263 20 15MB
English Pages 345 [348] Year 1981
Andreae Farming, Development and Space
Bernd Andreae
Farming Development and Space A World Agricultural Geography Translated from the German by Howard F. Gregor
W G DE
Walter de Gruyter · Berlin · New York 1981
Author Bernd Andreae Professor für Landwirtschaftliche Betriebslehre Schweinfurthstraße 25 D-1000 Berlin 33 Translator Howard F. Gregor, Ph.D. Professor Department of Geography University of California, Davis Davis, California 95616
CIP-Kurztitelaufnahme der Deutschen
Bibliothek
Andreae, Bernd: Farming, development and space: a world agricultural geography / Bernd Andreae. Transi, from the German by Howard F. Gregor. Berlin; New York: de Gruyter, 1981. Dt. Ausg. u.d.T.: Andreae, Bernd: Agrargeographie ISBN 3-11-007632-2
Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data Andreae, Bernd. Farming, development and space. Revised translation of: Agrargeographie. Bibliography: p. Includes index. 1. Agricultural geography. S495.A4713 338.1Ό9 81-4755 ISBN 3-11-117632-2 AACR2
© Copyright 1981 by Walter de Gruyter & Co., Berlin 30. All rights reserved, including those of translation into foreign languages. No part of this book may be reproduced in any form - by photoprint, microfilm, or any other means - nor transmitted nor translated into a machine language without written permission from the publisher. Typesetting: Verena Boldin, Aachen. Printing: Karl Gerike, Berlin. - Binding: Lüderitz & Bauer, Buchgewerbe GmbH, Berlin. Printed in Germany.
Translator's Introduction
Professor Andreae introduces his volume as "a small textbook for students of geography and the agricultural sciences" and as the first German-language introduction to agricultural geography to be submitted by an agricultural economist. It is more. Andreae speaks from a land with a long and vigorous tradition in agricultural-geographic research, where agricultural economists antedate geographers in their particular concern for the spatial aspects of agricultural geography, and where the lehrbuch is usually more comprehensive and analytical than the kind that has given the textbook a dubious reputation in many circles elsewhere, particularly in the English-speaking world. But more specifically, Andreae draws on this inheritance and his own prolific work to offer us one of the few detailed pictures of world agricultural patterns as they are influenced by individual farm operations and agricultural development. Rather than proceeding from the region to the detail, the usual approach for geographers, Andreae is concerned with building the bridge (to use his metaphor) between agricultural economics and agricultural geography by proceeding from the farm to the comprehension of larger areas. He is also at pains to explain how farming practices and types change as population pressures increase and industrialization brings about increasing integration of agriculture into the national economy. His three-stage theory of farming development, monoculture-*· diversification^· specialization, and its corresponding sequence of extensiveness-> labor-intensiveness-»· capital-intensiveness, are themes that run though much of the book. These two distinctions, the emphases on farming operations and agricultural development insofar as they affect world agricultural spatial patterns, are expressed in the main title of this English-language edition of what originally appeared under the principal heading of Agrargeographie*. Since that time, Professor Andreae has expanded his treatment of the ecological and economic boundaries of farming and the agricultural geography of the United States, and I have enlarged his already extensive bibliography to include especially more sources in English. I am grateful to both author and publisher for their help and patience. No translator can do full justice to the original work, though I hope my role as both translator and colleague "at the other end of the bridge" will compensate in part. Howard F. Gregor Davis, California, March 1981 * AGRARGEOGRAPHIE - Strukturzonen wirtschaft. Berlin 1977.
und Betriebsformen
in der Weltland-
Foreword
Agricultural geography is a part of economic geography, and as such, is the science of the agriculturally transformed earth surface, with all its associated natural, economic, and social interrelations as reflected spatially. This surface is composed of agricultural zones and agricultural regions, which in turn are made up of farms, the building stones of agricultural geography. Agricultural geography is distinctly a boundary science. Not only the economic geographer and the agricultural economist, but also the plant and animal geographers, the climatologist, the sociologist, the ethnographer, the cultural geographer, and others have contributed to the many causal relations in the world agricultural structure. Thus up to now no single and fairly exhaustive overall view has been presented by the various disciplines. That is the fate of any boundary science. Nor can the book offered here lay claim to a consideration of all aspects. Sociocultural and religious influences had to remain largely unconsidered. Agricultural geography was for a long time accounted for scientifically almost exclusively by economic geographers, who for this purpose sought the help of agricultural economists and found it in rich amount, especially in the contributions of Engelbrecht, von Thünen, Aereboe, Busch, and Rolfes. In the last two decades agricultural economists have become notably more interested in the geography of agriculture as they have been called to all ends of the earth to advise, direct, and plan in areal development. They have thus been motivated to sharpen, through as geographically extensive a view as possible, their judgements on the agricultural problems of entire regions in Latin America, Africa, and Asia. Thus they have earnestly sought, from their side, associations with economic geography. The bridge was now being thrown across from both banks. The two disciplines were getting closer to each other. As a result, I believed that the time had come to fulfill an oft-expressed wish by submitting from the side of agricultural economics the first German-language introduction to agricultural geography. Its aim is to be a small textbook for students of geography and the agricultural sciences, one that is embracing but still concise, motivating but still easily readable, and which seeks to provide understanding even more than information. The core of the book is based on my lectures on agricultural geography at the Berlin Technical University.
8
Foreword
The economic geographer advances from the world agricultural economy or agricultural zones to the detail, whereas I, conversely, proceed from the farm to the comprehension of larger areas. It is obvious that the two different approaches must lead to different emphases, results, and conclusions. No value judgement, however, lies in this statement. I do not wish the reader to come away with an impression of "either-or" but rather one of "not only, but also," so that the bridgeheads thrown up from the two banks by economic geography and agricultural economics will finally coalesce into one unit. I am grateful to the publishers for the encouraging trust with which they have received me into their author's circle, and for their appreciation of my wishes. Respect for my most tried and true secretary and co-worker of more than sixteen years, Frau Elsbeth Greiser, née Goehle, requires that I cite her and all the other unnamed helpers whom she represents with warmest thanks. I should like to dedicate this book to my wife, Gisela Andreae, née Freiin von Reibnitz. For more than three decades, she has supported me unfailingly in my work, sharing all sacrifices and privations. Without that support, the book would not have materialized. Now she can also share in the pleasure over its completion.
Berlin-Dahlem, January 1977
Bernd
Andreae
Contents
Abbreviations Glossary
15 17
Introduction: Origins and Evolution of Agriculture — A Three-Stage Theory
27
I.
II.
Agricultural Geography as a Science 1. Definitions 2. Objectives and Significance of Agricultural Geography 3. Work Methods of Agricultural Geography
.
The Climatic Zones of World Agricultural Space and their Significant Features for the Agricultural Economy . . . . 1. Tropical Rainy Climates a) Rainforest Climate b) Humid Savanna Climate c) Tropical Highland Climates 2. Dry Climates a) Dry Savanna Climate b) Shrub Savanna Climate c) Steppe Climate d)Semidesert Climate 3. Humid Warm-Temperate Climates a) Subtropical Dry-Summer Climate b) Subtropical Warm-Summer Climate c) Marine Cool-Summer Climate 4. Humid Cool-Temperate Climates a) Continental Warm-Summer Climate b) Continental Cool-Summer Climate c) Subarctic Climate
III. The Delimitation of World Agricultural Space 1. The Expansion of World Agricultural Space as a Current Problem 2. Ecological Boundaries of Farming a) Polar Boundaries b) Altitudinal Boundaries c) Dry Boundaries d)Wet Boundaries
30 30 31 31
33 33 33 34 36 37 37 38 39 39 40 40 41 42 42 43 43 43 45 45 48 48 52 57 66
10
Contents
3.
4.
5. 6.
e) Soil Boundaries f) Slope Boundaries g) Unfavorable Exposure Economic Boundaries of Farming a) Settlement and Industrial Boundaries b) Transport Boundaries c) Commercialization Boundaries Boundary Shifts with Economic Growth a) Mechanical Technological Advances as a Cause . . . b) Biological Technological Advances as a Cause . . . . c) General Economic Growth as a Cause Contraction of World Agricultural Space as a Future Prospect Summary
IV. Farms as Building Stones of the Agricultural Region . . . 1. Reasons for Diversified Farm Production a) Work Spacing b) Crop Rotations c) Fertilizer Balance d)Feed Balance e) Self-Sufficiency f) Spreading Risk 2. Reasons for Spatial Differentiation of Farms a) The Physical Location of Production b) Population Density, Educational Level, and Personality of the Farm Operator c) Size of Farm, Ranch, and Plantation d) Location of the Farm for Transport e) The Diversified Farm in the Tension Field of Force Groups 3. Reasons for Temporal Changes in Farms a) Price-Cost Development aa) Price Relations between Agricultural Products . . bb) Cost Relations between Agricultural Inputs cc) Price-Cost Relations between Agricultural Products and Inputs b) Technological Advances aa) Organic Technological Advances bb) Mechanical Technological Advances V.
The Principal Farming Systems of World Agriculture . . . 1. Grassland (Grazing) Systems a) Nomadic Grazing
67 68 69 70 70 70 74 76 76 78 79 82 85 87 88 88 90 91 92 93 93 94 94 95 96 102 105 106 106 107 109 110 Ill Ill Ill 113 114 114
Contents b) Sedentary Extensive Grassland Farming (Ranching) . . c) Sedentary Intensive Grassland Farming 2. Annual-Cropping Systems a) Primitive Rotation Farming b) Ley Farming c) Grain Farming d)Hoe Crop Farming 3. Perennial-Cropping Systems a) Gathering b)Bush and Tree Crop Farms c) Plantations VI. The Agricultural Geography of the Humid Tropics . . . . 1. Regions of Rainfed Farming a) Rainfed Farming in the Tropical Rainforest Belt. . . b) Rainfed Farming in the Humid Savannas c) Rainfed Farming in the Tropical Highlands 2. Regions of Irrigation Farming a) Farm Management Functions of Crop Irrigation . . . b) Irrigation Methods in Geographic Comparison . . . . c) Rice Growing as a Representative of Irrigated Cropping on Family Farms 3. Regions with Predominantly Bush and Tree Crops . . . a) Farm Management Characteristics and Geographic Distribution b)The Principal Bush and Tree Crops and their Locations c) Peasant Farms or Plantations? aa) Typical Peasant Crops bb) Typical Plantation Crops cc) Crops Suitable for both Peasant Farms and Plantations VII. The Agricultural Geography of the Dry Areas 1. Regions of Extensive Grassland Farming a) Zones of Nomadic Herding b) Zones of Sedentary Grassland Farming c) Seasonal Feed Balance as the Central Problem. . . . 2. Regions of Dryland Crop Farming a) Wheat-Fallow Farming b) Millet-Sorghum-Peanut Farming c) Other Forms of Dryland Cropping 3. Regions of Combined Extensive Grassland Farming and Dryland Crop Farming a) Risk as a Hindrance to Diversified Production . . . .
11 115 115 117 117 118 119 120 122 122 123 124 127 132 132 137 140 141 143 143 145 149 149 152 154 155 155 156 160 165 166 167 169 174 176 181 185 187 187
Contents
12
b)The Example of Southwest Africa c) Modifications by Economic and Ecological Variants . 4. The Macrospatial Structure of a Dry Area: The Example of Australia a) Physicospatial Structure b) Agricultural Zones c) Water Reclamation Projects VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes . . . 1.The Agricultural Geography of Western Europe . . . . a) Place-Specific Characteristics b) Methodology of Delimitation and Statistical Derivation of Agricultural Regions c) Crop Rotation Regions d)Land Use Regions e) Livestock Regions f) Complex Agricultural Regions g) Summary 2. The Agricultural Geography of North America . . . . a) Place-Specific Characteristics of the United States . . b)The Dairy Zone c) The Corn Zone d) Agricultural Regions with Mixed (General) Farming . e) The Cotton Zone f) The Wheat Regions. . . g) Regions of Extensive Grassland Farming (Ranching) . h) Coastal Regions with Fruit and Vegetable Growing Dominant i) Industrialized Animal Production on Specialized Farms j) Regional Differences in the Factor Combination . . . 3. The Agricultural Geography of the East Bloc Countries . . a) Place-Specific Characteristics b) Large Socialist Farms as a Regionalizing Feature . . . c) Problems of an Areally-Suitable Agricultural Production d) Stages of Socialization e) Agricultural Zones in the Baltic-Adriatic Area . . . . f) Agricultural Zones of the Soviet Union g) Agricultural Zones of the People's Republic of China . IX. Structural Changes in World Agricultural Space with Economic Growth 1. Forces for Development 2. Changes in the Factor Combination
187 189 190 191 191 195 196 197 197 207 210 214 222 227 231 232 232 237 238 240 241 242 243 244 246 247 250 250 252 252 253 256 260 266
271 271 273
Contents
a) Factor Costs and Factor Combination in Sparsely Settled Countries b) Factor Costs and Factor Combination in Densely Settled Countries c) Differences in the Overall Trend of Change in the Factor Combination d) Developmental Tendencies in Farm Size 3. Diversification and Specialization of the Production Program a) One-sided Farms at the Beginning of Development . . b) Diversification Tendencies in the Pre-industrial Era . . c) Specialization Tendencies in the Industrial Era . . . d) Stages in Farming Diversification and Specialization in the March Toward Total Economic Integration . . . 4. Changes in Farming Systems in Selected Climatic Zones. a) Tropical Rainforest Climate b) Humid Savanna Climate c) Dry Savanna and Steppe Climates d) Marine Cool-Summer Climate e) Continental Cool-Summer Climate
13
274 277 279 280 284 284 286 287 289 290 291 292 293 295 297
Outlook: The Agricultural Evolution Theory of Friedrich Aereboe in the Light of this Agricultural Geography 299 Bibliography Figures Index
303 323 327
Abbreviations
AC AL CC CL CLLU °C DM Dpf EEC EC FAO FL FRG GDR GU ha kcal kg K20 kStU LLU m MD MH MHP MHPh MY
Ν PFA
Agricultural census (complete census) Agricultural land (FL + idle cropland and pasture + private parks, sod farms, ornamental gardens) Catch crop Cultivable (arable) land = land usually cultivated annually Large livestock unit (cattle) Degrees Celsius = 5 ( ° F - 3 2 / 9 ) ; °F = 9(°C/5) + 32 Deutsche mark (West Germany) = $ 0.27 U.S., as of 1969 Deutsche pfennig (West Germany) = $ 0.0027 U.S., as of 1969 European Economic Community (Common Market) European Community Food and Agricultural Organization of the United Nations Farmed land = cropland, including kitchen gardens, permanent grassland, orchards, vineyards, hops, nurseries, and woodlots Federal Republic of Germany (West Germany) German Democratic Republic (East Germany) Grain unit, corresponding in nutritive value to 100 kg grain Hectare (2.47 acres) = 10,000 m 2 ; 100 ha = 1 km 2 (0.39 mi. 2 ) Kilocalorie (1,000 calories) Kilogram (2.2 lbs.) = 1,000 gm; 1,000 kg = 1 metric ton (2,204 lbs.) Potash fertilizers (pure nutrient) Kilo starch unit (1,000 StU) = 1.408 Scandinavian feed units Large livestock unit, corresponding to 500 kg liveweight Meter (3.3 ft.) = 100 cm = 1,000 mm (40 in.) Man-day. In the tropics usually only 5.5 to 7 man-hours. Man-hour Motor hp (horse power) Motor hp hour Man-year = equivalent of one full-time worker working at least 2,400 MH annually. In the tropics usually only 1,500 to 1,700 MH/year. Nitrogen fertilizers (.pure nutrient) Primary forage area, used exclusively for feed production
16
PLLU P2 O5 % AL % CL % FL q RLLU S. beets S. gr. TPh TPU W. gr.
Abbreviations
Large livestock unit (productive livestock) Phosphoric acid fertilizers (pure nutrient) % of agricultural land % of cultivable (arable) land % of farmed land Quintal = 0.1 metric ton = 100 kg (220.4 lbs.) Roughage-consuming large livestock unit Sugar beets Spring grain (spring plowing and planting) Traction power hour Traction power unit (equivalent of 1 horse; 5 tractor hp = 1 TPU) Winter grain (fall plowing and planting)
Glossary
Basic agricultural-geographic concepts (after Manshard 1968, pp. 9ff.) Science of the agriculturally transformed — agricultural geography = earth surface. Science of the spatial distribution of geo— social geography graphically relevant social structures. Common expression for economic form or — economic formation - life form. Portion of the earth surface used agricul— agricultural space - turally in any way. Spatial unit with a clear farming dominance. — agricultural area = — agricultural zone = Agricultural area which can be associated globally with climatic and vegetation belts. — agricultural region = Part of the earth surface with a clearly defined agricultural structure, thus with an assured unity. — farm Any type of operational unit in agriculture. Extensive livestock raising unit, usually of — ranch significant size. — plantation Large farms having their own processing facilities for their products (sugarcane mills, sisal factories, tea factories, etc.). Rural land use concepts (alphabetical) (see Fig. 1, p. 16) — Alpine farming Extensive livestock raising in high mountain areas, which often lie above timberline and can only be grazed about 90 days per year. annual-crop farming Crop rotations with only annual crops. cash catch crops Crops planted after the main crop in the same year, but still supplying a marketable product. cereals Small grains (see leafy crops). cover crop rotation Leafy crop — leafy crop — grain. crop rotation Chronological succession of field crops. All land on which crops are regularly cropland alternated (see Fig. 1). Areal extent of crop types in % CL. cropland share
18
Glossary
Organization
SPECIAL CROPS
of Farmed
Land
(FL)
CROPLAND (CL)
PERMANENT GRASSLAND"
L E A F Y CROPS
CATCH CROPS
Tree and bush crops l i k e gropes, fruit, hops, nursery products, basket w i l l o w
— SMALL
GRAINS
Underseeds, stubble seeds, w i n t e r catch crops
Rye, w h e a t , barley, oats, spelt, mixed grains
HOE CROPS'
COMBINE-HARVESTED L E A F Y CROPS Rape, rapeseed, grain corn, threshed legumes, grass seeds, etc.
C O M B I N E - H A R V E S T E D CROPS or incorrectly, " G R A I N
ROUGHAGES Clover, g r a s s - c l o v e r , a l f a l f a , corn silage, pasture and m e a d o w , s w e e t lupines, etc.
Potatoes, sugar b e e t s , fodder hoe crops, tobacco, f i e l d vegetables and other garden plants raised as field crops, like strawberries
FODDER CROPPING- 1
CROPS"
'fr. I t t i : TU ( i r a t i l i m "bu crop·" '» rttiini« hin end iliiwhirt in thi tut, rather (hen tinng it the • suai. • M in this ceil nit tuffieiintly cimprihentivt, English translation at "root crops "
Figure 1
— cropping
system
— crop years
double-crop rotation dry farming
— extensive leafy crops
— five-course rotation — foreign compatibility
four-course grass-clover
rotation farming
= Field- or crop-rotation system = form of cropping organization. = In ley farming (see ley farming) the cropping periods for annual crops; in contrast to grass years, cropping periods for perennial forage crops. = Leafy crop — leafy crop - grain — grain. = Farming system in which fallow is inserted in the crop rotation to conserve water (e.g. 1. fallow - 2. wheat - 3. wheat). = Threshed legumes, field forage crops, oil crops, fallow; in contrast to the intensive leafy crops (hoe crops). = Leafy crop — grain — grain — grain — grain. = Compatibility of different crops; in contrast to self-compatibility = compatibility of similar crops. = Leafy crop — grain — grain — grain. = Intensive form of ley farming, with only a two- to three-year period of fodder cropping.
19
Glossary
— grassland cropping — grass years — "Hauberg" farming
— intensive leafy crops — "Kunstegart" (Ger.) — leafy crops
— ley farming
— monoculture — "Naturegart" (Ger.) — non-cash catch crops
— Norfolk rotation — primary crop rotation
— production elasticity — production goal — production — rotation
intensity
component
— rotation period — rotation plan
Emphasizing rotation pasture, rotation meadow, grass-clover, alfalfa, grass-alfalfa. Periods of perennial forage crops (see crop years). Combined forestry and cropping on farms among lighter stands of oak forest in central Europe. Grain is planted between the trees, which are cut for tanbark. Hoe crops. Alpine ley farming (see ley farming) with seeded pasture. All preparatory, support, and main crops other than the cereals in crop rotations: hoe crops, forage crops, legumes, oil and fiber crops, fallow. Based on crop rotations that include the harvesting and grazing of grass plots (leys) over a period of several years. Constant cultivation of the same crop, e.g. permanent grain cropping. Alpine ley farming with volunteer pasture. Crops planted after the main crop in the same year, but which no longer yield a marketable product. Leafy crop — grain — leafy crop — grain. Rotation nearer the farmyard or more important economically; in contrast to the secondary crop rotation, which is farther from the farmyard or less important economically. Adaptability of farm organization. Production program = range of farm enterprises. Amount of labor and materiel expenditures, plus tax payments, per hectare. Sub-rotation, consisting of a leafy crop and following grain crops. Length of the rotation in years. Basic rotation type, in which only the two most important crop groups, i.e. leafy and grain crops, are distinguished.
20
Glossary
secondary crop rotation = See primary crop rotation. — / ^ A m ^ o + Ì K Ì l i f i r \T o p r n « m Compatibility rof a crop with itself (see — c>ni/>AM4ti/i^îJit7tVι» self-compatibility foreign compatibility). — "Sennerei" (Ger.) Dairy farming on Alpine pastures. — three-fìeld system Leafy crop - grain — grain. — useful economic life Span of years in which land can be cropped. Intensity concepts — intensity
= Amount of labor and materiel expenditures, plus tax payments, per hectare. Thus one can speak of livestock-, labor-, or fertilizerintensive farms. Of fundamental importance is the difference between farming intensity = organizational intensity - proportion of the farming structure in intensive enterprises like hoe cropping, raising of special crops, or milk production, and — specialization intensity = operational intensity = expenditures of labor, fertilizers, etc., per hectare in one and the same farming enterprise.
Cost concepts (see Fig. 2.) — Of fundamental importance are the concept-pairs: special costs — overhead costs variable costs — fixed costs average costs — marginal costs. Cost
Concepts
Full Costs - Average total costs
per
production
Costs
unit
S P E C I A L COSTS unequivocal
D COSTS
V A R I A B L E lorilttmc) S P E C I A L COSTS
V A R I A B L E {OPERATING) C O S T S
F I X E D (FIRM) C O S T S
— MARGINAL COSTS allotted to the last production unit
Figure 2
Glossary
21
Farm size classes a) Classification by market dependence — subsistence farms: with operators selling less than 25% of production — weakly commercialized farms: with operators selling 25 to 50% of production — strongly commercialized farms: with operators selling 50 to 75% of production — fully commercialized farms: with operators selling more than 75% of production b) Classification by labor composition — large-scale wage-labor farms are those whose operators do not work manually but can devote themselves exclusively to management problems. — wage-labor family farms, or large family farms, are those whose operators employ wage labor but participate both as manager and manual worker. — land-rich family farms are those with extensive farmland in relation to family labor potential. — land-poor family farms are those with insufficient farmland for the family labor potential. Forms of farming diversity — monoculture = one-sided production program — specialized farming = moderately varied production program — mixed fanning = highly varied production program — diversification = increasing production variety — specialization (farming simplification) = reduction of production variety. Efficiency concepts (see Fig. 3) — gross return = Farm income plus value of normal withdrawals for personal needs, retirement payments, rent in kind, and perquisites, plus value of inventory additions in livestock and farm-produced inputs. — reimbursement share = Gross cash returns less variable special costs (cost of seed, livestock purchases, veterinary services, feed concentrates, chemical fertilizers, plant protection agents, drying, cleaning, etc.; partly also fuel, machine, and hand labor costs; also interest payments on working capital). — farm income = Gross returns minus expenditures, farm taxes and encumbrances = Income from production factors of land, labor, capital, and management.
Glossary
22
Derivation
of
of the Efficiency
Measurements
of the Farm
Cash
Enterprise
receipts
+ other outputs value of s u r p l u s inventories, home consumption,and perquisites
= FARM
PRODUCTION
per ha = g r o s s land p r o d u t t i v i t y , per MY = g r o s s labor p r o d u c t i v i t y
I
LESS C a s h expenditures + other e x p e n d i t u r e s depreciation, inventory shortages + farm taxes and
interest on
debts
=TOTAL E X P E N D I T U R E S and
FARM
FARM
TAXES
INCOME
: income from production factors of land, labor, capital,and management FARM =
INCOME
per h a
I
net land p r o d u c t i v i t y ^ ^ « — — "
FARM —
=
INCOME
LESS
MY
LESS I for h i r e d labor i n d . s o c i a l and accident i n s u r a n c e perquisites, and h o u s ης
I Interest p a y m e n t s on working capital
Wages
LABOR INCOME
GROSS
NCOME
income of the farm f a m i l y f r o m labor and capital LESS
W a g e e s t i m a t e for t h e f a r m
NET
RETURN
C A P I T A L INCOME
Figure 3
per
net labor productivity
family-
23
Glossary
— gross income = Farm income minus hired labor expenditures = Income of the farm family from land, labor, capital, and management. — labor income of the farm family = Gross income minus interest payments on working capital. — net return = Gross income minus wage claims of family labor = Interest payments on working capital plus operator's profit. — gross land productivity = Gross output per ha FL — gross labor productivity = Gross output per MY — net land productivity = Farm income per ha FL — net labor productivity = Farm income per MY Livestock production based on grain feed can be: hog fattening, poultry raising, and egg production. Abbrevations and concepts for the agriculture of the East Bloc — Agricultural-Industrial Complex (AIC) = Totality of the economic domains which contributes to agricultural production or shares in the manufacture of foodstuffs (GDR — German Democratic Republic). — Agricultural Producers' Cooperative (APC) = Legally autonomous collective farm; differentiated into types I to III according to the amount of production factors used (GDR). — Agro-Chemical Center (ACC) = Specialized service enterprise that stores, transports, and provides fertilizers of all kinds for participating farms (GDR). = Collective of farmers that — Brigade fulfills production goals set by the cooperatives (GDR). — Cooperative Organization (COO)
= New farm type, developed through the collaboration of the APC and PE (People's Estate) organi-
Glossary
— Kolkhoz
— Kombinat for Industrial Fattening
- Machine Tractor Station
- People's Estate (PE)
— People's Commune (PC)
— Sovkhoz
(MTS)
(KIF)
zations, service organizations, as well as units of the Food and Trade Economies (GDR). Farm type in the Soviet Union; cooperative formed by the collectivization of former peasant farms (USSR). Large, state-owned industrial farm specializing in the production of a specific animal product, e.g. cattle, hogs, poultry (GDR). A former machinery-lending station in the Soviet agricultural system, with repair shops. Now replaced by the Farm Machinery Association (FMA). State farm created after 1945 through expropriation and consolidation of farmland (GDR). Type of agricultural organization in China; embraces entire districts; organized into production bridges. The commune is a multi-purpose institution and includes, besides agricultural production functions, those of a political, administrative, and communal nature. (PRC — People's Republic of China). Farm type in the Soviet Union; state farm created through expropriation of large estates or land reclamation (USSR).
Glossary
25
Glossary of Tropical and Subtropical Crops English
Botanical
German
cocoa, cacao coffee tea tobacco
Luxury Plants Theobroma cacao L. Coffea spec. Thea (Camellia) sinensis L. Nicotiana spec.
Kakaobaum Kaffee Tee Tabak
Para rubber, caoutchouc tree gutta-percha
Rubber and Gum Plants Hevea brasiliensis Muell. Arg. Sapo taceae
gum arabic tree
Acacia spec.
Guttaperchaliefernde Pflanzen Gummiakazien
Oil and Fat-Producing Plants Elaeis guineensis Jacq. Cocos nucífera L. Olea europaea L. Glycine max L. Arachis hypogaea L. Sesamum indicum DC. Rincinus communis L.
Ölpalme Kokospalme Ölbaum Soja Erdnuß Sesam Rizinus
oil palm coconut palm olive soybean peanut, groundnut sesame castor bean, castor oil plant
Parakautschukbaum
manioc, cassava yam sweet potato
Roots and Tubers Manihot esculenta Crantz Dioscorea spec. Ipomoea batatas Poir.
banana, plantain pineapple citrus fruits date palm fig mango
Fruit Crops Musa spec. Ananas comosus Merr. Citrus spec. Phoenix dactylifera L. Ficus carica L. Mangifera indica L.
Banane Ananas Zitrus Dattelpalme Feigenbaum Mangobaum
sugarcane
Sugar-Producing Plants Saccharum officinarum L.
Zuckerrohr
rice corn, maize sorghum millet
Grains Oryza sativa L. Zea mays L. Andropogoneae Paniceae
Reis Mais Hirsen, große Hirsen, kleine
Maniok Yam Batate or Süßkartoffel
26
English cotton kapok, silk cotton tree jute deccan hemp, kenaf roselle hemp, sorrel ramie, China grass, rhea sisal abaca, Manila hemp
Glossary
Botanical
German
Fiber Plants Gossypium spec. Ceiba spec.
Baumwolle Kapok
Corchorus spec. Hibiscus cannabinus L. Hibiscus sabdariffa L. Boehmeria spec.
Jute Kenaf Roselle Ramie
Agave sisalana Perline Musa textilis Νees
Sisal Faserbanane
Introduction: Origins and Evolution of Agriculture A Three-Stage Theory
The development of agriculture can be divided roughly into three epochs. These three stages, all of which have been experienced by the industrial countries, still exist side by side in the developing areas. 1. The representatives of economies that simply occupy, or appropriate space (gatherers, hunters, fishermen, and herders) struggle against the pressure for expanding their radius of action. Entire races, such as the Bushmen, pygmies, aborigines, or Patagonians, have starved or languished to the extent of their depletion of food sources. Their problem has been a growing lack of space. The primitive exploitive stage and early phase of gathering takes up the overwhelming part of the historical period of the economic development of man: 98—99 % (Manshard 1968, p. 20). The nomadic population of the six Sahel nations has grown in the last three decades at an annual rate of about 1.7 %. Overgrazing has been the result. When, then, a severe drought also set in during the last few years, a catastrophic famine ensued, its severity shocking the world. Nature had cruelly corrected the biological balance, which economies at this primitive level and with growing populations can hardly maintain. The spatial problem had become a survival problem. 2. Limited food reserves and a narrow radius of action for man and animals thus set limits to expansion, and sooner or later force human groups to turn to exploitive economies. The stage of hoe culture, later of plow culture, is now attained. Clearing and cultivation supplement harvesting. Agriculture has now evolved from the simple collections of wild plants. Only now can one speak of farmers. Their history takes in only about the last 10,000 years. Steppe-shifting, bog-burning, and forest-burning systems of shifting cultivation are examples of such soil-exploiting economies. Man draws deeply from nature's budget without having as yet the means for reimbursement. As a result, fertility-depleting agriculture must be followed in a few years by many years of grass, bush, or forest fallow, so that the fertility and ecological balance which the deficient hand of man has damaged or destroyed may be restored. These events are not historical reminiscences. Shifting cultivation is still predominantly practiced by more than 200 million people over an area
28
Introduction
of more than 30 million km 2 . Nor does the cause of this system lie in the economic irrationality of a population that is practically at the cultural stage of the Neolithic. So long as settlement remains dispersed, this economy can even be carried on with great efficiency. By using lavishly extensive and easily available land supplies, labor expenditures are minimized and almost all capital investment is dispensed with, and thus a minimum cost combination in the prevailing factor cost relationships is attained. Growing population nevertheless leads to a fateful vicious circle: more cropland is needed and for that reason the fallowing period is shortened. A shorter fallowing period leads to incomplete regeneration of soil fertility. Decreasing crop yields stimulate further expansion at the expense of the fallowed land — and so on. With such a self-destructive system the Mayan culture shifted more and more from the center of the Yucatan Peninsula to the periphery until, reaching the ocean, was extinguished. (P. Gourou: The Tropical World. New York, 1961). 3. With increasing population density, therefore, exploitive economies too are finally no longer able to provide sufficient food. More forms of land use emphasizing cultivation are now required. Once again the spatial problem becomes more discriminating. Plow culture requires plowable soil and thus cleared land. According to the principle of minimum expenditures, therefore, all agricultural peoples have first selected the treeless steppes and prairies, the natural grassland. The coniferous forests, which set down shallow roots and allowed clearing by burning, followed. Only after this did permanent cropping penetrate the regions of the deep-rooted forests. When Slavs came from the east and settled Mecklenburg, they simply passed through the beech and oak forests which were closer to them in the east. They settled first in the more distant western part of the country because there in the coniferous forests the work required for clearing was modest. Also, they could use their iron hook plow better in the light soils. Thus the available agricultural technology determines the choice of area. Malawi is an overpopulated agricultural country and yet possesses extensive unutilized land resources. But the soils are so heavy that they still cannot be worked at the stage of hoe culture that prevails there. Only if more powerful energy sources are made available in the form of draft animals or tractors can these areas be converted to cropland. Up to now only the subsistence economies have been considered. Since cities and markets develop earlier and more vigorously than infra-structures, a new spatial, or locational problem confronts market-oriented agriculture in its supply and demand situation. The ancient cultural centers of mankind did not lie on the Nile, in Mesopotamia, on the Indus
Introduction
29
and Ganges, on the Mekong Delta, or on the Yangtze simply because of the food-production capacity of the fertile alluvial soils and the possibilities for irrigation; here waterways guaranteed what at the time was, even more than today, the cheapest form of transport. To the same extent that the growing population had to push the settlement area farther and farther into the interior, the problem of transport access worsened. When Thünen's "Der isolierte Staat" appeared for the first time in 1826, the "steamship (from 1807) and the railroad (from 1825) were only in their infancy, and sixty years would have to pass before the first motor vehicle (1886) appeared. Otherwise Thünen's space picture would have looked different. The concentric rings would have retreated to a more radial arrangement of farming types. In the less accessible areas within the developing countries agricultural systems are often less a function of market distance than they are of distance from the major transport arteries. Only when the transport network thickens and transport charges lower as national economic development progresses, does the farmer again free himself of the locative disadvantage of the more outlying areas. Then he can adapt much better to the natural locative restrictions. With the greatly increased number of production methods this is also now far more necessary and far more possible. Eventually, further economic growth and a wealth of technical advances lead to such a complete control of natural forces by means of irrigation, drainage, fertilization, plant protection, adaption of the genetic potentials of plants and animals, and the like, that the farmer can carry on his business much more independently of the natural spatial or areal factors. Consequently in highly developed industrial countries the personality of the farm operator dominates to a degree heretofore unknown. Emotional, and not spatial or locational problems now come to the fore. Thus the evolution of agriculture might be viewed as a variation on the well-supported three-stage theories of Richard Krzymowski (Geschichte der deutschen Landwirtschaft [History of German Agriculture]. Stuttgart, 1951) and Eduard Hahn (Von der Hacke zum Pflug [From the Hoe to the Plow]. Leipzig, 1914), one that would normally proceed as follows: Occupation Exploitation Cultivation (Appropriation) (Depletion) (Husbandry)
I. Agricultural Geography as a Science
To keep the focus of this book on specific agricultural-geographic subjects as much as possible, this chapter was made very brief and fragmentary. In spite of its methodological significance, the author believed allowances could be made since major statements already are available on this subject. Besides noting the cited sources, the reader should refer to the bibliography and especially the pertinent works on economic geography listed there.
1. Definitions Agricultural geography is defined by Otremba (1976, p. 62) as the science of that part of the earth surface transformed by agriculture, not only as a whole but in its parts, its physiognomy, its inner structure, and its interrelationships. Agriculture is understood to be the management of the land for purposes of producing plant and animal products to satisfy human needs. Agriculture certainly is also a way of life, but primarily it is an economy. Thus agricultural geography is obviously a branch of cultural geography, but even more a component of economic geography. The following basic agrospatial concepts, according to Manshard (1968, p. 10 f.), are of help in understandig agricultural-geographic relationships: Agricultural space is a term applied to any land surface that is used agriculturally in any form whatsoever. In contrast, an agricultural area is defined as a spatial unit characterized by a clear dominance of farming. Structurally, it is a part of a larger heterogeneous spatial unit such as a state or physical area. Agricultural zones are agricultural areas that can be associated with different climatic and vegetation belts and exhibit a definite structural and physiognomic uniformity. The agricultural region is a part of the earth surface which, on the basis of defined geofactors and social and historic realities, possesses specific field and settlement forms, technical resources, and crop and livestock economies, and whose agrarian structure bears definite uniform characteristics. Further definitions can be found in the glossary on page 15.
1. Agricultural Geography as a Science
31
2. Objectives and Significance of Agricultural Geography A major objective of agricultural geography is the analysis of the agriculturally structured areas and their natural, economic, and social relationships and organizations as reflected spatially. The primary goal of agricultural geography, according to Manshard (1968, p. 9), consists of investigating the spatial differentiation of the various manifestations of agriculture. The results of such agricultural-geographic studies are necessary for any transforming activity of man, insofar as they are spatially oriented. Agricultural geography provides help for decision-makers: the demographic planner, who plans public services and utilities; the transportation engineer, who has to determine the routing of auto expressways or the siting of new ports; the regional planner, who is looking for the most favorable location for recreation areas; the agricultural specialist, who wishes to improve the agricultural structure; the hydraulic engineer, who is planning new dams; the food economist, who wishes to optimize the production and distribution of foodstuffs; and numerous other specialists. The smaller the planning area, the more the agricultural sciences can help; the larger the planning area, however, the more agricultural geography must provide the necessary aid (e.g. for the UNO, FAO, UNESCO). Thus it is no surprise that agricultural geography is especially well developed in the two large countries of the U.S. and U.S.S.R. Further objectives of agricultural geography and their connection with agricultural economics were already sketched in the foreword of this volume.
3. Work Methods of Agricultural Geography As a subdiscipline of economic geography, agricultural geography combines the elements and work methods of geography with those of the economic and agricultural sciences (Manshard 1968, p. 9). Thus work methods are as diverse as problems raised. In principle, one frequently takes the following steps in agricultural-geographic investigations: 1. Precise formulation of the problem. 2. Determination of the research design. 3. Data collection a) Collection and organization of primary data (building types, crop rotation systems, etc.), b) Collection and processing of secondary data (global and especially regional statistics; in part, even bookkeeping information and farm surveys).
32
I. Agricultural Geography as a Science
4. Areal organization of data by agrospatial units, if possible by mapping; in other cases, graphs, diagrams, and tables may help. 5. Spatial analysis of the processed data with the help of methods, information, and theories from geography, the natural sciences, and economics. 6. Derivation of basic conclusions through elimination of exceptional cases. 7. Answering of the questions first raised with the principal results of the investigation.
II. The Climatic Zones of World Agricultural Space and their Significant Features for the Agricultural Economy Whoever wishes to study and to understand the spatial arrangement of world agriculture must keep in mind the climatic zones. They are the most important differentiating force on a world scale. It is on them, therefore, that our first and foremost interest must be focused. Fig. 4 indicates the most important climatic zones of Africa, and it is supplemented by Fig. 5.
1. Tropical Rainy Climates The tropical rainy climates are identical with the collective notions of "humid tropics" or "inner tropics." From the agricultural-geographic standpoint one must be concerned with at least a threefold subdivision:
a) Rainforest Climate This climate is found in the equatorial lowlands. The Congo Basin and the Guinea Coast stand out in Fig. 4. The Amazon Basin and large parts of Indonesia also have a rainforest climate. This climate is hot and moist throughout the year. Two rainy seasons totaling at least 1,500 mm of precipitation, no month with less than 60 mm rainfall, an average temperature varying only between 25° and 28°C during the entire year, and a relative humidity seldom falling below 90% (6:00 a.m.) produce a moist climatic type that brings forth an evergreen, ombrophylic rainforest. This is the proverbial luxuriant tropical vegetation that the layman usually identifies with all tropical vegetation, though it occurs only in a relatively small part of the tropics, and just in the rainforest climate. The rainforest climate has eight-and-a-half to twelve wet months and thus must be characterized as humid to perhumid. Since the natural vegetation of this climate is forest, it is no surprise that bush and tree crops are favored among the cultivated plants: cacao, rubber, oil palms, coco palms, and coffee ( C o f f e a robusta). With the exception of the palms, these crops provide no basic foodstuffs. That partly explains the sparse settlement of the Amazon and Congo basins. Bananas, sugarcane, manioc, yams, corn, and under certain conditions, rice, are also cultivated. Conditions for livestock raising in this climate are extraordinarily unfavorable, as they also are for man, and particularly for whites, who cannot tolerate well this constantly moist and hot climate.
34
II. The Climatic Zones of World Agricultural Space
b) Humid Savanna Climate The humid savanna bounds the rainforest belt on both northern and southern margins. Its climate, with its six to eight-and-a-half wet months and 600 to 1,500 mm of rain, is subhumid. Rainfall is concentrated in one long rainy period in the summer, followed by a short dry period in the winter. Grasslands occur as luxurious grass savannas with gallery forests, and woodlands take the form of monsoon forests.
36
II. The Climatic Zones of World Agricultural Space
The raising of ruminants is now possible since the danger of disease, in contrast to the situation in the rainforest climate, is less. On the demand side, livestock raising is of course still restricted because of the low purchasing power of the population. The contact zone between the humid savanna and rainforest climates is designated as the wet boundary of grazing. The crops of the rainforest climate that demand the most water, such as cacao, rubber, and coffee, are little cultivated in the humid savanna climate, and the cultivation of oil palms and manioc also diminishes. Even yams become somewhat uncertain. In contrast, new types enter the cultivated plant society, crops that require a dry period for ripening: bush beans (Phaseolous) and peanuts.
c) Tropical Highland Climates One cannot speak of a tropical highland climate in the singular, for here, depending on the altitude, slope, exposure, and conditions of moisture, light, and heat, can be found more diverse climatic variants than anywhere else. The association with the tropical rainforest climates is also problematical, because dry climates also occur in tropical highlands, and temperate or even Arctic climatic elements appear in very high regions of the Himalayas and Andes. Tropical highlands begin, by general agreement, at about 100 m above sea level, The average annual temperature in Madras, at sea level, comes to 27.8°C, but at the 2,280 m-high hill station of Ootocamund, in the Nilgiri Mountains, reaches only 13.8°C. This is a difference of ± 0.6°C per m. As a result, in the tropical semiarid lowland millet, sorghum, and peanuts dominate the landscape and in the moist monsoon climate of the Indian southwest coast rubber, pepper, bananas, and manioc are grown. In the high mountains, however, which are still frost-free, tea, coffee ( C o f f e a arabica), potatoes, and vegetables are cultivated (Piekenbrock 1958, p. 20). Thus somewhat the same succession of agricultural landscapes that we encounter on a trip from the Congo to the Mediterranean or from Amazonas to the La Plata can be experienced again with an ascent of a few hundred kilometers in high mountains along the equator. There are specific altitudinal levels, physiologically determined and economically relevant, for our cultivated plants. In the equatorial zone (10° N.L. to 10° S.L.) many crops have an — altitudinal minimum. Economic cultivation of coffee, e.g., is only possible above 950 m, tea above 1,300 m, potatoes and passion fruit above 1,600 m, and wheat only above 2,000 m. Also diverse is the - altitudinal range. Coffee ( C o f f e a arabica) extends from 950 to 2,000 m, corn from 0 to 2,800 m. All crops, however, have an
2. Dry Climates
37
— altitudinal boundary. In Costa Rica, e.g., cultivation of rice stops at 1000 m, coffee at 1,450 m, sugarcane at 1,500 m, cooking bananas (plantain) at 1,700 m, and criollo grasses at 2,000 m, whereas imported grasses, red clover, corn, potatoes, and European vegetable types ascend to 2,800 m (Spielmann 1969, pp. 4 2 - 5 1 ) .
2. Dry Climates The dry climates are set off from the tropical rainy climates by the climatic dry boundary, where the number of humid months in the year now comes to, at most, six. While the tropical rainy climate is usually characterized agriculturally by a water surplus, all tropical dry climates, without exception, suffer from a water deficit. This situation also applies to what are called the outer tropics. Dry climates are not only found in the tropics, but in the subtropics and in the temperate and even cooler latitudes as well. Common agricultural characteristics nevertheless appear to allow their treatment as a group.
a) Dry Savanna Climate This type clearly belongs to the tropics, as the vegetation formations of the savannas occur almost exclusively there. The dry savannas usually insert themselves as a very small belt between the humid savannas and shrub savannas. Larger areas of this climatic type are found throughout almost the entire Zambezi Basin, in the southern part of the Sahel Zone, in western Malagasy, as a belt through India, in northernmost Australia, and in parts of Mexico. Three-and-a-half to six humid months permit rainfed farming, i.e. cropping without irrigation. Grasslands take the form of short grass savannas, and woodlands appear as deciduous dry forest (e.g. miombo). In contrast to the humid savanna, the rainy season is much shorter and less favorable for production. With only 300 to 600 mm of rain a year, the climate is definitely semiarid. It is an example of the typical alternately wet-and-dry tropics. Cropping now can be supported only by the most drought-resistant crops, mostly millet, sorghum, peanuts, and bush beans. Even the cultivation of yams is no longer possible because of the long dry season. Shifting cultivation must often be resorted to in order to save water. In contrast to the temperate climate, however, livestock raising becomes more important relative to crop farming because of the increasing competitive advantage resulting from the dryness. Thus dryland cropping and extensive grazing are competitive in this climatic zone from the standpoints of both farming system and regional physical environment. Their
38
II. The Climatic Zones of World Agricultural Space
various types, as well as the ecological and economic competition factors, will have to be thoroughly analyzed and interpreted in Chapter VII.
b) Shrub Savanna Climate The shrub savannas are set off from the dry savannas agricultural-geographically by the so-called dry boundary, the boundary of rainfed farming. Thus there is practically nothing but extensive grazing in the shrub savannas. Indeed, irrigation can gain little additional farmland because of the low water table and the fact that even large rivers have no steady flows because of the very long dry period. Only an exceedingly onesided agricultural landscape can develop in this semiarid climate, with its short rainy season of up to four humid months at the most and just 100 to 300 mm precipitation. Natural pastures are used with littledemanding animals, more with cattle in the direction of the equator but more with sheep in the poleward direction. This type of livestock grazing is practiced in the New World on cattle farms (ranches) and in the Old World still frequently by nomads. The shrub savanna climate includes the largest part of Southwest Africa and the.Kalahari, and the northern portion of the Sahel Zone. Further
Climatic
Inner
Zones of the
Tropics
Outer
Qraj_iTV c_l i m a t_e s_| Humid
Rainforest humid
zone
D R Y
Tropics
Humid
savanna subhumid
Dry
savanna
semiarid
^Tropical Over
C L I M A T E S Dry
Tropics
Tropics
Shrubland
Tropics
steppe
semiand
\l,500 N
> 1.500 m m
humid
;
Semi-desert arid
Desert arid
months
Constantly Tropics
I RAINY
SEASON
per year
12-8,5
Figure 6
- 600 m m
SEASONS
8,5-6 Wet
6-3,5 W e t - a n d Tropics
Dry
3,5-1
< 1
Dry
1,000m
above sea level
C o n d i t i o n s of heat and h u m i d i t y v a r y considerably a c c o r d i n g to a l t i t u d e and e x p o s u r e . Climate generally s i m i l a r to that of the humid s a v a n n a
a n n u a l precipitation
2 RAINY
Highlands
Tropics
< 1
2. Dry Climates
39
examples are southern Somalia and South Ethiopia and a broad zone of northern Australia. Fig. 6 may facilitate the overview of the tropical climates with its schematic presentation (p. 36).
c) Steppe Climate Steppes have an agricultural-geographical character that is similar to that of the dry and shrub savannas. They are often not suitable for rainfed farming, though they are pasture areas par excellence. Overall, they suffer from a lack of water for man, plants, and animals. But the steppes lie beyond the tropics of Cancer and Capricorn, in the subtropical and middle latitude climates. This leads to a modification of the economic characteristics that apply to the dry and shrub savannas: — Precipitation in the shrub and dry savannas declines — as everywhere in the tropics — in the summer, but in the steppes usually in the winter. The result is that animals in the steppes are exposed to greater stress, since calves and lambs must be nursed while the vegetation is dormant — and all this in the greater summer heat. — The network of watering places must be denser because the foragepoor season coincides with the heat period. — Under certain conditions there is a need to keep feed in reserve for the dry season. — Under certain conditions there is also the need in the continental cold-winter climate to protect the animals from inclement weather with primitive stalls. — Under certain conditions less productive animal breeds or varieties must be given priority because of their greater cold resistance, such as the yak in interior Asia or the llama in the Andes. — Cultivated plants are now completely different from those in the dry tropics because of the varying light and heat conditions from place to place. Large steppe areas are found in the Intermountain states of the United States, in North Africa, in the Spanish Meseta, in the Don area, and in large parts of interior Asia.
d) Semidesert Climate The arid semidesert with less than 100 mm precipitation per year form the transition from the shrub savannas and steppes to the dry-hot deserts with their still scantier and only sporadic rainfall. Deserts usually lie beyond the dry boundary of habitation, though they are partly utilized
40
II. The Climatic Zones of World Agricultural Space
by desert nomads, and industries of sorts develop in the vicinities of oases and oil wells. It is well established climatologically that almost all large deserts of the world lie on or near the tropics of Cancer and Capricorn. This is pretty much the situation for the Sahara and the Arabian Desert, the Namib and all of interior Australia, and the Iranian, Pakistani, and interior Asian deserts (in Kazakhstan, Uzbekistan, eastern Turkestan, etc.). Thus the semideserts surrounding the deserts also lie near the two tropics and therefore cannot be easily differentiated as to whether they belong to tropical or subtropical areas. Only the somewhat more humid zones of the semideserts can still be used for sedentary grassland farming. The remaining portions can be used only episodically by nomads, hunters, and gatherers. The dry boundary of livestock grazing thus extends through the middle of the semideserts.
3. Humid Warm-Temperate Climates The three variants of this climatic group are distinguished from each other, from the agricultural-geographic viewpoint, not only in temperature conditions but in the amount of precipitation and especially its distribution.
a) Subtropical Dry-Summer Climate Representatives of this climatic type are the Mediterranean area, the south coast of the Black Sea, a wide zone from the Caucasus to almost the Persian Gulf, the hinterland of Capetown, the largest part of California, central Chile, and parts of the south coast of Australia. Agriculture bears the stamp of warm, moist winters and hot, dry summers. This climate becomes more extreme as we approach the dry climates. In North Africa, only the typical winter rainy season allows rainfed farming, whereas in the summer drought and heat preclude all cropping without irrigation. Of the four regions in Table 1, all but the Po Plain belong to the subtropical dry-summer climate. One can see that the total yearly precipitation, though in itself not insignificant, is unfavorably distributed. Thus in the June-to-August quarter only 104 mm fall on the Campanian coast, no more than 86 mm fall in northern Apulia, and just 71 mm fall on the coast of the Ionian Sea. These amounts are respectively 8.3, 13.3, and 8.9% of the yearly total, and their use effectiveness, moreover, with a mean temperature of 23°C, has to be very low. Under such extreme ecological restrictions agricultural land use is a compromise decision between
3. Humid Warm-Temperate Climates
41
Table 1: Climatic Data for Italy (Ten-Year Averages) Quarter
Lower Po Piain (Bassa Padania)
Tyrrhenian Coast (Campania)
I. Precipitation Dec. March June Sept.
- Feb. — May — Aug. — Nov.
Annual Total
Coast of the Ionia Sea
in mm
186 200 160 230
440 259 104 378
213 161 86 187
324 169 71 231
776
1,181
647
796
II. Mean Dec. March June Sept.
Northern Apulia
Temperatures in °C
- Feb. — May — Aug. — Nov.
2.5 12.3 22.4 13.7
7.9 13.0 23.4 16.9
6.5 12.4 22.7 15.8
7.9 13.0 23.4 16.9
Annual Mean
12.7
15.3
14.4
15.3
Source: Annuario di Statistica Agraria 1948, Rome, 1948. Cited by M. Rolfes, Die betriebswirtschaftlichen Grundlagen des Zuckerrübenbaues in den Ländern der Europäischen Wirtschaftsgemeinschaft, Teil II. Manuscript reproduced by the Forschungsgesellschaft fur Agrarpolitik und Agrarsoziologie e.V., Bonn, 1961, pp. 47 and 56.
— the restriction of cropping to the fall, winter, and spring months; — the shift to bush and tree crops, which through their deep root systems can better endure the summer dryness (grapes, olives, almonds)/ and — irrigated agriculture. Usually, in the interest of maximizing income, it is not a question of selecting one of these three options but of deciding on the appropriate combination of two or all three.
b) Subtropical Warm-Summer Climate For this climatic type, Table 1 offers some data for the Po Plain. It is apparent that temperatures are lower and precipitation is more evenly distributed. Here the summer heat can be used for agriculture without irrigation. Important world farming areas are associated with this climate: a large part of China, southern Japan, parts of the Australian east coast, large parts of northern India, southeastern United States, Brazil south of the tropic, and the La Plata countries.
42
II. The Climatic Zones of World Agricultural Space
If summer temperatures are sufficient, then heat-loving crops like rice, peanuts, soybeans, or cotton can be cultivated. If the winters are still mild enough, year-around crop production with two or even three harvests per year is possible. Then crops which like a cooler climate, such as grapes, winter grain, or forage crops, are planted in the winter, and those which require a warm climate, such as rice, soybeans, sweet potatoes, or vegetables, are grown in the summer. In this way, crop rotations can be developed within a calendar year, as the following examples show. Crop Rotations in Southern Japan (Tsuzuki 1963, p. 210) Example A: Example Β : Winter: renge grass Winter: w. grain Summer: rice Spring: vegetables Summer: rice Summer: vegetables
c) Marine Cool-Summer Climate This climatic type, also designated as oceanic, has its widest distribution in the European Community area, which except for Italy is almost totally encompassed here. Mild winters and cool summers are characteristic: a climate which vigorously promotes fodder growth and consequently is also favorable for cattle raising. This is still more the situation when longer and even year-around pasturing is possible (Cornwall, parts of Normandy, areas around the Bay of Biscay). Such climatic conditions reduce feeding and building costs and thus increase profitability. Root crops (sugar beets, potatoes) and grains dominate the fields. Among the grains, wintergrown types rank first because the long fall easily permits their cultivation, even after the root crops. All other areas with marine cool-summer climate are very much smaller and, with the exception of a northerly coastal strip in western North America, lie in the southern hemisphere: the tip of southeast Australia, New Zealand, the southern tip of South America, and large parts of the Republic of South Africa.
4. Humid Cool-Temperate Climates Under this designation are subsumed climates in which the most important agricultural criterion is not the amount of precipitation, but the minimum temperature.
4. Humid Cool-Temperate Climates
43
a) Continental Warm-Summer Climate For the continental warm-summer climate, this restriction still does not apply to the summer, to be sure, but to the winter whose lengthening leads to a longer rest period for vegetation. Significant grain corn areas are found in this climatic area, thus the American Corn Belt south and west (up to 100° W.L.) of Chicago and the greatest part of the Balkan area. China north of Peking, Korea, and large portions of northern Japan also belong here. Besides corn, soybeans also grow well to some extent.
b) Continental Cool-Summer Climate Now the winter becomes still longer and colder and the summer also cooler. Precipitation falls predominantly in the summer. Agriculture reacts with an emphasis on spring-grain and fodder cropping. The latter already assumes well-established forms in such areas as the Dairy Belt of northeastern United States and southeastern Canada, central Sweden, and the Baltic Provinces. Only three large areas display these climatic features: one, the area north of the Sea of Japan; another, a broad belt in North America which extends from New York and Halifax through the Great Lakes and well beyond Winnipeg; and a third, the great block of central and eastern Europe, delimited approximately by the cities of Oslo — Szczecin (Stettin) — Vienna — Magnitogorsk — Leningrad.
c) Subarctic Climate Finally, poleward of the continental cool-summer climate, and naturally only in the northern hemisphere, is the subarctic climatic belt which extends northward beyond the Arctic Circle. Characteristic features are a moderately warm summer, a very long and cold winter, a concentrated summer precipitation, and a natural coniferous forest flora. The region includes almost all of Scandinavia north of the three capitals, the U.S.S.R. approximately north of a line through Leningrad — Tomsk — Irkutsk, as well as a broad belt of northern Canada and Alaska extending from the regions around southern Hudson Bay westward to the Bering Sea. The Arctic Circle passes through all these large areas. The same climate also appears at the higher medium and high mountain elevations of more southerly latitudes, such as the Alps, Carpathians, and Andes. For agriculture, the most significant of all climatic features is the short growing season. It allows fodder cropping to dominate even more than in the continental cool-summer climate, and of course always in well-
44
II. The Climatic Zones of World Agricultural Space
established forms. Fodder cropping is superior here despite the long stallfeeding period because it completely utilizes the effective plant growth period, from the first day to the last, whereas with crops which have to be replanted annually, a part of the costly and all too short growing season is lost in planting, cultivating, and harvesting. To this handicap should be added the rapid impoverishment of the domesticated plant community toward the north, as the specific polar boundaries are exceeded. The cultivation of sugar beets finally stops at 61° N.L., that of wheat at 63°, and that of spring barley and potatoes at 70°. Thus crop rotations in the far north are only possible in ley farming systems, in which four to six or more years of grassland cropping are followed by one or two years of spring barley and potatoes.
III. The Delimitation of World Agricultural Space 1. The Expansion of World Agricultural Space as a Current Problem By 1976, world population had exceeded the 4-billion mark, or sixteen times the number, quarter of a billion, living in the time of Christ. By 2007, that number is expected by the UNO to reach 7.7 billion, and by 2050 to come to as much as 14 to 15 billion. According to projections by the FAO, world food demands by the year 2050 will be seventeen to eighteen times that of 1960. Already more than two thirds of the world population lives in the developing countries. Nearly 400 million people suffer from hunger. By about 1985, the number of afflicted may well rise to 750 million. During this period, to be sure, sizable food surpluses in the developed countries must also be taken into account; but in the developing countries an increase in demand of around 70% will only be matched by an increase in production of less than 50% (Matzke 1975, p. 362). What can be done so that food production will not just keep pace with population growth, but will surpass it in providing the adequate diet so urgently needed? Basically, agricultural productivity can be increased three ways: 1. through an increase in operational intensity by means of augmented investment in irrigation, fertilization, pest control, plants and animals of high genetic quality, etc; 2. through an increase in organizational intensity, that is, through successive substitution of intensive enterprises for extensive ones, thus e.g. roots and tubers in place of grains or dairying instead of cattle fattening; and 3. through an expansion of agricultural space beyond its present boundaries. As Table 2 shows, only about a third of the world land surface is now used agriculturally, and that with a 2:1 ratio of permanent grassland to cropland. The agricultural share of land in the agricultural countries is clearly lower than in the industrial countries. Countries with extremely small agricultural shares are almost without exception developing countries, whereas those with extremely high agricultural proportions are to be found among the industrial countries. Thus agricultural proportions are the lowest where most people are undernourished or even starving. In contrast, where agricultural surpluses are accumulating, as in Western Europe, agricultural shares are the highest. There must be reasons for this.
46
III. The Delimitation of World Agricultural Space
Table 2: Proportion of Land in Agriculture Geographic or Political Unit
Permanent Cropland Grassland
Bush and Tree Crops
Total Agricultural Area
% of Total Area A. World B.
Continents South America Africa Asia 1 Europe 1
22.4
11.0
33.4
21.6 26.3 19.5 18.4
4.9 6.9 17.5 29.3
26.5 33.2 37.0 47.7
Development2
C. National Groups by Stage of Economic Agricultural Countries Industrial Countries D. Countries with Extremely Bahamas Egypt Oman Libya E. Countries with Extremely Nigeria West Germany Australia Denmark 1
3
20.6 27.6 Small Proportion 0.1 3
4.7 4.0
0.1 2.7 0.1 1.3
High Proportion 27.1 21.7 59.1 6.7
30.7 39.7
10.1 12.1
30.5 5.8 61.6
of Land in 0.1
of Land in 23.6 2.2 0.4
Agriculture
0.9 0.1 0.1
1.1 2.8 4.9 5.3
Agriculture 50.7 54.4 65.0 68.7
Excluding U.S.S.R. — 2 Excluding countries with centrally controlled economies. Source: F AO, Production Yearbook, Vol. 27 (1973), Rome, 1974, pp. 3 ff. - = none, or in negligible quantity.
The boundaries of agricultural space can be drawn on the bases of cold, drought, wetness, soil salinization, market isolation, and other agents. Accordingly, one speaks of polar boundaries, altitudinal boundaries, dry boundaries, wet boundaries, settlement boundaries, and so forth. It is by no means as simple to delineate these boundaries of world agricultural space. This is because they are not lines, but zones, and within these zones three different boundary lines have to be defined: (1)the effective boundary, the actual limit of agricultural production according to land use statistics; (2) the profitability boundary, the boundary where returns equal zero; and (3) the technological boundary, the boundary up to which land could be farmed according to the current stage of technology, if economic considerations were waived.
1. The Expansion of World Agricultural Space
47
Only the first, the actual boundary, will be discussed. It is not fixed, but on the contrary fluctuates with the successes and failures of economic life. After the last war, in Siegerland, the unproductive and finally extinct Hauberg farming system was revived. By 1976, a total of 310,00 ha in West Germany was no longer being used agriculturally, though it was still arable (social fallow). The fluctuation of the actual boundaries of agricultural space is almost identical with that of the limits of the inhabited area. That the correlation is not complete is shown by examples such as oil drilling in the desert. With greater population density, minor income demands, and food shortage, the actual boundary shifts toward the profitability boundary or even coincides with it, though the profitability boundary also advances under such conditions because of higher prices for agricultural products. Thus under these conditions the three boundaries are close to one another, i.e. the boundary zone is narrow. The situation is quite different with low prices for agricultural products and high income demands of the rural population. The actual boundary then retreats from the marginal locations, while the technological boundary is characterized by far-flung outposts. The boundary zone is therefore wide and within it occurs what we today, for example, label as highland exodus in the western European mountains of moderate altitude or in the Apennines. Here the highland boundary of agricultural space is lowering. An analogous phenomenon is found today in the semidesert areas around the Sahara, where the meager pastures can no longer be used. The dry boundary of agricultural space is retreating here, the effective dry boundary moving away from the technological. It is obvious that at present the reverse movement, the advance of the farming boundaries, is stronger and more frequent. Thus, for example, in the tropical rainy climates with trifling population densities, agricultural boundaries are being extended outward with every new road and railroad. A broad band of pioneer farms originates to the right and left of these transportation arteries because, although not shortening the spatial distance from market, they do reduce the economic distance so that the effective transportation boundary can expand around the market site in eccentric rings. The chains of pioneer farms that are pushing forward in this way into the Amazon or Congo basins in the tropical forest region soon result in country-town or city-like settlements, so that the spatial distance to market is also reduced and additional settlements become viable on the periphery. From all this it follows that the boundaries of the farming area can be conditioned not only ecologically but economically.
III. The Delimitation of World Agricultural Space
48
2. Ecological Boundaries of Farming In the following we shall first look at the characteristics of the individual ecologically-determined boundaries of the farming area and their approximate courses.
a) Polar Boundaries The polar boundaries of cultivated plants are more important for the industrial countries than for the developing ones. As indicated in Fig. 7, potatoes and spring barley push farthest into the high north, up to about 70° N.L. This is possible only through ley cropping and (or) fallowing, as Overview 1 makes clear. Overview J: Crop Rotation Types in Lapland
Β
A Arctic Circle 1.—5. 6. 7. 8.
D North Cape
Grassland 1.— 8. Grassland Potatoes, oats 9. S. barley Fallow 10. Potatoes S. barley 11. S. barley
1. —10. Grassland 1. Fallow 11. Potatoes 2. Potatoes 12. S. barley 3. Fallow 4. S. barley
% CL
62.5 8.0
17.0 12.5
72.7 9.1 18.2
Grassland Potatoes S. barley, oats Fallow
83.4 8.3 8.3 -
25.0 25.0 50.0
The growing season is so short that one must use as much of it as possible for the growth of the cultivated crops without losing time for so much as plowing a furrow. Thus in crop rotation A, land preparation begins in the last grass cropping year with a prompt plowing and in the fallow year. In crop rotation D, land preparation, potatoes, and spring barley alternate with one another so that for crops, cultivation can directly follow the drying of the soil in conjunction with the snow melt and harvesting can beat the outbreak of the next winter. Thus a maximum growing season is attained, one closely corresponding to physical circumstances. Ley cropping and fallowing are methods of extending the growing season for food crops and in general are prerequisites for their cultivation. This also holds true for other locations with extremely short growing seasons (Overview 2).
2. Ecological Boundaries of Farming
Northern / / s.Borie Cropping Boundaries
Citrus Fruits
Figure 7
49
50
III. The Delimitation of World Agriculture Space
Overview 2: Crop Rotations with an Extremely Short Growing Season A
Β
Siberian Coniferous Forest Zone
Graubünden 1,500 m Altitude
1. Complete fallow 2. S. grain 3. Complete fallow 4 . - 5 . S. grain
1.—10. Naturegart l l . S . barley
C
D New York State Harsh Altitudes
1.—5. Grass-clover 6. Corn silage 7. Oats
1.—8. Grass-clover 9. Green oats
The Siberian fallow-crop rotation resembles the northern Swedish rotation D. In Graubünden, the cultivation of spring barley as a bread grain in spite of a short growing season is forced. In the case of crop rotation D, oats can no longer ripen. They are, however, still raised green to rejuvenate the grass-clover turf. Without the oats, a conversion from the more productive rotation grassland to the less productive permanent grassland would be necessary. Wheat is found only up to about 63° N.L., and only in western Norway can it be extended farther poleward, through the influence of the Gulf Stream. The northern boundary of beet cultivation corresponds approximately to the northern boundary of the Swedish East Göta Plain (61° N.L.). Grain corn offers a good example of how advances in plant breeding can push back the polar boundary; in the last two decades it has made a truly victorious march through central Europe. The map (Fig. 7) shows that the polar boundary running through southern Europe restricts the distribution of some useful plants that are extremely important for developing countries: rice, olive trees, citrus fruits, and cotton. If we now direct our observations to Fig. 8 and Overview 3, beginning at the equator and moving gradually into the middle and higher latitudes, then the following can be said: — Coconut and oil palms favor locations particularly near the equator (polar boundary of 15° or 16° N.L.). — Sisal, cacao, coffee, bananas, manioc, and rubber have very low polar boundaries of 19° to 25° N.L. because they find their physiological optimum under humid tropical conditions. — Sweet potatoes, cotton, sugarcane, peanuts, tea, and citrus fruit push farther north, up to 35° to 42° N.L., thus into the subtropics. Some of them, however, such as sweet potatoes or sugarcane, also find suitable locations directly on the equator.
2. Ecological Boundaries of Farming
51
At the stage of pure hand labor, peanut raising is burdened with an extremely unfavorable work distribution since 70% of an already high labor expenditure of up to 130 MD/ha is allotted to the harvest. Thus the sooner rural underemployment permits reduction of the high labor peak, the easier it becomes to put a high share of the cultivated land into the crop.
2. Regions of Dryland Crop Fanning
185
c) Other Forms of Dryland Cropping If the agronomic dry boundary is viewed in the strictest sense, then the forms of dryland cropping can be considered almost exhausted with the treatment of the grain-fallow and millet-sorghum-peanut systems. However, if the boundary is seen as a more or less broad — and this is advisable, then the picture becomes much more varied. Now crops behind the "boundary," those that are not quite so drought-resistant and shortlived as wheat, barley, millet, sorghum, and peanuts, can also be added to the farm program. Increasing precipitation does not bring a change in the basic lead-crop elements of dryland crop farming, wheat and barley on the subtropical dry boundaries and millet, sorghum, and peanuts on the tropical dry boundaries. The cropping system, though, can be expanded with some companion crops. These provide more supplies for domestic use, encourage rotations, and help to spread risk and to space work. Sesame advances to the subtropical and tropical dry boundaries with a precipitation minimum of only 400 mm/yr. and a growing season of just three to four months. The plant has great value as a preparatory crop in both its minor soil demands and its improvement of conditions for the lead or "hub" crop. Its seeds are also rich in oil content (51%) and quality. Yet despite all this, the crop has attained a world hectarage that is only 30% of that planted to peanuts. On large farms, cultivation of the crop has been hindered by the difficulties of mechanizing the harvest and processing the product. On small farms, the problem is one of sesame cropping furnishing only about half as much of the land productivity of peanut raising. Sesame cropping often takes place in mixed planting. Characteristic partners are sorghums, millet, cotton, peas, corn, and dry rice (Franke 1975, Vol. I). All forms of legumes are valuable near the agronomic dry boundary. They make a grain-dominant rotation more flexible, provide protein for human nourishment, and through their symbiosis with certain bacteria (bacterium radicicola) promote the fixation of nitrogen, which is so expensive in the developing countries. Garbanzos are distributed along the subtropical dry boundary and bush peas are found along the tropical dry boundary. Both have a short growing season and both are highly resistant to drought. Both are also good preparatory crops and furnish human nourishment, with garbanzos also providing a cash crop and bush peas supplying feed. Roselle hemp and kenaf require a somewhat higher precipitation of 450 or 500 mm/yr. They are especially sensitive to temporary drought. Their fibers are suitable for the manufacture of a yarn that is similar to jute and can be used to make sacks and other woven articles. The Africans usually use only the bast and twist it into coarse, thick ropes for tether-
186
VII. The Agricultural Geography of the Dry Areas
ing domestic animals, securing grass mats to the roofs of huts, and the like. Both of these fiber plants thus serve almost exclusively home needs. The sweet potato is cultivated when rainfall reaches about 500 mm. It is the most drought-resistant of the roots and tubers, and can get along if necessary with a short rainy period of only three to four months. Although its labor productivity is the smallest of the field crops that have been named so far, its land productivity is by far the highest. This makes it a natural subsistence crop for small family farms that suffer from food shortages but have a rich labor potential, so that the required 175 to 200 MD/ha can be satisfied. On somewhat larger farms, sweet potato cultivation diminishes, though it is still carried on in small areas to supplement the food supply and for as long as moisture permits. Beginning with the 500 mm precipitation boundary, the range of potential cultivated plants greatly expands. With more than 500 mm moisture and a sufficiently long rainy season, two completely new cash crops appear, cotton and tobacco. They can be raised as a companion, or support crop or as a hub crop determing the orientation of farm operations. Both are also amenable in their cropping techniques to widely differing combinations of labor and capital, so that their production can be adapted to extremely constrasting farm sizes and stages of economic development. To this widespread economic distribution can be added a sizable ecological dispersion, which extends practically from the equator up into the subtropics. Overview 16 lists some cotton rotations (unirrigated). Overview 16: Cotton Rotations in Tropical Rainfed Farming A Gezira/Sudan — 1.—2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8.
Fallow Cotton Fallow Sorghum Egyptian bean Fallow Cotton
Fallow Cotton Grain Roots and tubers
50 25 13
Β Central African Republic increasing precipitation
C Uganda
1.—16. Bare and bush fallow 17. Cotton 18. Peanuts with corn and manioc 1 9 . - 2 0 . Manioc
1 . - 2 . Fallow 3. Cotton 4. Sorghum-milletcotton 5. Manioc and sweet potatoes
in % CL 80 5 2 12
40 40 20 20
3. Regions of Combined Extensive Grassland and Dryland Crop Farming
187
Small proportions of the cropped area are devoted to cotton even in the very dry areas, and indeed at one time the crop was largely centered in the semiarid tropics. It is raised for domestic needs or for cash on the distant markets, an option favored by the transport capability of the cotton fiber. In Mali and Niger the northern boundary of cotton raising runs closer to the Sahara than does the northern boundary of peanut cultivation.
3. Regions of Combined Extensive Grassland Farming and Dryland Crop Farming a) Risk as a Hindrance to Diversified Production Extensive grassland farming and dryland crop farming are in fact found only rarely in pure form on the agronomic dry boundary, and as a rule are combined. It is immediately evident that dryland cropping does not give ground in the direction of the agronomic dry boundary in abrupt fits and starts, but rather in a gradual and step-by-step form. The very last positions are also the very places where the last bit of cropland is stubbornly defended. This is because the dry zones are usually quite isolated from markets and the farmer therefore is highly reluctant to do without cropping for all his family needs. Also, the longer the dry season becomes on approach to the semideserts the more necessary it is to produce feed to carry livestock through times of distress. Subsistence cropping is also still worthwhile, despite its much smaller yields than those of commercial cropping, because the farmer saves on marketing costs. Nor do small returns prevent subsistence farming for food and feed from competing with systems depending on purchased supplementary supplies, since the latter are encumbered by high purchasing costs. Similarly, looking in the reverse direction, i.e. from the natural grassland of the shrub savannas to the cropped areas in the dry savannas, one sees no abrupt withdrawal of grazing in favor of dryland crop farming. Rather, it is first a cautious penetration of small fields into the rangeland, on the order of probably 1% AL, and then expanding with increasing precipitation to 3, 8, 15, 30, and probably also 40 to 50% AL. Pure crop farms in the vicinity of the agronomic dry boundary are highly unusual.
b) The Example of Southwest Africa What is at first a very timid establishment of some dryland crop farming is necessary because cropping near the dry boundaries is subject to high risk and thus can only acquire the status of a small subsidiary enterprise.
188
VII. The Agricultural Geography of the Dry Areas
Grain corn yields in Southwest Africa can fluctuate between 0 and 45 q/ha. Table 14 shows the yield oscillations for some sample years, based on national averages. The influence of the two drought periods of 1943 to 1945 and 1957 to 1962 is clearly recognizable, for the years 1946 and 1960 show large fallow areas, low hectare-yields, and smaller proportions in ripened grain. Table 14:
Year
Grain Corn Cultivation in Southwest Africa, 1 9 2 1 - 1 9 7 0
Cultivated Land in 000s of ha Cultivated Fallow Land
1921 1946 1950 1955 1960 1970
31.9 39.8 66.5
11.9 11.8 34.5
Corn
7.9 13.9 17.9 24.4 24.7 32.0
Corn in % of Cultivated Area 73.3 81.1 91.6 88.5 77.1 39.0
Corn Harvests % ripened
q/ha
62.3 95.5 90.1 72.3
3.84 1.08 6.40 5.94 2.43 3.80
Source: Bähr, J.: Kulturgeographische Wandlungen in der Farmzone Südwestafrikas (Bonner Geographische Abhandlungen, No. 40), Bonn, 1968, pp. 5 2 f f .
Today, in the great South African "Maize Triangle" of the Transvaal and Orange Free State, corn grain on the farms of whites does not become profitable until yields of 11 to 12 q/ha are reached. Thus, with the yield levels and fluctuations as shown in Table 14, a farmer whose main enterprise was corn cropping could in no way survive. Corn cultivation is of course justified to a minor extent in ranching operations, where the grain furnishes produce for the workers and provides feed. If the crop fails to mature, the cobs can be fed to cattle or hogs and, if necessary, preserved as silage for times of feed shortage. The Uitkom experimental farm at Grootfontein is trying to introduce suitable forms of such a complementary system. There are grassland farming systems in the extreme northeastern part of the farming zone in Southwest Africa that use more than 200 ha of cropland. In 1960, farm operators generally devoting some land to cropping cultivated an average of 41.9 ha in the Gobabis District, 53.3 ha in the Otjiwarongo District, 56.6 ha in the Grootfontein District, and 61.3 ha in the Tsumeb District, the figures rising with improvement in precipitation. Yet even in the last two named districts in which 40% of the total cultivated land was located, the proportion of farmland in cropland came to only 0.8 or 0.9% (Bahr 1970, p. 53). Even in densely
3. Regions of Combined Extensive Grassland and Dryland Crop Farming
189
settled Ovamboland (South-West Africa), only 10 to 20% of the land is cultivated, while the remaining area is used for cattle grazing, the typical activity of the Bantu tribes. Many goats are also raised. Millet and to a degree sorghum, the principal food crops, almost completey dominate the cropland, with the rest in peanuts (protein supply) and a little corn (consumed fresh). The millet consists largely of pennisetum. The supply of protein is furnished primarily by cow's milk and secondarily by peanuts. The main food supply comes from cropping. Millet-sorghum monoculture is widespread. Grass fallow is introduced at irregular intervals and for varying periods. As precipitation in Ovamboland increases from 450 mm in the southwest to 600 mm in the northeast, the character of the landscape changes from one of bush to tree savanna. Cultivation, not even represented in the southwest, increases in a northeasterly direction. Distinctly cash crops, however, are also not to be found in the northeast. Instead, principal cash sources are the proceeds from the sale of wickerwork and especially the wages for contract labor for Europeans beyond the homelands.
c) Modifications by Economic and Ecological Variants Though both are in the same areas, the northern and northeastern parts of Southwest Africa, native farmers emphasize millet and sorghum and European farmers concentrate on corn. The reasons for this are primarily the differences in farm size and pastureland-cropland ratios. On European farms, and especially those in the Otavi Valley, cropland is devoted almost exclusively to corn, though it is less drought-resistant than millet or sorghum. This is because — an especially efficient marketing organization exists for corn; — corn is needed for food for the farmworkers; and — the feed value of corn stover is higher than that of millet and sorghum straw, so that — this aspect weighs especially heavily in the years when the grain harvest fails. In Ovamboland, contrarily, millet and sorghum are heavily favored in areas with the same amount of rainfall because — the soils here are lighter and more saline; — millet and sorghum require less cultivation (hoe cultivation) and fertilization; — the Ovambos prefer millet and sorghum as their basic foodstuffs, in which the brewing of beer plays a role;
190
VII. The Agricultural Geography of the Dry Areas
— millet and sorghum can do better by themselves than corn, so that cropping can concentrate near the huts (village settlements); and — cropping is more prominent on the Ovambo farms than on the European farms, and thus Ovambo operators cannot bear as high a risk with crop failure in grain farming as can European operators. As to which of the various forms of dryland crop farming on the agronomic dry boundary combines with livestock raising into a single farming system, we can, ignoring special conditions, make the following generalizations about agricultural zones and operational motivations: In the temperate or mid-latitude climates it is the w. wheat-fallow economy, or in higher latitudes (Dakotas, Canada), the s. wheat-s. barleyfallow economy, since millet, sorghum, and peanuts do not grow here. In the subtropics with winter rain it is also the w. wheat-fallow economy, since the growing season falls in the cool winter, which is favorable for wheat but fails to satisfy the heat requirements of millet, sorghum, and peanuts. In the dry savannas, which basically receive summer rain, peanuts, millet, and sorghum are areally suitable because they are very much heatloving plants. Small native farmers prefer peanuts, millet, and sorghum, even if the location is less favorable for them, for the simple production techniques, food habits (also beer), and the possibility of dealing with the high labor peaks for peanuts all speak for these cultivated plants. European farmers, in contrast, tend more toward the grain-fallow economy, which can be more easily mechanized and thus less burdened with sharp labor peaks. That production techniques are more difficult does not matter, and wheat is a better cash crop. With greater remoteness from markets, grain corn becomes the first field crop to penetrate the extensive grassland farming system. In marketoriented operations, increasing transport costs cause the agronomic dry boundary to shift into the more humid and prolific areas, so that corn becomes more competitive. This applies to all farm sizes, since corn is not only a good subsistence crop, but also a good commercial crop. This also holds for both the dry savannas and the wet-summer subtropics.
4. The Macrospatial Structure of a Dry Area: The Example of Australia We shall conclude the chapter on the agricultural geography of the dry areas by describing the agrospatial structure of a large dry area, with Australia as the example.
4. The Macrospatial Structure of a Dry Area: The Example of Australia
191
a) Physicospatial Structure For the illustration of the physicospatial structure we can turn to the world precipitation map (Fig. 5, p. 35) and the map sketch of the seasonal climates in the dry areas of the earth (Fig. 39, p. 161). The Tropic of Capricorn passes through Australia, and around this axis are grouped the climatic zones. On both sides of the tropic can be found a large landmass of deserts and semideserts with only 130 to 250 mm annual precipitation. Even less than 130 mm fall in the center of this block, north of Adelaide. A large part of this section, especially the western part, permits no agriculture of any kind. Bordering this desert block on all sides but the northwest is a semiarid ring. A steppe climate with wet winters and dry summers and about 250 to 500 mm annual precipitation locates on the subtropical southern side, while a steppe climate with a short summer rainy period and the same amount of rainfall marks the southeastern side. Shrub and dry savannas with similar precipitation amounts characterize the northern arc. Only the outer ring on the coasts of the country is strongly differentiated. On the southwestern tip and also between Adelaide and Melbourne we find Ά Mediterranean climate, with approximately 510 to 760 mm annual precipitation, which is concentrated in the winter. The southeast coastal strip, in contrast, is distinguished by a subtropical wet-summer climate and, directly on the Pacific, even by a constantly humid subtropical climate. In the latter case, precipitation increases from 760 to 1,270 mm, as in the vicinity of Sydney or Brisbane. Humid savannas with the same precipitation span are found on the tropical north coast, and regionally they are more extensive. Annual precipitation at Darwin reaches 1,780 mm, and at Townsville it goes even beyond that. The agricultural effects of a decline from at least 760 mm precipitation on the northern and eastern coasts to less than 130 mm in the interior of this continent are heightened by a related spatial trend, an increase in variation of annual precipitation (mean deviation) of from 15 to 25% to over 40% of the average.
b) Agricultural Zones What agricultural zones have now been formed in these physical areas, and why? To begin with, there are, according to Fig. 46, extensive parts of the interior of the country that lie beyond the area of human habitation and permit no agriculture whatsoever. 1. Proceeding outward to the boundary of livestock grazing, the first activity to be encountered in wide areas is extensive sheep grazing. It claims a semicircular belt that is interrupted only on the southern
VII. The Agricultural Geography of the Dry Areas
192
coast, extending from northwestern Queensland and through New South Wales and the southeastern part of South Australia to the western part of Western Australia. This large sheep grazing belt can again be subdivided into three zones (Dahlke 1973, pp. 403ff.): a) A zone of pure sheep grazing forms the innermost ring, has the greatest extent, and allows no rainfed farming of any kind. Semiarid or even arid climates produce such a scanty vegetation of grasses and bushes, and walking distances to watering places are so great, that cattle raising usually remains excluded and sheep raising must assume its least demanding form, raising animals only for wool. This form also copes best with the great distances to market, for only the excellent transport and storage qualities of a product like wool can overcome the problem. Since a profitable farm operation requires from 5,000 to 10,00 sheep and the carrying capacity of
Agricultural
Zones of
Australia
DARWIN
NSVILLE
SYDNEY
BOURNE
Sheep
^TASMANIA
grazing
Dairy
Cattle grazing Wheat farming-sheep Source:
Figure 46
Sugarcane plantations
grazing
Berney, M. Australia Sydney reproduction in Harms Handbuch vol. VII, 6 th ed 1968, p. 186).
zone
1965. der
(Generalized Erdkunde
4. The Macrospatial Structure of a Dry Area: The Example of Australia
193
the pasture varies anywhere from 3 to 30 ha per sheep, depending on the density and type of vegetation, farm sizes are large. They range from 15,000 up to 300,000 ha and in some places as high as 400,000 ha. It is to be expected that the boundary of livestock raising will retreat from the desert to the same extent that labor productivity must increase. Today there are still regions used in which 40 ha of range is needed for one sheep. We estimate 30 ha to be marginal. With continued rapid development of Australia, the limit will soon become 20 ha per sheep, or in other words, the unpopulated center of Australia will expand. b) Next to the inner ring is a more humid, sheep grazing-wheat belt. Wheat-fallow farming is established on smaller areas. Although the system is associated with heavy risk, it does provide many an advantage, not only in providing sheep with stubble and pasture fallow, but in spreading risk and spracing work. And since range vegetation is now more plentiful, sheep can be raised for both wool and meat. The combined effect of all these conditions is to make possible a typical farm flock of only 1,000 to 5,000 head. c) The coastal termination of the sheep grazing belt is identified by a combination of sheep raising with cattle raising. The normal flock size comes up to only 500 to 2,000 sheep, for precipitation has increased from 500 to 1,250 mm per year. The double use of the sheep (wool and meat) is now so pronounced that lambs are fattened for the market. 2. Just as the desert area of interior Australia is bordered on the south by a belt of extensive sheep grazing, so is it bordered on the north by a zone of extensive cattle grazing. Although the cow is superior to the sheep in competition for use of the range in the greater part of the world, the competitive position of sheep raising in Australia is far stronger. This is due to, among other things, the fact that — wool is more capable of transport than beef, which for a very isolated continent with sizable agricultural surpluses is of great significance. Of the total current production, some 35% of the beef, 33% of the mutton, and 84% of the wool is exported, mainly to Europe; — the dry areas of the continental interior have so low a carrying capacity, so few watering places, and so much open range, that they place a premium on the characteristics in which the sheep is superior to the cow: ranging capability, herding instinct, and thirst tolerance; and — there are dryland pastures in which no competition exists, because if they could not be used by sheep they would become wasteland.
194
VII. The Agricultural Geography of the Dry Areas
The result is that extensive cattle raising can only become important in regions unsuitable for sheep raising. This is the case in the coastal strip of the tropical north. The high-grass savannas are not suitable for sheep raising because of their low nutrient value, and because the sheep are difficult to control here. The dingoes (wild dogs) endanger the sheep here in much the same way that jackals do in Africa. A cardinal problem of the Australian ranch (called "station" in Australia) is one of supplying the market with an extremely wide-meshed transport net. Usually extensive distances must be negotiated in cattle drives before the animals can be loaded for shipment or slaughtered. After slaughter, export needs require that the meat be preserved and transport weight reduced as much as possible. Sixty percent of the total beef export is frozen and the rest canned. 3. The more intensive wheat farming-sheep grazing system forms the third category of drought-resisting farming types in Australian agricultural space. It outlines a small, elongated zone in the winter-rain area of the southern continent, lying approximately between the isohyets of 250 and 635 mm. A typical wheat fanner farms about 400 ha, depends on his own or an expanded family labor supply, sows about 12 q/ha of grain in the fall or early winter, and harvests it in the early summer. In the more humid areas of the wheat belt, the operator has broken away from the dry farming system of earlier periods and has inserted drought-resistant clover varieties between for sheep raising, protection against erosion, and improved soil fertility. The following are typical rotations (Dahlke 1973, pp. 198f.): B. A. C. .—3. Clover 1.-4. Clover 1.-2. Clover 4. Wheat 5. Wheat 3. Wheat 5. Wheat 6. Wheat. 4. Wheat The farmer generally cultivates wheat two years in a row and then follows it with two, three, or four years of clover pasture so that the clover takes up 50, 60, or 67% CL. Clover can be left longer on the lighter soils than on the heavier types. Rotation Β has the best prospects for a wide distribution. 4. The other agricultural zones of Australia lie on the wetter east coast, which has at the least 760 mm annual precipitation and is the major populated area of the country. A dairy zone has developed in the southern, subtropical coastal strip to supply the large cities, and sugarcane is raised in the northern and tropical coastal belt. But discussion of these and other agricultural zones exceeds the limits of this chapter on the agricultural geography of the dry areas.
4. The Macrospatial Structure of a Dry Area: The Example of Australia
195
c) Water Reclamation Projects As in all dry areas, the expansion of the irrigated area plays a special role. Also, as everywhere else, efforts are concentrated not so much in the regions where precipitation is the lowest and water could be used to the maximum, but rather in the areas where irrigation water can be obtained most easily and cheaply. Of the numerous water reclamation projects in Australia, only the most important and also boldest one will be mentioned here: the "Snowy Mountains Scheme," currently in construction. It will help to stimulate development in what is already the economic heart of the continent, the Sydney-Adelaide-Melbourne triangle of the southeastern region. Water will be conducted from the 1,000 to 1,500 m-high Snowy Mountains into the Murray River and its tributaries, which drain an area of 100 million ha, or four times the size of the FRG. This will be accomplished with a complex of 17 dams, 160 km of aqueducts, seven hydroelectric power plants, and one pumping station. The rivers will then receive an additional volume of 235 million m 3 . This will permit an expansion of the irrigated area in Australia, now up to about 1.69 million ha, by 0.25 million ha. About three quarters of the irrigated land in Australia will then be in the drainage area of the Murray River (Schendel 1971, pp. 8 f.). The heavy losses of water through evaporation from the reservoirs will be reduced by 30% by covering the surface with a film of acetyl alcohol. This in turn will increase the irrigation capacity of the project.
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
To the two large climatic realms of world agriculture already described, the humid tropics and the dry areas, we can now add a third, that of the middle latitudes. Fig. 30, p. 133, shows that intensive cropping concentrates in the mid-latitude climates, and Fig. 47 makes it clear that the regional differentiation of world nutrition is one that favors the higher latitudes. The Regionalization Minimum
Supply Κ
jj u p
per to
head
Less Source
and
2 2 0 0 calories
requirement
per
of World person
and
Nutrition
day= 2 600
calories
day: jEEj 2200
to
2600 calories
t h a n 2 6 0 0 c a l o r i e s per undernourishment, and
^ ^
2 6 0 0 to 3 0 0 0 c a l o r i e s
g ^ j over
3000 calories
h e a d a n d day o f t e n s i g n i f i e s d i s e a s e , hunger, in e x t r e m e cases, d e a t h .
F ΔΟ
Figure 47
However, one should not conclude from these two facts that the midlatitude climates favor agriculture more than do the humid tropics. Rather, it is the much higher stages of development of the national economies of Europe and North America that stimulate agricultural produc-
1. The Agricultural Geography of Western Europe
197
tion and the food economy. The agricultural regions of the higher latitudes, which we shall discuss now, are at such a high development stage in spite of, rather than because of the mid-latitude climates. They are thus conditioned far more economically than ecologically. No attempt will be made here to present a complete agricultural geography of the middle latitudes, so that the most important and instructive agricultural areas with mid-latitude climates can be treated more thoroughly. They are the area of the European Common Market of the Nine, North America, and the East Bloc.
1. The Agricultural Geography of Western Europe The following attempt to delimit farming types and structural zones in European agriculture and to interpret their spatial picture lies in the boundary area between agricultural economics and agricultural geography. Since there is no economic enterprise that is areally bound to such a high degree as agriculture, an attempt should first be made to give the place-specific characteristics of European agriculture. After that, a systematic representation of farms, which takes into account the objectives of scientific regional analysis, can be developed. Only then is the way made clear for considering in turn the spatial patterns of systems of crop rotation, land use, livestock raising, and farming. In concluding, we shall at least allude to some of the problems of competition among agricultural regions stemming from Europe's internal boundaries. Although the Common Market of the Nine is the object of our regional investigation, and the statistical and cartographical information is restricted to it, examples will now and then be drawn from neighboring regions when this is factually possible and usefull for understanding relationships.
a) Place-Specific Characteristics On a macrospatial scale, climate remains the most important place-specific factor for agricultural production. Five major climatic zones can be distinguished in Europe (see Fig. 48): 1. Temperate summer, cold winter: The largest part of Scandinavia belongs to this climatic belt. The mean annual temperature in southern Sweden is +6°C. It lowers toward the north, falling to - 2 ° C in Lapland. 2. Temperate summer and winter: Here one can speak of a Central European transitional climate. Hoe cropping and winter-grain cropping play a significant role.
198
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
Climatic
Areas (after
of
Europe
Sydow-Wagner)
Climate at Central European m o u n t a i n islands ! [ j East European c o n t i n e n t a l ] ^
^
climate
West European oceanic
[UBI
Mediterranean
m i l l
Continental steppe
f X /
Subtropical
• " • Mean annual
HOT,
s
I
T
^
-
^
T
SUMΜERA
climate
climate climate
WINTER
climate isotherms
DRY
Pi 11 í I SUMMER,·
Source Or. H e r r m a n n H a a c k : Physikalischer Wondatlos
Figure 48
TEMPERA
Central European t r a n s i t i o n a l c l i m a t e
Illlllll'llll
χ WARM. I
Gotha Justus Perthes.
S
,0°
WE
1. The Agricultural Geography of Western Europe
199
3. Mild winter, cool summer: This climate is typical for Great Britain and a large part of France. Fodder growth is vigorous and consequently so is the development of cattle raising. 4. Very mild winters and warm summers dominate the regions around the Bay of Biscay, i.e. northern Spain and southwestern France. 5. Hot, dry summers and warm, wet winters distinguish the Mediterranean area. These conditions become more emphatic the farther one proceeds to the south, until finally agriculture is possible only during the winter rainy season and the summer heat and drought are hostile to all cropping. The mean annual temperature ranges from 14° to 18°C. The coldest climate is that of the high mountain chains of Europe, especially in Norway and the Alps. Fodder cropping clearly reigns in this mountain climate. Less cold is the East European continental climate. Then comes the Central European transitional climate, in which hoe cropping and winter-grain cropping play a significant role. It is the major zone of hoe crop-grain crop farming. The West European oceanic climate is distinguished by its very mild winters, which favor fodder cropping and permit almost year-around grazing. While mowing of meadows characterizes fodder cropping in the highlands, grazing of pasture prevails here. The Mediterranean climate is marked by mild winters and hot, dry summers, which provide strong support for bush and tree crops. Finally, the subtropical climate of southern Italy makes it possible to raise, among other things, fruits, olives, almonds, and cotton. To delineate farming types it is important to know the duration of a temperature of at least 5°C, since most cultivated plants begin to assimilate nourishment at this level (Fig. 49). Phenological dates are also important, e.g. the beginning of the winter wheat harvest. Near its northern cropping boundary wheat cannot be harvested until August, whereas in Italy all of the crop must be brought in by the end of May. Fig. 7, p. 49, shows the northern cropping boundaries of important cultivated plants. Potatoes are cultivated farthest north, even beyond the northern boundary of Sweden. Cropping of summer barley stops a little farther south, strains of which in their quadrilocular forms can mature in 60 to 65 days. Also important for cropping is the northern boundary of winter wheat. It runs a little north of the Stockholm-Oslo line and extends still farther north in the warm Gulf Stream climate of western Norway, a phenomenon also to be observed in the cropping boundaries of spring barley and potatoes. The northern cropping boundary of the sugar beet coincides approximately with the northern boundary of the Swedish East Göta Plain. Then comes a broad belt running through Central Europe, in which all the important cultivated plants of the mid-latitude climates, with the exception of specialty crops and decidedly heat-loving crop types, can be raised.
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
200
Duration (Number
Figure 49
of a
of days
Temperature of at least 5°C
computed
on the basis
of the
in
Europe
monthly
mean)
1. The Agricultural Geography of Western Europe
201
The cropping boundary of grapevines is to be sought approximately along a line running from the mouth of the Loire to the Mosel, after which it drops southward in Hesse and Bavaria. The cropping of grain corn has become possible much farther north than was the case earlier, when earlier-ripening hybrid strains still had not been developed. Already the Rhine-Main area must be considered capable today of producing grain corn, and noteworthy proportions of land devoted to the crop can be found on scattered farms almost up to the Mittelland Canal. The cropping boundary of rice runs still farther south. We have, of course, only two significant rice cropping areas in Europe, one in the Rhone Delta and the other on the Po Plain in Lombardy. The boundary of the olive tree is important in the southern European countries. In Italy it practically coincides with the northern boundaries of Liguria, Tuscany, and Umbria. Farther south is to be found the cropping boundary of citrus fruits. The only areas in Italy favorable for citrus crops are Sicily, Apulia, Calabria, and a strip on the west coast extending up to the latitude of Rome. Mean annual precipitation in Europe is highly variable. In the horizontal dimension, it will generally increase the closer we come to the Atlantic coastal area. In the vertical dimension, it normally increases with altitude. However, for the farmer the amount in itself is not decisive; seasonal distribution is also important. Uniform distribution over the entire year, which is especially favorable for fodder growth, is found in the maritime area. The continental climate, in contrast, is partially handicapped by presummer drought. Under such conditions fodder cropping cannot claim any sizable areas, and in grain cropping as much emphasis as possible must be put on types that ripen early and use the winter moisture efficiently, as is true of our winter grain types. The Mediterranean climate is characterized by a dry summer. Only 86 mm of rain falls in northern Apulia in the June-to-August quarter, while on the coast of the Ionian Sea the amount is but 71 mm. Here annual cropping must either be restricted to the winter months or supported by irrigation. However, the farmer in the Mediterranean countries adjusts to the pronounced summer drought in still other ways, namely with bush and tree crops. With their deep root system, they can utilize the winter moisture and groundwater better than annual crops can, and consequently are able to surmount the many dry months without much damage. Amount and seasonal distribution of precipitation still do not completely account for the formation of farming types. Both must be seen in relation to temperature conditions. With high temperatures, a relatively rich amount of precipitation is taken up by the atmosphere relatively quickly through intense evaporation; the cultivated plants thus benefit from only a small part of the moisture. Conversely, with lower temper-
202
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
atures and thus less evaporation, a smaller amount of precipitation can penetrate deeper into the soil and there become available for plants. Seen in this relationship, abundant precipitation in warm areas gains quite a different aspect. Dry periods occur there in spite of the precipitation. But if, as in the Mediterranean region, the summer months have relatively meager rainfall with high temperatures, the result is a pronounced drought for several months, a special climatic feature of this portion of the EC area. Thus, when the efficiency of precipitation is considered, we get a completely different picture from the one presented when precipitation amount is considered in isolation. The first one shows, for example, that in the Atlantic coastal area, with its relatively low temperatures, high humidity, and much of its precipitation in the form of fog and drizzle, even relatively small amounts of precipitation are sufficient to give fodder cropping the upper hand. In the Allgäu, on the other hand, a much greater amount of precipitation has to fall to ensure the predominance of fodder cropping, especially since rain here falls in shorter periods and more torrential form, humidity is lower, and solar radiation is stronger. Finally, in the Mediterranean area 1,000 mm of precipitation still does not mean much, when one considers the hot climate, the very dry air, and the unfavorable seasonal distribution of this precipitation. What, now, is the situation for the soils of Europe? If the mountain soils are left out of consideration, then we have the following picture (Fig. 50). Great Britain and the Baltic Sea coastal area have many loam soils. South of that is a broad zone represented by sandy soils, and it embraces Jutland, the Geest region of Schleswig-Holstein and Lower Saxony, the province of Brandenburg, and large parts of Poland. South of that is the Central European loess belt, which thrusts between the northern sandy soils and the southern sub-Alpine mountains. It begins in the Paris Basin, extends over Flanders and the Cologne-Aachen Bay, then narrows in the Westphalian Hellweg region. Continuing east, it widens again in the Hildesheim-Brunswick and Magedburg portions of the fertile plain of the Börde and then almost disappears, only to become prominent again on the Wroctaw (Breslau) Platform, after which it finally expands into Eastern Europe as a very broad zone in the Ukraine. South of this loess zone, a great variety of soil types prevail. A high proportion of the Mediterranean countries is in clay soils. Other place-specific factors of a physical nature that are important here include relief, exposure, and slope. All are especially important for highland agriculture. An effect of the physical location factors is reflected in the grassland-farmland ratio. Fig. 51 shows to what extent permanent grassland in Europe is distributed. The Atlantic coastal area is especially prominent in grassland, though of course still surpassed by the Alpine area. Permanent grassland in most parts of Europe is physically deter-
1. The Agricultural Geography of Western Europe
203
Figure 50
mined and little capable of conversion to another land use. Only in Great Britain and France can a part of the permanent grasslands be explained by economic reasons. Generally one can say that for modern agriculture a smaller amount of land in permanent grassland is more favorable. In most parts of Europe a larger proportion is a strain on farm management. Roughage can be
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
204
land
in Permanent Grassland e an Community
[ 2 3 up to 15 pet. of AL g / g 16-30 pet. of AL IMI 31-45 pet. of AL 46-60 pet. of AL EvJ over 60 pet. of AL According
to the
statistics
for
the
period
1955 - 1961.
Figure 51
produced much more efficiently through cultivation, because then fodder cropping can better support commercial farming with its crops that improve the soil and require little fertilizer. The areas with little permanent grassland, such as Denmark, Sweden, and parts of Italy, can avail themselves of the great advantages of cultivating crops for roughages: better soil conditions preceding the crop; rich supplies of
205
1. The Agricultural Geography of Western Europe
root humus, which allow the farmer to keep the manuring operation within bounds; higher productivity of fodder cropping; and so forth. Next t o be characterized are the economic
place-specific
factors
for
European agriculture. If Europe did not have such a strongly varied relief, one would be able to recognize intensity rings in European agriculture. They would lie concentrically around the large industrialized area bounded approximately by the four cities, Manchester, Brunswick, Karlsruhe, and Paris. Here lies the center of gravity for industrial production and the great population concentration that is the principal customer for European agriculture. It is next to this area that, so far as economic place-specific factors are concerned, highly intensive farming must develop. However, the farther the agricultural zones are from this population concentration, the more agriculture is burdened with production and transport costs and the more extensive the types of farming become. In this connection, the high density of the transport net marks another economic prerequisite for agricultural production in Europe. Also important is the distribution of farm sizes. The smallest farms are in Norway and in a broad zone that extends through southwestern Germany to the Riviera. Areas with the largest farms are most extensive in Spain and Italy, followed by smaller regions in central France, and then eastern England. Between these two large zones lie areas with medium to large family farms (see Fig. 52). The distribution of farm sizes cannot be explained by inheritance customs alone. Yet it can be observed that the areas with predominantly divided inheritance are northern France, the Riviera, Italy, and southwestern Germany, while those with a prevailing undivided inheritance are southern France, Bavaria, Westphalia, Lower Saxony, Schleswig-Holstein, Denmark, Scandinavia, and Great Britain. Another product of inheritance customs is the average size of farm parcel. Areas with predominantly divided inheritance generally have only small parcels, while in areas with mostly undivided inheritance the individual farm parcels are larger. The importance of parcel size in the era of technology is well established, particularly in areas with divided inheritance, which because of the smaller parcels are at a great disadvantage for mechanization. The size of the labor force in European agriculture is a consequence of all the factors of the agricultural structure that have just been noted, but primarily of farm size and also parcel size. The Federal Republic, Italy, and the Benelux countries especially stand out as labor-intensive areas. In the Federal Republic and Benelux countries, the high labor intensity may be attributed most immediately to large livestock numbers and then to extensive hoe cropping. In Italy, contrarily, it is more the large share of bush and tree crops that determine the large work force. Southern Italy also has rural overpopulation, which is rooted, on the one
206
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
Production Elasticity
of Agricultural
Regions in the EEC
Figure 52
hand, in a latifundia system that is still not completely eliminated, and on the other, in a lack of industrial potential. But the size of the labor force per 100 ha FL cannot always be viewed as an expression of farming types. The reverse relationship is perhaps stronger, in that where a
1. The Agricultural Geography of Western Europe
207
large rural labor force exists because of small family farms, there intensive farming types can be expected to achieve a breakthrough. As everywhere in agriculture, relations here are also reciprocal.
b) Methodology of Delimitation and Statistical Derivation of Agricultural Regions The possibility of delimiting and mapping agricultural regions, and thereby facilitating spatial investigation by means of the map model, was provided with the introduction of newer methods in regional agricultural statistics in the late 1870s. In Germany, Engelbrecht (1930) was the first to recognize the possibility of depicting cartographically the regional distribution and concentration of individual crops. Thus he provided, as a major founder of agricultural geography, the stimulus for an approach, whose foundation up to today is still not fully laid. The crop atlases of Engelbrecht were of course still one-dimensional. If the maps were to represent more fully the agricultural conditions of an area, they would have to be able to show complex phenomena, or systems. For that purpose, the delimitation of land use systems based on crop ratios offered especially good possibilités, since the necessary statistics were available for the small administrative units and could be systematically processed for larger areas with a reasonable expenditure. This led to the development of the cartographic representation of land use systems, in which Busch (1936) and Woermann (1943) were especially active. European farming systems thus have been defined for a long time by land use systems. These were distinguished by designating the lead crop and first companion crop. At first these two crops were simply determined by their share of the land. Only a well-read work by Brinkmann (1930, pp. 559 ff.) sparked interest in a new and better delimitation method. Brinkmann determined the lead and companion crops by the product of the areal share in % AL and a crop-specific weighted index number. This weighted index number was then used to compure the farm enterprise weight of the individual crop-type groups. Busch (1936) adopted this method and produced a weighted-index system that was appropriate to Central Europe at the time. He then proceeded to delimit the land use systems as follows (Overview 17): The most important crop types were first combined according to their relationships in the farm operation into a few major groups — fodder, grain, and hoe cropping. The crop data for these principal groups were computed in % AL. These data were then multiplied by the weighted index numbers, which take into account the varying farm management weights of the individual crop groups. The product of the crop share of AL times the weighted index number yielded the crop weight. Fodder cropping, grain cropping, and hoe cropping were now ranked by their
208
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
Overview 17: Determination of Land Use Systems with the Help of Weighted Index Numbers (Example)
Crop Area in ha Fodder cropping (F) 20 ha permanent grassland Hoe cropping (H) 6 ha potatoes 4 ha sugar beets Grain cropping (G) 10 ha w. rye 10 ha s. grain Total 50 ha AL
% AL χ
Crop Weighted Index Number = Weight
40
0.5
12 8
2.0 2.5
40
1.0
100%
20 24 20
44
40 H-G
crop weight, and the land use system was classified with the designation of the lead and first companion crop (e.g. H—G = hoe and grain crop farming). In this manner, economic enterprises and areas with related farm management structures were combined into groups. This method of delimiting land use systems has long been the dominant one. Various authors (Rolfes, Woermann, and Blohm, among others) have basically taken over the Busch method, though they have partially refined the discriminations by modifying the weights in the index numbers. The resulting more sharply differentiated graduations of the index number values have thus made possible a more exact delimitation of the land use systems. However, the refining of the method also increased the work necessary for determining the systems, so that macrospatial analysis using fine areal detail became increasingly difficult. The statistical determination of land use systems became still more laborious with the application of a method devised by Hoffmann (1954, pp. 263 ff.) which involved multiplying the crop area data for the crop groups by weighted index numbers based not on expenditures, but on yields. These weights were obtained by averaging yields over several years, and were then made comparable by converting the values to grain units. In point of fact, standardized weighted expenditure indices have lost their value in our age of technology, since every farm enterprise today can be encumbered with very different amounts and composites of expenditures depending on the stage of technological development. On the other hand, the use of weighted index numbers for yields requires so much work that they are hardly suitable for macrospatial investigations, since statistics for sufficiently small administrative units or regions must now be prepared for both land use and harvesting.
1. The Agricultural Geography of Western Europe
209
None of the methods so far described is adequate for the regional analysis that is planned here for the agricultural areas of the European Community of the Nine. The functional relations between land use and livestock raising have become so relaxed, that only a very incomplete picture of the livestock enterprise can be obtained from the land use system. Thus as a criterion of the farming system (the objective of all the regionalization methods), the land use system is in most cases no longer capable of being more than a partial and only indirect indicator. While the necessity of using weighted index numbers is undisputed, all of them up to now have more or less failed to provide a universally verifiable scale unit. In the following presentation, weighted index numbers based on the total hand labor expenditures for crop and livestock enterprises are offered as the most characteristic expenditures factor in the agriculture of the industrial states. Now livestock systems as well as land use systems are distinguished (Andreae 1964). Thus the procedures for delimiting land use and livestock raising systems have been selected so as to be fully compatible and consequently now capable of defining farming systems. Eight farming enterprises have been selected as the most important for inclusion in the computations: Farming Enterprise
Symbol
Weighted Index
Fodder cropping Grain cropping Hoe cropping Specialty crops Dairy cows Young cattle Small ruminants Swine
F G H Β D Y R S
1 1 5 20 3 1 0.2 0.3
Number
As for the rest of the method, Overview 18 shows the stages in which the land use system, the livestock raising system, and finally, as their summation, the farming system, are determined. First, the crop weights of the four land use enterprises were determined, with the result indicating a pure hoe cropping system. Then the livestock weights for the four livestock enterprises were computed in the same manner, the result denoting a swine-sheep raising system. Finally, the farming system was arrived at, now taking into consideration all eight farming enterprises. Hoe cropping achieved the highest weight in this farm operation and consequently was listed as the leading farm enterprise. Swine raising attained the second highest weight and thus became the companion enterprise. The third highest weight was for sheep raising, which also was listed as a supplementary enterprise. The farming system was therefore characterized as a hoe crop-swine-sheep raising operation ( H - S - R ) . The coordination of the individual procedures is thus complete, since both land use and livestock enterprises are evaluated on the basis of a
210
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
Overview 18: The Method of Determining the Farming System (Example Farm) Land Use Enterprise
Symbol
Fodder cropping Grain cropping Hoe cropping Specialty crops
F G H Β1
Cultivated Weighted Area in Index % AL Number 5.7 53.0 40.0 1.3
1 1 5 20
Total crop weight
System Designation 3
5.7 53.0 200.0 26.0 284.7
Land Use System:
Pure hoe cropping system
Livestock Enterprise
Symbol
Head per Weighted 100 ha AL Index Number
Dairy cows Young cattle Sheep and goats Swine
D Y R2 S
9.1 4.0 296.0 287.0
3 1 0.2 0.3
Total livestock weight
H Livestock Weight
System Designation 3
27.3 4.0 59.2 86.1 176.6
Livestock Raising System:
Swine-sheep raising system
Farming weight IFarming System|
Crop Weight
S-R 461.3
Hoe crop-swine-sheep raising farm
H-S-R3|
1
Β =
2
R = small ruminants. The first letter indicates the leading farm enterprise, the second the companion enterprise, and the third the supplementary enterprise. No companion and supplementary enterprises are named if the lead enterprise attains at least two thirds of the total crop, livestock, or farming weight.
3
bush and tree crops.
weighted index of 1 being equal to 45—50 MH per 100 ha AL. Also, no companion and supplementary farm enterprises were named if the lead enterprise attained at least two thirds of the total crop, livestock, of farming weight.
c) Crop Rotation Regions The overview of farming types in the agricultural area of the European Community of the Nine will first be restricted to just cropping, and later will be gradually expanded to include more complex phenomena. The scope of cropping is shown by Fig. 53. The two most important European Community of the Nine will first be restricted to just cropping, and later will be gradually expanded to include more complex phenom-
1. The Agricultural Geography of Western Europe
Figure 53
211
212
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
ena. The scope of cropping is shown by Fig. 53. The two most important European rotation categories are ley farming and annual-crop farming. The value chosen for separating the two is 25% CL in fodder cropping. Rotation systems that include this proportion or more in fodder cropping feature leys with a useful economic life of at least two years and crops that conserve and enrich the soil and save labor. All of these characteristics make up the essence of ley farming types and differentiate them from types of annual-crop farming. The regions of ley farming are ranked by the number of years a ley is cropped after it is sown. Regions of annual-crop farming, thus rotations with crops harvested only once and of no more than a year's duration, are ordered by the ratio of grain crops to leafy crops. The class graduations signify a decrease in grain cropping and an increase in cultivation of the leafy crops, and with that, an increasing realization of the principles of crop rotations. Ley farming regions stand out in Fig. 53 where — the growing season is short (northern Europe); — the precipitation is high (mountain areas, especially the Alpine area and the mountains in western Great Britain); — the precipitation, though not very high, is well distributed seasonally and accompanied by high humidity (Great Britain and the Atlantic coastal area of France); and — the precipitation, though not very high, is supplemented by irrigation (Po Plain). Northern Europe shows very clearly that as the growing season becomes shorter with approach to the Arctic Circle, the cropping period for leys lengthen and the regions of ley farming consequently assume an increasingly extensive character. A useful economic life of only two years for leys is typical of Jutland and Scania, while in central Sweden it is already three years. With advances into still more northerly latitudes periods lengthen to four, five, six, and more years. In Great Britain, ley farming exhibits an east-west as well as north-south differentiation. The. north-south contrast is caused by the shortening of the growing season in the direction of Scotland, whereas the east-west differentiation results from the gradual rise of the terrain from the east coast to the west, up to the mountain areas of Cornwall, Wales, and Cumberland. Somewhat unexpected is the marked prominence of ley farming in France. The reason, besides the moist Atlantic climate and the highlands of the French Central Plateau, may be the relatively extensive type of agriculture that characterizes almost all French agricultural zones. Especially extreme forms of ley farming may appear in the Alpine area because here high precipitation and a short growing season converge. Since the place-specific factors are numerous (altitude, slope, exposure,
1. The Agricultural Geography of Western Europe
213
etc.) and vary sharply within small areas, a minutely compartmentalized and variegated picture of widely contrasting agricultural regions is typical. Ley farming based on irrigation is represented on the Po Plain. The warm climate, combined with a rich supply of water flowing from the Alps, has allowed the development of an extraordinarily productive ley system. The many cuttings make possible a large investment in livestock, the majority of which are kept in the stall the year around. This agricultural region is the most important dairy area of Italy. Two large regions stand as symbols of annual-crop farming. Fig. 53 clearly shows the influence of a changing grassland-farmland ratio north of the Alps. In general, it can be said that areas with a large proportion of land in permanent grassland are characterized by rotations poorer in leafy crops. Thus the great grassland girdle of the North Sea coastal area stands out like the pre-Alpine areas with a heavy emphasis on grain cropping. Even more influential is the size of farm. The West German states (Länder) with relatively large farms, such as Schleswig-Holstein, Lower Saxony, Westphalia, and Bavaria, are characterized by four- and three-course rotations of annual crops. In contrast, in the federal states settled by small farmers, such as Hesse and Baden-Württemberg, Norfolk rotations or their related forms are still practiced to some extent. Fig. 53 shows the South European region of annual-crop farming as having overall a large proportion in leafy crops. Usually at least the stage of Norfolk rotations, and often even that of practically no grain rotations, is attained. The reasons, among others, are: — The correlation between grassland share and crop rotation, so obvious in Central Europe, is less clear in Southern Europe. This is because the mild climate provides a long, in part year-around grazing season, so that a larger grassland proportion and more livestock do not necessarily require that a large amount of land be given to grain for supplying feed and straw. — Also to be kept in mind is that the hot, dry climate allows barn manure to have only a minor effect. Grain cropping with an emphasis on manuring is typical only of locations in mid-latitude climates. — In addition, since there is only a minor operational need for grain hectarage, more land can be given over to the cultivation of leafy crops, here in the form of grain corn. Corn is an ideal leafy crop for warm climatic areas. Also, all of its cropping procedures can be mechanized for maximum effect, and thus it does not have nearly the labor-intensive character of the most important representatives of leafy crop cultivation in Central Europe, sugar beets and potatoes.
214
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
Thus countries and regions with climates suitable for grain corn, when faced with rising wage levels and increasing pressures for mechanization, do not depend as heavily on rotations emphasizing small grains as does Central Europe. The Klagenfurt Basin and Krappfeld areas of Carinthia are outstanding examples of this. If one looks at the crop rotation regions of Europe as a whole and views them in strongly simplified outline, three large rotation regions can be seen to stand out: — A region with heavy emphasis on fodder cropping. It is characterized by ley farming and it embraces, besides Scandinavia, the entire Atlantic coastal area and the mountain regions. — A region with heavy emphasis on grain cropping. It is characterized by four- and three-course rotations and it embraces the entire block of Central and Eastern Europe. — A region with heavy emphasis on leafy crops. It lies in the Mediterranean area and comprises the countries with a climate suitable for grain corn, such as Spain, southern Italy, and Jugoslavia.
d) Land Use Regions Fig. 53, showing crop rotation regions, can only offer insights into the organization of crop farming. If one wishes to obtain an overview of the organization of the entire agricultural area, permanent grassland and bush and tree crops must also be considered. Land use systems must be delimited, as is done in Fig. 54. The methodology for obtaining this more comprehensive view was illustrated above (Chapter VIII-1-b). First all land use enterprises were assigned to one of four major groups (fodder cropping, grain cropping, hoe cropping, specialty crops). Then the share of each of these major groups in % AL was determined, using mean data for administrative units. These figures were then multiplied by a weighted index number based on normal work procedures. The product of crop share and index number yielded the crop weight. The crop group with the highest crop weight represents the lead crop, or principal cropping emphasis, and the second highest represents the companion crop, or secondary cropping emphasis. Lead and companion crops give the land use system its name. If one of the four crop groups obtains two thirds or more of the total crop weight, the land use system is identified only by the lead crop. Fig. 54 allows us to recognize in macrospatial form a threefold division of land use regions in Europe: 1. In Northern Europe we find a region of fodder cropping farms. It is supplemented by the greater part of Great Britain, which in the Atlantic coastal areas is especially favorable for fodder growth, and the
1. The Agricultural Geography of Western Europe
Agricultural
215
Land Use Systems in the European Community
AUSTRIA
ΓΓΠ F o d d e r c r o p p i n g
VVCORSICA
Fodder c r o p p i n g - g r a i n or r e v e r s e
Χ/λ
cropping, ( o. r. I
Fodder c r o p p i n g - h o e c r o p f a r m i n g o r.
SSSl F o d d e r c r o p p i n g - s p e c i a l t y
«¡Jii·:?-^ S A R D I N I A
c r o p s o. r.
B S Hoe c r o p f a r m i n g - g r a i n c r o p p i n g
o. r. SICILY
figa Specialty
c r o p s - hoe crop f a r m i n g
252 Specialty
crops
The
first-named
cropping
the
next
According
Figure 54
highest to
the
share land
emphasis
of
the
use
requires
labor censuses
demand for
o r. the
highest
forali the
and
the
second-named
agricultural
period
19SS
-
land 1961.
use.
one
216
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
European highlands, especially the Alpine area, but also such places as the French Central Plateau and the higher locations in the Black Forest. Grain cropping occurs as a companion enterprise in fodder cropping with a shorter growing season or on larger farms, or in both situations (Central England). In contrast, with a longer growing season or smaller farms, or both situations, hoe cropping becomes the secondary operation (Norway, Black Forest). Finally, if the growing season is still longer and the terrain rugged, fodder cropping can appear in combination form with specialty crops (central France). 2. In Central Europe we have a region of hoe cropping farms. The greater parts of northeastern France, western Germany, and Poland stand as a symbol of hoe-grain crop farming. Much less common is the combination of the system with a secondary emphasis on fodder cropping (eastern Scotland, Brittany), and even more rarely, on bush and tree crops. 3. Southern Europe, finally, stands as a symbol of specialty crop farms. Wherever a warm, hot climate has favored bush and tree crops, there the specialty crop system with its many variants has arisen. Fodder cropping appears as a secondary enterprise in rugged mountain areas, while on the dry plains the role is taken over by grain cropping and in Italy by hoe cropping. If we compare this picture of land use regions with the maps depicting the place-specific conditions for Europe, the following can be said: — There is a clear relationship between land use systems and the temperature and the length of the growing season. Fodder cropping systems predominate where the growing season is short and the climate cold. The group of hoe cropping systems begin to appear as the growing season becomes longer and the climate more moderate. In a very warm and hot climate, it is the group of specialty cropping systems that dominates. — Land use systems are also clearly related to the amount and seasonal distribution of precipitation. Fodder cropping systems are definitely prominent in a very moist climate, as are hoe cropping systems in a moderately moist climate and specialty cropping systems in a dry climate. The distribution of precipitation also exerts an influence on the shaping of land use systems. Fodder cropping needs uniformly distributed precipitation. Hoe cropping also requires a fairly balanced precipitation level during the growing season and in our middle latitudes needs an especially good amount of moisture in July and August. Where the precipitation maximum is earlier and there is a pronounced spring drought, grain cropping succeeds as the lead enterprise. If the precipitation distribution becomes even more unfavorable and the climate has a decidedly dry summer, as in the Mediterranean area, bush and tree crops gain ground. Their deep root systems enable
1. The Agricultural Geography of Western Europe
217
them to make much better use of the groundwater than do the annual crops, and for that reason they can better survive longer drought periods. Fodder cropping puts its stamp on the most extensive land use regions. The distributional structure of fodder cropping regions is appropriately the reflection of the climatic realms, for climate, from a macrospatial standpoint, is the underlying initiator of fodder cropping in general and its modifications in particular. Three types of fodder cropping regions distinguished by climate appear in Europe. The polar fodder cropping regions are found in Scandinavia. Fodder cropping comes increasingly to the fore as one goes poleward, and the reasons for this are the shortening of the growing season and the unusual light and heat conditions in the realm of the midnight sun. These circumstances overwhelmingly favor fodder cropping. It becomes increasingly competitive with commercial cropping toward the pole, until finally it cimpletely displaces it. The maritime fodder cropping regions embrace those of the northwest German and Dutch coastal areas, Great Britain, and the region around Cherbourg. Here it is less the amount of precipitation and more its good distribution and high humidity that favors fodder cropping. The maritime climate is better suited to grazing pasture than moweing meadow. This is particularly the case where the winters are mild enough to allow almost year-around grazing, while on the other hand the colder winters of the German marsh belt cause a feed shortage. Types of livestock farming that make possible a seasonal adjustment of herd size to a drop in feed supplies (livestock raising and summer feeding farms) are then regarded as desirable. A short growing season and abundant moisture combine to give their stamp to the montane fodder cropping regions. It stands to reason that fodder cropping will assume extreme forms in precisely the higher mountains. The largest single montane fodder cropping region is the Alpine area, including the foothills. However, fodder cropping appears at specific altitudes in almost all European highland areas, such as the Black Forest, Vosges, Hohe Venn, Sauerland, Ardennes, and French Jura and Central Plateau. The mountain climate favors pasture mowing over grazing. This has its advantages for management because the winters are long. The farming enterprise of combined fodder cropping and livestock raising is, apart from the raising of certain specialty crops, the only one in European agriculture that permits monoculture. Today one of the most important and extreme forms of specialization taking place on fodder cropping farms of up to 30 ha is the abandoning of the remaining crop areas and a shifting to pure grassland farming. The examples in the Dutch grassland marshes or in the Württemberg Algäu show that the pure grassland farm can be operated more profitably than the mixed
218
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
farm. If despite this advantage the shift to pure grassland farming is taking place only slowly, this is because of the sizable capital investments required. Even if the intensification of farming practices is now economically attractive, it also requires more livestock and more room for stalls, hay, and silage. Investment needs are also increased considerably when the grassland areas are enlarged as well as farmed more intensively. Grain cropping farms also feature locational types that differ in cause, characteristics, and problems. The dominant grain cropping enterprise can be coupled to a companion enterprise of fodder cropping or hoe cropping, whereas it is only seldom combined with specialty crops. In the Mediterranean countries, a pronounced summer drought leads to the superiority of grain cropping on the large farms. So long as irrigation is impossible, preference must be given to crops that can adapt to this precipitation distribution by making good use of the winter moisture and ripening soon after the onset of the dry summer. These are the earlier ripening grain types, especially the winter grains. Motivations are quite different in the soil-determined grain cropping economies. In the fertile lands of the "grain börde" it has been the very special loess soil with its even deposition and weak admixtures of loam that have strongly encouraged grain cropping. The physical characteristics of this soil are much more favorable for grain production than for hoe crops. The heart of this grain börde lies in the Westphalian border area surrounding Lippstadt, Soest, and Warburg. A northern outlier runs from Warburg into the Hanoverian Kalenberg country, a southern one into the Hessian loess zone. Everywhere in these areas, grain cropping has been widely distributed for decades. Similar farming structures are found today on the young cultivated marshes. Grain yields of 40 to 55 q/ha and rape yields of 25 to 35 q/ha now make it impossible for hoe cropping, already handicapped by the fall dampness, to compete. Here it is a matter of operators of land-rich or wage-labor family farms being able, or even having to abandon hoe cropping and livestock raising in favor solely of crops that can be harvested by combine, thus crops whose labor productivity (net) can hardly be surpassed. Fehmarn Island is an example of where grain and rape cultivation today is strongly emphasized and uniformly developed. The need to improve the labor setup by shifting to less intensive land use is also one that faces operators of land-rich and wage-labor family farms on other soil types, as it does all over Europe. Grain cropping is especially favored where the labor capacity of the farm is extremely limited, for it requires only minor labor expenditures because of the nature of the crops and is the most capable of being mechanized by present technological standards. Because of the influence of place-specific motives on grain farming, which have already been noted, grain cropping farms are distributed in
1. The Agricultural Geography of Western Europe
219
more isolated than agglomerated fashion, and only rarely in the form of compact regions. It is certain, though, that mechanization in the future will strengthen even more the trend to grain farming, for grain cultivation can be mechanized today far more efficiently than hoe cropping or the combined enterprise of fodder cropping-livestock raising. Fully mechanized grain cropping now requires only 20 to 25 MH/ha and has become almost impervious to wage labor costs. This contrasts with the at least 100 to 110 MH/ha needed for raising seed potatoes and the 55 to 63 MH/ha required for sugar beets. A further stimulus to grain cultivation is that a three- to four-year succession of the crop is no longer as disadvantageous as it was still two decades ago, thanks to greater efficiency and more chemical fertilization, therapeutic plant protection, and chemical weed control. The group of hoe cropping systems can be subdivided two ways, by the extent of hoe cropping and by the principal hoe crop type (sugar beets, potatoes, field vegetables, and the like). Prerequisites for the development of hoe cropping farms are: — a soil favorable for hoe cropping; — a long growing season, which facilitates work spacing; — only a small part of the land in grassland; — a favorable market location for hoe crops; — a rational distribution of fields; and — farm sizes suitable for the most intensive cultivation, thus land-poor family farms or large scale wage-labor farms. Hoe crop-grain crop farming is a very adaptable and well balanced system that is extensively distributed in the mid-latitude climatic zone and can still be encountered on almost all types of soil, so long as they are not too heavy. It can be found on both the sandy soils of the North German Plain and the intermediate soils of the broad loess belt deposited on the edge of the Central German Highlands, on what are often quite heavy loam soils in Hesse and Franconia, and finally even on the clay soils of the Dutch province of Zeeland and of Brittany. In contrast, pure hoe cropping, that is with at least 35% FL in hoe crops, has much more sharply fixed soil demands. Practically no other soils but of the intermediate kind allow it to satisfy the following prerequisites: — Several types of hoe crops must be able to be raised, since the reciprocal relationships in the system complex make it almost impossible for just one crop type to attain 35% FL. As a result, — the soil must be heavy enough to be able to support sugar beets, but — at the same time not so heavy that it hinders profitable potato cultivation. With these requirements, the soil conditions for the pure hoe cropping system are already quite closely determined. These conditions are given
220
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
on the darker and loamier soils of the central loess belt in the Hildesheim-Brunswick börde, the Cologne-Aachen Bay, parts of Flanders and Brabant, the Rhine-Main area, and the Rhine Plain in Baden, as well as on the portions of recent diluvium in the eastern parts of North Hanover around Burgdorf, Uelzen, and Lüneburg. Pure hoe cropping is more independent of soils where field vegetables are raised in the vicinity of large markets, such as West Berlin, the Vierland area near Hamburg, the Vorgebirge, or hill lands around Bonn, and next to the Naples-Salerno population agglomeration. Grain cropping offers only small resistance to the penetration of these locations by hoe cropping. Grain and hay harvests are so plentiful that the grain hectarage required for internal economies is at a minimum. The developmental tendencies of hoe cropping are not the same for the two farm size classes for which it is suited. Operators on large scale wagelabor farms, which are extremely sensitive to wage labor costs, are now trying to parry rapidly rising wages with mechanization and other technologies. That is why they tend to restrict hoe cropping in favor of enterprises that can be more easily mechanized, the raising of grains and oil crops. In the warmer climates this tendency is not discernible because there hoe crops are available that can be fully mechanized at all stages of work. In the U.S., soybeans, peanuts, and cotton have made it possible to develop farming systems that put an extraordinary emphasis on hoe crops and yet save on labor. In contrast, operators on the land-poor family farms remain true to hoe cropping in spite of mechanization difficulties, for they must use their rich and readily available family labor supply that would otherwise be unexploited and increase by all means available their gross income with the help of higher gross returns. However, in climatic zones that are warmer, sunnier, and free of late frost, the same need applies to the rainsing of bush and tree crops of a specialty type, which are generally adopted where a suitable climate combines with a lack of land and a high rural settlement density. Specialty crop farms are even more climatically conditioned than fodder cropping farms, and even more in need of full labor utilization and a production increase than hoe cropping farms. The map shows them to be in southern Italy, in Sicily and Corsica, on the Riviera, in Provence and Languedoc and far into the Rhone Valley, also in the Garonne, in the Upper Rhine and Mosel valleys, as well as other places. Still this map does not do justice to the distribution of specialty crop farms, since bush and tree crops frequently do double duty in cultivated fields and in meadows. One need only think of the extensive areas of the Po Plain, which in the statistics appear as cultivated land but actually comprise grain fields interrupted by rows of fruit trees, among which are strung a third crop, grapevines.
1. The Agricultural Geography of Western Europe
221
Bush and tree crops of a specialty type appear in Western Europe in the forms of: 1. fruit growing with modest heat demands (Altes Land near Hamburg, Lake Constance area); 2. viticulture; 3. olive cultivation; and 4. fruit growing with exacting heat demands (citrus fruit, figs, almonds, cherries, apricots). Climatic demands increase from 1 to 4. Grapevines already need a mean annual temperature of at least +9.5°C and come into conflict with hoe cropping in the dry-summer Mediterranean climate. Olives and citrus fruit are confined to Spain and central and southern Italy. Monoculture occurs in specialty crop farming just as it does on fodder crop farms. This is especially true for viticulture, which can employ family labor productively throughout the year. Citrus fruit raising also shows a strong tendency toward monoculture. In Europe, though, little use is made of the specialized farm. The standard is the mixed farm, since it has the advantages of reducing risk, providing fertilizer balance, and spacing work. The question now is what crop groups can specialty crops associate with in the farm unit. Naturally either feed or grain crops must be preeminent, for the cultivation of specialty crops requires large amounts of manure, which in turn demand companion crops of land use enterprises that supply it. There is also the. fact, however, that hoe cropping does not fit in with specialty crop farming in the economic aspects of labor, since both create high labor peaks in the fall. Hoe cropping thus competes with the specialty crops for the labor and manuring capacity of the farm, so that as a rule specialty crop farms must do without a large quota of hoe crops. Fig. 54 shows that actually specialty crops are usually combined with fodder cropping in all mountainous areas. In the mountain lands, the different climatic requirements of both crop groups can be satisfied. Let one recall, for example, the steep slopes of the Mosel or Ruwer valleys, which are covered with vines that find ideal environmental conditions with southern exposure. The valley bottoms and the summits of the Eifel and Hunsriick, in contrast, have a larger share of fodder crops. In this way it is possible to combine manure-producing fodder crops with manure-demanding specialty crops. This is also a successful solution from the standpoint of labor demand, since viticulture requires predominantly summer work while livestock raising requires more winter work. But where there is only level land and thus little climatic contrast, and where the climate moreover is dry, bush and tree crop farming combines with a larger share of grain cropping. Grain cropping also fits in quite well with bush and tree crops from the standpoint of labor spacing. It also has a complementary relationship with respect to manuring needs, for it furnishes raw material for humus in the form of straw.
222
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
Finally, we also come upon a combination of bush and tree crops with more emphatic hoe cropping. That such farming types can occur, though we have earlier established that hoe crops and specialty crops compete for the labor and manuring capacity of the farm, can be explained as follows: — Farm size favors this combination in the Upper Rhine Valley. The small peasant farmers must increase their organizational intensity by all available means. The family labor situation makes it possible to deal with the fall labor peaks, which are caused by the grape and hoe crop harvests. — The explanation for the specialty crop-hoe crop farms in Italy is quite different. The useful effect of barn manure in the Mediterranean and subtropical climate is only minor. At the same time, though, production costs for barn manure are high when year-around grazing is possible, in that animals must be stabled and fodder crops harvested simply for the sake of producing barn manure. Farming based on manure production is therefore largely dispensed with. For these reasons, there is little competition between specialty and hoe crops in the subtropics for manure. As to the need for work spacing, we must bear in mind that hoe cropping in the Mediterranean area is mostly a winter operation. But if this is the case, the hoe crop and specialty crop harvests no longer make heavy demands on labor during the same period. The orange harvest in Sicily lasts from November to April and does not interrupt the later potato and sugar beet harvests. Thus with the shift of hoe crops to the winter, and consequently their harvests to the spring, the labor-demand relationships between specialty crops and hoe crops are turned around. Hoe cropping now not only ceases to compete with specialty crop farming, it complements it. This is why the combination of hoe cropping and specialty crop farming prevails so widely in Italy, whereas it is hardly imaginable for farm management in most of the middle latitudes. Thus we have another illustration of the fact that there are simply no models in agriculture that have validity everywhere and at all times.
e) Livestock Regions Next we shall show, with the aid of Fig. 55, the regional structure and zonal arrangement of the livestock raising systems in the European Community. The delimitation of the system was made in the same way as was done for the land use systems (Ch. VIII-1-b). The four most important livestock enterprises selected were those emphasizing dairy cows, young cattle, small ruminants, and swine. Poultry were not considered. Only a brief look at Fig. 55 is enough to convince one of the outstanding importance of milk production in European livestock raising. Pure
1. The Agricultural Geography of Western Europe
223
JL Livestock Raising in the European
111
Da,r
ËHI
Dairying-hog
^ ^
D a i r y i n g - r a i s i n g of y o u n g
>" n 9 raising
R a i s i n g of y o u n g '
~ 1 Dai rying - sheep
Γ| [~[¡ S h e e p
and goat
}-!->[ S h e e p
The
and goat
first-named
highest
share
Developed
Figure 55
Systems Community
t y p e of of
from
the
cattle
cattle - d a i r y i n g and goat
raising
raising - dairying r a i s i ng - r a i s i n g
livestock
labor
livestock
raising
demand
counts
for
takes all
for
SICILY
of y o u n g c a t t l e (or reverse!
the
highest
livestock
the
time
and
the
raising.
about
I960.
second - named
one
the
next
224
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
dairying, i.e. a system in which dairying makes up at least two thirds of the total livestock weight, is found only in more northerly latitudes, beginning with the Po Plain and Gascony. Only in these areas are the amount and seasonal distribution of precipitation favorable enough so that dairy farming systems, so highly dependent on seasonal feed balance, can strongly dominate. But, for dairy farming systems to flourish, it is not only necessary to have a good feed base and favorable labor situation, but also to have all other enterprises with ruminants impeded in their development. That is why dairying systems occur more frequently — in fodder cropping than in other land use systems, since this system usually provides no appropriate feed sources for small ruminants. This is true, of course, only for the plains; — on family farms than on large scale wage-labor farms, since the larger units put more emphasis on cattle raising and fattening to save on labor; — on plains than in mountains, since mountainous areas may provide a summer feed surplus for raising young cattle (Norway, Alps) and are often so afflicted by drought, sterile soils, steep slopes, and rocky surfaces that they are fit only for grazing by small ruminants (Scotland, Sardinia, Apennines); and — in the East Bloc countries than in the Western countries, since the economic situation for food production in the East Bloc countries favors the more efficient nutrient transformer, the dairy cow, over the far less efficient transforming agent, the feeder animal. A dairy cow with five years of useful economic life and 4,500 kg annual milk production converts 100 kg of plant protein into 38.9 kg of animal protein, whereas a feeder animal (young feeder with 500 kg final weight) yields only 12.7 kg animal protein. For carbohydrates and fats, the comparative yield figures are 25.2 versus 5.2%. Thus only the wealthier peoples can raise the nutrient-expensive feeder on a large scale. Regions of combined dairying and raising of young cattle occur where the above-named qualifications for dairying are not quite so favorable. The raising of young cattle acquires the character of a companion livestock enterprise, either through a considerable emphasis on breeding (large parts of West Germany) or through provision of a greater role for fattening (England, France). In the latter case it may even become the lead enterprise, which as a rule requires that pure cattle fattening farms process more beef animal types (eastern England, Ireland). Fig. 56 shows more clearly the variations that the dairy cow-young cattle combination is capable of, and how the individual cattle farming types are associated with the agricultural zones for the Common Market of the Nine (see also Fig. 57). Less common is the association of dairying with sheep and goat raising. These combinations are found
1. The Agricultural Geography of Western Europe
225
Cattle Farming in the European
... young
cattle
per 100 d a i r y c o w s pT7!7
up
Y^fy
Principal
Farm
Type
to
40
D r y l o t and s e m i - d r y l o t
41 -
90
Self-supplying
dairy
9| - 150
Dairy-cattle
raising
j ^ s ^ l 151 - 300
Dairy-cattle
fattening
! · > & ! 301 - 600
Cattle
over 600
Cattle
Developed
Figure 56
from
livestock
farms farms farms farms
f a t t e n i n g - dai ry f a r m s fattening counts
for
farms the
period
1957
to
1962.
Types Community
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
226
— in the mountains of western Norway, where the sterile, steep, and rocky surfaces are fit for no other agricultural use but sheep and goat grazing, and where the milking of goats for human use is a feature of the many small part-time farms; and - in the mountainous parts of the Mediterranean area (see Fig. 55), where besides the already-noted inducements for the raising of small ruminants, there is the long summer drought that calls for ruminants that can range widely enough to obtain adequate feed, and in more critical situations, survive on brush (goats). Small ruminants also can, because of their great talent for climbing, find nourishment in high mountainous areas that are less affected by drought but cannot be reached by cattle. Types of Cattle Raising and their Locationa! SDl
Dl
SD
FARM
up
to
¿0
DAIRY
DCF
DCR
0 R Y LOT FARM S EM 1 - 0 RY LOT SELF-SUPPLYING FARM
CFD
DAIRY-CATTLE
DAIRY-CATTLE
RAISING FARM
FATTENING FARM
151 -
9 1 - 150 Young cattle
41-90
incréasing
in
per
Labor ,
100
dairy
of
demand
Permanent
CATTLE
FATTENING-DAIRY
FATTENING
RAISING-FATTENING
FARM
FARM
3 0 1 - 6 0 0
FARM over
600
cows
the
arrow
.
g r a s s l a n d , •/·
Market distance
price •
CRF
CATTLE
Farm size (FL)
)
Milk
CF
CATTLE
300
the direction
Orientation
increasing P r i c e of
)
in r e l a t i o n
to
heifers
P r i c e of s l a u g h t e r c a t t l e H 1
Wage Selling
of
level
»
animals
Figure 57
Where conditions for dairying are still relatively favorable, sheep and goat raising occur only as a companion enterprise (Norway, Abruzzi, Sicily). In contrast, where the place-specific factors are especially extreme, sheep and goat raising become such powerful competitors of dairying for the most efficient use of feed that they become the lead livestock enterprise. This reduction of dairying, from its normally dominating p o s i t i o n a l m o s t e v e r y w h e r e in E u r o p e t o a c o m p a n i o n role, o c c u r s m o s t
1. The Agricultural Geography of Western Europe
227
prominently along parts of the French Mediterranean coast and in Corsica, Sardinia, and the southern Italian massif (Fig. 55). In other regions, dairying finally drops out of the system classification altogether, as the raising of young cattle now become the principal companion livestock enterprise. This can be explained by severe summer drought or high mountain locations, combined with a variety of economic inducements for cattle feeding (Wales, Scotland). Systems combining the raising of sheep, goats, and young cattle become the accepted livestock raising systems. Hog raising usually occurs as a companion enterprise of dairying and here serves as, among other things, a superior processor of skim milk. In Europe, four regions of hog raising with four different feed bases stand out: — the acorn hog-fattening area of the Iberian Peninsula; — the grain com hog-fattening area in Hungary, Vojvodina, and the Banat (Mangalitza breed); — the potato hog-fattening area embracing the light soils of the North European Plain (including Farther Pomerania), where in the industrial countries for the last two decades farmers have been rapidly switching over to grain feeding; and — the old barley hog-fattening area, with the agricultural-export country of Denmark as the prototype. Barley feeding also dominates in WestGermany, but is being increasingly supplemented by corn. Although hog raising is frequently a lead livestock enterprise on individual farms, it is seldom important enough to characterize large regional units.
f ) Complex Agricultural Regions The methods of delimiting land use and livestock raising systems (Figs. 54 and 55) have been selected so that systems are now statistically compatible and therefore can be combined to represent the total, or farming system. Eight farm enterprises (four land use and four livestock enterprises) and a farming weight, calculated by summing the total crop and livestock weights, are the principal elements in the computation of the farming system. Farming systems can then be characterized by the three most important farm enterprises, the lead, companion, and supplementary enterprises. They are the farm enterprises that claim the highest, second highest, and third highest share of the labor demand of the farm and thus are particularly prominent in the farming weight. Theoretically, there are no less than 520 farming systems possible using the classification applied here. The outward manifestations of the agricultural operations on our continent are thus so diverse and complex
228
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
that only a multi-patterned map (and then only in simplified form) makes it possible to obtain an overview of the geographic distribution and quantitative significance of the farming systems in the European area. There now only remains the task of combining the representations in Figs. 54 and 55 into regional models of farming systems. In light of the farm size structure and high degree of industrialization in Europe, it is only natural that intensive farm interprises leave their stamp on family farms almost everywhere. They are predominantly: — dairying in the oceanic climate of the northwestern part of the continent; — hoe cropping in the transitional climate of Central Europe; and — bush and tree crop farming in the Mediterranean climate of Southern Europe. Our computations have supported this threefold regional subdivision. In one region the lead enterprise is dairying, in the second it is hoe cropping, and in the third it is the raising of bush and tree crops. It is also clear that these large agricultural zones are associated with the major climatic areas. Thirdly, we can now observe that the farming systems change from northern to southern Europe in such a way that a dominating secondary production gradually gives way to a dominating and finally exclusive primary production. This is illustrated with the aid of Fig. 58. This map shows the total farming weights broken down into their crop and livestock components. It gives information on the stages of labor intensity in land use. One can observe that labor intensity in primary production in Europe increases progressively from north to south. Labor intensity in land use must be increased to the same extent that fodder cropping is replaced by hoe cropping, and it, in turn, by the cultivation of bush and tree crops. That the map does not show these relations very clearly on a large areal scale can be explained in part by the highly varying farm sizes within small areas, a common situation for Europe. Further, one can see that the gradation of labor intensity in livestock raising is completely different. In secondary production, the labor intensity of the Northwest European countries with their heavy emphasis on dairying and hog raising puts them at the top of scale, whereas that of the Mediterranean area with its minor livestock role puts it at the lower end. In Northwestern Europe, labor on the farm is used mainly for livestock raising, whereas production stressing fodder cropping requires less work. In contrast, in Southern Europe the labor potential of the farm is used chiefly for specialty crops, while livestock raising is given little space. The overall labor intensity of the farm thus presents a more balanced picture than the gradations revealed by the isolated examinations of primary production on the one hand and secondary production on the other.
1. The Agricultural Geography of Western Europe
229
Figure 58
In a large free-trading area, every production orientation has, according to the iron laws of spatial economic equilibrium, the tendency to move to the locations where its products can be most cheaply produced and brought to consumers. The spatial arrangement of the production enter-
230
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
prises of agriculture then becomes the result of competition. Where goods can flow freely across political boundaries, this competition is not so much that of overall national agricultural economies as it is of similar farming systems that compete across frontiers. This is especially the case in the vicinities of the internal boundaries of the European Community. Thus, for example, the fodder cropping farmers of the German North Sea coastal areas, who cannot do away with extensive and large scale stall feeding, have come into competition with the fodder cropping farmers of the French Atlantic coast, who with year-around grazing can produce much more cheaply. Farmers in the Cologne-Aachen Bay and certain Belgian districts compete to supply the sugar refineries in the region. Also drawn into competition are the vintners of the Rhine, Mosel, Saar, and Ruwer areas with those in the climatically favored. French vineyards. Operators in the fruit farming regions in the Altes Land or next to Lake Constance must defend themselves from the competition of those in the climatically-favored South Tyrol, not to mention the growing challenge, in turn, to all the Central European fruit farmers by the producers of tropical and subtropical fruits. Potato cropping farmers of the Ems country and the Münster Bay contest the potato farmer of the Dutch Geest; vegetable growers in the Dutch province of Zeeland struggle with those of the Bonn Vorgebirge to satisfy consumer demand in the Rhine industrial area. French and West German farmers raising slaughter cattle compete for the Italian market. All of these examples are but a few of those illustrating that in the long run it is not the national agricultural economies as a whole that compete across international boundaries, but rather similar agricultural regions and farm types. This interregional competition is governed by a widely varying areal range of influence, the extent varying from product to product. To cite a few examples: — When fruit and vegetables flow from Holland to the Rhine-Ruhr area today, this is only partly because of the objective locational advantages of our neighboring country. There is also the subjective factor, the greater "know how" of the Dutch gained through much longer experience. Together they lead to such a better input-output ratio that the costs of transport into the Federal Republic are justified. — When early potatoes come into the German markets from Sicily during middle and late March and from Campania in April, we have a situation in which there is no competition. These crops are also still competitive at the end of May, since they are ready for harvest, while the West German early potatoes usually still are not. The climatically-determined early harvest dates for southern Italy and southern France are so advantageous for prices that the long rail journey of perishable products is still worthwhile. For the West German producer of early potatoes, this means an almost ruinous competition.
1. The Agricultural Geography of Western Europe
231
— Many large farmers in the Federal Republic today would like to use residual pasture and beet leaf for raising calves, but the profit position of the enterprise is unsatisfactory. In large parts of England and France, however, the raising of calves is one of the traditional farm enterprises. Cheaper land and a milder winter make it possible for the farmer to operate with less expense for land use, buildings, winter feed, and labor. Production costs in parts of England and France are so small that the farmer can also profit from calf raising, an enterprise that is by nature weak in output but in any case still more profitable here than in West Germany. In all three of these examples German agriculture has, through no fault of its own, locational handicaps and thus competitive disadvantages. These in turn reduce income, so long as variations in production costs cannot be sufficiently equalized through interregional differentiations of agricultural prices. It is quite obvious from all this that: — labor-intensive farm enterprises, other things being equal, are favored in countries with still relatively low wage levels; — crops whose raising can be most profitably mechanized do not belong in rugged mountain lands; — individual farm size classes have their different spheres of interest in the rest of Europe just as they do in West Germany; and — quality is playing an increasingly decisive role for fruit, wine, malting barley, and the like. Thus, for example, the Wèst German farmer raising malting barley need not fear the competition of partner countries in the European Community, since domestic malting barley production has a clear advantage in quality and transport costs which the German maltman and brewer cannot do without. The qualitative advantage of our malting barleys, noticeable practically every year, results in good market opportunities in the European Community for the German farmer. These few observations on the interregional competition of farm enterprises, farm systems, and agricultural regions along the internal boundaries of Europe are still further evidence of how indispensable a structural analysis of the European area, from an agricultural-geographic and farm management standpoint, is to an equitable and balanced regional development policy for the Community of the Nine.
g) Summary There is no economic enterprise that is so spatially bound as agriculture. For the scientific regional analysis of large areas like that of the European Community, climate is the most important differentiating locational factor for agricultural production.
232
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
Climates in the area of the Common Market of the Nine range from a Central European transitional type to a pronounced oceanic type, and from mountain varieties to the Mediterranean and subtropical types. The area thus offers the most varied conditions for agricultural production, as well as an extraordinary diversity of farming types. Their regional distribution was presented in a series of maps, based on a newly developed classification. The agricultural regions that were delimited almost completely blot out the international boundaries. This is an indication of the dominance of the ecological factors over the economic qualifications of production. Consequently it is not primarily the overall national agricultural economies of the European Community that compete across the frontiers, but rather the farming types and agricultural regions that are conditioned by the same physical elements.
2. The Agricultural Geography of North America The treatment of the agricultural geography of North America will be essentially confined to the United States. The total national area will be considered, though the western part (approximately west of the 100th meridian) is classed with the dry areas and therefore was partly discussed in part in Chapter VII. The large Canadian area will only occasionally be referred to since the agricultural geography of its southern provinces resembles that of northern U.S. (see Fig. 13, p. 61), while the agricultural-geographic conditions in northern Canada duplicate those of northern Scandinavia and northern Russia: forest regions with scattered fodder cropping farms concentrating on ley farming, followed by forest and shrub regions, and finally transition to the tundra.
a) Place-Specific Characteristics of the United States The United States encompasses within its boundaries many agricultural regions of the mid-latitude climatic zones, and in addition some important agricultural regions of the dry climates. The reasons for this great variety lie in the sharp variations of the physical and economic bases of production. Without a doubt, the largest industrial agglomeration of the U.S. lies in the Northeastern states. The Northeast, however, can no longer be considered as the only economic focal point in the U.S. As early as the year 1818, Goethe had expressed a belief to his friend Eckermann that
2. The Agricultural Geography of North America
233
some day one would establish a navigable link between the Mediterranean and Red seas. He also predicted that a canal would be cut through Central America, and that when completed, the center of gravity in the United States would gradually shift from the Northeast to the Pacific Coast. With the realization of the first two predictions by Goethe, it now appears that the third will also come true. During the 1940—50 decade, the population of California grew by 53%. The economic development of the San Francisco Bay Area and Los Angeles-San Bernardino-San Diego region has been grandiose, and obviously has also had an influence on the agriculture of the hinterlands. Today a third economic focal point is developing in the Texas oil area, though of course for ecological reasons it has had less effect on agriculture. Insofar as physical conditions are concerned, the principal mountains and rivers generally run in a north-south direction and in so doing divide the U.S. into five major natural areas, namely
Annual
Precipitation
| = Ξ ) 380 - 520 After Kincer and In; Atlas of American
Figure 59
in the United
g s ^ 760 - 1000 Marschner, Agriculture.
==j
Weather Bureau, U.S.D.A. Washington. 1936.
States
over
1270
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
234
1. the Atlantic Coastal Plain, which extends from the New England states to Florida and finds its westerly limit in the Appalachian Highlands; 2. the Appalachian Highlands themselves, with their broad masses and deeply incised transverse valleys; 3. the Mississippi and Missouri basins, with their extensive, fertile, and centrally-located plains, overlain in large sections by chernozem and prairie soils; 4. the immense highland area between the Rocky Mountains in the east and the Sierra Nevada and Cascade mountains in the west; and 5. the Pacific Coastal Lowlands, with their orographic and topographic peculiarities. This physiospatial arrangement influences the variation in precipitation conditions decisively. Viewed macrospatially, one can say that annual precipitation decreases from east to west, from 1,200 to 1,500 mm in the humid Atlantic coastal area to less than 200 mm in the arid Western Mountain states (see Fig. 59, above). The east-west arrangement of precipitation zones is countered by a northsouth differentiation in the growing season (Fig. 60). It decreases from
The Available
Growing Season in the United
States
A n n u a l Crowing S e a s o n in D a y s W \
below 120
ϋΠ3 120-150 ilio 150-180 Source
Figure 60
After Gardner and Reproduced in : Atlas Bureau of Agricultural
Ross. Weather Bureau, U.S. D A of American Agriculture, ed. by 0 E.Baker, Economics, Washington, 1936.
2. T h e Agricultural G e o g r a p h y o f N o r t h A m e r i c a
235
more than 240 days on the Gulf Coast and in the states bordering Mexico to 90 to 120 days in the Great Lakes area along the Canadian border. Because the gradation patterns of precipitation and growing season meet at about right angles to each other, individual agricultural areas in the U.S. are endowed with highly varying combinations of moisture, heat, and light. Almost all kinds of transitions are found among such widely contrasting conditions as the moist and cool environment of the extreme Northeast, which recalls the Algäu; moist and hot subtropical Florida; the dry Northern Plains states with their hot summers and cold winters, a climate similar to that of the Ukraine; the desert climate and meager plant cover of Arizona; and the dry-summer Mediterranean climate of California. A soils map of the U.S. completes our physicospatial picture (see Fig. 61). As in Europe, topographic and pedologie differences in the U.S. give rise to frequent changes in farming systems even over extremely small distances. But on a macrospatial scale, the influence of climate on farming types appears more marked. In fact, we find that the climatic
Distribution
of the Principal Soil in the United States
Types
/ / / Podzol soils INCSI Cray-brown podzolic soils t888%i Red and yellow soils Ι·.·Χ·| t=| ÉS2) EZ3
Prairie s o i l s Chernozem soils Brown steppe soils Desert soils Other s o i l s
Figure 6 1
After: In:
Mar
Atlas
Washington,
but, of
C. Γ,
American 1936.
USD.
A Agriculture
236
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
differences, as shown by the maps, have given areas of agricultural production a well-defined orientation. The following map (Fig. 62), which presents the agricultural zones of the U.S., is in large part a mirror of the
(N 2 3. E
2. The Agricultural Geography of North America
237
individual climatic areas. Even a cursory glance at this map is enough to inform one that specialization in specific land use enterprises is greater in the various agricultural areas of the U.S. than it is in European areas. This is because all U.S. agricultural areas, with their widely varying physical natures, are united in one large economic structure, one that is not fragmented by tariff barriers and other obstacles to free trade. This has allowed stronger interregional competition between production orientations, with the result that every product is produced where production and marketing costs are the lowest. This tendency has also been strengthened by the fact that all energy sources in the U.S. have, at least until recently, been relatively cheap, with low freight rates making it possible to exchange goods over great distances. In Europe, barriers to this trade are still much more formidable because of higher freight charges, and even more, international customs barriers. Further, there are the efforts at autarky by the European states, which have lead to the production in the majority of countries of products that are little justified environmentally and could be produced more cheaply in other countries. The economic integration of the Western European states is reducing these disadvantages. Whether the currently-increasing costs of oil will eventually be enough to seriously affect the course of economic integration in large areas such as Western Europe and North America remains to be seen.
b) The Dairy Zone In the cool and moist Northeast, a large area of permanent pastures and cultivated crops stretches from the New England coast, through the Great Lakes area, and beyond the northern Mississippi. This is the dairy zone, or "Dairy Belt" as it is usually labeled in America. It correlates almost exactly with the continental cool-summer climatic zone, and hence also extends up into southeastern Canada where this climate prevails. Thus Ottawa and Winnipeg are still in the middle of this dairy region. The most important grain in the U.S., corn, generally cannot ripen in this zone because its minimum growth period can barely be attained. Almost all of it is raised for silage. Fodder cropping, on both a permanent and rotation basis, comes to the fore, since it is favored on the production side by the cold, humid climate and the partly poorer soils, as well as by the hilly areas which discourage mechanization. On the market side, a heavy production of milk, butter, and cheese is stimulated by proximity to the industrial and urban agglomerations of the extreme Northeast and smaller urban concentrations elsewhere such as in southeastern Wisconsin-northeastern Illinois and Michigan (See Overview 19).
238
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
Overview 19: Crop Rotations in the New England States Valley Locations « I II
III
• Highest V
IV
Locations
1.-3. Clover- 1.-5. Clover- 1.-8.-10. Clover-grass 1.-2. Alfalfa1.-3. Alfalfagrass ley grass ley ley grass ley grass ley 4. Corn 6. Corn 11. Green oats 4. Grain corn 3.-4. Grain corn silage silage 7. Oats 5. Oats 5. Vegetables 5. Corn silage 6. Oats, 6. Oats w. Wheat 7. W. Wheat Decline of vegetable and wheat cropping
—:—>•
Decrease in cropping of grain corn, later also of corn silage
>•
Changing from alfalfa-grass ley to clover-grass ley Increasing economic life of leys
>
Conentrates sold —>· Produced only for own needs —»· All concentrates purchased 0—60%
% of sales proceeds from dairying Increasing specialization
100%
>•
c) The Corn Zone The middle and western parts of the dairy region are bordered on the south by the heart of American agriculture, the grain corn zone, the famed Corn Belt. It is roughly bounded on the south by the great curves of the Ohio River and the middle and lower Missouri. The center of grain corn cultivation lies in the continental warm-summer climatic zone. The farming systems of the Corn Belt are not as standardized as those of the Dairy Belt. To be sure, grain corn cultivation stands supreme in the land use scheme, seldom taking less than a third of the cultivable land, usually a half, and occasionally even 100%; but the way it is used varies according to the soil, terrain, and distance to market. Corn can be sold directly, fed to dairy cows, used to fatten ("finish") hogs and cattle, or used simply to raise them. Fig. 63 offers a schematic sketch to illustrate this. The major marketing center of the Corn Belt is Chicago, the third largest city on the North American continent. From here, agricultural products fan out in all directions, but particularly to the industrial centers of the Northeast. With increasing distance from Chicago in a southerly, westerly, and easterly direction, not only does distance from the market increase, but soil quality diminishes and terrain becomes more rolling. Since all three of these elements influence farm organization in the same direction, there has developed, when viewed schematically, a combina-
2. The Agricultural Geography of North America
239
Diagram
The Thünen Spatial Pattern in Chicago's Hinterland
a
"cf cc ttle fatten'm9
Figure 63
tion ring-sector arrangement of agricultural production zones south of the city, which brings to mind the Thiinian spatial picture. On the outskirts of Chicago and farther south into central Illinois, where the plains are fertile and ideal for machinery, and grassland is minor, an economy without livestock has formed. Corn, soybeans, and oats are sold directly to the market close at hand. Next, and farther south, comes a ring-like zone in which corn is ultimately coverted into manufacturing milk or pork. In the next and very broad ring, hog and cattle fattening dominate. The area in permanent grassland has naturally increased, and since the hilly surfaces also increase the threat of erosion, it becomes necessary to insert grass-clover leys into the rotation, perhaps even for several years duration. Livestock must then be kept to use the fodder growth. They are then brought up, through intensive feeding of corn, to prime slaughter weight. Finally, in a fourth zone, the proportion of FL in plowed land declines still further. Increasing dryness toward the west causes corn yields to fall faster than fodder crop yields, just as increasing precipitation to-
240
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
Overview 20:
Crop Rotations in the Corn Belt
I
II
III
IV
1. Corn
1. Soybeans 2.-4. Corn 5. Oats
1. Soybeans 2.-3. Corn 4. Oats
1. Clover- 1. Clovergrass ley grass ley 2.-3. Corn 2. Corn 4. Oats 3. Oats
2. Corn 3. Corn
100
in % of ;ultivable land 50 Corn 50 25 Soybeans 25 Oats 25 Clover-grass ley 25
60 20 20
Monocultura! farms
·
Mixed farms
ward the east does. Also, the greater mechanization difficulties encountered farther south and east have so restricted corn cropping relative to fodder cropping that the operator can no longer support intensive feeding of the now quite large cattle herds with only his own production. Consequently farmers have adjusted to a system stressing the raising of hogs and cattle for the adjacent fattening zone. Overview 20 shows some typical crop rotations of this agricultural region that come under the banner of grain corn cropping.
d) Agricultural Regions with Mixed (General) Farming Adjacent to the Corn Belt on the south is an area that is already subtropical in its warm summer, a zone of mixed, or general farming. Here it is already too warm for optimal corn production, while for optimal cotton production it is still not warm enough. Moreover, since a large part of this zone is extensively traversed by the broad masses of the Appalachian Highlands, growing conditions vary on even a microspatial scale. Thus the range of crops is broad and includes corn, winter wheat, oats, clover-grass ley, soybeans, fruit, and vegetables. Most farms also raise livestock since large areas of permanent grassland and the threat of erosion call for clover-grass ley farming and the age and poverty of the soils make a manuring economy advisable. A special feature of this zone is the cultivation of tobacco, which concentrates especially in Virginia, North Carolina, and central Kentucky. Although it holds a central position in the overall farm operation, its high labor peaks and great capacity for using barn manure create strong pressures for mixed farming. Diversified production is the distinguishing characteristic of this zone. Farming is more diversified here than in any other large agricultural region of the United States. The integration of several enterprises on the same farm has clearly left its stamp on farm management.
2. The Agricultural Geography of North America
241
e) The Cotton Zone The zone bordering the mixed farming strip on the south, the Cotton Belt, can only be described with qualifications. Its subtropical warmsummer climate still helps to make this area the third largest cotton region in the world, but the crop has been increasingly retreating to just a few specially suited sections, particularly the lower Mississippi Valley. The distribution is somewhat more belt-like if only farm income or sales source is considered, though even this pattern is no longer quite so extensive as indicated on Fig. 62. With these spatial contractions, the traditional monoculture has largely disappeared. Still typical, though, and particularly among many of the smaller farms, is a specialized operation that avoids livestock and makes cotton the principal money crop, accompanied by only one to three companion crops such as corn, peanuts, soybeans, sweet potatoes, or sorghum. Livestock raising in the South has notably expanded since the last world war, but it is still insufficiently developed relative to regional potentials. The best croplands are still reserved almost exclusively for cash crops, and here cotton raising produces no feed byproduct other than cottonseed. Also, few pure feed crops have a place in the more intensive cropping systems. Even where livestock farming has made important advances, and lands have been sown to grass and heavily fertilized, there have been limits. The required large initial investments and the high incidence of risk have restricted the greatest benefits of the highly profitable beef cattle raising to areas with the largest farms. The minor scale of grain cropping in the South, and made even more so by the recent decline of corn in favor of soybeans, is also posing a barrier to continued livestock expansion. Finally, the lesser availability of grain for feed combines with the opportunity for year-around grazing to make manuring uneconomic. In the last two decades, cotton production in the U.S. has been rapidly shifting from the Southeastern to the dry Southwestern states. The costs of the irrigation that is necessary there are easily compensated by the more mechanized large scale operations and the dependability of the dry harvest weather. With that, we have described in coarse outline the most important agricultural regions east of the 100th meridian, which corresponds roughly to the 500 mm-precipitation line. However, at least three more agricultural regions may be mentioned. Two encompass the dry and much less productive western half of the United States, excluding the widely dispersed but highly intensive irrigated oases, as well as the irrigated cotton areas already noted. The third region is actually a collection of widely scattered coastal areas, all of which share a reputation for highly intensive fruit and vegetable farming, and in some cases livestock farming that suggests factory operations.
242
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
f) The Wheat Regions The zone of wheat cultivation forms the transition to the semiarid western areas. It extends from northern Texas, through the states of Kansas, Nebraska, North and South Dakota, and far up into Canada. It also has an exclave in the Columbia Basin, which takes in parts of the states of Washington, Oregon, and Idaho. Fertile grassland soils and gentle terrain combine with dryness to make dry farming indispensable to this area, but particularly to the western part of the zone. Here the fully mechanized grain farm is at home, a unit on which is still frequently practiced the purest form of monoculture simply because there is no cultivated plant other than wheat that has sufficient drought resistance, though sorghum has now often become a major companion in certain warmer parts of the zone. This heavy emphasis on wheat has given rise to the well-known suitcase farmer. The southern winter wheat zone (Winter Wheat Belt), with its core in Kansas and its up to 200 growing days, is to be differentiated from the northern spring wheat zone (Spring Wheat Belt), which in part has only 100 growth days. To the west, precipitation falls from 750 to less than 400 mm. The lower precipitation limit for dry farming of wheat (taking into account evaporation, solar radiation, and precipitation regime) is 375 mm in Texas, 300 mm in South Dakota, and only 230 mm in the Canadian province of Saskatchewan. The more recent extensive cultivation gains made with large machine aggregates have strongly reduced production costs of wheat and have made it more competitive with extensive grassland farming. Farm data and types of crop rotations for a variety of locations in the wheat region can be found in Table 12 and Overview 14 of Chapter VII-2-a, pp. 179 f. Unfortunately, the coincidence of high wheat prices with relatively high precipitation during and after both world wars encouraged the expansion of wheat farming too far into the drier grasslands, which become ever more so toward the west. Here the frequent drought years pose great risk and also threaten farms with erosion. The mistake, to be sure, has been recognized, but the process of returning the critical areas to grazing is not only technically difficult, because of the difficulty of reestablishing a grass cover in semiarid areas, but also economically problematical, since the now denser settlement would require considerable thinning. The minimum support for a farm family that shifts from wheat farming to extensive grassland farming must increase from 4 0 0 - 7 0 0 ha up to 1,800-2,200 ha, this within a span of 250 to 520 mm/year. Thus the capacity of a specific region for wheat farms is about four times as high as that for ranches.
243
2. The Agricultural Geography of North America
g) Regions of Extensive Grassland Farming (Ranching) The last large agricultural region of the United States to be named is that of extensive grassland farming, or ranching. It embraces almost all of the Intermountain states and includes extensive highland areas that lie between the Rocky Mountains and the Sierra Nevada, dry steppes, semideserts, and mountains. Minimal rainfall or rugged terrain, or more rarely, great remoteness from transportation, even excludes the dry farming system, or grain-fallow economy, and generally permits only the most extensive form of agricultural land use, the grazing of large areas of sparse natural vegetation by feeder stock. In the hot-summer state of Arizona, in extreme southwestern U.S., livestock raising like this can be carried on with as little as 250 mm of annual precipitation, and extensive sheep raising can be practiced with as little as 150 mm. Naturally, then, quite extensive pasture areas per animal are needed (see Fig. 64 and Fig. 42, p. 168). Subzones must also be distinguished within the grassland farming region. A southern area, with year-around grazing and only occasional emergency feeding in drought periods, is joined on the north by a zone in which regular winter feeding is mandatory. In the vicinity of the high mountain Pastureland per Cattle Unit in the Western States of the U.S.
Y//Á
2 0
"
30
¡•>X;[ > 30
Black, Wilcox. New
Figure 64
Clawson, Farm York,
Sayre,
and
Management,
1947. p.
SS2.
244
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
chains, herds are driven, as in the high Alps, in long seasonal migrations Cattle cover up to 80 to 110 km in their trek from the valley ranch, where winter grazing goes on in the open, to the foothill pastures and eventually the summer pastures in the mountains. Sheep travel even as much as 160 to 200 km.
h) Coastal Regions with Fruit and Vegetable Growing Dominant Most fruits and vegetables are distinguished by high hectare yields, low value per unit weight, and high perishability. Thus they are sensitive to transport and are located as close as possible to markets. But since major population centers have risen as transport nodes in certain coastal areas, the largest and most important fruit and vegetable regions are also to be found in those very same coastal strips, especially since they are favored climatically. They include the lower Great Lakes littorals; the Boston, New York, Philadelphia, and Washington areas; large sections of Florida; the Gulf Coast in the vicinity of Mobile, New Orleans, and Baton Rouge; the area at the mouth of the Rio Grande; and the longitudinal valleys of California. The following comments will be restricted to the irrigated valleys in California with their Mediterranean climate, and will concentrate on the specialized production programs of individual farms and regions. In the last three decades, California has experienced an unexpected economic upswing and registered huge population growth rates. This especially applies to the Los Angeles, San Bernardino, and San Diego areas. The result has been rapidly rising wage and income demands, relatively favorable prices for capital, and increasing cost of land. The altered relations between factor costs have thus forced a recombination of the production factors. Much greater emphasis has been put on capital investment, labor inputs have been sharply curbed, and farming has been intensified. In return, extremely high capital investment has brought with it highly advanced stages of specialization that conflict with the basic principles of mixed farming, especially as concerns the need for spacing work, rotating crops, and spreading risk (see Ch. IV-1). Briefly described below, and without any claims for completeness, are a few interesting examples of farm management types that have resulted from this opposition of economic forces: aa)
Specialization has been especially successful with bush and tree crops. Three-, two-, and even one-crop farms are common. There are farms whose only support is a crop such as grapes, citrus fruit, dates, walnuts, or apples. Harvests, then, bring substantial labor peaks, which cannot be controlled through internal economies.
2. The Agricultural Geography of North America
245
Monoculture of this kind is possible only because Filipino or Mexican migrant labor crews stand on call, for they seek to space their own work by migrating so as to utilize the ecological distinctiveness of the California area. Indeed, the same fruit types ripen not only in different locations, but at different times, and here not only according to latitude, but to altitude and distance from the ocean as well. A corollary of this flexibility is that California accomodates almost all fruits of the mid-latitude and subtropical climatic zones with the most varied seasonal labor demands. Requirements associated with crop rotation do not need to be observed with the perennial crops, and with irrigation the production risks are also smaller, so that monoculture under these conditions is relatively easy. bb) Production risks are even smaller with greenhouse crops, the production factors of which — moisture, heat, air, nutrients — can be regulated by the farmer. A horticultural farm in the vicinity of San Francisco grows nothing but chrysanthemums on 1.4 ha under glass, and on a continuing basis. Flowers are cut every two weeks, and 24 hours later are standing in the vases of customers in Chicago or New York (aerial transport). Market risks are reduced by the grower taking advantage of the laws of photoperiodism. The chrysanthemum, as a short-day plant, needs a shorter period of daylight to produce blooms. Depending on the market situation, the farmer will either slow bloom formation with nocturnal lighting during the vegetative phase or accelerate it by darkening the greenhouse for a few hours in the morning and evening. Thus in addition to the production factors mentioned above, the farmer has the period of light under his control. cc)
Vegetable growing, with its high degree of specialization, encounters substantial difficulties. Almost all vegetables can be raised in a short growing season, so that in California often three different types can follow one another in the same year. The next year other types should be grown for reasons of plant hygiene. Rotations thus bring advantages, but they also require diversified production. Specialization in vegetable growing is also hindered not just by high market risks, but by the annual labor program. Specialization can nevertheless be occasionally successful, as shown by a farm operator who has 40 ha FL in irrigation, employs six tractors, purchases considerable manure, and draws 70% of his sales revenues from celery. Two years of celery are followed by only one year of lettuce, spinach, and dry beans, this to obtain such crop rotation benefits as loosening of the soil and addition of humus. This threeyear quasi-rotation, on a farm geared for maximum production, is then repeated.
246
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
dd) In the Salinas Valley and other places, complete vegetable rotations are made compatible with a high degree of specialization through lease rotation. Since many farmers wish to specialize in one or two vegetables, but cannot do so because of the diseases, pests, and weeds associated with such continuous cropping, they rotate leases so that they can continue to grow the same vegetables for short periods on diverse soils. Thus in place of the alternation of crops on the same land (crop rotation), we have the alternation of land with the same crops (lease rotation). The canneries are anxious for supplies and therefore offer inviting prices to the growers so that they can put up with the inconveniently short leases and the annually fluctuating distances to the fields.
i) Industrialized Animal Production on Specialized Farms Strong specialization tendencies also make themselves felt in animal production, where the pressures for drastic labor economies call for uniformly extensive capital investments. Cost-effectiveness requires that these investments be exploited to the maximum, which can only be done through specialization. Thus the same locational forces that have stimulated California fruit and vegetable growing also have lead to an extensive industrialization of production in livestock raising, aa) Included here is the fattening ("finishing" in the parlance of American stockmen) in feedlots of cattle raised on the range. One feedlot I visited in the Sacramento Valley holds 3,000 two- to three-year old animals in its corrals. A feeding period of three months permits four turnovers of stock annually, so that this operation sends 12,000 slaughter cattle to market every year. Another feedlot even supplies the market with 40,000 feeders annually. No feeds of any kind are produced; everything is purchased. Feeds include alfalfa green meal, barley, dried molasses, and cottonseed cake. They are prepared in large mixing machines and transported to the feeding troughs by trucks equipped with mechanical unloaders that operate laterally. An overseer on horseback completes this picture of large scale feeding operations, bb) Operators of dry lot dairy farms in the Riverside-San Bernardino area will, in extreme cases, buy alfalfa hay from the El Centro area, over 230 km away, and deliver the milk over the same 230 km back to El Centro. Milk cannot be economically produced around El Centro because of the hot desert climate, and alfalfa cannot be profitably raised around Riverside because of the high cost of land. The herds of milking cows average 200 to 500 head. Milking goes on 20 hours a day.
2. The Agricultural Geography of North America
247
cc)
Most advanced of all is the specialization in poultry raising. In Germany, a pure poultry farm is already designated as highly specialized if operations are organized into the following divisions: 1. breeding for hatching eggs; 2. incubation; 3. brooding; 4. raising layers; 5. fattening fryers; 6. processing market eggs; and 7. processing manure. In California, however, specialization is often even much more advanced in the way many operators participate in the production process, each taking care of only one of the above functions. Industrialized livestock and poultry farms obey the same laws that industries observe in their locational orientation. Based on the character of the particular animal production, they are — either supply-oriented: near feed suppliers (sugar refineries, breweries, wineries, orange juice plants, oil mills, etc.) — or market-oriented: near population agglomerations, packing plants, dairies, egg-processing plants, etc.
j) Regional Differences in the Factor Combination Just as production orientations sharply vary from place to place in the U.S., so also are the comparative availabilities and consequently the princes of the production factors quite variable. Thus the optimal productive combination for individual areas must also be a variable one. Of labor may be considered typical of all the U.S. For the individual agricultural areas, though, this is not always true, or if so, only with marked cultural areas, though, this is not always true, or if so, only with marked gradations. This can be understood more clearly if we divide the U.S. into three parts, first by drawing a north-south line that follows the western boundaries of the states of North and South Dakota, Nebraska, Kansas, Oklahoma, and Texas, and then by drawing an east-west line that corresponds with the northern boundaries of the states of Delaware, Maryland, West Virginia, Kentucky, Arkansas, and Oklahoma. We thus arrive at three broad regional complexes that the Bureau of the Census has used for statistical purposes: North, South, and West (see Fig. 65, p. 248). Land in the sparsely settled, isolated, and little-developed West is in surplus almost everywhere and therefore is cheap, especially since the climate bestows upon it only minor natural productivity. On the other
248
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
Figure 65
hand, labor is extremely scarce and expensive, since life on the isolated farms offers little attraction for the wage laborer. It is therefore advisable to farm as large an area as possible with the fewest possible workers. This goal comes ever closer to realization the more the radius of human action is expanded by large scale use of livestock or machinery. Thus large inventories are accumulated per worker. In relation to the area farmed, however, inventories remain as small as labor investments, so that one must speak of extremely extensive economic practices. The situation is completely different in the South. It still has a relatively high rural population density and is the least industrially developed of the three regions relative to population. The lesser competition of industry for labor and the system of tenancy ensure that labor in the Southern states is still available to agriculture relatively cheaply, and thus its application need not be as frugal as in the West. Land prices, though, are much higher than in the West, not only because of the high value of output, but because of the brisk demand for cropland. The fullest possible utilization of the productive reserves of the soil must therefore be the first economic objective. Since livestock raising is still
249
2. The Agricultural Geography of North America
encountering obstacles and mechanization is hampered by many small farms, while labor is still relatively cheap, operators economize on inventories and greatly increase labor expenditures per areal unit, and thus are labor-intensive in their practices. Finally, in the industrial North, land prices are still higher than in the South and wages and income demands of the farmer are about as high as in the West. Here neither land nor labor can be invested in rich amounts, but instead the highest possible use must be made of them with the most economical application. This can only be done by applying large inventories of every kind (livestock, machinery, fertilizers, feeds) on both a per-hectare and per-worker basis. These measures are facilitated by the relatively low costs of industrially-produced farm inputs at the farm gate, due to their nearness to the production centers. Operations in the North are therefore markedly capital-intensive and overall even more intensive than in the South. Land prices increase from West to South to North, wages increase from South to North to West, and prices of capital goods increase from West to North to South. The proportions of the investment in the production factors vary inversely with their prices to a degree hardly attained in any other country, largely because hardly anywhere else is agriculture organized so much on the profit principle as it is in the United States. The combination of these patterns in the three agricultural areas are schematized in Overview 21. Overview 21: Proportional Investment of Production Factors in Maximizing Income in U.S. Agriculture
Land Labor Working Capital Consumptive Capital Management
West
South
South
much little much little moderate
little much little moderate little
little little much much much
Indicative of the contrasting combinations of production factors in these three large regions is that more than half of the land in the U.S. is in the West, more than half of the employed are in the South, and more than half of the value of agricultural production is in the North.
250
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
3. The Agricultural Geography of the East Bloc Countries a) Place-Specific Characteristics Because of the major influence of socialization policies, the extensive territory of the East Bloc can be considered as essentially one agricultural area. It extends from the eastern Harz and the Bohemian Forest to the Okhotsk and China seas, and from the Arctic Ocean to the Himalayas. This land mass is broadly divided into the following climatic zones (see also Ch. II): 1. The Arctic climate belt begins somewhat north of Archangel, runs up to the mouth of the Ob near the Arctic Circle, and then extends, in varying width, to the Bering Straits. The tundra vegetation generally permits only seasonal grazing by the reindeer of seminomads, such as the Turkish Yakuts. 2. Next comes the widely distributed Subarctic climate belt, stretching from the White Sea to Kamchatka. Its southern boundary runs approximately from Karelia, through Sverdlovsk and Ulan Bator, to Khabarovsk. 3. Then follows, still farther south, a continental cool-summer climate bloc, which differs from the Subarctic climate belt in areal trend by starting out with a wide western part and gradually narrowing to the east, finally disappearing completely in Mongolia. The delimitation of this climatic wedge is given approximately by the three points of Leningrad, Bucharest, and Novosibirsk. An exclave is found north of the Sea of Japan. 4. There is a continental warm-summer climate, thus a pronounced graincorn climate, in the East Bloc in two relatively small regions. One prevails in northeastern China, on the southern edge of the exclave just mentioned. Peking and Seoul are located in this area. The second area of this climatic type is the largest part of the Balkan Peninsula, i.e. the Danube Basin south of Budapest and the bordering mountain regions. 5. Still farther south are the bordering zones with a subtropical warmsummer climate. They include the area on the Adriatic as well as parts of the Black Sea coast. Above all, however, a major part of the People's Republic of China, the entire southeast, lies in this climatic zone. 6. Finally there are still other climatic types in the East Bloc, but their agricultural influence will not be considered here because they are not to be classed as middle latitude types. In mind here are, on the one hand, the enormous inner-Asian areas with dry climates (arid and
3. The Agricultural Geography of the East Bloc Countries
251
semiarid), and on the other, the Indochinese areas with tropical rainy climates (wet, wet-and-dry). The extreme importance of the climatic factor of precipitation amount for agriculture in the East Bloc can also be seen in Fig. 5, p. 35. The soil conditions that help to make for agricultural differentiations on a microspatial scale are of only minor significance in the macrospatial view of agricultural zones as used here. Still the following can be said (Krische 1933, p. 22, citing Glinka 1927): — By far the largest parts of Poland and the USSR consist of podzolized (leached) soils, which prevail in both Subarctic and continental coolsummer climatic zones. Although easily worked, they are also poor in nutrients. They are farmed especially for potatoes, rye, and leys. — Adjacent to this podzolized area on the south is an extremely wide and fertile belt of Chernozem (blackerths) and Chernozemic soils that are superbly qualified for the cultivation of sugar beets and wheat. This band surrounds the Black Sea to the north and runs in an eastnortheast direction to China. — Adjoining this fertile area on the south are the chestnut-brown, brown, and gray soils, which are distributed in the Danube area. — Brown-and-yellow soils dominate in central Germany, Jugoslavia, and eastern China. Their often considerable resistance to cultivation is becoming even more disadvantageous with mechanization, while the advantage of a naturally rich supply of nutrients is being increasingly lost as chemical fertilizers become cheaper. — Still farther south on the southeast coast of China, starting from about Shanghai, and in the southern half of Albania, we are already encountering the red soils of the subtropical climate. Another important place-specific factor for the agriculture of the East Bloc is the density of the transport net. In 1960, the railroad density in central Silesia amounted to over 200 km of lines per 1,000 km 2 ; in the Leningrad and Moscow areas, 50 to 100 km; in the greatest part of the Ukraine, only 5 to 20 km; and in Uzbekistan, as little as 0 to 5 km of lines. Enormous Siberia has only one commercially significant east-west rail line, a situation made even more serious by the fact that most of the navigable rivers flow from south to north, thus perpendicular to the rail route. Moreover, they are handicapped by ice for much of the year. The variations in the density of the transport net are further exaggerated by the increasing sparsity of roads in Russia in both a northerly and easterly direction. Road construction in the northern part of the country is expensive, since forests must be cleared and hard winter freezing requires large amounts of gravel fill. When this problem is combined with the decreasing population density to the north and east, one can
252
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
easily see why transport construction costs per inhabitant progressively increase, and why even wealthy countries with the same conditions must be content with only a loose transport network (cf. northern Sweden). The effects of conditions like these on the character of agricultural regions is by no means unimportant.
b) Large Socialist Farms as a Regionalizing Feature The extensive physicogeographic differences in the East Bloc are not reflected in the farming types, agricultural regions, agricultural areas, and agricultural zones as strongly as one might assume. The reason for this is that the socialization of agriculture has led to a definite leveling of the farm size structure, so that farm size is not capable of exerting the decisive influence on agricultural differentiation that it does in large parts of the Western world. The large socialist farms (APC or Kolkhoz and PE or Sovkhoz) are widely established in the agriculture of the East Bloc, and thus their influence on the agricultural region is clearly visible in the macrospatial aspects of the economy.
c) Problems of an Areally-Suitable Agricultural Production The physical agents in agriculture, such as climate, soil, and relief, do not always make their full weight felt in the centrally-planned economies of the socialist countries. In the Western free market economy, production is largely controlled by the market and after harvest takes place. In contrast, production in the Eastern centrally-planned economy is mainly controlled by the Plan, which is drawn up well before the growing season. Macrospatial production plans, however, can only cope to a certain extent with highly-varying local conditions compared with the effectiveness of the production decisions of independent peasants, farmers, ranchers, or planters, who are directly involved in the operations and are motivated by material rewards. If allowance is made for this involuntary weakness in adaption in socialist agriculture, then there is still to be considered what in certain cases is a deliberate arbitrariness in locating agricultural production. Since prices must not be fixed by the market, a specific type of production also need not be completely areally suitable, but can be forced into less favorable locations by the priorities of politics. The hopyards along the autobahn between Helmstedt and the Elbe are certainly not locationally justified, and a large part of Krushchev's land cultivation program in Kazakstan was no less unqualified. The first situation of course represents an effort to save currency, while the latter was an action designed to reduce the grain deficit in Russia. Thus what would be absurd in the private economy may be economically sensible from the viewpoint of the national economy.
3. The Agricultural Geography of the East Bloc Countries
253
d) Stages of Socialization Because socialism bears so heavily on the absolute and relative effectiveness of the many formative agents in agriculture, it is necessary to consider briefly collectivization itself. Table 15 shows, according to the latest census reports at this writing, that for all the countries listed, except Poland and Jugoslavia, less than 10% AL was in the private sector and for many countries the figure approached the zero mark. This land was split up among the hectarages of the independent peasant farms and the private parcels of collective farmers and state employees. Also to be noted in Table 15 is that 1. socialization in all countries is clearly increasing with time; 2. within the socialist sector the collective farms generally dominate by far, while the state farms are retreating (exceptions: Cuba, USSR, Jugoslavia, Romania); 3. in the Soviet Union a clear shift of emphasis in favor of the Sovkhoz has taken place; and 4. Polish agriculture has maintained, with 84.3% AL, by far the largest areal share in the private sector. Table 15:
Areal Share of the Socialist Sector in the Agriculture of the East Bloc
State
Albania Bulgaria China (PR) Czechoslovakia GDR
Jugoslavia Cuba North Korea Poland Romania USSR
Hungary 1
Year
1959 1972 1956 1972 1960 1968 1972 1971 1963 1957 1969 1959 1972 1928 1940 1962 1960 1972
Socialist· Sector, % AL
Private Sector, % AL
Collective Farms
State Farms
Total
73.5
21.6
96.0
4.0
95.1 99.7 100.0 91.6 92.5 92.0 94.4 15.0 1
8.4 7.5 8.0 5.6 85.0
15.7 72.7 90.7 2.4 87.5 96.9 77.8 97.2
84.3 27.3 9.3 97.6 12.5 3.1 22.2 2.8
85.0
7.0
4.9 0.3
1
65.0 93.7 1.2 44.1
14.5 28.6
1.2 78.6 53.0
1.2 8.9 43.9
% of cultivated land. Source: Beyme, K. von: Ökonomie und Politik im Sozialismus. Munich, Zurich 1975, pp. 55 f.
254
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
In general, the reapportionment of property and land use rights among the agricultural production factors is accomplished in the following four phases of collectivization (Beyme 1975, p. 56): Phase 1: expropriation of the lands of the large landowner; Phase 2: beginning of actual collectivization; Phase 3: transition to more socialized forms of collective farming: Phase 4: elimination of the coexistence of collective farms and state farms (future plans). In the Soviet Union, the first phase took place in the time from 1917 to 1921, the second phase occurred between 1929 and 1933, and the third phase began in 1952. In the German Democratic Republic, land reform was initiated in 1945 and the first APC was established in 1952. By 1960, about two-thirds of the APCs had been converted to Type II status. In the People's Republic of China, the first three phases were initiated in the years 1950, 1953, and 1958 (Beyme 1975, p. 57). Only by recognizing the primacy of politics over economy can one understand why the large socialist farm has been exalted as the prototype for the agriculture of all East Bloc countries (except Poland) regardless of such things as the stage of national economic development, the educational level of the population, and the ecological realities. In the preceding chapters of this book, attention has been repeatedly directed to the fact that under various ecological conditions there are also various farm sizes that can be regarded as optimal. In Chapter IX-2 it will be shown that during the course of national economic development the farm size structure in agriculture must change. All the countries for whom an agricultural census has been available for many decades substantiate this. All the more astonishing then, is that in the East Bloc, under the most varied conditions, the same concept is extolled: the superiority of the large socialist farm. If it is imperative for national economic interests that an agriculture involving millions of illiterate small farmers be raised to a much higher level in a short time, then the large socialist farm may have a place. It offers a much greater radius of action for a small elite of proficient, flexible, and progressive farm operators, and thus provides much greater efficiency. This need does not apply to highly developed industrial states, though, since almost every farmer has enough of the entrepreneurial qualities whose application is to the national interest. Capitalism motivates the individual through material inducements, whereas socialism motivates him through social consciousness. In Central and Eastern Europe this has not worked out. Also, a detailed system of worker remuneration based on amount and quality of work (work units) on the large socialist farms has not been able to evoke the same will to work displayed by the independent West European farmers in exploiting their
255
3. The Agricultural Geography of the East Bloc Countries
opportunities and avoiding their risks. As a result, the large socialist farms, in spite of their good provisions for mechanization, are by our concepts oversupplied with labor. Table 16 provides some details on the Agricultural Producers' Cooperatives of the German Democratic Republic. The observable tendencies toward fewer and larger units and toward greater socialization of the production factors could be considered representative of the greatest part of the East Bloc. Table 16:
Agricultural Producers' Cooperatives in the GDR
Characteristic
Type I APC
Type II APC
Type III APC APC Total
For operations in common in the APC
only the cultivable land
field crops, grassland, perennial crops, draft animals, machinery
total farm unit
at least 40 to 60%
at least 30 to 70%
at least 20 to 80%
Computation of income by work units, by land share Shift in the number of APCs, by types 1960 1968 Number of APCs in 1968, by ha AL: up to 200 ha 500 to 1,000 ha 2,000 & more ha
12,976 1,185 (1973)
3,372 400
-
6,353 5,759
19,329 11,513
313 2,410 91
3,585 2,810 91
Source: Statistisches Jahrbuch der DDR 1963, p. 230; 1964, p. 246; 1966, p. 264; 1969, p. 184.
As to how much these political goals conflict with the increase that is needed in production is shown by Table 17, the data being extracted from the report presented by Gomulka at the Eighth Plenum of the Central Committee of the Plish United Workers' Party. Here it should be noted that Polish state farms stem almost entirely from former German estates, whose field patterns and buildings were taken over and whose place-specific advantages over farms in the Congress Poland area are often considerable. Also, even if one takes into account the difficulties associated with the initiation of collectivization in the middle 1950s, the deficiency in production remains, which may be an overall reflection of the weaknesses in areal adjustment and performance enthusiasm that have been mentioned earlier.
256
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
Table 17:
Effects of Socialization on the Agricultural Production of Poland
Characteristic
Unit
Private Farms
Collective Farms
State Farms
Share Share Gross Share
% % zloty/ha
78.7 83.9 621.1 100.0
8.6 7.7 517.3 83.3
12.6 8.4 393.7 62.8
of AL of agricultural production returns of gross returns
%
After Zotschew, T.: Die Entwicklungsprobleme der polnischen Wirtschaft. Kiel 1957, pp. 3f.
e) Agricultural Zones in the Baltic-Adriatic Area The area from the Baltic Sea to the Adriatic, as shown in Fig. 66, includes all the types of agricultural regions that are generally found in Eastern Europe. The agricultural regions on the map have been delimited on the basis of official statistics for primary administrative units, and are organized according to the five most important farm enterprises or farm enterprise groups: grain cropping, fodder cropping, hoe cropping, specialty crops (grapes, fruit, and other bush and tree crops), and dairying. The secondary enterprises were assigned to these main enterprises, so far as possible, according to the closeness of their farm enterprise relationship. The scale of the land use enterprises was expressed in % AL, and that of dairying in cows per 100 ha AL. Cropland values and herd densities were then weighted by their corresponding mean labor expenditures. This was accomplished for the land use enterprises by multiplying the cropland value in % AL by the weighted index, and for dairying by multiplying the herd density per 100 ha AL by the weighted index. The agricultural regions were then named after the three farm enterprises having the highest, second highest, and third highest weights. The area being discussed is composed of the following nine types of agricultural regions (see Fig. 66): 1. The hoe crops-dairying-grain region forms the largest unbroken block of territory. Eastern Mecklenburg, Brandenburg March, Pomerania, Silesia, and the largest part of Congress Poland belong to it. A warm summer with a July/August maximum, a sufficiently long fall, largely level terrain and light soils, as well as the dominance of small peasant farms in Poland, are all factors that have strongly favored hoe cropping and especially the cultivation of potatoes. Because potatoes can be used in various ways, their cultivation can be quite well adapted to the needs of different farm sizes and varying market distances. Labor expenditures per hectare climb in the sequence of industrial potatoes — table potatoes — seed potatoes — feed potatoes for fattening hogs. Transport costs per
257
3. The Agricultural Geography of the East Bloc Countries
Agricultural
Agricultural
Sea-Adriatic
Sea Area
Regions
! " ! ! > ! Grain-Special ^ ^
Zones in the Baltic
Crops-Dairying
Fodder Cropping - D a i r y i n g - S p e c i a l Crops
:. ; · . : O a i r y i n g - F o d d e r Cropping - S pecia 1 Crops ' . ' . ' ; Dairying-Hoe Crops-Fodder
Cropping
] Dairying -Hoe Crops - Grain >,\'
Hoe C r o p s - Dairying - Drain I Special Crops - Dairying-Fodder
N ^ s Ü Special
Cropping
Crops-Dairying-Grain
2 2 3 Special C r o p s - G r a i n - Hoe Crops
E x a m p l e D e l i m i t a t i o n of an A g r i c u l t u r a l Farm Enterprise
Region
Cropland Head per Multiplier · / . AL 1000 ha AL·
Farm Enterprise Weight
Fodder Cropping
24
—
1
Grain
50
—
1
50
25
—
5
125
1
—
20 3
90
Cropping
Hoe Cropping Special Crops Dairying ( c o w s )
—
30
24
20
The rank order of the (arm enterprise weights characterizes the area as a Hoe Crops - Dairying - Grain Region
Statistical censuses primary
bases: Official land and livestock counts, by administrative units (about
Figure 66
hectare fall in the sequence of seed potatoes — table potatoes — hog fattening — alcohol. Accordingly, operators — on large socialist farms in the vicinity of cities such as Szczecin (Stettin), Berlin, Poznan (Posen), and Warsaw will raise table potatoes. — on large socialist farms farther from markets will produce seed potatoes. — on large socialist farms at a very great distance from markets, e.g. in Farther Pomerania, will cultivate industrial potatoes and make use of a distillery or starch factory.
258
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
— on land-poor family farms in Congress Poland will combine the cultivation of feed potatoes and fattening of hogs so as to provide productive work and to save on transport costs. No more than second place can be given to dairying in the designation of the agricultural region, since in most cases only a little permanent grassland is available and the light soils are not adequate for clover. In addition, intercropping must be held within strict limits because of the dry climate and a growing season that is shorter than in West Germany. Only on the better soils where sugar beet cropping is favored over potatoes is the feed base for dairying broadened, with fresh beet leaf, beet leaf silage, and dry beet chips as the products. This is especially true of the Magdeburg Börde, the Ucker March, and the Wroclaw (Breslau) Platform. Crop rotations for this large area range — from the pure three-field economy, occurring in a broad belt from Poznan to the Russian border, — through many intermediate stages in the Oder-Vistula area, — to the pure crop rotation economy in the German Democratic Republic and Farther Pomerania. 2. The roles of the dominating farm enterprises are reversed in the dairying-hoe crops-grain regions. They are areas where heavy soils hinder hoe cropping and encourage fodder cropping, or where groundwater conditions make it necessary to leave a larger portion of the land in permanent grassland. Warmia (Ermland) and Masuria are as much examples of these conditions as are Galicia or the Bratislava Lowland. 3. A small modification is to be found in the dairying-hoe crops-fodder cropping regions that include western Mecklenburg and by far the largest part of Czechoslovakia. The prevailing cropping system in the CSSR is a clover-grass economy, with a two-year useful economic life for fodder cropping. In the surrounding Bohemian Mountains, a three-year period is also common. Fodder crops take up 20 to 40% CL (Andreae 1964, p. 80). 4. The agricultural regions of the continental steppe climate are of quite a different character. A large special crops-grain-hoe crops region stands out in Hungary because viticulture consumes the largest part of the farm labor potential, even though it also claims only a relatively small quota of the agricultural area. Since the locationally-favored viticulture competes with hoe cropping for manure and for labor in the fall, hoe cropping can only be given third place in farm enterprise weight. 5. Grain-special crops-dairying regions show up on the map only in the Vojvodina, in the Banat, and in eastern Slovenia. Here extremely large state farms reign, having taken over the traditionally heavy emphasis on grain cropping because of the compelling ecological conditions. Emphatic
3. The Agricultural Geography of the East Bloc Countries
259
grain landscapes like those here are no longer found anywhere else in Europe except in parts of the Ile-de-France. 6. South of this region, in Serbia, is a special crops-dairying-grain region. In hilly country, this enterprise combination is a good one for making the most of the varying place-specific conditions on the farm. Cool northern slopes and high plateaus can be allocated to grassland, southern slopes can be given over to viticulture, and valley bottoms can be used for large scale mechanized operations. Fodder cropping/dairying and viticulture are complementary in their labor and manuring needs. Crop farming is of service in great part because of the raising of grain corn, so typical of the Balkans and a critical source of not only food but supplementary feed. Thus crop rotations are governed by nurse crops from almost beginning to end, or in other words, the leafy crops take up more than half of the cultivated land. 7. Special crops-dairying-fodder cropping regions dominate Slovenia and Croatia. Thus they are similar to the agricultural region described in 6, except for the difference that fodder cropping now attains a greater farm management weight than that of grain cropping. 8. The agricultural regions of Herzegovina and Montenegro are again areas of stronger concentration on fodder cropping and dairying. A special characteristic of these areas is migratory grazing, without which the dairying-fodder cropping-hoe crops region and fodder cropping-dairyinghoe crops region would hardly have been able to develop and which, on their part, prescribe a rugged terrain. The Mediterranean climate is not conducive to dairying, first, because plant growth ceases in the summer, and second, because taurine cattle are less resistant to heat. On the other hand, well-defined grassland areas in the Dinaric and North Macedonian mountains would hardly be of use to farms because under difficult winter conditions, large amounts of winter feed would have to be procured. Migratory grazing now provides the feed balance. When, by the end of May, the pastures in the lowlands are exhausted and the hot season has set in, the migrations of the herds to the cool mountain pastures begin. In this way, from the beginning of June to the end of September, feed is obtained for the livestock. After that, the lowlands again provide feed sufficient to the next May. The individual migratory trails run to 45 to 85 km, so that the herds travel from 90 to 170 km per year (Beuermann 1967). The longer the migrations and the scantier the pasture, the more the sheep and the goat displace the cow. For this information we are indebted to A. Beuermann and his penetrating study of migratory grazing in Southeastern Europe.
260
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
f) Agricultural Zones of the Soviet Union Table 18 gives an overview of the development of Soviet agriculture as a whole from 1940 to 1967, and further reinforces what was said earlier about the general trend. Here, however, the spatial aspect is of greater interest. A large land block like the Soviet Union, with a significant north-south dimension, offers the opportunity of working out the relationships between the physical-geographic zones and agricultural zones. The situation is especially favorable because the great zonal structure in the western part of the country is hardly disturbed by mountains. From the Kola Peninsula to Tashkent, zones of tundra, coniferous forest, mixed forest, forest steppe, steppe, semidesert, and desert form a pattern of succession, the sequence finally terminating at the edge of the large mountainous area near Tashkent (Fig. 67, p. 263). The agricultural zones associated with these natural zones are characterized in Overview 22, p. 262, by some examples of crop rotations (Könnecke 1967, pp. 301 ff.). 1. The coniferous forest zone is not favorable for agricultural production. Podzol soils, precipitation that declines in an easterly direction from about 600 to 250 mm, severe winters, and above all, a short growing seaTable 18:
Number, Size, and Inventories of Large Socialist Farms in the Soviet Union, 1940 to 1967
Characteristic
Unit A.
Number of sovkhozes Size of sovkhozes Labor force Cattle Swine Tractors Combines
1950
1960
1967
235.5 1,429 614
121.4 3,061 1,221 212 224 98 3.9 1.4
44.0 6,446 2,962 395 807 609 14.3 6.1
36.2 6,000 3,000
7,375 26,200 745 1,957 1,715 54.6 27.9
12,783 22,800 617 2,017 916 54.8 20.7
Kolkhozes
Number of kolkhozes in 000s Size of kolkhozes ha AL Cultivable land per kolkhoz ha Labor force MY/kolkhoz Cattle head/kolkhoz Swine head/kolkhoz Tractors no./kolkhoz Combines no./kolkhoz B.
1940
85 35 1.8 0.6
1,092 599 23.6 7.0
Sovkhozes
in 000s ha AL MY/sovkhoz head/sovkhoz head/sovkhoz no./sovkhoz no./sovkhoz
4,159 4,988 12,200 12,900 334 330 592 562 459 500 17.7 14.8 6.4 6.6
Source: Leonóarevic, I.: Die landwirtschaftlichen Betriebsgrößen in der Sowjetunion in Statistik und Theorie. Wiesbaden 1969, pp. 21 and 26.
3. The Agricultural Geography of the East Bloc Countries
261
son, are little conducive to diversified and flexible land use. The northern boundary of the compact cultivated area runs approximately along the 60th parallel. In European Russia, potatoes, spring barley, vegetables, and fodder crops are cultivated up to the Arctic coast. Individual useful plants also penetrate the river valleys far to the north in Asiatic Russia. Crop rotations A to C evidence the short growing season in several ways: — first, in the perennial ley cropping, the only system capable of utilizing the growth period from the first day to the last since the soil must be worked in the spring and in the fall; — also, in the extremely minor role of winter grain cropping, which is possible only after full fallow or after a crop that permits bastard fallow (ley cropping); — further, in the frequent occurrence of full fallow, which ensures a thorough cultivation of the soil; and — finally, in the possibility of planting potatoes after potatoes since in this climate there is no need to be concerned about a nematode infestation. In the east Siberian coniferous forest zone, small cultivated areas are scattered over the extensive forest and grass areas in much the same way as in higher locations among the European sub-Alpine mountains. With a growing period of but 90 to 110 days and precipitation falling to as little as 220 mm, as in Yakutia, crop rotation C is quite understandable. Only the pressure of self-subsistence in these isolated areas can induce cropping under such difficult conditions. 2. The mixed forest zone can be viewed as being far more favorable agriculturally. Crop rotations show this clearly: a rich complex of crops, no more full fallow, hardly any perennial fodder cropping, and a larger share of winter grains. The opportunities for winter grain cropping are especially evident in the Byelorussian crop rotation F, in which winter rye can be planted right after the potato harvest. Annual precipitation lies in a range quite favorable for crop farming, 500 to 750 mm. Milk, potatoes, and pork are the main products, the result of relatively prolific forage growth in the wetter areas, an average of about 40% AL in permanent grassland, and a relatively dense and prosperous population in the Moscow-Kiev-Minsk-Leningrad area. Vegetables are also raised near the consuming centers, and sugar beets are increasingly cultivated to the south. The centrally-planned economy has produced a Thiinian spatial pattern in the near vicinity of Moscow. Highly specialized farming zones are found in concentric circles around the capital city, their ordering caused by diminishing transportability of the principal products in an outward direction. Thus fresh milk and vegetable production are found in the innermost ring. Farther from the market center is a ring with emphasis on potatoes, with up to 50% CL in the crop. Manufacturing milk belongs
262 Overview 22:
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes Crop Rotations in the Agricultural Zones of the Soviet Union (Könnecke 1967)
Coniferous Forest Zone A. Leningrad Oblast B. Yaroslavl Oblast 1.-2. Leys 3. Potatoes 4. Potatoes, root crops 5. Peas, oats
1.-2. Leys 3. Flax (for seed), s. wheat 4. Potatoes, legumes 5. Oats 6. Fallow 7. W. wheat, w. rye 8. Spring grains
D. Moscow Oblast
Mixed Forest Zone E. Grodno Oblast
1.-2. Leys 3. Flax (for seed) 4. Early potatoes 5. W. wheat 6. Potatoes 7. Oats
1. Field forage 2. Flax (for seed) 3. Potatoes 4. Feed corn 5. Field forage 6. Winter grains
G. Southern Forest Steppe 1.-3. Leys 4. Corn, w. grainsstubble seed 5. Vetch-oats
K. Kuban Area (irrigation) 1.-2. Field forage 3.-4. Rice 5. Vegetables, hoe crops 6.-7. Rice
Forest Steppe Zone H. Central Russia 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6.
Flax (for fiber) Sugar beets Flax (for fiber) Potatoes Flax (for fiber) Field beans
Steppe Zone L. Virgin Lands 1. Corn 2. Corn, carrots, s. beets 3. Green forage
C. Siberia 1. 2. 3. 4.
Full fallow Spring grains Spring grains Full fallow, hoe crops 5. Spring grains
F. Byelorussia 1. Potatoes 2. Winter rye-lupine stubble seed (on very thin soils)
J. Siberia 1. S. beets, potatoes, field beans 2. S. wheat 3. S. Wheat
M. Virgin Lands (irrigation) 1.-2. 3.-5. 6. 7.-10.
Alfalfa Cotton Legumes, corn Cotton
263
3. The Agricultural Geography of the East Bloc Countries
Regional
Zones in the Soviet
I H Tundra Zone
R>]Mixed Forest Zone
^^Steppe Zone
ÍS3 S e Ä n e
EE3 Forest Steppe Zone
^
Source
Κ ön η e eke,
G.:
Fruchlfolgen
Berlin,
Union
|
1 Desert Zone
Semi-Desert Zone [ΠΠΠ]Other Zones 1967,
p. 29 6
Figure 67
to one of the outermost rings, and is supported by annual fodder crops like feed corn and mixed legumes. Flax raised for flaxseed also earns a place in these crop rotations since it is fairly independent of market distance. 3. The extraordinarily agriculturally valuable forest steppe zone is a belt that extends for 4,500 km along the southern edge of the European mixed forest zone and the Siberian coniferous forest zone. A humid climate and thick, humus-rich black soils favor the cultivation of grains and sugar beets. Annual precipitation and growing season steadily diminish to the east, the latter from 220 days in the Ukraine to 160 days in western Siberia. This means a declining importance of winter wheat and an increasing significance of spring wheat. Situations are frequently encountered in the Ukraine where less than 10% AL is in permanent grassland, about 40% CL is in leafy crops (sugar beets, corn, sunflowers, legumes, and potatoes), and 60% CL is in grain. The diversity of cropping is not nearly so great on the other side of the Urals because of the severe winter temperatures and lack of snow and the unfavorable soil conditions.
264
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
4. South of the forest steppe zone is the steppe zone. Farmers here can rely on 500 mm annual precipitation, and in some places the figure is as low as 250 mm. The efficiency of these amounts for plant physiology is only minor because of the high rate of evaporation. Water and wind erosion are also problems. But the soils are naturally productive, so that their cultivation has become profitable with irrigation. The situation has become even more attractive when the climatic warmth can be used for crops that can thrive in only a few parts of the USSR: rice in the Kuban area or cotton. The potential for further irrigation lies in the lower courses of the great rivers of the Dnieper, Donets, Don, Volga, and Ural. 5. The agricultural handicaps of dryness, very high evaporation, saline soils, and wind erosion are intensified in the semidesert and desert zones. Here irrigation is the absolutely indispensable condition for cultivation, since natural rainfall is usually less than 200 mm. Alfalfa/cotton rotations, as well as sugar beets and grain corn, then match vegetables and tobacco in gaining the upper hand. Where irrigation cannot be practiced - and this is the case for by far the largest part of this region, extensive grazing dominates the landscape. In the last few decades, the Soviet Union has made great efforts to increase its agricultural production. Of the measures that have drastically changed certain agricultural regions, three above all should be named: 1. Expansion of irrigation systems: Primitive forms of irrigation were replaced by more effective types and additional irrigation installations were constructed. An additional 800,000 ha of cultivated land were created by irrigation in the area of the Volga-Don Canal. Eventually the Volga will be used to irrigate 15 millón ha in the eastern Volga area and along the Caspian Sea (see Fig. 68). For the more distant future, water reclamation plans of the Soviet Union call for the conversion of more than 25 million ha into productive irrigated land. 2. Pushing back of the polar boundaries of cropping: Biological technological advances in plant breeding have made it possible to raise spring barley, potatoes, and winter rye increasingly north of the Arctic Circle. 3. Cultivation of the virgin lands: The most renowned and significant part of the virgin lands that has been cultivated is the Siberian steppe zone, which embraces approximately the northern third of Kazakhstan. Here, from 1953 to 1960, 20 million ha of arable land were reclaimed from natural grassland. However, just as in the western U.S., part of this expansion by dry farming has taken place in areas that are much too dry, where the risk of drought is great. To return these lands to extensive grazing is difficult because problems such as wind erosion hinder the regeneration of the natural steppe grass. A million hectares of virgin lands and old fallow were also reclaimed for cultivation in the Soviet Far East, from 1954 to 1960. Soybeans, grains,
3. The Agricultural Geography of the East Bloc Countries
265
and livestock dominate, with vegetables, potatoes, and dairying concentrating near the cities (Könnecke 1967, p. 308). The major reserves here of virgin lands suitable for cultivation lie in the Amur area, the granary of the Russian Far East, which forms a transition to the agricultural zones of North China.
266
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
g) Agricultural Zones of the People's Republic of China The discussion of the agricultural zones of China must first be prefixed by a general overview of the agricultural economy of the country. Collectivization has been carried out in the following stages (Rochlin and Hagemann 1971, p. 87): before 1950: individual peasant farms, with an average farm size of 1.62 ha (1949); the average holding of the "large landowner" came to 18.2 ha, for large-scale farmers, 4.4 ha, for medium-scale farmers, 1.1 ha, and for small farmers, 0.4 ha (Böttcher 1971, p. 16). 1950 to 1955: mutual aid teams; private property remained intact, though draft animals and equipment were used in common by six to fifteen households. 1952 to 1956: agricultural producers' cooperatives of 10 to 50 households, with an average holding of 37.5 ha; ownership in common of land, large livestock, and equipment; also private farmland. 1953 to 1958: advanced agricultural producers' cooperatives; 100 to 160 households; average holding of 153 ha in 1958; private property restricted to gardens and small animals. 1958 to 1959: people's communes; agricultural production, forestry, fishing, local industry, large agrotechnical projects; over 5,000 households, subdivided into production brigades and production teams; average holding of 4,565 ha in 1959. after 1959: revised people's communes, i.e. reduction to as little as 1,600 households and an average of 1,360 ha; stronger emphasis on agriculture; extensive intensification through more irrigation and use of commercial fertilizer; mechanization and cultivation of marginal soils. In 1974, the approximately 50,000 people's communes in the PRC were almost the only organizational form of agriculture. In Table 19 some economic data on Chinese agriculture are compared with those of several important and widely contrasting countries in order to illustrate the difficult situation of the People's Republic. The two most populous countries on earth, China and India, which take in 36% of the world population, are still densely settled agrarian states. Poverty of capital and lack of industrialization reinforce each other in such countries and contribute to a situation in which agricultural inputs of industrial origin, such as the labor-saving tractor and yield-increasing chemical fertilizers, are still extraordinarily scarce and expensive. Small harvest returns are the result, and this forces a sharp reduction in the consumption of animal products so as to avoid the food losses inherent
267
3. The Agricultural Geography of the East Bloc Countries Table 19:
Economic Data on the Agriculture of the People's Republic of China in Comparison with Some Other Countries, 1974
Characteristic
Unit
PR China
India
Japan
Population 1,2 Population density 3 Agricultural land, ''4 of which is irrigated1,4 Cropland: grassland1'4 Chemical fertilizer expenditures 3 Tractors 3 Yields: Wheat Rice Milk Food production per head: Grains Meat 1974 index
million people/km mill, ha
740 85 327 23.3 1.6
548 175 178 17.7 0.08
105 291 5.7 45.4 0.07
61 249 13.3 2.0 0.6Í
203 22 435 3.7 1.3
243 97.0
40.2 10.1
47.6
18.4 49.8 4,666
% 1: ... kg pure nutrient/ha AL per 1,000 ha AL
16.4 0.5
15.6 1.0
404 49.6
q/ha q/ha kg/cow/yr.
12.8 32.7 544
11.6 16.4 486
28.0 58.4 900
kg kg 1961/65 = 100
311 11.2 110
198 1.1 96
157 13.2 109
FRG
—
3,880
USA
372 1,000 58.2 84.0 113 112
1 Latest census. - 2 Mostly 1970. - 3 1973. - 4 Mostly 1972. - 5 Total area. Sources: UNO: Statistical Yearbook 1974. New York 1975. - F AO: Production Yearbook 1974. Rome 1975. — Statistisches Jahrbuch über Ernährung, Landwirtschaft und Forsten der BRD 1975. Hamburg and Berlin 1975.
in the processing of feed by the animal. In 1969 only 14.6% of the gross production of Chinese agriculture consisted of animal products, compared to 80.5% of the food production of the German Federal Republic. Nevertheless, not even grain production per head in the People's Republic of China attained the same levels as those in the USA and the FRG, though grain is a much more basic food item in China and India (rice) than it is in the FRG or the USA (wheat, rye). Because of the large north-south extent of the PRC, the agricultural geography of the country reflects a zonal structure that is just as clear and interesting as that of Soviet Russia. The characteristics of the two countries beautifully complement each other since China lies closer to the equator. The agricultural zones are differentiated in Fig. 69 as follows, from north to south (see Biehl 1973, pp. 14 ff.): 1. First is the spring wheat-millet-sorghum zone, with only one harvest per year. It includes the Manchurian Plain in the north and runs along the southern edge of Inner Mongolia. As is the case in the Russian coniferous forest zone, the northern part of the US grain belts, or the wide reaches of Canada, this is an area where the hard winters scarcely permit
268
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
any forms of winter grain cropping. The desert-and-oasis province of Sinkiang can be similarly evaluated, for Siberian climatic characteristics are also found there.
2. The winter wheat-cotton zone, which begins south of Peking and encompasses the largest part of the great Yellow Plain with the provinces of Hopeh, Shantung, Honan, and Shansi, can be considered as already much more favorable agriculturally. The very reference to cotton in the zonal designation points to a much warmer climate. Here is the one thing that is typical of the greater part of China and of most warm countries: more than one harvest per year. In this zone, it is possible to raise winter wheat that ripens soon enough to allow grain corn to be planted after the harvest and then brought to maturity, all in the same
3. The Agricultural Geography of the East Bloc Countries
269
year. Cotton follows in the second year, and it of course takes up the entire growing season. Thus the outcome of this crop rotation is three harvests in two years, something that may be viewed as a typical and not isolated occurrence. 3. Two harvests every year can be obtained in the adjoining and still more southerly zone, the mixed zone. Rice, which thrives in the heat, is often raised in the summer, while wheat, which has little resistance to heat, is raised in the winter. Exactly the same rotation within a calendar year can frequently be found under similar ecological conditions in other countries: in the constantly wet subtropics, as in parts of the La Plata states; in the dry-summer subtropics, as in Egypt or Turkey in the form of summer irrigation of rice; or in semiarid areas, as in parts of Chile where there is year-around irrigation of both crops. In other cases, one can find the following rotations in the mixed zone: 1st year winter: winter wheat summer: grain corn 2nd year winter: legumes summer: cotton. Thus here also two harvests are obtained every year. 4. The rice-tea-silk zone begins somewhat north of the Yangtze line. The production program here is even more diversified. Now as much as two and a half harvests can be taken from the rice fields per year in a pattern somewhat like the following: 1st year winter: early wheat or green manures (legumes) summer: two successive rice crops 2nd year winter: late, high-yielding winter crop summer: more demanding rice. Since the rice planted is usually wet rice, leveled fields are required. Hills and slopes are consequently used differently. Tea bushes and mulberry trees are cultivated there. Tung oil and citrus fruits are also produced on those sites. 5. The southernmost agricultural zone of the country is probably best designated as the rice-tropical crops zone. While paddies are worked as they are in the northern adjoining zone, bush and tree crops that find their physiological optimum only in the tropics gain acceptance as well: oil palms, coconut palms, coffee bushes, silk-cotton trees, sisal agave, pineapples, and the like, Here one cannot help but feel that concessions are being made to a foreign trade economy. With a shortage of currency, strivings for autarky in agriculture lead to a production that is little justified locationally, which in turn will diminish the overall value of that productivity.
270
VIII. The Agricultural Geography of the Middle Latitudes
That today double cropping is possible on about half of the arable land of China is due not only to the geographic position of the country, but to the expansion of irrigation, from 16% of the cultivated land in 1949 to already 33% of it in 1969 (FAO). Droughts as well as floods must be combatted. Thus efforts have first concentrated on building dikes in central and southern China in order to protect large areas from floods. China has recognized that large flood control projects must provide for industrialization as well as irrigation. Moreover, it is in the fortunate position of being able to capitalize on a half a century of experience by other countries in the modern technology of dike construction and stream regulation. Experience has taught that only if a river is fully harnessed up to its source with a step-like chain of reservoirs, can it be regulated for maximum efficiency and used to the fullest for irrigation, navigation, and hydroelectric power. The projects in the three large river basins of the Yangtze, Hwai, and Hwang are being carried out with especially this concept in mind. By the middle of the fifties, the People's Republic of China had already about 70 million ha of land under irrigation, and had plans for expanding this to 93 million by 1967. How extremely vital these questions of water control are to the country may be seen in a report of the Peking People's Daily that in 1960 more than half of the Chinese cultivated area was afflicted by floods or droughts.
IX. Structural Changes in World Agricultural Space with Economic Growth
We shall conclu.de this book by treating some of the evolutionary and theoretical aspects involved in the tendencies of farms to shift location and to change form, insofar as these changes help to differentiate agricultural space.
1. Forces for Development The processes of national economic growth give rise to significant evolutions and adaptions among farms because — as explained in Chapter IV-3 — they generate technological advances and these in turn decisively influence the level and structure of agricultural prices. Abel (1967, p. 355) has investigated the long-term development of prices of production factors in Germany, beginning with the end of the Middle Ages (see Fig. 70). From the 15th century to the first half of the 19th century, i.e. in the agrarian period, land prices rose by sixteen times, prices of capital goods (here represented by iron prices) by about 80%, and wages by only 9%. Hence, in these centuries, there was steadily increasing pressure for intensification, and above all for increasing labor intensity. At the beginning of the industrial period, however, these price trends either changed their course or their rate of increase. From the first half of the 19th century to the end of the thirties in our century, land prices only doubled, while wages increased almost five times and prices of capital goods became cheaper and decidedly so. The industrial era was thus marked by a moderation of labor intensity and an increase in capital intensity. The development of prices in West Germany during the postwar period has continued these trends. On the whole, these trends appear to have, at least for densely settled countries, a definite universality, and are of basic importance for the following discussion. Technological advances, price and wage trends, and institutional and political changes, are the engines of agricultural development. The consequences are the following: a) Industrialization raises mass income, demand for food, and with that, agricultural prices. Other conditions being equal, the purchasing power (exchange value) of agricultural products for wages and farm inputs must rise. But because the prices of manufactured inputs are also fall-
272
IX. Structural Changes in World Agricultural Space
ing with industrialization and wages are increasing because of the competition for labor, the following differentiations in farming operations must occur: aa) Farming intensity is increased by expanding the intensive enterprises at the expense of the extensive enterprises, and by restricting fallowing; bb) Capital is substituted for labor, in sparsely settled countries with labor-saving capital goods (machines for working the soil, planting, harvesting, transporting, processing) and in densely settled countries more with yield-increasing inputs (irrigation, chemical fertilization, veterinary hygiene, possibly feed concentrates); cc) Whether specialization intensity is raised overall, i.e. whether the reduction of labor expenditures in the individual enterprises is more than compensated by the additional application of yieldincreasing inputs, depends on the ratio of the wage increase to the decline in capital costs. In densely settled developed coun-
2. Changes in the Factor Combination
273
tries this question is always answered in the affirmative; in sparsely settled ones, it is not always so. b) As general affluence increases, and with that, changes in consumption habits of the population as well, prices of animal products definitely increase faster than those of plant products. Livestock raising is therefore stimulated in its present locations and its expansion is encouraged elsewhere. Farms on which there is no livestock become mixed operations, as land use is integrated with livestock raising and the two are mutually promoted through fodder cropping and a manuring economy. In this way a close symbiosis has developed between land use and livestock raising, one that has, among other things, helped Central European agriculture to achieve its very high productivity. c) Improvements in infrastructure and agricultural structure reduce costs, and thus improve the input-output ratio, and with that increase the intensity of agriculture as well. Expansion of markets and consolidation of the transport net exert a leveling influence on agriculture. Regional differences that were caused by varying distances to market become blurred, as transport costs diminish overall and thus become less variable among the farms. But the more this happens, and the effect of isolation from the market is reduced, the more agriculture adapts to the physical conditions affecting production. d) At the highest stage of national economic development, wages and income expectations in agriculture rise much more quickly than the prices of agricultural products and the costs of land use and industrially-produced farm inputs. The purchasing power of agricultural products for hand labor falls drastically, and the purchasing power of hand labor for every input rises. The result is that every worker in agriculture must be provided with much more land and capital goods. In the present stage of technology in the FRG, this means that with the great efforts to enlarge the farm, there must also be a reduction in farming intensity by continuing to increase specialization intensity (e.g. less hoe cropping and dairying, but higher productivity per hectare and per animal).
2. Changes in the Factor Combination If one takes a good look at the progress of economic development, one can roughly distinguish four development stages: aa) agrarian countries, bb) agrarian-industrial countries, cc) industrial-agrarian countries, dd) industrial countries.
274
IX. Structural Changes in World Agricultural Space
a) Factor Costs and Factor Combination in Sparsely Settled Countries Industrialization makes land and labor more expensive, but capital cheaper. The combination mix of production factors is a product of reciprocal actions based on cost relationships. The more the marginal productivity of a production factor falls, the more this factor must be expended relative to the others. One must always strive to expand inputs of each production factor just enough to ensure that its marginal productivity covers its costs. The minimum cost combination is achieved when the marginal yields of all three production factors are proportional to their marginal costs. Consequently expensive production factors, other things being equal, must be applied sparingly, whereas the cheapest production factor must be accorded quantitative superiority in the production process, since as its cost is small its marginal productivity can also be low. Thus it is possible to deduce the optimum combination of production factors for the different stages of national economic development directly from the theory of marginal productivity. To demonstrate this, we shall turn to a table elaborated by Herlemann (1954, pp. 355 ff.), whose basic ideas we shall be largely following here. In Fig. 71, which shows the various combination possibilities of the land, labor, and capital factors in agricultural production, the shortage of a factor relative to the other two is indicated by one or two minus signs and the predominance of a factor relative to the others is indicated by one or two plus signs. The agrarian states represent developing countries in which no differentiation of practical significance for the national economy has so far taken place. The remaining stages depict the result of increasing levels of industrialization, which is usually a characteristic of economic development. But the process of industrialization can take two fundamentally different courses, depending on whether it takes place in sparsely settled countries or in countries with a high population density (see Fig. 72). First, let us deal with the changes in the minimum cost combination arising in the course of national economic development in sparsely settled agrarian countries with fewer than 60 inhabitants per 100 ha FL. The greatest part of Central and South America and many African countries can be included in this group. Land is still fairly abundant in these areas, so it is also cheap. Labor is less cheap, while all capital goods purchased from industry are exceedingly expensive. Therefore it is possible to do without high land and labor productivity, whereas in contrast heavy stress must be put on achieving high capital productivity. As a result, land is used generously and capital goods are used sparingly wherever the desired effects can be achieved by increasing labor input. The agricultural system
275
2. Changes in the Factor Combination Diagram
Factor Costs and Factor Combinations in the Course of National Economic Development Sparsely Settled Countries
Typical Examples
Development
Progression
Densely Settled Countries
X%
&
y
Typical Examples
Α. Cost Relationships Zaire, Ethiopia
+
+ + Agrarian Country
+ +
Mexico, Zambia, Kenya
-
+
+
Agrarian-Industrial Country
Argentina, Uruguay
+
++
-
Industrial-Agrarian Country + +
U.S.A., Australia
+
++
Industrial Country
—
+ + +
+ + Egypt, Ghana, Thailand
— -
+
+
-
Colombia, Iran, Ecuador Chile, Finland Great Britain, F R G
+ +
B. Input Combinations
see above
+ +
+
Agrarian
+ + +
+
A g r a r i a n - I n d u s t r i a l Country
-
Costs
and
Depending
inputs on
of
+ —
production factors
Herlemann, H -H
Country
+ +
Industrial-Agrarian Country
+ + Industrial Country are
— — very low
Technisierungsstuten
der Landwirtschaft
+
_
—
-
— low „Ber
ub
+ high Lana w ", Hamburg
see above + —+ + + + very high and Bertin,
Ν F, Vol XXX11 {t95¿!, ρ 33Sft
Figure 71
as a whole must be regarded as extensive. Farming types typical of this stage are the forest-burning system of shifting cultivation in the humid tropics and the grain-fallow and extensive grassland farming systems in the dry climates. The next stage is characterized by the countries in which industrialization is beginning to make itself felt in the agricultural structure, the agrarian-industrial countries. Although land is still abundantly available, the labor potential in agriculture is being reduced because of competition from industry. Capital goods are less scarce. The effect of all this on the scarcity ratios of the production factors is that land and labor are becoming more expensive, whereas capital is becoming cheaper. In contrast to the stage represented by the agrarian counries, labor productivity must now be increased and less stress need be put on capital productivity. The labor input is therefore reduced through an increase in the capital input. The agricultural system as a whole must still be regarded as extensive. With the third stage of development, and further industrialization, areas of concern become the industrial-agrarian countries. Land is somewhat scarcer but still relatively cheap. Labor, though, has become significantly
276
IX. Structural Changes in World Agricultural Space
more expensive in the course of the industrialization process, while the cost of capital goods and credit has decreased. As a result labor productivity must again be greatly increased, while capital productivity may be
2. Changes in the Factor Combination
277
allowed to relax even further. Agricultural operations are now laborextensive but capital-intensive. The changes in the minimum cost combination for the agricultural systems sketched so far have been directed toward raising the efficiency of human labor with increasing use of labor-saving machinery and vehicles (mechanization). With the help of this equipment it is possible to open up new areas to cultivation. The bearer of progress in the development of new cultivation techniques is the agricultural machinery industry, whose progress is in turn favored by the expansion of areas under cultivation and the increasing specialization of farms. Output per unit of area of labor-extensive agriculture is still relatively low. Agriculture is at the mechanization stage (Herlemann 1954). The United States is an example of the dominantly industrial countries of stage 4. Because of the very high level of industrialization land and labor have become even more scarce and expensive, while capital goods have become still cheaper. It is therefore now urgent to combine high labor productivity with high land productivity, even if this can only be bought with an exceptionally high capital input and the resulting drop in capital productivity. The agricultural system must be intensive, particularly capital-intensive. But the increase in capital input takes different forms at this stage. The improvement of the purchasing power ratio between agricultural products and industrially produced inputs now makes it possible to increase the use of yield-increasing inputs in combination with better quality seed, improved crop rotations,, better tillage, seed cleaning and seed dressing equipment, and the like. The agricultura machinery industry, which is becoming increasingly concerned with the manufacture of labor-saving machines and equipment (seed drills, mechanical hoes, fertilizer spreaders, cultivators, etc.), and the chemical industry (fertilizers, weed killers, seed dressings, vaccines, etc.) are becoming increasingly important for agricultural production. As a result of the rising cost of land, the use of land-saving inputs has come to take its place beside the use of laborsaving capital goods (Herlemann 1954).
b) Factor Costs and Factor Combination in Densely Settled Countries The progression of capital investment is reversed in the agriculture of densely populated areas, with more than 60 inhabitants per 100 ha FL. Here land-saving capital goods are most important at first, while laborsaving equipment is introduced only later. The intensification phase here thus precedes the mechanization phase (see Fig. 71, p. 275, right half).
278
IX. Structural Changes in World Agricultural Space
The starting point for development is now the overpopulated agrarian state. Countries such as India, Taiwan, and Java fit this category. Land is scarce and therefore expensive, labor is abundant and consequently cheap, and capital goods are expensive because of the lack of industrialization. The result is that while one can be content with low labor productivity, land and capital productivity must be high. These economic goals are reached with production methods that are as capital-extensive as they are labor-intensive. Appropriate farming types are wet-rice cultivation, combined with substantial cropping of roots and tubers, or laborintensive bush and tree crops. Economic conditions in these densely settled developing countries are usually unfavorable because industrialization is too slow relative to population growth, the result being an increasing overpopulation of the rural areas with all its adverse effects on labor productivity and living standards. In spite of a high intensity of labor and a predominantly vegetarian diet, the domestic agricultural output guarantees only a minimum caloric supply for the population. An excessively high birthrate, large fluctuations in crop yields, and an inadequate importing capacity increase the difficulties of supply which find their expression in periodic famines and epidemics. Since birth control promises little success and possibilities for emigration are limited, the ultimate solution lies in a well-planned program of industrialization which, in view of the dearth of domestic capital resources, will have to be supported by foreign capital (Herlemann 1954). The beginning of the industrialization process gives rise at first to the agrarian-industrial countries. Land prices are still high, wages are on the increase, but the prices of capital goods are lower. To allow for these cost conditions high land productivity must be combined with growing labor productivity, even at the price of diminishing capital productivity. Thus one farms with increasing capital intensity and decreasing labor intensity. The prevailing scarcity of land coupled with a still adequate labor supply at first appears to justify all expenditures that serve to increase the productivity of land. The intensity of agriculture, which is based on relatively high labor expenditures and increasing employment of yield-increasing inputs, is expressed in increasing yields per unit of area, though with a still comparatively low labor productivity. Only with the increasing shortage and expense of farm labor that come with advanced industrialization are the farmers in the densely settled states finally forced to improve labor productivity with heavy mechanization. Thus the objective of economic development - whether in an overpopulated or sparsely settled agricultural country — is at all times the industrial state, which is characterized by a high input of capital designed to obtain a high productivity of land and labor. A high degree of industri-
2. Changes in the Factor Combination
279
alization makes for a high level of wages and a shortage of labor, so that efforts must concentrate on obtaining high labor productivity. A high population density in relation to agricultural land also makes necessary high land productivity. This is feasible as soon as the price levels of agricultural products increase with the growing purchasing power of the consumer. Thus land and labor productivity must be increased simultaneously. This can only happen, however, because the costs of capital inputs now are low, which make possible a decisive increase in labor productivity through mechanization and in land productivity through intensification. Human labor is replaced by machines and land is replaced by yield-increasing inputs. The ultimate combination of production factors is thus characterized by the economical use of land and labor and a very generous use of capital in every form. Agriculture now is capitalintensive.
c) Differences in the Overall Trend of Change in the Factor Combination Let us conclude by summarizing. Three elementary production factors in agriculture must be differentiated: land, labor, and capital. Technically they do not have to be combined according to a specific set of ratios. Indeed, within wide limits they are interchangeable. From the economic point of view, though, there is for each stage of economic development only one minimum cost combination of these three production factors, one derived from the relationship between their prices and which alone ensures that production is at its cheapest. Basic to the attainment of the most economic factor combination is the recognition that, everything else being equal, the higher the price of a production factor the more sparing its input must be. This is so because first, on a farm run on the profit principle the marginal yield (measured in money) should cover the cost of the input of the factor in question, and second, the marginal productivity of the factor sinks if its input is progressively increased in relation to the other two. Meanwhile, the cheapest production factor should be accorded the quantitative predominance in the production process. Progress in national economic development, which is generally achieved through increasing industrialization, leads to a situation in which capital goods gradually become cheaper while labor becomes more and more expensive. One of the results of this is that human labor is increasingly supplemented by capital goods. Which capital goods will come to the fore in the course of economic development will depend on the availability of land. In sparsely settled agrarian countries the initial concern is the replacement of manual labor. Here then, the mechanization phase pre-
280
IX. Structural Changes in World Agricultural Space
cedes the intensification phase. Not until later, when agricultural land begins to grow scarce, will yield-increasing inputs be increasingly expended. The situation in overpopulated agrarian countries is entirely different. Here land becomes scarce more quickly than labor, so that yield-increasing inputs must be given priority because they make it possible to use land sparingly. Mechanization comes in only later, when labor has become increasingly scarce and expensive with industrial progress. In short, it is clear that the changes in the minimal cost combinaton in the course of national economic development can vary greatly from one country to another, depending on whether the countries were initially sparsely or densely populated. It also follows that in developing countries with varying economic structures, technological progress will take different forms. Mechanical technological advances will be of primary benefit to the sparsely settled agrarian countries, whereas organic technological advances will particularly lighten the future path of overpopulated agrarian countries.
d) Developmental Tendencies in Farm Size The development of farm size during economic growth can also be inferred from what has been said (see Fig. 73): Fig. 73 allows us to conclude that, among other things, 1. changes in farm size in sparsely and densely settled countries show quite different trends. 2. farms in densely settled countries are considerably smaller than those in sparsely settled countries at all stages of national economic development. 3. farm size differences among farms with varying density of settlement are the smallest at the beginning of national economic development because farms are of the subsistence type, with farmers striving to provide all of the food needed by the family. 4. farm size differences are the greatest in the middle stages of economic development. Farms must contract in densely settled countries because of population growth, and the substitution of yield-increasing capital goods for land makes this possible. In sparsely settled countries the substitution of machine capital for labor forces the farmer to cultivate larger areas. 5. farm sizes for the two country groups begin to approach each other at the highest stage of national economic development, though naturally not as closely as at the beginning of development. In the densely settled countries, industrialization now permits rural out-migration
281
2. Changes in the Factor Combination Diagram
Long-Term Development Trends in Farm in the Agricultural Domain
Agrarian Countries
lAgrarian-Industrial Industrial-Agrarian, | Countries I Countries ¡ ECONOMIC
L Labor Input
level:
I) Incl.
tractors.
2} Chemical
-low fertilizers,
Industrial Countries
GROWTH
M Machinery') — — very tow
Size
•
Ρ Production + high irrigation,
+ + very plant
protection,
input21 high feed concentrates,
etc.
Figure 73
and the establishment of large mechanized farms. In the sparsely settled countries, it is becoming increasingly difficult to obtain agricultural workers, so that the operator must fall back on as advanced a technology and specialization intensity as possible. Fig. 73 of course shows only the typical long-term trends in farm size in the agricultural domain, and cannot be taken to mean that development will always take place in this way and no other. Above all, one should not get the impression that for each of the stages of economic development there is only one optimum farm size in agriculture. More likely, it can be generally said that a mixture of different farm sizes is the most favorable, no matter what the time or place and regardless of whether farming is of the free enterprise or socialist type. Fig. 74 shows how profoundly the chain reaction in the current adaption process in West European agriculture has influenced the farm size structure. Of particular note is that
282
I X . Structural Changes in World Agricultural Space
Diagram
Medium-
and Long-Term
Development Higher wages
Alternatives
for West European
Farms
and income are sought
either within
agriculture
w i t h maintenance
of f u l l - t i m e
outside of with
forming
1. m e c h a n i z a t i o n
land-rich extensive
3.production intensification per ha and a n i m a l
farming
(many c o m b i n e - h a r v e s t e d crops, sugar beets, c a t t l e a n d hog f a t t e n i n g )
agriculture
a b a n d o n m e n t of f u l l - t i m e
farming
through
through
land-poor intensive
farming
( hoe, i n d u s t r i a l , and specialty crops)
\
extra-income I e.g.
farming
tourism)
part-lime
farming
{intensity
reduced)
full n o n - f a r m e m p l o y m e n t and only rural r e s i d e n c e (FL
is s o l d , rented, or l e f t i d l e )
Figure 74
1. above all, wage and income expectations are rising, which raises the question of whether the full-time farm can and should be maintained, or whether agriculture can continue as a part-time operation, with the farmer taking an off-farm job. 2. a greater share of the farmers who wish to remain full-time operators are under considerable pressure to expand their operations; 3. external upgrading with further mechanization leads to land-rich extensive farms, whereas 4. internal upgrading with a major increase in productivity has as its consequence land-poor intensive farms. The conditions for their survival are usually more difficult than are those for the farms named under 3. Fig. 75 lists six different farm size classes for West German agriculture today, among which there are still transitional types. This figure also shows that the adaption procedures of the six main classes to changing economic conditions are highly variable. Farms of varying size have very contrasting economic and sociological potentialities and limits, as already described in Chapter IV-2-c. The information in Fig. 75 is not of agricultural-geographic interest in itself. It is of use, though, in providing the necessary comparisons referred to in this chapter on changes in the factor combination, and in
2. Changes in the Factor Combination
Adaptation
^ ^ F A R M
Processes of Various Farm Size an Expanding Agriculture
SIZES
MEASURES A. Decisive for f a r m i n g is a h i g h capital productivity labor p r o d u c t i v i t y land p r o d u c t i v i t y
F U L L - T I M E
XvXvX ^
^
^
Classes
F A R M S
^ O v V X V ' X \
\
\
\
\
\
^ A
\FAMILY
in
FARMS
\ \
\
\
^
\
success
B. Labor e c o n o m i e s result f r o m labor expenditures in commerce and business more production i n p u t s fully mechanized fleldwork C
283
F u l l m e c h a n i z a t i o n is a c h i e v e d with operator's m a c h i n e r y machinery cooperatives m a c h i n e r y pools customwork n e i g h b o r ' s help
D. F u l l y m e c h a n i z e d f a r m i n g , r e q u i r e s less l a n d - i n t e n s i v e cultivation methods f u l l use of l a r g e - m a c h i n e r y capacities f a r m i n g specialization making way for less intensive enterprises
-
-
-
-
_
-
(-) (-1
-
-
(-)
-
—
E. F u l l y m e c h a n i z e d o p e r a t i o n s in t h e farming s y s t e m lead to labor economies labor s h i f t s into livestock f a r m i n g easing of w o r k l o a d s
—
-
F. L i v e s t o c k r a i s i n g is abandoned made less intensive and more specialized made more intensive and specialized expanded beyond i t s own feed base G. E s p e c i a l l y d e s i r e d f o r i m p r o v e m e n t of i n c o m e is more m a c h i n e c a p i t a l more l i v e s t o c k c a p i t a l more f a r m l a n d
-
_
_
-
-
-
-
-
—
—
_
—
Figure 75
explaining those of the next section on the development patterns of the production program in economic growth.
284
IX. Structural Changes in World Agricultural Space
3. De versification and Specialization of the Production Program In the following we present an outline of the historical development of farms as seen from the viewpoint of degree of diversification. Without wishing to ignore the flowing transitions of economic actuality, we shall emphasize only three stages of farming diversity (see Overview 23). Overview 23: Stages in Farming Diversity
Characteristic
Single-Prod- Specialized Mixed uct Farms Farms Farms
Number of potential cash crops one Share of sales returns obtained by the principal farm enter> 90% prises one-sided Farm organization Developmental trends
• capital-intensiveness, the following change in farming diversity must be expected: monoculture -*• diversification specialization.
IX. Structural Changes in World Agricultural Space
290
Diagram
Farm
Diversification
and Specialization
in Economic
Growth
Figure 76
4. Changes in Farming Systems in Selected Climatic Zones In the course of economic development land becomes increasingly scarce, so that it must be farmed ever more productively, i.e. used more intensively. With the change from a sparsely to a densely settled agrarian state, there is at first an increasingly large labor force available, while all forms of capital goods continue to be very expensive. Hence the necessary agricultural intensification in this phase of development must be effected by increasing labor expenditures. Only when considerable industrialization develops does the labor force decline and, as with land, become more expensive while commercially-produced capital goods become cheaper. In this latter phase of development, further intensification must be strived for by increasing capital investment. In the course of economic development, the productivity of land must first be increased, and later also that of labor. However, the triad of intensity stages that satisfies this demand follows a sequence of: extensiveness -> labor-intensiveness -> capital-intensiveness. This resume of the last section will help us to explain and to understand the following developmental sequences. It already explains the old cultural-historical developmental theories: Richard Krzymowski's three-stage theory: hunting and sishing ->- nomadism ->· crop farming.
4. Changes in Farming Systems in Selected Climatic Zones
291
Eduard Hahn's three sequential forms: 1. gathering hunting and fishing (only in particular locations); or 2. gathering -> hoe culture garden culture; or 3. gathering -> hoe culture -»· plow culture -»• nomadism. Here, though, developmental sequences peculiar to a few selected climates will be listed and briefly explained (Andreae 1972).
a) Tropical Rainforest Climate Farming systems in the constantly wet tropical rainforest climate will always show a marked tendency to remain land use (i.e. cropping) systems and will in the course of economic development change according to the following sequence: Stage 1: haphazard forest-burning system of shifting cultivation; Stage 2: organized forest-burning system of shifting cultivation with natural forest fallow; Stage 3: organized forest-burning system of shifting cultivation with man-induced forest fallow; Stage 4: organized forest-burning system of shifting cultivation with plow cultivation; Stage 5: legume fallowing; Stage 6: grass fallowing; Stage 7: ley farming; and Stage 8: bush and tree crop farming. This progression of stages is consistent with the need to raise land productivity first and then labor productivity. It is therefore the usual pattern, though this does not exclude the possibility of some stages being skipped where there is a very rapid and dynamic economic development. In some cases, also, the sequence can change. The haphazard forest-burning system of shifting cultivation was replaced directly by oilpalm growing in parts of Nigeria and by cocoa production in southern Ghana, because the geographical position of these countries on an ocean allowed them to benefit from high prices in the world market. The combination of man-induced forest fallow with plow cultivation presents problems and is skipped in many countries. Foreign trade often makes bush and tree cultivation possible at a time when the home market still cannot fully absorb the animal products of ley farming. In general, however, the sequence of farming systems given here will prevail during economic development. The order is realistic because an expansion of the proportion of productive land with a simultaneous, increase in hectare yields is at first achieved with increased labor expenditures. The change from the haphazard to the organized forest-burning
292
IX. Structural Changes in World Agricultural Space
system of shifting cultivation simply, increases the proportion of cropped land, i.e. simply increases the amount of labor used. The change from natural to artificial fallow does require some capital in the form of plant stock, but this kind of capital can be created by labor on the farm itself. Only with the change from hoe to plow culture do capital expenditures, in the form of implements and draft animals, increase substantially. When forest fallowing is replaced by legume fallowing, additional capital is required for seeds, and still more for fertilizers when legume fallowing is replaced by grass fallowing. The highest form of land use, ley farming or bush and tree crop farming, necessitates considerable additional capital investment in the respective form of livestock or permanent plant stock.
b) Humid Savanna Climate In the humid the course of Stage 1: Stage 2: Stage 3: Stage 4: Stage 5:
savanna the emphasis in farming will probably change in economic development as follows: forest-burning system of shifting cultivation; bush-fallowing system of shifting cultivation; grass-fallowing system of shifting cultivation; rainfed farming without fallowing and livestock raising; rainfed farming without fallowing but with livestock raising; and Stage 6: irrigation farming without fallowing but with livestock raising. Here, too, development is at first directed toward an increase in the proportion of productive land through a continuing reduction in the number of fallow years, the fallow vegetation consequently changing from forest via bush to grass. Later an attempt is made to dispense with fallow altogether in the interest of land productivity, and it soon becomes obvious that livestock are a prerequisite of permanent rainfed farming in the interests of fertilizer production. The increased demand for animal products now makes this possible. For its part livestock raising, with its demands for a seasonal feed balance, helps to bring about the last and decisive step to irrigation farming. The humid savanna is perfectly suited for this, since it has a relatively small water requirement but abundant supplies of groundwater. A rational system of dams and reservoirs is now also possible because rivers flow throughout the year. As long as land productivity is the first concern and labor still cheap, various methods of irrigation can be used. Beginning with a specific wage level, sprinkler irrigation will become progressively more economic, since it requires much less labor and capi-
4. Changes in Farming Systems in Selected Climatic Zones
293
tal equipment becomes cheaper in the course of development. Thus sprinkler irrigation, together with chemical fertilization, plant protection, and the like, ensures high labor productivity while maintaining high land productivity.
c) Dry Savanna and Steppe Climates In spite of the greater need for irrigation in the dry savanna, irrigation farming finds fewer opportunities because of the shortage of water. In this area, the decisive sequence of changes in farming systems in the course of national economic development can be described thusly (see Fig. 77, p. 294): Stage 1: extensive grassland farming; Stage 2: savanna shifting cultivation; Stage 3: grain-fallow farming with extensive grassland farming (ranching); Stage 4: crop rotations organized to include fodder and legume cropping, in conjunction with extensive grassland farming; and Stage 5: penetration of dryland crop farming by moderately intensive grassland farming. At first the fodder cropping in stage 4 serves primarily the aims of soil biology rather than feed production. Planted grass fallow is at first introduced primarily in support of wheat and barley cropping (steppes) or of millet, sorghum, or corn cropping (dry savannas), and not in support of livestock farming during times of feed shortage. This does not exclude, of course, the possibility of using fodder crops for grazing during the dry season or for producing hay. In this way they form the link between cattle fattening and corn, millet-sorghum, wheat, or barley cropping. Fodder cropping allows rotations to be used for grain cropping and broadens the feed base for cattle fattening in the dry season. It supplies root humus for the cultivated crops and winter feed for the grazing animals; the animals transform part of this feed into manure which in turn benefits the grain crops. In this way the two farm enterprises of slaughter cattle production and grain cropping, which once existed side by side in isolation, now give rise to an association, an integrated whole, a farming system. In the course of further development, more productive field crops are also cultivated, such as garbanzos, peanuts, sunflowers, sesame, and eventually even crops like cotton. This crop farming as a whole continues to encroach upon the natural pasture areas, until it finally occupies
4. Changes in Farming Systems in Selected Climatic Zones
295
all the farmland where conditions are suitable for cultivation (gradient, depth of topsoil, groundwater table, etc.). The penetration of dryland crop farming by moderately intensive ranching, in stage 5, is due ultimately to the fact that even with the most modern technology, the yields of the field crops in these dry locations are not sufficient to satisfy the income demands typical of the developmental stages of a highly advanced national economy. Ranching is clearly superior to dryland crop farming in labor productivity. However, in the shrub savannas and dry steppes, which lie outside of the potential rainfed farming zone, the evolution can occur only within the ranching or extensive grassland farming system. According to the principle of extensiveness -»• labor-intensiveness -»• capital-intensiveness, the sequence of changes in the course of national economic development will be as follows (see Fig. 43, p. 172): Stage 1: nomadic grazing; Stage 2: sedentary grassland farming with seasonal migrations; Stage 3: bridging of the dry season with the farm's own feed reserves and by drawing on the animals' fat deposits; Stage 4: increasing the number of watering places; Stage 5: increasing pasture subdivision; Stage 6: purchasing additional feed; and Stage 7: farms producing on the farm all feed for the dry season. This gradual advancement of capital investment is set in motion both by an improvement in the market exchange value of animal products for farming inputs and by an improvement in market access for the farm. The improvement of the feed balance also contributes, in accordance with physical conditions, to the increase in productivity of livestock farming types.
d) Marine Cool-Summer Climate An example of the changes in farming systems in a mild and humid middle latitude climate is provided by the genesis of the crop rotations of central England (see Fig. 78). As in many other climatic zones, cropping here had its beginnings in shifting cultivation. This was subsequently replaced by primitive ley farming and later, beginning with the eighth and ninth centuries AD, by the three-course rotation with fallow. Toward the end of the eighteenth century, the early industrialization of England had already caused agricultural prices to rise so much that the consequent intensification had lead to the Norfolk rotation with no less than 25% CL in hoe cropping.
IX. Structural Changes in World Agricultural Space
296
Diagram
Genesis of the Crop Rotations of Central Shifting
England
Cultivation
( F r o m t h e beginning of a g r i c u l t u r e )
Primitive
Ley
Farming
F r o m 8 t h to 9 t h c e n t u r y , e x p a n s i o n of land, t h u s m a k i n g p r i m i t i v e ley f a r m i n g
Three-Course
Rotation, with 1. Fallowing
2. Winter 3. S u m m e r
cultivated impossible
Fallow
cropping cropping
F r o m 18th c e n t u r y on, i n t e n s i f i c a t i o n w i t h c o m p l e t i o n of I n t r o d u c t i o n of clover and t u r n i p s
enclosure.
Norfolk Rotation 1.Red clover 2. Wheat
3. Root crops it. S. ( S p r i n g ) b a r l e y
Light
Soils
1. Red clover 2. W h e a t 3. S. b a r l e y
During the last war, s h i f t f r o m p e r m a n e n t p a s t u r e to g r a i n l a n d , a r e a c t i o n to price a d v a n t a g e s for c r o p s , s u b v e n t i o n s , d e f i c i t s in feed concentrates, r e d u c t i o n of l i v e s t o c k h e r d s , etc.
4. Root crops 5. S. barley
4. W h e a t 5. S. b a r l e y
6. Root crops 7. S. b a r l e y
Soils
1. Red clover 2. W h e a t 3. W h e a t
4. Beans Improved Three-Course
Rotation
5. Wheat 6. O a t s
6 . S. barley
1.-3. Ley (grass)
Heavy
C u r r e n t d e v e l o p m e n t tendencies because of depletion of soil f e r t i l i t y , price a d v a n t a g e s for a n i m a l p r o d u c t s , etc.
Ley
Farming
1.-3. Ley (grass) 4. W h e a t 5. W h e a t
6. Beans 7. O a t s
S u m m a r i z e d from: D a v i e s , W . : Grassland and Soil Fertility. In: Grassland Management. Bulletin No 151. of the M i n i s t r y of Agriculture and Fisheries. London 1952, pp. 62-63. M e r c e r , W. B . , et al.: B r i t i s h Farming. H.M.s. Stationery Office.London 1951,pp.55-60. S a n d e r s , H.G.:The New Rotations. In: Management in Farming. H M s. Stationery Office, London 1919, pp. 3 2 - 3 5 .
Figure 78
4. Changes in Farming Systems in Selected Climatic Zones
297
This positive development of English farming came to an abrupt end in the 1870s, when England adopted the free trade doctrine and sacrificed its agriculture for industrialization. From 1873 to 1896 wheat prices in England fell by about half, barley prices by a third, and potato prices by more than half; meanwhile wages rose by a third. During the 1870— 1937 period, England converted 40% of its cultivated land to permanent grassland. With the convulsions of the world economic crisis in the 1930s and the second world war, this trend was reversed: 2.7 million ha of permanent pasture were plowed up from 1937 to 1944 and incorporated into rotations. While at first the emphasis was on crop production within the framework of an improved three-course rotation because of the need for food, a shift was made after the war back to the climaticallyfavored livestock raising, though now less on the basis of permanent than on rotation pasture. The ley farming system is an intensive form of grassland farming.
e) Continental Cool-Summer Climate The development of English agriculture is not too typical for a middle latitude climate since it has been subjected to drastic foreign trade and other political measures. Aereboe (1923, p. 320) characterizes the main line of development of farming types under the influence of changing economic conditions as follows: Stage 1: extensive grassland farming; Stage 2: one-field farming with shifting on pastureland; Stage 3: two-field farming with shifting on pastureland; Stage 4: three-field farming with shifting on pastureland; Stage 5: three-field and fallow farming without shifting; Stage 6: improved three-field farming, fallow partly grazed; Stage 7: improved three-field farming, fallow completely grazed; Stage 8: rotation farming with intensive legume cropping; Stage 9: rotation farming with intensive fodder cropping (clover); Stage 10: rotation farming with intensive hoe cropping and green manuring; Stage 11: pure farming of hoe crops, grains, and green manure crops; and Stage 12: market gardening forms of cropping. Aereboe's conception of the evolution of farming systems was strongly conditioned by his knowledge of steppe agriculture in the GovernmentGeneral of Voronezh. The situation in the Voronezh district suggested
298
IX. Structural Changes in World Agricultural Space
to him that all agricultural development was preceded by extensive grassland farming, which later evolved into grain farming. Still later fodder crops, as well as legumes and oil crops, would be cultivated. Hoe cropping would then come in, and gradually it would displace the earlier systems, first the cropping of legumes and than fodder cropping.
Outlook: The Agricultural Evolution Theory of Friedrich Aereboe in the Light of this Agricultural Geography
Many of the highly absorbing chapters in Aereboe's Allgemeinen landwirtschaftlichen Betriebslehre (General Farm Management) that deal with price relationships in their influence on farm organization focus on the evolution of farming systems. It generally begins with extensive grassland farming as the first stage. But extensive grassland farming is not the first stage of agricultural development in all climatic realms. To be sure, Aereboe recognized that extensive grassland farming was not at the beginning of historical development everywhere, for man to some extent had cultivated land before he had succeeded in domesticating productive animals. However, Aereboe at first did not perceive that even in the geographic coexistence of the various economic development stages of today, extensive grassland farming does not always make up the lowest stage. An extensive grazing operation in the tropical rainforest belt is in no way possible, since pasture would be taken over by bushes and forest in short order. In addition, the nagana disease that is carried by the tsetse fly still makes it impossible to raise cattle or sheep in wide areas. It is the hunter, fisherman, and gatherer, and not the herdsman, who mark the beginning of development in the constantly wet tropical rainforest climate. Nor is the beginning of any agriculture later associated with extensive livestock raising; instead, farming is one of pure plant production using digging stick and bush hoe. Pure grain farming without shifting as a middle stage in the development of cultivation also does not exist in the tropical rainforest belt. Permanent grain cropping is possible here only in the form of wet rice cultivation, but this must be considered as hoe culture from the farm management point of view, given the requisite tillage procedures in the inner tropics which usually include the starting of the plants in seedbeds and their subsequent transplanting in the fields. Grain cropping in the strict sense can never acquire great significance in the tropical rainforest, so that the Aereboe model of farming development does not apply there. His thesis, „Grain farming remains the backbone of cultivation at all stages of agricultural development. . .," also requires qualification for other climatic zones. Even in the warm-temperate oceanic climate of eastern United States, up to about the Mississippi, grain cropping plays only a subordinate role despite the currently high wage levels. This is
300
Outlook
because the hot summer ensures that leafy crops such as cotton, grain corn, soybeans, and peanuts, with their amenability to full mechanization in all operational phases, are superior to grain cropping in the competition for production factors. In other world climatic belts, of course, the thesis of Aereboe that extensive grassland farming signifies the first stage of any agriculture holds true; not, however, his conception of extensive grassland farming developing further via grain farming. On the hot and dry steppes and semi-deserts the amount of precipitation does not even allow the practice of the dry fanning system, grain-fallow farming. Thus here, beyond the dry boundary of cropping in the marginal zone of the inhabited area, further farm development occurs in one great leap, from extensive grassland farming directly into intensive irrigation farming. Examples of this are offered by such places as the American Intermountain states, the South African Karroo, and the semideserts of the Russian area. In later years, Aereboe himself recognized the limitations of his evolution theory with respect to climatic zones. Five years after the last edition of his Betriebslehre, in 1928, Aereboe came out with his Agrarpolitik (Agrarian Policy), in which he again devoted an extensive chapter to farming systems and their dependence on price relationships and the physical qualifications of agriculture. Toward the end of this section, he said (Aereboe 1928, p. 116): "With that, the essential points concerning the economic systems of agriculture in the middle latitude zones have been covered. Space prevents a more careful condideration of the same items for the subtropics and tropical zone. If that were to be done, then for the subtropics the various systems of irrigation farming would demand special attention, and for the tropics the forms of plantation farming there would have to be discussed. With regard to tropical plantation farming, it is to be noted that in all rainy areas of the tropics weed growth is so prolific that not only is the cleared land quickly covered by large and small weeds, it is also very rapidly taken over by bushes and forest if clearing operations are not constantly maintained. But this precaution again requires so much labor that the minimum expenditure per hectare of land must be extremely large. Thus cultivation on the scale of mid-latitude agriculture is generally not possible in tropical agriculture." These observations by Aereboe also are in need of debate. Both of the tropical farming systems named by Aereboe force in fact a high minimum intensity; yet irrigation farming is even today not the most important farming system in the subtropics, and plantation farming was also at that time not the most widely distributed farming system in the tropics. The conclusion by Aereboe that "cultivation on the scale of mid-latitude agriculture is generally not possible in tropical agriculture" needs the qualification that Aereboe had already expressed two decades earlier: "Tropi-
Outlook
301
cal and subtropical agriculture are from the beginning subject to pressures for a much higher farming intensity than that of the colder zones." Even if Aereboe were to have meant by "rainy areas" only the tropical rainforest zones, his conclusion would hardly hold. His reference to the prolific weed growth and the threat of bush and forest encroachment is of course quite correct. However, the forest in the humid tropics is in several ways not an enemy of crop farming, but its best friend. During the many years of forest fallow, the trees help man to fight the weeds, to provide for concentration of plant nutrients, and to guarantee a free regeneration of soil fertility. Thus even today the forest-burning system of shifting cultivation holds its own in the humid tropics, a system which up to now has been much more important than plantation farming and today is still practiced by more than 200 million people scattered over 30 million km 2 . This system of shifting cultivation must be considered as a thoroughly extensive form of cultivation. In extreme cases, only one year of cropping is followed by eighteen to twenty years of fallow, which makes for extremely small capital expenditures, consisting almost solely of hand tools and approaching zero value. Labor expenditures, then, when related to area, are only about 2.5 MY per 100 ha of usable land, whereas grainfallow farming on the Spanish Meseta requires up to 3 to 4 MY/100 ha AL. Although sheep grazing on the Spanish Meseta uses only 1.5 MY/ 100 ha AL, attendant capital expenditures for livestock, wells, watering installations, and fences, as well as labor aids come to as much or half again as much as that of the monetary labor expenditures. There are certainly even more extensive forms of grassland farming, but the difference from the forest-burning system is less one of amount than orientation of intensity. While the forest-burning system of shifting cultivation in the tropical rainforest zone is more labor-intensive than the most extensive grassland farming, it is also even more capital-extensive and overall must be regarded as a definitely extensive form of cultivation. The thesis of Aereboe on the tropical rainforest zone applies to the perennial crops. With respect to annual crops, however, this can only mean that extensive cropping occurs in forms different from those in the middle latitudes, and not that there is actually none. Quite the opposite is true: cultivation in this climatic zone suffers less from an overly high intensity minimum than from a deficient capacity for intensification. The shifting cultivation system can at the maximum feed only 40 to 50 people per square kilometer, and is the cause of undernourishment in many overpopulated developing countries. Only 20% of the land can be used, since for a maximum of three crop years a minimum of twelve years of forest fallow must follow. How to develop cultivation systems that allow a higher intensity stage but do not destroy soil fertility has been a cardinal problem of tropical agriculture for decades (see p. 136ff).
302
Outlook
Finally, the twelve-stage theory of Aereboe (see p. 297) cannot even be applied to the areas of cool middle latitude, climates without restrictions, though he claimed a much greater general validity for it there. The twelve developmental stages posited by Aereboe are a succession of progressively increasing farming intensities. In actuality, however, farming intensity reaches its culmination point in highly industrialized states and on large farms, and then begins to decline. Aereboe proceeded on the assumption that the purchasing power of agricultural products for capital and labor would continually increase. But in West Germany, since about 1950, the exchange value of agricultural products has increased only for capital goods, whereas it has fallen for wage labor. The result has been a decrease in intensity in farm organization, which has led in part to the elimination of livestock and hoe crops. Aereboe's hypothesis runs to the effect: always organize more intensively and always operate more intensively. In contrast, the guiding purpose of farm development in Central Europe today is: organize extensively — operate intensively, i.e. less intensive farm enterprises, but higher productivity per hectare and per animal. These considerations of the agricultural-gegraophic limits of the Aereboeian evolution theory do not in any way lessen the value of its penetraiting and logically-based insights. They only show its unavoidable limits. An all-embracing and exhaustive genetic model of farming types can never and will never come from one pen. The types of world agriculture are still too many, their zonal structure and spatial differentiation all too diverse.
Bibliography
Abel, W. 1967: Agrarpolitik. 3d ed. Göttingen. Aereboe, F. 1923: Allgemeine landwirtschaftliche Betriebslehre. 6th ed. rev. Berlin. Aereboe, F. 1928: Agrarpolitik. Ein Lehrbuch. Berlin. Agrawal, G.D., and Bansil, P.C. 1969: Economic Theory as Applied to Agriculture. Delhi. Anderson, J.R. 1970: A Geography of Agriculture. Dubuque, Iowa. Anderson, J.R. 1973: A Geography of Agriculture in the United States Southeast. Vol. 2 of Geography of World Agriculture. Ed. by G. Enyedi. Budapest. Andreae, B. 1964: Betriebsformen in der Landwirtschaft. Stuttgart. Andreae, B. 1965: Die Bodenfruchtbarkeit in den Tropen. Nutzbarmachung und Erhaltung. Betriebswirtschaftliche Überlegungen für die Arbeit in Entwicklungsländern. Hamburg and Berlin. Andreae, B. 1966: ,, Weidewirtschaft im südlichen Africa. Standorts- und evolutionstheoretische Studien zur Agrargeographie und Agraröknomie der Tropen und Subtropen. No. 15 of Geographische Zeitschrift, Beihefte Erdkundliches Wissen. Wiesbaden. Andreae, B. 1972: Landwirtschaftliche Betriebsformen in den Tropen. Bodennutzung und Viehhaltung im Spannungsfeld von Tradition und Fortschritt. Hamburg and Berlin. Andreae, B. 1973: Strukturen deutscher Agrarlandschaft. Vol. 199 of Forschungen zur deutschen Landeskunde. Bonn-Bad Godesberg. Andreae, B. 1974: "Diversifizierung und Spezialisierung der Farmwirtschaft im Tropenraum," Berichte über Landwirtschaft, Vol. 52, New Series, pp. 497 ff. Andreae, B. 1974: Die Farmwirtschaft an den agronomischen Trockengrenzen. No. 38 of Geographische Zeitschrift, Beihefte Erdkundliches Wissen. Wiesbaden. Andreae, B. 1976: 'Strukturzonen und Betriebsformen in der europäischen Landwirtschaft," Geographische Rundschau, Vol. 28, No. 5. Andreae, B. 1976: ''Agrarsysteme," Handwörterbuch der Wirtschaftswissenschaft, Vol. 1, pp. 155 ff. Göttingen, Tübingen, and Stuttgart. Andreae, B. 1977: "Farming Regions in the Tropics: Environment, Geographical Comparisons and Socio-Economic Development." W. Krause (ed.) Handbook of Vegetation Science, Vol. 2: Agriculture. The Hague.
304
Bibliography
Atlas der deutschen Agrarlandschaft, 1962—1972. Wiesbaden. Atlas de la France rurale, 1968. Paris. Aubert, H.-J. 1964: "Die Entwicklung der Plantagenwirtschaft Sri Lankas im Rahmen der Agrarwirtschaft nach der Erlangung der Unabhängigkeit." Cologne Dissertation. Auty, R.M. 1976: "Caribbean Sugar Factory Size and Survival," Annals of the Association of American Geographers, Vol. 66, pp. 76 ff. Bachman, L.L., and Christensen, R.P. 1967: "The Economics of Farm Size," In: Southworth, H.M., and Johnston, B.F. (eds.): Agricultural Development and Economic Growth. Ithaca, N.Y. Bähr, J. 1968: Kulturgeographische Wandlungen in der Farmzone Südwestafrikas. No. 40 of Bonner Geographische Abhandlungen. Bonn. Bähr, J. 1970: "Strukturwandel der Farmwirtschaft in Südwestafrika," Zeitschrift für ausländische Landwirtschaft, Vol. 9, pp. 147 ff. Baker, O.E. 1926-1933: "Agricultural Regions of North America," Economic Geography, Vols. 2—9. Ball, A.G., and Heady, Ε.O. (eds.) 1972: Size, Structure, and Future of Farms. Ames, Iowa. Baren, F.A. van 1964: "Fysisch-geographische aspecten van de aride en semiaride gebieden," Tijdschrift von Het Koninglijk Nederlansch Aardrikjkskundig Genootschap Amsterdam, Voi. 81, pp. 182 ff. Bartha, R. 1971: Das Klima der Sahel-Zone. No. 59 of Afrika-Studien, pp. 23 ff. Munich. Bartlett, H.H. 1956: "Fire, Primitive Agriculture, and Grazing in the Tropics." In. Thomas, W.L., Jr. (ed.) 1956: Man's Role in Changing the Face of the Earth, Chicago, pp. 692 ff. Benneh, G. 1972: "Systems of Agriculture in Tropical Africa," Economic Geography, Vol. 48, pp. 244 ff. Bennett, M.K. 1960: A World Map of Food-Crop Climates. Vol. I, No. 3, of Food Research Institute Studies. Stanford, Calif. Beuermann, A. 1967: Fernweidewirtschaft in Südosteuropa. Braunschweig. Beyme, K. von, 1975: Ökonomie und Politik im Sozialismus. Munich and Zürich. Biehl, M. 1973: Die Landwirtschaft in China und Indien. 4th ed. rev. Frankfurt/M. Birch, J.W. 1954: "Observations on the Delimitation of Farming Type Regions, with Special Reference to the Isle of Man," Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, Vol. 20, pp. 141 ff. Birch, J.W. 1963: "Rural Land Use and Location Theory: A Review," Economic Geography, Vol. 39, pp. 273 ff.
Bibliography
305
Blanckenburg, P. von, and Cremer, H.-D. (eds.) 1971): Handbuch der Landwirtschaft und Ernährung in den Entwicklungsländern. Vol. 2. Stuttgart. Blaut, J.M. 1967: "The Ecology of Tropical Farming Systems," Revista Geografica, Vol. 28, pp. 47 ff. Blenk, J. 1971: Die Insel Reichenau. No. 33 of Heidelberger Geographische Arbeiten. Heidelberg. Boesch, H. 1966: Weltwirtschaftsgeographie. Braunschweig. Boesch, H. 1968: Wirtschaftsgeographischer Weltatlas. Munich. Boesch, H. 1968: "The World Land Use Survey," International Yearbook for Cartography 1968, pp. 156 ff. Bonnamour, J. 1973: Géographie rurale — méthodes et perspectives. Paris. Bonuzzi, V. (ed.) 1972: Agricultural Typology and Land Utilisation. Proceedings of the Agricultural Typology Commission of the International Geographical Union. Center of Agricultural Geography and Institute of Agricultural Economy and Policy of the University of Verona. Verona. Borcherdt, C. 1961: "Die Innovation als agrargeographische Regelerscheinung," Arbeiten aus dem Geographischen Institut der Universität des Saarlandes, Vol. VI, pp. 13 ff. Borchert, G. 1967: Die Wirtschaftsräume Angolas. Transportprobleme — Rentabilitätsgrenzen. Special No. of Hamburger Geographische Studien. Hamburg. Borchert, G., Oberbeck, G., and Sandner, G. (eds.) 1971: Wirtschaftsund Kulturräume der außereuropäischen Welt — Festschrift für Albert Kolb. Hamburg. Borchert, G. 1972: Die Wirtschaftsräume der Elfenbeinküste. Vol. 13 of Hamburger Beiträge. Hamburg. Boserup, E. 1965: The Conditions of Agricultural Growth. Chicago. Böttcher, G. 1971: China als kommunistisches Entwicklungsland. Munich and Zürich. Bowman, I. 1931: The Pioneer Fringe. Special Publication No. 13 of the American Geographical Society. New York. Brinkmann, T. 1930: "Entwicklungslinien und Entwicklungsmöglichkeiten der landwirtschaftlichen Erzeugung Argentiniens," Berichte über Landwirtschaft, New Series, Vol. XIII, pp. 569 ff. Brinkmann, T. 1935: Economics of the Farm Business. Trs. and eds. Benedict, E.T., Stippler, H.H., and Benedict, M.R. Berkeley. Britton, D.K., and Hill, B. 1975: Size and Efficiency in Farming. Lexington, Mass., and Westmead, England. Brown, D. 1971: "Agricultural Development in India's Districts," Dissertation. Cambridge, Mass.
306
Bibliography
Brunei, R. 1968: "'Die Bedeutung der Sozialstruktur und der Region für die Agrargeographie," Münchner Studien zur Sozial- und Wirtschaftsgeographie, Vol. 4, pp. 15 ff. Buchanan, R.O. 1959: "Some Reflections on Agricultural Geography," Geography, Vol. 44, pp. 1 ff. Busch, W. 1936: Die Landbauzonen im deutschen Lebensraum. Stuttgart. Cantor, L.M. 1969: A World Geography of Irrigation. London and Edinburgh. Carlin, J. 1956: "Trends in Western Australian Agriculture," Farm Policy, Vol. 5, pp. 86 ff. Chang, J.-H. 1968: "The Agricultural Potential of the Humid Tropics," Geographical Review, Vol. 58, pp. 333 ff. Chang, J.-H. 1968: Climate and Agriculture: An Ecological Survey. Chicago. Chang, J.-H. 1977: "Tropical Agriculture: Crop Diversity and Crop Yields," Economic Geography, Vol. 53, pp. 241 ff. Chao, Κ. 1970: Agricultural Production in Communist China: 1949— 1965. Madison, Wis. Chisholm, M.: 1963: "Tendencies in Agricultural Specialization and Regional Concentration of Industry," The Regional Science Association, Vol. 10, pp. 157 ff. Chisholm, M. 1964: "Problems in the Classification and Use of the Farming Type Region," Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, Vol. 35, pp. 91 ff. Chisholm, M. 1970: Rural Settlement and Land Use. Chicago. Chou, M., et al. (eds.) 1977: World Food Prospects and Agricultural Potential. New York and London. Clark, C., and Haswell, M.R. 1970: The Economics of Subsistence Agriculture. 4th ed. rev. London. Clarke, J.I. 1959: ' Studies of Semi-Nomadism in North Africa,"Economic Geography. Vol. 35, pp. 95 ff. Clarke, J.I. 1959: "Studies of Semi-Nomadism in North Africa," Economic Geography, Vol. 35, pp. 95 ff. Clayton, E.S. 1964: Agrarian Development in Peasant Economies: Some Lessons from Kenya. Oxford. Clout, H.D. 1972: Rural Geography. Oxford and New York. Coppock, J.T. 1964: An Agricultural Atlas of England and Wales. London. Coppock, J.T. 1964: "Crop-Livestock and Enterprise Combinations in England and Wales," Economic Geography, Vol. 40, pp. 65 ff.
Bibliography
307
Coppock, J.T. 1968: "The Geography of Agriculture," Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. XIX, pp. 153 ff. Courtenay, P.P. 1965: Plantation Agriculture. New York and Washington. Crkvencic, J., and Klemencic, V. 1967: "Arbeitsrichtungen and -ergebnisse der Agrargeographie in Jugoslawien," Mitteilungen für Agrargeographie, Vol. 17, pp. 201 ff. Csáki, Ν. 1974: Land Supply and International Specialization in Agriculture. Vol. 3 of Geography of World Agriculture. Ed. by G. Enyedi. Budapest. Dahlke, J. 1973: Der Weizengürtel in Südwestaustralien. Anbau und Siedlung an der Trockengrenze. No. 34 of Geographische Zeitschrift, Beihefte Erdkundliches Wissen. Wiesbaden. Das landwirtschaftliche Betriebsgrößenproblem im Westen und Osten, 1961. Special No. 13 of Agrarwirtschaft. Darby, H.C. 1956: "The Clearing of the Woodland in Europe." In: Thomas, W.L., Jr. (ed.) 1956: Man's Role in Changing the Face of the Earth, Chicago, pp. 183 ff. Datoo, B.A. 1978: "Toward a Reformulation of Boserup's Theory of Agricultural Change," Economic Geography, Vol. 54, pp. 235 ff. Deshler, W.W. 1963: "Cattle in Africa: Distribution, Types, and Problems," Geographical Review, Vol. 53, pp. 52 ff. Duckham, A.N., and Masefield, G.B. 1970: Farming Systems of the World. New York. Dumont, R. 1957: Types of Rural Economy: Studies in World Agriculture. Tr. D. Magnin. New York. Dumont, R. 1964: Sovkhoz, kolkhoz, ou le prolèmatique communisme. Paris. Dumont, R. 1965: Chine surpeuplée: tiers-monde affamé. Paris. Dunn, E.S. 1954: The Location of Agricultural Production. Gainesville, Fla. Dussart, F. (ed.) 1971: L'habitat et les paysages ruraux d'Europe. Vol. 58 of Les congrès et colloques de l'université de Liège. Liège. Edwards, Α., and Rogers, A. 1974: Agricultural Resources. London. Edwards, D., and Rees, A.M.M. 1964: "The Agricultural Economist and Peasant Farming in Tropical Conditions." In: International Explorations of Agricultural Economics. Ames, Iowa. Engelbrecht, T. 1930: Die Landbauzonen der Erde. Supplementary No. 209 of Petermanns Geographische Mitteilungen. Gotha/Leipzig. Enyedi, G. 1967: "The Changing Face of Agriculture in Eastern Europe." Geographical Review, Vol. 57, pp. 358 ff.
308
Bibliography
Enyedi, G. 1968: "Landwirtschaftliche Bodennutzung in Ungarn," Petermanns Geographische Mitteilungen, No. 2, pp. 81 ff. Enyedi, G. (ed.) 1976: Rural Transformation in Hungary. Budapest. Erickson, F.C. 1948: "The Broken Cotton Belt," Economic Geography, Vol. 24, pp. 263 ff. Falkner, F.R. 1939: Beiträge zur Agrargeographie der afrikanischen Trockengebiete. Stuttgart. Faucher, D. 1949: Géographie agraire. Paris. Feder, E. 1973: Agrarstruktur und Unterentwicklung in Lateinamerika. Frankfurt/M. Fels, E. 1967: Der wirtschaftende Mensch als Gestalter der Erde. Vol. 5, 2d ed. rev., of Erde und Weltwirtschaft, ed. by R. Lütgens. Stuttgart. Fochler-Hauke, G. (ed.) 1959: Allgemeine Agrargeographie. Frankfurt/M. Food and Agriculture Organisation of the United Nations 1975: Production Yearbook 1974. Vol. 28. Rome. Found, W.C. 1971: A Theoretical Approach to Rural Land Use Patterns. New York. Franke, G., et al. 1975, 1967: Nutzpflanzen der Tropen und Subtropen. 2 vols. 1st vol. 2d ed. Leipzig. Frenzel, K., et al. 1968: Harms Handbuch der Erdkunde. Vol. VII: Australien, Ozeanien, Polargebiete, Weltmeere. 6th ed. rev. Munich. Fuller, A.M., and Mage, J.A. 1976: Part-Time Farming: Problem or Resource in Rural Development. Proceedings of the First Rural Geography Symposium, University of Guelph, Guelph, Ontario, Canada. Norwich, England. Fussell, G.E. 1965: Farming Technique from Prehistoric to Modern Times. Oxford. Garrison, W.L., and Marble, D.F. 1957: "The Spatial Structure of Agricultural Activities," Annals of the Association of American Geographers, Vol. 47, pp. 137 ff. George, P. 1963: Précis de géographie rurale. Paris. George, P. 1965: Géographie agricole du Monde. Paris. Gerling, W. 1954: Die Plantage. Würzburg. Gilbank, G. 1974: Introduction a la géographie générale de l'agriculture. Paris. Glaser, G. 1967: Der Sonderkulturanbau zu beiden Seiten des nördlichen Oberrheins zwischen Karlsruhe und Worms. No. 18 of Heidelberger Geographische Arbeiten. Heidelberg.
Bibliography
309
Gleave, M.B., and White, H.P. 1969: "Population Density and Agricultural Systems in West Africa." In: Thomas, M.F., and Whittington, G.W. (eds.) 1969: Environment and Land Use in Africa. London. Gnielinski, S. von, 1968: "Zuckerrohranbau in Liberia und seine wirtschaftliche Bedeutung," Zeitschrift für ausländische Landwirtschaft, Vol. 7, pp. 276 ff. Gómez-Ibáñez, D.A. 1977: "Energy, Economics, and the Decline of Transhumance," Geographical Review, Vol. 67, pp. 284 ff. Gourou, P. 1961: The Tropical World: Its Social and Economic Conditions and Its Future Status. Tr. E.D. Laborde. 3d ed. New York. Gourou, P. 1956: "The Quality of Land Use of Tropical Cultivators," In: Thomas, W.L., Jr. (ed.) 1956: Man's Role in Changing the Face of the Earth, Chicago, pp. 335 ff. Gregor, H.F. 1959: "Push to the Desert — The pressure of agriculture on California's arid land illustrates the law of diminishing returns," Science, Vol. 129, pp. 1329 ff. Gregor, H.F. 1962: Environment and Economic Life. Princeton, N.J. Gregor, H.F. 1963: "Industrialized Drylot Dairying: An Overview," Economic Geography, Vol. 39, pp. 299 ff. Gregor, H.F. 1965: "The Changing Plantation," Annals of the Association of American Geographers, Vol. 55, pp. 221 ff. Gregor, H.F. 1970: "The Large Industrialized American Crop Farm — A Mid-Latitude Plantation Variant," Geographical Review, Vol. 60, pp. 151 ff. Gregor, H.F. 1970: Geography of Agriculture: Themes in Research. Englewood Cliffs, N.J. Gregor, H.F. 1974: An Agricultural Typology of California. Vol. 4 of Geography of World Agriculture. Ed. by G. Enyedi. Budapest. Gregor, H.F. 1975: "A Typology of Agriculture in Western United States — In World Perspective." In: Montresor, E., and Pecci, F. (eds.) 1975: Agricultural Typology and Land Utilisation. Proceedings of the Agricultural Typology Commission of the International Geographical Union. Center of Agricultural Geography and Institute of Agricultural Economy and Policy of the University of Verona. Verona. Gregor, H.F. 1976: "Agricultural Intensity in the Pacific Southwest," Proceedings of the Association of American Geographers, Vol. 8, pp. 45 ff. Gregor, H.F. 1979: "The Large Farm as a Stereotype: A Look at the Pacific Southwest," Economic Geography, Vol. 55, pp. 71 ff. Gregory, S. 1969: "Rainfall Reliability." In: Environment and Land Use in Africa. London.
310
Bibliography
Gribaudi, D. 1964: "Geografia agraria." In: Un sessantennio di Ricera Geografica Italiana, pp. 301 ff. Rome. Grigg, D.B. 1966: "The Geography of Farm Size — A Preliminary Survey," Economic Geography, Vol. 42, pp. 204 ff. Grigg, D.B. 1969: "The Agricultural Regions of the World: Review and Reflections," Economic Geography, Vol. 45, pp. 95 ff. Grigg, D.B. 1970: The Harsh Lands. London. Grigg, D.B. 1974: The Agricultural Systems of the World. Groeneveld, S., and Meliczek, H. (eds.) 1978: Rurale Entwicklung zur Überwindung von Massenarmut — Hans Wilbrandt zum 75. Geburtstag. Saarbrücken. Grotewold, A. 1959: "Von Thiinen in Retrospect," Economic Geography, Vol. 35, pp. 346 ff. Hahn, E. 1882: "Die Wirtschaftsformen der Erde," Petermanns Mitteilungen, Vol. 38, pp. 8 ff. Hall, P. (ed.), and Wartenberg, C.M. (tr.) 1966: Von Thiinen's Isolated State. Oxford. Hambloch, H. 1966: Der Höhengrenzsaum der Ökumene. No. 18 of Westfälische Geographische Studien. Münster. Hart, J.F. (ed.) 1972: Regions of the United States. New York. Hart, J.F. 1975: The Look of the Land. Englewood Cliffs, N.J. Harvey, D.W. 1966: "Theoretical Concepts and the Analysis of Agricultural Land Use Pattern in Geography," Annals of the Association of American Geographers, Vol. 56, pp. 361 ff. Hase, H.J. von, 1964: Die Auswirkungen der Dürrejahre in Südwestafrika und ihre Überwindung. Vol. 65 of Der deutsche Tropenlandwirt. Witzenhausen. Haystead, L., and Fite, G.C. 1955: The Agricultural Regions of the United States. Norman, Okla. Heady, Ε.O. 1952: Economics of Agricultural Production and Resource Use. New York. Heady, E.O. 1966: Agricultural Problems and Policies of Developed Countries. Oslo. Herlemann, H.-H. 1954: "Technisierungsstufen der Landwirtschaft," Berichte über Landwirtschaft, New Series, Vol. XXXII, pp. 335 ff. Hewes, L. 1956: "Risk in the Central Great Plains - Geographical Patterns of Wheat Failure in Nebraska, 1931 — 1952," Geographical Review, Vol. 46, pp. 375 ff. Hewes, L. 1958: "Wheat Failure in Western Nebraska, 1931-1954," Annals of the Association of American Geographers, Vol. 48, pp. 375 ff.
Bibliography
311
Higbee, E. 1958: American Agriculture: Geography, Resources, Conservation. New York. Highsmith, R.M. 1965: "Irrigated Lands of the World," Geographical Review, Vol. 55, pp. 328 ff. and Pl. 1. Hodder, B.W. 1968: Economic Development in the Tropics. London. Hoffmann, E., Ewert, H., and Giither, A. 1954: "Die Abgrenzung von Bodennutzungs- und Betriebssystemen," Agrarwirtschaft, Vol. 3, pp. 263 ff. Hofmeister, Β. 1961: "Wesen und Erscheinungsform der Transhumance," Erdkunde, Vol. 2, pp. 121 ff. Hofmeister, B. 1974: "Die quantitative Grundlage einer Weltkarte der Agrartypen." In: Festschrift für Georg Jensch aus Anlaß seines 65. Geburtstages. Berlin. Hohnholz, J. 1975: "Agrargeographische Beobachtungen im Norden Thailands," Naturwissenschaftliche Rundschau, Vol. 28, pp. 311 ff. Hunter, J.M. 1967: "Population Pressure in a Part of the West African Savanna: A Study of Nangodi, Northeast Ghana," Annals of the Association of American Geographers, Vol. 57, pp. 101 ff. Igbozurike, M.U. 1971: "Ecological Balance in Tropical Agriculture," Geographical Review, Vol. 61, pp. 519 ff. Ilesic, S. 1968: "Für eine komplexe Geographie des ländlichen Raumes und der ländlichen Landschaft als Nachfolgerin der reinen 'Agrargeographie,' " MSSW, Vol. 4, pp. 67 ff. Instituto Geografico de Agostini, Novara, and International Association of Agricultural Economists (eds.) 1969—1970: World Atlas of Agriculture. Novara. Jackson, W.A.D. 1956: "Virgin and Idle Lands of Western Siberia and Northern Kazakhstan: A Geographic Appraisal," Geographical Review, Vol. 46, pp. 1 ff. Jäger, F. 1946: Die klimatischen Grenzen des Ackerbaus. Zürich. Jäger, H. 1963: "Zur Geschichte der deutschen Kulturlandschaft," Geographische Zeitschrift, Vol. 2, pp. 90 ff. Jaron, Β., Danfors, E., and Vandie, J. (eds.) 1973: Arid Zone Irrigation. Vol. 5 of Ecological Studies. New York. Jätzold, R. 1970: Die wirtschaftsgeographische Struktur von Siidtanzania. No. 36 of Tübinger Geographische Studien. Tübingen. Jensch, G. 1969: Klima-Globus. Berlin. Jentsch, E.-G. 1965: "Die Struktur der Nahrungsversorgung und der landwirtschaftlichen Produktion Tunesiens in Vergangenheit, Gegenwart und Zukunft." Berlin Dissertation.
312
Bibliography
Joerg, W.L.G. 1932: Pioneer Settlement. Special Publication No. 14 of the American Geographical Society. New York. Johnson, E.A.J. 1970: The Organization of Space in Developing Countries. Cambridge, Mass. Johnston, B.F. and Kilby, P. 1975: Agriculture ά Structural Transformation. New York and London. Juelich, V. 1975: Die Agrarkolonisation im Regenwald des mittleren Rio Huallaga (Peru). No. 63 of Marburger Geographische Schriften. Marburg/L. Jurion, F., and Henry, J. 1969: Can Primitive Farming be Modernised? Kisangani, Zaire. Kayser, B. 1963: Economies et sociétés rurales dans les régions tropicales. Paris. Kellerman, A. 1977: "The Pertinence of the Macro-Thünian Analysis," Economic Geography, pp. 255 ff. Keuning, H.J. 1964: "Agrarische Geografie: Doelstelling, Ontwikkeling, Methoden," Tijdschrift van het koninklijk Nederlandsch Aardrijkskundig Genootschap, Vol. 81, pp. 10 ff. Klages, E. 1949: Ecological Crop Geography, London. Kollmorgen, W.M., and Jenks, G.F. 1958: "Suitcase Farming in Sully County, South Dakota," Annals of the Association of American Geographers, Vol. 48, pp. 27 ff. Kollmorgen, W.M., and Jenks, G.F. 1958: "Sidewalk Farming in Toole County, Montana, and Traill County, North Dakota," Annals of the Association of American Geographers, Vol. 48, pp. 209 ff. Könnecke, G. 1967: Fruchtfolgen, Berlin. Köppen, W. 1923: Die Klimate der Erde. Berlin and Leipzig. Kostrowicki, J. 1970: "Land Use Studies as a Basis of Agricultural Typology of East-Central Europe," Geographia Polonica, Vol. 19, pp. 263 ff. Kostrowicki, J., and Tyszkiewicz, W. (eds.) 1970: Essays on Agricultural Typology and Land Utilization. Vol. 19 of Geographia Polonica. Warsaw. Kostrowicki, J. 1970: Agricultural Typology. Selected Methodological Materials. Warsaw. Kostrowicki, J., and Szczesny, R. 1972: Polish Agriculture. Vol. 1 of Geography of World Agriculture. Ed. by G. Enyedi. Budapest. Kostrowicki, J., and Tyszkiewicz, W. (eds.) 1979: Agricultural Typology — Proceedings of the Eighth Meeting of the Commission on Agricultural Typology, International Geographical Union, Odessa, USSR, 20—26 July 1976. Vol. 40 of Geographia Polonica. Warsaw.
Bibliography
313
Kramer, F.L. 1967: "Eduard Hahn and the End of the 'Three Stages of M a n , ' " Geographical Review, Vol. 57, pp. 73 ff. Krische, P. 1933: Landwirtschaftliche Karten als Unterlagen wirtschaftlicher, wirtschaftsgeographischer und kulturgeschichtlicher Untersuchungen. Berlin. Ländliche Problemgebiete. Beiträge zur Geographie der Agrarwirtschaft in Europa. No. 13 of Bochumer Geographische Arbeiten. Paderborn 1972. Laur, E. 1930: Einführung in die Wirtschaftslehre des Landbaues. 2ed ed. rev. Berlin. Laut, P. 1968: Agricultural Geography. 2 vols. Melbourne and London. Leaman, J.H., and Conkling, E.C. 1975: "Transport Change and Agricultural Specialization," Annals of the Association of American Geographers, Vol. 65, pp. 425 ff. Lebeau, R. 1969: Les grandes types de structures agraires dans le monde. Paris. Leoncarevic, I. 1969: Die landwirtschaftlichen Betriebsgrößen in der Sowjetunion in Statistik und Theorie. Wiesbaden. Leser, H. 1971: Landschaftsökologische Studien im Kalaharirandgebiet um Auob und Nossob (Östl. Südwestafrika). Vol. 3 of Erdwissenschaftliche Forschung. Wiesbaden. Lewis, R.A. 1962: "The Irrigation Potential of Soviet Central Asia," Annals of the Association of American Geographers, Vol. 52, pp. 99 ff. Lohr, L. 1971: Bergbauernwirtschaft im Alpenraum. Graz und Stuttgart. Manshard, W. 1962: "Agrargeographische Entwicklungen in Ghana," Westfälische Geographische Studien, No. 15, pp. 81 ff. Manshard, W. 1962: Beiträge zur Geographie tropischer und subtropischer Entwicklungsländer. Indien—Westafrika—Mexiko. No. 2 of Gießener Geographische Schriften. Gießen. Manshard, W. 1968: Einführung in die Agrargeographie der Tropen. Mannheim. Manshard, W. 1970: Afrika — südlich der Sahara. Vol. 5 of Fischer Länderkunde. Frankfurt/M. Martin, A. 1958: Economics and Agriculture. London. Masefield, G.B. 1948: "The Life of Perennial Crops," East African Agricultural Journal of Kenya. Nairobi. Matzke, O. 1975: "Der Hunger wartet nicht," Der Förderungsdienst, Vol. 23, pp. 362 ff.
314
Bibliography
Mayhew, A. 1970: "Structural Reform and the Future of West German Agriculture," Geographical Review, Vol. 60, pp. 54 ff. McCarty, H.H. 1954: "Agricultural Geography." In: James, P.E., and Jones, C.F. (eds.) 1954: American Geography: Inventory and Prospect, Syracuse, N.Y., pp. 258 ff. McPherson, W.W. (ed.) 1968: Economic Development of Tropical Agriculture. Gainesville, Fla. Montresor, E., and Pecci, F. (eds.) 1975: Agricultural Typology and Land Utilisation. Proceedings of the Agricultural Typology Commission of the International Geographical Union. Center of Agricultural Geography and Institute of Agricultural Economy and Policy, University of Verona. Verona. Morgan, W.B., and Munton, R.J.C. 1971: Agricultural Geography. London. Muller, P.O. 1973: "Trend Surfaces of American Agricultural Patterns: A Macro-Thiinian Analysis," Economic Geography, Vol. 49, pp. 228 ff. Niederstucke, H. 1970: "Bodennutzungsformen in tropischen Höhenlagen," Landwirt im Ausland, Vol. 4, pp. 74 ff. Nye, P.H., and Greenland, D.J. 1960: The Soil under Shifting Cultivation. Commonwealth Bureau of Soils. Technical Communication. No. 51. Bucks. Obst, E. 1965: Allgemeine Wirtschafts- und Verkehrsgeographie. 3d. ed. rev. Berlin. Olsen, K.H. 1963: "Die geographische Bedingtheit agrarischer Wirtschaftsformen," Zeitschrift für ausländische Landwirtschaft, Vol. 2, pp. 1 ff. Otremba, E. 1960: Allgemeine Agror- und Industriegeographie. Vol. 3 of Erde und Weltwirtschaft, ed. by R. Lütgens. 2d ed. rev. Stuttgart. Otremba, E. 1969: Der Wirtschaftsraum — seine geographischen Grundlagen und Probleme. Vol. 1 of Erde und Weltwirtschaft, ed. by R. Lütgens. 2d ed. rev. of Die geographischen Grundlagen und Probleme des Wirtschaftslebens, by R. Lütgens. Stuttgart. Otremba, E. 1976: Die Güterproduktion im Weltwirtschaftsraum. Vols. 2 and 3 of Erde und Weltwirtschaft. 3d ed. rev. Stuttgart. Otremba, E., and Kessler, M. 1965: Die Stellung der Viehwirtschaft im Agrarraum der Erde. No. 10 of Erdkundliches Wissen. Wiesbaden. Paffen, K.H. 1953: Die natürliche Landschaft und ihre räumliche Gliederung (Mittel- und Niederrheinlande). Vol. 68 of Forschungen zur deutschen Landeskunde. Remagen.
Bibliography
315
Papadakis, J. 1966: Climates of the World and their Agricultural Potentialities. Buenos Aires. Peattie, R. 1931: "Height Limits of Mountain Economies: A Preliminary Survey of Contributing Factors," Geographical Review, Vol. 21, pp. 415 ff. Peet, J.R. 1969: "The Spatial Expansion of Commercial Agriculture in the Nineteenth Century: A von Thünen Interpretation," Economic Geography, Vol. 45, pp. 283 ff. Perpillou, A. 1961: L'agriculture dans les régions climatiques du globe. Paris. Perpillou, A. 1965: Géographie rurale. Paris. Pfeifer, G. 1956: "The Quality of Peasant Living in Central Europe." In: Thomas, W.L., Jr. (ed.) 1956: Man's Role in Changing the Face of the Earth, Chicago, pp. 240 ff. Pfeifer, G. (ed.) 1971: Symposium zur Agrargeographie — anläßlich des 80. Geburtstages von Leo Waibel am 22. Februar 1968. No. 36 of Heidelberger Geographische Arbeiten. Heidelberg. Phillips, J. 1959: Agriculture and Ecology in Africa; A Study of Actual and Potential Development South of the Sahara. New York. Phillips, J. 1961: The Development of Agriculture and Forestry in the Tropics: Patterns, Problems, and Promise. New York. Piekenbrock, P. 1958: Vegetation und Pflanzenbau in den Tropen. Deutsche Afrika-Gesellschaft. Series No. 7. Bonn. Pössinger, H. 1968: Landwirtschaftliche Entwicklung in Angola and Moçambigue. No. 31 of Afrika-Studien, ed. by Ifo-Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung. Munich. Prunty, M., Jr. 1951: "Recent Quantitative Changes in the Cotton Regions of the United States," Economic Geography, Vol. 27, pp. 189 ff. Raddatz, E. 1954: "Über den Einfluß der Pflanzenzüchtung auf die Produktivität in der Landwirtschaft," Göttingen Dissertation. Radulescu, N.A., Velcea, J., and Petrescu, N. 1968: Geografìa Agricultura Romaniei. Bucharest. Rakitnikov, A.K., and Mukomel, I.F. 1962: "Agricultural Regionalization," Soviet Geography: Review and Translation, Vol. V, No. 9, pp. 24 ff. Reeds, L.G. 1964: "Agricultural Geography: Progress and Prospects," Canadian Geographer, Vol. 8, pp. 51 ff. Reeds, L.G. (ed.) 1973: Agricultural Typology and Land Use. Proceedings of the Agricultural Typology Commission of the International Geographical Union. Department of Geography, McMaster University, Hamilton, Ontario, Canada. Hamilton.
316
Bibliography
Rikkinen, Κ. 1969: „Agricultural Geography in Transition," Acta Geographica, Vol. 19, pp. 1 ff. Rochlin, P., and Hagemann, E. 1971: Die Kollektivierung der Landwirtschaft in der Sowjetunion und der Volksrepublik China. Deutsches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung. Special No. 88. Berlin. Roubitschek, W. 1964: "Die räumliche Differenzierung der Bodennutzung im Gebiet der DDR," Mitteilungen für Agrargeographie, Vol. 4, pp. 967 ff. Roubitschek, W. 1969: Standortkräfte in der Landwirtschaft der DDR. Gotha/Leipzig. Royen, W. van 1954: The Agricultural Resources of the World. Vol. I of Atlas of the World's Resources, ed. by W. van Royen. New York. Rühl, Α. 1929: Das Standortsproblem in der Landwirtschaftsgeographie (Das Neuland Ostaustralien). No. 6 of Historisch-volkswirtschaftliche Reihe. Berlin. Ruppert, K. 1960: Die Bedeutung des Weinbaues und seiner Nachfolgekulturen für die sozialgeographische Differenzierung der Agrarlandschaft in Bayern. No. 28 of Münchner Geographische Hefte. Ruppert, K. 1968: "Die Almwirtschaft der deutschen Alpen in wirtschaftsgeographischer Sicht," Bayerisches Landwirtschaftliches Jahrbuch, Special No. 1, pp. 38 ff. Ruppert, K. 1972: "'Deagrarisation' in Jugoslawien," WGI-Berichte zur Regionalforschung 9, pp. 38 ff. Munich. Ruppert, K. (ed.) 1973: Agrargeographie. Vol. 171 of Wege der Forschung. Darmstadt. Ruppert, K., and Meienberg, P. 1964: "Das Luftbild als Hilfsmittel agrargeographischer Forschung," Umschau, Vol. 7, pp. 207 ff. Ruthenberg, H. 1965: "Probleme des Überganges vom Wanderfeldbau und semipermanenten Feldbau zum permanenten Trockenfeldbau in Afrika südlich der Sahara," Agrarwirtschaft, Vol. 14, pp. 25 ff. Ruthenberg, H. 1967: "Organisationsformen der Bodennutzung und Viehhaltung in den Tropen und Subtropen." In: Handbuch der Landwirtschaft und Ernährung in Entwicklungsländern, Vol. 1, pp. 122 ff. Stuttgart. Ruthenberg, H. 1971: Farming Systems in the Tropics. Oxford. Ruthenberg, H. 1972: Landwirtschaftliche Entwicklungspolitik. Materialsammlung, No. 20 of Zeitschrift für ausländische Landwirtschaft. Rutter, W. 1963: Die Stellung Australiens im Standortssystem der Weltwirtschaft. Vol. 2 of Weltwirtschaftliche Studien. Göttingen.
Bibliography
317
Sapozhnikova, S.A., and Shashko, S.I. 1960: "Agroclimatic Conditions of the Distribution and Specialization of Agriculture," Soviet Geography: Review and Translation, Vol. 1, No. 9, pp. 20 ff. Sarfalvi, B. 1970: "Regional Differentiation and Geographical Interpretation of the Social Structures of Agrarian Regions," Geographical Papers, Vol. 1, pp. 191 ff. Sauer, C.O. 1952: Agricultural Origins and Dispersals. No. 2 of Bowman Memorial Lectures, American Geographical Society. New York. Schendel, U. 1971: Bericht über eine wasserwirtschaftliche Studien- und Kongreßreise nach Australien, Neuseeland, Hawaii und Kalifornien. Kiel. Schickele, R. 1931: "Untersuchungen über die Formen der Weidewirtschaft in den Trockengebieten der Erde." Berlin Dissertation. Schiffers, H. 1972: Die Sahara und ihre Randgebiete. No. 61 of AfrikaStudien, ed. by Ifo-Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung. Munich. Schiffers, H. 1974: Dürren in Afrika. Vol. 47 of Forschungsberichte der Afrika-Studienstelle. Munich. Schmithüsen, J. 1968: Allgemeine Vegetationsgeographie. Vol. IV of Lehrbuch der allgemeinen Geographie, ed. by E. Obst. 3d ed. rev. Berlin. Schreiber, D. 1973: Entwurf einer Klimaeinteilung für landwirtschaftliche Belange. Vol. 3, Special Series, of Bochumer Geographische Arbeiten. Paderborn. Schröder, K.H. 1953: Weinbau und Siedlung in Württemberg. Vol. 73 of Forschungen zur deutschen Landeskunde. Remagen. Schultz, T.W. 1953: The Economic Organization of Agriculture. New York. Schutt, P. 1972: Weltwirtschaftspflanzen. Berlin and Hamburg. Schweinfurth, U. 1966: Die Teelandschaft im Hochland der Insel Ceylon als Beispiel für den Landschaftswandel. No. 15 of Heidelberger Studien zur Kulturgeographie. Wiesbaden. Seavoy, R.E. 1973: "The Shading Cycle in Shifting Cultivation," Annals of the Association of American Geographers, Vol. 63, pp. 522 ff. Shand, R.T. (ed.) 1969: Agricultural Development in Asia. Berkeley. Shirlaw, G. 1966: An Agricultural Geography of Great Britain. New York. Siedlungs- und agrargeographische Forschungen in Europa und Afrika. No. 3 of Braunschweiger Geographische Studien. Wiesbaden. Skibbe, B. (ed.) 1958: Agrarwirtschaftsatlas der Erde. Gotha. Smith, R.H.T. (ed.) 1972: Spatial Structure and Process in Tropical West Africa. Vol. 48 of Economic Geography. Worcester, Mass.
318
Bibliography
Southworth, H.M., and Johnston, B.F. (eds.) 1967: Agricultural Development and Economic Growth. Ithaca, N.Y. Spencer, J.E. 1966: Shifting Cultivation in Southeastern Asia. Berkeley. Spencer, J.E., and Stewart, N.R. 1973: "The Nature of Agricultural Systems," Annals of the Association of American Geographers, Vol. 63, pp. 529 ff. Spielmann, O. 1969: "Viehwirtschaft in Costa Rica." Hamburg Dissertation. Stamp, L.D. (ed.) 1961: A History of Land Use in Arid Regions. Vol. XVII of Arid Zone Research, UNESCO. Paris. Statistical Office of the United Nations (ed.) 1975: Statistical Yearbook 1974. New York. Statistisches Bundesamt Wiesbaden, Allgemeine Statistik des Auslandes 1972: Länderkurzberichte Tschad 1972. Stuttgart and Mainz. Statistisches Jahrbuch der DDR 1963-1964, 1966, and 1969. Berlin. Statistisches Jahrbuch über Ernährung, Landwirtschaft und Forsten 1975. Hamburg and Berlin. Stokes. C.J. 1968: Transportation and Economic Development in Latin America. New York. Stone, Κ.H. 1967: "Geographie Aspects of Planning for New Rural Setling in the Free World's Northern Lands," In: Cohen, S.B. (ed.): Problems and Trends in American Geography, pp. 221 ff. New York. Stone, K.H. 1979: "Third World Settlement Frontiers: Modest Population Absorbers," GeoJournal, Vol. 2, pp. 193 ff. Stone, K.H. 1979: "World Frontiers of Settlement," GeoJournal, Vol. 3, pp. 539 ff. Stuart, R.C. 1972: The Collective Farm in Soviet Agriculture. Lexington, Mass. Symons, L. 1972: Russian Agriculture: A Geographical Survey. New York. Symons, L. 1979: Agricultural Geography. 2d ed. rev. Boulder, Colo. Tarrant, J.R. 1974: Agricultural Geography. New York. Thiede, G. 1971: Standorte der EWG-Agrarerzeugung. Schwerpunkte und Entwicklungstendenzen. Berlin and Hamburg. Thiede, G. 1975: Europas grüne Zukunft. Düsseldorf and Vienna. Thünen, J.H. von (1826) 1966: Der isolierte Staat in Beziehung auf Landwirtschaft und Nationalökonomie. Hamburg (1826) and Darmstadt. Tosi, J.A., Jr., and Voertman, R.E. 1964: "Some Environmental Factors in the Economic Development of the Tropics," Economic Geography, Vol. 40, pp. 189 ff.
Bibliography
319
Troll, C. 1966: Die räumliche Differenzierung der Entwicklungsländer in ihrer Bedeutung für die Entwicklungshilfe. No. 13 of Erdkundliches Wissen. Wiesbaden. Troll, C. 1968: Die Entwicklungsländer in ihrer kultur- und sozialgeographischen Differenzierung. Bonner Akademische Reden 23. Bonn Troll, C. 1969: "Die Landnutzungskartierung in den Rheinlanden," Erdkunde, Vol. 2, pp. 81 ff. Troll, C. 1970: Argumenta Geographica. Festschrift. Bonn. Troll, C. 1975: "Vergleichende Geographie der Hochgebirge der Erde," Geographische Rundschau, Vol. 27, pp. 195 ff. Tschudi, A.B. 1973: "People's Communes in China," Norsk Geografisk Tidsskrift, Vol. 27, pp. 5 ff. Tsuzuki, T. 1963: "Die Fruchtfolgen des japanischen Ackerbaues," Berichte über Landwirtschaft, New Series, Vol. 41, pp. 833 ff. Udo, R.K. 1965: "Sixty Years of Plantation Agriculture in Southern Nigeria, 1902-1962," Economic Geography, Vol. 41, pp. 356. Uexkull, H.R. von 1969: "Reis in Asien — Probleme und Möglichkeiten einer Produktionssteigerung," Zeitschrift für ausländische Landwirtschaft, Vol. 8, pp. 248 ff. Uhlig, H. 1965: "Die geographischen Grundlagen der Weidewirtschaft in den Trockengebieten der Tropen und Subtropen." In: Weidewirtschaft in Trockengebieten. Vol. 1, Series I, Gießener Beiträge zur Entwicklungsforschung. Stuttgart. Uhlig, H. (ed.) 1967: Basic Material for the Terminology of the Agricultural Landscape. Vol. 1, Types of Field Patterns. Gießen. Uhlig, H. (ed.) 1975: Südostasien — Austral-pazifischer Raum. Vol. 3 of Fischer-Länderkunde. Frankfurt/M. Uhlig, H., Manshard, W., and Gerstenhauer, A. 1962: Beiträge zur Geographie tropischer und subtropischer Entwicklungsländer. Indien — Westafrika — Mexico. Schriften, No. 2 of Gießener Geographische Schriften. Gießen. U.S. Department of Agriculture 1972: Indices of Agricultural Production in Africa and the Near East 1962—71. ERS-Foreign 265. Washington, D.C. U.S. Department of the Interior 1970: The National Atlas of the United States of America. Washington, D.C. Vaijo, U. 1977: Finnish Farming: Typology and Economics, Vol. 6 of Geography of World Agriculture. Ed. by G. Enyedi, Budapest. Visher, S.S. 1955: "Comparative Agricultural Potentials of the World's Regions," Economic Geography, Vol. 31, pp. 82 ff.
320
Bibliography
Waibel, L. 1933: Probleme der Landwirtschaftsgeographie. Breslau. Walter, H. 1964 and 1968: Die Vegetation der Erde in ökophysiologischer Betrachtung. 2 vols. Stuttgart. Walter, H. 1970: Vegetationszonen und Klima. Stuttgart. Walton, K. 1969: The Arid Zones. London. Wang, Y., Nagel, F., and Ruthenberg, H. 1969: Bodennutzung und technischer Fortschritt auf Taiwan. Special No. 7 of Zeitschrift für ausländische Landwirtschaft. Frankfurt/M. Weaver, J.C. 1954: "Changing Patterns of Cropland Use in the Middle West," Economic Geography, Vol. 30, pp. 1 ff. Weaver, J.C. 1954: "Crop-Combination Regions in the Middle West," Geographical Review, Vol. 44, pp. 175 ff. Weaver, J.C. 1954: "Crop-Combination Regions for 1919 and 1929 in the Middle West," Geographical Review, Vol. 44, pp. 560 ff. Weaver, J.C. 1958: "A Design for Research in the Geography of Agriculture," Professional Geographer, Vol. 10, No. 1, pp. 2 ff. Webster, C.C., and Wilson, P.N. 1969: Agriculture in the Tropics. 3d ed. rev. London. Weischet, B.G. 1977: Die ökologische Benachteiligung der Tropen. Stuttgart. Whittlesey, D. 1936: "Major Agricultural Regions of the Earth," Annals of the Association of American Geographers, Vol. 26, pp. 199 ff. Why te, R.O. 1967: Milk Production in Developing Countries. London. Wilhelmy, H. 1970: Beiträge zur Geographie der Tropen und Subtropen. Festschrift. Tübingen. Wilhelmy, H. 1975: Reisanbau und Nahrungsspielraum in Südostasien. • Kiel. Wilkens, P.-J. 1974: Wandlungen der Plantagenwirtschaft. Die Entkolonisierung einer Wirtschaftsform." Hamburg Dissertation. Windhorst, H.-H. 1975: Spezialisierte Agrarwirtschaft in Südoldenburg. Eine agrargeographische Untersuchung. Vol. 2 of Nordwest niedersächsische Regionalforschungen. Leer. Winkler, E. 1963: Agrargeographie der Schweiz. Schweizer Landwirtschaft. Zürich. Wirth, E. 1962: Agrargeographie des Irak. No. 13 of Hamburger Geographische Studien. Hamburg. Wirth, E. 1969: "Das Problem der Nomaden im heutigen Orient," Geographische Rundschau, Vol. 21, pp. 41 ff. Woerman, E. 1943: Landwirtschaftliche Anbausysteme in Europa. Colored map at a scale of 1:5 million. Berlin.
Bibliography
321
Woerman, E. 1944: Europäische Nahrungswirtschaft. Vol. 14, No. 99, New Series, of Nova Acta Leopoldina. Ed. by E. Abderhalden. Halle (Saale). Simplified version of colored map noted above. Wrigley, G. 1971: Tropical Agriculture — The Development of Production. London. Yates, P.L. 1960: Food, Land and Manpower in Western Europe. New York 1960. Zabko-Potopowicz, A. 1957: "The Development of the Geography of Agriculture since World War I," Przeglad Geograficzny, Vol. 29, pp. 21 ff. Zelinsky, W., Kosinski, L.A., and Prothero, R.M. (eds.) 1970: Geography and a Crowding World: A Symposium on Population Pressures upon Physical and Social Resources in the Developing Lands. New York. Zotschew, T. 1957: Die Entwicklungsprobleme der polnischen Wirtschaft. In: Material über die wirtschaftliche Lage und Entwicklung der Volksrepublik Polen. Institut für Weltwirtschaft, Forschungsabteilung. Kiel.
Addendum Andreae, B. 1978: Agrarregionen unter Standortstress. Produktionsverfahren der Bodennutzung in Marginalzonen des Weltagrarraumes. Kiel. Andreae, B. 1978: "Planungsstufen von Kleinfarmen im Generationswechsel — Das Hochland Kenias als Modell," Geographische Rundschau, Vol. 30, pp. 304 ff. Andreae, B. 1978: "The Minimum Cost Combination in Agriculture — with Special Reference to Developing Countries in Tropical Areas," Geo Journal, Vol. 2, pp. 203 ff. Andreae, B. 1979: "Agrarprobleme der Dritten Welt. Irrtum und Wahrheit zwischen Tradition und Fortschritt," Geographische Rundschau, Vol. 31, pp. 390 ff. Andreae, B. 1979: "Cultivation of Sugar Beet and Sugar Cane in the Peshawar Basin of Pakistan." In Institute for Scientific Co-operation (ed.), Plant Research and Development, Vol. 9, pp. 52 ff., Tübingen. Andreae, B. 1980: "Stufen der Wildnutzung in Afrika," Zeitschrift für Jagdwissenschaft, Vol. 26, pp. 84 ff.
322
Bibliography
Andreae, Β. 1980: Weltwirtschaftspflanzen im Wettbewerb. Ökonomischer Spielraum in ökologischen Grenzen. Eine produktbezogene Nutzpflanzengeographie. Berlin and New York. Bonnamour, J., Brunei, P., and Flaires, P. (eds.) 1980: L'Aménagement Rurale. Actes du V e Colloque Franco-Polonais de Géographie, Cerisy-la-Salle, Septembre 1977. Centre de Recherches sur l'Evolution de la Vie Rurale, Université de Caen. Caen. Hayami, Y., Ruttan, V.W., and Southworth, H.M. (eds.) 1979: Agricultural Growth in Japan, Taiwan, Korea, and the Philippines. Honolulu. Husain, M. 1979: Agricultural Geography. Delhi. Koutaniemi, L. (ed.) 1978: Rural Development in Highlands and HighLatitude Zones. Proceedings of the International Geographical Union's Commission on Rural Development. Department of Geography, University of Oulu, Oulu, Finland. Oulu. Rostankowski, P. 1979: Agrarraum und Getreideanbau in der Sowjetunion 1948—1985. Eine agrargeographische Studie. Berlin. Späth, H.-J. 1980: Die agro-ökologische Trockengrenze in den zentralen Great Plains von Nord-Amerika. Vol. 15 of Erdwissenschaftliche Forschung. Wiesbaden.
Figures
Fig. Fig. Fig.
1 2 3
Organization of Farmed Land 18 Cost Concepts 20 Derivation of Measurements of the Efficiency of the Farm Enterprise 22 Fig. 4 Climatic Zones of Africa 34 Fig. 5 Average Annual Precipitation on the Earth 35 Fig. 6 Climatic Zones of the Tropics (Diagram) 38 Fig. 7 Northern Cropping Boundaries in Europe 49 Fig. 8 Distribution of the Principal Useful Plants 51 Fig. 9 Effective Altitudinal Zones of Useful Plants in the Equatorial Belt 54 Fig. 10: Altitudinal Zones of Useful Plants in Java Compared with Natural Vegetation 55 Fig. 11 The Northern Limit of Rainfed Farming in Chad 59 Fig. 12 Agronomic Dry Boundaries in the Republic of South Africa 60 Fig. 13 Agronomic Dry Boundaries in North America 61 Fig. 14 Drought Severity and Land Use in Algeria 62 Fig. 15 The Agronomic Dry Boundary in the Sudan-Sahel Natural Realm 63 Fig. 16: Competitive Shifts among the Production Orientations of Livestock Economies with Increasing Market Distance 73 Fig. 17: Changes in Agricultural Enterprises in the Wet-and-Dry Tropics with Increasing Market Distance 73 Fig. 18 Intensity Qualifications for Two-Man Farms 97 Fig. 19 Tractors on Single-Operator Farms 98 Fig. 20 Technical and Structural Arrangements in Livestock Farming 99 Fig. 21 Interfarm Machinery Use in West German Agriculture, 1971
100 Fig. 22: Price-Cost Relationships at the Farm Gate with Increasing Market Distance 103 Fig. 23: Farming Intensity and Farming Diversity with Changing Market Distance 104 Fig. 24: Development of Purchasing Power of Agricultural Products for Wage Labor 108 Fig. 25: Development of Purchasing Power between Wage Labor and Farm Machinery 109 Fig. 26: Farming Regions of the World (colored map) End Papers Fig. 27: Seasonal Climates of the Tropics and Subtropics 128
324
Figures
Fig. 28: Humid and Arid Months, Vegetation Belts, and Farming Systems in the Tropics and Subtropics 129 Fig. 29 Fanning Systems in the Climatic Zones of the Tropics 131 Fig. 30 Cropping Intensity Levels in World Agricultural Space 133 Fig. 31 Decline in Yields with Prolonged Cropping in the Humid Tropics under the System of Shifting Cultivation 134 Fig. 32: Yield Level of Crops under Shifting Cultivation Depending on the Cropping Interval 136 Fig. 33 Ley Farming in African Wet Savannas 138 Fig. 34 Irrigated Areas in World Agricultural Space 142 Fig. 35 Irrigated Rice Monocultures with Varying Degrees of Land Utilization 145 Fig. 36 Wet Rice Rotations with Varying Degrees of Land Use 146 Fig. 37 Cross-Section of a Village Farm Settlement in Zaire 149 Fig. 38 Comparative Productivity of Tea, Coffee, and Cacao Farms 158 Fig. 39: Seasonal Climates in the Dry Areas of the Earth 161 Fig. 40: Rain Curve for Grootfontein/Southwest Africa, 1899/1900 to 1962/1963 162 Fig. 41: Variations in Annual Rainfall in Africa 165 Fig. 42: Carrying Capacity of Natural Pasture in the Republic of South Africa 168 Stages of Feed Balance in Grassland Farming of Semiarid 43: Fig. Climates 172 Fig. 44 The Effect of Fallowing in the Dry Farming System 176 Fig. 45 Zones of Intensity of the Dry Fanning System 177 Fig. 46 Agricultural Zones of Australia 192 Fig. 47 The Regionalization of World Nutrition 196 Fig. 48 Climatic Areas of Europe 198 Fig. 49 Duration of a Temperature of at least 5° C in Europe 200 Fig. 50 Soil Map of Europe 203 Fig. 51 Land in Permanent Grassland in the European Community 204 Fig. 52 Production Elasticity of Agricultural Regions in the EEC 206 Fig. 53 Crop Rotation Types in the European Community 211 Fig. 54 Agricultural Land Use Systems in the European Community 215 Fig. 55 Livestock Raising Systems in the European Community 223 Fig. 56 Cattle Farming Types in the European Community 225 Fig. 57 Types of Cattle Raising and their Locational Orientation 226 Fig. 58 Labor Intensity in the Agriculture of the European Community 229 Fig. 59: Annual Precipitation in the United States 233 Fig. 60: The Available Growing Season in the United States 234
Figures Fig. 61: Fig. 62 Fig. 63 Fig. 64 Fig. Fig. Fig. Fig.
65 66 67 68
Fig. 69 Fig. 70 Fig. 71 Fig. 72: Fig. 73: Fig. 74: Fig. 75: Fig. 76: Fig. 77: Fig. 78:
325
Distribution of the Principal Soil Types in the United States 235 Farming Zones of the United States 236 The Thiinen Spatial Pattern in Chicago's Hinterland 239 Pastureland per Cattle Unit in the Western States of the U.S. 243 Agricultural Regions in the United States 248 Agricultural Zones in the Baltic Sea-Adriatic Sea Area 257 Regional Zones in the Soviet Union 263 Hydroelectric Power and Irrigation Projects in the Volga-Don Area 265 Agricultural Zones of China 268 Long-Term Trends in Prices and Wages in Germany 272 Factor Costs and Factor Combinations in the Course of National Economic Development 275 Farmland Shares in World Agricultural Space 276 Long-Term Development Trends in Farm Size in the Agricultural Domain 281 Medium- and Long-term Development Alternatives for West European Farms 282 Adaptation Processes of Various Farm Size Classes in an Expanding Agriculture 283 Farm Diversification and Specialization in Economic Growth 290 The Epochal Sequence of Agrarian Land Use Types in the Dry Savannas 294 Genesis of the Crop Rotations of Central England 296
Index Agricultural space: contraction, 83; defined, 30; delimitation, 45 ff., 85 f.; expansion, 45, 82, 86; expansion as a problem, 45 ff.; farming systems, 113 ff., end papers; structural changes, 271 ff. See also Agricultural area Agricultural surpluses, 45, 193 Agricultural system, 113. See also Farming systems Agricultural zones, 105, 127; defined, 30; French, 212; in the Baltic-Adriatic area, 256 ff.; of Australia, 190 ff.; of China, 266 ff.; of the Soviet Union, 260 ff.; of the United States, 236 ff.; of the World, end papers. See also Agricultural regions; Economic formations Agriculture: origins and evolution of, 27 ff.; farming systems of, 113 ff. Agro-Chemical Center (ACC), 23 Agronomic dry boundary, 57, 60 ff.; 77 f., 82 ff., 127, 129, 131, 160 ff., 181 ff., 187, 190 Agrospatial structure, 190 Aircraft, 122 Airplane seeding, 147 f. Alaska, 43, 116 Albania, 253 Agricultural space Agricultural boundaries. See Boundaries Alcohol, 75, 257; acetyl, 195 Agricultural capacity: expansion, 83 ff.; intenAlfalfa, 18 f., 74, 90, 92, 122, 138, 179, sification, 83 ff. 238, 246, 264 Agricultural evolution theory, 27 ff., 299 ff. Algeria, 57, 62 Agricultural geography, 30 ff.; and Aeroboe's Algerian Plateau, 166 evolution theory, 299 ff.; definitions, 30; Alkalinization, 67 objectives and significance, 31; of the dry Allgäu, 202, 217, 235 areas, 160 ff.; of the East Bloc countries, Almonds, 41, 124, 199, 221 250 ff.; of the humid tropics, 127 ff.; Alpine area, 202, 212, 216 f. of the middle latitudes, 196 ff.; of North Alpine farming, 17 America, 232 ff.; of Western Europe, 197 ff.; Alpine farms, 69 work methods, 31 f. Alpine ley farming, 19 Agricultural Industrial Complex (AIC), 23 Alpine pastures, 69, 85 Agricultural land (AL), 1 5 , 4 6 , 8 4 , 146 f., 159, Alpine valleys, 69 178 f., 182 f., 187, 204, 207 f., 210, 253, Alps, 43, 53, 68, 84, 116, 119, 199, 224 255 ff., 260 f., 263, 267, 287, 301. See also Altes Land, 2 2 1 , 2 3 0 Cultivable land; Farmed land Altitudinal boundaries, 36 f., 46, 52 ff., 141 Agricultural Producer's Cooperative (APC), 23, Altitudinal minimum, 55 254, 256 Altitudinal range of cultivation, 55 Agricultural products: price-cost relations Altitudinal zones, 53 ff. between, and inputs, 110f.; price Amazon Basin, 33, 47, 67, 95, 123 relations between, 107 f. See also indiAmazonas, 36 dual products Andes, 36, 39, 43, 53 Agricultural regions, 214 ff.; 232; complex, Angola, 150 227; defined, 30; in the United States, Animal breeding, 170, 224, 226 248; delimitation, 207 ff. See also AgriAnimal cropping systems, 17, 114, 117 ff., cultural zones; Economic formations 212 f., end papers Abaca, 26, 124 Aborigines, 27 Abruzzi, 226 Absolute costs, 107 Absolute prices, 107 Acorn hog-fattening area, 227 Acquisitive economy, 123 Actual agricultural boundaries, 46 f. Adaptation processes, 106ff., 160, 170ff., 283 Afforestation, 135 Africa 46, 57, 66, 78, 95, 139, 141, 193; East, 167, 181; South-West, 189; Southeast, 138; Southern, 122 f.; Southwest 38, 78, 162, 167, 169. 187 ff.; West, 70, 123, 135, 139, 151, 154 African Highlands, East, 118 Agave landscapes, 155 Agrarian-industrial countries, 273, 275 ff. See also Agricultural states; Developing countries Agrarian structure: defined, 30 Agricultural (agrarian) states, 45 f., 103 f., 143, 145, 271ff., 280ff., 290, 294; overpopulated 278, 280. See also Agrarian-industrial countries; Developing countries Agricultural area: defined, 30; 85. See also
Index Animal crops, 201, 285 Apennines, 47, 84 f., 224 Appalachian Highlands, 233 Apples, 244 Appropriative economies, 9, 102, 294 Apricots, 124, 221 Apulia, 40f., 201 Arabia, 57 Arabian Desert, 40 Arabian Peninsula, 163 Arable land. See Cultivable land Arctic coast, 261 Ardennes, 217 Argentina, 57, 74, 176, 275 Arid semideserts, 127 Arid zones, 38 f., 115, 124, 127 f., 160 ff., 190 ff., 235, 263 ff. See also Dry climates Arizona, 115, 235, 243 Arkansas, 147 Ash, 134 Asia, 39, 46, 53, 57, 141; East, l l O f . , 171; Southeast, 122; Southeastern, 95,110, 141 Assam, 69, 135 Aswan Dam, 68 Atlantic coastal area, 201 f., 212, 214, 234 Atlantic Coast: French, 230 Australia, 37, 39 ff., 46, 119, 176, 190 ff., 275 Autarky, 94, 230, 269 Bacteria, 185 Baden, 220 Baden-Wiirtemberg, 213 Bahamas, 46 Bali, 69 Baltic-Adriatic area, 256 f. Baltic Provinces, 43 Baltic Sea coastal area, 67, 77, 202 Balkan Peninsula, 250 Balkans, 43, 72, 259 Bananas, 25, 33, 36 f., 50, 52 f., 58, 72, 74, 125, 150ff., 285 Banat, 227, 258 Bangladesh, 66 Bangkok Plain, 66 Bantu tribes, 167 Bare fallow, 58 Barley, 18, 44, 48f., 52ff., 56, 58, 62, 67, 71, 77, 81, 86, 90, 100, 111, 119, 122, 138, 141, 164, 176 ff., 199, 261, 264, 293, 296; feeding, 227; hog-fattening area, 227; malting, 230 f. Bavaria, 201, 205, 213 Bean pickers, 112 Beans, 122, 138 f., 180f., 245, 262, 285, 296; Bechuana, 138; broad, 90; bush, 36 f., 52, 54 f., 58, 139, 141; Egyptian, 186
327 Bedouins, 171 Beef, 193 f.; animals, 224; prices and production, 107 Beer, 189f. Beet chips, 258 Beet harvester, 77, 288 Beet leaf, 231; silage, 258 Beets, 49, 5 2 f „ 286 Belgium, 84, 110 Benelux countries, 205 Berbers, 166, 171 Biological balance, 27 Biological technological advances, 78 f. Birth control, 278 Black Forest, 216 Black Sea Coast, 40, 250 f. Blue lupine, 177 Bog-burning shifting cultivation, 27, 118 Bohemian Mountains, 258 Börde, 202, 218, 220 Borneo, 140 Botswana, 65 Boundaries: actual, 46 f.; agricultural, 47 f.; agronomic dry, 57, 60 ff., 77 f., 82 ff., 127, 129, 131, 160 ff., 181 ff., 187, 190; altitudinal, 36 f., 46, 52 ff., 141; commercialization, 74 ff.; dry, 38 ff., 46, 57 ff., 86, 129, 131, 160, 169, 174 ff., 300; dry, of human habitation, 127, 129, 131; dry, of livestock farming, 129, 131; ecological, 48 ff.; economic, 46 f., 70 ff.; economic dry, 82; effective, 46 f., 86; expansion beyond, 45; geographic, 84; grazing, 36; humid warm-temperate, 40 ff.; in Europe, 49; industrial, 70; livestock grazing, 191 ff.; northern, in Europe, 199 ff.; of tropics and subtropics, 128, 161; polar, 44, 46, 48 ff., 52, 79, 84, 86, 264; precipitation, 115, 169; productspecific transport, 72 f.; profitability, 46 f., 70 ff., 86; settlment, 46, 70; shifting cultivation, 133; shifts, 76 ff.; slope, 68 f.; social, 84; soil, 46, 67 f., 77; subtropical, 185; technological, 46 f., 86; transport, 47, 70ff.; tropical, 185; wet, 36, 46, 66 f., 86 ; wet, of grassland farming, 131 ; wet, of grazing, 129 Boundary shifts, 76 f. Brabant, 220 Brandenburg, 202; March, 256 Bratislava Lowland, 258 Brazil, 41, 125, 150 f., 182 Brigade, 23 Brittany, 219 Brüssel sprouts, 122 Bucket wheels, 147 f. Bulgaria, 25 3 Bulls, 80
328 Bush and tree crop farming, 82 f., 130 ff., 149ff., 228, 2 9 I f . Bush and tree crop farms, 87, 114, 122 ff., end papers Bush and tree crops, 41, 46, 83, 92, 94, 123 ff., 125, 131, 136f., 163, 199, 201, 205, 214, 216, 2 2 0 f f . , 244, 256, 269, 278; farm management, 149 ff.; principal locations, 152 ff.; regions with predominantly, 149 ff.; See also Perennial crops Bushmen, 27, 122 Butter, 71, 73, 237 Byelorussia, 262 Cacao, 25, 33, 36, 50, 5 2 f f . , 58, 124 ff., 131, 150 f., 153 f., 158, 291; farms, 114, 158 f. Calabria, 114, 201 Calcium, 91 California, 40, 53, 67, 89, 122, 163, 244 f. Caloric yield, 139 f. Calories, 196 Calves, 65, 71; beet leaf for raising, 231; on feed, and types of cattle raising, 226; production of, 169; raising of, 231 Camels, 66, 80, 166 f., 170 Cameroon, 59 Campania, 40 f., 230 Canada, 43, 79, 110, 116, 176, 190, 232, 237, 242 Canneries, 112, 246 Cape Province, 119 Capital, 21, 94, 173, 186, 271 ff., 283, 291, 295, 302; consumptive, in U.S. agriculture, 249; -cost ratios between labor and machinery, 182; expenditures on U.S. wheat farms; 179; favorable prices for, 244; goods, 123, 249, 271 ff., 290, 302; in the U.S. factor combination, 247 ff.; income, 22; inputs, 82 f., 103 ff., 137, 171 ff., 291, 301; intensity, 110, 151, 173 f., 182 f., 249, 271 ff., 286 ff.; investments, 115, 146, 167, 171 ff., 218, 244, 272, 277 ff., 286, 290, 292; lack of, 123; land, 115; poverty of, 266; productivity, 146, 277 ff.; substitution of, for labor, 154; working, in U.S. agriculture, 249; working, on U.S. wheat farms, 179 Capitalism, 254 Caravan zone, 105 Carbohydrates, 224 Carinthia, 214 Carpathians, 4 3 Carrot harvesters, 112 Carrots, 122 Cash crop farms, 182 Cash crops, 152, 190, 284 Cash expenditures, 22. See also Capital
Index Cash wages, 102 Cashmere, 75 Cassava, 25, 125, 132, 134, 141. See also Manioc Castor bean, 25 Castor oil, 25 Catch crops (CC), 286; cash, 17; non-cash, 15, 19, 119, 122; winter, 18 Caucasus, 40 Cattle, 24, 38 f., 42, 74, 8 0 f . , 115, 136, 166 f., 170, 173, 188, 226, 244, 246, 260; dairy, 101, 209 f., 225, 285; drives, 194; fattening, 81, 224, 238 f., 293; -fattening farm, 65, 225 f.; grazing, 60; herding, 163; price of slaughter, 226; raising, 94, 104, 115, 166, 169, 192 ff., 199, 224 ff., 240; slaughter, 107 ff., 226, 230, 285, 293; types of, raising, 226; young, 209 f., 222, 225 f. See also Farming systems; Livestock raising Cattle farming. See Farming sytems; Livestock raising Cattle feeding. See Cattle fattening Cattle finishing. See Cattle fattening Cattle Unit (CU), 101. See also Large livestock unit Cauliflower, 122 Celery, 245 Central African Republic, 59, 184, 186 Central America, 274 Central Asia, 171 Central Europe, 7 7 f . , I l l , 118, 120, 132, 207, 213 f., 216, 228, 302 Central European loess belt, 101, 202 Central German Highlands, 219 Central Schwerin Marsh, 77 Cereals. See Grains Chaco, 57 Chad, 59, 144, 175 Cheese, 71, 73, 237; making, 85 Chemical fertilization, 219, 272. See also Fertilizers, chemical Cherbourg Peninsula, 116 Cherries, 124, 221 Chickpeas. See Garbanzos Chile, 40, 120, 145, 269, 275 China, 24, 41, 43, 69, 107, 143 f., 153, 181, 250 f., 253 f., 266 ff.; agricultural zones, 268; North, 265 Chinarinde 55 Cinchona, 55 Citrus farming, 89 Citrus fruit, 25, 49, 50, 5 2 f f . , 58, 62, 131, 201, 221, 244, 269; raising, 221 Citrus trees, 150 Clearing, 28 f., 117 f., 132 ff. See also Shifting Cultivation Climates, 33 ff., 231, 290 ff.; and tropical farming regions, 127; Arctic, 250;
Index (Continuation Climates) Central European transitional, 198 f.; constantly humid subtropical, 191, 269; constantly wet tropical rainforest, 33 ff., 38, 127 ff., 291 f., 299, 301; continental cool-summer, 43, 237, 250f., 297 f.; continental steppe, 258; continental warmsummer, 43, 238, 250; dry, 34, 37 ff., 53, 250f., 293 ff.; dry savanna, 34, 37, 293 ff.; East European continental, 198 f.; hot, dry summer and warm, wet winter, 198 f., humid cool-temperate, 42 ff., 297 f.; humid savanna, 33 ff., 292 f.; humid warm-temperate, 34, 40 ff., 295 ff.; in Europe, 197 ff.; in the Common Market, 232; marine cool-summer, 34, 42, 295; Mediterranean, 94, 191, 198f., 222, 228, 235, 244, 259; mid-latitude, 190; mild winter, cool summer, 198 f.; rainforest, 33f., 38, 127ff., 29If., 299, 301; seasonal, 127 f., 161; semidesert, 39 f.; shrub savanna, 38 f.; steppe, 34, 39, 191, 293 ff.; Subarctic, 43, 250f.; subtropical, 222; subtropical dry-summer, 34, 40 f.; subtropical warm-summer, 41 f., 250; temperate summer and winter, 197 f.; temperate summer, cold winter, 197 f.; tropical highland, 36 f.; tropical rainy, 33 ff., 291 ff.; very mild winter and warm summer, 198 f.; warm-temperate oceanic, 299; West European oceanic, 198 f.; wetsummer subtropical, 41, 190; winter-rain subtropical, 40, 190, 269 Climatic zones, 33 ff., 290 ff., 300; in Europe, 197 ff.; of Africa, 34; of the tropics, 38 Clover, 18 f., 49, 71, 122, 194, 238, 240, 285; red, 37, 55, 90, 238, 258, 296 f. Cocoa. See Cacao Cocoa Marketing Board, 155 Coconut palms, 25, 33, 50 ff., 58, 124 ff., 126, 131, 150, 153, 155, 269 Coffee, 33, 36 f., 50 ff., 58, 123 ff., 131, 150 ff., 269, 285, 287; farms, 158 f. Collective farms, 24, 252 ff., 260 Collectivization, 254 f., 266 Cologne-Aachen Bay, 202, 220, 230 Colombia, 53, 74, 275 Colorado, 179, 181 Columbia Basin, 77, 119, 179 f., 242 Columbia Plateau, 57 Combine-harvested crops, 100, 180 Combines, 77, 100, 111, 122, 147 f., 260, 288 Commercial steppe grassland farming, 167 ff. See also Farming systems; Grassland farming; Ranching Commercialization: boundaries, 74ff.;of farms, 75; stages, 74 Common Market. See European Economic Community
329 Communes, People's, 266 Competition, terms of, 107 ff., 139 ff., 187 ff., 230 ff. Competitive shifts, 73, 81 Congo, 134 Congo Basin, 33, 36, 47, 67, 95 Continental cool-summer climate, 43, 237, 250 f.; farming changes in, 297 f. Continental warm-summer climate, 43, 228, 250 Cooperative Organization (COO), 23 f. Cooperatives, 23f., 75, 155; Agricultural Producers', 255, 266; wine growers, 124 Coriander, 139 Corn, 18, 25, 33, 36, 49ff., 58, 60, 69, 72, 74, 78f., 91 f., 100, 111, 119, 122, 125, 132, 134, 138 f., 141, 164, 174, 178, 184, 186, 188 f., 213 f., 237, 259, 262 ff., 288, 293, 300; Belt, 43, 236ff.; cropping, 285; U.S., zone 238 ff. Cornwall, 4 2 , 1 1 9 , 2 1 2 Corsica, 220, 227 Cost-production ratio, 81, 182. See also Costs; Input-output ratio; Minimum cost combination; Price-cost relations Cost relation: between agricultural inputs, 109 f. Costa Rica, 37, 53 f., 74 Costs, 88 ff., 231, 242, 286 ff.; digressions of, 125; fixed, 115; joint, 288; of release of labor, 88; opportunity, 97; recovered, 150; structure of, 115; types defined, 20. See also Cost-production ratio; Input-output ratio; Minimum cost combination; Pricecost relations Cottage industry, 75 f. Cotton, 26, 42, 49f., 52, 55, 58 ff., 64, 91, 122, 134, 138 f., 141, 143f„ 176, 186 f., 220, 240, 262, 264, 268f., 287, 293, 300; Belt, 236, 240 f.; -seed, 241; -seed cake, 246; Zone, 241 Cowpeas, 175 Cows, 166, 169, 183, 193, 246, 259; dairy, 209, 222, 224, 238; in calf, and types of cattle raising, 226 Cream, 72 f., 115 Crop atlases, 207 Crop compatibility: defined, 18, 20 Crop failure, 190 Crop ratios, 207 Crop rotation regions, 210 ff. Crop rotations, 42, 90 f., 100 f., 245 f., 258 f., 277, 286, 288, 293, 297; changes, with increasing precipitation, 180 f.; component, 19; cotton, 186; cover, 17; double-crop, 18; extensive, in Pakistan, 164; five-course, 18; field, 18; four-course, 18, 211, 214; in African wet savannas, 138; in altitudinal zones, 56; in China, 269; in dry farming,
330 (Continuation Ciop rotations) 177; in Glaubünden, 50; in hoe crop farming, 122; in irrigated cropping, 138, 144 ff., 164; in Lapland, 48; in New York state, 50; in rainfed cropping, 138 f.; in Siberia, 50; in West German farming, 119; in the Australian wheat farming-sheep grazing system, 194; in the Central European loess strip, 101; in the Corn Belt, 240; in the New England states, 238; in the Soviet Union, 262, 264; intensive, in Pakistan, 164; near the agronomic dry boundary, 64; Norfolk, 19, 211, 213 f., 295 f.; normal, on U.S. wheat farms, 179; of central England, 295 f.; on large farms, 138; on small farms, 138; on two-man farms, 100; peanut-millet, 58; peanutsorghum, 58; peanut-millet-sorghum, 58, 184; period, 19; plan, 19; primary, 19; poorer in leafy crops, 213; pure grain, 78; secondary, 19 f., three-course, 2 1 1 , 2 1 4 , 295 ff.; types of, in the European Community, 211; vegetable, 246; wet rice, 146 Crop weight, 208 ff. Crop years, 18, 135 Crop yields, 139 f.; under shifting cultivation, 136 Cropland: defined, 17 f. Cuba, 125, 150 Cultivable (arable) land (CL), 260; defined, 15; proportion in, 16, 18, 48, 81, 84, 100, 107, 138, 141, 177 ff., 183, 186, 211 f., 239, 258, 261, 263, 270. See also Agricultural land; Farmed land Cultural landscape, 141 Cumberland, 1 1 9 , 2 1 2 Czechoslovakia (CSSR), 253, 258 Dairy Belt, 43, 92, 236 ff. See also Dairy zone Dairy-cattle fattening farms, 225 f. Dairy-cattle raising farms, 225 f. Dairy farming, 20, 58, 104, 213, 222 ff., 226 ff., 256 ff., 265, 273 Dairy-hog farming, 223, 227 Dairy production, 170 Dairy-young cattle farming, 223 f. Dairy zone: in Australia, 194; in the United States, 237 f. See also Dairy Belt Dams, 292 Danuble Basin, 250 Date palms, 25, 51, 59, 62, 67, 150, 163, southern limit, 63 Dates, 124, 244 Deciduous dry forest, 37 Denmark, 46, 107, 109, 204, 227 Densely settled countries, 271 ff., 277 ff., 281, 290 Desert climate, 34. See also Climates
Index Deserts, 191, 260, 263 f.; dry-hot, 127; semi-, 260, 263 f., 300 Developing countries, 27 ff., 45 f., 80 ff., 104 f., 122, 154, 274 ff., 301. See also Agrarian-industrial countries; Agricultural states Development: forces for, 271 ff.; policy, 84, 195 f.; price-cost, 106 ff., 275 ff.; 290; stages (national economic), 79 ff., 171 ff., 196, 290. See also Economic growth; Economic integration Diesel engines, 147 f. Digging stick, 117, 147, 175, 299 Dikes, 270 Dill district, 84 Diluvium, 220 Dinaric Mountains, 259 Dingoes, 194 Diseases, 81, 91, 93, 151, 246, 286 Distillery, 257 Diversification, 21, 88 ff., 154; in the preindustrial era, 286 ff., hindrance of risk to, 187; of farming, 104 ff.; of the production program, 284 ff.; stages in farming, 80 ff., 289 ff., 294 Diversified farms, 87 f., 105 f. See also Manysided farms; Mixed farms Diversity, farming, 93; stages in, 80 f., 284 ff. Divided inheritance, 205 Dole Company, 156 Domesticated animals, 114 Don Steppe, 285 Donkeys, 66, 80, 166 Drainage, 29, 77 Draining: marsh soils, 77 Drinking places, 167, 171 ff. Drought, 62, 160 ff., 187, 226, 242 f., 264, 270 Dry boundaries, 38 ff., 46, 57 ff., 86, 129, 131, 169, 174 ff., 300 Dry climates, 34, 37 ff., 53, 250 f., 293 ff. See also Arid zones Dry farming, 18, 37, 58, 64, 77, 81, 119, 127, 164, 175 ff., 242, 264, 300. See also Grain-fallow farming; Dryland cropping Dry savanna climate, 37 f.; farming changes in, 293 ff. Dryland cropping, 58 ff., 81, 160, 164, 174 ff., 185 ff., 293 ff. See also Dry farming; Grainfallow farming Drylot dairy farms, 246 Drylot farms, 225 f. Dutch, 230 East Bloc, of the, Ecological Ecological Economic
197, 224; agricultural geography 250 ff. boundaries, 48 ff. dispersion, 186, 232 boundaries, 46 f., 70 ff.
Index Economic distance, 47. See also Market distance Economic dry boundaries, 82 Economic formations: defined, 17; growth, 106ff., 2 7 I f f . ; stages, 8 0 f f . , 292; theory, 27 ff., 301 ff. See also Agricultural regions; Agricultural zones Economic growth, 79 ff., 106, 271 ff., 286, 289 ff.; boundary shifts with, 76 ff. See also Development; Economic integration Economic integration, 237, 288 ff. See also Development; Economic growth Economic life, 118, 124, 153, 224; defined, 20; of bush and tree crops, 150; of fodder cropping, 258; of leys, 212; of pineapple, 156 Ecosystem, 68 Ecuador, 275 Educational level, 95 f. Effective boundaries, 46 f., 86 Efficiency: defined, 21 Egg production, 2 3 , 1 1 1 Egypt, 46, 68, 120, 143 ff., 269, 275 Eifel, 221 El Centro area, 246 Elbe Marsh, 114 Electric fence, 112 Embroidery, 75 Emigration, 278 Emilia, 90 Employment opportunities, 178 Ems country, 230 Enclosure farming, 167 ff. Enclosures, 167, 172 ff. Energy: content, 139; sources, 237 England, 77, 90, 110, 205, 216, 224, 231, 295 f. See also Great Britain Ermland, 258 Estanciero, 74 Ethiopia, 39, 123, 125, 141, 149 f., 170, 275 Europe, 46, 106, 110, 116, 118, 124, 174, 196 ff.; agricultural geography of Western, 197 ff.; Central, 43; Eastern, 4 3 , 2 0 2 , 214; Northern, 118, 212, 214; Southeastern, 259; Southern, 213, 216, 228; Western, 197 ff., 237 European Common Market. See European Economic Community European Economic Community (EEC, EC), 15, 42, 94 ff., 197 ff., 230; cattle farming types in the, 225; internal boundaries of the, 230; labor intensity in the, 229; land use systems in the, 215; livestock raising systems in the, 223; market opportunities in the, 231; permanent grassland in the, 204; production elasticity in the, 206; rotation types in the, 211 European farms, 189 f., 282 Exchange value. See Purchasing power
331
Exploitive economies, 27, 294 Export needs, 194 Export policy, 137 Export trade, 137 Exports, 125, 149, 154 Exposure, unfavorable, 69 f. Extensive farms, 104, 284 Extensive grassland farming, 151, 160, 242 ff., 293 ff., 297 ff.; and dryland crop farming, 187 ff.; sedentary, 115; regions, 165 ff. External upgrading, 282 Extra-income farming, 282 Factor combinations, 28, 113, 173, 273; changes in, 273 ff.; differences in the United States, 247 ff.; in densely settled countries, 277 ff.; in sparsely settled countries, 274 ff. See also Minimum cost combination; Production factors Factor costs, 28, 247 ff.; in densely settled countries, 277 ff; in sparsely settled countries, 274 ff. See also Minimum cost combination; Production factors Factory processing, 154 Fallow, 19, 186, 297, 301; bare, 122, 130, 164, 176 f., 181, 184; bastard, 261; bush, 27, 130, 151, 186; forest, 27, 130, 134 f., 139, 291; full, 261 f.; grass, 27, 130, 175, 293; old, 264; pasture, 193; years, 135 Fallowing, 184, 272, 294, 296; bare, 164, 176 ff.; forest, 292; grass, 291 f.; in dry farming, 176; legume, 291 f. Family farms, 21, 146 ff., 224, 288; small-. 114, 207 FAO, 15, 31, 45, 84 Far East, Russian, 265 Farm development forces, 88 ff. Farm family, 152 Farm gate prices, 102, 106, 126, 137 Farm income, 21 f. Farm Machinery Association (FMA), 24 Farm organizations, 102 Farm parcels, 205 Farm-produced inputs: and market distance, 103 ff. Farm production, 22 Farm settlement: in Zaire 149 Farm size, 21, 76, 96 ff., 146, 157 ff., 188 f., 192 ff., 222, 231, 252, 254; and collectivization stages, 266; and precipitation, 179, 183; and production elasticity, 206; and types of cattle raising, 226; classes for tea farms and plantations, 157; classes for West German agriculture, 282 f.; developmental tendencies in, 280 ff.; differences in, and pastureland-cropland ratios, 189; distribution of, in Europe, 205; minimum, 143, 151, 280 ff.; production and, 206; productivity and, 283
332 Farmed land (FL), 15, 18, 97 f., 100, 102, 114, 206, 219, 226, 239, 274, 276 f. See also Agricultural land; Cultivable land Farmers, 27, 252; Central European fruit, 230; collective, 253; European, 189 f.; fodder cropping, 230; hoe cropping, 219; large, 231, 266; medium-scale, 266; native, 189 f.; peasant, 1 4 9 , 1 5 1 , 2 2 2 ; potato, 230; small, 254, 266; suitcase, 242; vegetable, 230; West European, 254; West German, 231; wheat, 194 Fanning systems, 113 ff.; and market distance, 105; annual cropping, 17, 114, 117 ff., 212 f., end papers; bog-burning shifting cultivation, 27, 118; bush and tree crop, 82 f., 130ff., 149 ff., 228, 291 f., end papers; cattle, 24, 38 f., 42, 72 ff., 80 f., 115, 136, 166 f., 170, 173, 188, 193, 226, 244, 246, 260; changes in, 290 ff.; commercial steppe grassland, 167 ff.; com, 285; dairy, 20, 58, 104, 213, 2 2 2 f f . , 226 ff., 256 ff., 265, 273; dairy-hog, 223, 227; dairy-young cattle, 223f.; determining, 210, 227, 2 5 6 f . ; dry, 18, 37, 58, 64, 77, 81, 119, 127, 164, 175 ff., 242, 264, 300; dryland, 58 ff., 81, 160, 164, 174 ff., 185 ff., 293 ff.; enclosure, 167 ff.; evolution of, 199 ff.; extensive grassland, 115, 151, 160, 164 ff., 171 ff., 187 ff., 242 ff., 293 ff., 297 ff.; extensive livestock, 7 2 f . ; extra-income, 282; fenced-range, 167 ff.; fodder crop, 18, 43 f., 68, 71, 81, 91 f., 116 ff., 169, 172, 174, 199, 201 f., 204, 207, 209 f., 214 ff., 232, 237, 240, 256 ff., 293 ff.; fodder crop-grain crop, 215 f.; fodder crop-hoe crop, 215 f.; fodder crop-livestock, 219; fodder crop-specialty crop, 215 f.; forest-burning shifting cultivation, 27, 118, 125, 130, 132, 134 f., 291, 301; fruit, 221, 244; fruit, truck, and mixed, 236, 244 ff.; full-time, 282; grain, 60, 7 2 f . , 92, 104, 111, 119f., 190, 197, 199, 207, 209 f., 213 f., 218 ff., 256, 258, 285, 298 f., end papers; grain-fallow, 15, 76 f., 110, 114 f., 178, 180, 184 f., 242, 293 ff., 301; grass-clover, 18; grassland, 40, 44, 58, 60 ff., 65, 80 f., 83, 86, 110, 114 ff., 127, 130, 151, 160, 164 ff., 171 ff., 187 ff., 217 f., 2 4 2 f f . , 293 ff., 297 ff., end papers; grassland (grazing), 114 ff., 131, 188, 301 \ Hauberg shifting cultivation, 19, 118; hoe (root) crop, 86, 91, 104, 107, 120 ff., 189, 197, 199, 207, 209 f., 214 ff., 228, 256 ff., 273, 291 ff., end papers; hoe crop-grain crop, 215 f., 219; improved three-field, 297; in European agriculture, 197 ff., 207; in the dry areas, 160 ff.; in the humid tropics, 127 ff.; in the middle latitudes, 196 ff.;
Index integrated, 81; irrigated fodder crop, 174; irrigation, 29, 38, 41, 60, 68, 82 f., 93, 102, 125, 127, 129 f., 132, 141 ff., 149, 151, 163 f., 300; Kunstegart, 19, 68 f.; labor-intensive, 231; latifundia, 206; ley, 18 f., 44, 48, 56, 92, 118 f., 138 f., 141, 211 ff., 261, 291, 295 ff., end papers; livestock, 33, 36 f., 40, 42, 58, 71, 75, 78, 92, 94, 110, 115 f., 119, 123, 129, 131, 179, 190, 217, 2 4 6 f . , 273, 285, 297; market garden, 297; maritime fodder, 116; millet-sorghum-peanut, 181 ff.; mixed, 21, 139, 152, 236, 240, 244, 273, 285; molapo, 65 f.; monocultural, 1 9 , 2 1 , 5 6 , 91, 125, 145, 151, 154, 169, 181, 184, 217, 221, 240, 242, 245, 285, 289 f.; montane fodder, 116; Naturegart, 19, 50, 68 f.; nomadic, 66, 75, 80, 114, 166 ff., 171 f., 291, 294 f.; of the Corn Belt, 238; one-field, 297; open-range steppe grassland, 167 ff.; part-time 282; peasant, 56, 15 5 f. ; perennial-cropping, 114, 117 ff., 122 ff., end papers; plantation, 17, 55, 87, 95, 102, 105, 122 ff., 153, 289, end papers; plow, 27 ff., 77, 86, 135, 294; polar fodder, 116; primitive rotation, 117 f.; principal, in world agriculture, 113 ff.; pure dairy, 222 ff.; pure grassland, 217 f.; rainfed, 37, 40, 57, 59 f., 83, 129 ff., 137 ff., 143, 151, 160, 292, 295; ranching, 64, 77 f., 80 f., 115 ff., 167 ff., 129, 167 ff., 182 ff., 236, 293 ff., end papers; rice, 145 ff., 278; savanna grassland, 166 ff.; savanna shifting cultivation, 174 f., 293 ff.; sedentary extensive grassland, 115, 167 ff., 243 f.; sedentary grassland, 167 ff.; sedentary intensive grassland, 115 ff. ; sequence of, 291 ff.; sheep, 5 8 , 6 0 , 6 2 , 115, 191 f., 194, 226; sheep, goat, and dairy, 223 f., 226; sheep, goat, and young cattle, 223, 227; shifting cultivation, 27 f., 37, 58, 80 f., 95, 117 f., 125, 129 ff., 140, 174ff., 285, 291, 2 9 3 f f . ; special-crop and general, 236; specialized, 21; specialty crop, 215 f., 221; specialty crop-hoe crop, 215 f., 222; steppe shifting cultivation, 27, 58, 80 f., 117 f., 174 ff.; subsistence, 187; sugar beet, 77, 100, 1 1 0 f „ 258; tea monoculture, 56; terrace, 55, 68; three-field, 20, 120, 296 ff.; three-field and fallow, 297; tobacco, 236, 240; traditional, 231; tropical, 131 ff.; 300 f.; two-field, 297; vegetable, 245 f.; wet-rice, 299; wheatfallow, 182, 190, 193; wheat-sheep, 192 194; wild steppe grassland, 167 ff.; young cattle-dairy, 223 Farms, 17, 87 ff., 289; and force groups, 87 f., 105 f.; bush and tree crop, 87, 114, 122 ff., end papers; cacao, 114, 158 f.; cash crop,
Index (Continuation Faims) 182; cattle fattening-dairy, 225 f.; cattle raising-fattening, 226; coffee, 158 f.; collective, 252 ff., 260; dairy-cattle fattening, 225 f.; dairy-cattle raising, 225 f.; diversified, 87 f., 105 f.; drylot, 225 f.; drylot dairy, 246; European, 189 f.; 282; expansion of, 178, 280 ff.; extensive, 104, 284; family, 21, 146 ff., 224, 288; feeder stock, 169; fodder cropping, 214ff., 220 f., 232; forces determining organizational structure, 88 ff., 105 f., 189f., 191 ff., 252; four-tractor, 98; full-time, 282 f.; fully commercialized, 21, 75; German, 94 f.; grain cropping, 218, 221; hoe-cropping, 220, 222; horticultural, 245; in Congress Poland, 255; income on, 21ff., 97, 182 f.; industrialized livestock, 247; industrialized poultry, 247; Kikuyu, 285 285 f.; labor-intensive, 104; land-poor family, 21, 220, 283; land-poor intensive, 282; land-rich extensive, 282; land-rich family, 21, 218, 283; large, 21, 75, 89, 112, 124, 151, 218ff., 252ff., 256, 283, 302; large family, 21; large scale wagelabor, 21, 220, 224, 283; little commercialized, 75; livestock raising, 116; location of, and supply and demand, 28, 70ff., 102 ff., 190 ff., 238f., 295; location of, for transport, 102 ff.; many sided, 104 ff., 284; marginal, 77; maritime fodder cropping, 116; mechanized, 281; mixed, 221, 240, 284, 289; monocultural, 89, 104 ff., 117, 151, 217, 240, 244, 284 ff., 289; one-crop, 244; one-sided, 104 ff., 284 f., 289; one-tractor, 98; Ovambo, 190; parttime, 226, 282f.; peasant, 75, 124,153ff., 253, 256, 266; pioneer, 47, 77; pure cattlefattening, 224ff.; pure crop, 187; pure grassland, 93, 217f.; self-supplying cattle fattening, 169; self-supplying dairy, 225 f.; semi-drylot, 225 f.; sheep, 114; singleoperator, 98; single-product, 284; size, 96 ff.; small, 97 ff., 285; small family, 114, 207; socialist, large, 251, 254, 257, 260; spatial differentiation of, 94 ff.; specialized, 104, 221, 240, 246, 284, 289; specialty crop, 220; state, 24, 252 ff., 260; strongly commercialized, 21, 75; subsistence, 21, 182, 280; summer feeding, 116; tea, 157 ff.; temporal changes in, 106 ff.; three-crop, 244; three-tractor, 98; two-crop, 244; two-man, 97, 100; two-tractor, 98; wage-labor family, 21, 218 f., 283; weakly commercialized, 21; wheat, 179, 242; wheat-fallow, 178, 180 Fats, 224 Federal Republic of Germany (FRG). See Germany, West
333 Feed, 39, 101, 181, 249, 259, 293, 295; balance, 92, 114ff., 151, 169ff., 224, 259, 286, 292, 295; concentrates, 21, 92, 110, 170, 174, 272; corps, 221; purchase?, 116; purchasing, 160, 170 ff., 295; reserves, 172 ff.; shortages, 170,188, 217; supplies, 116; surplus, 224 Feeder stock, 66, 72 f., 101, 107, 167, 169, 183, 224, 226, 243, 246; farms, 169, Feedlots, 246 Feeds, 111 Fehmarn Island, 119,218 Fenced-range farming, 167 ff. See also Farming systems; Grassland farming; Ranching Fences, 172, 301 Fertilization, 29, 91, 101 f., 147, 162, 189. See also Manuring Fertilizer: balance, 91 f., 221; expenditures, 157; spreaders, 277 Fertilizers, 16, 111, 148, 204, 249, 277, 292; chemical, 21, 91, 109f., 135, 152, 174, 251, 267, 286, 288; organic, 92, 124, 221 ff., 286 Fields: rational distribution, 219 Figs, 25, 221 Finland, 79, 84, 275 Fish, 122 Fishermen, 299 Fishing, 27, 123, 291, 294, end papers Fixed costs, 288 Flanders, 202, 220 Flax, 75, 179, 262 f. Flood control projects, 270 Flooding, 82 Floods, 68, 270 Florida, 235 Flowers, 245 Fodder crop-grain crop farming, 215 f. Fodder crop-hoe crop farming, 215 f. Fodder crop-livestock farming, 219 Fodder crop-specialty crop farming, 215 f. Fodder cropping, 18, 43 f., 68, 71, 81, 91 f., 116 ff., 169, 172, 174, 199, 201 f., 204, 207, 209 f., 214 ff., 232, 237, 240, 256 ff., 293 ff.; farms, 214 ff., 220 f., 232 Fodder crops, 118, 122, 143 f., 145, 179 f., 222, 261, 293, 297; manure-producing, 221
Food, 259, 289, 297; demands, 45; habits, 190; processing, 59; production, 45 ff.; production capacity, 143; surpluses, 45 Forage, 92; crops, 19, 42. See also Feed Force groups: and farm organization, 87 f., 105 f. Forest-burning shifting cultivation, 27, 118, 125, 130, 132, 134 f., 291, 301 France, 84, 95, 199, 203, 205, 212, 216, 224, 230 f. Franconia, 219
334 Free trade, 95 French Central Plateau, 212, 216 f. Fruit, 25, 95, 122, 199, 230f., 245, 256, 294; growing, 221, 244; trees, 220 Fula, 171, 167 Full-time farming, 282 Full-time farms, 282 f. Galicia, 258 Gambia, 135 Game, 122 Ganges, 29 Garbanzos, 122, 180, 185, 293 Garden culture, 291 Gardens, 266 Garonne, 220 Gascony, 224 Gatherers, 40, 299 Gathering, 27, 40, 122 f., 291, 294 Geest, 202, 230 General farming. See Mixed farming Geographic boundaries, 84. See also Boundaries German agriculture, 231. See also Germany German Democratic Republic (GDR). See Germany, East German farms, 94 f. German marsh belt, 217 Germany, 84, 95, 107, 109f., I l l , 114, 176, 207, 271 ff.; East, 15, 23, 253 ff.; West, 15, 24, 46 f., 69, 84, 107 ff., I l l f., 145, 205, 213, 216, 224, 227, 230 f., 258, 267, 275, 302 Ghana, 114, 125, 149, 155, 275 Goats, 66, 80, 166, 170, 209, 226, 259, 285 Gobabis District, 188 Göta Plain, 50, 199 Grain: feeding, 227; landscapes, 259 Grain-corn zone. See Corn Belt Grain-cropping farms, 218, 221 Grain-fallow farming, 15, 7 6 f . , 110, 114 f., 178, 180, 184 f., 242, 293 ff., 301. See also Dry farming; Dryland farming; Grain farming Grain farming, 60, 7 2 f . , 81, 92, 104, 111, 119 f., 190, 197, 199, 207, 209 f., 213 f., 218 ff., 256, 258, 285, 298ff., end papers. See also Grain-fallow farming Grain Unit (GU), 15 Grains, 16, 18, 25, 42 f., 50, 59, 69, 107, 117, 120, 122, 139, 144, 147, 176, 178 ff., 186, 212, 218, 220f., 239, 241, 258, 262 ff., 267, 288, 293, 297 Grape farms, 114 Grapes, 41, 49, 52, 62, 222, 244, 256 Grapevines, 202, 220 f. Grass, 19, 71, 139, 171, 238, 240 f., 258; -clover farming, 18; cultivated, 138; guinea, 74; natural, 238, 264; renge, 42,
Index 144 f.; seeds, 18, 119; Sudan, 122; years, 19 Grassland, 19, 83, 255; farmers, 174; -farmland ratio, 2 0 2 f f . , 213; (grazing) systems, 114 ff., 131, 188, 301; marsh, 110; permanent, 18, 44 f., 48, 77, 84, 202 ff., 214, 240, 258, 261, 263, 267, 297; permanent, and types of cattle raising, 226; permanent, in the European Community, 203; pure, farmers, 93; rotation, 50 Grassland farming, 40, 44, 58, 60 ff., 65, 83, 86, 130, 217 f., 293, 295, end papers; extensive, 80, 83, 89, 110, 115, 127, 151, 127, 151, 160, 164 ff., 171 ff., 187 ff., 2 4 2 f f . , 293 ff., 297 ff.; sedentary extensive, 115; sedentary intensive, 115 ff.; semi-intensive, 81 Graubünden, 50 Grazing boundaries, 36 Grazing systems. See Grassland (grazing) farming systems Great Britain, 116, 119, 199, 202 f., 205, 212, 214, 217, 275. See also England Great Lakes area, 235, 237, 244 Greenhouse crops, 245 Grootfontein District, 188 Gross income: defined, 22 f. Gross return: defined, 21 Groundnuts. See Peanuts Groundwater, 217, 292, 295 Growing season, 212; and land use intensity, 122; and the polar boundaries, 48; available, in the United States, 234; for tropical field crops, 139; length of, and land use systems, 216; length of, and rice monocultures, 145; length of, and wet rice rotations, 145; short, 261; short, and adaption to aridity, 164 Growth cycles, 151 Guatemala, 134 f. Guinea Coast, 33 Gulf Coast (U.S.), 2 3 5 , 2 4 4 Gum arabic, 25, 123 Gum plants, 25 Gur, 164 Guyana, 120, 145 Hacendados, 74 Haciendas, 74 Hand processing, 156 Handicraft industries, 84 Hanover, 287; North, 220 Harvest: failure, 160; fluctuations, 143; processing, 124, 155; risk, 77, 152, 289 Harvesting: mechanized, 110; problems, 77, 151, 154; technology, 57, 77, 147 f., 242 Hauberg shifting cultivation, 19, 118 Hawaii, 155
Index Hay, 81, 92, 170, 174, 218, 220, 293; baler, 100; bean, 138; chopper, 100; mowing wild, 172 Heifers, 183; price of, and types of cattle raising, 226 Hemp, 26, 185 f. Herbicides, 77f., l l l f . , 122, 288 Herreros, 78, 167 Herzegovina, 259 Hesse, 201, 213, 219 Hessian loess zone, 218 Hides, 72 f. Highland exodus, 47 Hildesheim-Brunswick Börde, 220 Himalayas, 36, 53 Hoe, 28 f. Hoe crop-grain crop farming, 215 f., 219 Hoe cropping, 86, 91, 104, 107, 120 ff., 189, 197, 199, 207, 209 f., 214 ff., 228, 256 ff., 273, 291 ff. Hoe cropping farms, 220, 222 Hoe crops, 18, 19, 100, 108, 122, 146, 220, 222, 262, 297, 302. See also Root crops Hoe culture, 27, 28, 291, 299 Hoe farmers, 96 Hoe (root) crop farming, 86, 91, 104, 107, 114, 120 ff., 189, 197, 199, 207, 209 f., 214 ff., 228, 256 ff., 273, 291 ff., end papers Hoes, 117, 143, 147 f., 175, 299 Hog fattening, 23, 239, 256 Hog finishing. See Hog fattening Hog raising, 89, 227, 240 Hogs, 24, 108, 188, 209 f., 238. See also Swine Hohe Venn, 217 Holland, 95, 109 f., 230 Home processing, 154 Honan, 268 Honduras, British, 134 Honey, 123 Hopeh, 268 Hops, 124 Hopyards, 252 Hormone weed killers, 91 Horses, 166 f., 288 Horticultural farms, 245 " H u b " crop, 185 Humid cool-temperate climates, 42 ff., 297 f. Humid savanna climate, 33 ff.; farming changes in, 212 f. Humid temperate climates: and attitudinal crop boundaries, 53 Humid tropics: agricultural geography of, 127 ff. Humid warm-temperate boundaries, 40 ff. Humid warm-temperate climates, 34, 40 ff. Humus, 221, 245, 293; losses, 137; production, 91 f.; root, 205
335 Hungary, 227, 253 Hunger, 45 Hunsriick, 221 Hunters, 40, 299 Hunting, 27, 40, 80, 123, 291, 294, end papers Hybrids, 111 Hydroelectric power, 195, 265, 270 HYVs, 79 Iberian Peninsula, 227 Idaho, 242 Ile-de-France, 259 Illinois, 237, 239 Improved three-field farming, 297 Income: expectations, 74, 273; farm, 21 f.; gross, 21 f.; gross, on U.S. wheat farms, 179; levels, 81, 84 f.; mass, 174; maximization, 41, 249 India, 37, 41, 68, 125, 139, 145, 150, 154, 181 f., 267, 278 Indochinese areas, 251 Indonesia, 33, 125, 149 Indus, 28, 163 Industrial-agrarian countries, 273, 275, 277 Industrial boundaries, 70 Industrial countries, 46, 68, 85, 104, 116, 145, 157, 170, 254, 273, 275, 277 f., 293, 302 Industrial processing, 154 Industrial zone, 105, 249 Industrialization, 81, 205, 271, 273, 275 ff., 288 ff., lack of, 266; policy, 137 Industrialized animal production, 246 f. Industrialized livestock farms, 247 Industrialized poultry farms, 247 Industrially-produced inputs: and market distance, 103 ff. Infrastructure policy, 137 Inheritance customs, 205 Input-output ratio, 95, 134, 273, 284, 286. See also Cost-production ratio; Costs; Minimum cost combination; Price-cost relations Insecticides, 111, 122, 148, 152 Integrated farming systems, 81 Intensification, 84, 287, 2 9 0 f f . , 301; and agricultural capacity, 83 ff.; of crop rotations, 296; of cultivation, 137; of yield, 85 Intensity: agricultural, 111, 289; capital, 110, 151, 173 f., 182 f., 249, 271 ff., 286 ff.; cropping, in China, 268; cropping, in world agricultural space, 133; farming, 20, 272, 302; farming, and market distance, 103; high labor, 2 0 5 , 2 7 8 , 295; labor, 97, 101, 109 f., 182 f., 205, 222, 229 f., 249, 254 f., 271, 277 ff., 288, 290; labor, in agricultural development,
336 (Continuation Intensity) 271 ff., 286 ff.; labor, in land use, 228; minimum, 300; of fertilization, 101; of specialization, 20, 101 f.; operational, 20, 45, 104; organizational, 20, 45, 104, 222; orientation of, 301; production, 19, 247 ff.; rings in European agriculture, 205; specialization, 20, 101 f., 272 f.; stages and economic growth, 290 f.; zones of, in the dry farming system, 177 Intermountain states (U.S.), 300 Internal upgrading, 282 Ionian Sea coast, 40 Irak, 163 Iran, 40, 57, 119, 176, 275 Ireland, 224 Iron, 272 Irrigated fodder crop farming, 174. See also Irrigation farming Irrigation, 148, 163, 195, 201, 245, 262, 264, 266, 270, 272; farm management functions and, 143; farming, 29, 38, 41, 60, 68, 82f., 93, 102, 125, 127, 129 f., 132, 141 ff., 149, 151, 163, 300; ley farming based on, 213; methods compared, 143 f.; projects, 264 f., 270; sprinkler, 96, 112, 292. See also Water Israel, 65 Italy, 41, 84, 95 f., 119 f., 199, 204 f., 213 f., 216, 220 f., 230 Ivory, 84
Jackals 194 Japan, 41, 43, 69, 120, 143, 146, 153 Java, 53, 69, 95, 125, 135, 148f., 150, 154, 278 Joint costs, 288. See also Costs Jugoslavia, 214, 253 Jura, French, 217 Jute, 26, 51, 75, 164 Jutland, 117, 202, 212
Kalahari, 38 Kale, 122 Kalenberg country, 218 Kansas, 57, 114, 119, 179 ff., 242 Kapok, 26, 52, 55 Karakul fleece, 72 Karroo, 300 Kazakhstan, 40, 57, 252, 264 Kenaf, 58, 75, 185 f. Kentucky, 240 Kenya, 53, 57, 64, 141, 150f., 167, 182ff., 275, 285; Highlands, 138, 141 Kikuyu country, 287 Kikuyu farms, 285 f. Kilo starch unit (kStU), 15, 101
Index Kirghiz, 166 Klagenfurt Basin, 214 "Know-how," 230 Kolkhoz, 24, 252 ff., 260 Kombinat for Industrial Fattening (KIF), 24 Korea, 43; North, 253 Kuban area, 262, 264 Kunstegart farming, 19, 68 f. Kurds, 171 Labor, 21, 94, 146, 154, 170, 173, 186, 224, 258, 260, 272 ff., 283, 290 f., 300, 302; abundant, 97; capacity of the farm, 222; composition, 21; cost ratios between, and machine capital, 182; costs, 89 f., 286 ff.; demand and types of cattle raising, 226; demands, 167, 221; division of, 104, 126, 136, 169; economics and farmsize, 283; expenditures, 124, 147 ff., 151 f., 178 ff., 301; expenditures per hectare, 256; family, 221 f.; Filipino migrant, 245; gross productivity of, 23; hand, 89, 184, 273; hired, 22; in European agriculture, 205 ff.; in Southeastern Asia, 122; in the Southern states (U.S.), 248 f., in the U.S. factor combination, 247 ff.; income, 22 f., inputs, 137, 139, 244; intensity, 97, 101, 109 f., 182 f., 205, 222, 229 f., 249, 254 f., 271, 277 ff., 288, 290; -intensive farming, 231; mechanized, 89, 96 ff.; Mexican migrant, 245; migratory, 89; net productivity of, 23, 115; peaks, 112, 151f., 154, 184, 190, 221 f., 240, 244; productivity, 21, 29, 84, 111, 115, 124, 135, 145 ff., 158, 181 ff., 186, 193, 277 ff., 291; saved, 77; seasonal, 89; spacing, 88 ff., 114, 151, 184, 219, 221, 244, 284, 288; wage, costs, 220 Lake Chad area, 167 Lake Constance area, 221 Lambs, 39 Land, 21, 146, 173, 244, 283, 290, 294; and irrigated rice, 141; capital, 115; cheaper, 231; costs of, use, 286; cultivable, 260; cultivated, 178; determination of, use systems, 208; gross, productivity, 23; in the U.S. factor combination, 247 ff.; labor intensity in, use, 228; net, productivity, 23; ownership, 266; permanent and constant, use, 143; -poor intensive farms, 282; -poor family farms, 21, 220, 283; preparation, 147; prices, 174, 248 f., 27Iff.;productivity, 21 ff., 112, 115, 124, 134, 136, 143, 158, 182 f., 278 ff., 292 ff.; reserves, 171; -rich extensive farms, 282; -rich family farms, 21, 218, 283; rising, values, 287; surplus, 247 f.; use, 273, 288; use cycles, 150; use intensity and growing season length, 122; use intensity
Index (Continuation Land) and water supplies, 122; use intensity in iiiigation farming, 144; use regions, 214 ff.; use systems and cartographic representation, 207; use types in dry savannas, 294 Languedoc, 220 La Plata countries, 41, 269 Lapland, 48, 111, 197 Lapps, 86 Large family farms, 21. See also Wage-labor family farms Large farms, 21, 75, 89, 112, 124, 151, 218 fT., 252 ff., 256, 283, 302 Large livestock unit (LLU), 15, 168. See also Cattle unit Large-scale operations, 151 Latifundia farming, 206 Latifundios, 89 Lead crop, 185, 207, 214 Lead enterprise, 224 Leafy crops, 18, 178, 212 ff., 259, 263, 300 Lease rotation, 246 Legumes, 18 f., 145, 164, 180 f., 262 f., 269, 286, 298 Leningrad Oblast, 262 Lettuce, 245 Ley farming, 18 f., 44, 48, 56, 92, 118 f., 138 f., 141, 211 ff., 261, 291, 295 ff., end papers Leys, 211, 239 f., 251, 262; useful economic life, 118, 238 Liberia, 135 Libya, 46, 57 Liguria, 201 Linen, 75 Livestock, 21, 23, 114, 160, 213, 218, 248 f., 259, 265, 301 f.; regions, 222 ff. Livestock raising, 33, 36 f., 40, 42, 58, 71, 75, .78, 92, 94, 110, 115 f., 119, 123, 129, 131, 179, 190, 217, 246 f., 273, 285, 297; and farm size, 283; dry boundary of, 127; extensive, 72 f., 83, 243, 264, 299; in the European Community, 2 2 2 f f . ; i n the South, 241; sedentary, 80 f.; technical and structural arrangements in, 99. See also Farming systems Llama, 39 Local zone, 105 Locational orientation, 94 ff., 191 ff., 226, 252 Loess belt, 101, 202, 219 Lombardy, 201 Los Angeles area, 233, 244 Lucerne. See Alfalfa Lüneburg Heath, 119 Lupine, 18, 64, 262 Machine Tractor Station (MTS), 24
337 Machinery, 90, 109, 174, 239, 248 f., 277, 279, 288; cooperatives, 99ff., 283; corn picking, 288; costs, 99 ff.; cotton picking, 288; custom hiring, 99 ff.; interfarm, use, 99 ff.; operator's, 283; pools, 99 ff., 283; use in West German agriculture, 100 Madras, 36 Magdeburg Börde, 122 Maize. See Corn Maize Triangle, 188 Malagasy, 37, 145 Malawi, 28, 96, 138 f. Malaysia, 125, 150 Mali, 175, 182, 187 Man: -day (MD), 15, 139 f., 184, 186; -hour (MH), 15, 77, 110f., 124, 147, 153, 158, 164, 179, 182, 219; -year (MY), 15, 22, 101, 182 f., 260, 301 Management, farm, 21, 203, 299; active measures of, 170 ff.; for bush and tree crops, 149 ff.; functions of crop irrigation, 143; in U.S. agriculture, 249; passive measures of, 170 ff.; types, 244 ff.; weight, 259 Manchurian Plain, 267 Mangoes, 25 Manioc, 25, 33, 36, 50, 52ff., 58, 74, 125, 132, 139, 286. See also Cassava Manufactured inputs, 271 ff. Manure, 81, 91 f., 151, 221, 245, 258, 293; barn, 222; -demanding specialty crops, 221; green, 181, 184, 269, 297; -producing fodder crops, 221 Manuring, 109; capacity, 221 f.; economy, 240, 273; green, 91, 291 ff., 297. See also Fertilization Many-sided farms, 104 ff., 284. See also Diversified farms; Mixed farms Marginal areas, 86. See also Marginal zones Marginal farms, 77 Marginal locations, 47 ff., 84, 191 ff., end papers Marginal productivity, 109, 274, 279 Marginal yield, 279 Marginal zones, 47 ff., 75, 80, 115, end papers. See also Marginal areas Marine cool-summer climate, 34, 42; farming changes in, 295 ff. Maritime climate, 116 Maritime fodder cropping farms, 116 Maritime fodder cropping regions, 217 Maritime fodder farming, 116 Market: dependence, 21; distance, 47, 73, 84ff., 102ff., 190 ff., 238ff., 295; distance and agricultural production zones, 238 ff.; distance and farming diversity, 104; distance and farming intensity, 104; distance and socialist farm production, 256 ff.; distance and types of cattle raising
338
Index
(Continuation Market) Mixed farming, 21, 139, 152, 236, 240, 244, 273, 285 226; distance and wage levels, 103; expansion, 273; garden farming, 297; Mixed farms, 221, 240, 284, 289. See also position, 156; prices, 137; risks, 93, 169, Diversified farms; Many-sided farms 289 Mixed forest, 260, 262 f. Molapo farming, 65 f. Marketing boards, 124, 150 Molapos, 65 Markets, 28, 220; expansion of, 273; great Molasses, 246 distances to, in Australia, 192; remoteness Mongolia, Inner, 267 from, 190 Mongols, 166 Marsh soils, 77 Monocultural farms, 89, 104 ff., 117, 151, 217, Marshes: young cultivated, 218 240, 244, 284 ff., 289. See also One-crop Masai, 167, 171 farms; One-sided farms; Single-product farms Mass income, 174 Monocultural landscapes, 72 Masuria, 258 Monoculture, 19, 21, 56, 91, 125, 131, 145, Mate, 51 151, 154, 169, 181, 184, 217, 221, 240, Mauritania, 57 242, 245, 285, 289 f. Mayan culture, 28 Montana, 179 Meadows, 18 f.; mowing of, 199; permanent, 68 f. Montane fodder cropping regions, 217 Montane fodder farming, 116 Meat, 139, 170, 193 f., 267; animals, 174 Montenegro, 259 Mechanical technological advances, 76 ff., I l l f. Moscow: Oblast, 262; service area, 72 Mechanization, 77, 97 ff., 106, 110, 120, Mosel Valley, 220 f., 230 125, 180, 220, 237, 266, 277, 282, 300; Mozambique, 66 and farm size, 283; and smaller parcels, Münster Bay, 230 205; difficulties, 2 4 0 / 2 4 9 ; increasing Mulberry trees, 269 pressures for, 214; over-, 90 Mushrooms, 294 Mechanized farms, 281 Mutton, 193 Mechanized harvesting, 110 Mutual aid teams, 266 Mecklenburg, 28, 256, 258 Mediterranean area, 40, 62, 68, 78, 163, 199, Nagana disease, 77, 136, 299 Namib, 115 201 f., 214, 216, 228 Natural landscape, 141 Mediterranean climate, 94, 191, 198 f., 222, Naturegart farming, 19, 50, 68 f. 228, 235, 244, 259. See also Climates Navigation, 270 Mediterranean coast, 181, 202, 227 Nebraska, 179, 242 Mediterranean countries, 201, 218 Nematodes, 90 Mekong Delta, 29 Neolithic culture, 28 Melons, 123 Nepal, 5 3 Meseta, 39, 301 Net return, 22 f. Mesopotamia, 28 New York State, 50 Mexico, 37, 53, 275 New Zealand, 110 Michigan, 237 Ngamiland, 65 Migrations, 66; out-, 280 Niger, 175, 182, 187 Milk, 65, 71, 73, 80, 93, 104, 108, 110, Nigeria, 46, 59, 125, 135 115, 139, 166, 224, 227, 237, 239, 261, 267, prices and types of cattle raising, 226; Nile, 28; Delta, 68, 122, 163 Nilgiri Mountains, 36 production and prices, 107 Nitrogen, 110, 286; fertilizers, 110 Millet, 25, 3 6 f . , 5 2 f f . , 58, 74, 7 7 f . , 81, 86, Nomadic grazing (herding), 27, 66, 75, 80, 117, 125, 138 f., 144, 151, 164, 175 ff., 114, 171 f., 291, 294 f., zones, 166 ff. 267 f., 286, 288, 293; -sorghum-peanut See also Farming systems; Livestock raising farming, 181 ff. Nomads, 38, 65, 127, 294, 299; desert, 166, Minimum cost combination, 28, 145 ff., 152, 170; mountain, 167, 171; semi-, 166f., 274 ff., 279. See also Cost-production ratio; 250; steppe, 166 Costs; Input-output ratio; Price-cost ratio; Norfolk rotation, 19, 211, 213 f., 295 f. Price-cost relations Normandy, 42 Miombo woodland, 37, 129 North Africa, 3 9 f . , I l l , 163 Mississippi Basin, 234 North America, 42, 60, 118, 196 f.; agriMississippi Valley, 241 cultural geography of, 232 ff. Missouri Basin, 234
339
Index North Carolina, 240 North Dakota, 179, 190, 242 North European Plain, 227 North German Marsh, 101, 116 North German Plain, 219 North Macedonian Mountains, 259 North Sea Coast, 213; German, 230 Northeast (U.S.), 232 f., 237 Northern boundaries: in Europe, 199 ff. Northern Plains (U.S.), 179; states, 235 Norway, 50, 199, 205, 216, 224, 226 Nug, 141 Nurse crops, 259 Nutrient balance, 91, 109, 286 Nutrient concentration, 286 Nutrient reservoir, 173 Nutrient yield, 173 Nutrients, 117, 134, 141, 170, 177, 251, 301 Nutrition: regionalization of world, 196 Oases, 39, 62, 241 Oats, 18, 48 ff., 54, 56, 71, 100, 119, 138, 180, 238 ff., 262, 296 Oceanic climate: and production risk, 93 Oder-Vistula area, 258 Oil crops, 19, 25, 154, 220, 298. See also Oil palms Oil mills, 87, 155 Oil palms, 25, 33, 36, 50ff., 55, 58, 124 f., 126, 131, 150 f., 154, 269, 286, 291. See also Oil crops Oil pumpkin, 139 Okavango Swamp, 65 Olives, 25, 41, 49 f., 52, 58, 62, 124, 155, 163, 199, 201, 221 Oman, 46 One: -crop farms, 244; -field farming, 297; -sided farms, 104 ff., 284 f., 289; -tractor farms, 98. See also Monocultural farms; Single-product farms Open-range steppe grassland farming, 167 ff. See also Farming systems; Grassland farming; Ranching Opportunity costs, 97 Optimal productive combination, 247 ff. Orange Free State, 188 Oranges, 222 Oregon, 242 Organic matter, 141 Organic technological advances, 111 Otavi Valley, 189 Otjiwarongo District, 188 Ovambo farms, 190 Ovamboland, 189 Ovambos, 189f. Overgrazing, 27 Overpopulated agrarian state, 278, 280 Overpopulation, 205
Ownership: land, 266 Oxen, 77, 96, 173, 183, 288 Pacific Coastal Lowlands, 234 Pakistan, 40, 68, 154, 163 f. Palm nuts, 123 Paprika, 122 Paris Basin, 79, 90, 202 Part-time farming, 282 Part-time farms, 226, 282 f. Passion fruit, 36, 52, 55, 153 Passive adaptation, 106 f., 160, 170 ff. Pasture, 18, 74, 86, 169, 259, 297; carrying capacity of natural, 168, 193; dryland, 193; fallow, 193; mowing, 217; natural, 164; per cattle unit in western U.S., 243; permanent, 297; requirements on U.S. wheat farms, 179; residual, 231; rotation, 180, 297; zone, 105 Patagonia, 57 Patagonians, 27 Pea viners, 112 Peanut-millet rotation, 58 Peanut-sorghum rotation, 58, 184 Peanuts, 25, 36 f., 42, 50ff., 55, 58 f., 78, 134, 138f., 144, 164, 175, 177 f., 181 ff., 220, 241, 286, 293, 300 Peas, 58, 71, 121, 141, 177, 262 Peasant crops, 150, 155 ff. Peasant family, 151 Peasant farm economies, 56, 155 f. Peasant farms, 75, 124, 153ff., 253, 256, 266 Peasants, 124, 252; German, 75 People's Commune (PC), 24, 256 People's Estate (PE), 24 People's Republic of China (PRC). See China Pepper, 36, 150 Perennial cropping systems, 114, 117 ff., 122 f., end papers Perennial crops, 122, 125 f., 143, 150, 152, 164, 245, 255, 301. See also Bush and tree crops Personality, 29, 95 f. Peru, 53 Peshawar Basin, 163 f. Pests, 8 1 , 9 1 , 9 3 , 1 5 1 , 2 4 6 , 2 8 6 Phenological dates, 199 Philippines, 135 Photoperiodism, 68 Pineapple, 25, 124, 150, 154f., 269 Pioneer farms, 47, 77 Place-specific characteristics: and spatial differentiation of farms, 94 ff.; of Australia, 191 ff.; of the dry areas, 160 ff.; of the East Bloc countries, 250 f.; of the tropics, 127 ff.; of the United States, 232 ff.; of Western Europe, 197 ff. Plains states (U.S.), 89
340 Plant breeding, 78f., 84, 111, 264 Plant protection, 21, 29, 93, 147, 162, 219, 288, 292 f. Plantains, 25, 37 Plantation crops, 150, 155 ff. Plantation farming, 125, 151, 300 f., end papers Plantation zone, 105 Plantations, 17, 55, 87, 95, 102, 105, 122 ff., 151, 153 f., 157, 287, 289, 300 f., end papers; Indonesian rubber, 123; size, 96 ff.; sugarcane, 145 Planters, 252 Plow, 28f.,117, 175 Plow cultivation, 27 ff., 77, 86, 135, 291, 294 Plums, 124 Po Plain, 40f., 79, 96, 119, 201, 212ff., 220, 224 Poland, 202, 216, 253 ff. Polar boundaries, 44, 46, 48 ff., 52, 79, 84, 86, 264 Polar fodder cropping regions, 217 Polar fodder farming, 116 Polish United Workers' Party, 255 Pomerania, Farther, 75, 227, 256, 258 Population, 267; consumptive habits, 273; density, 95 f., 146, 173, 175, 205, 248, 267, 294; density and agricultural development, 274 ff.; growth, 28, 45, 82, 105, 175, 178 ff., 244, 286; high, density in the (U.S.) South, 248; over-, 205. See also Settlement Pork, 71, 75, 239, 261 Potash, 91 Potato harvesters, 100, 288 Potato hog-fattening area, 227 Potatoes, 18, 36, 44, 48, 51 ff., 56, 58, 69, 71, 75, 86, 90, 95, 122, 138, 141, 199, 213, 219, 222, 230, 251, 256 ff., 285 f.; English, 138; feed, 256; seed, 104, 219, 256; sweet, 25, 42, 50ff., 58, 74, 125, 132, 138, 143 ff., 186, 241, 285 ff. Poultry, 24, 285 Poultry raising, 23, 89, 247 Pre-Alpine areas, 213 Precipitation, 34, 115 f., 118, 160 ff., 168 f., 176 ff., 201 f., 216 ff., 234 f., 242f.; agricultural effects of a decline in, 191; annual, in the United States, 233; and crop rotations in dry farming, 177; and land use intensity, 122; and land use systems, 216 f.; and ley farming, 118; and ley farming regions, 212; and tropical vegetation formations, 127 ff.; average annual, 35; boundaries, 115,169; boundaries in Africa, 165; curve for Grootfontein, Southwest Africa, 162, 166; favorable distribution of, 116; fluctuations,
Index 160, 162 f., 165 f.; limits of extensive grazing, 115; mean annual, in Europe, 201 f.; on the agronomic dry boundary, 57; seasonal distribution, 64; uneven distribution of, 160; variations in Africa, 165. See also Climates Preparatory crop, 185 Price-cost development, 106 ff. Price-cost differences, 106 Price-cost ratio, 74, 110, 144 ff., 170, 173, 247 ff., 297. See also Cost-production ratio; Costs; Input-output ratio; Minimum cost combination; Price-cost relations Price-cost relations, 71, 78, 102 ff., 247 ff., 271 ff., 297; between agricultural inputs, 109 f.; between agricultural products, 107 ff.; between agricultural products and inputs, 110 f. See also Cost-production ratio; Costs; Input-output ratio; Minimum cost combination; Price-cost ratio Price-cost shifts, 86, 88 Prices, 110, 252, 271 ff., 295 ff.; barley, 297, farm gate, 102, 106, 126, 137; in Germany, 272; iron, 272; land, 27 ff., 174, 248 f., 272; potato, 297; rye, 272; wheat, 297; world market, 126 Primary forage area (PFA), 15 Primitive rotation farming, 117 f. Product-specific transport boundaries, 72 f. Production, 249; and farm size, 206; Brazilian agricultural, 284; brigades, 266; costs, 88, 231, 242, 286 ff.; deficiency in, 255; diversity, 21, 88 ff., 105 f., 154, 187, 240, 284 ff.; elasticity, 19, 101, 143, 206; factors, 21, 28, 109 ff., 146 ff., 183, 247 ff., 255, 274; farm, 22; function, 176; intensity, 19, 247 ff.; methods, 146 ff., 155 f., 169 ff., 247 ff.; physical location of, 94 f.; prices of, factors, 271 ff.; process, 274; program, 19, 21, 88, 101 ff., 106 f., 113 ff., 167 f., 182 ff., 247, 284 ff.; risk, 169 f., 187; teams, 266 Productivity, 21, 23, 124, 143, 158, 241 ff., 269, 273 f., 282, 292 ff., 302; and farm size, 283; capital, 146, 277 ff.; comparison, 139 f., 158f.; labor, 21, 29, 84, 111, 115, 124, 135, 145 ff., 158, 181 ff., 186, 193, 277 ff., 291; land, 21 ff., 112, 115, 124, 134, 136, 143, 158, 182 f., 278 ff., 292 ff., marginal, 109, 274, 279; market, for sheep and cattle, 167; of livestock farming types, 295; optimal, combination, 247 ff. Profitability boundaries, 46 f., 70 ff., 86 Protein, 185, 189; animal, 224; content, 139; plant, 224; ratio, 286; yield, 139 Provence, 220 Purchasing power, 271 ff.; between wage labor and farm machinery, 109; low, 136;
Index
341
(Continuation Purchasing power) of agricultural products, 108, 111, 271, 302; of animal products, 170, 174, 295 Pure grassland farmers, 93. See also Grassland farmers Pure cattle-fattening farms, 224 ff. Pure crop farms, 187 Pure grassland farming, 217 f. See also Farming systems; Grassland farming Pure grassland farms, 217 f. Pygmies, 27 Pyrethrum, 52, 55, 138 Queensland,
192
Rainfed farming, 37, 40, 57, 59 f., 83, 129 ff., 137 ff., 143, 151, 160, 292, 295; in developing countries, 149; in the humid savannas, 137 ff.; in the tropical highlands, 140 f.; in the tropical rainforest, 132 ff. Rainforest, 55, 63, 67, 94, 124, 138 ff., 153, 299 ff.; climate, 33 ff., 38, 127 ff., 291 f., 299, 301; rainfed farming in the, 132 ff. Ramie, 26 Ranchers, 66, 74, 127, 252 Ranches, 17, 38, 74 f., 87, 96 ff., 101, 172, 182 f., 194, 242, end papers Ranching, 64, 77 f., 80 f., 115 ff., 129, 167 ff., 182 ff., 236, 243, 293, 295, end papers. See also Farming systems; Grassland farming Range: fenced-, farming, 167; open-, farming, 167 Rape, 18, 100, 119 f., 144;-seed, 1 8 , 9 0 ; yields, 218 Reclamation: water, 195, 264 f., 270 Reimbursement share, 21 Reindeer, 86, 250 Relief, 52 Rent differential, 159 Residential zone, 105 Rhine: industrial area, 230; -Main area, 79, 119, 201, 220; Plain, 220; Valley, 220, 222, 230 Rhineland, 90; -Pfalz, 84; -Ruhr area, 230 Rhone delta, 20 Rhone Valley, 220 Rice, 25, 33, 37, 42, 49 ff., 55, 59, 66 f., 79, 91, 120, 122, 132, 134, 139, 141, 144 ff., 201, 262, 264, 267, 269, 278; cultivation, 95, 129, 299; farming, 145 ff., 278; yields, 110 Risk, 185,187 ff., 193, 245, 255; harvest, 77, 152, 289; market, 93, 169, 289; of drought, 264; production, 169 f.; reducing, 221; spreading, 93; to diversified production, 187 Riverside-San Bernardino area, 246 Riviera, 205, 220
Romania, 253 Root crops, 25, 42, 132, 139, 186, 262, 278, 294, 296. See also Hoe crops Root forage crops, 92 Root humus, 118 Root system, 122 Roughages, 18, 204 Row-spraying, 112 Rubber, 25, 33, 36, 50 ff., 55, 58, 95, 124 ff., 131, 150, 153, 286 Rugs, 75, 84 Ruminants, 209, 222, 224, 226 Russia, 232, 251 f., 261 f. See also Soviet Union Ruwer Valley, 221, 230 Rye, 1 8 , 5 1 , 5 6 , 7 1 , 9 1 , 1 0 0 , 2 5 1 , 2 6 2 , 264, 267 Saar, 230 Sacramento Valley, 67, 122, 163, 246 Sago palm, 51 Sahara, 40, 47, 62, 78, 86, 166, 181 Sahel, 27, 37 f., 63, 110 Salinas Valley, 246 Salinization, 68 Salt carbonates, 67 Salt efflorescence, 67 San Francisco Bay Area, 233 San Joaquin Valley, 163 Sao Paulo, state of, 114 Sarawak, 135 Sardinia, 224, 227 Saskatchewan, 57, 242 Sauerland, 217 Savanna climate, 34 ff., 292 f. Savanna grassland farming, 166 ff. See also Grassland farming Savanna shifting cultivation, 27, 58, 80 f., 117 f., 174 ff., 293 ff. Savannas: bush, 189; dry, 39, 63, 129, 165, 190 f., 294 f.; high-grass, 130, 137 ff., 194; humid, 63, 129 f., 137, 139, 292; semiarid shrub, 127; shortgrass, 37; shrub, 39, 129, 165, 191, 295 Sawahs, 69 Saxony, Lower, 2 0 2 , 2 0 5 , 2 1 3 Scania, 117, 212 Scandinavia, 43, 111, 197, 205, 214, 217, 232 Scarcity ratios, 75 Schleswig-Holstein, 79, 202, 205, 213 Scotland, 1 1 9 , 2 1 2 , 2 2 4 , 2 2 7 Sedentary extensive grassland farming, 115, 167 ff., 243 f. See also Farming systems; Grassland farming Sedentary grassland farming, 167 ff. See also Farming systems; Grassland farming Sedentary intensive grassland farming, 115 ff. See also Farming systems; Grassland farming
342 Seed dressings, 277 Seed drills, 277 Seed costs, 21 Seedbeds, 147 f., 299 Seeds, 277, 292; stubble, 18; under-, 18 Self-subsistence, 114, 123 Self-sufficiency, 93, 123, 155, 261 Self-supplying cattle fattening farms, 169 Self-supplying dairy farms, 225 f. Semi-desert, 129, 191; climate, 39 f. Semi-drylot farms, 225 f. Senegal, 175, 182 ff. Serbia, 259 Serengeti National Park, 114 Sesame, 25, 58, 175, 184, 293; cropping, 185 Settlement: boundaries, 46, 70; density, 175, 261, 274 ff., 294. See also Population density Shansi, 268 Shantung, 268 Sheep, 38, 65, 80, 84, 86, 166 f., 170, 192 ff., 209, 244, 259; and goat and dairy farming, 223 f., 226; and goat and young cattle farming, 223, 227; farms, 114; grazing-wheat belt, 193; Karakul, 62; raising, 58, 60, 62, 115, 1 9 3 f f . , 226; raising-cattle raising belt, 193. See also Farming systems; Livestock raising Shifting cultivation, 27 f., 37, 95, 129, 132 ff., 140, 285, 294 ff., end papers; bog-burning, 27, 118; Hauberg, 19, 118; forest-burning, 27, 118, 125, 130, 132, 134 f., 291, 301; savanna, 174 f., 293 ff.; steppe, 2 7 , 5 8 , 80 f., 117 f., 174 ff.; with plow cultivation, 291. See also Clearing Shrub, 127, 129; savanna climate, 38 f., savannas, 39. See also Bush Siberia, 1 1 1 , 1 2 2 , 2 5 1 , 2 6 2 Sicily, 201, 220, 222, 230 Sickles, 147 f. Sierra Leone, 135 Siegen district, 84 Silesia, 251, 256 Silk, 75, 269; cotton trees, 26, 269 Simplification: of farming, 105 f. See also Specialization Single-operator farms, 98 Single-product farms, 284. See also Monocultural farms; One-crop farms; One-sided farms Sinkiang, 268 Sisal, 26, 50, 52 f., 58, 72, 124 f., 150, 154, 163, 269, 287; factories, 87, 155; landscapes, 125 Skins, 169 f. Slaughtering, 171 Slavs, 28 Slope boundaries, 68 f. Slovenia, 258 f.
Index Small family farms, 144, 207. See also Farms Small farms, 97 ff., 285. See also Farms Small-scale processing, 154 Snowy Mountains, 195; Scheme, 195 Social boundaries, 84 Social fallow, 47, 84 Socialism, 253 f. Socialist farms, large, 251, 254, 257, 260. See also Farms Socialization: of agriculture, 252; of the production factors, 255; policies, 250; stages of, 253 ff. Soil boundaries, 46, 67 f., 77 Soil-determined grain cropping economies, 218 Soil erosion, 67, 118, 137, 239 f., 242, 264 Soil fertility, 118, 125 f., 130, 132, 137, 141, 150f., 173, 175, 286, 299 ff. Soil productivity, 135 Soil types, 202 f., 220, 235 Soils, 202 f., 218 ff.; black, 263; cultivation of marginal, 266; grassland, 242; in central England, 296; in the East Bloc, 251; marsh, 77; of Europe, 202 f.; types in the United States, 235; volcanic, 135 Somalia, 39 Somalis, 171 Sorghum, 25, 3 6 f . , 52 f., 58, 74, 77 f., 81, 117, 125, 138 f., 164, 175 ff., 241 f., 267 f., 288, 293; millet, and peanut farming, 181 ff. South Africa, Republic of, 42, 57, 60, 70, 168, 176 South America, 42, 46, 53, 274 South Dakota, 57, 190, 242 Southern Plains (U.S.), 179 Soviet Union, 24, 31, 43, 84, 111, 116, 176, 253 f., 260 ff., 267; crop rotations, 262; large socialist farms, 260; regional zones, 263 Sovkhoz, 24, 2 5 2 f f „ 260 Soybeans, 25, 4 2 f „ 51 ff., 145, 164, 220, 239 ff., 264, 288, 300 Spain, 199, 205, 214, 221 Sparsely settled countries, 271 ff., 274 ff., 281 Specialization, 21, 92, 94, 105, 117, 125, 152, 247, 277; and farm size, 283; in economic integration, 2 8 9 f . ; i n t h e industrial era, 287 ff.; in the United States, 236; in vegetable growing, 245; increasing, 238; of the production program, 284 f.; on fodder cropping farms, 217; stages in farming, 289 f.; strong, 246 Specialized farming, 21. See also Farming Specialized farms, 104, 221, 240, 246, 284, 289 Specialty crop farming, 215 f., 221 Specialty crop farms, 220
Index Specialty crop-hoe crop farming, 215 f., 222 Specialty crops, 18, 94, 209 f., 214 f., 218, 220 f., 228, 236, 256 ff. Spinach, 245; harvesters, 112 Sprinklers, 156 Sri Lanka, 69, 125, 150, 154, 157 Stall feeding, 222, 230 Starch factory, 257 State farms, 24, 252 ff., 260 Steppe, 260, 262 ff., 293 ff.; climate, 3 4 , 3 9 , 191, 293 ff.; hot and dry, 300; salt, 127; shifting cultivation, 27, 58, 80 f., 117 f., 174 ff.; shrub, 129; subtropical grass, 129 Straw, 221 Strawberries, 18 Strip grazing, 112 Strongly commercialized farms, 21, 75. See also Farms Subarctic climate, 43, 250 f. Subsistence, 93; crops, 132, 152, 182, 186, 190, 289; economies, 28; farming, 187; farms, 21, 182, 280; self-, 114, 123 Subtropical boundaries, 185 Subtropical dry-summer climate, 34, 40 f. Subtropical warm-summer climate, 41 f., 250 Sudan, 57, 59, 63, 134, 144, 167, 186 Sudanese blacks, 167 Sugar, 150; beet farming, 77, 100, 110 f., 258; beets, 16, 18, 42, 44, 58, 77, 90, 95, 100, 108, 122, 164, 199, 213, 219, 222, 251, 261 ff.; production, 148; refineries, 230; yield in cane, 155 Sugarcane, 25, 33, 37, 50, 52 ff., 58 f., 72, 74, 91, 95, 124 f., 132, 139, 141, 143 ff., 148, 150, 164, 194, 287 f.; landscapes, 125, 155; mills, 87, 102, 155, 164; monoculture, 102; zones, 155 Sumatra, 135 Summer feeding farms, 116 Sunflowers, 177, 263, 293 Supply and demand: and farm location, 28, 70 ff., 102 ff., 190 ff., 238 f., 295 Surpluses: agricultural, 193; land, 247 f. Sweden, 43, 71, 107, 110, 117, 197, 199, 204, 212 Swine, 209 f., 222, 260, 285. See also Hogs Taiwan, 69, 120, 143, 145, 278 Tanzania, 53, 123, 125, 150, 167 Tariff barriers, 95, 237 Tea, 18, 25, 36, 50, 52 f., 55, 58, 124 ff., 131, 150, 153, 155, 157 f., 268 f., 285, 287; bushes, 269; factories, 87, 153; farms, 157 ff.; landscapes, 56, 125; monoculture, 56 Technical auxiliary enterprises, 75 Technical inputs, 174 Technical progress, 175
343 Technological advances, 86, 88, 90 ff., 208, 271; biological, 78 f.; mechanical, 76 ff., I l l ff.; organic, 111 Technological boundaries, 46 f., 86 Technology, 180; agricultural, 28, 76 ff., 11 Iff.; harvesting, 57, 77, 147 f., 242; mechanized, 76ff., I l l ff., 288; state of, 106 Teff, 52, 54 f., 141 Temperature: in Europe, 201 f.; land use systems and, 216; of at least 5°C, 200. See also Climates Terrace farming, 55, 68 Terraces, 55, 69 Texas, 57, 242 Thailand, 66, 146 ff., 275 Three: -field and fallow farming, 296 ff.; -crop farms, 244; -field system, 20, 120, 297; -stage theory, 27 ff., 290 f.; -tractor farms, 98 Thiinen circles, 71 Thiinen model, 104 ff., 205; in Chicago's hinterland, 238 ff.; in the Storsjön area, 71; in the vicinity of Moscow, 261, 263 Tibet, 53 Tobacco, 25, 52, 58, 138, 141, 164, 186, 236, 240, 264; farming, 236, 240 Trace elements, 68 Traction power, 16, 288; motorized, 91, 96; unit, 16. See also Tractors Tractor: drivers, 96; four-, farms, 98; one-, farms, 98; plows, 147; three-, farms, 98; two-, farms, 98 Tractors, 28 f., 68, 77 f., 85, 90, 100, 245, 260, 266 f., 288. See also Traction power Trade: foreign, 269, 291, 297 Traditional farming, 231 Transport: access, 76; aerial, 245 ; boundaries, 47, 70 ff.; consolidation of the, net, 273; costs, 29, 102ff., 125, 137, 153, 155, 256 f., 273; cotton fiber, 187; density in Europe, 205; density in the East Bloc, 251 f.; facilities, 124; location of farms for, 102 ff.; net and the Australian ranch, 194; network, 29, 93; network in Sweden, 252; nodes, 244; pineapple, 156; problems, 71, 76, 126, 150, 155, 191 ff.; truck, 92; unfavorable, situation, 169; with camel caravans, 166; wool, 192 Transvaal, 138, 188, 285 Tropical boundaries, 185 Tropical farming, 131 ff., 300 f. See also Farming systems Tropical highlands, 38, 124, 130, 163; bush and tree crops in the, 153; climates, 36 f., rainfed farming in the, 140 f.; sisal in the, 163; wheat in the, 181 Tropical rainy climates, 33 f.; and altitudinal crop boundaries, 53; farming changes in, 291 f. See also Climates
344 Tropics, 38, 93, 124, 153; outer, 165 ff.; wet-and-dry, 38 Tsetse fly, 77, 299 Tsumeb District, 188 Tubers, 25, 80, 139, 186. See also Hoe crops; Potatoes; Root crops Tundra, 250, 260, 263; pastures, 86 Tung oil, 269 Tunisia, 57, 180f. Turkestan, 40 Turkey, 143, 176, 269 Tuscany, 201 Twelve-stage theory, 297, 302 Two: -crop farms, 244; -field farming, 297; -man farms, 97, 100; -tractor farms, 98 Tyrol, South, 230 Uganda, 150, 186 Ukraine, 202, 235, 251 Umbria, 201 Underemployment, 89, 184 Undernourishment, 301 Undivided inheritance, 205 UNESCO, 31 United States, 31, 39, 41, 84, 89, 110, 122, 146 ff., 176, 178 ff., 220, 232 ff., 247, 249, 275, 277; annual precipitation, 233; farming zones, 236 ff.; growing season, 234; place-specific characteristics, 232 ff.; soil types, 235; Southeastern, 241; Southern, 247 f.; Southwestern, 241; Western, 247 f. UNO, 31,45 Upper Volta, 175, 182 Uruguay, 275 Useful economic life, 20, 118, 124, 150, 153, 156, 212, 224, 258 U.S.S.R. See Soviet Union Uttar Pradesh, 144 Uzbekistan, 40, 251 Vaccines, 277 Vegetable canning industry, 112 Vegetable cropping, 112, 244 f. Vegetables, 18, 36, 42, 53 ff., 60, 62, 93, 95, 120ff., 138f., 141, 144f., 219f., 230, 238 f., 244 ff., 261 f., 264 Vegetation: belts, 129; climax, 141; formations, 127 ff.; zones, 171 ff. Vesuvius, 120 Vetch, 262 Veterinary hygiene, 78, 272 Veterinary services, 21 Vierland area, 220 Vintners, 230 Vineyards: French, 230 Virgin lands, 262; cultivation, 264; reserves, 265 Virginia, 240
Index Viticulture, 49, 52, 62, 75, 89, 92, 114, 221 f., 256, 258 Vojvodina, 227, 258 Volga-Don area, 265 Vorgebirge, 220, 230 Vosges, 217 Wage-labor family farms, 21, 218 f., 283 Wage levels, 84, 103, 107 ff., 123, 214, 231, 244, 249, 271 f., 297; and market distance, 103; and types of cattle raising, 226; in Germany, 272; on U.S. wheat farms, 179 Wales, 119, 212, 227 Walnuts, 244 Warmia, 258 Washington, 242 Water, 162 f., 175, 178; buffalo, 147 f.; land use intensity and, 122; reclamation projects, 195, 264 f., 270. See also Irrigation Watering places, 39, 192, 295, 301 Weakly commercialized farms, 21 Weaving, hand, 75 Weed control, 91, 111, 137, 219 Weed growth, 118, 134, 137, 301 Weed killers, 277 Weeds, 78, 91, 118, 122, 171, 246, 300 f. Weighted-index system, 207 ff., 214 Wells, 171 f., 301; tube, 6 6 , 7 8 Westphalia, 213, 217 f. Westphalian-Hellweg region, 202 Wet boundaries, 36, 46, 66 f., 86 Wet-rice farming, 299 Wheat, 18, 36, 44, 49, 51 ff., 56, 58, 60, 62, 64, 77ff., 84, 90, 100, 108, 111, 119, 122, 138, 141, 144, 164, 176 ff., 194, 199, 238, 240, 251, 262 f., 267 ff., 293, 296; Belts, 236, 242; -fallow farming, 176 ff.; fallow farms, 178, 180; farming, 77, 179, 242; regions in the U.S., 242; -sheep farming, 192, 194. See also Farming systems Wickerwork, 189 Wild animals, 80, 114, 194 Wild plants, 123 Wild steppe grassland farming, 167 ff. See also Farming systems; Grassland farming; Ranching Winches, 147 f. Wine, 231. See also Grapes Wisconsin, 237 Work spacing, 88 ff., 114, 151, 184, 219, 221, 244, 284, 288 Wrocfew (Breslau) Platform, 202 Yak, 39 Yakuts, 250 Yams, 25, 33, 36 f., 74, 132, 139, 286 Yangtze, 29
Index Yaroslavl Oblast, 262 Yellow Plain, 268 Yields, 84 f., 141, 286; fluctuations, 278; fox grain crops, 176 f., 179; in different locations, 94; in the peanut-millet-sorghum rotation, 184; increased by capital inputs, 82; increasing gross, 143; of land uses, 90; on U.S. wheat farms, 179; on young cultivated marshes, 218; under shifting cultivation, 134, 136; uniform fodder, 286
Young cattle-dairy farming, 223 Yucatan, 28 Yucca, 74, 139 Zaire, 135, 149 f., 275 Zambesi Basin, 37 Zambia, 135, 275 Zeeland, 219, 230 Zimbabwe, 74
Agrarzonen Farming Regions
Vorherrschende
landwirtschaftliche
Betriebsfori
Graslandsysteme
Ackerbausys.
Grazing Systems
0
Arable Farmii
Weidenomadismus
Wander
Nomadism
Ranch wirtsch
feld
bau
Shifting Cultivation
a ften
Feldgraswirtschaften
Ranching
Ley
D
Marginafe
oder
Farming
submarginale
m
Zonen
M a r g i n a l or Submarginal Regions
E n t w i c k e l t noch ( D e v e l o p e d by) W v a n R o y e n : The A g r i c u l t u r a l Resources of the World. New York 19.51. S.8.
(
( for e>
F i g u r e 26
der Erde OÍ t h e
World
Entwurf
(Design):
B.Andreae
Cancer
Kapstadt ^
men
( Predominant
Types of
•>teme
Dauerkultursysteme Perennial Crop Cultivation
ng
ΓΊ Li
Körnerbauwirtschaften Grain Farming
Pflanzungen Plantations without Factories Plantagen Plantations with Factories
Hackfruchtbauwirtschaften Root Crop Farming z. T. Sammeln, Jagd und :ample hunting, fishing )
Farming)
Fischfang) ©
C o p y r i g h t by W a l t e r de Gruyter, Berlin • N e w York
1981