low Countries (Sixteenth Century) Gijs Dreijer The Nautical Republic of the Carrera de Indias: Commerce, Navigation, Casos Fortuitos and Avería Gruesa in the Sixteenth Century Marta García Garralón

169

193

215

The Genoese Experience General Average in Genoa: Between Statutes and Customs Antonio Iodice The Economic Structure of Maritime Trade Calling at the Port of Genoa Through the Analysis of General Average Data (Sixteenth–Seventeenth Centuries) Luisa Piccinno Financing and Risk in Genoese Maritime Trade During the Eighteenth Century: Strategies and Practices Andrea Zanini

259

297

335

Mature Systems Divide and Rule: Risk Sharing and Political Economy in the Free Port of Livorno Jake Dyble

363

CONTENTS

GA Adjustments in Amsterdam: Reinforcing Authority Through Transparency and Accountability (Late Sixteenth–Early Seventeenth Century) Sabine Go ‘The Honour of Giving My Opinion’: General Average, Insurance and the Compilation of the Ordonnance de la marine of 1681 Lewis Wade

xvii

389

415

Bibliography

431

Index

479

Notes on Contributors

Andrea Addobbati is Professor of Modern History at the University of Pisa. His research interests focus on the history of maritime trade and cultural history. Amongst his works: Commercio, rischio, guerra: il mercato delle assicurazioni marittime di Livorno, 1694–1795 (Pisa, 2007); ‘War Risks and Speculation: The Accounts of a Small Livorno Insurer (1743–1748)’, in Ph. Hellwege and G. Rossi eds., Maritime Risk Management: Essays on the History of Maritime Insurance, General Average and Maritime Loan (Berlin, 2021). Giovanni Ceccarelli is Professor of Economic history at the University of Parma and former Visiting Fellow at Princeton University and EHESS Paris. His research interests include: early modern commerce and finance, late medieval economic thought, and food and retail history. On these topics, he published four books: Risky Markets, (Brill, 2020) Typicality in History, (Peter Lang, 2013) Un mercato del rischio, (Marsilio, 2012) Il gioco e il peccato, Il (Mulino, 2003) and 50 articles and book chapters. Gijs Dreijer wrote his Ph.D. on the development of General Average and adjacent forms of Averages in the Low Countries in the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries, being awarded a dual Ph.D. degree by the University of Exeter and the Vrije Universiteit Brussels (VUB) in 2021. He is primarily interested in maritime, legal and economic history of the Low Countries, having also written about the eighteenth-century Ostend Company. At present he is postdoctoral researcher at Leiden University

xix

xx

NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS

where he also received his B.A. and M.A., researching how Dutch firms exploited the resources of other European colonial empires. Jake Dyble was awarded his Ph.D. jointly by the University of Exeter and the University of Pisa in 2021; his thesis examined risk management in the free port of Livorno. Before this, he studied for his B.A. and M.Phil. at the University of Cambridge, where he received first-class honours and the Trevelyan prize. He has also published on Mediterranean slavery and is currently researching the connections between European trade and Orientalism. Maria Fusaro is Professor of Social and Economy History at the University of Exeter where she directs the Centre for Maritime Historical Studies. She is the PI of AveTransRisk—Average—Transaction Costs and Risk Management During the First Globalization (Sixteenth-Eighteenth Centuries). Amongst her publications: Political Economies of Empire in the Early Modern Mediterranean: The Decline of Venice and the Rise of England 1450–1700 (Cambridge, 2015). Marta García Garralón (Universidad Nacional de Educación a Distancia—UNED, Madrid) works on the educational, institutional and operational aspects linked to maritime history. She has published on seafarers’ apprenticeship and the professionalisation of naval officers and pilots. Amongst her works: La Universidad de Mareantes de Sevilla (1569–1793) (Seville, 2007), and ‘The Seamen of the Indies Trade and the University of Seafarers of Seville’, International Journal of Maritime History, 25 (2013): 91–102. Sabine Go researches the emergence and development of economic institutions during early modern and modern times in the Low Countries. She is PI of ‘Risky Business’ which is developing a database of marine insurance premiums from the fifteenth until the nineteenth centuries. Her most recent research focuses on the involvement of the Dutch insurance industry with slavery. Amongst her works: Marine Insurance in the Netherlands 1600–1870: A Comparative Institutional Approach (The Hague, 2009) and ‘Shared Burdens: The General Average adjustment of the Jan Maria’, International Journal of Maritime History, 33 (2021): 322–343. Ron Harris is the Kalman Lubowsky Professor of Law and History, and former Dean, at the Faculty of Law in Tel-Aviv University. His

NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS

xxi

main research field is the history of the business corporation. He is the author of Going the Distance: Eurasian Trade and the Rise of the Business Corporation, 1400–1700 (Princeton, 2020) and Industrializing English Law: Entrepreneurship and Business Organization, 1720–1844 (Cambridge, 2000). Antonio Iodice works on free port institutions, General Average procedures and insurance policies redacted in Genoa during the Early Modern period. He was awarded his first Ph.D. in Early Modern History at the University of Naples Federico II with a double agreement with the University of Aix-Marseille. He just finished his second Ph.D. in Maritime History at the University of Exeter in a bilateral agreement with the University of Genoa. Hassan Khalilieh is Chair of the Department of Multidisciplinary Studies at the Leon H. Charney School of Marine Sciences, University of Haifa. He is a specialist in Islamic admiralty and maritime law, and international law of the sea of the Early and Classical Islamic periods. Amongst his works: Islamic Law of the Sea: Freedom of Navigation and Passage Rights in Islamic Thought (Cambridge, 2019). Daphne Penna is Assistant Professor in Legal History at the University of Groningen. Her interests are Roman and Byzantine law and in particular their influence on the European legal tradition. She is the author of The Byzantine Imperial Acts to Venice, Pisa and Genoa, 10th– 12th Centuries. A Comparative Legal Study (The Hague, 2012). She has published numerous articles on legal issues concerning Byzantium and the Italians and on various sources of Byzantine law, including the Rhodian Sea-Law, the ‘new’ Basilica scholia, the Ecloga Basilicorum and the Hexabiblos. Luisa Piccinno is Associate Professor in Economic History at the University of Genoa. Her major area of expertise is the economic history of the Republic of Genoa especially in its maritime sector. Amongst her recent publications: ‘Genoa: a City with a Port or a Port City?’, in W. Blockmans, M. Krom, J. Wubs-Mrozewicz eds., The Routledge Handbook of Maritime Trade around Europe 1300–1600 (London, 2017); and with A. Iodice, ‘Whatever the Cost: Grain Trade and The Genoese Dominating Minority in Sicily and Tabarka (16th–18th Centuries)’, in L. Andreoni, L. Mocarelli, G. Ongaro, D. Do Paço eds., Minorities and Grain Trade in Early Modern Europe, Special Issue of Business History (2021).

xxii

NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS

Ana María Rivera Medina is Professor of Medieval History at the Universidad de Educación a Distancia (Spain). Her current fields of interest and work are Atlantic Medieval Maritime History and Digital Humanities. She is a member of Spanish and European research networks and groups. She is the editor of Ports in the Medieval European Atlantic: Shipping, Transport and Labour (Woodbridge, 2021). Lewis Wade recently defended his Ph.D. dissertation at the University of Exeter, entitled ‘Privilege at a Premium: Insurance, Maritime Law and Political Economy in Early Modern France, 1664-c. 1710’. An article drawing on his doctoral research, entitled ‘Royal Companies, Risk Management and Sovereignty in Old Regime France’, is forthcoming in the English Historical Review. Andrea Zanini is Associate Professor of Economic History at the University of Genoa. His main areas of expertise are the organisation of trade and finance during the early modern period and the evolution of regional economies in the long run. He is the author of several books, including Impresa e finanza a Genova. I Crosa, secoli XVII–XVIII (Genoa, 2017).

List of Figures

General Average, Compulsory Contributions and Castilian Normative Practice in the Southern Low Countries (Sixteenth Century) Fig. 1

Varieties of Averages in the Low Countries (fifteenth–sixteenth centuries)

197

GA Adjustments in Amsterdam: Reinforcing Authority Through Transparency and Accountability (Late Sixteenth–Early Seventeenth Century) Image 1 Image 2 Image 3 Image 4 Image 5 Image 6 Image 7

The first insurance ordinance of 1598 of the city of Amsterdam The first folio of the stipulations to guide the conduct of a ship’s master The first folio explaining the procedure of GA adjustments at the Chamber of Insurance and Average Process of calculating GA contributions The Adjustment of the incident with the ship commandeered by Hidde Hiddesz Table of standardized measure of rope per type of ship Damage assessment and reduction of the final amount

396 399 400 402 404 406 408

xxiii

xxiv

LIST OF FIGURES

The Economic Structure of Maritime Trade Calling at the Port of Genoa Through the Analysis of General Average Data (Sixteenth–Seventeenth Centuries) Graph 1 Graph 2 Graph 3 Graph 4

Nationality of (1589–1592) Nationality of (1597–1599) Nationality of (1600–1608) Nationality of (1640–1641)

patroni/masters submitting Average reports 311 patroni/masters submitting Average reports 312 patroni/masters submitting Average reports 317 patroni/masters submitting Average reports

Image 1 Image 2

Giuseppe Felloni’s ‘travel card’ Giuseppe Felloni’s ‘travel card’

Map 1

The European port network connected to Genoa (1640–1641) The Mediterranean port network connected to Genoa (1640–1641)

Map 2

324 302 303

331 332

List of Tables

Risky Narratives: Framing General Average into Risk-Management Strategies (Thirteenth–Sixteenth Centuries) Table 1 Table 2 Table 3 Table 4 Table 5 Table 6

Subscriptions in the role of insurance buyer and underwriter in Florence (1524–1526) Insured values by amount underwritten in Florence in a selected trimester (March–May 1526) Contracts subscribed, by frequency and temporal extension of underwriters, in Florence (1524–1526) Value insured, by frequency and temporal extension of underwriters, in Florence (1524–1526) Main “leading insurers” in Florence (1524–1526) Distribution of underwriters in the role of “leading insurer” in Florence (1524–1526)

88 88 89 89 90 91

General Average, Compulsory Contributions and Castilian Normative Practice in the Southern Low Countries (Sixteenth Century) Table 1 Table 2

Definitions of varieties of Averages in the Low Countries (sixteenth century) GA contributions paid by Juan Henriquez (1562–1563)

198 205

xxv

xxvi

LIST OF TABLES

The Economic Structure of Maritime Trade Calling at the Port of Genoa Through the Analysis of General Average Data (Sixteenth–Seventeenth Centuries) Table 1 Table 2

Distribution of Average reports for the period 1600–1608, by type of vessel Distance from the port of origin for ships submitting Average reports in Genoa (1600–1608)

320 322

Financing and Risk in Genoese Maritime Trade During the Eighteenth Century: Strategies and Practices Table 1 Table 2 Table 3

Types of bottomries contracted in Genoa during the eighteenth century Bottomry loans obtained by Nicolò Maria Cavagnaro and his investors (1770–1772) Bottomry loans obtained by Nicolò Maria Cavagnaro by type of guarantee (1770–1772)

346 357 358

‘The Honour of Giving My Opinion’: General Average, Insurance and the Compilation of the Ordonnance de la marine of 1681 Table 1

The amounts underwritten by the Chambre in livres tournois in the years 1668–1672, alongside the losses recorded in those years. N.B. this does not include Averages

422

Why and How Risk Is Shared

Sharing Risks, on Averages and Why They Matter Maria Fusaro

Over the last couple of years, thanks to the impact of the COVID-19 global pandemic, the issue of risk and its management has taken centre stage, like probably never before in history, becoming a central element of the political, social and economic global discourse well beyond the academic ivory tower. Part of this public conversation stems from a longstanding debate on global risk management, mainly the argument that Western societies have become too risk averse and thus incapable of appropriately evaluating risk, something with wide-ranging political and

The research for this essay was conducted thanks to funding from the European Research Council (ERC) under the European Union’s Horizon 2020 Research and Innovation Programme ERC Grant agreement No. 724544: AveTransRisk—Average—Transaction Costs and Risk Management during the First Globalization (Sixteenth-Eighteenth Centuries). M. Fusaro (B) University of Exeter, Exeter, UK e-mail: [email protected]

© The Author(s) 2023 M. Fusaro et al. (eds.), General Average and Risk Management in Medieval and Early Modern Maritime Business, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-04118-1_1

3

4

M. FUSARO

societal consequences.1 This line of argument has been particularly pervasive within the Anglo-American political and economic sphere, as the connection of freedom with the willingness to take risks has fostered a cult of entrepreneurship, which has been elevated to the highest form of individual contribution to society and has become a defining element of the currently hegemonic Anglo-American variety of capitalism.2 Though in contemporary popular discourse entrepreneurship is usually connected with risk-taking, in actual practice successful businesses have constantly strived towards managing risk.3 The maritime world has always been the riskiest of all working environments. Immense technological developments over the last century have not dented this primacy—alas— as it remains the most dangerous type of activity for both individuals and goods.4 It, therefore, comes as no surprise that the maritime world is also the place where risk management has enjoyed the longest sustained attention, fostering innovation and both private and public institutional solutions for its appropriate management. General Average (GA) is most likely the oldest of such risk management instruments.5 One of its most distinctive elements—jettison—can 1 Interesting analyses in R. V. Ericson and A. Doyle eds., Risk and Morality (Toronto 2003); especially the sharp synthetic contributions of David Garland (‘The Rise of Risk’, 48–86) and Ian Hacking (‘Risk and Dirt’, 22–47); A. Burgess, A. Alemanno, and J. Zinn eds., Routledge Handbook of Risk Studies (Abingdon–New York 2016). For a stimulating analysis of the historical literature on these issues: F. Trivellato, ‘Economic and Business History as Cultural History: Pitfalls and Possibilities’, I Tatti Studies in the Italian Renaissance, 22 (2019): 403–410; on contemporary debates within policy and business: P. De Vincentiis, F. Culasso, and S. A. Cerrato eds., The Future of Risk Management, vol. I: Perspectives on Law, Healthcare, and the Environment (Cham 2019). 2 The literature on varieties of capitalism is massive; for the issues raised in this volume, see M. Fusaro, ‘The Burden of Risk: Early Modern Maritime Enterprise and Varieties of Capitalism’, Business History Review, 94 (2020): 179–200, and bibliography therein quoted. 3 On the interplay of ‘risk’ and ‘uncertainty’ in modern economics, and the theory of ‘animal spirits’ see: G. A. Akerlof and R. J. Shiller, Animal Spirits: How Human Psychology Drives the Economy and Why It Matters for Global Capitalism (Princeton 2009); building on J. M. Keynes, The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (London 1936), 161. 4 Rose George, ‘Worse Things Still Happen at Sea: The Shipping Disasters We Never Hear About’, The Guardian (10 January 2015), at https://www.theguardian.com/world/ 2015/jan/10/shipping-disasters-we-never-hear-about. 5 On the issue of the origin and different etymologies of the word ‘average’ see the essays of Andrea Addobbati and Hassan Khalilieh in this volume.

SHARING RISKS, ON AVERAGES AND WHY THEY MATTER

5

claim to be directly referenced already in the Old Testament and in the Acts of the Apostles.6 The principle of ‘deliberate sacrifice for common benefit’ which is at the root of GA is, in and of itself, a relatively simple concept and was generally agreed upon across the centuries and in different legal traditions. But its practical operation, both in terms of applicability and apportioning procedures, was articulated in rather different ways across time and space. These differences—and consequent disagreements, hence litigation—have been at the basis of commercial disputes and jurisdictional battles for centuries. There is a general average act when, and only when, any extraordinary sacrifice or expenditure is intentionally and reasonably made or incurred for the common safety for the purpose of preserving from peril the property involved in a common maritime adventure.7

This is the formal contemporary definition, as spelled out in Rule A1 of the ‘York/Antwerp Rules’ (YAR), the contractual regime governing the ascertainment of General Average contributions under the aegis of the Comité Maritime International . It is striking how this contemporary formulation mirrors that provided in the sixteenth century by Quintin Weytsen, author of the first learned legal treatise on Averages: “Average is the common contribution of the things found in the ship in order to make good the damage voluntarily inflicted upon items, whether belonging to merchants or the ship, so that lives, ship, and the remaining goods may escape unscathed”.8 6 Jonah, 1: 5 and Acts of the Apostles , 27: 14/14–19 both references from the Bible New International Version. See also: E. Kleiman, ‘Externalities and Public Goods in the Talmud’, in A. Levine ed., Oxford Handbook of Judaism and Economics (Oxford 2010), 107–126; E. Mataix Ferrándiz, ‘Will the Circle Be Unbroken? Continuity and Change of the Lex Rhodia’s Jettison Principles in Roman and Medieval Mediterranean Rulings’, Al Mas¯ aq, 29/1 (2017): 41–59. 7 The official text of YAR 2016 is available at: https://comitemaritime.org/work/yorkantwerp-rules-yar/ (last accessed 20 December 2021). See also: R. R. Cornah, R. C. G. Sarl, and J. B. Shead eds., Lowndes & Rudolf: General Average and York-Antwerp Rules, 15th ed. (London 2018). For a detailed and critical analysis of current practices see: F. Siccardi, Avaria comune e le regole di York e Anversa (Turin 2019). 8 Q. Weitsen [Weytsen], Tractatus de Avariis.Cum observationibus Simonis a Leeuwen et Matthei de Vicq (Amsterdam: H. & T. Boom 1672 [1617]), 1: “Avaria est communis contributio rerum in navi repertarum, ad sarciendum damnum bonis quorundam mercatorum sive nauclerorum eum in finem sponte illatum, ut vita, navis, & reliqua bona salva

6

M. FUSARO

This continuity forces us to confront immediately two fundamental problems in the analysis of GA: its longevity and its apparent immutability. Scholarly literature on GA is scant, particularly so from the historical perspective, as the strength of the ‘immutability’ paradigm has hindered the analysis of how theoretical definitions and practical applications changed across time. The most active area of historical investigation has been the technical-juridical one connected with the earliest origins of this contribution and its reception by Roman law. However, this literature displays a more active interest in tracing continuities than in discussing differences and their development.9 General Average is just the best known among the many varieties of Averages which supported medieval and early modern European maritime trade. In very general terms, it is possible to divide them into two major groups: ‘simple or common averages’ applied to expenses due to damages to ship and cargo after accidents in navigation, and to some of those costs which today we would define as transaction costs; and ‘gross or common averages’—what today is known as GA—which applied instead to extraordinary expenses regarding ship or cargo which were ‘voluntarily’—and successfully—undertaken during the voyage with the aim of saving the venture.10 Still in the most general of terms, whilst damages and expenses for the former fell on their owner/s, in the case of the latter—as the ‘act’ had been done to save the common venture—expenses were instead proportionally shared among all participants in the venture for reasons of equity. Within the scope of this essay, it is not possible to give a detailed analysis of all these variants, but for the moment it will suffice to say that, under the two major categories just mentioned, there

evadant”, I wish to thank Jake Dyble and Andrea Addobbati for our stimulating conversations on translating Latin into English. On Weytsen see G. P. Dreijer and O. Vervaart, ‘Een Tractaet van Avarien – 1617’, Pro Memorie, 21/2 (2019): 38–41. 9 On the contextualization of the Lex Rhodia within Roman law a good starting point is: J.-J. Aubert, ‘Dealing with the Abyss: The Nature and Purpose of the Rhodian Sea-law on Jettison (Lex Rhodia De Iactu, D 14.2) and the Making of Justinian’s Digest’, in J. W. Cairns and P. J. du Plessis eds., Beyond Dogmatics: Law and Society in the Roman World (Edinburgh 2007), 157–172; see also the considerations of A. Cordes, ‘Lex Maritima? Local, Regional and Universal Maritime Law in the Middle Ages’, in W. Blockmans, M. Krom, J. Wubs-Mrozewicz eds., The Routledge Handbook of Maritime Trade Around Europe, 1300–1600 (Abingdon–New York 2017), 69–85, 75–76. 10 For a classic description see: Carlo Targa, Ponderationi sopra la Contrattatione Marittima (Genoa: A. M. Scionico 1692), 255–260.

SHARING RISKS, ON AVERAGES AND WHY THEY MATTER

7

were several other types of Averages, and their distribution across different regions and jurisdictions was rather uneven, with the Iberian world probably displaying the widest variety.11 As a side note, a further challenge in unpacking the complex polysemic universe of Averages lies precisely in the practical difficulty of providing clear and effective English translations of this varied nomenclature, as it appears in different languages in the original documents.12 The scope of this volume is to provide an analytical synthesis of the multifaceted developments of Averages in Europe across the medieval and early modern period, though the focus will be primarily on those which today we know as GA. Given the relative obscurity of this risk management tool outside a small group of specialists, it was essential for us to provide a ‘mapping of the terrain’, which would provide solid grounding for further analyses within our project and beyond.13 Throughout the volume, the contributions discuss Averages from three intersecting perspectives: their intellectual and philosophical conceptualizations, their normative developments across Europe and the Mediterranean, and their practical operations in the wider Mediterranean and Iberian Atlantic.14 One of the principal concerns has been to provide a detailed analysis of their technical elements, both in terms of the variety of normative solutions, and in terms of the complexities of the apportioning procedures and calculations.15 This complexity has been a daunting but essential challenge, being one of the main reasons why scholars have shied away from approaching the study of Averages, which has resulted in mistakes and misunderstandings in the secondary literature. However, beyond an erudite analysis of minute normative and operational differences—which certainly enriches the field, but can also verge 11 On the Iberian varieties of Averages, see the contributions of Ana María Rivera Medina, Gijs Dreijer and Marta García Garralón in this volume. 12 To help with this, the AveTransRisk project is producing a detailed historical glossary. Worth noting how the confusion in the nomenclature of different types of ‘averages’ was already lamented within the English language, on this see G. Rossi, Insurance in Elizabethan England: The London Code (Cambridge 2016), 142. 13 Average-Transaction Costs and Risk Management During the First Globalization (Sixteenth-Eighteenth Centuries), see: http://humanities.exeter.ac.uk/history/research/ centres/maritime/research/avetransrisk/. 14 On the Iberian Atlantic see Ana María Rivera Medina and Marta García Garralón in this volume. 15 On this see the contribution of Sabine Go in this volume.

8

M. FUSARO

on the pedantic—the real purpose behind this volume is to provide an analytical discussion of why Averages do matter, and what we can learn from the long-term historical development of this ancient legal institution. Over the past decade, scholarship has fully acknowledged the importance of the maritime sector as an engine of European economic growth and institutional innovation during the early modern period.16 Its expansion, quantitatively in terms of tonnage, and qualitatively in terms of geographical range, stimulated profound structural changes across Europe which had important consequences on the global scale. The intensification of maritime activities led to closer and more frequent contacts among countries and legal systems, which led to exchanges and hybridizations in usages and customs, and increasingly also in enacted law. These changes on the ground and on water also stimulated a re-conceptualization of the maritime space, which in the seventeenth century became the protagonist of a real renaissance of intellectual and legal reasoning. This culminated in a famous war of books, which set the foundations of the debate between mare clausum and mare liberum which still reverberates today in claims of island nations‚ and in the constant renegotiations on the limits of territorial waters, from fishing rights to managing environmental risks.17 As Ron Harris argues in his contribution to this volume, in the early modern period “maritime trade is where the institutional cutting-edge could be

16 R. W. Unger ed., Shipping and Economic Growth 1350–1850 (Leiden–Boston 2011). 17 H. de G, Mare Liberum, sive de jure quod Batavis competit ad Indicana commercia

dissertatio (Leiden: Ludovici Elzeviri 1609); for a recent critical edition: H. Grotius, The Free Sea, translated by R. Hakluyt with W. Welwod’s critique and Grotius’ reply, edited and with an introduction by David Armitage (Indianapolis 2004); J. Selden, Mare Clausum seu de Dominio Maris libri duo (London: W. Stansby for R. Meighen 1635). For some recent analyses and critical syntheses: M. van Ittersum, Profit and Principle: Hugo Grotius, Natural Rights Theories and the Rise of Dutch Power in the East Indies, 1595– 1615 (Leiden 2006); R. Morieux, The Channel: England, France and the Construction of a Maritime Border in the Eighteenth Century (Cambridge 2016); P. Emmer, ‘Mare Liberum, Mare Clausum: Oceanic Shipping and Trade in the History of Economic Thought’, in C. Buchet, G. Le Bouëdec eds., The Sea in History—The Early Modern World (Woodbridge 2017), 671–678; G. Calafat, Une mer jalousée: Contribution à l’histoire de la souveraineté (Méditerranée, XVII e siècle) (Paris 2019). On contemporary debates: J. A. Black, ‘A New Custom Thickens: Increased Coastal State Jurisdiction within Sovereign Waters’, Boston University International Law Journal, 37/2 (2019): 355–394; it needs to be mentioned that the latter’s historical overview contains mistakes, like a lot of the literature centred on contemporary issues related to GA.

SHARING RISKS, ON AVERAGES AND WHY THEY MATTER

9

found. This is where new and innovative organizational solutions were designed”. Historical and economic scholars have been especially interested in the Atlantic system, focussing on those northern European countries which took best advantage of these changes to expand their colonial possessions across the globe’s oceans.18 For a long time, the Mediterranean was left out of these important debates, as it was perceived to be a spent force, destined to spend a few centuries in a state of managed decline at best, whilst innovation and modernity moved on to other oceans. However, scholarly attention is slowly shifting back to the Mediterranean, as it is precisely within this particular sea that the interaction between different economic and legal systems has been longest and consistently more intense.19 There, maritime operational solutions to overcome political, legal and cultural differences benefitted for the longest time from the active engagement of political entities which, quite apart from their confrontations and economic competition, granted each other full mutual recognition. This focus on the Mediterranean, therefore, descends directly from the fact that, regardless of which legal system they ‘belonged’ to, seafarers and merchants were in agreement on the essential nature of jurisdictions. It is thus possible to trace these interactions across multiple societal layers, from arbitrated dockside disagreements to litigation in municipal courts, to international diplomatic missions.20

18 This literature is immense, for an entry point: D. Armitage, A. Bashford, and S. Sivasundaram eds., Oceanic Histories (Cambridge 2017), and bibliographies therein quoted; also L. A. Benton, ‘The Legal Regime of the South Atlantic World, 1400–1750: Jurisdictional Complexity as Institutional Order’, Journal of World History, 11 (2000): 27–56. 19 A project dedicated specifically to these issues was ConfigMed (ERC Advanced Grant n° 295868, PI Wolfgang Kaiser), see: W. Kaiser and J. Petitjean eds., Litigation and the Elements of Proof in the Mediterranean (16th-19th C.), special issue of Quaderni Storici, 153 (2016); further outputs of this project are in the Brill series Mediterranean Reconfigurations, see: https://brill.com/view/serial/CMED. 20 On this see: M. Fusaro and A. Addobbati, ‘The Grand Tour of Mercantilism: Lord

Fauconberg’s Italian Mission (1669–1671)’, The English Historical Review, 137 (2022): 692–727. https://doi.org/10.1093/ehr/ceac116; A. Addobbati and J. Dyble, ‘One Hundred Barrels of Gunpowder. General Average, Maritime Law, and International Diplomacy between Tuscany and England in the Second Half of the 17th Century’, Quaderni Storici, 168/3 (2021): 823–854. https://doi.org/10.1408/104536.

10

M. FUSARO

Risk-Sharing and Risk-Shifting Pre-modern European trade was supported and fostered by a variety of risk management tools. A variety of commercial associations and capitalraising solutions were developed to this end. The great protagonist among risk management tools is undoubtedly premium insurance, its birth and development firmly established as one of the classic topics of European economic history and one of the major outcomes of the Italian medieval commercial revolution.21 Over the last few decades, the growing interest in ‘insurance’, across different subfields and national historiographies, owes a lot to the powerful and multifaceted intellectual impact of New Institutional Economics (NIE), which brought a tight focus on the role of institutions in fostering economic growth.22 The historical development of insurance took centre stage in these analyses, from both the perspectives of risk management and transaction costs analysis, as insurance came to be considered as a fundamental tool supporting European pre-modern economic development and growth.23 Most recent studies concentrate on the development of insurance markets across the continent, a development connected with the speculative element increasingly present in

21 Rossi, Insurance in Elizabethan England; A. Tenenti and B. Tenenti, Il prezzo del rischio. L’assicurazione mediterranea vista da Ragusa (1563–1591) (Rome 1985); A. Tenenti, Naufrages, corsaires et assurances maritimes à Venise 1592–1609 (Paris 1959); F. Edler de Roover, ‘Early Examples of Marine Insurance’, The Journal of Economic History, 5 (1945): 172–200. 22 Several works by Douglass North are crucial here: D. C. North, ‘Beyond the New Economic History’, The Journal of Economic History, 34 (1974): 1–7; Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance (Cambridge 1990); ‘Institutions’, The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5 (1991): 97–112. 23 On transaction costs, some selected classics: D. C. North, ‘Transaction Costs, Institutions and Economic Performance’, International Center for Economic Growth, Occasional Paper Series, 30 (1992); O. E. Williamson, ‘The Economics of Organization: The Transaction Costs Approach’, American Journal of Sociology, 87/3 (1981): 549–577; Idem, ‘Transaction-Cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual Relations’, Journal of Law and Economics, 22 (1979): 233–262; R. H. Coase, ‘The Nature of the Firm’, Economica, 16/4 (1937): 386–405. On their connection with insurances: A. L. Leonard, ‘Contingent Commitment: the Development of English Marine Insurance in the Context of New Institutional Economics, 1577–1720’, in D’Maris Coffman, A. L. Leonard, L. Neal eds., Questioning Credible Commitment: Perspectives on the Rise of Financial Capitalism (Cambridge 2013), 48–75 and bibliography therein quoted.

SHARING RISKS, ON AVERAGES AND WHY THEY MATTER

11

insurance contracts.24 Furthermore, insurance as an innovative speculative instrument played an important role in raising working capital for European commercial expansion across the globe, and in widening the pool of investors in such enterprises. Created to protect maritime trade, insurance also developed as a veritable instrument of financial risk-hedging beyond the maritime sector.25 One of the side effects of the wholesale adoption of NIE was the general assumption that risk management tools experienced a rather linear development, with more modern and rational instruments simply replacing older ones. Only recently have scholars arrived at an appreciation of the variety and resilience of older instruments—such as Averages and sea loans—in providing flexible risk management.26 Seen in this light, Averages fall squarely within this present reappraisal of the European historical variety, as opposed to development, of risk management and profit-sharing instruments and institutions.27 Scholarly literature acknowledges that Averages were a precursor of insurance,28 and from this descends a general assumption that insurance’s massive success and global expansion transformed Averages into the poor 24 G. Ceccarelli, Risky Markets: Marine Insurance in Renaissance Florence (Leiden 2020); A. L. Leonard ed., Marine Insurance: Origins and Institutions: 1300–1850 (Basingstoke 2015); A. Addobbati, Commercio, rischio, guerra. Il mercato delle assicurazioni marittime di Livorno (1694–1795) (Rome 2007). Early awareness of the speculative element in: H. Van der Wee, The Growth of the Antwerp Market and the European Economy, Fourteenth-Sixteenth Centuries, 3 vols (The Hague 1963), II: 327–328; U. Tucci, ‘Gli investimenti assicurativi a Venezia nella seconda metà del Cinquecento’, in his Navi, mercanti e monete nel Cinquecento veneziano (Bologna 1981), 145–160. 25 Examples of this transformation into proper financial instruments in: O. Gelderblom, A. de Jong, J. Jonker, ‘Learning How to Manage Risk by Hedging: The VOC Insurance Contract of 1613’, European Review of Economic History, 24 (2020): 332–355; H. Casado Alonso, ‘Insuring Life, Insuring Debt: Life Insurance in Sixteenth-Century Spain’, Pedralbes, 40 (2020): 75–95; P. Hellwege ed., The Past, Present, and Future of Tontines: A Seventeenth Century Financial Product and the Development of Life Insurance (Berlin 2018). 26 P. Hellwege and G. Rossi eds., Maritime Risk Management: Essays on the History of Marine Insurance, General Average and Sea Loan (Berlin 2021); on the continuing relevance of sea loans see the contribution of Andrea Zanini in this volume. 27 On this see: S. F. Mansell and A. J. G. Sison, ‘Medieval Corporations, Membership and the Common Good: Rethinking the Critique of Shareholder Primacy’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 16 (2020): 579–595. 28 Starting with E. Bensa, Il contratto di assicurazione nel Medio Evo: studi e ricerche (Genoa: Tipografia marittima editrice 1884); K. Nehlsen – von Stryk, L’assicurazione

12

M. FUSARO

man’s solution, or a simply obsolete risk management tool. Furthermore, in some sections of the maritime sector, there have been recurrent debates about GA’s role and relevance within contemporary shipping.29 One of the issues hinges on the operational complexities of GA as an instrument, even now that they are regulated under the aegis of the YAR rules.30 Another focuses on their supposed irrelevance, given the existence of increasingly complex systems of reinsurance to further spread the risk of maritime ventures and their associated costs. The underlying assumption is that this is a recent development, which makes GA an unnecessary relic of the past.31 However, the intertwining of Averages and insurance dates back to fourteenth-century Italy. Early Florentine policies, and the rich material extant in the Datini archive, provide ample evidence of how fully comprehensive coverage—that is to say, including expenses related to Averages— was already part of Italian medieval insurance policies.32 Exclusionary clauses increased with the passing of time, mostly determining limits below which it was not worth activating the policy.33 The only exception to this appears to be Venice, where insurance policies explicitly excluded Averages with the formula ‘free of Average’ (‘franche d’avaria’), this exclusion becoming the defining characteristic of Venetian policies.34

marittima a Venezia nel XV secolo (Rome 1988); J. P. Van Niekerk, The Development of the Principles of Insurance Law in the Netherlands from 1500 to 1800 (Hilversum 1998). 29 For a synthesis of the debate see: P. Mukherjee, ‘The Anachronism in Maritime Law That Is General Average’, WMU Journal of Maritime Affairs, 4/2 (2005): 195–209, and bibliography therein quoted. 30 On these issues are essential: J. Kruit, General Average, Legal Basis and Applicable Law: The Overrated Significance of the York-Antwerp Rules (Zutphen 2017); and her ‘General Average—General Principle Plus Varying Practical Applications Equals Uniformity?’, Journal of International Maritime Law, 21 (2015): 190–202, and bibliography therein quoted. 31 Mukherjee, ‘The Anachronism in Maritime Law’. 32 Ceccarelli, Risky Market, Chapter 1; Nehlsen – von Stryk, L’assicurazione marittima. 33 Addobbati, Commercio, rischio, guerra, 133–134 and bibliograhy therein. On exclu-

sionary clauses regarding Averages see Bensa, Il contratto di assicurazione, 75–76; A. Baldasseroni, Delle Assicurazioni Marittime, Trattato, 4 vols (Florence: Stamperia Bonducciana 1786), III: 100–130. On the Tuscan debate on these issues: Addobbati, Commercio, rischio, guerra, 190–191, 224–230. 34 Nehlsen – von Stryk, L’assicurazione marittima, 216–228.

SHARING RISKS, ON AVERAGES AND WHY THEY MATTER

13

These early Italian usages would take some time to be properly formalized in legislation, which happened only in the sixteenth century: in Florence in 1523 and 1529, and in Genoa in 1589.35 On the normative side, Iberians were quicker to legislate on the insurability of Averages, starting with the Ordenanzas promulgated in Barcelona (1435–1484).36 It is worth noting how a particularly active debate on these issues took place in the following century in the Iberian-ruled Low Countries, where the constant interaction of Iberian commercial practice and local rules is proving to be a most stimulating laboratory for legal borrowing.37 The importance of these transplanted Iberian legal concepts goes well beyond their contribution to the economic development of the Low Countries; they triggered a profound institutional transformation of the whole maritime sector in Northern Europe, with long-term consequences on commercial organizational development.38 Even from such a brief sketch it is clear how complex, both theoretically and operationally, the relationship between insurance and Averages was, and this remains a matter of debate even in contemporary practice. During the early modern period, jurisprudential treatises and compilations of legislation usually dealt with insurance and Averages in close proximity.39 They were both instruments of risk management; however,

35 For Florence: Addobbati, Commercio, rischio, guerra, 118–119, and the contribution of Jake Dyble in this volume. For Genoa see the contributions of Luisa Piccinno and Antonio Iodice in this volume, and A. Iodice, Averages and Seaborne Trade in Early Modern Genoa, 1590–1700 (Unpublished PhD thesis, University of Exeter and Università di Genova, 2021). 36 M. J. Palaez, ‘El seguro marítimo en el Derecho histórico Catalán’, in his Historia del Derecho de la navigación, vol.I: Trabajos de teoría e historia de derecho marítimo y de derecho aeronáutico (Barcelona 1994), 138–160; F. Mansutti, ‘La più antica disciplina del contratto di assicurazione: le Ordinanze sulle sicurtà marittime’, Assicurazioni: rivista di diritto, economia e finanza delle assicurazioni private, LXXIV (2008): 683–692. 37 On these issues see the contribution of Gijs Dreijer in this volume, and his The Power and Pains of Polysemy: General Average, Maritime Trade and Normative Practice in the Southern Low Countries (Fifteenth-Sixteenth Centuries) (Unpublished PhD thesis, University of Exeter-VUB, 2021). 38 G. Dreijer, ‘Maritime Averages and the Complexity of Risk Management in Sixteenth-Century Antwerp’, TSEG/ Low Countries Journal of Social and Economic History, 17/2 (2020): 31–54. 39 G. M. Casaregi ed., Libro del Consolato del Mare (Lucca: Cappuri & Santini 1720); A. Verwer, Nederlants See-Rechten: Avaryen en Bodemeryen Begrepen in de Gemeene Costuimen vander See; de Placcaten van Keiser Karel den Vijfden 1551 en Koning Filips den

14

M. FUSARO

Averages were—and still are—structurally and substantially different, as they have remained a strictly mutualistic form of protection and, unlike insurance, did not develop into a speculative instrument. This makes them a most interesting example of a non-market phenomenon, whose rich quantitative data is providing us with a wealth of evidence related to transaction and protection costs. The novelty of insurance has been seen in its being an instrument which allowed economic activities to move from the sharing of risk between partners, to the shifting of risk onto third parties not directly involved in the enterprise. Scholarship is now acknowledging that this shift was not as quick—or, indeed, as linear—as argued by the classic historical and economic literature.40 Especially within the maritime sector the element of risk sharing remained particularly strong, as evidenced by the continuing successes of the little investigated ‘Protection and Indemnity Clubs’ (known as ‘P&I Clubs’) through which ship-owners associations take care of their insurance needs internally.41 It also can be argued that Averages could be defined as a type of mutualistic insurance.42 Outside of the maritime world, insurance developed another strong tradition of mutuality, especially within the Northern European social welfare sector, and this has also remained somewhat on the margin of mainstream debates on risk management.43 Whilst mutual insurance retains a strong connection with market phenomena, if nothing II 1563’t Tractaet van Mr Quintyn Weitsen van de Nederlantsche Avaryen (Amsterdam: Jan Boom 1711); Targa, Ponderationi; E. Cleirac, Us et coustumes de la mer, divisées en trois parties: I. De la navigation. II. Du commerce naval & contracts maritimes. III. De la iurisdiction de la marine. Avec un traicté des termes de marine & reglemens de la nauigation des fleuves & rivieres (Bordeaux: Guillaume Millanges 1647); W. Welwood, An Abridgement of all Sea-Lawes; gathered forth of all Writings and Monuments, which are to be found among any People or Nation, upon the Coasts of the Great Ocean and Mediterranean Sea: And specially Ordered and Disposed for the Use and Benefit of all Benevolent Sea-Farers, within his Maiesties Dominions of Great Britanne, Ireland, and the Adiacent Isles thereof (London: Humfrey Lownes, for Thomas Man 1613). 40 An issue discussed in Giovanni Ceccarelli contribution in this volume. 41 P&I Club usually provide cover for Protection and Indemnity (P&I), but also

‘Freight, Demurrage and Defence’ (FD&D) and War Risks; further details on one of the most globally important ones, the London Pandi, at: https://www.londonpandi.com/doc uments/150th-history/ (last accessed 20 December 2021). 42 See Addobbati, Commercio, rischio, guerra, 224–230. 43 M. H. D. van Leeuwen, Mutual Insurance 1550–2015: From Guild Welfare and

Friendly Societies to Contemporary Micro-Insurers (London 2016), 3.

SHARING RISKS, ON AVERAGES AND WHY THEY MATTER

15

else because it needs to keep premiums competitive in relation to the open insurance market, Averages are a purer non-market phenomenon, making them particularly useful for economic historians especially for the analysis of commodities prices. The quantitative data produced during GA procedures generally provides very stable and reliable historical prices and costs, as their evaluation is necessarily closer to the ‘real’ ones—that is to say, the values perceived to be ‘real’ by all involved—simply because all who were involved in GAs were active participants in the business venture, and therefore, over/underestimation of costs and commodity prices would affect all parties, each with substantially different interests within the venture. Frauds of course did take place, but our project’s quantitative results are supporting the reliability of the quantitative data.44

The Theory and Practice of Risk Management: Silent Partnerships, Moral Hazards and (the Impossibility of) Correct Procedures The mutual element which underpins GA was a constitutive element of European and Islamic legal traditions.45 In the Lex Rhodia de Jactu, as reported in Justinian’s Digest ,46 the presence of a common danger was the decisive criterion for the sharing of damages by all stakeholders in the venture. In the more capacious rules described in the later Rhodian Sea Laws, which extended the applicability of Averages well beyond those cases described in the Lex Rhodia, the criteria remain the same: avoidance

44 http://humanities-research.exeter.ac.uk/avetransrisk/. The statistical analysis of Sicilian wheat prices on the basis of GA documentation provides rich evidence in this regard, see: L. Piccinno and A. Iodice, ‘Whatever the cost: Grain trade and the Genoese dominating minority in Sicily and Tabarka (16th-18th Centuries)’, Business History, (2022) https://doi.org/10.1080/00076791/2021.1924686. For the analysis of a questionable claim see: Addobbati and Dyble, ‘One Hundred Barrels of Gunpowder’. 45 For extra European equitable risk sharing solutions see: D. Attard, M. Fitzmaurice, I. Arroyo, N. Martinez, E. Belja eds., The IMLI (International Maritime Law Institute) Manual on International Maritime Law, vol. II: Shipping Law (Oxford 2016), 580; A. Reid, ‘The Hybrid Maritime Actors of Southeast Asia’, in Buchet and Le Bouëdec eds., The Sea in History—The Early Modern World, 112–122. 46 D. 14,2; A. Watson ed., The Digest of Justinian (transl. Mommsen, ed. maior), 4 vols (Philadelphia 1985).

16

M. FUSARO

of common dangers brings about a proportional sharing of associated costs.47 The forcibly shared nature of any maritime venture—via the unit of the ship, which includes both crew and cargo—means that the maritime venture is a single entity during its travels and everyone involved shares all dangers and costs. This created a form of silent partnership between all interested parties. The same principle is evident across all European legal traditions and also in Islamic regulations on General Average. In the words of Abraham Udovitch: this incipient on-board relationship is transformed into a more explicit connection. The loss of commercial merchandise belonging to any one owner, creates an involuntary partnership among all the owners of a cargo on a ship.48

In commenting on Islamic rules on jettison, Udovitch wrote, in practical terms, the notion of partnership does not appreciably change how matters were settled in a post-jettison situation. Nevertheless, it is interesting and, I believe, quite significant that the principle of ‘general average’ that is formulated in the Rhodian Sea-Laws in terms of a broad principle that is then applied to numerous specific instances, is, in the context of Islamic law, transformed and translated into the associational framework of a partnership.49

Easy to intuitively grasp, this idea proved rather complex to translate into precise and accurate legal terms. This complexity only increased in the early modern period when the rise of learned jurists, who played a growing role not only in universities but also in state bureaucracy and courts all across the European continent, stimulated a continentwide push towards squeezing mercantile customs into precise categories 47 W. Ashburner, The Rhodian Sea-Law (Oxford 1909); and M. Humphreys ed., The Laws of the Isaurian Era: The Ecloga and Its Appendices (Liverpool 2017), 113–128. On these issues see the contribution of Daphne Penna in this volume. 48 A. L. Udovitch, ‘An Eleventh Century Islamic Treatise on the Law of the Sea’, Annales Islamologique, 27 (1993): 37–54, 51. 49 Udovitch, ‘An Eleventh Century Islamic Treatise’, 51–52. Issues further developed in H. S. Khalilieh, ‘Islamic Laws of General Average’, Journal of Maritime Law and Commerce, 50/3 (2019): 353–378, and in his contribution to this volume.

SHARING RISKS, ON AVERAGES AND WHY THEY MATTER

17

derived from Roman law (ius commune).50 The result was the creation of ex post formal categories and definitions that fitted within the overarching structure of jurisprudential learned law. This phenomenon accelerated during the seventeenth century, when maritime legislation effectively became a laboratory of proto-codification in response to states’ attempts to expand and strengthen their jurisdictional reach.51 Johan van Niekerk, in his analysis of the legal development of GA within Roman-Dutch law, argued for the existence of a strong agreement in the early modern Dutch jurisprudential literature that “a tacit maritime partnership (navalis societas, or societas et communio tacita)” is the legal basis for GA, and concludes that “this partnership arose automatically because of the factual (and non-consensual) community of risk (communio periculis ) existing between the interests on board a ship”.52 However, van Niekerk’s pragmatic view was (and is) not universally shared, as from a technical jurisprudential perspective the whole issue of whether GA was effectively supported by a ‘tacit’ partnership remains contested.53 Trying to solve this conundrum, an intriguing concept emerged—the

50 A sharp synthesis of these issues from a cultural perspective in: P. Burke, Hybrid Renaissance: Culture, Language Architecture (Budapest–New York 2016), 144; from a more legal perspective: E. Kadens, ‘Convergence and the Colonization of Custom in Pre-Modern Europe’, in O. Moréteau, A. Masferrer and K. A. Modéer eds., Comparative Legal History (Cheltenham 2019), 167–185; D. De ruysscher, ‘Maxims, Principles and Legal Change: Maritime Law in Merchant and Legal Culture (Low Countries, 16th Century)’, Zeitschrift der Savigny-Stiftung für Rechtgeschichte, Ger.Abt. 138 (2021), and their bibliographies. 51 F. Trivellato, ‘“Amphibious Power”: The Law of Wreck, Maritime Customs, and Sovereignty in Richelieu’s France’, Law and History Review, 33 (2015): 915–944; and her ‘“Usages and Customs of the Sea”: Étienne Cleirac and the Making of Maritime Law in Seventeenth-Century France’, Tijdschrift voor Rechtsgeschiedenis / Revue d’histoire du droit / Legal History Review, 84/2 (2016): 193–224; D. De ruysscher, ‘Maxims, Principles’; M. Fusaro, The Making of a Global Labour Market, 1573–1729: Maritime Law and the Political Economy of the Early Modern Mediterranean, forthcoming with Cambridge University Press. 52 Van Niekerk, The Development of the Principles, 1: 76, discussion of the relevant texts at 74–76. 53 For a contemporary analysis of GA as an ‘implied contract’ see the considerations of G. M. Gauci, ‘Of Piracy and General Average: Contribution in General Average for Ransom Payment Occasioned by Piratical Activity’, Journal of Maritime Law and Commerce, 50/2 (2019): 235–255.

18

M. FUSARO

germinamento—which allows us to glimpse the border between operational customs and their formalization in learned legal scholarship.54 The seventeenth-century Genoese jurist Carlo Targa described the germinamento as a deliberation made by the shipmaster, with the agreement of the merchants if present, otherwise of the majority of the crew, to voluntarily sacrifice part of the ship or cargo to avoid a bigger danger which would threaten the entire venture.55 This pretty obscure legal escamotage was probably devised for the purpose of reassuring university-trained legal professionals who could be sitting in those courts which certified the whole GA process, and who were less familiar with, when not downright sceptical towards, maritime usages and customs. The schizophrenia between the jurisprudential and operational realities continued to plague GA practices. Having created a new legal category to formally constitute the ship’s risk community, it remained the fact that acts leading to GAs were necessarily performed under extremely difficult circumstances. In other words, if an event (casus fortuitus ) leads to actions to save the venture, thus creating the conditions for a GA, there is an unavoidable clash between formal legal procedures and the acutely timesensitive emergency of impeding danger at sea. The essays in this volume describe all manner of different formal procedures. How frequently they were followed in practice is unclear, although common sense leads us to believe that they were rarely. Targa, on the basis of his long service in the Genoese court of the Conservatori del Mare, was of the opinion that GA cases in which all such formalities were observed were precisely those which should have been examined with particular attention, as most likely their formal perfection concealed fraud. One can easily visualize his sarcastic look when he wrote:

54 L. Goldschmidt, ‘Lex Rhodia und Agermanament: Der Schiffsrath – Studie zur Geschichte und Dogmatik des Europäischen Seerechts’, ZHR (Zeitschrift für das gesamte Handelsrecht ), 35 (1888): 37–90, 321–395; for an analysis and the relevant bibliography see the contribution of Andrea Addobbati in this volume. 55 Targa, Ponderationi, Chapter LXXVI ‘Di Germinamento’, 316–317: “Questa non è

altro che una deliberatione fatta dal Capitano di Nave, ò dal Patron di Barca, approvata da Mercanti se vi sono, ò non essendovene, dalla maggior parte della gente di Nave di volere volontariamente arrischiarsi, incontrando un pericolo remoto, o danno minore, per schivarne un maggiore più prossimo, per doversi poi ripartire il danno del perso, ò Guasto sopra il salvato […]”.

SHARING RISKS, ON AVERAGES AND WHY THEY MATTER

19

when great danger looms, juridical acts do not naturally come to mind, and amongst the great quantity I have seen in more than sixty years of maritime judicial practice, I can remember no more than four or five declarations which recounted all correct juridical forms, and in each of these there were reasons for criticism as they appeared too premeditated.56

The category of ‘moral hazard’ has been well investigated with regard to insurance, both historically and in contemporary practice. In David Garland’s words, “‘moral hazard’ describes the temptations to bad behaviour (false claims, carelessness, wilful damage, etc.) that the promise of compensation can produce for an insured party”.57 The mutualistic basis of GA goes a long way in limiting moral hazard, founded as it is on proportional sharing among stakeholders who have different interests in the venture. Additionally, because it is an instrument not subject to speculation, it is more likely that it does actually produce reliable price and costs data, as sharing mechanisms disincentivized the over- or under-valuing of damages. However, a formally perfect GA procedure could hide many ills, and given both the complexity and the varieties of GA regulations, the responsibility of the ship master in handling the whole process was at the forefront of jurisprudential debates and the daily practice of the courts.58

56 Targa, Ponderationi, Chapter LIX ‘Di annotatione sopra il Gettito’, 253: “[…] sopraggiungendo un grande pericolo, poco vengono a memoria li atti giuridici, et io in anni sessanta di pratiche maritime che n’havrò veduto gran quantità non mi ricordo haver veduto Consolati á pena quattro in cinque fatti per gettito notato giuridicamente alla forma prenarrata, et in ogn’un di questi vi è stato da criticare per esser parsi troppo premeditati”. 57 Garland, ‘The Rise of Risk’, 54. For moral hazard in insurance, see C. Kingston, ‘Governance and Institutional Change in Marine Insurance, 1350–1850’, European Review of Economic History, 18 (2013): 1–18 and bibliography therein quoted; I thank Gijs Dreijer for bringing to my attention the further distinction made between “moral and morale hazard, the former denoting an increased chance that some person intentionally causes a loss or is unwilling to pay to prevent losses, the latter as an act that causes someone to be less careful than they would otherwise be”, in A. C. Williams and R. M. Heins, Risk Management and Insurance (New York 1964), 51. 58 See the comprehensive analyses of Guido Rossi, ‘The Liability of the Shipmaster in Early Modern Law: Comparative (and Practice-Oriented) Remarks’, Historia et ius, 12 (2017), available at: http://www.historiaetius.eu/uploads/5/9/4/8/5948821/rossi_ guido_12.pdf (last accessed 12 October 2021); ‘The Barratry of the Shipmaster in Early Modern Law: polysemy and mos italicus ’, Tijdschrift voor Rechtsgeschiedenis, 87/1 (2019):

20

M. FUSARO

Another important issue that needs to be acknowledged is that the nature of GA produces somewhat of a structural bias favouring ships’ interests above merchants’. There are several factors to take into account in this regard. The initial declaration and the subsequent paperwork were produced by the master, and the witnesses were usually crew members. Cargo interest was (and is) far more fragmented among different stakeholders who were not usually present on the vessel during the event itself. The value of the cargo was also usually higher than that of the vessel, and ship interests commonly contributed a small fraction of its total value. Furthermore, whilst in the early modern period it was becoming common for cargo to be insured, the same was not true for ships (what today we would call ‘hull insurance’). All these factors skewed the process, and fraud remained a possibility especially from the ship side, as GA could provide a convenient mechanism for defraying ships’ maintenance and refurbishment costs, and also cover for human mistakes.59 The bottom line is that in handling GA there was no alternative to cooperation without trust.60 No single actor—be it an individual or state authority—had the capacity or the legal infrastructure to control the whole process, so there was no alternative to trusting one’s counterparts. And in practical real-life terms, a ship master could cheat once or maybe twice, but not much more as information circulated between merchants and ports, and masters’ reputation was a matter of commercial knowledge.61 If he did not act professionally, eventually merchants would not trust him; in the Mediterranean maritime world, reputations travelled quickly, and the importance of individuals’ reputation emerge strongly

65–85; ‘The Barratry of the Shipmaster in Early Modern Law: The Approach of Italian and English Law Courts’, Tijdschrift voor Rechtsgeschiedenis, 87/4 (2019): 504–574. 59 Issues discussed at length in J. A. Dyble, General Average in the Free Port of Livorno, 1600–1700 (Unpublished PhD thesis, University of Exeter and Università di Pisa, 2021). 60 J. Wubs-Mrozewicz, ‘The Concept of Language of Trust and Trustworthiness: (Why) History Matters’, Journal of Trust Research, 10 (2019): 91–107; on its importance in long-distance trade: F. Trivellato, The Familiarity of Strangers: The Sephardic Diaspora, Livorno, and Cross-Cultural Trade in the Early Modern Period (New Haven–London 2009). For a more sociological analysis, see K. S. Cook, R. Hardin, and M. Levi, Cooperation Without Trust? (New York 2002). 61 For actual examples of the preference (even competition) among merchants for specific ships, because of their reputation for seaworthiness, and the concomitant avoidance of others, see: S. D. Goitein, A Mediterranean Society, 6 vols (Berkeley–London 1967–1993), I: 313.

SHARING RISKS, ON AVERAGES AND WHY THEY MATTER

21

from the documentation.62 Reputation remained a crucial element of premodern credit-worthiness, especially within a mutualistic environment where reciprocity was embedded. Considering all these factors, it is clear that we are, therefore, confronted with a perfect example of the type of obscure professional knowledge and language which can easily engender scepticism in nonexperts. Not a lot has changed in the intervening centuries. Reviewing the most recent edition of Lowndes & Rudolf , the ‘bible’ of GA contemporary legal management, Angus Glennie comments that “even for the professional lawyer, the law of general average is particularly esoteric and abstruse”.63 And it is precisely this esoteric element which is at the root of a particularly intriguing issue in the long life of GA, namely that its operation and procedures have been put into question whenever new players have entered the system; this happened with the English and Armenians in the seventeenth-century Mediterranean, and it is happening with the Chinese on the global scale today, making GA a sensitive bellwether of structural changes within maritime trade. Periodic attempts to discuss or reform the mechanisms underpinning mutual cost redistribution reveal the cultural specificities of risk analysis, and further point to the crucial importance of trust, both in the pre-modern period and today.64

62 On the issue of masters’ reputation: M. Fusaro, ‘Public Service and Private Trade: Northern Seamen in Seventeenth Century Venetian Courts of Justice’, The International Journal of Maritime History, 27 (2015): 3–25. 63 A. Glennie, ‘Review of Lowndes & Rudolf: General Average and York-Antwerp Rules’, Edinburgh Law Review, 23/3 (2019): 461–462. 64 G. Alfani and V. Gourdon, ‘Entrepreneurs, Formalization of Social Ties, and Trust-

building in Europe (Fourteenth to Twentieth Centuries)’, The Economic History Review, 65 (2012): 1005–1028; Wubs-Mrozewicz, ‘The Concept of Language of Trust’; Fusaro and Addobbati, ‘The Grand Tour of Mercantilism’. On the diversity of risk perception and management: J.-P. Platteau, ‘Mutual Insurance as an Elusive Concept in Traditional Rural Communities’, Journal of Development Studies, 33 (1997): 764–796.

22

M. FUSARO

Lex Maritima, Lex Mercatoria and Early Modern States The international nature of Averages allows us to see the interaction of operational convergence and legal pluralism across Europe, providing an alternative perspective on the vexed issue of lex mercatoria.65 Maritime legislation across Europe was characterized by a general agreement on the underlying principles, which is especially evident when operational elements were concerned, paired with an extreme variety of legal and contractual solutions. Thus, arguably since the time of the Digest in late Antiquity, the Mediterranean was characterized both by variant local practices and a common underlying set of principles, much in the same way as these issues developed later in the Baltic and North Seas.66 The commonalities were indeed many, and this, paired with the wealth of normative evidence characterizing the European maritime legal world since the Middle Ages, has led Albrecht Cordes to argue that “the lex maritima thereby functions as a ‘key witness’ for the lex mercatoria because its sources are more tangible than the sources of the lex mercatoria and thus should provide documentary evidence”.67 Using Cordes’ image, thanks to their longevity Averages can thus be considered as ‘expert witnesses’ on these issues. And their testimony is unambiguous, as the procedural framework, and the actual legal practice which embodied and enacted this common principle, differed greatly across the continent. The general agreement on principles was at the heart of GA, and some elements of operational convergence were necessary. Across time, all jurisdictions agree that GA events should be reported in a timely fashion, so the damage report had to be completed in the first port encountered after

65 A lively synthesis of the contemporary debate on a ‘new lex mercatoria’, in N. E. Hatzimihail, ‘The Many Lives—and Faces—of Lex Mercatoria: History as Genealogy in International Business Law’, Law and Contemporary Problems, 71/3 (2008): 169–190. 66 O. R. Constable, ‘The Problem of Jettison in Medieval Mediterranean Maritime Law’, Journal of Medieval History, 20 (1994): 207–220; for the Baltic and North Sea: E. Frankot, ‘Of Laws of Ships and Shipmen’. Medieval Maritime Law and Its Practice in the Towns of Northern Europe (Edinburgh 2012); and her ‘Medieval Maritime Law from Oléron to Wisby: Jurisdictions in the Law of the Sea’, in J. Pan-Montojo and F. Pedersen eds., Communities in European History: Representations, Jurisdictions, Conflicts (Pisa 2007), 151–172. 67 Cordes, Lex Maritima? 70–71; also Udovitch, ‘An Eleventh Century Islamic Treatise’, 43.

SHARING RISKS, ON AVERAGES AND WHY THEY MATTER

23

the accident—normally with the support of local experts, who evaluated the extent and cost of the damages suffered—and then certified by local authorities, and this report had then to be accepted by the authorities of the destination port; hence the embedded transnationality of these legal instruments.68 The actual apportioning of costs was usually done in the venture’s intended final destination, frequently (but not always) where the majority of the cargo receivers were based. At this stage, the differences between different jurisdictions emerged. In most countries, courts with jurisdiction on maritime matters checked, approved and certified Averages’ documentation.69 Courts, therefore, performed an essential role in overseeing the process; the need to ensure correctness in the paperwork, and propriety and due process in the whole procedure was particularly important given the transnational element, as documentation produced in one jurisdiction needed to be valid in all others. Carlo Targa underlined this element arguing that it is not possible in one part of the world to deal with maritime matters in one way, and differently somewhere else, because of the shared interests than many different people can have in the same event.70

However, if there was almost universal procedural convergence regarding the opening acts of a GA procedure, from that moment onwards differences started to emerge. The original reports were checked for consistency, especially regarding the narrative of the event; then the bill of lading, and—crucially—the list of expenses which were a direct consequence of the GA act were examined. Then a list of the damages was prepared and, cross-referencing the financial documentation, the approved costs were apportioned among all parties. Which type of expenses were claimable through GA differed between jurisdictions; other 68 The report was called in Italian ‘consolato’, and in English ‘sea protest’, due to the historical peculiarities of the usage of this term, in this essay I am using instead the more neutral term ‘report’. 69 The exception here is England, where the process was overseen by notaries; on these issues see: G. Pizzoni, ‘British Power in the Mediterranean: Sea Protests and Notarial Practice in Nineteenth-century Malta’, The Journal of Imperial and Commonwealth History (2022), https://doi.org/10.1080/03086534.2022.2086206 70 Targa, Ponderationi, 323–324: “[…] non potendosi, in una parte del mondo, circa la contrattatione maritima operare in un modo e in altra in diverso, per l’interesse comune che tanta gente diversa puonno haver in un istesso fatto”.

24

M. FUSARO

important differences had to do with the modalities of cargo evaluation and with the percentages of the contributions owed by each party. The whole system was accustomed to these differences, which were an accepted reality of maritime trade. Litigation of course did happen, but this was a relatively rare occurrence, probably due to the problem of coordinating different parties who could be very distant from each other. When litigation took place, it was generally handled by those same courts which had dealt with the certification stage, and the evidence shows clear awareness by these courts that rules would differ in other places.71 The involvement of courts in certifying GA procedures is evidence of how the management of the maritime sector in general, and that of Averages in particular, is a particularly fruitful field for investigating the interaction of state (or municipal) legislative activities—government— and private rules and regulations—governance—as procedures regulating Averages straddled these two sets of rules.72 Indeed, it can further be argued that handling and managing risk exposure was a way to buttress the state and gain entry into the corridors of power, as late seventeenth-century French developments clearly exemplify.73 However, it should also be underlined that states’ claims to sovereignty always contained an aspirational element, even more so when applied to merchants and seafarers, the most mobile and slippery of all economic actors.74 The current regime under which GA are regulated and settled provides telling evidence of both the unifying aspirations and practical impossibility of a proper lex mercatoria.

71 For example, the Kampen Gulden Boeck mentioned that rules on contribution could

be different in other ports, on this see the analysis of Dreijer, The Power and Pains of Polysemy, 143. 72 On the intertwinement of mercantile practice and official law: D. De ruysscher, ‘Maxims, Principles’. 73 On these issues is dedicated the essay of Lewis Wade in this volume; see also his Privilege at a Premium: Insurance, Maritime Law and Political Economy in Early Modern France, 1664-c. 1710 (Unpublished PhD thesis, University of Exeter, 2021); and his article: ‘Royal Companies, Risk Management and Sovereignty in Old Regime France’, forthcoming in The English Historical Review. 74 A synthetic view of the complexity of states’ jurisdictions in contemporary shipping in: J. A. Black, ‘A New Custom Thickens: Increased Coastal State Jurisdiction Within Sovereign Waters’, Boston University International Law Journal, 37/2 (2019): 355–394.

SHARING RISKS, ON AVERAGES AND WHY THEY MATTER

25

The existence of such divergence in the handling of GA was at the root of the long and complex negotiations among states which occupied the better part of the nineteenth century, leading to a series of international conferences culminating in 1890 with the creation of the first York-Antwerp Rules (YAR). Since then, YARs have been regularly revised, with the most recent edition issued in 2016. These ‘rules’ (note that these are not ‘laws’) are managed by the Comité Maritime International (CMI), which declares itself to be the oldest organization in the world exclusively concerned with the unification of maritime law and related commercial practices. Article 1 of the CMI Constitution states: It is a not-for-profit international organization established in Antwerp in 1897, the object of which is to contribute by all appropriate means and activities to the unification of maritime law in all its aspects. To this end it shall promote the establishment of national associations of maritime law and shall cooperate with other international organizations.75

Let us go back to Albrecht Cordes, whose succinct conclusions on the supposed medieval and early modern lex maritima well serve as a comment on Averages and their application: To encounter a great degree of continuity and uniformity on the side of the challenges must not be confused with the variety of responses tried out in the attempt to face that challenge. The bottom line remains the same: not a single example of a uniform legal response to a specific challenge of maritime trade law has ever been found.76

75 https://comitemaritime.org/about-us/; some short official, histories of the Comité are available at: https://comitemaritime.org/about-us/history/ (last accessed 18 December 2021). 76 Cordes, ‘Lex Maritima?’, 80; also A. Cordes, ‘The Search for a Medieval Lex mercatoria’, Oxford U Comparative L Forum 5 (2003), at: https://ouclf.law.ox.ac. uk/category/authors/albrecht-cordes/ (last accessed 18 December 2021); E. Kadens, ‘The Myth of the Customary Law Merchant’, Texas Law Review, 90 (2012): 1153– 1206; D. De ruysscher, ‘Conceptualizing Lex Mercatoria: Malynes, Schmitthoff and Goldman Compared’, Maastricht Journal of European and Comparative Law, 27/4 (2020): 465–483.

26

M. FUSARO

Conclusion Storms at sea were a popular subject for Baroque music, and the pieces’ compositional structure would usually concentrate on the naturalistic element. Central was the developmental arc of the storm itself, the composer’s focus tightly directed at replicating the relentless strength of natural phenomena from their slow build-up into frenzied fury, followed by their winding down, heralding the return of calm. Baroque music’s passion for the tempest—both as metaphor and as representational challenge—was always matched to a tight formal frame, as if unruliness could come to the fore and preserve its aesthetic power only when mediated by order.77 This fascination with the tempest did not abate entirely, even with the advent of the classical style. Joseph Haydn’s Symphony no. 39 (known as the ‘Tempesta di mare’) has a slightly different structure; the storm is indeed there and develops along traditional musicological structures, but the piece has puzzled critics, as the highly kinetic storm depiction alternates with movements with formalized balletic elements, a precise and even precious minuet form which somehow does not seem to fit.78 For me it embodies a perfect representation of General Average, a complex and messy event punctuated and resolved by moments of high procedural formality. The utter dominance of the force of nature in maritime trade is a constant over time, its taming a perennial aspiration, careful managing of its consequences a necessity. In the early modern period maritime disasters

77 I warmly thank Alessandra Campana for our conversations sharing her expertise on Baroque music forms and storm representations. 78 The peculiar structure of the piece is usually attributed to “Haydn’s search for new narrative strategies for a genre caught up in the tensions between the boisterous concert opener, courtly representation, the bourgeois concert hall and the demands of “connoisseurs””, see: F. Diegarten, ‘Time Out of Joint—Time Set Right: Principles of Form in Haydn’s Symphony No. 39’, Studia Musicologica, 51/1–2 (2010): 109–126, 109.

SHARING RISKS, ON AVERAGES AND WHY THEY MATTER

27

affected not just trade in and of itself; rather, their consequences reverberated across the economy.79 Risk in all its multifaceted expressions is a constituent element of human activities, its economic repercussions a constant societal concern through time and space. I started this essay noting how the centrality of risk reduction is strongly embedded in every aspect of the maritime enterprise, as any seaborne activity entails high levels of exposure to danger. Risk has also been central to the complex relationship between (maritime) commercial enterprise and its ethical and moral dimensions. During the Middle Ages, in Giacomo Todeschini’s words, “it was precisely the constant risks to which [merchants] were exposed that legalised, in the eyes of canonists and theologians, especially Franciscan ones, [merchants’] economic virtue”.80 Francesca Trivellato recently reminded us how “modern scholars of commercial and maritime law are accustomed to thinking that by the seventeenth century, this field of inquiry had entered the sphere of politics and left that of theology”,81 whilst in actual practice the ethical framing of economic activities has been a most active

79 On the effect of maritime disasters in money supply shocks see: A. Brzezinski, Y. Chen, N. Palma, and F. Ward, ‘The Vagaries of the Sea: Evidence on the Real Effects of Money from Maritime Disasters in the Spanish Empire’, Working paper No. 170, European Economic History Society, available at: https://econpapers.repec.org/paper/ heswpaper/0170.htm (last accessed 30 December 2021). 80 G. Todeschini, Ricchezza francescana. Dalla povertà volontaria alla società di mercato (Bologna 2004), 133; also his I mercanti e il tempio. La società cristiana e il circolo virtuoso della ricchezza fra Medioevo ed Età Moderna (Bologna 2002). Particularly important are the works of Giovanni Ceccarelli: ‘Le logiche del rischio economico fra XIII e XV secolo’, in A. De Vincentiis ed., Il moderno nel medioevo (Rome 2010), 201–212; ‘Quando rischiare è lecito. Il credito finalizzato al commercio marittimo nella riflessione scolastica tardomedievale’, in S. Cavaciocchi ed., Ricchezza del mare, ricchezza dal mare (Florence 2006), 1187–1200; ‘Risky Business: Theological and Canonical Thought on Insurance from the Thirteenth to the Seventeenth Century’, Journal of Medieval and Early Modern Studies, 31/3 (2001): 607–658, the latter especially for its analysis of how ‘risk’ came to assume a ‘price’. 81 F. Trivellato, The Promise and Peril of Credit: What a Forgotten Legend About Jews and Finance Tells Us About the Making of Commercial Society (Princeton 2019), 56. An issue also raised by W. Decock, ‘In Defense of Commercial Capitalism: Lessius, Partnerships and the Contractus Trinus ’, Max Planck Institute for European Legal History Research Paper available at: https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_ id=2162908&download=yes (last accessed 20 December 2021).

28

M. FUSARO

of area of debate throughout the history of economic thought, as it is in contemporary politics and policy. In the middle of the twentieth century, for what will most likely prove to be a short period, the paradigm of homo oeconomicus triumphed in the developed world, and consequently in its scholarship.82 Single-minded concentration on the rational pursuit of economic success, through strategies and policies aimed at the maximization of economic profit, was the hegemonic paradigm. Contemporary societies are now confronted with truly global risks, from climate change and its effects to increasing societal destabilization resulting from growing inequalities. Confronted with the systemic financial crisis afflicting the current hegemonic variety of capitalism, and with increasing concerns especially about global inequality, the classic separation between ‘economics’ and ‘morality and ethics’ is blurring again.83 Once considered one of the pillars of rational modernity, this separation is now increasingly seen as a problematic fissure with potentially dangerous societal consequences. Risk and profit have always been privileged stages where societal ethical values are at the forefront of both economic and political debates. The way in which the associated ethical questions are posited and solved provides an additional dimension. This reframing of the discourse has advanced since the 2008 financial crisis, with its critique of unbridled capitalism, leading to a new impetus in the search for more ethical investments which would lead to more sustainable and equitable economic and social development.84 I mentioned earlier how GA has its critics within the maritime sector. However, it is possibly more important to note how the equitable principle behind contemporary GA is also finding new support precisely

82 The literature on this concept is daunting large, for a recent critical synthesis: D. A. Urbina and A. Ruiz-Villaverde, ‘A Critical Review of Homo Economicus from Five Approaches’, The American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 79/1 (2019): 63–93 and bibliography therein quoted. 83 On rising inequality, just one example which had a massive impact well beyond academia: T. Piketty, Capital in the Twenty-First Century (Cambridge, MA 2014) and his Capital and Ideology (Cambridge, MA 2019). 84 M. Mazzucato, The Value of Everything: Making and Taking in the Global Economy (London 2018); and her Mission Economy: A Moonshot Guide to Changing Capitalism (London 2021).

SHARING RISKS, ON AVERAGES AND WHY THEY MATTER

29

because of its ethical implications. Gotthard Mark Gauci, one of the critical voices regarding GA, has recently admitted that whilst cumbersome and a cause of delay, general average is intended to avoid an advantage for one party at the expense of another; indeed there is a strong argument that a general average contribution to a general average sacrifice can be justified as an operation of the gain-based principle that a legal remedy should be available for unjustified enrichment.85

Mutatis mutandis, the principle of aequitas is re-entering contemporary economic policy discourse, from the growing interest in equity-based investments inspired by traditional Islamic law investment instruments, to the search for new ways of sharing profits and losses.86 Beyond the maritime sector, and within the wider area of transport law, more sustainable transport solutions are drawing inspiration from the mutuality of GA sharing, and the peculiarities of its risk community, to find ways to allocate costs in a more equitable and sustainable manner.87 Within present discussions on reforms in bankruptcy regulations in the US, the GA principle is being proposed as an example, as it would dictate that stakeholders share costs and losses in proportion to the value of their holdings.88 It should be clear now that the history of Averages has much to contribute not just to the historiography of risk management, but also to its future developments, above and beyond the maritime sector. Maritime history for a long time has been a self-contained field, and its relatively recent entry into the mainstream should remind us how embedded it

85 Gauci, ‘Of Piracy and General Average’, 249; Italics mine. 86 S. Nazim Ali, W. Tariq and B. Al Quradaghi eds., The Edinburgh Companion to

Shari’Ah Governance in Islamic Finance (Edinburgh 2020); N. Mazuin Sapuan, ‘An Evolution of Mudarabah Contract: A Viewpoint from Classical and Contemporary Islamic Scholars’, Procedia Economics and Finance, 35 (2016): 349–358; N. H. D. Foster, ‘Islamic Perspectives on the Law of Business Organisations I: An Overview of the Classical Sharia and a Brief Comparison of the Sharia Regimes with Western-Style Law’, European Business Organization Law Review, 11 (2010): 3–34. 87 Julia Hörnig (Erasmus Universiteit Rotterdam) is currently preparing a project on these issues. 88 A. J. Casey, ‘Chapter 11’s Renegotiation Framework and the Purpose of Corporate Bankruptcy’, Columbia Law Review, 120/7 (2020): 1709–1770.

30

M. FUSARO

has always been in European historiography. It is no coincidence that since the times of Plato, the ‘ship of state’ is the arch-metaphor for good management and respect for reciprocal obligations and needs within human societies.89

89 Plato, The Republic, Edited and translated by C. Emlyn-Jones, W. Preddy (Cambridge, MA 2013), 6: 488a–89a.

SHARING RISKS, ON AVERAGES AND WHY THEY MATTER

31

Open Access This chapter is licensed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/ by/4.0/), which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this chapter are included in the chapter’s Creative Commons license, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the chapter’s Creative Commons license and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder.

General Average and All the Rest: The Law and Economics of Early Modern Maritime Risk Mitigation Ron Harris

General Average is probably the longest existing maritime trade institution, first used by Greek and Roman sailors in antiquity and still in use today by the global maritime industry. Premium-based marine insurance is much younger. The first evidence for its use is from around 1300 CE. Why did the two institutions originate more than a millennium apart? This timing question cannot be resolved solely by analysing the primary historical records. The answer to this significant question was not written down by contemporaries and will not be found in the texts they left behind. We need theories in order to approach it. While theories

I would like to thank Giovanni Ceccarelli, Maria Fusaro, Roy Kreitner, Robert Scott, participants in the “Sharing risk: General Average, 6th-21st Centuries” Conference (Genoa, Archivio di Stato, 16–18 May 2019) and anonymous reviewers of the article for valuable comments, references and suggestions and Anna Ashurov and Maya Hay for the excellent research assistance. R. Harris (B) Tel-Aviv University, Tel Aviv, Israel e-mail: [email protected]

© The Author(s) 2023 M. Fusaro et al. (eds.), General Average and Risk Management in Medieval and Early Modern Maritime Business, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-04118-1_2

33

34

R. HARRIS

about the mitigation of risk might not be the only relevant theories for addressing the question, they are sufficiently instructive to serve as the core of this article. The fastest and least costly way of sending cargos in antiquity was by ships. A geospatial model, created by Walter Scheidel and Elijah Meeks, shows very vividly how travel time and transportation costs rose very steeply in the Roman world once one was getting from the Mediterranean into the surrounding overland routes.1 We do not have a similar reconstruction of medieval travel time and costs. We can guess that the general picture is similar; the use of natural wind energy, rather than animals that had to be fed, and the larger scale of ships available, compared to packs and wagons, saved time and costs, as they did in the Roman era. The relative differences between sea and overland travel were even higher in the Medieval era due to the absence of well-developed roads and facilities, and the political instability after the fall of Rome.2 The use of maritime transportation created an opportunity for substantial trade advantage and hefty profits. However, maritime trade faced the gravest challenges and the highest risks of all sectors in pre-modern economies. Ships were foundered and wrecked, pirates and foreign rulers could seize goods, cargoes could be damaged, lives could be lost, loans could be negated, agents could abscond, market prices could fluctuate, and demand for goods in the marketplace could dissipate. In a meta-survey of the findings of marine archaeology of the Mediterranean, Andrew Wilson identifies 1646 shipwrecks for the period before 1500 CE.3 This is the lower bound for actual ship loss. More shipwrecks are likely to be discovered as marine archaeology expands its underwater surveys and excavations. Other shipwrecks will never be discovered because they did not survive. Foundering was not the only risk faced by maritime trade; it was the one better captured by

1 Walter Scheidel and Elijah Meeks, ‘ORBIS: The Stanford Geospatial Network Model of the Roman World’, Stanford University Libraries. http://orbis.stanford.edu (last accessed 30 December 2021); W. Scheidel, ‘The Shape of the Roman World: Modelling Imperial Connectivity’, Journal of Roman Archaeology, 27/1 (2014): 7–32. 2 R. W. Unger ed., Shipping and Economic Growth 1350–1850 (Leiden 2011). 3 A. Wilson, ‘Developments in Mediterranean Shipping and Maritime Trade from the

Hellenistic Period to AD 1000’, in D. Robinson and A. Wilson eds., Maritime Archaeology and Ancient Trade in the Mediterranean (Oxford 2011), 33–59.

GENERAL AVERAGE AND ALL THE REST …

35

modern archaeologists and historians. Jettison, damage to cargo, piracy, business losses were not well recorded but were prevalent. The environment of maritime trade activities was, in economists’ terms, one of uncertainties, high risks, vast information asymmetries, augmented agency problems, weak enforcement of contracts, and fragile protection of property rights.4 Dealing with such a tough economic environment was a foremost institutional challenge for pre-modern contemporary merchants, jurists, and rulers. Maritime trade is where the institutional cutting-edge could be found. This is where new and innovative organizational solutions were designed. The application of Frank Knight’s theoretical framework, which distinguishes between uncertainty and risk, can take us a long way in answering this question. It focuses on the ability to price risks. As we shall see, Knight’s theory will not take us all the way. I will next show that by introducing Douglass North’s theory of institutional evolution, both the historical story and the theoretical framework get murkier. I will then add Robert Scott’s contracts theory. I will offer a synthesis on both levels, namely on how to overcome the historical puzzle and how to reconcile the theories. After combining the theories into a more comprehensive framework, we can utilize this framework in order to analyse the origins and early evolution of insurance, General Average, and additional maritime trade institutions. I will deal with three of the most renowned of these institutions: the sea loan, the commenda and the business corporation. This essay does not aspire to offer fully fledged answers to the questions posed above. Instead, it is a demonstration of the value of the theoretical framework offered here in generating research questions and in orientating the historical research. A more systematic and comprehensive application of the theoretical framework offered here for the available historical records is required in order to better base and exhaust the historical insights. This essay originated in a key-note lecture, delivered by an outsider to the field that deals with similar puzzles in different historical contexts, does not report the findings of actual historical research. It is programmatic, setting up the stage in terms of questions. Answers to these questions will have to be provided by historians specializing in the

4 For a parallel analysis of risk and risk mitigation devices in the same period, see Maria Fusaro and Giovanni Ceccarelli contributions in this volume.

36

R. HARRIS

period, such as the scholars taking part in the European Research Council project on General Average (AveTransRisk), led by Maria Fusaro.5

Frank Knight on Uncertainty and Risk Frank Knight (1885–1972) is famed for conceptualizing a distinction between risk and uncertainty. His book in which he created this distinction—Risk, Uncertainty and Profit —is one of the most canonic books in economics and beyond.6 Knight explains: The practical difference between the two categories, risk and uncertainty, is that in the former the distribution of the outcome in a group of instances is known (either through calculation a priori or from statistics of past experience), while in the case of uncertainty this is not true, the reason being in general that it is impossible to form a group of instances because the situation dealt with is in a high degree unique.7

Knight identifies three possible states of the world: (1) a priori probabilities which are derived deductively, as in rolling a dice; (2) statistical probabilities which are generated by empirical evaluation of relative frequencies, as in life insurance; and (3) estimates, in which “there is no valid basis of any kind for classifying instances”.8 Knight identified risk with points 1 and 2 and uncertainty with 3. From a different perspective, Knight is designated by “risk” situations, in which insurance markets can exist, and by “uncertainty” situations, in which insurance markets cannot. Knight was not a historian. He does not offer his own historical narrative of the shift of environments from uncertainty to risk. He does not offer a historical account of the origins of marine insurance. One insight is apparent in Knight’s framework. An economic environment cannot move from uncertainty to risk by developing insurance. In an environment of uncertainty, premium-based third party marine insurance (hereafter premium-based marine insurance or simply marine insurance) cannot 5 ‘Average-Transaction Costs and Risk Management During the First Globalization (Sixteenth-Eighteenth Centuries)’, https://humanities.exeter.ac.uk/history/research/cen tres/maritime/research/avetransrisk/. 6 Having 22,000 citations. 7 F. H. Knight, Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit (Boston 1921), 118. 8 Knight, Risk, 113.

GENERAL AVERAGE AND ALL THE REST …

37

be developed and offered. Insurance is not the facilitator; according to Knight, it is the outcome. The causation runs the other way around. The birth and further development of marine insurance is a response to a shift of the trade environment from one riddled with uncertainty to one in which uncertainties were already converted to quantifiable risks. Knight does not offer a coherent dynamic theory for the environmental shift. One has to infer the dynamics from his quite static and abstract analysis. Once applying Knight’s theoretical lens, we know where to look for the dynamics. We have to study the informational front. The prohibitive factor that prevents the development of marine insurance is the inability to price maritime risks. The solution was to have more information that would gradually convert uncertainty into risk. Could medieval merchants achieve this? In other words, was increased information exogenous or only somewhat endogenous to the institutional dynamics related to the development of marine insurance? I will get back to these questions later. Note that, for Knight, insurance is not an invention. It is not the case that, until a certain point in the historical flow, merchants did not understand that risk is a prohibitive or costly hurdle that had to be mitigated in order to expand trade further. It is also not the case that merchants did not know how to organize insurance firms or how to draft insurance contracts. Knight does not consider the need to develop a mathematical understanding of probabilities and their calculations. Even if they fully understood the importance of risk mitigation and had the mathematical, organizational, and legal know-how, they could not invent insurance because they were unable to price the risk premium.

38

R. HARRIS

Douglass North on Transaction Costs and Risk Spreading Let’s juxtapose now Knight’s framework with that of Douglass North (1920–2015).9 North was another famed economist. He was economics Nobel Laureate (in 1993) for “renewed research in economic history by applying economic theory and quantitative methods in order to explain economic and institutional change”.10 North placed on his research agenda institutions, organizations, contracts, and transaction costs, rather than the information needed for pricing. His framework is explicitly dynamic and historical, though admittedly not based on detailed archival research but rather on a stylized narrative. Let’s see whether North’s starting point can provide us with some of the dynamic dimensions and historical specifications that Knight failed to provide. We’ll do it initially with respect to insurance, as this institution was important for both Knight and North. For North, institutional evolution (in tandem with technological innovation) drives economic development.11 “Institutions exist to reduce the uncertainties involved in human interaction”.12 The contribution of institutions to economic development is generated by their role in reducing 9 Knight is identified by some scholars as related to the institutionalist school within

economics. North is identified as related to the new institutionalist school. One could view North as continuing Knight’s institutionalist tradition. But others argue that Knight was not really an Institutionalist and that North’s New Institutionalism is not built upon old Institutionalism. On these issues: G. M. Hodgson, ‘Frank Knight as an Institutional Economist’, in J. E. Biddle et al. eds., Economics Broadly Considered: Essays in Honor of Warren J. Samuels (London 2001), 64–93; P. F. Asso and L. Fiorito, ‘Was Frank Knight an Institutionalist?’, Review of Political Economy, 20/1 (2008): 59–77. 10 R. W. Fogel and D. C. North, ‘The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1993’, The Nobel Prize. https://www.nobelprize.org/prizes/ economic-sciences/1993/summary (last accessed April 30, 2020). 11 North’s definition of institutions is: ‘Institutions Are the Rules of the Game in Society, or More Formally, Are the Human Devised Constraints That Shape Human Interaction’, in D. C. North ed., Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance (Cambridge 1990), 3. A more recent influential definition is that of Avner Greif, ‘An Institution Is a System of Social Factors That Conjointly Generate a Regularity of Behavior’, in his Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade (Cambridge 2006), 30. 12 North, Institutions, Institutional Change, 25; D. C. North, Understanding the Process of Economic Change (Princeton 2005); D. C. North and R. P. Thomas, The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History (Cambridge 1973).

GENERAL AVERAGE AND ALL THE REST …

39

transaction costs and facilitating transactions. Institutional innovations lowered transaction costs, according to North, along three margins: (1) increasing mobility of capital; (2) lowering information costs; and (3) spreading risks. We are interested here in the third. The institutional evolution that led to the increase in capital mobility included the development of methods for the evasion—and, eventually, the repeal—of usury laws, the development of bills of exchange, better enforcement of contracts, and the development of devices for better monitoring of agents. The lowering of information costs was achieved by the invention of the print, the publication of price and exchange lists, the standardization of weights and measures, a postal system, and more. Insurance and portfolio diversification are the two institutional innovations for spreading and reducing risk, and by this, for reducing transaction costs. The development of marine insurance is a prime example of a risk spreading institutional innovation that lowers transaction costs and enhances economic development.13 According to Knight, only after uncertainty is converted into risk does insurance emerge. Do we face here a theoretical contradiction between Knight and North? For Knight, insurance is evidence for the conversion of uncertainty into risk. It is an outcome of the conversion. For North, insurance is a means for transforming uncertainty into risk. Is insurance the institutional innovation that facilitates the conversion of uncertainties into risks? If not, how do we get from a world of uncertainties to a world of risks? So, is this a disagreement between Knight and North as to what came first, the chicken or the egg?

Robert Scott on Contracts Under Uncertainty While Knight is interested in pricing risk that enables insurance, North is interested in the evolution of the institutions that supply insurance. He takes us in this direction but not all the way. He does not offer a theory for the supply of insurance as an institutional innovation. He does not analyse the organizational and contractual details. Robert Scott, from Columbia Law School, a leading theoretician in the fields of contracts and commercial transactions, can take us the rest of the way from pricing to contracts. Scott has developed over the years, with various co-authors, a theory

13 North, Institutions, Institutional Change, 126–127.

40

R. HARRIS

about the different types of contracts that will be developed and used in different environments.14 Scott is not a historian. He is interested in the changes that occur as a system moves from the present into the future. This move often involves the introduction of new and experimental technologies, the entrance into new markets and the use of innovative business methods. Scott provides an account of the change in the production of contracts along two continuums, the shift from low uncertainty to higher uncertainty environments, and the shift from thinner (lower scale) to thicker (higher scale) markets. For Scott, uncertainty increases with innovation. Scale increases with maturation. I will use here mainly the first dimension and, along with it, a reverse shift. For me, the general historical shift of markets is from higher uncertainty to lower uncertainty. For Scott, it is the other way around. The difference stems from the fact that I, as a historian, am interested in the longer-term historical shifts and am not focusing only on the initiation stage but also on the maturing stage of any new technology or method. Scott’s prediction is that, along with the uncertainty to certainty dimension, contracts will evolve from collaborative contracts, that braid formal and informal enforcement and sanctions, to long-term relational contracts that set general standards of behaviour, such as best effort, and finally, to complete bespoke contracts that cover numerous contingencies.15 The rationale for this evolution is that the lower the uncertainty is, 14 A. Schwartz and R. E. Scott, ‘Contract Theory and the Limits of Contract Law’, Yale Law Journal, 113/3 (2003): 541–619; R. E. Scott and G. G. Triantis, ‘Anticipating Litigation in Contract Design’, Yale Law Journal, 115/4 (2005): 814–879; R. J. Gilson, C. F. Sabel, and R. E. Scott, ‘Braiding: The Interaction of Formal and Informal Contracting in Theory, Practice and Doctrine’, Columbia Law Review, 110/6 (2010): 1377–1447; S. J. Choi, G. M. Gulati, and R. E. Scott, ‘The Black Hole Problem in Commercial Boilerplate’, Duke Law Journal, 67/1 (2017): 1–77; R. E. Scott, ‘The Paradox of Contracting in Markets’, Law and Contemporary Problems, 83 (2020): 71–99. 15 Scott’s analysis has a second dimension, the scale of the market dimension. Along the continuum of this dimension, contracting will shift from atomistic bilateral to multilateral network embedded contracting as the markets become thicker. The rationale for this is that the thinner the market, the more difficult it is to match several parties to jointly run a transaction, while the more traders involved in a market and the more frequent the trade transactions are, the more possible it is to run multilateral transactions to do this in networks, and the ticker the markets, the more self-sustained are the networks. The network renders the contracts effective by allowing the monitoring of breaches and enforcing of contracts. As the uncertainty in thick markets decreases, networks will evolve from ones in which regulatory state intervention (a spider) is necessary in order to hold the network together, to ones in which the state is absent (spider less networks), and this

GENERAL AVERAGE AND ALL THE REST …

41

the more feasible it is to draft contractual terms ex-ante, while the higher the uncertainty, the more cost-efficient it is to draft simple contracts and delay the costs to the ex-post litigation stage. Scott’s contribution over Knight is that there are ways to draft contracts even under uncertainty. Contracts can be drafted in a manner that facilitates pricing under uncertainty. He is more concrete, compared to North, about how to do this, namely which types of contracts would fit each environment best. Scott’s theory can guide historical research to look for a specific direction of change over time. However, it cannot provide concrete predictions as to which form of contract is expected to be used at a specific point in time. By now, we realize that information is pivotal to all three theoretical frameworks. For Knight, information about probabilities is the key. For North, one of the three transaction costs margins, next to risk spreading, is information costs. For Scott, the information determines the suitable contract type. However, Scott also views contracts as a means for generating information. Contracts can require one of the parties to provide information to the other, say by way of requiring agents to report to principals regularly and to provide detailed itinerary and accounts. Scott’s contribution, in this respect, is that his model turns information into an endogenous factor.

Knight, North, Scott and the Origins of Marine Insurance Let’s use my integration of the uncertainty-risk theoretical frameworks developed by Knight, North, and Scott for explaining the origins and timing of premium-based marine insurance. We’ll start with insurance rather than General Average because it is in the centre of the analysis of Knight and North and yields itself more conveniently for analysis. Premium-based marine insurance first appeared in the Italian city-states of

serves as a conduit for the flow of private information to networks in which the network is based on private ordering and dispute resolution. Because this article is not interested in the development and role of networks, this second dimension will only feature in it in an ancillary way.

42

R. HARRIS

the thirteenth to fifteenth centuries CE Mediterranean.16 It spread northwards to Antwerp, Amsterdam, and London in the following centuries.17 Premium-based marine insurance allowed merchants to convert more considerable contingent losses into a smaller fixed charge. How could Mediterranean maritime merchants cross the threshold and move from an environment of unquantifiable uncertainty into an environment of measurable risks? Knight explains his prime route from uncertainty to risk: “The amount of uncertainty may, however, be reduced in several ways, as we have seen. In the first place, we can increase our knowledge of the future through scientific research and the accumulation and study of the necessary data”.18 The pricing of the premium depends upon the measurement of probability based on a fairly accurate grouping into classes. Risks did not have to be calculated on the precise individual probability of a single merchant to lose his cargo on the seas, but could also be done at the group level, by finding the proportions of the members of the group which may be expected to lose their cargo. The premium could be set in a heuristic manner, which is not based on a formal concept of probability and mathematical calculations, called by Giovanni Ceccarelli “proto-probabilistic” mathematical thinking or “pre-actuarial” stage in insurance.19 He shows that the shift from viewing the sinking of a ship

16 L. Piccinno, ‘Genoa, 1340-1620: Early Development of Marine Insurance’, in A. Leonard ed., Marine Insurance: Origins and Institutions, 1300–1850 (Basingstoke 2016), 25–45. 17 D. De ruysscher, ‘Antwerp 1490–1590: Insurance and Speculation’, in Leonard ed., Marine Insurance, 79–105; J. Puttevils and M. Deloof, ‘Marketing and Pricing Risk in Marine Insurance in Sixteenth-Century Antwerp’, The Journal of Economic History, 77/3 (2017): 796–837; S. Go, Marine Insurance in the Netherlands 1600–1870: A Comparative Institutional Approach (Amsterdam 2009); G. Rossi, Insurance in Elizabethan England: The London Code (Cambridge 2016). 18 Knight, Risk, 179. It does not follow that insurance markets will necessarily exist. Other problems, such as moral hazard, can prevent them from developing. Yet, other solutions, for example organizational solutions of grouping together risks into a single firm, can emerge. 19 G. Ceccarelli, ‘The Price for Risk-Taking: Marine Insurance and Probability Calculus

in the Late Middle Ages’, Journ@l Électronique d’Histoire des Probabilités et de la Statistique, 3/1 (2007), available at: http://eudml.org/doc/130865 (last accessed 20 December 2021); G. Ceccarelli, ‘Risky Business: Theological and Canonical Thought on Insurance from the Thirteenth to the Seventeenth Century’, Journal of Medieval and Early Modern Studies, 31/3 (2001): 602–652, 607.

GENERAL AVERAGE AND ALL THE REST …

43

as a matter of god’s will or pure luck (that could at most be gambled about) to one that views it as a matter of statistical probabilities (mathematically trained insurance actuaries could price that) was incremental. The insurer had to convince the insured that there was a fairly plausible contention between premium contributions and actual risks, that the insured are bearing a fair share of the burden.20 In a competitive insurance market, the insurer also had to be able to set the price of the risk premium so that it would be sufficiently accurate and competitive, subject the insurance contract to low costs, and enable legal enforcement and effective dispute resolution in the event of disagreements. A first way identified by Knight for turning uncertainty into risk is by a systematic collection of data about risks. Knight did not develop the distinction between information as non-excludable public good and information as an excludable private good, nor between public gathering and production of information by rulers or municipalities and information gathered by individual merchants. Later scholars did. The development of the Italian city-states supported the information gathering assistance they provided in their hometown, on board ships, and by consuls in overseas ports. It facilitated a more systematic gathering of the fortunes of ships and their cargos and the ensuing losses. This constituted part of the shift from the environment of uncertainty to the environment of risk. A second way hinted by Knight is by the faster circulation of information due to the increased level of trade. The thickness and scale of trade increased with the commercial revolution. Longer length spans of repeated voyages to the same destinations, higher frequency of voyages, thicker trade networks, and larger commercial and banking family firms gradually led to the accumulation of sufficient information about the a priori probabilities. Knight has in mind the thickness of trade in goods, not of insurance.21 As we shall see, Scott has in mind the thickness of the insurance market as an information generator.

20 R. Z. Friedman, Probable Justice: Risk, Insurance, and the Welfare State (Chicago 2020). 21 Similar analysis along the thinness to the thickness dimension was conducted by Rosenthal and Wong. They predict that thicker markets will be able to rely on informal reputation-based enforcement, whereas thinner markets will have to resort to formal legally based enforcement, see J.-L. Rosenthal and R. Bin Wong, Before and Beyond Divergence: The Politics of Economic Change in China and Europe (Cambridge, MA 2011).

44

R. HARRIS

A third related way identified by Knight for reducing uncertainty is increased control over the future. Applying this to maritime trade would involve the building of sturdier ships, the elimination of piracy, the setting of international law of naval warfare, the production of better weather forecasts and the use of safer sea routes.22 Once more information about maritime events becomes available through any of the three ways, the environment becomes one of risk rather than uncertainty. Premium insurance soon followed. Transaction costs probably decreased, and economic outcomes improved. The distinction between this third way and the two previous ways of moving from uncertainty to risk is that in the first two, the frequency of negative maritime events is better measured, and in the third, the overall number of negative events is reduced.23 Information gathering can be endogenous to trade, as increasing frequency of voyages to the same destinations and denser trade networks produce more positive and negative events on which probabilities can be calculated. It can be exogenous to trade, say through more investments by rulers and municipalities in information gathering. Knight reminds us that information is not a free lunch, as the gathering involves costs. While Knight says that insurance is the outcome of the conversion of uncertainty into risk, North says that Insurance is a solution. North acknowledges that the development of insurance is complicated, yet he does not offer a plausible path for its origins and early development.24 Scott offers such a gradual and relatively plausible and predictable path. The first insurance contracts are predicted by Scott to have been individually tailored. Later insurance contracts are predicted to have been repetitions of previous contracts and eventually boiler-plate standard form insurance policies. The first insurance contracts were likely to cover only one scenario, later contracts a handful of scenarios of damages or loss. More mature insurance contracts were likely to be based on the prediction of numerous likely scenarios and responded to the various eventualities by many if–then clauses. Insurance contracts were likely to evolve into 22 See the contribution of Andrea Addobbati in this volume. 23 Knight mentions two more ways for reducing uncertainty: slowing up the march of

progress and the pooling together of activities into larger organizations. We will turn to the latter later on. 24 A. B. Leonard, ‘Introduction: The Nature and Study of Marine Insurance’ (in Leonard ed., Marine Insurance, 3–22), shows that North’s historical analysis has more value as an agenda setter than as a detailed historical research.

GENERAL AVERAGE AND ALL THE REST …

45

longer and more detailed contracts gradually. It was unlikely that the first insurance contracts included general standards saying that the insurer will cover every damage, every maritime damage or any damage that was not caused by the insured or due to the negligence of the insured.25 All of these predictions can and should be put to historical examination. There is a significant corpus of insurance contracts that survived in notarial and municipal archives in Italian city-states, and they can be examined using these theoretical insights and predictions.26 Four factors complicate the theory-informed study of the origins of insurance based on insurance contracts. First, most contracts did not survive. Second, contracts were also drafted to bypass usury laws and some of their clauses reflect this rather than dealing with information deficiencies. Third, insurers had to find ways to deal with moral hazard problems, which are distinct from pure information problems. Fourth, some of the contractual terms were set in city customs and regulations, and a study of these has to complement the text of the insurance contracts. These complicating factors should not discourage historians of insurance. They could be dealt with in a variety of ways.27 While the development of the form of insurance contracts can be predicted by applying the above theoretical frameworks, the timing of its first appearance is not well postulated by the theory of either Knight, North, or Scott. For Knight, there are two states of the world—uncertainty and risk—and the only way to know that we moved from the

25 Such contracts meant that the contracting costs were shifted from the ex-ante drafting stage to the ex-post litigation stage. But, as we learned from Knight, insurance cannot be priced under uncertainty. It seems as though delaying the costs from the front-end to the backend is not a solution for pricing the insurance contracts. 26 F. Edler de Roover, ‘Early Examples of Marine Insurance’, The Journal of Economic History, 5/2 (1945): 172–200; H. O. Nelli, ‘The Earliest Insurance Contract. A New Discovery’, The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 39/2 (1972): 215–220. 27 Another aspect that this article does not deal with is moral hazard. Moral Hazard is the possibility that once insured, the policy holding trader will not care whether he gets the goods or the insurance indemnification. Because of this, he will not try to mitigate maritime risks and avoid damages to the goods. Moral hazard problems might be prohibitive to the development of insurance markets. Moral hazard can be, at least, partially offset contractually. The development of contractual responses to moral hazard problems is a worthy topic of historical investigation. One example from a later period is C. Kingston, ‘Marine Insurance in Britain and America, 1720–1844: A Comparative Institutional Analysis’, The Journal of Economic History, 67/2 (2007): 379–409. Similar investigations can be conducted for the earlier history of marine insurance as well.

46

R. HARRIS

former to the latter is by observing the appearance of insurance.28 For North and Scott, the shift is gradual and continuous. One can observe a gradual evolution of insurance contracts. The timing of the appearance of insurance relates to the reduction of uncertainty, which in turn relates to the increased circulation of information. This increase, according to Scott, is partly exogenous—the increased thickness and scale of trade created more information about the probability of negative events. It is also partly endogenous, as the experimentation with insurance contracts and the learning by doing or drafting them generated information. They can, for example, generate information by requiring the policyholder to provide information at the underwriting stage or the claim stage. Such requirements would require the policyholder to collect, record and report information that would not absent the contract. The exact timing in which premium marine insurance was likely to first appear is not postulated by theory. We don’t know exactly how much information of which type is sufficient for pricing insurance accurately enough and for drafting clauses that would cover sufficient if–then contingencies. Even if we knew how much information was theoretically needed, we don’t know to measure how much of the relevant information was actually available for would-be insurers at any point in time. Yet, it will not come as a surprise that the commercial revolution of the eleventh to thirteenth centuries, that took place mainly in the Italian city-states of Venice, Florence, Genoa, Pisa, produced increasing trade information and reduced uncertainty to a level that gave rise to the first insurance contracts.29 We don’t know how far into the revolution, the informational environment became sufficiently thick and certain to give birth to insurance. The Roman Empire poses a challenge to our Knight-based-analysis, which explains the origins of risk-mitigating institutions, such as insurance, as an outcome of the environmental shift from uncertainty to risk. The enigma addressed in this section is why institutions that were developed in the commercial revolution did not develop accordingly in the 28 Knight does not account for the possibility that insurance will not be practised for reasons other than absence of information, say lack of demand, inability to perceive protoprobabilistic mathematics, organizational obstacles, or theological or legal prohibition. 29 R. S. Lopez, The Commercial Revolution of the Middle Ages, 950–1350 (Cambridge 1976); F. C. Lane, Venice: A Maritime Republic (Baltimore 1973); Greif, Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy; P. R. Milgrom, D. C. North, and B. R. Weingast, ‘The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs’, Economics and Politics, 2/1 (1990): 1–29.

GENERAL AVERAGE AND ALL THE REST …

47

previous transition from uncertainty to risk, which occurred during the rise of the Roman Empire. Our discussion, so far, focused on the transition from the Middle Ages to the early modern world. It assumed a linear progression of the level of available information and correspondingly of trade institutions. However, the informational environment of trade in the Mediterranean did not progress linearly from antiquity to the commercial revolution of the Middle Ages, viz. the timing of the birth of insurance. Its progress can presumably be described as an upward sine wave in the Greek and early Roman era, a downward towards the collapse of the Roman Empire that continued into the post-Roman era, and an upwards wave with the rise of Islam and the Italian commercial revolution. The second peak was probably lower than the first (due to the segmentation of the sea to Arab and Latin dominated regions, if not for economic development level as well). By the first and second centuries CE, the Mediterranean was Mare Nostrum (“Our Sea”), an internal sea of the Roman Empire. Trade networks were thick, the scale of activity was high, Imperial infrastructure was well developed, and looting by foreign rulers and pirates was a non-issue. Information on the loss of ships must have been well known. Probabilities could have been predicted and risks could be priced. The Mediterranean in high antiquity was presumably an environment of risk, not uncertainty, an environment of lower risks than those of the commercial revolution of the late Middle Ages. In Knightian terms, the environment became, with the development of political stability and trade infrastructures, as the Roman Empire prospered, more conducive to insurance. On the face of it, the demand for risk-shifting devices should have been in place. Ships sank in the Roman Mediterranean. This is well known, thanks to marine archaeology, which discovered over the years hundreds of shipwrecks in the bottom of the Mediterranean. Some 1000 such ships were dated to the heyday of the Roman Empire.30 So, the enigma is why didn’t insurance originate in Roman times and had to await the commercial revolution a millennium later? Could it be the case that the Romans did not know how to think about probabilities? Could there have been some obstacles on the way of organizing firms or

30 Second century BCE to fourth century: CE. Wilson, ‘Developments in Mediterranean Shipping’. The larger number of wrecks attributed to this period does not indicate higher maritime risks. They more likely reflect more maritime traffic.

48

R. HARRIS

of drafting contracts? Could there have been Roman substitutes to insurance, which dealt with maritime risks in different methods? The answer to the enigma of why insurance did not develop as early as the Roman Empire is a task for Roman historians. It is beyond the scope of this essay.

Before Marine Insurance---General Average Let’s use the same theoretical framework for explaining the earlier origins of General Average. General Average is applied in the event of sacrifices of ship cargo or equipment to save the ship and the rest of the cargo. The paradigmatic General Average was initially applied to jettison, which occurred when part of the cargo was intentionally thrown overboard in order to save the ship from sinking, grounding, or capture by pirates, and the ship was indeed saved. Over time, the application of General Average was extended to sacrifice by the ship captain (on behalf of the owner) of sails, ropes, anchor and equipment in order to slow or lighten the ship, and so to save the ship in a storm, to pay pirates a ransom, in coins or jewellery, in order to let the ship and the rest of the cargo go, and other scenarios.31 The basic principle was that as the damage was averaged, the loss was shared by all. At least four questions arose: What types of losses, beyond jettison, fall under General Average? By whom should the decision to sacrifice or jettison be made? Which damages should be assessed and shared, and based on which price? Who should take part in sharing the burden of the damages (freight shippers, passengers, crew) and based on what (weight or value)? These complications will be discussed below. General Average deals only with a subset of the potential risks and losses at sea. General Average could not deal with maritime risks as comprehensively as insurance. General Average is possibly the oldest maritime trade institution still in use today. Its history stretches throughout two millennia, if not more. It is discussed in detail in book 14 of Justinian’s Corpus Juris Civilis, which deals with “The Rhodian Law of Jettison”.32 The Roman jurists, whose texts were collected by the editors of the Digest, go back to the second and third centuries CE. References to Lex Rhodia can be found in

31 W. Ashburner, The Rhodian Sea-Law: Edited from the Manuscripts (Oxford 1909). 32 C. H. Monro ed. and transl., ‘Fourteenth Book’, Digest of Justinian (Cambridge

1909), 378.

GENERAL AVERAGE AND ALL THE REST …

49

first century CE Roman texts, and some scholars believe that a customary Rhodian maritime law existed as early as 600 BCE.33 Jettison, as a practice, is mentioned in Jonah’s biblical story.34 Thus, with some speculative stance, we can imagine General Average to be 2500 years old. Even a conservative estimate would hold the General Average’s origins to predate that of the premium marine insurance by at least a thousand years.35 Importantly, for our analysis, is that General Average did not develop during the heyday of the Roman Empire when maritime risks were low due to political stability and well-developed economic facilities, but in earlier centuries when risks were high and uncertainties still ubiquitous. How could General Average function in a world of uncertainty? In case of damage to the ship or cargo, resulting from jettisoning or other voluntary sacrifices of cargo or ship equipment in order to save the rest, all stakeholders proportionally share any losses. Some cargo owners could be more vulnerable than others to jettison, for example, those whose cargo was heavier per value and could have more impact on saving the ship, or those whose cargo was placed, based on loading rules, on the upper deck and could be thrown faster on emergency. General Average better aligned the interests of the various cargo owners so that they would be all supportive of the jettison when effective in saving the ship. General Average also solved ex-ante problems, by making cargo owners more indifferent regarding the location of their cargo on board or whether other cargo on board is more or less valuable per weight than theirs’. The significant advantage of General Average over insurance is that the risk is not allocated to outsiders. The Average was being calculated only between those who had stakes in the ship, cargo owners and passengers. As the risk was not separated and as no one purchased it, there was no need to price the risk ex-ante. All calculations were made ex-post. This solved Knight’s problem. What about Scott’s contract drafting problem? Is it at all relevant for analysing General Average? Should we understand General Average to 33 D. Bolanˇca, V. Pezelj, and P. Amiži´c, ‘General Average—An Ancient Institution

of Maritime Law’, Ius Romanum, 2 (2017): 1–10; O. R. Constable, ‘The Problem of Jettison in Medieval Mediterranean Maritime Law’, Journal of Medieval History, 20/3 (1994): 207–220; Andrea Addobbati in this volume. 34 Jonah 1: 5. 35 For the origins and migration of General Average, see the contributions of Daphne

Penna and Andrea Addobbati in this volume.

50

R. HARRIS

be an implicit contract? The question is important for its own sake. It is also relevant in order to ascertain the relevance of Scott’s theoretical framework. We will approach the question using both contemporary and modern understandings of what is contractual. The rules of General Average are known to have been retained in Mediterranean customary laws, in the Digest part of the Justinian Code, and the regulations of Italian city-states. This may create the impression that it was a statute or a regulation. But, in fact, it should possibly be conceptualized as a contractual rule. To be clear, General Average was not a separate, formal, explicit and written contract. One should not expect to find General Average contracts. The question is whether General Average was an implicit background contractual term that was read into freight contracts, even if not spelled up in them. The conceptualization of General Average as a contractual rule is supported by the location of the rule in the Digest in the sections (Book XIV, Section II) that deal with contracts between shippers and merchants, such as locatio conductio and receptum nautarum.36 General Average could be viewed as either a mandatory rule or as a default rule. When the Romans dominated the entire Mediterranean, the actual effect of the General Average rule was universal; one could presumably not trade on the sea without being subjected to it. Another way of viewing General Average in the Roman Empire is that it does not matter whether one conceptualizes it as a contractual rule or a marketplace regulation; the outcome is similar. In earlier or later periods, it could be viewed as a mandatory rule for every ship departing a port that adopted the rule but not for ships departing other ports. Alternatively, it could be viewed as a take-it-or-leave-it clause in freight contracts, which means that one could not freight without implicitly agreeing to General Average. Yet, it could not be a default clause that some passengers and cargo freighters on a ship would accept, while others would reject by opting out of them. Bear in mind that the fact that General Average was widely followed in the postRoman Mediterranean ports does not mean that its details were uniform in all these ports. The question that had to be decided was which rules would apply for which ship in each of its voyages. This determination can be understood as being made based on an implicit contractual agreement. 36 E. Mataix Ferrándiz, ‘Will the Circle Be Unbroken? Continuity and Change of the Lex Rhodia’s Jettison Principles in Roman and Medieval Mediterranean Rulings’, Al-Mas¯ aq, 29/1 (2017): 41–59, 43–44.

GENERAL AVERAGE AND ALL THE REST …

51

Another way of conceptualizing General Average as contract was offered by Levin Goldschmidt. He viewed the germinamento as a contract based on a consultation followed by an agreement to jettison made on the spot on board a ship when the danger becomes imminent. In this version, it is not a law applied to the ship or an agreement made before the departure but rather the decision to jettison that made the General Average enforceable. Andrea Addobbati discusses at length in this volume the history and details of the germinamento and the misunderstandings with respect to it.37 The examination of additional contractual and regulatory aspects of General Average deserves more scholarly attention. General Average contractual rules were simpler than insurance contracts and specified only one contingency, one set of eventualities, the jettisoning of cargo without the sinking of the ship. In General Average, those whose cargo was not jettisoned had to share the damages. Scott’s framework can be used to explain why General Average contracts were likely to develop before marine insurance contracts. Insurance contracts had to address partial loss as well as total loss, sinking as well as jettisoning, weather-related damages as well as man-made damages by pirates or foreign rulers, and human mistakes made by crew or merchants. General Average was a good institutional solution for an environment of uncertainty, yet it had its limits. General Average provided no relief in the event of sinking and total loss. In such an extreme event, everybody lost everything; hence, there was no averaging to be made and no stakeholder could share the burden of the loss of other stakeholders. Having on the same ship cargos that were subjected to General Average and other cargos that were not subjected to it could create unmanageable conflicts of interest at times of trouble. It seems as though ex-ante stakeholders were behind a veil of ignorance, not knowing in advance whose cargo will be jettisoned, so there was no apparent reason for them to reject a freight contract that will include a General Average clause.

37 See Andrea Addobbati in this volume.

52

R. HARRIS

Applying the Theoretical Framework for Other Maritime Institutions Let’s see the value of the theoretical framework developed here for other maritime trade institutions that dealt with risk. We’ll examine first institutional solutions that do not require the crossing of the threshold from uncertainty to risk. We’ll discuss three such institutions in the order in which they appeared historically, the sea loan, the commenda, and the business corporation. The Sea Loan Could the sea loan be such solution? In a sea loan, the borrower was exempted from repaying the loan if the ship was wrecked. General Average contracts were less costly to draft and relied on a lower level of knowledge about possible states of affairs. Sea loans were distinct from regular loans in that they provided the ability to separate the allocation of different risks to the two parties. The sea risk, loss of ship or goods at sea, was allocated to the lender, while the business risk, changes in demand and supply and market price fluctuations, was held by the borrower. More specifically, in the case of loss of the ship or goods on the way, in the open sea, either due to drowning or capture by pirates, the borrower was discharged from the debt. The sea loan originated in antiquity, there is some evidence that it might also have been operative in the commerce of the Phoenician merchant kings of the Levantine coast as early as the second millennium BCE.38 In Athenian law, by the fifth and fourth centuries BCE the sea loan (nautikòn dáneion) was apparently widely used.39 In Roman times, the sea loan (foenus nauticum) was a distinct and well recognized legal category, which was reflected in the Justinian Code.40 So, they were a

38 J. R. Ziskind, ‘Sea Loans at Ugarit’, Journal of the American Oriental Society, 94/1 (1974): 134–137. 39 The Athenian form may have been based on even earlier Phoenician merchant practices. See Ziskind, ‘Sea Loans’, 134–137; E. E. Cohen, Athenian Economy & Society: A Banking Perspective (Princeton 1992); P. Millett, Lending and Borrowing in Ancient Athens (Cambridge 2002). 40 Ashburner, The Rhodian Sea-Law; C. B. Hoover, ‘The Sea Loan in Genoa in the Twelfth Century’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 40/3 (1926): 495–529.

GENERAL AVERAGE AND ALL THE REST …

53

product of early Greco-Roman antiquity and possibly even of the ancient Middle Eastern civilizations. The sea loan was known to the Byzantine Empire, was not accepted by Islamic law and re-emerged in the Latin West with the revival of trade in Italy.41 The puzzling fact is that sea loans were in use from antiquity, long before insurance. Why did sea loans originate so early? In theory, the statistical probability of the loss of ships on the high seas had to be known for the sea loan to function. The lender had to know it in order to price the sea risk properly and add the sea risk premium to the interest charged (based on risk-free loan interest and probably also credit default risk premium) for the loan. This probability is unknown in an environment of uncertainty. So, the sea loan seems not to be a wellfunctioning institution in terms of risk pricing under uncertainty. The Knight-inspired puzzle, as raised in the context of insurance, is reiterated in the context of the sea loan. However, the puzzle why insurance did not appear in the heyday of the Roman Empire when information about maritime losses in the Mediterranean was presumably readily available, does not apply here, because sea loans were available. However, a few factors may explain why sea loan contracts could be drafted and produced under higher uncertainty than insurance contracts. The drafting of the contract was less costly if we are convinced by Scott’s analysis, in sea loan than in insurance, as it had to cover a narrower set of contingencies. While the maritime risk of full loss at sea was allocated by the sea loan contract to the lender, other contingencies were not covered by the sea loan contract. Regulations, including Roman Catholic usury laws, capped the interest on sea loans in the Latin world from the twelfth century. Thus, the market was not free. Because interest rates could not reflect the risk premium, there was no necessity to know probabilities in order to price them. Yet, it is possible that the response of lenders was through credit rationing, offering loans only for durations and routes in which risk premium could be calculated and the compound was below the cap. Because the risk was only one of several dimensions of the sea loan transaction, the risk premium did not have to be calculated as precisely as insurance contracts in which only the risk was sold.

41 R. Harris, Going the Distance: Eurasian Trade and the Rise of the Business Corporation, 1400-1700 (Princeton 2020), 110–118.

54

R. HARRIS

The Medieval sea loan, the contemporary of the early insurance contracts, was more sophisticated than the sea loan of antiquity. Two variations emerged out of the ordinary sea loan. The first was the bottomry, a loan secured by the ship itself. The second was the respondentia, a loan secured by the goods. Both functioned in an environment of risk, rather than uncertainty, and it indeed functioned differently. The interest rate on sea loans in the twelfth century, which also reflected the sea risk premium, was 25–33% for western Mediterranean round trips, and as high as 40– 100% for voyages to the Levant.42 The expected profits were high enough to justify this. The sea loan and insurance offered different ways of mitigating risks. The sea loan did not allow the allocation of risk to a third party that was unconnected to the underlining trade transaction and did not yield itself to the spreading of the risk among many, as insurance did. On the other hand, the sea loan did not require precise pricing of the risk, could function with cruder price categories and possibly involved lower transaction costs. The theoretical framework offered here reshapes research questions concerning the history of the sea loan, introduces new puzzles and offers initial and speculative responses to some of the questions and puzzles. Well-based responses are beyond the scope of the present article. Commenda The basic commenda was a bilateral contract involving two parties, the sedentary investing party and the travelling agent. The investing party provided capital in the form of goods and cash and was entitled to a share of the profit. The travelling party provided his labour by travelling with the goods by sea or land to faraway markets in order to exchange the commenda goods with local goods and return with these to the investing party. The itinerary and goods to be bought were set in advance to some extent. The intention was to split the profits upon return based on a pre-agreed basis, typically 25–75%. The commenda was thus an equity-investment contract, specifying investments and payoffs. The

42 Hoover, ‘The Sea Loan in Genoa’.

GENERAL AVERAGE AND ALL THE REST …

55

commenda was also a labour contract with the travelling party investing labour, expertise, information, contacts and bodily risk.43 What can the theoretical framework of this article inform us about the timing of origins and course of development of the commenda? The first appearance of the commenda was in early Islamic Arabia. There are legal discussions of the commenda (qirad, mudarabah) in Islamic juristic texts by the eighth and ninth centuries. It predated the first use of premium insurance. The commenda first appeared in Italy, in Venice, Pisa and Genoa in the eleventh and twelfth centuries.44 Interestingly, the commenda did not exist in the Roman Mediterranean. Was the commenda well suited to an environment of prevalent uncertainties? In theory, in commenda contracts, the risks are split between the investing party and the travelling party. The investing party risked his financial investment, and the travelling party risked his body and soul, the labour he invested in the project, and his share in the expected profits. The loss at sea was a major risk factor. The investments could vary and so could the share in the profits or losses. The parties could negotiate, in advance, these inputs and outputs based on the expected risk. Risk assessment was influenced by the destination, the length of the venture, the expectations for market prices and profits, and more. Knight’s framework would suggest that an environment of uncertainty cannot give rise to commenda contracts because, in such an environment, risks could not be priced and the splitting of profits and losses could not be negotiated and agreed upon. The shares in the investment and in the payoffs could be viewed as a mode of pricing the risks given the environment. Thus, it could not take place in an environment uncertainty but only of risks. The Scott layer of the theory may lead to a different postulation. It can explain why the commenda nevertheless originated in an environment of high uncertainties that could not give rise to insurance. The gist of the commenda is that it is a best-effort contract, that the traveller has a sort of fiduciary duty to act to the benefit of the investor, to do business as

43 Harris, Going the Distance, 130–170. For the historiography of the commenda, see F. Trivellato, ‘Renaissance Florence and the Origins of Capitalism: A Business History Perspective’, Business History Review, 94/1 (2020): 229–252. 44 L. Favali, Qirad Islamico: Commenda Medievale e Strategie Culturali Dell’Occidente (Turin 2004); G. Mignone, Un Contratto Per i Mercanti del Mediterraneo: L’evoluzione del Rapporto Partecipativo (Naples 2005). For a possible Byzantine antecedent of the commenda see the contribution of Daphne Penna in this volume.

56

R. HARRIS

though it was solely to his benefit. The commenda can be viewed as a formal contract that contains a general standard, whose detailed application was decided ex-post in the event of a dispute, rather than ex-ante specified contingent rules. Unlike in insurance contracts, the specification is done ex-post by the tribunals or courts when settling disputes. In an environment of a less developed legal system, in which third party dispute resolution by professional judges is unavailable, the commenda can be viewed as a collaborative contract that in Scott’s terms braids informal, as well as formal, components. The commenda contract generates information by requiring the travelling agent to deliver itinerary, bills of ladings and accounts of his travels, transactions and profits. Based on these, the investing party verifies whether the traveller shirked or cheated according to prevailing informal norms. The investing party could, in case of a breach, impose a reputational sanction. Different layers of the theoretical framework used here lead to different, if not contradictory, analysis and conclusions for the development of the commenda. One strand views an environment of risks as a precondition for the commenda. The other sees the commenda as able to function in an environment of uncertainties. The under-determinacy of the theory, with respect to the commenda, may result from the fact that dealing with risks is not its main purpose. The commenda, unlike insurance, was not intended to deal exclusively with risks. It was also, even primarily, an employment or agency contract. The Business Corporation The joint-stock business corporation originated only as late as the sixth century. It was, among other things, a response to an increase in uncertainty. This increase did not result from the deterioration in the circulation of information about probabilities in a given environment. The commercial revolution converted uncertainties into risks in the context of the Mediterranean trade. This is the story that explains the emergence of marine insurance. But, this was not the story that gave rise to the business corporation. The relevant development in the sixteenth century was the entrance of Europeans into new trade environments in the Atlantic and around the Cape of Good Hope into the Indian Ocean. One could revert to the familiar contractual solution, by allocating risks contractually to outsiders. This could be done by way of premium insurance (already regularly used in the Mediterranean), by way of sea loans

GENERAL AVERAGE AND ALL THE REST …

57

in which the lender bore the sea risk, or even by way of regular loans in which the lender did not bear the sea risk but bore the risk of insolvency.45 But, all of these required attributing probabilities in order to price transferred risks. The new environment was unfamiliar and adventurous. This was the kind of increase in uncertainty due to innovative business activities along the lines analysed by Scott. Oceanic trade, particularly Asian trade, was thinner and involved higher uncertainties than the well-established Mediterranean trade. Insurance was unavailable for the long Asian voyages that lasted for 2–3 years and often ended in loss.46 Because of the lack of prior experience with these long voyages in unfamiliar waters and trade, probabilities of loss could not be estimated, insurance premium could not be priced, and insurance cloud not be offered. The solution was to face the uncertainties by pooling many of them together into a single enterprise. That is, rather than investing in a single ship or a single venture of a few ships sailing together in the same season to the same destination port, investing in an enterprise that operated numerous ships over several years to a variety of ports. The idea of pooling risks together was not altogether new. What was new was the organizational platform used. The innovative organizational solution was the joint-stock business corporation.47 The basic theoretical basis for the risk mitigation element of the business corporation can be found in Knight’s theory. He says: “it is simply a matter of an elementary development of business organization to combine a sufficient number of cases to reduce the uncertainty to any desired limits”. And adds: “The possibility of thus reducing uncertainty by transforming it into a measurable risk through grouping constitutes a strong incentive to extend the scale of operations of a business establishment”.48 45 The early business corporations did not rely on the limited liability, owner shielding, typical features of the modern business corporation; on this R. Harris, ‘A New Understanding of the History of Limited Liability: An Invitation for Theoretical Reframing’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 16/5 (2020): 643–664. 46 In the north Atlantic travel times were shorter, voyages more frequent, information denser, the environment turned sooner into one of known risks and insurance became available, in ports like Antwerp, Amsterdam and London, turning into a structured underwriters’ marketplace in the form of the Lloyds. See C. Kingston, ‘Governance and Institutional Change in Marine Insurance, 1350-1850’, European Review of Economic History, 18/1 (2014): 1–18. 47 Harris, Going the Distance, 251–275. 48 Knight, Risk, 128.

58

R. HARRIS

It is interesting to note that, in this sense, Knight is also an institutionalist. For him, the path from uncertainty to risk does not only go through gathering information and calculating probabilities (or increasing control over future probabilities), but also through organizational tools that are not that distinct from North’s. In our case, the consolidation of numerous ventures, voyages, events and decisions alleviated the need to set the probability for the loss of each ship in each segment of a voyage. The consolidation of several voyages having several ships each made “the law of large numbers” applicable to the first business corporations, the English East India Company [EIC] and Dutch East India Company [VOC]. They handled uncertainties by pooling them together through the longevity offered by the legal personality and the scale offered by joint-stock equity investment. The EIC and VOC did not have to convert these maritime and trade uncertainties into insurable risks in order to enter oceanic trade with Asia.49 As the seventeenth century progressed, information was gathered, recorded and processed in the headquarters of these business corporations. The uncertainties were converted into risks, the risks were reduced, insurance became available, and the pooling together of uncertainties was not essential anymore.50 By the eighteenth century, the EIC and VOC became rent-seeking monopolies and territorial rulers. Running the trade by smaller merchant houses backed by insurers like the Lloyds of London became potentially more efficient. A political struggle began between the monopolies and new entrants.

Conclusion Traditional historical analysis is good at reconstructing the pattern of development of maritime trade institutions based on research that looks for the trace of records that were preserved in archives. It is not good at explaining the timing of origins and path of evolution of these institutions. Historians assume, often implicitly, that institutions were invented once societies realized that they are beneficial and learned how to design 49 Harris, Going the Distance, 275–231; G. Dari-Mattiacci, O. Gelderblom, J. Jonker, and E. C. Perotti, ‘The Emergence of the Corporate Form’, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 33/2 (2017): 193–236. 50 For the interplay between General Average, insurance and the VOC in Amsterdam, see Sabine Go in this volume.

GENERAL AVERAGE AND ALL THE REST …

59

them. As there are usually no historical records that explain the origins and paths, historians cannot do more than this. The Knight-North-Scott framework takes us a long way forward in understanding the history of risk mitigation trade institutions. Knight calls attention to the role of information in the shift from uncertainty to risk and the development of insurance. North calls our attention to the role of information in reducing transaction costs and enhancing growth. Scott reminds us that institutions involve contractual drafting and that contracts can deal with information shortage and information generation. By doing this, we realize that the challenge was not to discover how beneficial are insurance and other risk mitigation institutions. The focus, instead, should be on how to solve the informational challenges with respect to risk assessment and pricing and contractual drafting in which without insurance cannot come to life. The theoretical framework calls for the comparison of different riskmitigating institutions, in terms of their ability to function in environments of higher and lower uncertainty. Organizing business under uncertainty is different than under risk. The early start and long history of General Average can be explained by the fact that it can function well under uncertainty, even high uncertainty. Once in place, General Average further evolved through contractual refinements of the details of its application. One set of research issues relates to change over time. The details of this evolution can be worked out through a careful historical investigation that is coupled with contract theory. Information is not only exogenously given but also endogenously generated by institutions. Contracts can be designed so that they will generate the information needed for these contracts to function. The commenda contract is an excellent example of a contract that includes information generation elements. It can function in an environment of uncertainty because it does not rely only on the environment (say the state or the thickness of the trade network) for information but also generates information on the level of the contractual relations. Another contract theory insight distinguishes between frontend contractual drafting and backend dispute resolution over the contract. The less information is available in advance, the costlier it is to write down a detailed contract that covers the expectations of the principal from the agent in many contingencies and the more cost-efficient it is to write a longer-term relational contract that requires best effort. The commenda

60

R. HARRIS

is an example of a contractual design that implements this insight in a manner that saves on transaction costs. Yet, another insight from Scott’s theoretical framework is that the lower the uncertainty, the more feasible it is to draft a complete contingent (if–then) contract. The higher the uncertainty, the more feasible it is to draft contracts that cover a single contingency. This insight fits the fact that sea loan contracts developed long before insurance contracts. Risk can be mitigated in different ways: allocation, spreading or pooling. We are only beginning to understand under which legal and organizational frameworks and maritime risk environments were risk spread, as opposed to pooled or allocated. The shift from uncertainty to risk is not well explained by economic theory. The history of organizational solutions for mitigation of maritime uncertainties and risks, from General Average and sea loan to insurance and the business corporation, cannot only benefit from but also contribute to the theory of institutional development more generally.

Open Access This chapter is licensed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/ by/4.0/), which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this chapter are included in the chapter’s Creative Commons license, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the chapter’s Creative Commons license and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder.

Risky Narratives: Framing General Average into Risk-Management Strategies (Thirteenth–Sixteenth Centuries) Giovanni Ceccarelli

Over the last few years, historians have extensively investigated on the role of risk in the history of finance, and the development of riskmanagement techniques in the United States since the late nineteenth century. Well-established approaches that considered such innovations

The research for this essay was conducted thanks to funding from the European Research Council (ERC) under the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research and Innovation Programme ERC Grant agreement No. 724544: AveTransRisk—Average—Transaction Costs and Risk Management During the First Globalization (Sixteenth-Eighteenth Centuries). Preliminary versions of this essay were presented at the 3rd Biennial Richard Robinson Workshop on Business History (Portland State University) and at the International Conference on Risk and the Insurance Business in History (Universidad Internacional de Andalucía). The author is grateful to all those who provided their observations in these occasions. The author would also like to thank Maria Fusaro, Sabine Go and Andrea Addobbati for their helpful comments on earlier versions of this essay. G. Ceccarelli (B) University of Parma, Parma, Italy e-mail: [email protected]

© The Author(s) 2023 M. Fusaro et al. (eds.), General Average and Risk Management in Medieval and Early Modern Maritime Business, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-04118-1_3

61

62

G. CECCARELLI

beneficial in themselves have been questioned, by pointing out the consequences of the pervasive spread of financial tools designed to mitigate risks. It appears, rather, that a socially uneven distribution of risk went along with the financial efficiency brought by these novelties, whose legitimacy rested on narratives identifying individual freedom with the taking of risks.1 This essay explores the possibility that something similar might have occurred in early modern Europe, when marine insurance provided an alternative to contracts previously used to mitigate the risks connected to sea trade. It also aims at discussing whether the spread of specialized insurance markets, beginning in the sixteenth century, brought to a substantial shift in the distribution of these types of risks from a restricted trading group to a broader social base. Premium-based marine insurance was crucial in supporting longdistance commerce in the early modern period, since it allowed merchants to carry out business with less capital than the risks of their trade demanded. Initially developed in Italy in the fourteenth century, it later spread to Spain reaching the Atlantic ports of Antwerp, Amsterdam and London during the sixteenth century.2 This timing and geographic origin favoured a mainstream interpretation that ‘romantically’ considered insurance as an iconic expression of late medieval merchant capitalism. In a narrative dominated by inventive financial techniques, and efficient systems of commercial letters, it was described as the new tool actors were in need of to reduce the risks of doing business.3 A major flaw in this interpretation is to take premium insurance as something that appeared ‘out of the blue’, as if previously there were no other instruments to support maritime trade. However, marine insurance developed alongside a set of different and pre-existing mechanisms

1 L. Hyman, Debtor Nation: The History of America in Red Ink (Princeton 2011); J. C. Ott, When Wall Street Met Main Street: The Quest for an Investors’ Democracy (Cambridge, MA 2011); J. Levy, Freaks of Fortune: The Emerging World of Capitalism and Risk in America (Cambridge MA 2012). For a theoretical framework see J. Beckert, Imagined Futures: Fictional Expectations and Capitalist Dynamics (Cambridge, MA 2016). 2 F. Edler de Roover, ‘Early Examples of Marine Insurance’, The Journal of Economic History, 5 (1945): 172–200. 3 Two typical examples of this approach are: L. A. Boiteux, La fortune de mer: le besoin de securité et les debuts de l’assurance maritime (Paris 1968); F. Melis, Origini e sviluppi delle assicurazioni in Italia (secoli XIV–XVI), Volume 1: Le fonti (Rome 1975).

RISKY NARRATIVES: FRAMING GENERAL AVERAGE …

63

to mitigate risks.4 Yet, scholars preferred to focus on what seemed to be the ‘modern’ solution to the problem, given that with this contract ‘sea risks’ became the specific object of the agreement.5 In carrying out everyday business insurance was not the only existing option. Merchants and ship-owners willing to manage the risks of navigation could turn to a broad array of alternatives, including sea loan, Averages, sea exchange and various types of partnerships.6 In addition to contracts and business agreements, other strategies could be used, like employing armed vessels, dividing the cargo among multiple carriers and sailing in convoy. Considering the resilience proven by several of these possible responses to sea risks—for example, sea loans/bottomry and General Average—the traditional historical reconstruction in which backward techniques are replaced by more developed ones appears oversimplified. A good way to look at their interplay is, on the contrary, to think about an ecosystem where competition goes along with coexistence and cooperation, like a forest made of trees and bushes of different species each adapting to their ecological niche.7 Clearly, these responses to navigation risks are not equivalent. A first divide is between strategies aiming at preventing the probability of a mishap, and those designed to minimize the consequences of it. Sailing in convoy or shipping goods on armed vessels is—adopting a terminology coming from decision theory—a form of self-protection to prevent a loss, not to reduce its negative effects. For example, well into the eighteenth century, coral fishers in Southern Italy tackled the threats coming from Barbary pirates by recruiting armed protection.8 Quite the opposite is what occurs with General Average, sea loans or insurance. These do 4 Some insights on these issues in are in Ron Harris essay in this volume. 5 For a recent summary, see L. Piccinno, ‘Genoa, 1340–1620: Early Development of

Marine Insurance’, in A. B. Leonard ed., Marine Insurance: Origins and Institutions, 1300–1850 (Basingstoke 2015). 6 R. S. Lopez and I. W. Raymond, Medieval Trade in the Mediterranean World: Illustrative Documents Translated with Introductions and Notes (London 1955), 162–211; Melis, Origini e sviluppi delle assicurazioni, 12–13, 56–57, 87, 93. 7 The comparison of market institutions and ecosystem has been widely adopted by business historians, see L. Hannah, ‘Marshall’s “Trees” and the Global “Forest”: Were “Giant Redwoods” Different?’, in N. R. Lamoreaux, D. M. G. Raff, P. Temin eds., Learning by Doing in Markets, Firms, and Countries (Chicago 1999), 253–293. 8 V. Ferrandino, Il Monte pio dei marinai di Torre del Greco. Tre secoli di attività al servizio dei corallari (secc. XVII-XX) (Milan 2008), 49.

64

G. CECCARELLI

nothing to diminish the probability of an accident, whereas they have a great role in minimizing its economic consequences.9 They way in which they do it is, however, different. Here a second distinction needs to be stressed, the one between risk-spreading and risk-shifting. For example, General Average redistributed damages and expenses that could occur to ships and cargoes by allocating them to all interested parties, according to a principle of joint liability. General Average essentially was a risk-spreading technique, a mutual form of protection designed for actors who were routinely engaged in sea trade, including merchants, ship-owners and shipmasters. By contrast, in premium insurance, the risk is not shared but shifted (or hedged) from one party to another. Protection is granted by individual underwriters, each responsible just for the coverage they agreed to subscribe for. Limited liability is the tool that allows this to go beyond a restricted circle of actors, replacing risk-sharing with risk-shifting.10 Nevertheless, when adapting modern classifications to the framework of the period from the thirteenth to the sixteenth century, distinctions are not so clear-cut; if one considers other tools that could be adopted as a response to sea risks, sharing and shifting were often combined. Clear examples are bottomry and sea exchange, where loan and insurance are mingled together.11 Moreover, in day-to-day business actors unlikely chose just one option but tended to adopt a multifaceted strategy. For instance, one could use insurance in combination with armed vessels, spending less money for premium and more for freight, since in this case insurance costs halved.12 Likewise, an underwriter could enter into the contract not in a personal capacity but on behalf of a firm, sharing thus 9 I. Ehrlich and G. S. Becker, ‘Market Insurance, Self-Insurance, and Self-Protection’,

The Journal of Political Economy, 80/4 (1972): 623–648. 10 N. A. Doherty, ‘Some Fundamental Theorems of Risk Management’, The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 42/3 (1975): 447–460; R. Holzmann and S. Jørgensen, ‘Social Risk Management: A New Conceptual Framework for Social Protection, and Beyond’, International Tax and Public Finance, 8/4 (2001): 529–556, esp. 541–542. 11 R. de Roover, ‘The Organization of Trade’, in M. M. Postan ed., The Cambridge Economic History of Europe, vol. 3: Economic Organization and Policies in the Middle Ages (Cambridge 1965), 42–118, 53–57; see also Andrea Zanini’s contribution in this volume. 12 G. Ceccarelli, ‘The Price for Risk-Taking: Marine Insurance and Probability Calculus in the Late Middle Ages’, Journ@l électronique d’Histoire des Probabilités et de la Statistique/Electronic Journ@l for History of Probability and Statistics, 3/1 (2007): 6–7, 16. http://eudml.org/doc/130865 (last accessed 29 December 2021).

RISKY NARRATIVES: FRAMING GENERAL AVERAGE …

65

the risk with multiple partners.13 Even the choice of using saints and other religious terms to name a ship is revealing of a manifold approach. Recent scholarship has provided further complexity to this framework. By putting the emphasis on transaction costs and stressing the role of institutions in managing this business, it appears that contract innovation is only one side of the story. Moving from some influential insights by Douglass North and Avner Greif, the focus has thus shifted from financial novelties to insurance governance.14 This allowed scholars to develop a new narrative in which premium insurance, notwithstanding its innovative potential, for a long time continued to mimic previous forms of solidarity adopted by those involved in maritime trade. For a long time, insurance was an activity parallel to commerce, a risk-spreading technique envisaged to share rather than transfer risk. Merchants acted alternatively as underwriters and insurance buyers, specialization was very limited, and no complex organization emerged. Given this prevailing mutualism, customary mechanisms of contract enforcement were at work; well suited for small groups, they increased the level of confidence reducing in turn the cost of transacting. Insurance markets were efficient, since they functioned as a ‘club’ providing services a small number of ‘members’.15 Empirical evidence of this framework is widespread, but we can briefly turn to a specific example to have a case in point. During the Renaissance, Florence was a major insurance market, yet the number of those operating in it was surprisingly small. If in the late fourteenth century it involved no more than two hundred individuals, at the beginning of the sixteenth century, the number rose to four or five hundred. In a city of 40/50,000 inhabitants, just a narrow circle—roughly corresponding to 1% of the population—was involved in insurance, whereas the remaining 99% had nothing to do with it. Actors not only were few, but also tended to be extremely similar, fundamentally matching to a single profile. They were

13 G. Ceccarelli, Risky Markets: Insurance in Renaissance Florence (Leiden 2020), 178–

180. 14 D. C. North, Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance (Cambridge 1990), in particular 126–127; A. Greif, ‘On the Interrelations and Economic Implications of Economic, Social, Political and Normative Factors: Reflections from two Late Medieval Societies’, Working paper, Stanford University, 1997, in particular 33. 15 A. B. Leonard, ‘Introduction: The Nature and Study of Marine Insurance’, in A. B. Leonard ed., Marine Insurance.

66

G. CECCARELLI

male Florentine citizens, coming from families involved in long-distance trade and banking, members of the wealthiest households, enjoying a highly visible political status.16 Two informal mechanisms—exchange of roles and barriers to entry—were also at work, reinforcing this selection process. Underwriters and insurance buyers regularly exchanged their role on the market. Only a fraction of coverage from marine risks, corresponding to just about 6% of the total insured value, was offered to subjects who did not also act as insurers (see Table 1‚ at p. 88). If a merchant wanted to be relieved from the risks of sea trade, the same merchant had to be willing to run them on behalf of someone else. A similar outcome resulted from high barriers to entry, customarily applied to those willing to underwrite a contract. The minimum amount insurers were expected to cover, excluding some few exceptional cases, roughly corresponded to the yearly wage of the manager of a medium-sized commercial firm (see Table 2‚ at p. 88).17 The Florentine example shows that the spread of premium insurance did not imply per se that club-like markets were rapidly abandoned. What new studies suggest is that the transition was slower than previously thought, beginning only when contract innovation resonated with institutions supportive of impersonal transactions. External pressures, essentially ascribable to the rise of the Atlantic economy and the increasing demand for insurance, gradually altered this static framework by broadening the number of subjects who are engaged in the transactions.18 It is only during the sixteenth century, with a timing that differs from one market

16 R. Goldthwaite, The Economy of Renaissance Florence (Baltimore 2009), in particular 98–103; A. Addobbati, ‘Italy 1500–1800: Cooperation and Competition’, in Leonard ed., Marine Insurance, 47–77. 17 Exchange of roles and barriers to entry are common in most other insurance markets. See, for example, R. Doehaerd, ‘Chiffres d’assurance à Gênes en 1427–1428’, Revue belge de Philologie et d’Histoire, 27 (1949): 736–756; M. del Treppo, ‘Assicurazioni e commercio internazionale a Barcellona 1428–1429’, Rivista storica italiana, 69 (1957): 508–541. 18 C. Kingston, ‘Marine Insurance in Britain and America, 1720–1844: A Comparative

Institutional Analysis’, The Journal of Economic History, 67/2 (2007): 379–409; and the following essays, all in Leonard ed., Marine Insurance: S. Go, ‘Amsterdam 1585–1790: Emergence, Dominance, and Decline’, 107–129; A. Bogatyreva, ‘England 1660–1720: Corporate or Private?’, 179–203; G. Chet, ‘Britain and America 1650–1850: Harmonising Government and Commerce’, 249–268.

RISKY NARRATIVES: FRAMING GENERAL AVERAGE …

67

to another, that risk-shifting starts working alongside risk-spreading. Individuals previously excluded then entered the business; these newcomers could be foreigners arriving on the market like it happened in Genoa or Livorno, or locals taking over commerce until then carried out by alien merchants, as in the case of Antwerp or London.19 An indirect clue of their presence comes from the spread of legal interventions aiming (at least in part) at building an infrastructure capable of safeguarding these outsiders. Examples can be found in Florence (1524), Burgos (1538), Ragusa (present-day Dubrovnik) (1568), Antwerp (1563, 1570), Bilbao (1568), Amsterdam (1598) and London (1601). Whereas until then normative interventions always occurred in the broader framework of maritime regulation, now laws specifically designed for marine insurance become the standard. Typically, these would include: a procedure regulating insurance claims, a standard contract that needed to be followed, a specialized court having jurisdiction on insurance litigations and mandatory registration of contracts.20 By designing an institutional infrastructure suited to handle markets larger in scale, and more stratified in their structure, the passage from risk-spreading to risk-shifting was possible, and profit seeking could slowly work its way over protection

19 L. Piccinno, ‘Genoa, 1340–1620: Early Development of Marine Insurance’, 25– 45, 42–43; Addobbati, ‘Italy 1500–1800: Cooperation and Competition’, 63; D. De ruysscher, ‘Antwerp 1490–1590: Insurance and Speculation’, 79–105; G. Rossi, ‘England 1523–1601: The Beginnings of Marine Insurance’, 131–148; all in Leonard ed., Marine Insurance. 20 V. Barbour, ‘Marine Risks and Insurance in Seventeenth Century’, Journal of Economic and Business History, 1 (1928–29): 561–596, 572–573; L. A. Boiteux, L’assurance maritime à Paris sous le règne de Louis XIV (Paris 1945), 13; Boiteux, La fortune de mer, 110–123, 142; G. S. Pene Vidari, ‘Il contratto d’assicurazione nell’età moderna’, in L’assicurazione in Italia fino all’Unità (Milan 1975), 232–234, 271–285, 295; F. C. Spooner, Risk at Sea: Amsterdam Insurance and Maritime Europe, 1776–1780 (Cambridge 1983), 18; A. Tenenti and B. Tenenti, Il prezzo del rischio: l’assicurazione mediterranea vista da Ragusa (1563–1591) (Rome 1985), 92–97, 286; H. Casado Alonso, ‘Los seguros maritimos de Burgos. Observatorio del comercio internacional portugués en el siglo XVI’, Historia. Revista de Facultade de Letras do Porto, s. 3, 4 (2003): 213–242, 215–216; G. Rossi, Insurance in Elizabethan England: The London Code (Cambridge 2016), 75–88; H. Casado Alonso, El seguro maritimo en Castilla en los siglos XV y XVI (Valladolid 2021), 45–47.

68

G. CECCARELLI

seeking. In sum, contract and governance innovation opened transacting to competition, raising the overall performance of the insurance industry.21 An interpretation as such, though largely convincing, can be further expanded to encompass a broader set of circumstances under which previous forms of risk mitigation have been sided by new ones. For example, should we consider premium insurance and markets specialized in this type of transactions as socially neutral? Likewise, have some groups benefited from the spreading of these innovations to the disadvantage of others? As studies on nineteenth- and twentieth-century capitalism stress, larger attention should be given to the relation between risk allocation and financial innovation, as well as to the cultural background in which the latter emerges. Empirical investigations suggest that in the early modern insurance business a limited group of players guided the transactions, whereas a large share of those who took sea risks on behalf of affluent merchants were ‘followers’, lacking of information and adapting to decisions made by someone else.22 If one focuses on the way coverage was provided in day-to-day operations, the consequences of contract innovation are easier to detect. Before insurance joint-stock companies developed in the eighteenth century, the most commonly used technique was co-insurance. Derived from other areas of maritime economy, in which pooling was routinely used, it allowed to spread the risks of sea trade among a broad number of actors. Descriptions of how co-insurance was carried out reveal how in everyday business two actors were crucial: the specialized broker and the ‘leading insurer’.Those wanting to be insured, after having established the main features of the contract, needed to find people interested in underwriting it. A broker was in charge of this task, making insurers sign the contract,

21 S. Go, Marine Insurance in the Netherlands 1600–1870, a Comparative Institutional Approach (Amsterdam 2009); C. Kingston, ‘Governance and Institutional Change in Marine Insurance, 1350–1850’, European Review of Economic History, 18/1 (2014): 1–18. 22 C. Kingston, ‘Intermediación y confianza’, Ekonomiaz, 77/2 (2011): 64–85; Ceccarelli, Risky Markets, Chapter 11.

RISKY NARRATIVES: FRAMING GENERAL AVERAGE …

69

one after another. Being each liable only for the amount they accepted to cover, it was necessary to pool together large numbers of underwriters.23 Data show how the number of co-insurers has increased over time; in the late sixteenth century, it is possible to find single contracts in which coverage is divided among more than 150 underwriters.24 This system had, however, the flaw of requiring long negotiations between the insurance buyer and each insurer. Intermediaries were able to circumscribe this problem by adopting a specific marketing strategy; they limited the negotiations to one single individual considered experienced by the others. Having seen the signature of this ‘leader’, they would accept more easily the terms envisaged in the contract and quickly underwrote it at the same premium.25 Differences concerning scale and continuity of those engaged in transacting are visible in almost all early modern markets, but we can rely once more on sixteenth-century Florence for a detailed example. For sake of simplicity, let us consider only the supply side of the market. At one end of the spectrum, one finds occasional actors who carry out their business for few months and underwrite a total of 1–5 contracts at most, though numerically large—about 65% of the total—this group is not relevant in terms of insured values, accounting roughly for 10% of the total. At the opposite end of the spectrum, we find recurrent insurers, underwriting with a frequency of two or more contracts per week without significant interruptions over a rather long period of time (two, three years). Although in terms of insured values this group counts for almost 50% of the total, it is numerically very narrow, coinciding roughly with less than 10% of the total. In between these two opposites typologies, there are at

23 K. Nehlsen-von Stryk, L’assicurazione marittima a Venezia nel XV secolo (Rome 1988), 84; G. Ceccarelli, ‘Courtiers et assurances maritimes: les raisons d’une liaison profonde (XIVe -XVIe siècles)’, in M. Scherman, A. Wegener Sleeswijk, V. Demont eds., Le pouvoir des courtiers. Intermédiation marchande et évolution des pratiques commerciales, XIV e -XVIII e siècles (Paris 2018), 75–86. 24 For example, in late sixteenth century Ragusa, see Tenenti and Tenenti, Il prezzo del rischio, 181–183. 25 A clear example comes from the testimony given by the London broker John Julius

Angerstein during a House of Commons enquiry in 1810, Select Committee of the House of Commons … on Marine Insurance (London: W. Hughes 1810), 121: “If I have a cross risk to make, if it is from America, I go to a box where there are Americans to give me information; and so it is from the Baltic or any other part […] they are the people who can begin the policy for me better than the others, and I can by that means get it done”.

70

G. CECCARELLI

least two other classes of investors, making the picture even more complex (see Tables 3 and 4‚ at p. 89). This multilayered framework tended to replicate a fundamental mismatch among those who bought insurance and those who sold it, since only a fraction of the underwriters was interested in being insured: in sixteenth-century Florence, for example, this ratio was of about one in five (see Table 1‚ at p. 88). To match the demand coming from insurance buyers, a flexible participation of people only irregularly engaged in the transactions was therefore necessary. Since these latter were not demanding protection from marine risks, other ways to drive them in the business had to be at work. Specialized brokers and leading insurers had this role, granting this complex ensemble of actors the coordination required to properly function. Intermediation was a distinctive trait of insurance since its beginning in fourteenth-century Mediterranean ports, yet this quickly underwent a process of selection ending up in the hand of few professionals. This was furthermore favoured by regulations often limiting the number of brokers through a licence system. Whether it was Genoa or Venice, Antwerp or Ragusa, Burgos or Florence, by the late sixteenth century the largest share of the transactions was in control of an extremely narrow number of intermediaries, normally just two or three in each location.26 A further push to concentration came from leading insurers. Mentions to this group of experts can easily be found in seventeenth- and eighteenth-century sources, revealing that in Amsterdam and London, their reputation was crucial in convincing many occasional underwriters to engage in a business they knew little about.27 Once more, quantitative evidence coming from sixteenth-century Florence is highly illustrative, showing a polarized situation. On the one side, a small group, made of less than 40 underwriters, acted in this role in more than 70% of the total contracts; on the other, almost 70% of those who subscribed a contract

26 Concerning Genoa, see G. Giacchero, Storia delle assicurazioni marittime. L’esperienza genovese dal Medioevo all’età contemporanea (Genoa 1984), 117–136; and Melis, Origini e sviluppi delle assicurazioni, 156; on Venice see “Table 2” in Nehlsen-von Stryk, L’assicurazione marittima a Venezia, 502–524; on Florence: C. L. Daveggia, ‘L’intermediazione assicurativa nel Medioevo’, Assicurazioni, 52 (1985): 326–372. 27 For references concerning the Amsterdam and London insurance markets, see Boiteux, L’assurance maritime à Paris, 15; Spooner, Risk at Sea, 19 and 25; A. H. John, ‘The London Assurance Company and Marine Insurance Market of the Eighteenth Century’, Economica, n. s., 25 (1958): 126–141, 127.

RISKY NARRATIVES: FRAMING GENERAL AVERAGE …

71

never acted as ‘leading insurer’ (Table 5‚ at p. 90). This uneven distribution is further confirmed if one considers the restricted circle of the top 1%, which is made of just five underwriters, who held this position in almost one third of the overall transactions (Table 6‚ at p. 91). Looking at their identities, one finds that these individuals were not at all ordinary people, essentially coinciding with those in charge of managing the most affluent Florentine merchant-firms. For these firms insurance coverage was vital, as their fortunes were largely dependent from long-distance maritime trade. Specialized brokers and leading insurers were in the right position to appear reliable to most of the ordinary underwriters, who could follow their lead in subscribing a contract. Likewise, they probably had the positive effect of reducing information costs and risk aversion for actors who were not routinely operating in the market. Conversely, intermediaries and leading insurers reveal that the number of those really having bargaining power was extremely narrow, and that many ended up being just ‘followers’ of decisions taken by someone else. Their combined action, if considered under this light, clearly had an impact on risk allocation, perpetuating a divide between insiders and outsiders.28 However, this passage likely was not just the result of market forces and institutional infrastructure; part of the explanation can also refer to the framework in which it takes place. Marine insurance did not emerge in a vacuum, but intersected a dense rhetoric about risk-taking and its social and economic meaning. To explore this narrative, one can rely on sources coming from business culture, as well as from moral theology. Though apparently distant, these realms shared a common interest for sea trade and the risks deriving from it. For example, several arguments supportive of insurance are ascribable to discussions carried out by canon lawyers and theologians in the light of religious and legal principles. Among these: that buying and selling risks does not undermine God’s absolute power; that a distinctive trait of business rests on the individual assumption of risk; that insurance is socially useful. Commerce and navigation had little to do in setting the premises of this narrative, the breakthrough came from a seemingly peripheral realm, namely that of ‘wagering’. Risk forecasting emerged as a viable 28 G. Ceccarelli, ‘Coping with Unknown Risks in Renaissance Florence: Insurers, Friars and Abacus Teachers’, in C. Zwierlein ed., The Dark Side of Knowledge: Histories of Ignorance, 1400 to 1800 (Leiden 2016), 115–138.

72

G. CECCARELLI

option discussing someone rolling a dice or playing head or tails. Already by the late thirteenth century, in discussions about gambling, theologians had introduced the idea that risk could be evaluated and traded for money. A formal analysis of wagering allowed to state that property could be transferred on condition, without undermining God’s prerogatives. Gambling served as a model that was later expanded to include several types of agreements and risk-management tools into a specific class—that of the aleatory contract—which were deemed lawful. Concerns about the reasons behind individuals making bets or rolling dices did remain, as well as the link with superstition, drunkenness and other sinful activities. But the point made was that ‘moral’ issues had no impact on the ‘legal’ nature of these agreements, which was considered lawful by a large share of scholastic thinkers.29 Having connected the forecasting of future events to economic value, theologians went in search of a suitable criterion to assess it, thus developing the notion of par periculi causa (equal exposition to risk). This is a further step in a process representing risk as an object that can be bought and sold for a given price.30 Not surprisingly, scholastic thinkers will transfer this conception from wagering to insurance as soon as the latter started to spread. Marine risk could be depicted as an object that could be actively dealt with, something actors may forecast in economic terms and express through a number, a percentage. This can clearly be seen in arguments developed to remove any suspect of usury from insurance.31 A first set of thinkers, mainly Dominican friars that followed a thesis developed by Thomas Aquinas, 29 See, for example, Petrus Johannis Olivi, Tractatus de contractibus, in Pierre de Jean Olivi, Traité de contrats, ed. S. Piron (Paris 2012), 258–260 (p. III, q. 1); Alexander Lombardus (de Alexandria), Tractatus de usuris, in A. M. Hamelin ed., Un traité de morale économique au XIVe siècle. Le Tractatus de usuris de maître Alexandre d’Alexandrie (Louvain 1962), 204–205. See also G. Ceccarelli, ‘Gambling and Economic Thought in the Late Middle Ages’, Ludica, annali di storia e civiltà del gioco, 12 (2006): 54–63; C.O. Doron, ‘The Experience of Risk: Genealogy and Transformations’, in A. Burgess, A. Alemanni, J. O. Zinn eds., Routledge Handbook of Risk Studies (London 2016), 17–26. 30 Petrus de Trabibus, Quaestiones de quodlibeta (Qd. I, q. 40 “Utrum lucrum acquisito in ludo alearum teneatur ipse vincens perdenti sive alii restituere”), Florence, Biblioteca Nazionale, ms. Conventi Soppressi D.6.359, fol. 112va; Baldus de Ubaldis, In quartum et quintum Codicis libros commentaria (Venice: Iuntas 1599), fols. 16v–17r (lib. 4, rub., §. 4). 31 G. Ceccarelli, ‘Risky Business. Theological and Canonical Thought on Insurance from the Thirteenth to the Seventeenth Century’, The Journal of Medieval and Early Modern Studies, 31 (2001): 602–652.

RISKY NARRATIVES: FRAMING GENERAL AVERAGE …

73

argued that risk assumption has different legal meanings depending on the contract considered. This allowed to interpret insurance in terms of a lease contract, through which risks are transferred, until the merchandise safely arrives to destination, to a third party that lawfully deserves a payment, namely the premium.32 A more complex approach was supported by Franciscan theologians, that rested essentially on the idea that risk, when suffered by a businessman, was substantially different from risks undertaken by other persons. For many friars, including Peter Olivi, Monaldus of Capodistria, Francesc Eixemenis and Francesco of Empoli, maritime trade was the perfect example of commercial activity whose high risk justified profits. In their view, investments in this type of businesses have a potential value that merchants are able to estimate in advance. This way of reasoning allowed them to support premium insurance and also favoured a vision in which ‘navigation’ and ‘investment risk’ practically overlapped. Bernardino of Siena and Giovanni of Prato solved the problem by integrating the Dominican and Franciscans views: like in a lease contract, sea risk can be shifted from one individual to another, but its cost is a matter that specialists experienced in insurance should assess.33 It seems no coincidence that, strikingly similar arguments emerged within business culture and its multifaceted literary output, ranging from commerce handbooks, to memoirs for the instruction of youths, or more 32 Bartholomaeus de Sancto Concordio, Summa de casibus conscientiae cum supplemento Nicolai de Ausimo (Venice: [s.n.], 1474), fol. 299v (“Usura 1”, §. 24); Petrus Strozzi, Opusculum de Monte, in J. Kirshner, ‘Storm Over the “Monte commune”: Genesis of the Moral Controversy Over the Public Debt of Florence’, Archivum Fratrum Praedicatorum, 53 (1983): 219–276, 268; Laurentius de Rodulphis, De usuris, in Tractatus universi iuris, t. 7, “De contractibus, et aliis illicitis” (Venice: Ziletti 1584), fol. 38r. 33 Petrus Johannis Olivi, Quodlibet I, quaestio XVII , ed. by A. Spicciani, ‘Gli scritti sul capitale e sull’interesse di fra Pietro di Giovanni Olivi. Fonti per la storia del pensiero economico medievale’, Studi Francescani, 73 (1976): 317–321; Monaldus Iustinopolitanus, Summa (Lyon: Petrum Baleti 1516), fol. 285ra-rb; Francesc Eixemenis, Tractat d’usura, ed. J. Hernando I. Delgado (Barcelona 1985), 65–66; Franciscus de Empulis, Questio de monte, ed. L. Armstrong, ‘The Politics of Usury in Trecento Florence: The Questio de monte of Francesco da Empoli’, Mediaeval Studies, 61 (1999): 1–44, 34; Bernardinus Senensis, Quadragesimale de evangelio aeterno, in Bernardinus Senensis, Opera Omnia, 4 vols (Florence 1956), IV: 272–273; Ioannis de Prato, Contractus, Padua, Biblioteca Universitaria, ms. 694, fol. 145r. See also G. Ceccarelli, ‘Quando rischiare è lecito. Il credito finalizzato al commercio marittimo nella riflessione scolastica tardomedievale’, in S. Cavaciocchi ed., Ricchezza del mare. Ricchezza dal mare. Secc. XIII-XVIII (Florence 2006), 1187–1199.

74

G. CECCARELLI

structured treatises on household management. As I shall discuss in the rest of the essay, in the writings of merchants maritime risks experienced a semantic change, exemplifying a cultural climate that developed a set of themes supportive of insurance and risk-shifting. Whereas in the fourteenth century the approach was rather narrow, the later narrative discussed navigation risks and premium insurance side by side, with praiseworthy depictions of individuals taking responsibilities for decisions they make, embodied by the expert merchant capable of thwarting (if not foreseeing) potential mishaps. In the fourteenth century, references to navigation risks, and the business tools to confront them, were confined to technical trade literature (merchant manuals) with a rather narrow meaning. A good example is provided by Francesco Balducci Pegolotti who essentially restates the formulae customarily present in contracts envisaging a clause about the cargo’s safe arrival. His Pratica di mercatura, compiled precisely when and where premium insurance started being used, does not mention it, making, however, several references to bottomry and maritime exchange. Contrary to what occurs in theological writings, mentions to “risk of sea, men, fire, or pirates”, “risk and peril” suffered either by the carrier or the shipper, and commodities “safely discharged on land” did not originate any discussion about the economic value of sea risks. At most, they are considered for their cost function with reference to specific merchandise, bought in one market and transported to another where it will be sold.34 This tendency continues when premium insurance is eventually mentioned in this type of writings. For instance, in the notebook compiled by Ambrogio de Rocchi at the end of the fourteenth century ‘insurance’ appears, along with freight, land transport and duties in the list of items to take into consideration when assessing what he names as the prime cost (primo costo) of doing business between Valencia and Flanders. These lists include at times references to premium rates, which are, however, specified only in the light of the broader category of ancillary

34 P. Spufford, ‘Late Medieval Merchant’s Notebooks: A Project. Their Potential for the History of Banking’, in M. A. Denzel, J.-Cl. Hocquet, H. Wittho eds., Kaufmannsbücher und Handelspraktiken vom Spätmittelalter bis zum beginnenden 20. Jahrhundert /Merchant’s books and mercantile Pratiche from the Late Middle Ages to the Beginning of the Twentieth Century (Stuttgart 2002), 47–62; Francesco Balducci Pegolotti, La Pratica della Mercatura, ed. A. Evans (Cambridge, MA 1936), 45, 75, 196, 242, 321, respectively.

RISKY NARRATIVES: FRAMING GENERAL AVERAGE …

75

costs, being this latter the main point a merchant should assess.35 As it has been suggested by Bruno Dini, these rates reflect nothing more than a customary evaluation of sea risks, in which no distinction among the various factors involved is pointed out. Ambrogio de Rocchi appears to imply that expertise in insurance can be acquired only through practice, not by reading a handbook written by someone else.36 A few decades later, a slight change can be perceived in Giovanni da Uzzano’s Pratica di mercatura. His writing is among the first attempts to assemble a proper instruction manual for merchants, and this could explain the reason why sea risks are no longer mentioned only as contractual formulas or in terms of ancillary costs. Clearly, the wellestablished approach was still prevailing with a number of indications about standard prices required to cover shipments to Tuscan ports from several parts of Europe, including Southampton, Collioure and AiguesMortes.37 The Pratica continued to frame marine insurance as one cost item among others, but also suggested that readers should be aware of some basic elements influencing premium rates. When discussing business between England and Tuscany, these two approaches are combined: “And concerning marine insurance from London to Pisa, it is always between 12 and 15 florins percent, and at times more depending to threats that are known of, whether of pirates, or of others”.38 It was no longer just a matter of providing customary prices, da Uzzano now warned about contingent risks. In doing that, he admits that, along with commercial practice, written texts may also help to train merchants in risk forecasting and decision-making. For instance, in deciding whether to take insurance or not, to save the money of premiums: “there is the risk as well, which

35 B. Dini, Una pratica di mercatura in formazione (1394–1395) (Florence 1980), 138 and 187; Spufford, ‘Late Medieval Merchant’s Notebooks’, 49 and 59. 36 Dini, Una pratica di mercatura, 61. 37 Giovanni di Antonio da Uzzano, La pratica della mercatura, in Gian Francesco

Pagnini del Ventura, Della decima e di varie altre gravezze imposte dal comune di Firenze, 4 vols (Lisbon-Lucca [Florence: Bouchard] 1766) IV: 122, 131, 174; Spufford, ‘Late Medieval Merchant’s Notebooks’, 50, 53, 55. 38 Giovanni di Antonio da Uzzano, La pratica della mercatura, 119: “E per sicurtà di mare da Londra a Pisa sempre è da fior. 12 in 15 per 100 di valuta, e quando più secondo i pericoli che sentono, o di corsali, o d’altro”.

76

G. CECCARELLI

has to be assessed in the calculation, that if you do not buy insurance you can spare it if you safely arrive”.39 Yet, for a further shift to occur, a slightly different literary framework was needed, as well as writers at ease with both humanistic and business culture. Navigation became a typical metaphor adopted in merchants’ autobiographies to depict how one should manage its own life and wealth, in a storytelling in which the skilled shipmaster acquires the role of main character.40 A clear example is offered by the dialogue On the Family by Leon Battista Alberti, a sophisticated version of merchant notebooks and memoirs. The metaphorical use of sea risks likely derived from late medieval medical literature—an area which Alberti touched in his work Momus —where the image of the expert navigator exemplified how a physician should act in making a diagnosis and developing a cure.41 This image is restated to fit in the context of good household management that an idealized pater familias should follow. According to Alberti, protecting one’s own household is like sailing and requires knowing “how to steer according to the wind’s favour […] toward the harbor […], how to strike and furl the sails […] in storms and in such misfortunes”. It is not simply a matter of knowledge, but rather of applying it to a given framework, therefore, “when fortune is tranquil and good-natured, but still more when the times are stormy, the good father never departs from the pilot of reason”. This allows him to confront the risks coming from 39 Giovanni di Antonio da Uzzano, La pratica della mercatura, 159: “[…] e più e’ rischio che si dee stimare quello è ragione, che se non pigli sicurtà, te l’avanzi andando a salvamento, […]”. 40 An in depth analysis of how economic and social historians—including Federigo Melis, Christian Bec, David Herlihy and Christiane Klapisch-Zuber—have used this kind of sources can be found in A. Cicchetti and R. Mordenti eds., I libri di famiglia in Italia, Vol. 1: Filologia e storiografia letteraria (Rome 1985), 29–33. For an overview on this type of literature, see also A. Cicchetti, I libri di famiglia in Italia, Vol. 2: Geografia e storia (Rome 2001). 41 Arnaldus de Villa Nova, Repetitio Super Canonem Vita Brevis, in M. R. McVaugh and L. Garcia Ballester, ‘Therapeutic Method in the Later Middle Ages: Arnau de Vilanova on Medical Contingency’, Caduceus: A Humanities Journal for Medicine and the Health Sciences, 11/2 (1995): 73–86, 76. See also F. Wallis ed., Medieval Medicine, A Reader (Toronto 2010), 211; and M. Solomon, ‘Breaking Non Natural Bread: Alimentary Hygiene and Radical Individualism in Juan de Aviñón’s Medicina sevillana’, in M. Piera ed., Forging Communities: Food and Representation in Medieval and Early Modern Southwestern Europe (Fayetteville 2018), 147–158, 149; L. Boschetto, ‘Democrito e la fisiologia della follia. La parodia della filosofia e della medicina nel “Momus” di Leon Battista Alberti’, Rinascimento, II s., 35 (1995): 3–29.

RISKY NARRATIVES: FRAMING GENERAL AVERAGE …

77

the sea or life. The expert navigator—continues Alberti—“remains alert, foresees from a good distance every mist of envy, every storm cloud of hate, every lightning stroke of enmity”, and “encountering any contrary wind, any shoal and danger […] he acts the part of the experienced expert sailor”. But when it comes to skills, judgements are guided by information individuals can acquire, and choices should also be a matter of recalling “with what winds others have sailed, how they rigged their ships and how they sighted and avoided every danger”.42 The theme that On the Family puts forward is further developed in a number of later writings as a mean to tackle the unstable condition of human life. The image of a calm sea suddenly turning into a storm becomes for instance a recurring one, even Nicolò Machiavelli will exploit it to blame those princes who are not anticipating a political turnaround.43 In the Zibaldone written by Giovanni di Paolo Rucellai, it is stated in three different versions.44 Rucellai was an important Florentine merchant in close relations with Alberti, to whom he commissioned several architectural works.45 His approach to the topic clearly moves from the dialogue On the Family, arguing in favour of an active role, grounded on observation and expertise, when dealing with sea risks, as well as with the contingency of life. “We must not be subjected to anything – Rucellai argues – on the contrary we need to prepare to any event, not only what ordinarily happens but whatever might 42 R. Neu Watkins, The Family in Renaissance Florence: A Translation of I Libri Della Famiglia (Columbia, SC 1969), 36–37; Leon Battista Alberti, I Libri della Famiglia, eds. R. Romano, A. Tenenti, F. Furlan (Bari 1960), 17–18: “Non è solo officio del padre della famiglia, come si dice, riempire il granaio in casa e la culla, ma molto più debbono e’ capi d’una famiglia vegghiare e riguardare per tutto […] sapere con l’aura […] condursi in porto […], ritrarre e ritendere le vele a’ tempi, e nelle tempestati, in simili fortune e naufragii […]; e nella tranquillità e bonaccia della fortuna e molto più ne’ tempestosi tempi, mai partirsi dal timone della ragione e regola del vivere, stare desto, provedere da lungi ogni nebbia d’invidia, ogni nugolo d’odio, ogni fulgore di nimistà in le fronti de’ cittadini, e ogni traverso vento, ogni scoglio e pericolo in che la famiglia in parte alcuna possa percuotere, essere ivi come pratico ed esercitatissimo navichero, avere a mente con che venti gli altri abbiano navigato, e con che vele, e in che modo abbiano scorto e schifato ciascuno pericolo […]”. 43 Nicolò Machiavelli, The Prince, translated by J. B. Atkinson (Indianapolis 1976), 357–358, Chapter 24. 44 Giovanni di Pagolo Rucellai, Zibaldone, G. Battista ed. (Florence 2013), 365, 384,

420. 45 Rucellai, Zibaldone, xxxviii.

78

G. CECCARELLI

occur”.46 Not surprisingly this optimistic approach about the possibility of preventing mishaps (if not even forecasting them) comes from an individual who built his fortunes on maritime trade, proudly recalled on his coat of arms in shape of a sail blowing in the wind.47 In the second half of the fifteenth century, the model of the capable navigator is rooted in business culture to the point that it can be transferred to other specialists of sea risks, like the expert underwriter. Managing risks the proper way, i.e. by shifting them to someone else after a careful economic evaluation, comes to be a typical trait of how merchants self-represented themselves.48 Rucellai’s Zibaldone is a good example of this transition, given that its literary vein is intertwined with the traditional one of business instructions. The connection between risk and expertise is restated from the point of view of a merchant providing guidance to his sons about how markets work—including marine insurance ones. Information flows, accurately recorded to build solid experience, are depicted by Rucellai as the key for a successful business strategy.49 This memoir is written exactly in the same years when another merchant, Benedetto Cotrugli, offers in his handbook the clearest representation of this trend. At the crossroad of the two genres of merchant manuals and treatises on the family, the Book of the Art of Trade combines elements already visible in Giovanni da Uzzano with those of Leon Battista Alberti.50 Sea risks appear to emerge as a

46 Rucellai, Zibaldone, 384: “niuna cosa ci dèe essere subita, anzi dobbiamo tutte le cose provedere, non solamente quello che suole avenire ma tutto ciò che fare si può”. 47 N. Scott Baker, In Fortune’s Theater. Financial Risk and the Future in Renaissance

Italy (Cambridge 2021), 136–149. 48 G. Maifreda, From Oikonomia to Political Economy: Constructing Economic Knowledge from the Renaissance to the Scientific Revolution (Farnham 2012), 43–72; G. Todeschini, ‘Theological Roots of the Medieval/Modern Merchants’ Self-Representation’, in M. C. Jacob, C. Secretan eds., The Self-Perception of Early Modern “Capitalists” (New York 2008), 17–46. 49 Rucellai, Zibaldone, 26–27. 50 G. Favero, ‘A New Edition of Benedetto’s Cotrugli The Book of the Art of Trade’, in

Benedetto Cotrugli, The Book of the Art of Trade, C. Carraro and G. Favero eds. (London 2017), 9–19. On the relationship between Alberti’s On the Family and Cotrugli’s Book of the Art of Trade see Ugo Tucci’s ‘Introduction’ to Benedetto Cotrugli, Il libro dell’arte di mercatura, U. Tucci ed. (Venice 1990), 63.

RISKY NARRATIVES: FRAMING GENERAL AVERAGE …

79

realm of knowledge in which instructions can be given well beyond practical training, by engaging in some kind of analysis regarding the factors affecting them. Cotrugli is the first to provide a detailed list of the elements considered by businessmen in evaluating insurance premiums.51 He argues that “they must be constantly enquiring and asking about pirates or other illintentioned people, about wars, truces and reprisals, and all the things that can threaten a sea voyage”. In doing that, he even appears to trace a distinction between types of risks, beginning with contingent ones, like piracy and military clashes. He then focuses on structural risks, namely those that are stable over a period of time. First of all, the route to follow, which should be considered with great care; he advises that insurers “must keep navigation charts on their desks and be familiar with the ports and the beaches, the distances between one place and another”. Other important elements to take into account were also the type of vessel and the reputation of those who own it, as well as the type of merchandise insured and its possibly perishable nature. Therefore, Cotrugli warned to “also consider the status of the ship-owners and the merchants who are seeking insurance, and the ships, as well as their cargo”. In line with Alberti and Rucellai, however, experience and power of observation are essential features of this description. The ability of individuals to gather any piece of information and process it, their skills in keeping “their eyes open for all news from the seas”, became the precondition for any correct evaluation of sea risks.52 Cotrugli’s words reveal that premium insurance is the perfect setting where ideas about risk and its economic value can be explored. It was not the only one, however, as the discussions about gambling show. Within merchants’ culture and beyond, as early as the thirteenth century, business partnerships, General Average and other risk-sharing tools need also to be 51 The risk factors provided by the Book of the Art of Trade essentially match those emerging by taking into analysis insurance contracts of the fourteenth-sixteenth centuries, see: Ceccarelli, ‘The Price for Risk-Taking’, 5–6. 52 Cotrugli, The Book of the Art of Trade, 75; Cotrugli, Il libro dell’arte di mercatura, 176: “E per dire delli sicuratori, li ricordiamo che gli è di bisogno d’avere et aprire molto l’occhio alle novelle del mare, et al. continuo domandare et inquirere de corsali et male genti, et guerra, triegue, ripresaglie et tucte quelle cose che possono perturbare lo mare. Debbono tenere nello scriptoio loro la carta del navicare et sapere porti et spiagge, distantie di luogho et considerare la conditione de padroni et delli mercanti che asicurare si fanno, et delli navili, et considerare le mercantie”.

80

G. CECCARELLI

considered. Compared to insurance their treatment is less systematic, so a broad spectrum of writings by jurists, theologians and even teachers of commercial mathematics must be addressed if we are to arrive at a clearer image of how marine risks are discussed in this specific framework. Writings on commercial mathematics offer precious information on how merchants were expected to cope with the damages suffered by ships and cargos during navigation. At the end of the fifteenth century, Luca Pacioli summarized a two hundred years long tradition of business cases related to sea trade. Some of these clearly echo General Average, referring to the recovering of wine barrels that lost part of their content in a storm, or the expenses made for damaged ship equipment. As one would expect, the Summa de arithmetica describes in detail the type of calculations to be made in case of mishaps.53 However, these examples are not confined to this literary genre, since similar discussions can also be found in legal writings such as Paolo di Castro’s readings on the Digest (1429). For instance, in commenting the Lex Rhodia, quite surprisingly mathematics is used to address issues like the damages suffered by shipped goods during a jettison.54 In all these cases, a basic principle that merchants learnt at school was routinely applied, the so-called rule of three. It allowed, when knowing three elements of a proportion, to calculate the fourth unknown datum, without having to use equations. In practical terms, this implied to proportionally distribute costs among all the actors involved. As a result, sea risks are essentially treated from the perspective of mutual support, as noted by Olivia Remie Constable, “equalization of risks” is a

53 Lucas de Burgo S. Sepulchri, Somma di arithmetica, geometria, proporzioni e proporzionalità (Venice: Paganinus de Paganinis 1494), fols. 153r–154v; in particular fol. 153r, n. 43, fol. 153v, n. 48. Another fifteenth-century mathematician discussing many problems connected to maritime trade is Filippo Calandri, author of the first printed book of commercial arithmetic: F. Calandri, De Aritmetica opuscolum (Florence: Lorenzo Morgiani and Johann Petri 1492), fols. 63v–65r; elsewhere, in a handwritten collection of problems now available in critical edition, Calandri tackles a case of jettison in form of a brainteaser: Idem, Aritmetica: secondo la lezione del Codice 2669 (sec. 15.) della Biblioteca Riccardiana di Firenze, G. Arrighi ed. (Florence 1969), 193, 205–207. Cp. W. Van Egmond, Practical Mathematics in the Italian Renaissance: A Catalog of Italian Abbacus Manuscripts and Printed Books to 1600 (Florence 1980). 54 Paulus de Castro, Super secunda parte Digesti veteris (Venice: Andreas Calabrensis Papiensis, 1492) [unnumbered folios] in D.14.2.4.2 Cum autem. On the calculative dimension of General Average see the contribution of Sabine Go in this volume.

RISKY NARRATIVES: FRAMING GENERAL AVERAGE …

81

“common denominator” in these discussions.55 Not by chance, commercial arithmetic includes most cases concerned with navigation risks within a broader discussion centred on partnerships (ragioni di compagnia). The same line of argument emerges from legal texts, in starting with the risk-sharing point of view, explicitly linking the concept of common good to General Average. This connection appears already by midfourteenth century in the commentary to the Lex Rhodia by Bartolus of Saxoferrato. He does so by establishing an analogy between a fire threatening to destroy a group of houses and the jettison of a cargo: “when someone’s house is demolished by the neighbors to avoid the fire to spread, the neighbors must make reparation to the house owner, since the demolition was done for the common good”. These neighbours, Bartolo claims, have a shared responsibility, just like the owners of the jettisoned goods, the shipmaster and all the subjects involved in General Average do.56 This analogy, as well as the reference to common good, will later become a recurring argument. For example, Baldus de Ubaldis discussing the same passage will closely follow Bartolo’s words, while Paolo di Castro will connect the argument of common good to other parts of the Lex Rhodia.57 More in general, the language through which jettison is addressed hints at mutual aid, with a dominance of nouns and verbs referring to the act of ‘bringing together’, such as contributio, contribuere, collatio, conferre.58

55 O. Remie Constable ‘The Problem of Jettison in Medieval Mediterranean Maritime Law’, Journal of Medieval History, 20 (1994): 207–220, 208–209. 56 Bartolus de Saxoferrato, Lectura super prima et secunda parte Digesti veteris (Venice: Baptista de Tortis 1493), fol. 97rb, in D.14.2.2.pr. Si laborante: “Domini iactarum mercium habent actionem cum magistro, et magister cum ceteris non solum habet actionem: sed etiam retentionem mercium: ut fiat contributio. Item … quando domus alicuius destruitur a vicinis: ne ignis ulterius transeat quod debeat ei emendari a vicinis: quia pro communi utilitate factum est”. 57 Baldus de Ubaldis, Tomus secundus in Digestum vetus (Lyon: Joannes Thierri Lingonensis 1541), fol. 79va, in D.14.2.2.pr. Si laborante; Paulus de Castro, Super secunda parte Digesti veteris, in D.14.2.4.2 Cum autem: “damnum … passus est propter communem utilitatem omnium”. 58 For example, Bartholomaeus a Saliceto, In Secundam Digesti veteris partem (Frankfurt: Lazarus Zetznerus 1615), col. 340 in D.14.2.4pr. Navis and D.14.2.1 Sed si navis; also, Baldus de Ubaldis, Tomus secundus in Digestum vetus, fol. 79vb in D.14.2.2.4 Portio autem and Paulus de Castro, Super secunda parte Digesti veteris, [unnumbered folios] in D.14.2.4pr. Navis.

82

G. CECCARELLI

And this was precisely how canon lawyers and theologians also framed their discussions about long-distance maritime trade. By mid-thirteenth century, beginning with Geoffrey of Trani, scholasticism stood in favour of contractual tools allowing merchants to jointly take care of the risks and damages of navigation (communicare pericula et damna).59 The emphasis on ‘sharing’ made it easy to draw a clear watershed between these mutual arrangements and usury, thus distancing the discussion from the controversies related to canon law. By embracing this line of reasoning, Thomas Aquinas will make it extremely influential in the following centuries, to the point that even civil lawyers will often refer to the communicare pericula et damna formula.60 The resulting narrative, by linking risks to damages, made sea risks as something difficult to evaluate in advance and thus unworthy of being discussed in detail. As a consequence, these discussions do not provide a suitable framework for risk quantification. In the texts addressing General Average not only the word periculum is seldom mentioned, but it is never attached to terms that could hint at an economic potential, like price (pretium) or estimate (extimare).61 As seen above, these sources reveal that a calculative approach to risk takes shape only ex-post, when the potential threat has materialized and actually become a ‘loss’; only in these situations, a vocabulary suited to express the value of objects is used. Exceptionally periculum is framed in a hypothetical scenario, treated as an event that might occur in the future, as Baldus de Ubaldis comment on Lex Rhodia exemplifies. However, even in these cases no effort is made to numerically estimate maritime risk (periculum maris ), being this latter 59 Goffredus de Trano, Summa super tituli decretalium (Venice: Bernardinus Stagninus 1491), fol. 80rb-va in X. 5.19.19 Naviganti. 60 Thomas Aquinas, Summa Theologiae, II, II, in Opera omnia, 3 vols (Parma: Fiaccadori 1853), 281a–282ab. A crucial role in spreading Aquinas’ view is played by manual for confessors compiled by canon law experts in the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries, such as that by John of Freiburg: see Johannis de Friburgo, Summa confessorum (Lyons: Henricus Vortoma, 1518), fol. 87rb. Pier Filippo della Cornia provides a good example of how the theological approach spreads among civil lawyers: Petrus Philippus Corneus Perusinus, In primam Codis partem (Lyon: Eredi Giunta 1553), fol. 118vb, in C. 2.3.9 Si pascenda. 61 Any reference to risk (periculum) is missing from Bartolus of Saxoferrato’s comment on Lex Rhodia, as well as from that of Bartholomew of Saliceto, another relevant jurist of the late thirteenth, early fourteenth century. At best the term is generically linked to the risk of shipwreck, cp. Paulus de Castro, Super secunda parte Digesti veteris, [unnumbered folios] in D.14.2.6 Navis adversa: “quando navis non fuit in periculo perditionis”.

RISKY NARRATIVES: FRAMING GENERAL AVERAGE …

83

only considered in the light of prevention, depicted as a threat to avoid (evitare) rather than an event to evaluate and forecast.62 As argued earlier, similar dynamics emerge if one looks at commercial mathematics. While most risk-sharing agreements simply needed an ex-post assessment of profit and losses, some also required the forecasting of potential risks and returns.63 When a partnership was abruptly terminated by an unexpected event, for example, how should shares be calculated? This implied a change of perspective in the direction of probability calculus that, apart from few exceptional cases, did not yet occur.64 The ‘rule of three’ was so rooted in merchants’ culture that it was also applied to predict future events, falsely assuming that the future

62 Baldus de Ubaldis, Tomus secundum in Digestum vetus, fol. 79vb, in Dig.14.2.5pr. Amissae navis: “Pro nave amissa non habet locum collatio, sed pro arbore cesa ut evitetur periculum maris et mercium collatio locum habetur.” Cp. also Paulus de Castro, Super secunda parte Digesti veteris, [unnumbered folios] in D.14.2.2.1 Si conservatis: “quando mercatores vident tempestatem si non dubitant periclitari non debent magistro dicere quid habeat agree […] puta quod navem exarmet […] idem si fecit ne perclitaretur”. 63 Examples can be traced since the early fourteenth century. Paolo Gherardi, Opera

matematica. Libro di ragioni - Liber habaci. Codici magliabechiani classe XI, nn. 87 e 88 (sec. XIV) della Biblioteca Nazionale di Firenze, ed. G. Arrighi (Lucca 1987), 145–146; Gratia de’ Castellani, Chasi sopra chonpagnie. Dal codice Palatino 573 della Biblioteca nazionale di Firenze, ed. M. Pancanti (Siena 1984), 32–39; Libro d’abaco. Dal Codice 1754 (sec. XIV) della Statale di Lucca, ed. G. Arrighi (Lucca 1973), 75–79; Filippo Calandri, Una raccolta di ragioni. Dal Codice L. VI. 45 della Biblioteca comunale di Siena, ed. D. Santini (Siena 1982), 5–7, 26–27; Lucas de Burgo S. Sepulchri, Somma di arithmetica, fol. 152r, n. 31. 64 It is important to stress that the few hinting at the solution later provided by Pascal, did not so in referring to risk-sharing partnership and sea trade, but to wagering; for example, Filippo Maria Calandri who discusses how to divide a stake between two ball players, in one case, and two crossbowers, in the other: Filippo Calandri, Una raccolta di ragioni. Dal Codice L. VI. 45 della Biblioteca comunale di Siena, 13–14, 39–40. Also I. Schneider, ‘The Solution of the Two Main Problems Concerning Games of Chance in the Late European Middle Ages and the Possibility of Islamic Sources’, Bollettino di Storia delle Scienze Matematiche, 23/2 (2003): 99–108. Other two examples, found both in anonymous handwritten collections of commercial mathematic problems, are edited and discussed by R. Franci, ‘Una soluzione esatta del problema delle parti in un manoscritto della prima metà del Quattrocento’, Bollettino di Storia delle Scienze Matematiche, 22/2 (2002): 260–265; L. Toti Rigatelli, ‘Il “Problema delle Parti” in Manoscritti del XIV e XV Secolo’, in M. Folkerts, U. Lindgren eds., Mathemata. Festschrift für Helmuth Gericke (Wiesbaden-Stuttgart 1985), 229–236‚ 232–234.

84

G. CECCARELLI

would develop following the same pattern of the past.65 Only by midseventeenth century mathematicians will be able to design a theory suited to go beyond this traditional approach.66 Alternatives to premium insurance persisted over a long period not just in business practice, but also in the narrative describing them. As a result, sea risks continued to be framed in ways that varied according to the context in which they were discussed. Considering them as something that could be evaluated in advance, and therefore transferred in exchange for money, made little sense in the perspective of partnerships, General Average and similar risk-sharing tools. What mattered was the existence of well-functioning mitigation systems to mutualize losses. Commercial mathematics offered practical means to achieve this, while the concept of common good provided the moral rationale for a rhetoric emphasizing collective responses to marine risks. This double-pronged approach goes side by side with the line of reasoning developed at the same time about premium insurance, suggesting a long-term coexistence of these views. As seen for gambling, these discussions were never totally self-confined, revealing unexpected points of contacts and combinations. The image of the expert ship master introduced by Alberti provides a good case in point. While the individual decision-maker is clearly at the centre of the stage, the choices he takes impact the larger dimension of household and lineage. Not by chance the equivalent of the skilled ship master is the exemplary pater familias, who is in charge of safely delivering his wealth to the next generations, thus making it clear that is not simply a matter of ‘personal’ liability.67

65 N. Meusnier, ‘Le Problème des partis peut-il être d’origine arabo-musulmane?’, Journ@l électronique d’Histoire des Probabilités et de la Statistique/Electronic Journ@l for History of Probability and Statistics, 3/1 (2007): 1–14. 66 I. Hacking, The Emergence of Probability: A Philosophical Study of Early Ideas about Probability, Induction and Statistical Inference (Cambridge 1975), 12, 57–62; P. Bernstein, Against the Gods: The Remarkable Story of Risk (New York 1996), 60–72. 67 Neu Watkins, The Family in Renaissance Florence, 36–39; Leon Battista Alberti, I Libri della Famiglia, 17–19. Not by chance, this whole passage revolves around the words of Benedetto Alberto, Leon Battista’s grandfather, who connects the material duties of the exemplary “padre della famiglia” (36, 17) to moral ones. This combination is presented as the key to avoid a household from ruin (“ruinare”, 38, 18) and pass a family’s fortune from one generation to another. This intergenerational bond is pushed even forward when Benedetto Alberto claims that “the old, then, should be common fathers to all the young” (39, 19).

RISKY NARRATIVES: FRAMING GENERAL AVERAGE …

85

Cotrugli provides a further example of how the two levels can combine. As seen above, making judgements on the basis of personal expertise is a distinctive feature of the ideal insurer, but the emphasis on individual skills is only part of the picture. The Book of the Art of Trade devotes a full chapter to marine insurance, granting full recognition to a contract that until then had been given little space in merchant handbooks. The opening lines of this chapter are revealing of a converging narrative where the quantification and shifting of maritime risks go along with a broader collective effort to manage them. Premium insurance is defined as “convenient and useful not only to the merchants that insure and take out insurance, but also most beneficial to cities and republics”.68 Cotrugli’s words are not a novelty. Since the beginnings of the thirteenth century, scholasticism had developed a literary cliché made of long-distance trade and brave merchants supplying cities in need of provisions. The risk merchants took going by sea was seen as crucial in legitimizing their profits, as well as in granting them a public recognition for their role. The key-concept used, like in Bartolus of Saxoferrato discussion on General Average, is ‘common good’, but it was only in the following century that Bernardino of Siena explicitly linked this line of reasoning to insurance. The usefulness of insurance is directly connected with its support to the spreading of maritime trade, which is among the primary sources of wealth for a city (or a state). Since they take risks on behalf of the community, thus carrying out some form of civic duty, underwriters have the right to earn premiums.69 Not only this theme will inspire Cotrugli, but later will become popular to the point of spilling over from the realm of theology to political discourses and economic ideas, countering the spread of less positive narratives depicting insurers as selfish profiteers. Examples of this can be found in the speech Queen Elizabeth I delivered when the London Chamber of Assurance was reformed in 1601, as well as in the seventeenth-century French bestseller on maritime trade, Estienne

68 Cotrugli, The Book of the Art of Trade, 74; Cotrugli, Il libro dell’arte di mercatura, 175: “Lo sichurare è uno commune utile et commodo non solamente a mercanti che asicurano e si fanno asichurare, ma etiamdio egli è commodissimo ale ciptà e le republiche”. 69 Bernardinus Senensis, Quadragesimale de evangelio aeterno, IV: 273; Ceccarelli, ‘Risky Business’, 616, 629–630.

86

G. CECCARELLI

Cleirac’s Us et coustumes de la mer.70 The long-lasting success of this line of reasoning takes us back to our departure point. Depicting underwriting in terms of a collective effort carried out by a community of citizens shows how the relation between risk-shifting and risk-sharing continued to be multifaceted. At the same time, emphasizing extremely familiar arguments made contractual innovation not only more comprehensible, but also fully compliant with civic values. It was essentially a matter of extending to the expanding business of insurance, those well-established narratives about lending money to the city, or investing in local charitable institutions that were—as noted by Anthony Molho—presented as the standard way for citizens of “drawing profit from the state”.71 The connection was strong to the point it worked the other way around as well. When new forms of charitable pawnbroking (monte di pietà) did emerge, it seemed obvious to equal them to insurance. Under this light it could be easily claimed that, confronting the risks of sea trade, was evidence of public commitment that signalled social rise and civic inclusion.72 This rich imagery—jointly developed by merchants, mathematicians, jurists and theologians—was something more than a rhetorical exercise. Such ideas clearly mirrored (and resonated with) the functioning of markets run by small groups in need of investors granting coverage even if not involved in maritime trade. Seen from this perspective, the expansion of the insurance business taking place between the thirteenth and the sixteenth centuries acquires a richer meaning. It suggests that an

70 L. Lobo-Guerrero, Insuring War: Sovereignty, Security (New York 2012), 27; Estienne Cleirac, Us et coustumes de la mer, divisées en trois parties (Bordeaux: Jacques Mongiron Millanges 1661), 215; on this F. Trivellato, The Promise and Peril of Credit. What a Forgotten Legend About Jews and Finance Tells Us About the Making of European Commercial Society (Princeton 2019), 51–52. 71 A. Molho, ‘The State and Public Finance: A Hypothesis Based on the History of Late Medieval Florence’, The Journal of Modern History, 67 (1995): Supplement 124. 72 See, for example, Consilium almi collegii doctorum utriusque inclite civitatis Perusii super montem pietatis in Pro Monte Pietatis (Venice: Johannes Tacuinus 1494–1498), [unnumbered pages, but fol. 31r]. It is no coincidence to find the above-mentioned Pier Filippo della Cornia among the lawyers who wrote this legal text in 1469.

RISKY NARRATIVES: FRAMING GENERAL AVERAGE …

87

interaction between narratives about risk, and the development of riskmanagement tools, was at work far earlier than recently argued by Jens Beckert and Richard Bronk.73 If we look at the way markets actually worked, it was not just a matter of contract and institutional innovation, which proves to be efficient by being able to match an increasing demand for insurance and to include a larger number of underwriters. The expansion in scale did not overturn previously existing asymmetries but rather tended to reproduce them. On the one hand, there are groups needing protection for their maritime business, who control the market thanks to their bargaining power. On the other, there are ‘followers’ who can provide this protection thanks to risk-shifting innovations designed for this purpose, and supported by narratives promoting their adoption. This latter is, however, slower than claimed by earlier scholarship. The customary risk-sharing approach—whether it concerned tools or ideas— was not all of a sudden erased by the creation of premium insurance. As this paper shows, the rise of this latter can no longer be explored, without taking into account the resilience of the former.

Appendix See Tables 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, and 6.

73 J. Beckert, R. Bronk, ‘An Introduction to Uncertain Futures’, in J. Beckert, R. Bronk eds., Uncertain Futures: Imaginaries, Narratives, and Calculation in the Economy (Oxford 2018), 1–38.

88

G. CECCARELLI

Table 1 Subscriptions in the role of insurance buyer and underwriter in Florence (1524–1526) Type of subscriber

Subjects subscribing both as underwriter and insurance buyer Subjects subscribing only as underwriter or insurance buyer “Ufficiali alle sicurtà” Unspecified/Nonidentifiable subscriber Total

In the role of insurance buyer

In the role of underwriter

No. of No. of Value subscribers contracts insured (in florins)

No. of No. Value subscribers of insured shares (in florins)

75

797

621,300.5 72

3282 278,853.3

39

82

36,495.0 248

5210 380,792.2

1 –

2 –

3600.0 –

– 24

115

881

661,395.5 320

– –

– 1750.0

8516 661,395.5

Source Pisa, Archive of the Scuola Normale Superiore, Salviati I , “Libri di Commercio”, 70, cc. 3r–144r

Table 2 Insured values by amount underwritten in Florence in a selected trimester (March–May 1526) Value insured in florins (by amount underwritten)

9 ≤ 18 > 18 ≤ 24 >27 Total

9 ≤ 18 > 18 ≤ 24 >27 Total