183 48 3MB
English Pages 145 Year 2009
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved. Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated,
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved. Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science Publishers,
Climate Change and its Causes, Effects and Prediction Series
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
EMISSIONS TRADING: LESSONS LEARNED FROM THE EUROPEAN UNION AND KYOTO PROTOCOL CLIMATE CHANGE PROGRAMS
No part of this digital document may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system or transmitted in any form or by any means. The publisher has taken reasonable care in the preparation of this digital document, but makes no expressed or implied warranty of any kind and assumes no responsibility for any errors or omissions. No liability is assumed for incidental or consequential damages in connection with or arising out of information contained herein. This digital document is sold with the clear understanding that the publisher is not engaged in rendering legal, medical or any other professional services.
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
CLIMATE CHANGE AND ITS CAUSES, EFFECTS AND PREDICTION SERIES Global Climate Change Harace B. Karling (Editor) 2001. 1-56072-999-6 Global Climate Change Revisited Harace B. Karling (Editor) 2007. 1-59454-039-X Climate Change Research Progress Lawrence N. Peretz (Editor) 2008. 1-60021-998-5
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Climate Change: Financial Risks United States Government Accountability Office 2008. 978-1-60456-488-4 Post-Kyoto: Designing the Next International Climate Change Protocol Matthew Clarke 2008. 978-1-60456-840-0 Economics of Policy Options to Address Climate Change Gregory N. Bartos 2009. 978-1-60692-116-6 The Effects of Climate Change on Agriculture, Land Resources, Water Resources, and Biodiversity in the United States Peter Backlund, Anthony Janetos, and David Schimel 2009. 978-1-60456-989-6 Emissions Trading: Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs Ervin Nagy and Gisella Varga (Editors) 2009. 978-1-60741-194-9
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Climate Change and its Causes, Effects and Prediction Series
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
EMISSIONS TRADING: LESSONS LEARNED FROM THE EUROPEAN UNION AND KYOTO PROTOCOL CLIMATE CHANGE PROGRAMS
ERVIN NAGY AND
GISELLA VARGA EDITORS
Nova Science Publishers, Inc. New York
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Copyright © 2009 by Nova Science Publishers, Inc. All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system or transmitted in any form or by any means: electronic, electrostatic, magnetic, tape, mechanical photocopying, recording or otherwise without the written permission of the Publisher. For permission to use material from this book please contact us: Telephone 631-231-7269; Fax 631-231-8175 Web Site: http://www.novapublishers.com
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
NOTICE TO THE READER The Publisher has taken reasonable care in the preparation of this book, but makes no expressed or implied warranty of any kind and assumes no responsibility for any errors or omissions. No liability is assumed for incidental or consequential damages in connection with or arising out of information contained in this book. The Publisher shall not be liable for any special, consequential, or exemplary damages resulting, in whole or in part, from the readers’ use of, or reliance upon, this material. Independent verification should be sought for any data, advice or recommendations contained in this book. In addition, no responsibility is assumed by the publisher for any injury and/or damage to persons or property arising from any methods, products, instructions, ideas or otherwise contained in this publication. This publication is designed to provide accurate and authoritative information with regard to the subject matter covered herein. It is sold with the clear understanding that the Publisher is not engaged in rendering legal or any other professional services. If legal or any other expert assistance is required, the services of a competent person should be sought. FROM A DECLARATION OF PARTICIPANTS JOINTLY ADOPTED BY A COMMITTEE OF THE AMERICAN BAR ASSOCIATION AND A COMMITTEE OF PUBLISHERS. LIBRARY OF CONGRESS CATALOGING-IN-PUBLICATION DATA Available upon request ISBN: 978-1-61728-396-3 (E-Book)
Published by Nova Science Publishers, Inc. New York
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
CONTENTS Preface Chapter 1
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Chapter 2
Chapter 3
vii Climate Change and the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS): Kyoto and Beyond Larry Parker Climate Change: The European Union’s Emissions Trading System (EU-ETS) Larry Parker International Climate Change Programs: Lessons Learned from the European Union’s Emissions Trading Scheme and the Kyoto Protocol’s Clean Development Mechanism United States Government Accountability Office
Index
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
1
35
63 123
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved. Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
PREFACE The European Union’s (EU) Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS) is a cornerstone of the EU’s efforts to meet its obligation under the Kyoto Protocol. It covers more than 10,00 energy intensive facilities across the 27 EU Member countries; covered entities emit about 45% of the EU’s carbon dioxide emissions. This book explores climate change which is generally viewed as a global issue, but proposed responses typically require action at the national level. With the 1997 Kyoto Protocol now in force and setting emissions objectives for 20082012, countries that ratified the protocol are developing appropriate implementation strategies to begin reducing their emissions of greenhouse gases. These objectives are discussed in detail in this book. Chapter 1 - The European Union’s (EU) Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS) is a cornerstone of the EU’s efforts to meet its obligation under the Kyoto Protocol. It covers more than 10,00 energy intensive facilities across the 27 EU Member countries; covered entities emit about 45% of the EU’s carbon dioxide emissions. A “Phase 1” trading period began January 1, 2005. A second, Phase 2, trading period began in 2008, covering the period of the Kyoto Protocol, with a Phase 3 proposed for 2013. Several positives resulting from the Phase 1 “learning by doing” exercise assisted the ETS in making the Phase 2 process run more smoothly, including: (1) greatly improving emissions data, (2) encouraging development of the Kyoto Protocol’s project-based mechanisms — Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) and Joint Implementation (JI), and (3) influencing corporate behavior to begin pricing in the value of allowances in decision-making, particularly in the electric utility sector. However, several issues that arose during the first phase were not resolved as the ETS moved into Phase 2, including allocation schemes, shutdown credits and
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
viii
Ervin Nagy and Gisella Varga
new entrant reserves, and others. In addition, the expansion of the EU and the implementation of the directives linking the ETS to the Kyoto Protocol project-based mechanisms created new issues to which Phase 2 had to respond. A more comprehensive response to these issues is envisioned for Phase 3. The United States is not a party to Kyoto. However, almost four years of carbon emissions trading has given the EU valuable experience in designing and operating a greenhouse gas trading system. This experience may provide some insight into cap-and-trade design issues currently being debated in the United States. •
•
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
•
•
The U.S. requires only electric utilities to monitor CO2. The EU-ETS experience suggests that expanding similar requirements to all facilities covered under a cap-and-trade scheme would be pivotal for developing allocation systems, reduction targets, and enforcement provisions. In the U.S. debate on comprehensive versus sector-specific reduction programs, the EU-ETS experience suggests that adding sectors to a trading scheme once established may be a slow, contentious process. As with most EU industries, most U.S. industry groups either oppose auctions outright or want them to be supplemental to a base free allocation. The EU-ETS experience suggests Congress may want to consider specifying any auction requirement if it wishes to incorporate market economics more fully into compliance decisions. EU-ETS analysis suggests the most important variables in determining Phase 1 allowance price changes were oil and natural gas price changes; this apparent linkage raises possible market manipulation issues, particularly with the inclusion of financial instruments such as options and futures contracts. Congress may consider whether the government needs enhanced regulatory and oversight authority over such instruments.
Chapter 2 - The European Union’s (EU’ s) Emissions Trading System (ETS) is a cornerstone of the EU’s efforts to meet its obligation under the Kyoto Protocol. It covers more than 11,500 energy intensive facilities across the 25 EU member countries, including oil refineries, powerplants over 20 megawatts (MW) in capacity, coke ovens, and iron and steel plants, along with cement, glass, lime, brick, ceramics, and pulp and paper installations. Covered entities emit about 45% of the EU’s carbon dioxide emissions. The trading program does not cover emissions of non-CO2 greenhouse gases, which account for about 20% of the EU’s total greenhouse gas emissions. The first trading period began January 1, 2005. A second trading period is scheduled to begin in 2008, with a third one planned for 2013. In
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Preface
ix
deciding on its trading program, the European Commission (EC) adopted a “learningby-doing” approach to prepare the EU for the Kyoto Protocol’s emission limitations. The EU does not have major experience with emissions trading, and the EC felt that an initial program beginning in 2005 would give the EU practical familiarity in operating such a system. At first glance, it would appear that the EU may have little difficulty meeting its Kyoto Protocol requirements during the second trading period. The anticipated deficit between the second trading period for the original 15 Member States can be covered by trading with the 10 newer Member States that anticipate a surplus. Also, credits are likely to be available through Joint Implementation (JI) and Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) projects sanctioned under the Protocol. However, there are other considerations. The availability of surplus credits created via JI and CDM is restricted by the EC requirement that such credits be “supplemental” to a country’s domestic efforts. Each country is to spell out what “supplemental” means in its National Allocation Plans (NAPs) for the second trading period. Individual countries are likely to define that term differently — restricting allowance trades and purchases in some countries. Another consideration is the overall commitment of the Kyoto Protocol. As noted earlier, the ETS covers only a percentage of the overall greenhouse gas emissions in the various Member States of the EU. Some sectors not covered by the ETS may grow faster than sectors covered by it, creating difficulties for compliance. In particular, the transportation area is already a source of concern. A final consideration for the ETS is its suitability for directing long-term investment toward a low-carbon future — the ultimate goal of any climate change program. It is too early to tell whether the ETS’s market signal and individual countries’ NAPs will move investment in the appropriate direction. The early signs are not particularly encouraging, with the 2005-2008 NAPs producing an over- allocation of allowances and one major Member State (Germany) attempting to direct its second NAP toward carbon-intensive, coal-fired electric-generating facilities rather than low-carbon alternatives. Reluctance by countries to redirect their NAPs and an inconsistent price signal from the ETS make the long-term effect of the ETS uncertain. Chapter 3 - According to available information and experts, the ETS phase I established a functioning market for carbon dioxide allowances, but its effects on emissions, the European economy, and technology investment are less certain. Nonetheless, experts suggest that it offers lessons that may prove useful in informing congressional decision making. By limiting the total number of emission allowances provided to covered entities under the program and enabling these entities to sell or buy allowances, the ETS set a price on carbon emissions. However,
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
x
Ervin Nagy and Gisella Varga
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
in 2006, a release of emissions data revealed that the supply of allowances—the cap—exceeded the demand, and the allowance price collapsed. Overall, the cumulative effect of phase I on emissions is uncertain because of a lack of baseline emissions data. The longterm effects on the economy also are uncertain. One concern about design and implementation was that the economic activities associated with emissions from covered entities would shift from the European Union to countries that do not have binding emission limits––a concept known as leakage. However, leakage does not appear to have occurred, in part because covered entities did not purchase allowances but received them for free. The effect of the ETS on technology investment also is uncertain but was likely minimal, in part because phase I was not long enough to affect such investments. Phase I of the ETS offers three key lessons: (1) accurate emissions data are essential to setting an effective emissions cap; (2) a trading program should provide enough certainty to influence technology investment; and (3) the method for allocating allowances may have important economic effects, namely, free allocation may distribute wealth to covered entities whereas auctioning could generate revenue for governments.
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
In: Emissions Trading… Editors: E. Nagy, G. Varga, pp. 1-34
ISBN: 978-1-60741-194-9 © 2009 Nova Science Publishers, Inc.
Chapter 1
CLIMATE CHANGE AND THE EU EMISSIONS TRADING SCHEME (ETS): KYOTO AND BEYOND* Larry Parker
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
ABSTRACT The European Union’s (EU) Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS) is a cornerstone of the EU’s efforts to meet its obligation under the Kyoto Protocol. It covers more than 10,00 energy intensive facilities across the 27 EU Member countries; covered entities emit about 45% of the EU’s carbon dioxide emissions. A “Phase 1” trading period began January 1, 2005. A second, Phase 2, trading period began in 2008, covering the period of the Kyoto Protocol, with a Phase 3 proposed for 2013. Several positives resulting from the Phase 1 “learning by doing” exercise assisted the ETS in making the Phase 2 process run more smoothly, including: (1) greatly improving emissions data, (2) encouraging development of the Kyoto Protocol’s project-based mechanisms — Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) and Joint Implementation (JI), and (3) influencing corporate behavior to begin pricing in the value of allowances in decision-making, particularly in the electric utility sector. However, several issues that arose during the first phase were not resolved as the ETS moved into Phase 2, including allocation schemes, shutdown credits and new entrant reserves, and others. In addition, the *
Excerpted from CRS Report RL34150, dated November 24, 2008.
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
2
Larry Parker expansion of the EU and the implementation of the directives linking the ETS to the Kyoto Protocol project-based mechanisms created new issues to which Phase 2 had to respond. A more comprehensive response to these issues is envisioned for Phase 3. The United States is not a party to Kyoto. However, almost four years of carbon emissions trading has given the EU valuable experience in designing and operating a greenhouse gas trading system. This experience may provide some insight into cap-and-trade design issues currently being debated in the United States.
•
•
•
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
•
The U.S. requires only electric utilities to monitor CO2. The EU-ETS experience suggests that expanding similar requirements to all facilities covered under a cap-and-trade scheme would be pivotal for developing allocation systems, reduction targets, and enforcement provisions. In the U.S. debate on comprehensive versus sector-specific reduction programs, the EU-ETS experience suggests that adding sectors to a trading scheme once established may be a slow, contentious process. As with most EU industries, most U.S. industry groups either oppose auctions outright or want them to be supplemental to a base free allocation. The EU-ETS experience suggests Congress may want to consider specifying any auction requirement if it wishes to incorporate market economics more fully into compliance decisions. EU-ETS analysis suggests the most important variables in determining Phase 1 allowance price changes were oil and natural gas price changes; this apparent linkage raises possible market manipulation issues, particularly with the inclusion of financial instruments such as options and futures contracts. Congress may consider whether the government needs enhanced regulatory and oversight authority over such instruments.
OVERVIEW Climate change is generally viewed as a global issue, but proposed responses typically require action at the national level. With the 1997 Kyoto Protocol now in force and setting emissions objectives for 2008-20 12, countries that ratified the protocol are developing appropriate implementation strategies to begin reducing their emissions of greenhouse gases.[1] In particular, the European Union (EU) has decided to use an emissions trading scheme (called a “cap-and-trade” program), along with other market-oriented mechanisms permitted under the Protocol, to help it achieve compliance at least cost.[2] The decision to use emission trading to
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Climate Change and the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS)
3
implement the Kyoto Protocol is at least partly based on the successful emissions trading program used by the United States to implement its sulfur dioxide (acid rain) control program contained in Title IV of the 1990 Clean Act Amendments.[3] The EU’s Emissions Trading System (ETS) covers more than 10,000 energy intensive facilities across the 27 EU Member countries, including oil refineries, powerplants over 20 megawatts (MW) in capacity, coke ovens, and iron and steel plants, along with cement, glass, lime, brick, ceramics, and pulp and paper installations. Covered entities emit about 45% of the EU’s carbon dioxide emissions. The trading program covers neither CO2 emissions from the transportation sector, which account for about 25% of the EU’s total greenhouse gas emissions, nor emissions of non-CO2 greenhouse gases, which account for about 20% of the EU’s total greenhouse gas emissions. A “Phase 1” trading period began January 1, 2005.[4] A second, Phase 2, trading period began January 1, 2008, covering the period of the Kyoto Protocol, with a Phase 3 planned to begin in 2013.[5] Under the Kyoto Protocol, the then-existing 15 nations of the EU agreed to reduce their aggregate annual average emissions for 2008-20 12 by 8% from the Protocol’s baseline level (mostly 1990 levels) under a collective arrangement called a “bubble.” By 2006, collective greenhouse gas emissions in the EU were 2.7% below Kyoto baseline levels (2.2% below 1990 levels), mostly the result of a structural shift from coal to natural gas in the United Kingdom and the incorporation of East Germany into West Germany.[6] In light of the Kyoto Protocol targets, the EU adopted a directive establishing the EU-ETS that entered into force October 13, 2003.[7] The importance of emissions trading was elevated by the accession of 12 additional central and eastern Europe countries to EU membership from May 2004 through January 2007. Collectively, the 27 Members of the expanded EU’s greenhouse gas emissions dropped 7.7% from 1990 to 2006. The EC believes that the Phase 1 “learning by doing” exercise prepared the community for the difficult task of achieving the reduction requirements of the Kyoto Protocol. Several positives resulted from the Phase 1 experience that assisted the ETS in making the Phase 2 process run smoothly, at least so far. First, Phase 1 established much of the critical infrastructure necessary for a functional emission market, including emissions monitoring, registries, and inventories. Much of the publicized difficulties the ETS experienced in the first phase can be traced to inadequate emission data.[8] Phase 1 significantly improved those data in preparation for Phase 2 implementation. Second, the ETS helped jump-start the project-based mechanisms — Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) and Joint Implementation (JI) — created under the Kyoto Protocol.[9] As stated by Ellerman and Buchner:
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
4
Larry Parker The access to external credits provided by the Linking Directive has had an invigorating effect on the CDM and more generally on CO2 reduction projects in developing countries, especially in China and India, the two major countries that will eventually have to become part of a global climate regime if there is to be one.[10]
Third, according to the EC, a key result of Phase 1 was its effect on corporate behavior. An EC survey of stakeholders indicated that many participants are incorporating the value of allowances in making decisions, particularly in the electric utility sector where 70% of firms stated they were pricing in the value of allowances into their daily operations, and 87% into future marginal pricing decisions. All industries stated that it was a factor in long-term decisionmaking.[11] However, several issues that arose during the first phase remain contentious as the ETS implements Phase 2, including allocation (including use of auctions and reliance on model projections), shutdown credits and new entrant reserves, and others. In addition, the expansion of the EU and the implementation of the linking directives create new issues to which Phase 2 has had to respond. These new and continuing challenges for Phase 2 implementation are discussed below.
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
NATIONAL ALLOCATION PLANS AND THE ETS National Allocation Plans (NAPs) are central to the EU’s effort to achieve its Kyoto obligations. Each Member of the EU must submit a NAP that lays out its allocation scheme under the ETS, including individual allocations to each affected unit. For the second trading period, these NAPs were assessed by the EC to determine compliance with 12 criteria delineated in an annex to the emissions trading directive.[12] Criteria included requirements that the emissions caps and other measures proposed by the Member State were sufficient to put it on the path toward its Kyoto target, protections against discrimination between companies and sectors, delineation of intended use of CDM and JI credits for compliance, along with provisions for new entrants, clean technology, and early reduction credits. For the second trading period, the NAP must guarantee Kyoto compliance. NAPs for the second trading period were due June 30, 2006. By October 26, 2007, the EC had reviewed and approved (sometimes conditionally) all 27 Member States’ NAPs. As indicated by table 1, the EC reduced the proposed allocations of individual Member States by an average of 10.5% to increase the probability that the EU will achieve its target under the Kyoto Protocol. The need to reduce the
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Climate Change and the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS)
5
requested allocations reflects both the structure of the ETS and the lessons the EC learned during the first phase.
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Table 1. ETS Annual Allocations for Phase 2: 2008-2012 Member State
2005 Emissions (MMTCO2E)
Proposed Kyoto Cap (MMTCO2E)
Austria Belgium Bulgaria Czech Rep. Cyprus Denmark Estonia Finland France Germany Greece Hungary Ireland Italy Latvia Lithuania Luxembourg Malta Netherlands Poland Portugal Romania Slovakia Slovenia Spain Sweden UK Total
33.4 55.4 40.6 82.5 5.1 26.5 12.62 33.1 131.3 474 71.3 26.0 22.4 225.5 2.9 6.6 2.6 1.98 80.35 203.1 36.4 70.8 25.2 8.7 182.6 19.3 242.4 2122.16
32.8 63.3 67.6 101.9 7.12 24.5 24.38 39.6 132.8 482 75.5 30.7 22.6 209 7.7 16.6 3.95 2.96 90.4 284.6 35.9 95.7 41.3 8.3 152.7 25.2 246.2 2325.34
EC Approved Kyoto Cap (MMTCO2E) 30.7 58.5 42.3 86.8 5.48 24.5 12.72 37.6 132.8 453.1 69.1 26.9 22.3 195.8 3.43 8.8 2.5 2.1 85.8 208.5 34.8 75.9 30.9 8.3 152.3 22.8 246.2 2080.93
Approved as Percent of Proposed 93.6% 92.4% 62.6% 85.2% 77% 100% 52.2% 94.8% 100% 94% 91.5% 87.6% 98.6% 93.7% 44.5% 53% 63% 71% 94.9% 73.3% 96.9% 79.3% 74.8% 100% 99.7% 90.5% 100% 89.5%
Source: European Commission, “Emissions Trading: EU-wide cap for 2008-2012 set at 2.08 billion allowances after assessment of national plans for Bulgaria,” EC Press Release, October 26, 2007.
Need for Further Emissions Reductions It is unclear to what degree the first phase of the ETS achieved real emissions reductions. Emissions are dynamic over time; a product of a country’s population,
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
6
Larry Parker
economic activity, and greenhouse gas intensity.[13] To capture these dynamics, the Member States of the EU develop emissions baselines from models that project future trends in a country’s emissions based on these and other factors, such as anticipated energy and greenhouse gas policies.[14] During the first phase, the emissions goal was to put the EU on the path to Kyoto compliance — not actually comply with the Protocol (which wasn’t necessary until the 2008-2012 time period). Thus, countries developed “business as usual” baselines based on projected growth in emissions. Such a projected baseline suffers from two sources of uncertainty: data uncertainties, and forecasting uncertainties. On data, Phase 1 suffered from uncertainties with respect to data collection and coverage, in monitoring methods for historic data, and data verification. On projecting future emissions, Phase 1 faced uncertainties with respect to economic or sector-based growth rates. Fueled in many cases by over-optimistic economic growth assumptions, these uncertainties increased the probability of inflated business as usual baselines.[15] The combination of these factors and modest reduction requirements resulted in the emissions allocations for the 2005-2007 trading period being higher than actua1 2005 emissions.[16] This result has raised questions about how much reductions achieved during Phase 1 were real as opposed to being merely paper artifacts. On the positive side, verified emissions in 2005 were 3.4% below the estimated 2005 baseline used during the allocation process. In addition, the allowance prices for 2005 stayed persistently high, suggesting some abatement was occurring and raising questions of “windfall” profits. As stated by Ellerman and Buchner: First, and most importantly, the persistently high price for EUAs [EU emissions allowances] in a market characterized by sufficient liquidity and sophisticated players must be considered as creating a presumption of abatement. It would be startling if power companies did not incorporate EUA prices into dispatch decisions that would have shifted generation to less emitting plants. There is plenty of anecdotal evidence that this was the case, and the prominent charges of windfall profits assume that the opportunity cost of freely allocated allowances was being passed on (without noting the implications for abatement). Similarly, it would be surprising if there were no changes in production processes that could be made by the operators of industrial plants.[17]
However, EU emissions allowances (EUAs) during Phase 1 did not maintain value. Phase 1 EUAs were basically worthless during the final six months of 2007. This decline in EUA prices at least partially reflected the general non-transferability of Phase 1 EUAs to Phase 2. Only Poland and France included limited banking in their Phase 1 NAPs. The EC further restricted use of Phase 1
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Climate Change and the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS)
7
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
EUAs in Phase 2 with a ruling in November, 2006.[18] As a result, excess Phase 1 EUAs were worthless at the end of 2007.[19] One consequence of the non-transferability of Phase 1 EUAs is that prices for Phase 2 EUAs have been relatively firm, as indicated by figure 1 above. This firmness may reflect the ability of the EC to certify Phase 2 NAPs using more verifiable baseline data than were available for Phase 1.[20] Scarcity is critical for the proper functioning of an allowance market. A major reason the EC rejected ex post adjustments[21] was fear that such adjustments would have a disruptive effect on the marketplace.[22] Phase 1 did not firmly establish this foundation of markets;[23] based on the Phase 2 EUA future’s market, further market development appears to be occurring, although several challenges to that development will be discussed later.
Source: ECX Exchange. Figure 1. ECX CFI Futures Contracts: Price and Volume.
Need to Adjust ETS Allocations While the environmental performance of Phase 1 may be disputed, the need for additional reductions to achieve Kyoto is not. As indicated by the orange line in figure 2, the European Environment Agency (EEA) projects that the EU-15 existing measures will halt the projected increase in greenhouse gases; however, as indicated by the red line, they are insufficient to reduce EU-15 emissions to their Kyoto requirements that began in 2008. To achieve this target the EU envisions three actions: (1) further reductions by EU-15 countries, (2) the use of Kyoto mechanisms (Joint Implementation (JI) and Clean Development Mechanism (CDM); and, (3)
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
8
Larry Parker
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
the use of carbon sinks.[24] As indicated by the blue line, the EEA projects EU-15 emissions at 11.3% below Kyoto baseline levels by 2010 — 3.3 percentage points below its commitment of 8%.[25] As discussed earlier, the EU-27 as a whole does not have an emissions target comparable to the EU-15 bubble. By 2010, EU-27 emissions are projected at 7.7% below Kyoto baseline levels assuming current policies. This reduction is projected at 10% if additional measures are included. Currently, 22 of the 25 countries with reduction requirements are projected to meet them.[26] Only three countries are not projected to meet their requirements even with additional planned measures: Denmark, Italy, and Spain.[27]
Source: European Environmental Agency, Greenhouse Gas Emissions Trends and Projects in Europe 2008, (October 2008) p. 5. Figure 2. EU-1 5 Greenhouse Gas Emissions and Projections for the Kyoto Period: 2008-2012.
As indicated by table 1 earlier, part of the EC response to the need for additional measures to meet the Kyoto requirements was to reduce Member States’ proposed ETS allocations. In the case of new Members, these reductions were substantial in some cases. Only four countries — Denmark, France, Slovenia, and the United Kingdom — had no reductions made in their proposed ETS allocations.
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Climate Change and the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS)
9
Other responses include an EC-approved proposal to impose mandatory CO2 emissions standards on light-duty vehicles.[28]
ISSUES ARISING IN PHASE 2 NAPS FOR THE ETS
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Supplementarity As noted earlier, for Phase 2, the EC has issued a linking directive permitting the use of Kyoto mechanisms for compliance. Including the linking directive has had beneficial effects on the development of JI and CDM markets and more generally on CO2 reduction projects in the developing world.[29] This emerging JI/CDM supply has the potential to largely compensate for the projected EU-1 5 shortfall in meeting the Kyoto Protocol requirements.[30] According to the World Bank, the estimated aggregate shortfall (“distance to target”) for the EU15 for Phase 2 ranges from 900-1,500 million metric tonnes of CO2e (CO2 equivalent) with an average estimate of 1,250 million. This represents an 8%-10% further reduction from projected levels and is in line with the EU estimated shortfall discussed above.[31] The World Bank cites estimates that 1,000-1,200 million metric tonnes of CO2e credits from CDM and JI projects are likely to be imported into the EU-ETS: “Put in perspective, it means that installations, using credits from CDM and JI, could be in a balanced position or a marginally short one. In the latter case, fuel switching would help bridge the gap.”[32] However, a potential barrier to this scenario is the “supplementarity” requirements of the Kyoto Protocol which is embodied in criterion 12 of the EC NAP approval process. Supplementarity requires that developed countries, such as most EU countries, ensure that their use of JI/CDM credits is supplemental to their own domestic control efforts. In defining supplementarity for Phase 2, the EC used 10% of a country’s allowance allocation as a rule of thumb in approving NAPs — with a greater limit possible based on a country’s domestic efforts to reduce emissions. As indicated in table 2, this process resulted in some significant reductions in some countries’ proposed limits (e.g., Ireland, Poland, Spain), but some increase in others (e.g., Italy, Latvia, Lithuania). Although these reductions appear substantial in individual cases, most analysts agree that they do not represent a major barrier to the cost-effective use of JI/CDM. As stated by the World Bank: The Commission assessed NAPs for imports of carbon assets (including planned and substantiated governmental purchases) ostensibly with a view to limit imports to no more than 50% of the “expected distance
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
10
Larry Parker to target” for each Member State. According to the vast majority of analysts, this does not place any practical constraints on the demand for CDM/JI from EU installations: The market received the November 2006 EU decision to impose tighter caps with an immediate increase in the price of EUA-II, while uncertainty at that time about supplementarity caps immediately dampened prices for CERs [i.e., CDM credits] (secondary CER market reacted more quickly than the more stable primary market).[33]
Table 2. JI/CDM Limits for Phase 2: 2008-2012
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Member State Austria Belgium Bulgaria Czech Rep. Cyprus Denmark Estonia Finland France Germany Greece Hungary Ireland Italy Latvia Lithuania Luxembourg Malta Netherlands Poland Portugal Romania Slovakia Slovenia Spain Sweden United Kingdom
Proposed JI/CDM Limit (% of allocation) 20% 8% 20% 10% (not included) 19% 0 12% 10% 12% 9% 10% 50% 25% 5% 9% 10% (not included) 12% 25% 10% (50% in some cases) 10% 7% (not included) 39% 20% 8%
Approved JI/CDM Limit (% of allocation) 10% 8.4% 12.6% 10% 10% 17% 0 10% 13.5% 20% 9% 10% 10% 15% 10% 20% 10% (to be determined) 10% 10% 10% 10% 7% 15.8% 20% 10% 8%
Source: Source: European Commission, “Emissions Trading: EU-wide cap for 2008-2012 set at 2.08 billion allowances after assessment of national plans for Bulgaria,” EC Press Release, October 26, 2007. Proposed JI/CDM Limits from Cambridge University, Second Phase National Allocation Plans: A Comparative Analysis, at [http://www.econ.cam.ac.uk/research/tsec/euets/].
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Climate Change and the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS)
11
The advantage of EU access to the JI/CDM market is lower costs under current market conditions. Guaranteed CDM and JI credits are currently selling at a 10%- 30% discount to EUAs, a discount that reflects risks involved in CDM/JI transactions. The degree to which this discount continues depends to some degree on the efforts of participating governments and the CDM and JI Executive Boards to streamline procedures and regulations, firm up methodological assessments, and integrate the different markets. The Chinese government has set a credit price floor of 8-9 euro — price setting that reflects its dominant role in the CDM market.[34] The ability of CDM host countries to raise this floor to reflect more fully the 15-25 euro EUA price depends on supply. In contrast to the World Bank, Point Carbon reports that its survey of respondents claimed that CDM/JI supply will be insufficient to meet EU demand. As a result, price will be set by the marginal cost of EU domestic emissions reductions (which in turn sets the ceiling on EUA prices). The availability of JI/CDM credits will reduce that marginal cost (reducing the price of EUAs), but the survey suggests that JI/CDM prices are likely to rise.[35] In contrast, if the JI/CDM availability exceeds the need of the EU, the price would be set by the marginal cost of JI/CDM credit supply — a considerably lower price as reflected by the Chinese price floor. Some observers praise the broadening and increased flexibility that CDM and JI represent in helping Annex 1 countries meet their Kyoto requirements. The World Bank argues that the flexibility enshrined in the Kyoto flexibility mechanisms and other market mechanisms (e.g., banking) is a better “safety valve” for cost concerns than a price cap as suggested in some U.S. legislation. As stated by the World Bank: Flexibility is key to ensuring that there is a built-in safety valve for compliance without resort to market distortion through price caps.... It would be appropriate to recall here that flexibility is not the goal of climate policy; rather it is a tool to help achieve the most stringent targets. In this regard, the use of flexibility mechanisms in Phase II coupled with much stronger reductions in Phase III and the unilateral European target announced for 2020 should be at stringent enough levels that can help stimulate a low carbon clean investment future. Setting an arbitrary price cap distorts the level of innovation required to meet the compliance target and dilutes the ability to meet the environment target [footnote omitted].[36]
In contrast, some environmental groups are concerned that widespread use of CDM and JI will prevent the investment in domestic efforts that the Kyoto Protocol envisioned and that will be necessary as emission caps become more stringent and more countries participate.[37] In addition to concerns about the volume of outside
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
12
Larry Parker
credits that may be used in the ETS, there are issues over the quality of the credits, particularly with respect to “additionality” — the requirement in the Kyoto Protocol that project credits represent reductions that would not have occurred in the absence of the CDM program. In expressing concern about CDM not being additional to current policies, WWF-UK states: “It is important to remember that CDM projects do not themselves reduce net global greenhouse gas emissions — they merely allow the project investor to pollute more at home. Ensuring that projects are additional is therefore crucial to maintaining the environmental integrity of the whole system as a breach of this means that global emissions actually increase.”[38] Such concerns may prevent full exploitation of CDM opportunities for some time. For Phase 2, eleven EU countries have announced their intention to use Kyoto mechanisms to meet their commitments: Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, and Slovenia.[39]
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Auction Policy In general, allowances have been allocated free to participating entities under the ETS. During Phase 1, The EU-ETS Directive allowed countries to auction up to 5% of allowance allocations, rising to 10% under Phase 2.[40] Under Phase 1, only four of twenty-five countries used auctions at all, and only Denmark auctioned the full 5%. The political difficulty in instituting significant auctioning into ETS allowance allocations is the almost universal agreement by covered entities in favor of free allocation of allowances and opposition to auctions.[41] Free allocation of allowances represents a one-time transfer of wealth to the entities receiving them from the government issuing them.[42] The resulting transfer of wealth has been described by several analysts as “windfall profits.”[43] As summarized by Ellerman and Buchner: “Allocation in the EU ETS provides one more example that, notwithstanding the advice of economists, the free allocation of allowances is not to be easily set aside.”[44] Despite concerns about windfall profits and economic distortions resulting from the free allocation of allowances, there is little change in basic allocation philosophy for Phase 2. No country proposed auctioning the maximum percentage of allowances allowed (10%). Most do not include auctions at all.[45] The unwillingness of governments to employ auctions as an allocating mechanism revolve around equity considerations, including: (1) inability of some covered entities to pass through cost because of regulation or exposure to international competition; (2) potential drag on a sector’s economic performance from the up-front cost of auctioned allowances;
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Climate Change and the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS)
13
and, (3) the potential that government will not recycle revenues to alleviate compliance costs, international competitiveness impacts, or other equity concerns, resulting in the auction costs being the same as a tax.[46] Against these concerns, economic analysis provides several arguments in favor of auctions in general, and in the case of the EU ETS in particular. General arguments in favor of auctions include:[47] • • • •
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
•
Purest embodiment of the “polluter pays” principle; Reduces distributional distortions that free allocation (and accompanying “windfall profits”) can create; Creates a “level playing field” for existing and new covered entities; Gives the potential for reducing the impact of compliance on the economy as a whole if auction revenues are used to reduce more distorting taxes on investment (i.e., “double dividend”); and Can improve emission market liquidity and transparency.
In the case of the EU-ETS, the use of free allocations rather than auctions has created some perverse incentives for covered entities and unnecessary complexity to the ETS. As discussed later in more detail, providing allowances free to existing entities can encourage the continued use of inefficient plant, and reduce the incentive for investing in efficiency improvements. The degree to which this occurs depends on the specific allocation approach taken. In contrast, an auction can help create a price floor, particularly if coupled with a reserve price, that encourages development of new technologies and efficiency improvements in existing plant. A free allocation scheme generally has to make some provision for new entrants in addition to allocating allowances to existing entities. It also raises issues with respect to existing sources that later decide to shutdown. This added complexity to the ETS is discussed next.
New Entrant Reserves Unlike previous cap-and-trade programs, the Member States of the EU have included provisions for the allocation of allowances to new entrants to the system.[48] The reasoning behind this decision is based on equity: (1) it isn’t fair to allocate allowances free to existing entities while requiring new entrants to purchase them, and (2) the EU doesn’t want to put Member States at a
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
14
Larry Parker
disadvantage in competing for new investments.[49] These equity concerns trumped concerns about economic efficiency. As is the case for existing entities, the free allocation of allowances to new entrants is a subsidy. For the ETS, the size and distribution of this subsidy is left to the individual Member States. For Phase 1, the reserve varied widely from the average of 3% of total allowances: Poland set aside only 0.4% of its allocation for new entrants while Malta set aside 26%. For Phase 2, the spread continues with Poland reserving 3.2% of its allowances for new entrants in contrast to 45% proposed by Latvia.[50] The decision to employ a new entrant reserve adds complexity to Member States’ allocation plans and influences the investment decisions of covered entities. Rules have to be promulgated with respect to the reserve’s size, manner in which the allowances are dispensed, and how to proceed if the demand either exceeds the supply, or vice versa. As indicated, countries have not harmonized new entrant reserve rules with respect to size. Likewise, there is no standardization on dispensing allowances and replenishing the reserve: first-come, first-serve with no replenishment is one approach used, but a variety of procedures have been developed both to dispense allowances and to replenish the reserve if supply is inadequate.[51] Member States also have different formulas for determining how many allowances a new entrant should receive. Member States claim to use a form of “benchmarking” to determine allowance allocations — an approach based on a standard of “best practices” or “best technology” that is applied to the new entrant’s anticipated production or capacity. However, the definitions and application of the benchmarks used by the Member States are not uniform. This diversity in approaches to addressing new entrants results in technology or fuel-specific subsidies, which vary by country. Table 3 presents the results of a study of the value of annual allocations for a natural gas combined-cycle power plant under different countries’ Phase 2 new entrant allocation rules. Assuming an allowance value of 10 euro, the plant’s allocation would vary between 0 in Sweden (no free allocation) to 11 million euro annually in Germany.[52] At the current Phase 2 allowance price of 20 euro, this annual subsidy is equivalent to the fixed annual costs of the power plant.[53] Subsidies of this magnitude are likely to affect investment decisions. As noted by Schleich, Betz, and Rogge, these subsidies: “run counter to the logic of emission trading systems, where market prices and flexibility are supposed to guide investment decisions rather than subsidies for particular types of installations.”[54]
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Climate Change and the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS)
15
Table 3. Value of Annual Allocation for New NGCC Powerplant (millions of euro, allowance price of 10 euro) Country
Value of Free Allocation
Finland
2.7
Germany
11.0
Latvia
8.3
Lithuania
10.0
Poland
10.3
Sweden
0.0
Source: Markus Ahman and Kristina Holmgren, “New entrant allocation in the Nordic energy sectors: incentives and options in the EU ETS,” 6 Climate Policy (2006), p. 430.
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Closure Policy The reverse side of the new entrant allocation issue is the what to do with the allocations to existing plants that shut down. Under U.S. cap-and-trade programs, those allowances are retained by the company, based on the assumption that a new power plant will be built to replace the closed one. For most countries in the ETS, closure policy is directly linked to the new entrant reserve: allowances allocated to existing sources that shut down are fed into the entrant reserve to be allocated to new sources. Thus, free allowances to existing facilities are tied to continued operation of that facility. One reason for this approach may be the multiple country aspect of the ETS and the political fear that owners of facilities could shut down plants in one country, keep the allowance allocation, and move to another Member State.[55] Unfortunately, this closure policy encourages inefficient facilities to continue operating to maintain the subsidy that the free allowance allocation represents. As examined by Ahman, et al.: The withdrawal of allocation based on reduced economic activity or closure makes the loss of the allocation into an additional opportunity cost affecting the production decision. In considering the marginal cost of operation, the firm will recognize that it receives the allocation if and only if it continues to operate. Consequently, the firm will not maximize its profits only with respect to the cost of production (including resource cost and the opportunity cost of allowances); in addition, it will take into account the value of the allowances that it will lose should it cease to produce output. Imposing a condition that the allocation depends on continued operation of the
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
16
Larry Parker installation transform the allocation into a production subsidy [footnote omitted].[56]
One response to the perverse incentives of the closure rule has been pioneered by Germany and adopted by a few countries. Under the “transfer rule,” owners of existing facilities being shut down can transfer the allocation from that facility to a new replacement facility.[57] For Phase 1, seven countries — Germany, Greece, Hungary, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Poland, and the UK — included transfer rules in their NAP. For Phase 2, Cyprus, Flanders (part of Belgium), and Malta have joined in including such rules in their NAPs.[58]
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Benchmarking A third aspect of free allocation is benchmarking. As noted earlier, for new entrants benchmarking involves allocating allowances based on a standard of “best practices” or “best technology” that is applied to the new entrant’s anticipated production or capacity. Environmental and other groups have advocated the expansion of benchmarking to allocations for existing facilities in addition to new entrants. However, benchmarking is very difficult given the diversity of processes involved and subject to manipulation in favor of one technology or fuelsource over another. For example, The Netherlands made a serous attempt to use benchmarks in its allocation scheme, but abandoned the effort after 125 benchmarks were developed.[59] Benchmarks can also be used to encourage investment in one fuel-source over another. This issue has arisen in the case of Germany’s proposed Phase 2 NAP. As part of Germany’s overall energy policy, the NAP provides for the “fuelneutral” allocation of allowances to new powerplants based on benchmarks reflecting current best practice for each fuel. For a coal-fired facility, the benchmark is 750 grams CO2/Kwh reflecting a conversion efficiency of 45%. For natural gas-fired facility, the benchmark is 365 grams CO2/Kwh, reflecting a conversion efficiency of 55%. These are benchmarks that current technology can achieve without the addition of any carbon capture and sequestration technology or purchase of offsets from other sources. In addition, the government proposed to provide new entrants with a guaranteed allocation of allowances based on actual emissions for 10 years after a 4 year allocation based on an 85% capacity factor. As a result, the NAP would provide almost no incentive to utilities to reduce CO2 emissions by fuel shifting, and to essentially encourage the use of lignite — Germany’s most abundant and least expensive fossil fuel.[60] This policy reflects concerns about
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Climate Change and the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS)
17
Germany becoming too dependent on imported Russian natural gas, the price of which tracks oil.[61] Indeed, economic analysis suggests that the price of an EUA would have to reach 45 euro before lower-carbon emitting natural gas-fired facilities become more economic than coal.[62] As summarized by German utility RWE’s chief financial officer: The name of our oil is lignite. We want to develop this energy source using new technology and based on environmentally friendly processes. However, governments will have to create the right political framework for this to occur.[63]
In reviewing the German proposed NAP, the EC disapproved the guarantee of allowances to new entrants that extended beyond the Kyoto compliance period (2008-20 12), but approved the fuel-specific allocation formulas.[64]
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Allocation and Energy Policy As suggested above, the conflict between national energy policies and the free workings of a carbon market are reflected in most countries’ allocation schemes. The combination of free allocations to existing facilities and new entrants, along with closure and benchmarking policies, allow countries to maintain substantial control over energy policy and related economic investment regardless of the price signals the carbon market might send if the market economics of carbon emission reductions were the sole determinant of future investments. This control has been used to preserve existing investment and jobs, encourage exploitation of domestic resources (e.g., coal, lignite) and lower energy prices. Economists argue that such a strategy is based on an economic misconception about how prices are set,[65] and is inherently contradictory. As stated by Deutsche Bank Research: The political objective frequently expressed in both the EU and Germany of achieving lower energy prices at the same time as implementing climate protection measures should be rejected. The objectives of climate protection and lower energy prices (for fossil fuels) are contradictory. Higher energy prices are desirable from an ecological point of view. Although more competition in the electricity and gas sectors could — ceteris paribus — lead to a reduction in prices, this will probably be more than outweighed in the medium term by rising commodity prices and higher fiscal burdens. In this respect, more honesty is needed from all parties.[66]
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
18
Larry Parker
The EC has put some limitations on countries’ efforts to influence investment, including disallowing any ex post adjustments and allowance guarantees. As noted above, the EC explicitly disallows any provision of a country’s NAP that guarantees allowances to covered entities beyond the phase for which the allowances are allocated. The EC argues that allocation guarantees give such installations an unfair advantage over other installations that do not get such guarantees.[67] Proponents of allocation guarantees argue it is difficult to plan new investment based on five-year allowance allocations.[68] Yet, it is precisely the long term effects of new investments and the potential that they will lock-in high carbon emitting technologies that worry some, including the EC and member governments. As stated in the Stern Review:
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
The next 10 to 20 years will be a period of transition, from a world where carbon-pricing schemes are in their infancy, to one where carbon pricing is universal and is automatically factored into decision making. In this transitional period, while the credibility of policy is still being established and the international framework is taking shape, it is critical that governments consider how to avoid the risks of locking into a high-carbon infrastructure, including considering whether any additional measures may be justified to reduce the risks.[69]
Avoiding locking-in high carbon energy technology by encouraging deployment of advanced low carbon energy technology under the ETS would involve two elements: (1) reducing behavioral distortion resulting from the current free allocation system, and (2) energy pricing that reflects carbon costs. As indicated by the previous discussions, the NAP 2 submitted to and approved by the EC generally have not reduced the distortions from the free allowance system. The primary means of reducing such distortions would be to increase the use of auctions and/or by more extensive use of benchmarking based on capacity alone (not differentiated by fuel source). As indicated above, no country has submitted a NAP that requires the full 10% auctioning allowed by the EC for Phase 2, although the number of countries auctioning at least some percentage of their allocations has grown from four in Phase 1 to nine in Phase 2. In addition, the EC allows countries to institute or expand auctions at any time without its pre-approval. Uniform benchmarks are also rare with only four countries intending to use them to any significant degree.[70] With respect to a price signal for energy development, the Phase 1 experience was instructive with respect to the value of accurate emissions inventories and registries, but not in terms of developing a price floor that would stimulate
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Climate Change and the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS)
19
development of new technology. One mechanism to develop such a floor, banking, was not used extensively during Phase 1; indeed, as noted earlier, the lack of Phase 1 to Phase 2 banking contributed to the collapse in Phase 1 prices in 2007. It is likely to be far more important in Phase 2. In the context of the ETS, options to provide a price floor beyond banking include expanding use of auctions (including incorporating a reserve price into auctions), financial instruments (such as options and futures contracts), and expansion of industries covered by the ETS. The EC is moving very slowly with respect to auctions, despite support for them by environmental groups and economists. Financial instruments are being made available to entities by the major emission exchange, although not extensively used as of yet.[71] It is the third option, expanding coverage, that the EU has stated as an important goal for Phase 3.[72] With respect to longer-term planning and investment, the EC apparently agrees that a five-year allowance allocation may be too short and believes that in order to provide greater predictability for long-term investment decisions, a longer allocation period should be considered for Phase 3.[73]
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
LOOKING TO PHASE III The European Union is committed to achieving a 20% reduction in greenhouse gas emissions by 2020 from 1990 levels. A strategic component of the effort to achieve this target is a revised ETS. Table 4 indicates the proposed EU-wide ETS cap for the next Phase of EU greenhouse gas program (Phase 3). As indicated, the EC envisions a linear reduction in the ETS cap to match the reductions target under the overall 20% reduction program. These numbers will change as individual countries decide to include more facilities under the ETS and as the EC expands ETS coverage to include other sectors and non-CO2 greenhouse gases. The following discusses some of the major changes the EU envisions for the ETS in responding to this aggressive target.
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
20
Larry Parker Table 4. Annual ETS Cap figures for Proposed Phase 3 Year
Billion metric tons of CO2e
Annual limit for Kyoto compliance period (2008-2012)
2.083
2013
1.974
2014
1.937
2015
1.901
2016
1.865
2017
1.829
2018
1.792
2019
1.756
2020
1.720
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Source: European Commission, Questions and Answers on the Commission’s Proposal to revise the EU Emissions Trading System, (Brussels, January 23, 2009), response to question 12. Note: Figures are based on the current Phase 2 scope of the ETS. These need to be adjusted for three reasons: (1) extensions of ETS scope during phase 2 by Member states; (2) extensions of ETS scope by the EC for third trading period, and (3) the figures do not include inclusion of aviation, nor the emissions from Norway, Iceland, and Liechtenstein — non-EU countries that have linked their programs to the ETS.
Eliminating NAPs The EC is proposing to re-shape the ETS to improve its efficiency and eliminate some of the problems discussed above.[74] The improved emissions inventories resulting from Phase 1 allowed the EC to harmonize the types of installations covered by the ETS across the various Member States.[75] In addition, as noted above, the EC imposed a uniform rule on the Member States preventing the use of ex-post adjustments. However, Phase 2 made little advancement in harmonizing individual countries’ allocations schemes.[76] As with Phase 1, countries continue to differ widely on the use of auctions; design and use of benchmarks; design, size, and allocation for new entrant reserves; and rules for closure. For Phase 3, the EC is proposing to eliminate NAPs, replacing them with EUwide rules with respect to allowance availability and allocations. There would be one EU-wide cap instead of the 27 national caps under Phase 1 and 2. Allowances would be allocated under EU-wide, fully harmonized rules, including those governing: (1) auctions, (2) transitional free allocations for greenhouse gas intensive, trade-exposed
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Climate Change and the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS)
21
industries, and (3) new entrants. No free allocations would be made to installations that have shut down.[77]
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Expanding Coverage Despite the EC interest in expanding the ETS, its coverage in terms of industries included for Phase 2 is essentially the same as for Phase 1. The exception is for aviation. In December, 2006, the EC proposed bringing greenhouse gas emissions from civil aviation into the ETS in two phases.[78] As agreed to by the European Parliament in July, 2008, all intra-EU and international flights will be included under the ETS beginning in 2012. Emissions would be capped at 97% of average 20042006 emissions with 85% of the allowances being allocated free to operators. The cap would be reduced to 95% in 2013. The cap and auctioning of allowances would be reviewed as a part of Phase 3 implementation. In proposing changes for the third trading period, the EC has identified three CO2 emitting sectors for inclusion under the ETS: petrochemicals, ammonia, and aluminum. The ETS would also expand beyond CO2 to include nitrous oxide (N2O) emissions from nitric, adipic, and glyoxalic acid production, and perofluorocarbon (PFC) emissions from the aluminum sector. This would expand ETS covered emissions by 4.6% over Phase 2 allowance allocations, or about 100 million metric tons.[79] The harmonization and codification of eligibility criteria for combustion installations is expected to increase the coverage by a further 40-50 million metric tons. To improve the cost-effectiveness of the ETS, the EC proposes the Phase 3 provide a small installation exemption from the scheme. Currently, the smallest 1,400 (10% of total installations covered) installations emit only 0.14% of total emissions covered. The EC proposes that combustion size limitations of 20Mw be modified to include an emissions threshold of 10,000 metric tons of CO2 annually (provided the facilities is less than 25 MW). The EC estimates that 4,200 installations would opt out — accounting for 0.70% of total ETS emissions.[80]
Auctions As noted above, the EU has made little progress on expanding the use of auctions during Phase 2. Under Phase 3, auctioning would be the “basic principle for allocation subject to the need to avoid carbon leakage.”[81] Specifically, the EC proposes to auction at least two-thirds of available allowances, beginning in 2013.
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
22
Larry Parker
The introduction of auction would be differentiated by sector. In general, for the power sector, full auctioning would beginning in 2013. For other sectors, a more gradual phase-in would be envisioned with 80% of a sector’s allocation provided free in 2013, declining linearly to zero by 2020. Concern that stringent EU carbon policies may encourage production and related greenhouse gas emissions to shift to countries without carbon policies (i.e., carbon leakage), exceptions to this phase-out of free allowances will be made in sectors where carbon leakage may occur. The EC proposal also provides for the allocation of revenues from allowance auctions. Member states will conduct the auctions and receive the revenues in proportion to their 2005 emissions and per capital income. The EC states that a percentage of the proceeds should be used to fund emission reductions, adaptation activities, renewable energy, carbon capture and storage (CC S), the Global Energy Efficiency and Renewable Energy Fund, developing countries assistance, and mitigate increases in electricity prices on lower and middle incomes.
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
SUMMARY AND CONSIDERATIONS FOR U.S. CAP-AND-TRADE PROPOSALS The United States is not a party to the Kyoto Protocol and no legislative proposal before the Congress would impose as stringent or rapid an emission reduction regime on the United States as Kyoto would have. However, through almost four years of carbon emissions trading the EU has gained valuable experience. This experience, along with the process of developing Phase 3, may provide some insight into current cap-and-trade design issues in the United States.
Emission Inventories and Target Setting The ETS experience with market trading and target setting confirms once again the central importance of a credible emissions inventory to a functioning cap-andtrade program.[82] The lack of credible EU-wide data on emissions was a direct cause of the ETS Phase 1 allowance market collapse in 2006. Arguably, the most important result of Phase 1 was the development of a credible inventory on which to base future targets and allocations. In the United States, section 821 of the 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments requires electric generating facilities affected by the acid rain provisions of Title IV to monitor carbon dioxide in accordance with EPA regulations.[83] This provision was
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Climate Change and the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS)
23
enacted for the stated purpose of establishing a national carbon dioxide monitoring system.[84] As promulgated by EPA, regulations permit owners and operators of affected facilities to monitor their carbon dioxide emissions through either continuous emission monitoring (CEM) or fuel analysis.[85] The CEM regulations for carbon dioxide are similar to those for the acid rain program’s sulfur dioxide CEM regulations. Those choosing fuel analysis must calculate mass emissions on a daily, quarterly, and annual basis, based on amounts and types of fuel used. As suggested by the EU-ETS experience, expanding equivalent data requirements to all facilities covered under a cap-and-trade program would be the foundation for developing the allocation systems, reduction targets, and enforcement provisions.
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Coverage Despite economic analysis to the contrary, the EU decided to restrict ETS coverage to six sectors that represent about 45% of the EU’s CO2 emissions.[86] This restriction was estimated to raise the cost of complying with Kyoto from 6 billion euro annually to 6.9 billion euro (1999 euro) compared with a comprehensive trading program. A variety of practical, political, and scientific reasons were given by the EC for the decision.[87] The experience of the ETS up to now suggests that adding new sectors to an existing trading program is a difficult process. As noted above, a stated goal of the EC is to expand the coverage of the ETS. However, the experience of Phase 1 did not result in the addition of any new sector until the last year of Phase 2 when aviation will be included. The EU is attempting to expand its coverage with Phase 3, but the ETS will still cover fewer sectors emitting greenhouse gases than provided under most U.S. proposals. U.S. cap-and-trade proposals generally fall into one of two categories.[88] Most bills are more comprehensive than the ETS, covering 80% to 100% of the country’s greenhouse gas emissions. At a minimum, they include the electric utility, transportation, and industrial sectors; disagreement among the bills center on the agricultural sector and smaller commercial and residential sources. In some cases discretion is provided EPA to exempt sources if serious data, economic, or other considerations dictate such a resolution. A second category of bills focuses on the electric utility industry, representing about 33% of U.S. greenhouse gases and therefore less comprehensive than the ETS. Sometimes including additional controls on non-greenhouse gas pollutants, such as mercury, these bills focus on the sources with the most experience with emission
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
24
Larry Parker
trading and the best emissions data. Other sources could be added as circumstances dictate. As noted, the EU’s experience with the ETS suggests that adding sectors to an emission trading scheme can be a slow and contentious process. If one believes that the electric utility sector is a cost-effective place to start addressing greenhouse gas emissions and that there is sufficient time to do the necessary groundwork to eventually add other sectors, then a phased-in approach may be reasonable. If one believes that the economy as a whole needs to begin adjusting to a carbonconstrained environment to meet long term goals, then a more comprehensive approach may be justified. The ETS experience suggests the process doesn’t necessarily get any easier if you wait.
Allocation Schemes
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Setting up a tradeable allowance system is a lot like setting up a new currency.[89] Allocating allowances is essentially allocating money with the marketplace determining the exchange rate. As noted above, the free allocation scheme used in the ETS has resulted in “windfall profits” being received by allowance recipients. As stated quite forcefully by Deutsche Bank Research: The most striking market outcome of emissions trading to date has been the power industry’s windfall profits, which have sparked controversy. We are all familiar with the background: emissions allowances were handed out free of charge to those plant operators participating in the emissions trading scheme. Nevertheless, in particular the producers of electricity succeeded in marking up the market price of electricity to include the opportunity-cost value of the allowances. This is correct from an accounting point of view, since the allowances do have a value and could otherwise be sold. Moreover, emissions trading cannot work without price signals.[90]
The free allocation of allowances in the ETS incorporates two other mechanisms that create perverse incentives and significant distortions in the emissions markets: new entrant reserves and closure policy. Combined with an uncoordinated and spotty benchmarking approach for both new and existing sources, the result is a greenhouse gas reduction scheme that is influenced as much or more by national policy than by the emissions marketplace. The proposed expansion of auctions for Phase 3 of the ETS could simplify allocations and permit market forces to influence compliance strategies more fully. Most countries did not employ auctions at all during Phase 1 and auctions continue
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Climate Change and the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS)
25
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
to be limited under Phase 2. No country combined an auction with a reserve price to encourage development of new technology. The EC limited the amount of auctioned allowances to 10% in Phase 2: a limit no country chose to meet. Efforts to expand auctions met opposition from industry groups, but attracted support from environmental groups and economists. The EC proposed increase of auctioning to two-thirds of total allowances for Phase 3 would represent a major development for the scheme. Currently, all U.S. cap-and-trade proposals have some provisions for auctions, although the amount involved is sometimes left to EPA discretion. Most specify a schedule that provides increasing use of auctions from 2012 through the mid-2030s with a final target of 66%-100% of total allowances auctioned. Funds would be used for a variety of purposes, including programs to encourage new technologies. A couple of proposals include a reserve price on some auctions to create a price floor for new technology. Like the situation in the ETS, most U.S. industry groups either oppose auctions outright or want them to be supplemental to a base free allocation. Given the experience with the ETS where the EC and individual governments have been unwilling or unable to move away from free allocation, the Congress, like the EC, may ultimately be asked to consider specifying any auction requirement if it wishes to incorporate market economics more fully into compliance decisions.
Flexibility and Price Volatility Despite EU rhetoric during the Kyoto Protocol negotiations, it moved into Phase 2 without a significant restriction on the use of CDM and JI credits. This embracing of project credits will significantly increase the flexibility facilities have in meeting their reduction targets. In addition, Phase 2 includes the use of banking to increase flexibility across time by allowing banked allowances to be used in Phase 3. Each of these market mechanisms is projected to reduce both the EU’s Kyoto compliance costs and allowance price volatility. As a further defense against price volatility, the European emission exchanges are creating financial instruments, such as futures contracts and options, to permit entities to hedge against price changes. Unfortunately, Phase 1 experience with the ETS does not provide much useful information on the value of market mechanisms or financial instruments in reducing costs or price volatility. The combination of poor emissions inventories, non-use of project credits, and time-limited allowances with effectively no banking resulted in extreme price volatility in Spring 2006, and
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
26
Larry Parker
virtually worthless allowances by mid- 2007. The real test for the mechanisms employed by the ETS to create a stable allowance market is Phase 2. Initial indications are that a mature market for allowances appears to be developing, Like the ETS, U.S. cap-and-trade proposals would employ a combination of devices to create a stable allowance market and encourage flexible, cost-effective compliance strategies by participating entities. All include banking. All include use of offsets, although some would place substantial restrictions on their use. One proposal incorporates a “safety valve” that would effectively place a ceiling on allowance prices. Other proposals would create a Carbon Market Efficiency Board to observe the allowance market and implement cost-relief measures if necessary. Some see this as a more flexible response with the potential for avoiding or mitigating the environmental impacts of a safety valve (i.e., increased emissions). Additionally, concern has been expressed in the United States about the regulation of allowance markets and instruments. Based on experience with the ETS, the potential for speculation and manipulation could extend beyond the emission markets. Analysis of ETS allowance prices during Phase 1 suggests the most important variables in determining allowance price changes were oil and natural gas price changes.[91] This apparent linkage between allowance price changes and price changes in two commodities markets raises the possibility of market manipulation, particularly with the inclusion of financial instruments such as options and futures contracts. Congress may ultimately be asked to consider whether the Securities and Exchange Commission, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, the Commodities Futures Trading Commission, or other body should have enhanced regulatory and oversight authority over such instruments.[92]
REFERENCES [1]
[2]
Six gases are included under the Kyoto Protocol: carbon dioxide, methane, nitrous oxide, hydrofluorocarbons, perfluorocarbons, and sulfur hexafluoride. The United States has not ratified the Kyoto Protocol and, therefore, is not covered by its provisions. For more information on the Kyoto Protocol, see CRS Report RL33 826, Climate Change: The Kyoto Protocol and International Actions, by Susan Fletcher and Larry Parker. Norway, a non-EU country, also has instituted a CO2 trading system. Various other countries and a state-sponsored regional initiative located in the northeastern United States involving several states are developing mandatory cap-and-trade system programs, but are not operating at the current
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Climate Change and the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS)
27
time. For a review of these emerging programs, along with other voluntary efforts, see International Energy Agency, Act Locally, Trade Globally (2005). [3] P.L. 101-549, Title IV (November 15, 1990). [4] For further background on the ETS and its first year of operation, see CRS Report RL33581, Climate Change: The European Union’s Emissions Trading System (EU-ETS), by Larry Parker. [5] More information, including relevant directives, on the EU-ETS is available on the European Union’s web site at [http://europa.eu.int/ scadplus/leg/en/lvb/l280 1 2.htm]. [6] European Environment Agency, Greenhouse Gas Emissions Trends and Projections in Europe 2008 (October 2008), p. 5. [7] Directive 2003/87/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 13 October 2003 establishing a scheme for greenhouse gas emissions allowance trading within the Community and amending Council Directive 96/61/EC. [8] A Denny Ellerman and Barbara K. Buchner, “The European Union Emissions Trading Scheme: Origins, Allocations, and Early Results,” 1 Environmental Economics and Policy 1 (Winter 2007), pp. 69-70; and, International Emissions Trading Association, “IETA Position Paper on EU ETS Marking Functioning,” (no date), p. 3. [9] For more on the effect of the ETS on Kyoto mechanisms, see A Denny Ellerman and Barbara K. Buchner, “The European Union Emissions Trading Scheme: Origins, Allocations, and Early Results,” 1 Environmental Economics and Policy 1 (Winter 2007), p. 84; and, International Emissions Trading Association, “IETA Position Paper on EU ETS Market Functioning,” (no date), p. 2. For more information on the Kyoto Protocol mechanisms, see CRS Report RL33826, Climate Change: The Kyoto Protocol and International Actions, by Susan Fletcher and Larry Parker. [10] A Denny Ellerman and Barbara K. Buchner, “The European Union Emissions Trading Scheme: Origins, Allocations, and Early Results,” 1 Environmental Economics and Policy 1 (Winter 2007), p. 84. [11] European Commission, Directorate General for Environment, Review of EU Emissions Trading Scheme: Survey Highlights, (November 2005), pp. 5-7. [12] Commission of the European Communities, Directive 2003/87/EC, available at [http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/ LexUriServ.do?uri= OJ:L:2003:275:0032:0046:EN: PDF].
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
28
Larry Parker
[13] For more information, see CRS Report RL33970, Greenhouse Gas Emission Drivers: Population, Economic Development and Growth, and Energy Use, by John Blodgett and Larry Parker. [14] On the role of modeling in the first phase, see A Denny Ellerman and Barbara K. Buchner, “The European Union Emissions Trading Scheme: Origins, Allocations, and Early Results,” 1 Environmental Economics and Policy 1 (Winter 2007), pp. 72-73. [15] Regina Betz and Misato Sato, “Emissions Trading: Lessons Learnt from the 1st Phase of the EU ETS and Prospects for the 2nd Phase,” 6 Climate Policy (2006), p. 354. [16] For a further discussion, see Climate Change: The European Union’s Emissions Trading System (EU-ETS), CRS Report RL33581, by Larry Parker. [17] A Denny Ellerman and Barbara K. Buchner, “The European Union Emissions Trading Scheme: Origins, Allocations, and Early Results,” 1 Environmental Economics and Policy 1 (Winter 2007), p. 83. [18] European Commission, Communication from the Commission to the Council and to the European Parliament on the assessment of national allocation plans for the allocation of greenhouse gas emission allowances in the second period of the EU Emissions Trading Scheme, COM(2006) 725 final, (November 29, 2006), p. 11. [19] For a further discussion, see Joseph Kruger, Wallace E. Oates, and William A. Pizer, “Decentralization in the EU Emissions Trading Scheme and Lessons for Global Policy, 1 Environmental Economics and Policy 1 (Winter 2007), p. 126; and, Frank J. Convery and Luke Redmond, “Market and Price Development in the European Union Emissions Trading Scheme, 1 Environmental Economics and Policy 1 (Winter 2007), pp. 96-7, 107. [20] International Emissions Trading Association, “IETA Position Paper on EU ETS Market Functioning,” (no date), p. 2. [21] Once the EC has approved a country’s NAP, including the total number of allowances and the allocation to each covered entity, the allocations can not be re-visited. Attempts to include provisions permitting such post-approval adjustments to a facility’s allocation have been uniformly rejected by the EC. [22] European Commission, Communication from the Commission to the Council and to the European Parliament on the assessment of national allocation plans for the allocation of greenhouse gas emission allowances in the second period of the EU Emissions Trading Scheme, COM(2006) 725 final, (November 29, 2006), p 8; and, A Denny Ellerman and Barbara K. Buchner, “The European Union Emissions Trading Scheme: Origins,
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Climate Change and the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS)
[23]
[24]
[25]
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
[26]
[27] [28]
[29]
[30]
29
Allocations, and Early Results,” 1 Environmental Economics and Policy 1 (Winter 2007), p. 71. On the mixed record of the EU-ETS and the need for allowance scarcity to a functioning emissions market, see Eric Haymann, EU Emission Trading: Allocation Battles Intensifying, Deutsche Bank Research (March 6, 2007). For a generally positive view of ETS market development, see Frank J. Convery and Luke Redmond, “Market and Price Development in the European Union Emissions Trading Scheme, 1 Environmental Economics and Policy 1 (Winter 2007), pp. 97-106. For a more negative view, see Karsten Neuhoff, Federico Ferrario, Michael Grubb, Etienne Gabel, and Kim Keats, “Emissions Projections 2008-2012 Versus NAPs II,” 6 Climate Policy 5 (2006), pp. 395-410. For more information on the Kyoto Protocol mechanisms, see CRS Report RL33826, Climate Change: The Kyoto Protocol, Bali ‘Action Plan,’ and International Actions, by Susan Fletcher and Larry Parker. European Environment Agency, Greenhouse Gas Emissions Trends and Projections in Europe 2008, (October 2008) p. 5. Austria, Belgium, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Portugal, Sweden, United Kingdom, Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Romania, Slovak Republic, and Slovenia. Cyprus and Malta are not Annex 1 countries. European Environmental Agency, Greenhouse Gas Emission Trends and Projections in Europe 2008 (October 2008), p. 9. See European Commission, Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council: Setting emission performance standards for new passenger cars as part of the Community’s integrated approach to reduce CO2 emissions form light-duty vehicles, COM(2007) 856 final (December 19, 2007); and, European Commission, Results of the review of the Community Strategy to reduce CO2 emissions from passenger cars and lightcommercial vehicles, (Brussels, February 7, 2007). A Denny Ellerman and Barbara K. Buchner, “The European Union Emissions Trading Scheme: Origins, Allocations, and Early Results,” 1 Environmental Economics and Policy 1 (Winter 2007), p. 84. Also, see International Emissions Trading Association, “IETA Position Paper on EU ETS Market Functioning,” (no date), p. 2. The ten other Annex 1 EU countries (mostly Eastern European “economies in transition”) are estimated by the World Bank to have an excess of Assigned
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
30
[31] [32] [33] [34]
[35] [36] [37]
[38] [39] [40]
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
[41]
[42]
[43]
[44]
[45]
[46]
Larry Parker Amount Units (AAUs) of 700-1,500 million metric tonnes of CO2e. The two other EU countries — Cyprus and Malta — are non-Annex 1 countries. The World Bank, State and Trends of the Carbon Market 2007, (Washington, D.C., May 2007) pp. 14-16, 39-40. Ibid., p. 16. Ibid., p. 16. In 2006, China supplied 70% of CDM credits. Point Carbon, Carbon 2007, (March 13, 2007), p. 18. Ibid., p. 42. The World Bank, State and Trends of the Carbon Market 2007 (Washington, DC, May 2007), p. 39. For example, see World Wildlife Fund — UK, Emission Impossible: Access to JI/CDM Credits in phase II of the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (June, 2007). Ibid., p. 7. European Environmental Agency, Greenhouse Gas Emission Trends and Projections in Europe 2008 (October 2008), p. 9. For a further discussion of auctioning and the ETS, see Cameron Hepburn, et. al., “Auctioning of EU ETS phase II allowances: how and why?” 6 Climate Policy (2006), pp. 137-160. A Denny Ellerman and Barbara K. Buchner, “The European Union Emissions Trading Scheme: Origins, Allocations, and Early Results,” 1 Environmental Economics and Policy 1 (Winter 2007), p. 73. Joseph Kruger, Wallace E. Oates, and William A. Pizer, “Decentralization in the EU Emissions Trading Scheme and Lessons for Global Policy,” 1 Environmental Economics and Policy 1 (Winter 2007), p. 114. E.g., Deutsche Bank Research, EU Emission Trading: Allocation Battles Intensifying, (March 6, 2007) pp. 2-3; and, Regina Betz and Misato Sato, “Emissions Trading: Lessons Learnt from the 1st Phase of the EU ETS and Prospects for the 2nd Phase”, 6 Climate Policy (2006), p. 353. A Denny Ellerman and Barbara K. Buchner, “The European Union Emissions Trading Scheme: Origins, Allocations, and Early Results,” 1 Environmental Economics and Policy 1 (Winter 2007), p. 85. For a review of proposed NAP 2 auction proposals as of January 12, 2007, see Karsten Neuhoff, EU ETS Auction Workshop, (Cambridge, January 12th, 2007), p. 26. Martina Priebe, Distributional Effect of Carbon-allowance Trading, (Cambridge, January 12, 2007). Also, see Eurochambres, Review of the EU Emission Trading System (June, 2007), p. 5.
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Climate Change and the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS)
31
[47] Michael Grubb, The Growing Role of Auctioning in the Economy? Or Allocation Theory and the Practice in Europe: the Great Divide, (Paris, September 25, 2006), p 4. [48] For example, the U.S. acid rain program provides no allocation of allowances to new entrants; instead, an EPA sanctioned auction is held annually to ensure that allowances are available to new entrants. New entrants can also obtain allowances from existing sources willing to sell them, either directly, through the EPA auction, or via a broker. [49] A Denny Ellerman and Barbara K. Buchner, “The European Union Emissions Trading Scheme: Origins, Allocations, and Early Results,” 1 Environmental Economics and Policy 1 (Winter 2007), p. 75. [50] Karoline Rogge, Joachim Schleich, and Regina Betz, An Early Assessment of National Allocation Plans for Phase 2 of EU Emission Trading, Fraunhofer Institute System and Innovation Research (January 2006). [51] For a summary of 18 proposed NAPs with respect to new entrant reserves, see ibid., pp. 46-47. [52] Markus Ahman and Kristina Holmgren, “New entrant allocation in the Nordic energy sectors: incentives and options in the EU ETS,” 6 Climate Policy (2006), p. 430. [53] Ibid., p. 431. Estimated at 19.5 million euro (2003$). [54] Joachim Schleich, Regina Betz, and Karoline Rogge, EU Emissions Trading — Better Job Second Time Around? Fraunhofer Institute System and Innovation Research (February, 2007), p. 23. [55] Ibid., p. 19. [56] Markus Ahman, Dallas Burtraw, Joseph Kruger, Lars Zetterberg, “A TenYear Rule to guide the allocation of EU emission allowances,” 35 Energy Policy (2007), p. 1721. [57] For a further discussion of the German NAP II, see Christoph Kuhleis, The German NAP II (London, September 13, 2006). [58] Joachim Schleich, Regina Betz, and Karoline Rogge, EU Emissions Trading — Better Job Second Time Around? Fraunhofer Institute System and Innovation Research (February, 2007), p. 19. [59] A Denny Ellerman and Barbara K. Buchner, “The European Union Emissions Trading Scheme: Origins, Allocations, and Early Results,” 1 Environmental Economics and Policy 1 (Winter 2007), p. 77. [60] Klaus Traube, Germany’s NAP — Perspectives of Concerned Actors, (Salzburg, September 30, 2004), p. 5. As noted by the EC: this approach”encourages investment in new power plants but not automatically in low CO2 emitting ones.” European Commission, Questions
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
32
[61] [62]
[63] [64]
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
[65]
[66] [67]
[68] [69]
Larry Parker and Answers on Emissions Trading and National Allocation Plants for 2008 to 2012 (Brussels, November 29, 2006) p. 4. Reported by Vera Eckert, “Germany’s Coal Power Plans Threaten EU Climate Goal,” Reuter News Service, (May 15, 2007). Analysis by Booz Allen as reported by Vera Eckert, “Germany’s Coal Power Plans Threaten EU Climate Goal,” Reuter News Service, (May 15, 2007). Statement of Klaus Sturany, “RWE Slams German NAP Decision,” Carbon Finance, (March 16, 2007), p. 1. European Commission, On the assessment of National Allocation Plans for the allocation of greenhouse gas emission allowances in the second period of the EU Emission Trading Scheme accompanying Commission Decision of 29 November 2006 on the National Allocation Plans of Germany, Greece, Ireland, Latvia, Lithuania, Luxembourg, Malta, Slovakia, Sweden and the United Kingdom in accordance with Directive 2003/87/EC. (Brussels, November 29, 2006). As stated by Cameron Hepburn, et al., in the context of auctions: “One of the widest economic misconceptions about auctioning is that it would simply add costs which would be passed through to ‘downstream’ companies and consumers. [footnoted example omitted]. Yet, if firms maximize profits, then even with free allocation they pass on the opportunity costs of allowances to downstream prices. Changing from free allocation to auctioning will have little impact on product prices. [further explanatory footnote omitted] However, because auctioning raises revenue that may be reallocated, it has, prima facie, the potential to correct distributional impacts.” Cameron Hepburn, et al., “Auctioning of EU ETS phase II allowances: how and why?” 6 Climate Policy (2006), p. 140. Deutsche Bank Research, EU Emission Trading: Allocation Battles Intensifying (March 6, 2007) p. 8. European Commission, Questions and Answers on Emissions Trading and National Allocation Plans for 2008 to 2012 (Brussels, November 29, 2006), pp. 3-4. For example, see “RWE slams German NAP decision,” Reported in Carbon Finance (March 16, 2007). Nicholas Stern, The Economics of Climate Change: The Stern Review (Cambridge, 2006), p. xix. As stated by the EC with respect to fossil fuel power plants: “The expectations of higher costs associated with CCSequipped power plants after 2020 give rise to a tangible risk. This is the risk of a “non-CCS technology lock-in” as the result of ill-considered
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Climate Change and the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS)
[70]
[71] [72] [73] [74]
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
[75] [76]
[77]
[78]
[79]
[80] [81]
33
investment decisions with respect to the coal-fired capacity due for replacement in the coming 10-15 years. It is imperative to avoid a situation where much of the new build before 2020 is undertaken in a way that would either preclude or insufficiently guarantee the addition of CCS components on a sufficiently wide scale after 2020.” European Commission, Sustainable power generation from fossil fuels: aiming for near-zero emissions from coal after 2020 (Brussels, January 10, 2007), p. 7. Joachim Schleich, Regina Betz, and Karoline Rogge, EU Emissions Trading — Better Job Second Time Around? Fraunhofer Institute System and Innovation Research (February 2007), p. 17. For example, see European Climate Exchange, The Carbon Market: How to Trade ECX Emissions Contracts (July 2007). European Commission, Limiting Global Change to 2 degrees Celsius: The Way Ahead for 2020 and Beyond (Brussels, January 10, 2007), pp. 6-7. Ibid., p. 6. European Commission, Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council amending Directive 2003/87/EC so as to improve and extend the greenhouse gas emission allowance trading system of the Community (Brussels, January 23, 2008). European Commission, Limiting Global Change to 2 degrees Celsius: The Way Ahead for 2020 and Beyond (Brussels, January 10, 2007), p. 23. Joachim Schleich, Regina Betz, and Karoline Rogge, EU Emissions Trading — Better Job Second Time Around? Fraunhofer Institute System and Innovation Research (February 2007), p. 23. European Commission, Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council amending Directive 2003/8 7/EC so as to improve and extend the greenhouse gas emission allowance trading system of the Community (Brussels, January 23, 2008) p. 9. European Commission, Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council amending Directive 2003/87/EC so as to include aviation activities in the scheme for greenhouse gas emission allowance trading within the Community (Brussels, December 12, 2006). European Commission, Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council amending Directive 2003/87/EC so as to improve and extend the greenhouse gas emission allowance trading system of the Community (Brussels, January 23, 2008), p. 4. Ibid., p. 5. Ibid., p. 7.
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
34
Larry Parker
[82] As stated by CRS in 1992: “For an economic incentive system to be effective, several preconditions are necessary. Perhaps the most important is data about the emissions being controlled. Such data are important to levy any tax, allocate any permits, and enforce any limit.” CRS Issue Brief IB92125, Global Climate: Proposed Economic Mechanisms for Reducing CO2, by Larry Parker (archived November 16, 1994), p. 9. [83] Section 821, 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments (P.L. 101-549, 42 USC 7651k). [84] S.Rept. 101-952. [85] See 40 CFR 75.13, along with appendix G (for CEMs specifications) and appendix F (for fuel analysis specifications. [86] For more background, see CRS Report RL33581, Climate Change: The European Union’s Emissions Trading System (EU-ETS), by Larry Parker. [87] Ibid., p 3. [88] For an overview of cap-and-trade proposals under the 11 0th Congress, see CRS Report RL33 846, Greenhouse Gas Reduction: Cap-and-Trade Bills in the 110th Congress, by Larry Parker and Brent D. Yacobucci. For an overview of multi-pollutant control bills, see CRS Report RL34018, Air Quality: Multipollutant Legislation in the 110th Congress, by Larry Parker and John E. Blodgett. [89] Unlike a carbon tax which uses the existing currency system to control emissions — be it euro or dollars. [90] Deutsche Bank Research, EU Emission Trading: Allocation Battles Intensifying (March 6, 2007), p. 2. [91] Maria Mansanet-Bataller, Angel Pardo, and Enric Valor, “CO2 Prices, Energy and Weather,” 28 The Energy Journal 3 (2007), pp. 73-92. [92] For a discussion of regulation of allowances as a commodity and implications for a greenhouse gas emissions market, see CRS Report RL34488, Regulating a Carbon Market: Issues Raised by the European Carbon and U.S. Sulfur Dioxide Allowance Markets, by Mark Jickling and Larry Parker.
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
In: Emissions Trading… Editors: E. Nagy, G. Varga, pp. 35-62
ISBN: 978-1-60741-194-9 © 2009 Nova Science Publishers, Inc.
Chapter 2
CLIMATE CHANGE: THE EUROPEAN UNION’S EMISSIONS TRADING SYSTEM (EU-ETS)* Larry Parker
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
ABSTRACT The European Union’s (EU’ s) Emissions Trading System (ETS) is a cornerstone of the EU’s efforts to meet its obligation under the Kyoto Protocol. It covers more than 11,500 energy intensive facilities across the 25 EU member countries, including oil refineries, powerplants over 20 megawatts (MW) in capacity, coke ovens, and iron and steel plants, along with cement, glass, lime, brick, ceramics, and pulp and paper installations. Covered entities emit about 45% of the EU’s carbon dioxide emissions. The trading program does not cover emissions of non-CO2 greenhouse gases, which account for about 20% of the EU’s total greenhouse gas emissions. The first trading period began January 1, 2005. A second trading period is scheduled to begin in 2008, with a third one planned for 2013. In deciding on its trading program, the European Commission (EC) adopted a “learning-by-doing” approach to prepare the EU for the Kyoto Protocol’s emission limitations. The EU does not have major experience with emissions trading, and the EC felt that an initial program beginning in 2005 would give the EU practical familiarity in operating such a system.
*
Excerpted from CRS Report RL33581, dated July 31, 2006.
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
36
Larry Parker At first glance, it would appear that the EU may have little difficulty meeting its Kyoto Protocol requirements during the second trading period. The anticipated deficit between the second trading period for the original 15 Member States can be covered by trading with the 10 newer Member States that anticipate a surplus. Also, credits are likely to be available through Joint Implementation (JI) and Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) projects sanctioned under the Protocol. However, there are other considerations. The availability of surplus credits created via JI and CDM is restricted by the EC requirement that such credits be “supplemental” to a country’s domestic efforts. Each country is to spell out what “supplemental” means in its National Allocation Plans (NAPs) for the second trading period. Individual countries are likely to define that term differently — restricting allowance trades and purchases in some countries. Another consideration is the overall commitment of the Kyoto Protocol. As noted earlier, the ETS covers only a percentage of the overall greenhouse gas emissions in the various Member States of the EU. Some sectors not covered by the ETS may grow faster than sectors covered by it, creating difficulties for compliance. In particular, the transportation area is already a source of concern. A final consideration for the ETS is its suitability for directing longterm investment toward a low-carbon future — the ultimate goal of any climate change program. It is too early to tell whether the ETS’s market signal and individual countries’ NAPs will move investment in the appropriate direction. The early signs are not particularly encouraging, with the 20052008 NAPs producing an over- allocation of allowances and one major Member State (Germany) attempting to direct its second NAP toward carbon-intensive, coal-fired electric-generating facilities rather than low-carbon alternatives. Reluctance by countries to redirect their NAPs and an inconsistent price signal from the ETS make the long-term effect of the ETS uncertain.
OVERVIEW Climate change is generally viewed as a global issue, but proposed responses typically require action at the national level. With the 1997 Kyoto Protocol now in force, countries that ratified the protocol are developing appropriate implementation strategies to begin reducing their emissions of greenhouse gases.[1] In particular, the European Union (EU) has decided to use an emissions trading scheme (called a “capand-trade” program), along with other market-oriented mechanisms permitted under the Protocol, to help it achieve compliance at least cost.[2] The decision to use emission trading to implement the Kyoto Protocol is at least partly based on the successful emissions trading program used by the
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Climate Change: The European Union’s Emissions Trading System
37
United States to implement its sulfur dioxide (acid rain) control program contained in Title IV of the 1990 Clean Act Amendments.[3] The EU’s Emissions Trading System (ETS) is a cornerstone of the EU’s efforts to meet its obligation under the Kyoto Protocol. It covers more than 11,500 energy intensive facilities across the 25 EU Member countries, including oil refineries, powerplants over 20 megawatts (MW) in capacity, coke ovens, and iron and steel plants, along with cement, glass, lime, brick, ceramics, and pulp and paper installations. Covered entities emit about 45% of the EU’s carbon dioxide emissions. The trading program does not cover emissions of non-CO2 greenhouse gases, which account for about 20% of the EU’s total greenhouse gas emissions. The first trading period began January 1, 2005. A second trading period is scheduled to begin in 2008, covering the period of the Kyoto Protocol, with a third one planned for 2013.[4] Under the Kyoto Protocol, the then-existing 15 nations of the EU agreed to reduce their emissions by 8% from 1990 levels under a collective arrangement called a “bubble.” By 2001, collective greenhouse gas emissions in the EU were 2.3% below 1990 levels, mostly the result of a structural shift from coal to natural gas in the United Kingdom and the incorporation of East Germany into West Germany. Several countries, including Ireland, Spain, and Portugal, experienced emissions growth of over 30% during this period.[5] In light of the Kyoto Protocol targets, the EU adopted a directive establishing the EU-ETS that entered into force October 13, 2003.[6] The importance of emissions trading was elevated by the accession of 10 additional central and eastern Europe countries to EU membership in May 2004. Collectively, these 10 countries’ greenhouse gas emissions dropped 22.6% from 1990-2001, with only Slovenia’s emissions increasing during that time (10.4%). This expansion of the EU trading zone to 25 countries greatly increases the opportunities for cost-effective allowance trades. In deciding on its trading program, the European Commission (EC) adopted a “learning-by-doing” approach to prepare the EU for the Kyoto Protocol’s emissions limitations. The EU does not have major experience with emissions trading, and the EC felt an initial program beginning in 2005 would give the EU practical familiarity in operating such a system. The EC also wanted the most comprehensive program possible. As stated in its “Green Paper”: The wider the scope of the system, the greater will be the variation in the costs of compliance of individual companies, and the greater the potential for lowering costs overall. This argues in favour of a comprehensive trading scheme across different Member States covering all 6 greenhouse gases and sinks, and encompassing all emissions sources.[7]
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
38
Larry Parker
Economic analysis conducted by the European Commission confirms the potential cost-saving available from a comprehensive trading scheme. As shown in table 1, a comprehensive trading program is estimated by the EC to reduce Kyoto compliance costs to EU countries by 3 billion euro, or one-third over a compliance scenario that does not include trading among Member countries, and by 0.9 billion euro, or 13% below the estimate cost of compliance with the trading scheme ultimately chosen by the EC. Table 1. Cost of Reaching Kyoto Target to EU Member States in 2010 (in billions of 1999 euro) No Trading Among EU Member States 9.0
EU-wide Trading Among Energy Producers
7.2
EU-wide Trading Among Energy Producers and
Energy-Intensive
EU-wide Trading
Industries
Among All Sectors
6.9
6.0
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Source: EC Green Paper (Mar. 8, 2000), p. 27.
For a variety of reasons, the EC chose a trading system with limited coverage rather than a comprehensive system covering all sources and gases. Some European analysts have noted that EU politics played an important role in preventing serious consideration of a comprehensive program. As noted by Boemare and Quirion: A significantly wider coverage could have been provided only by an upstream system, which had been excluded by the [European] Commission at the beginning of the process. The reason was again political: an upstream scheme would have too much looked like a tax.[8]
Not surprisingly, this reason was not employed by the EC in explaining its decision to create a less comprehensive trading scheme at this time. As stated by the EC: ... there are sound scientific and practical reasons why the Community might not wish to establish a comprehensive scheme at this stage. There are considerable uncertainties surrounding the emissions of the fluorinated gases [HFC, PFC, SF6] and the absorption of carbon dioxide by sinks. Allocating allowances, monitoring emissions and enforcing compliance of small mobile emitters, such as private cars, raise complex technical and administrative issues.[9]
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Climate Change: The European Union’s Emissions Trading System
39
For determining the size of the trading program, the EC looked at five criteria: (1) environmental effectiveness, (2) economic efficiency, (3) the potential effects on competition, (4) feasibility, and (5) existence of alternative policies and measures. It felt that starting with a relatively small number of economic sectors and sources that contribute significantly to total emissions and for which trading could reduce cost significantly would “substantially” satisfy these criteria.[10] As noted, the six sectors chosen emit about 45% of the EU15’s CO2 emissions (which are about 80% of the EU’s total greenhouse gas emissions). The coverage for individual countries varies widely; only 20% of France’s greenhouse gas emissions are covered, compared with 69% of Estonia’s emissions.[11]
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
IMPLEMENTING THE ETS: NATIONAL ALLOCATION PLANS National Allocation Plans (NAPs) are central to the EU’s effort to achieve its Kyoto obligations. Each Member of the EU must submit a NAP that lays out its allocation scheme under the ETS, including individual allocations to each affected unit. For the first trading period, each country had to prepare a NAP by March 31, 2004 (May 1, 2004 for the 10 new EU Members). NAPs for the second period were due June 30, 2006. These NAPs are assessed by the EC to determine compliance with 11 criteria (12 for the second period) delineated in an annex to the emissions trading directive.[12] Criteria include requirements that the emissions caps and other measures proposed by the state are sufficient to put it on the path toward its Kyoto target, protections against discrimination between companies and sectors, along with provisions for new entrants, clean technology, and early reduction credits. For the second period, the NAP must guarantee Kyoto compliance. For the first period, the EC approved most of the necessary NAPs by the end of 2004. The last NAP was approved June 20, 2006 (from Greece). In general, the primary problem the EC found with NAPs that resulted in revisions were excessive allocation of allowances and state efforts to permit “ex-post adjustments” to their allocations. Excessive allocation problems resulted from states that left a gap in how they would achieve their target, to be filled with measures to be defined later; insufficiently delineated plans to purchase allowances; and unrealistic economic or emissions growth assumptions. Ex-post adjustments by states are not allowed; such adjustments are seen by the EC as potentially disruptive to the emissions market and creating uncertainty for companies.
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
40
Larry Parker
RESULTS FROM THE FIRST YEAR
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Emissions Levels For the 2005-2007 period, the European Union is not attempting to meet the Kyoto Protocol but to get experience with emissions trading with some modest emissions targets (i.e., to put the EU on the path toward meeting the Kyoto requirements). Table 2 provides the national emissions allocations and 2005 emissions levels for 21 EU countries as recorded by the Community Independent Transaction Log (CITL) by the compliance deadline of April 30, 2006.[13] For the first trading period, the 21 countries have allocated an annual average of 1.8295 billion allowances and set aside 73.4 million allowances for allocation to new sources or for auctions. Verified emissions in 2005 for covered sources is 1.7853 billion metric tons, according to the CITL.[14] The 44.2 million allowances allocated in excess of actual 2005 emissions have been characterized by EU’s Environment Commissioner as an “over-allocation” of allowances[15] and is considered responsible for a significant drop in allowances prices in May, 2006. The 2005 emissions total reflects emissions from 8,980 sources representing more than 99% of the allowances allocated. As of April 30, 849 sources in the 21 countries had not surrendered sufficient allowances. The EC will determine whether the insufficiency is the result of technical difficulties in national registries, tardiness, or noncompliance. Noncomplying sources are subject to a 40-euro penalty for each ton of emissions in excess of surrendered allowances under the ETS. Some commentators have suggested that annual average 2005-2007 allocations that are actually 44.1 million metric tons higher than the reported 2005 emissions are neither putting the EU on the path to the Kyoto requirements nor developing the trading market. In addition, this “over-allocation” does not include the 73.4 million metric tons of allowances held in reserve by the various countries for new entrants. The Climate Action Network (CAN), a network of 365 nongovernmental organizations, stated the following: Emissions limits set by Member States for the first phase were a major disappointment. To ensure maximum environmental benefit of the ETS and the overall success of the system as a whole, they need to be strengthened considerably. The Kyoto targets require ambitious caps with absolute reductions for the phase 2008-2012.[16]
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science Publishers,
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Table 2. Summary Information Per Member State Share of installations with verified emissions reports
Installations a covered
Installations not in compliance on 30 April 2006
Annual average allocation in 2005 to 2007 in tonnesb
Annual average allocation not
Member State
CO2 emissions for 2005 in tonnes
Installations that have not reported by 30 April
Austria
33,372,841
0
100.0%
199
0
32,674,905
330,050
Belgium
55,354,096
2
99.9%
309
2
59,853,575
2,545,876
82,453,727
39
98.4%
389
96,907,832
348,020
26,090,910
2
98.9%
380
4
31,039,618
2,460,382
Estonia
12,621,824
0
100.0%
43
1
18,763,471
189,529
Finland
33,072,638
10
100.0%
578
19
44,587,032
862,952
131,147,905
17
99.7%
1075
150,500,685
4,871,317
Germany
473,715,872
13
99.8%
1842
90
495,073,574
3,926,426
Greece
71,033,294
28
99.5%
141
29
71,135,034
3,286,839
Hungary
25,714,574
13
99.0%
229
19
30,236,166
1,424,738
Ireland
22,397,678
0
100.0%
109
0
19,238,190
3,081,180
Italy
215,415,641
208
95.4%
943
647
207,518,860
15,551,575
Latvia
2,854,424
1
99.9%
92
1
4,054,431
505,760
Lithuania
6,603,869
2
99.9%
93
4
11,468,181
797,213
Netherlands
80,351,292
0
100.0%
209
0
86,439,031
2,503,305
Portugal
36,413,004
1
99.9%
243
2
36,898,516
1,262,898
Czech Republicd Denmark
France
d
allocated at the outset in tonnesc
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science Publishers,
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Table 2. (Continued). Share of installations with verified emissions reports
Installations a covered
Installations not in compliance on 30 April 2006
Annual average allocation in 2005 to 2007 in tonnesb
Annual average allocation not
30,364,848
7,180
Member State
CO2 emissions for 2005 in tonnes
Installations that have not reported by 30 April
Slovak Republicd
25,237,739
0
100.0%
175
Slovenia
8,720,550
0
100.0%
98
0
8,691,990
66,667
Spaind Sweden
181,063,141 19,306,761
29
99.1% 99.4%
800 705
31
162,111,391 22,530,831
13,162,130 678,149
United Kingdom
242,396,039
15
99.9%
768
16
209,387,854
15,527,484
Total
1,785,337,819
99.1%
9,420
1,829,476,015
73,389,670
allocated at the outset in tonnesc
Note: As all data are held in the CITL and national registries, no data are available for those Member States without an active registry. The figures in this column indicate the number of installations with active registry accounts on 30 April 2006. They differ from figures communicated in earlier press releases because they are updated for installations that opted-out for the first trading period, opted-in, and installations without open accounts. The figures in this column are allowances allocated to existing installations at the start of the scheme. The figures in this column are allowances not allocated to existing installations at the start of the scheme but put aside mainly for new entrants and auctioning (in the cases of Denmark, Hungary, Ireland, and Lithuania). Due to technical problems in the national registries of the Czech Republic, France, the Slovak Republic, and Spain, the CITL did not receive wholly reliable information on the installation level surrenders from these Member States. Therefore, some fields are empty for these Member States. All data represented in the table were communicated directly to the European Commission by the respective authorities of these Member States.
Climate Change: The European Union’s Emissions Trading System
43
In general, the EC has seen the over-allocation issue as part of the “learningby-doing” process that should help the EU in implementing the second trading period beginning in 2008. As stated in its press release: The new 2005 emissions data gives independently assessed installationlevel figures for the first time and so provides Member States with an excellent factual basis for deciding upon the caps in their forthcoming national allocations plans for the second trading period, when the Kyoto targets have to be met. The plans are subject to approval by the Commission, which will also be making extensive use of the 2005 emissions data.[17]
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Market Activity, Prices, and Impact According to Point Carbon’s proprietary databases, the EU-ETS traded 362 million metric tons of CO2 in 2005, valued at 7.218 billion euro. Brokers were responsible for 57% of the volume, exchange markets did 15%, and bilateral transactions accounted for 28%. Of the exchange market volume, the European Climate Exchange (ECX) had the largest share at 63%, followed by Nord Pool with 24%, and Powernext with 7.9%.[18] The average price for an allowance traded in 2005 was 19.9 euro, with brokered and exchanged allowances averaging 20.6 euro and bilateral transactions averaging 18.2 euro. However, allowance prices have been quite volatile since trading begin in 2005, as indicated in figure 1 below.[19] In particular, allowance prices dropped from almost 30 euro to about 9-11 euro in April and May, sparked by a series of reported over-allocation of allowances in several Member States. By July 2006, allowance prices had recovered to about 17 euro in July. There are several reasons for the overall volatility in the allowance market. The EU-ETS is a maturing but still narrow market. Monthly volumes are increasing, but have never exceeded a 1.6% share of phase 1 allocations.[20] Modest volume for a new system is not surprising; trading volumes under the U.S. Clean Air Act Title IV sulfur dioxide trading program were very thin in the beginning. Even after several years of operation, SO2 allowances prices can change unpredictably and inexplicably.[21]
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
44
Larry Parker
Note: EUA 2006, based on 30 day rolling price change. Source: Margus Kaasik, Eesti Energia, Carbon Market: EUETS (May 9, 2006), p. 14.
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Figure 1. CO2 Market: Even If No “Big” News Highly Volatile.
Some reasons for ETS allowance price derivatives are explicable. As illustrated by figure 2, the ETS market responded to a variety of regulatory, climatic, and economic events over the first trading period. Regulatory events include the late approval of NAPs for several countries, along with the resulting over-allocation causing the sudden market correction in May 2006. Climatic events influencing prices include cold weather, which increased energy usage, and dry conditions, which decreased the availability of hydroelectric power.[22] The primary economic influence on the ETS revolved around fuel prices. During 2005, Point Carbon analysis indicates 79% of the variance (R2) in allowance prices was explained by changes in fuel prices (particularly for electric power), with 23% of the variance explained by the weather. This linkage between allowance prices and the power market is not surprising, as the power sector conducted the majority of trades in 2005 and therefore significantly influenced price development.
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Climate Change: The European Union’s Emissions Trading System
45
Source: Margus Kaasik, Eesti Energia, Carbon Market: EUETS (May 9, 2006), p. 14.
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Figure 2. CO2 Market: Large Price Changes in Very Short Amount of Time.
Source: Margus Kaasik, Eesti Energia, Carbon Market: EUETS (May 9, 2006) p. 11. Figure 3. There is a Very Long-Term Correlation Between CO2 and Electricity Price: Link Via Marginal Producer.
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
46
Larry Parker
Kaasik argues that the evidence from the past year indicates that fuel prices influence carbon prices, but not the reverse. Specifically, Kaasik sees allowance prices as a derivative of natural gas and coal pricing, at least in the short-term. Assuming natural gas-fired and coal-fired generation are the marginal cost suppliers of power, allowance prices will respond positively to increasing natural gas prices or decreasing coal prices. Likewise, allowance prices will respond negatively to decreasing natural gas prices or increasing coal prices. This creates a correlation over time between allowance prices and electricity price by influencing the marginal price of electricity. How this has evolved during the first trading period is illustrated by figure 3.
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Use of Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) and Joint Implementation (JI) The EU-ETS has provisions for linking its trading scheme to the Joint Implementation (JI) and Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) components of the Kyoto Protocol for countries that have ratified it. These project-based instruments involve Annex 1 countries in the case of JI, and between Annex 1 and developing countries in the case of CDM.[23] The EC’s linking directive allows operators to fulfil their allowance obligations under the EU-ETS using credits derived from JI and CDM projects. Their credits are equivalent to allowances in environmental and economic terms, but are not interchangeable. “Certified Emissions Reductions” (CERs) under the CDM must be issued by the Clean Development Mechanism Executive Board and may be used in either the first or banked for use in the second trading period.[24] Emissions Reduction Units (ERUs) under JI are transferred from one country to another — an exchange that cannot begin until the second trading period. Neither CERs nor ERUs are converted into EU-ETS allowances; rather, they are entered directly into the surrendered allowance table. There are other restrictions on the use of CERs and ERUs. In particular, for the second trading period the amount of CERs and ERUs that can used by an affected unit is limited by a percentage specified by its country. Several EU countries have established carbon funds to pursue JI and CDM opportunities.[25] In general, CER and ERU credits have sold at a discount to ETS allowance prices. The degree of discount has depended on the riskiness of the project. CER and ERU credits are available only when the projects are completed. Thus, where buyers take the risk of non-delivery, such as an emissions reduction purchase agreement (ERPA), prices are in the range of 8-12 euro. In contrast, for CERs
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Climate Change: The European Union’s Emissions Trading System
47
already issued, or where the sellers take the risk, prices are in the range of 13-15 euro.[26] The real impact of CDM and JI on the EU-ETS system will not be fully known until the second trading period, when EU demand for credits will increase substantially and other non-EU countries would be implementing their own Kyoto compliance strategies.
ISSUES
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
To assist its review of the ETS, the EC has surveyed stakeholders’ viewpoints on ETS implementation and long-term issues.[27] The report surveys the viewpoints of participating companies, governments, industry associations, market intermediaries, and non-governmental organizations (NGOs) from June to September 2005. Asked which of 12 topics surrounding ETS implementation entities felt were most important to them, companies, industry associations, and governments all ranked topics such as emissions reduction targets, allocation rules, and rules for new entrants and closures as the most important — topics that all relate to long-term uncertainty. Table 3 indicates the top five topics according to governments surveyed, along with their corresponding ranking by other stakeholders. The five issues are discussed below. Table 3. Importance of EU ETS Topics (ranking) Topic
Governments
Companies
Industry Associations
Market Intermediaries
NGOs
Emissions
1st
1st
1st
3rd
1st
2nd
3rd
2nd
Tied for 5
3rd
2nd
5th
7th
reduction targets Further
th
harmonization of
Tied for 6th
allocation plans
Treatment of new entrants/ closures Definition of combustion
4
th
10
th
5
th
Tied for 6
Tied for 6th
Tied for 8
th
Tied for 8
th
Tied for 8
th
Tied for 4th
Tied for 1 1th
installations Inclusion of sectors and gases
th
3rd
Source: European Commission, Review of EU Emissions Trading Scheme (November 2005), p. 13.
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
48
Larry Parker
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Tightening of Emissions Caps With the over-allocation issue in the first trading period, it is likely that the EC will take a harder stance in reviewing NAPs for the second trading period. The relationship between the ETS cap for the first trading period and the estimated ETS cap for the second trading period (the Kyoto Protocol requirements) varies substantially between countries, as illustrated in table 4. In general, the original EU15 countries have to reduce their emissions caps the most to meet their share of the EU’s requirements under the Kyoto Protocol, with several countries facing doubledigit percentage reductions. As indicated, EU-15 states, on average, have to reduce their emissions caps 6.8% (119 million metric tons) from their current levels to meet their requirements under the Kyoto Protocol-based second trading period. In contrast, as a group, the newer countries and the EU as a whole are in substantially better shape.[28] At first glance, it would appear that the EU would have little difficulty meeting its Kyoto Protocol requirements during the second trading period. The anticipated deficit between the second trading period for the original 15 Member States can be covered by trading with the newer Member States that anticipate a surplus. However, there are other considerations. First, countries with potential surpluses may want to retain at least some of that surplus to help fuel their countries’ economic growth, possibly at the expense of a Member State that needs allowances. Second, the extent to which surplus credits would be created via JI, the EC linking directive, requires that such credits (including from CDM) be “supplemental” to a country’s domestic efforts. Each country is to spell out what “supplemental” means in its NAP for the second trading period. A third consideration is the overall commitment of the Kyoto Protocol. As noted earlier, the ETS only covers a percentage of the overall greenhouse gas emissions in the various Member States of the EU. The analysis provided in table 3 assumes that the ETS will have to provide a proportional amount of that reduction based on 2003 emissions. However, some sectors not covered by the ETS may grow faster than sectors covered by the ETS, creating difficulties for compliance. In particular, the transportation area has become a major source of concern. The transportation sector is not a part of the ETS and is not likely to be included before the third trading period.[29] Instead, transport controls are based on voluntary agreements with automobile manufacturers to improve fuel economy, fuel-economy labelling of cars, and promoting fuel efficiency by fiscal measures.[30] The cornerstone is the agreements with automobile manufacturers to achieve improve new car fleet average CO2 emissions rates. As announced in 1996, the objective of the EU Council of Environmental Ministers and European Parliament was to achieve a
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Climate Change: The European Union’s Emissions Trading System
49
new car fleet average CO2 emissions rate of 120 grams per kilometer (g CO2/km) by 2005, or by 2010 at the latest.[31]
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Table 4: Comparison of 1st and 2nd Trading Period ETS Caps (in millions of metric tons of CO2 Equivalent unless otherwise noted)
Austria Belgium Czech Republic Denmark Estonia Finland France Germany Greece Hungary Ireland Italy Latvia Lithuania Luxembourg Netherlands Poland Portugal Slovakia Slovenia Spain Sweden UK EU-ETS 15 EU-ETS 23
Average Annual ETS Cap a (first trading period) 33.0 62.9 97.6 33.5 19.0 45.5 156.5 499.0 74.4 31.3 22.3 232.5 4.6 12.3 3.4 95.3 239.1 38.2 30.5 8.8 174.4 22.9 245.3 1,739.1 2,182.3
Estimated Annual ETS Cap (Kyoto Protocol) 24.6 57.9 118.6 24.9 35.4 37.5 159.6 483.2 75.5 43.0 20.1 194.7 10.1 33.4 2.7 88.9 331.0 35.4 38.9 8.3 142.8 24.4 247.8 1,620.1 2,239.0
Percentage
Difference -25.5% -8.0% 21.6% -25.6% 86.5% -17.7% 2.0% -3.2% 1.5% 37.3% -9.7% -16.3% 119.8% 171.5% -19.4% -6.7% 38.4% -7.2% 27.7% -5.4% -18.1% 6.7% 1.0% -6.8% 2.6%
Source: Based on data provided in Annex 1, European Commission, “Further Guidance on Allocation Plans for the 2008 to 2012 trading period of the EU Emissions Trading Scheme” (Brussels, Dec. 12, 2005) p. 11.
This objective was not met in 2005 and is unlikely to be met by 2010. Voluntary commitments by the European, Japanese, and Korean Automobile Manufacturers Associations in 1998 and subsequently endorsed by the EC set targets of 140 g CO2/km by 2008/2009. At the end of 2005, the average new car emissions rate is about 160 g CO2/km. The rate of reduction in CO2/km for new cars would have to double for the automobile manufacturers to achieve their commitments, which appears unlikely.[32] Indeed, despite improvements in
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
50
Larry Parker
emissions rates, CO2 emissions in the EU continue to rise because of increased miles driven, increased size and weight of cars, and falling car occupancy rates. The EC 2005 progress report also notes that despite EU’s effort to increase information on fuel efficiency and CO2 emissions for consumers, the effectiveness of the effort seems low: “a significant impact on consumer’s decisions could not yet be noticed.”[33] Attempts to balance the burden between ETS and non-ETS sectors have already created tension in Germany with respect to the second trading period. In its draft NAP for the second trading period (NAP II) submitted June 28, 2006, Germany proposes to reduce its ETS allocation from about 499 million metric tons to about 471 million metric tons, a decrease of 5.6%.[34] However, Germany’s 2005 emissions were only 474 million metric tons; thus the reduction is only 0.6% from last year’s emissions. In addition, Germany is proposing to permit every new power station built between 2008 and 2012 to opt out from CO2 caps and the ETS for 14 years, generally to encourage construction of coal-fired facilities. These emissions increases will have to be covered by the non-ETS sectors — commercial, residential, and transportation. An assessment done for Greenpeace International states that the German NAP II places “a disproportionate burden for emissions reductions on the non-ETS sectors” in terms of meeting its commitments under the EU Burden Sharing agreement.[35] Policies to fill in the gap reportedly include one plan to reduce emissions by 3 million tons by training German drivers to drive more economically.[36] As noted by the EC Report cited above, the effectiveness of public education programs such as this may be problematic.
Harmonizing NAPs The EU-ETS system involves an interplay between definitions and procedures that are EU-wide and those that are nationwide. The groundwork for the system is the Kyoto Protocol, which (1) defines the pollutants and sets the countries’ emissions targets; (2) defines the scope of participation: Annex 1 countries may implement emissions trading programs, and non-Annex 1 countries may participate through the CDM; (3) defines baseline emissions years and sinks; and (4) sets national inventory and compliance requirements. Within this framework, the EU defines the elements that make the EU-ETS work, including industry participants, the unit of trade (tradeable allowances equal to 1 metric ton of CO2), trading periods, settling up procedures, and linkages within and beyond the EU. With respect to the individual Member’s NAPs, the EC harmonizes the NAPs with respect to penalties, allocation method (e.g., grandfathering), monitoring,
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Climate Change: The European Union’s Emissions Trading System
51
and registries with the goal of achieving the Kyoto targets. It allows Members flexibility with respect to allocations to individual participants, the extent to which banking is permitted, and whether to permit the auctioning of up to 10% of allowances in the second trading period. As a result of this framework, there are significant differences between Members with respect to participant definitions, industry level emissions caps and allocations, and enforcement. To increase the economic and administrative efficiency of the ETS, some stakeholders are interested in improved harmonization of NAPs by the EC. Besides the issue of new entrants and definition of affected units specifically identified by the EC survey, harmonization issues include allocation methods and the use of auctions, the degree to which JI and CDM credits may be used for compliance, and monitoring, verification, and reporting rules. Table 5 illustrates the scope of potential harmonization issues facing the EU-ETS.
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
Table 5. NAP Harmonization Issues Subject
Source of Member Differences
Definition of allowances
Financial and tax treatment of allowances
Reliable emissions inventories
Inventory standards
Banking of allowances
Whether and how much banking permitted
Emissions caps
Stringency of caps and the extent of JI and CDM credits permitted
Monitoring, verification and reporting
Procedures and processes
Allocation
Allocation methods and whether and how much auctioning permitted
National registries
Design details
Voluntary participants
Whether to allow pooling or opt-in/opt-out
Definition of mandatory participants
Definition of sectors, size, installation, new entrant, and treatment of closures
Source: Adapted from Fiona Mullins, EU ETS Implementation: Room for Harmonisation (The Royal Institute of International Affairs, 2005).
One issue of particular interest is the effort to increase the use of “benchmarking” standards in setting allocations. Benchmarking generally involves allocating allowances based on best available technology and practices, rather than on historical emissions. However, the EC does not have the authority to scrutinize allocations at the facility level, so any allocation harmonization would be on a
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
52
Larry Parker
voluntary basis (“soft harmonization”). Also, allocation schemes, such as benchmarking, may not be suitable for some industries.[37] The EC’s survey of ETS stakeholders revealed that although more than two-thirds of the respondents from the cement, aluminum, and chemical industries thought benchmarking was an “interesting alternative,” less than a third of the respondents from the pulp and paper industry and refineries thought so.[38] In many ways, diversity between Member countries with respect to the ETS is inevitable. As stated by Grubb and Neuhoff with respect to allocation: The final way in which the EU ETS differs from many other trading systems is in the devolution of allocation responsibilities, in this case to its 25 Member States. This was an essential part of the deal that enabled the adoption of the Directive: Member States would have never ceded to the European Commission the power to distribute valuable assets to their industries. Nor is the EU ETS unique in devolving powers of allocation: it is typical in a number of US systems. Moreover, there are different degrees of harmonization, applicable to different aspects of the EU ETS, and the Commission can and does seek to increase the degree of harmonization through guidance notes.[39] [footnote omitted]
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
New Entrants The economic value of allowances is nowhere more evident than in discussions of new entrants. Indeed, as noted above, Germany is proposing to permit new coalfired powerplants built between 2008-20 12 to opt-out of the ETS for the first 14 years of operation in order to encourage construction. In its survey of ETS stakeholders, the EC found that 85% of all respondents favor a harmonized approach to new entrants and closures. Nearly 75% believed that those allowances should be provided free.[40] Likewise, an EU questionnaire conducted by the European Environmental Agency’s Topic Centre on Air and Climate Change indicated that most Member States would welcome harmonization of the treatment of new entrants and closures across the EU.[41] Analogous to the U.S. acid rain program, EU states have set up reserves to provide allowances to new entrants. In general, these allowances are provided free, as that is widely seen as helping boost new investment. However, the allocation methods developed by the Member States differ. Most states have yet to dip into their reserves for new entrants; however, the importance of the reserve will increase as the ETS enters its second, and eventually third, trading period. The manner in which new entrants receive allowances may have a significant effect on the long-term
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Climate Change: The European Union’s Emissions Trading System
53
direction of investment — whether it is directed toward low-carbon opportunities or used to support continuation of current economic development irrespective of its carbon intensity. Allocating allowances according to output and not differentiating according to the carbon intensity of the project would provide an incentive to develop low carbon alternatives. An example provided by Grubb and Neuhoff: New entrant reserves should be based on output or capacity, and avoid differentiating according to the CO2-intensity of the new investment. In particular, giving more to coal than gas plants rewards investment in new coal facilities, which would conflict with objectives to tackle climate change, increase the cost of future emissions reductions, and in the long run could lead to higher electricity prices. The damaging effects would be amplified if carbon-intensive new entrants not only receive free allowances for the period 2008-2012 but also receive promises for subsequent periods.[42]
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
The proposed treatment of coal-fired powerplants by the German Government indicates how difficult it will be to direct future investment toward low-carbon projects. However, it could be argued that the long-term success of the ETS and the EU’s commitment to Kyoto and any subsequent agreements rests on such a redirection with respect to new entrants and long-term investment.
Definition of Affected Units Another area in which several Member States would like more harmonization across the EU is the definition of a combustion installation.[43] Concerns revolve around ambiguity in the current definition of a combustion installation and the number of small installations covered under the ETS. The ETS applies to energy activities for all sectors with combustion installations above 20 MW of thermal rated input, oil refineries, coke ovens, and, subject to size criteria, iron and steel, cement, lime, glass, ceramics, and pulp and paper facilities. However, Finland and Sweden opted to include small district heating installations with a rated thermal input below 20 MW.[44] In contrast, as noted previously, Germany is attempting to have some planned coal-fired powerplants, which will be large producers of CO2, able to opt-out of the ETS for 14 years. In addition to the consistency issue, small installations (between 20MW and 50MW) account for 30% (about 3,000) of the total facilities covered under the ETS, but a very small percentage of total CO2 emissions.[45] Surveying 22 Member States, 36% of the covered installations produced less than 10,000 metric tons of CO2 annually.[46] The somewhat weak emissions data available at the time of the
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
54
Larry Parker
EU questionnaire suggest that while three-quarters of all emissions are produced by the largest 7.5% of installations, the small installations (under 10,000 metric tons) are responsible for less than 1%. Whether the ETS should continue to cover the roughly 3,500 facilities under 10,000 metric tons annually remains a hotly debated issue.
Expansion of Coverage
Copyright © 2009. Nova Science Publishers, Incorporated. All rights reserved.
In choosing a gradual, incremental approach to emissions trading, the EU is relying on other programs to control greenhouse gas emissions in other sectors, such as transportation. The difficulties the EC may encounter in not choosing a comprehensive approach to begin with is suggested by its survey of stakeholders. The survey suggests that the future direction of the ETS in terms of increasing coverage is toward incrementally adding more economic sectors, rather than addressing the more complex issue of a comprehensive system. Based on the survey, the focus is currently on the chemical, aviation, and aluminum industries.[47] Given that the number-one recommendation for future implementation of the ETS is to provide participants with a longer time frame for implementation, it is unclear when the ETS will become as comprehensive as the European Commission would like.
CONCLUSION At first glance, the ETS would appear an effective vehicle for the EU to meet its Kyoto Protocol obligations during the second trading period. The anticipated deficit between the second trading period for the original 15 Member States can be covered by trading with the newer Member States that anticipate a surplus. In addition, potential CERs and ERUs from the CDM and JI respectively may help maintain limits on allowance costs. Table 6 provides one series of estimates of available allowances for the Kyoto Protocol’s five-year compliance period. Obviously, not all these allowances may be available to the EU alone; other countries, such as Japan and Canada, may decide to incorporate emissions trading into their implementation strategies and acquire allowances from these sources. Yet, the totals suggest that all else being equal, the supply of allowances would be adequate.
Emissions Trading : Lessons Learned from the European Union and Kyoto Protocol Climate Change Programs, Nova Science
Climate Change: The European Union’s Emissions Trading System
55
Table 6. International Supply of Emissions Credits and Allowances (cumulative total 2008-20 12, million metric tons CO2) Source of Supply
Low Estimate
High Estimate
Clean Development Mechanism (CERs)
680
1,200
Joint Implementation (ERUs
120
980
Surplus Kyoto Allowances from Eastern Europe, Russia, and the Ukraine (AAUs)