124 58 19MB
English Pages 495 Year 2023
Pengfei Ni · Marco Kamiya · Jing Guo · Haidong Xu
The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion Global Urban Competitiveness Report (2019–2020)
The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
National Academy of Economic Strategy, CASS (NAES, CASS) United Nations Human Settlements Programme, UN-HABITAT
Pengfei Ni · Marco Kamiya · Jing Guo · Haidong Xu
The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion Global Urban Competitiveness Report (2019–2020)
Pengfei Ni Center for City and Competitiveness Chinese Academy of Social Sciences Beijing, China Jing Guo School of Government Management Shenzhen University Shenzhen, China
Marco Kamiya Division of Digital Transformation and Artificial Intelligence Strategy United Nations Industrial Development Organization Vienna, Austria Haidong Xu National Academy of Economic Strategy Beijing, China
ISBN 978-981-99-3552-9 ISBN 978-981-99-3553-6 (eBook) https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-99-3553-6 Jointly published with China Social Sciences Press The print edition is not for sale in China (Mainland). Customers from China (Mainland) please order the print book from: China Social Sciences Press. © China Social Sciences Press 2023 This work is subject to copyright. All rights are solely and exclusively licensed by the Publisher, whether the whole or part of the material is concerned, specifically the rights of translation, reprinting, reuse of illustrations, recitation, broadcasting, reproduction on microfilms or in any other physical way, and transmission or information storage and retrieval, electronic adaptation, computer software, or by similar or dissimilar methodology now known or hereafter developed. The use of general descriptive names, registered names, trademarks, service marks, etc. in this publication does not imply, even in the absence of a specific statement, that such names are exempt from the relevant protective laws and regulations and therefore free for general use. The publishers, the authors, and the editors are safe to assume that the advice and information in this book are believed to be true and accurate at the date of publication. Neither the publishers nor the authors or the editors give a warranty, expressed or implied, with respect to the material contained herein or for any errors or omissions that may have been made. The publishers remain neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. This Springer imprint is published by the registered company Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd. The registered company address is: 152 Beach Road, #21-01/04 Gateway East, Singapore 189721, Singapore
Contributors
Authors Marco Kamiya, Director of UN-HABITAT Urban Economics & Finance Bureau Ni Pengfei, Director of Center for City & Competitiveness, CASS Guo Jing, Assistant Professor, School of Government Management, Shenzhen University Li Bo, Ph.D., Associate professor at Tianjin University of Technology Ma Hongfu, Ph.D., Lecturer at Tianjin University of Finance and Economics Xu Haidong, Assistant Professor, National Academy of Economic Strategy, CASS Liz Paterson Gauntner, Consultant of the UN-HABITAT Serge Allou, UCLG World Secretariat Luc Aldon, UCLG World Secretariat Huáscar Eguino, Inter-American Development Bank Axel Radics, Inter-American Development Bank Mosha.A.C, University of Botswana Martim O. Smolka, Senior fellow of Lincoln Institute of Land Policy Gong Weijin, Ph.D., National Academy of Economic Strategy, CASS Li Qihang, Ph.D., Associate professor at Shandong University of Finance and Economics Cao Qingfeng, Ph.D., Lecturer at Tianjin University of Finance and Economics Guo Jinhong, Ph.D., Candidate at Nankai University Peng Xuhui, Ph.D., National Academy of Economic Strategy, CASS
Statistical and Big Data group Group Leaders: Wang Yu, Center for City & Competitiveness, CASS
v
vi
Contributors
Li Jianquan, Center for City & Competitiveness, CASS, Beijing Ultrawpower Software, Co., Ltd. Xu Shuai, Beijing Wenge Group Co., Ltd. Wang Xiaodong, Beijing Wenge Group Co., Ltd. Group Members: Liu Xiaokang, Center for City & Competitiveness, CASS Beijing Ultrawpower Software, Co., Ltd. Xing Wentao, Center for City & Competitiveness, CASS Bin Youcai, Center for City & Competitiveness, CASS Hu Min, Center for City & Competitiveness, CASS Hu Xufeng, Center for City & Competitiveness, CASS Luo Zikang, Beijing Wenge Group Co., Ltd. Liu Xingchen, Beijing Wenge Group Co., Ltd. Liu Jing, Beijing Wenge Group Co., Ltd. Chen Jie, Jiangxi University of science and technology Li Moxuan, Nankai University Xu Zhen, School of foreign languages, Peking University Chen Haichao, School of Economics and Management, Dalian University of Technology Zheng Yuhan, School of Art, Peking University Qin Yige, Honorary college of Tianjin Foreign Languages University Fan Uunying, School of International Relations, CASS Tang Keyu, School of English, Tianjin Foreign Languages University
Report Coordinators Huang Jin, Center for City & Competitiveness, CASS Liu Shangchao, Center for City & Competitiveness, CASS Zhang Yi, Consultant of UN-Habitat Guo Jing, Ph.D., Candidate at Graduate School of CASS
Contents
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
1
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31 2.1 From the Micro Level, the Change of Leading Cities Causes the Basic “Cell” Change of the World . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31 2.2 From the Perspective of Macro Structure, the Evolution of Global Urban System Determines the Change of the world’s Pattern and System . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52 2.3 From the Perspective of Macro Gross, Global Urban Development Has Completed the Epoch-Making Transformation of Human Civilization . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 73 2.4 From the Perspective of Space, the Changes of Global Cities’ Characteristics Determine the Evolution of world’s Characteristics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97 2.5 From the Dynamic Mechanism, the Human Development Momentum Bred by Cities Determines the Appearance and Change of the Urban World . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 111 3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.1 Global Trends in Municipal Finance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.2 Municipal Finance, Localization of the SDGs and the Role of UCLG . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.3 Subnational Finance in Latin American and the Caribbean: Recent Trends and Challenges . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.4 Municipal Finance in Africa with Special Focus on Botswana . . . . . 3.5 Charges to Building Rights: A Notable Value Capture Experience from Brazil . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.6 Conclusions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
133 133 144 157 168 179 186 187
vii
viii
Contents
4 Global Urban Economic Competitiveness Performance . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.1 Top 20 Cities: Fierce Competition Makes the Position Fluctuate Greatly, Global Comprehensive Centers and Technology Centers have Generally Improved, while Specialized Cities and Manufacturing Centers Declined Overall . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.2 Top 200 Cities: Europe Has More Cities Declined in the Ranking While Asia Has More Cities Improved . . . . . . . . . . . 4.3 Top 10 Urban Agglomerations: Northern California Has the Highest Average and Rhein-Ruhr Has the Smallest Internal Difference . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.4 Three Main Economies: China Has More Cities Declined in the Ranking, While Some European Cities Have Declined Steeply . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.5 Global Pattern: The Overall Level Has Declined, but the Divergence Has Narrowed. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.6 Global Sub-Regional Pattern: Northern China and Eastern Europe Declined While Southern China and India Rose in Ranking . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5.1 Local Factors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5.2 Living Environment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5.3 Soft Environment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5.4 Hard Environment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5.5 Global Contacts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5.6 Industrial Quality . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6 Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness Performance . . . . . . . . . . . 6.1 Top 20 Cities: Europe Holds the Most Seats, While Asia Has the Highest Mean Value . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.2 Top 200 Cities: Asia Holds the Most Seats and Europe Has the Highest Mean Value . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.3 Top 10 Urban Agglomerations: Seoul Has the Highest Mean Value, and Rhein-Ruhr is Best Balanced . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.4 Three Main Economics: The United States and the European Union Far Surpass China, and the Development of US Cities is of Potential . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.5 Global Pattern: North American and Western European Cities Perform Well and with Small Divergence, While Asian Cities Stay in Low Level and with Significant Internal Difference . . . . . . .
193
193 195
198
201 203
206 209 209 216 224 232 242 248 257 307 307 308 311
313
318
Contents
ix
6.6 Global Sub-regional Pattern: Coastal Cities and Cities Located in Temperate Zone Are Leading . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 321 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7.1 Economic Vitality . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7.2 Environmental Thoroughness . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7.3 Social Inclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7.4 Scientific and Technological Innovation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7.5 External Contacts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8.2 Theory and Method . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8.3 Empirical Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
325 325 336 344 351 359 367 419 419 423 427 471
Appendix . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 473 Afterwords . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 489
Chapter 1
Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
New York-Newark
United States
A+
1
1
0.8638
3
London
United Kingdom
A+
0.8762
2
0.8246
4
Singapore
Singapore
B
0.8614
3
0.9026
1
Shenzhen
China
C+
0.8403
4
0.7136
19
San Jose
United States
C
0.8359
5
0.6491
33
Tokyo
Japan
A+
0.834
6
0.9012
2
San Francisco-Oakland
United States
B
0.8284
7
0.8083
5
Munich
Germany
B
0.8009
8
0.7238
15
Los Angeles-Long Beach-Santa Ana
United States
B
0.7986
9
0.757
9
Shanghai
China
B+
0.795
10
0.6614
29
Dallas-Fort Worth
United States
B
0.7911
11
0.639
41
Houston
United States
B
0.7892
12
0.7034
24
Hong Kong
China
B
0.7876
13
0.8028
7
Dublin
Ireland
B
0.7857
14
0.5049
134
Seoul
Republic of Korea
B+
0.7752
15
0.7263
14
Boston
United States
B
0.7737
16
0.7161
17
Beijing
China
A
0.7602
17
0.6412
38
Guangzhou
China
C+
0.7509
18
0.6011
67
Miami
United States
C+
0.7257
19
0.6981
25
Chicago
United States
B+
0.7205
20
0.7478
10
Paris
France
A
0.7199
21
0.806
6
Frankfurt am Main
Germany
C+
0.7088
22
0.712
20
Tel Aviv-Yafo
Israel
D+
0.7065
23
0.6338
44 (continued)
© China Social Sciences Press 2023 P. Ni et al., The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-99-3553-6_1
1
2
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Seattle
United States
C+
0.704
24
0.6543
30
Suzhou
China
C
0.6879
25
0.611
58
Stockholm
Sweden
B
0.6826
26
0.7289
13
Philadelphia
United States
C+
0.6789
27
0.7092
21
Stuttgart
Germany
C
0.6744
28
0.7182
16
Osaka
Japan
B
0.6645
29
0.7701
8
Toronto
Canada
B
0.6575
30
0.7076
22
Baltimore
United States
C
0.6555
31
0.6177
50
Bridgeport-Stamford
United States
D
0.6549
32
0.5676
81
Dusseldorf
Germany
C
0.6521
33
0.5111
125
San Diego(US)
United States
C
0.6501
34
0.6141
54
Geneva
Switzerland
C
0.6489
35
0.6042
64
Atlanta
United States
B
0.6487
36
0.6514
32
Cleveland
United States
C
0.6486
37
0.6463
34
Perth
Australia
C
0.6422
38
0.6125
55
Denver-Aurora
United States
C+
0.6415
39
0.6321
45
Detroit
United States
C
0.6395
40
0.6021
66
Istanbul
Turkey
B
0.6381
41
0.5814
74
Nanjing
China
C+
0.6331
42
0.565
83
Wuhan
China
C
0.6305
43
0.5128
122
Taipei
China
B
0.6293
44
0.7051
23
Charlotte
United States
C
0.6277
45
0.5023
138
Nashville-Davidson
United States
C
0.6192
46
0.4935
145
Minneapolis-Saint Paul
United States
C+
0.6151
47
0.4856
150
Berlin
Germany
B
0.6148
48
0.689
26
Austin
United States
C
0.6127
49
0.5971
68
Hamburg
Germany
C+
0.6102
50
0.6318
46
Vienna
Austria
B
0.6019
51
0.6372
43
Abu Dhabi
United Arab Emirates
C
0.6
52
0.4269
224
Raleigh
United States
C
0.5999
53
0.6095
59
Chengdu
China
C+
0.5996
54
0.4943
143
Cologne
Germany
D+
0.5985
55
0.5916
71
Las Vegas
United States
C
0.5973
56
0.5197
117
Zurich
Switzerland
C+
0.5966
57
0.6268
47
Salt Lake City
United States
C
0.5848
58
0.6151
53
Richmond
United States
C
0.583
59
0.579
76
Copenhagen
Denmark
C+
0.5817
60
0.6174
51
Orlando
United States
C
0.5795
61
0.5961
69 (continued)
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
3
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Moscow
Russian Federation
B
0.5784
62
0.7343
12
Sydney
Australia
B
0.5783
63
0.6435
35
Hangzhou
China
C
0.5765
64
0.5085
130
Wuxi
China
D+
0.5763
65
0.5361
103
Barcelona
Spain
B
0.5757
66
0.7366
11
Birmingham
United Kingdom
C
0.5736
67
0.6423
37
Changsha
China
C
0.5727
68
0.4745
165
Milwaukee
United States
D+
0.5692
69
0.5456
95
Vancouver
Canada
C
0.5682
70
0.6075
61
Brussels
Belgium
B
0.5656
71
0.6032
65
Dubai
United Arab Emirates
C+
0.5653
72
0.5408
98
Calgary
Canada
C
0.5652
73
0.5209
116
Doha
Qatar
C
0.5622
74
0.5641
84
Hannover
Germany
C
0.5599
75
0.6158
52
Qingdao
China
C
0.5595
76
0.4941
144
Columbus
United States
C
0.5585
77
0.5727
79
Sendai
Japan
D+
0.5579
78
0.4856
151
Louisville
United States
D+
0.5559
79
0.5323
105
Essen
Germany
D+
0.5548
80
0.5271
107
Chongqing
China
C
0.5545
81
0.3911
284
Tianjin
China
C
0.5543
82
0.527
108
Kuala Lumpur
Malaysia
C+
0.5535
83
0.6093
60
Foshan
China
D+
0.5522
84
0.5264
109
Washington, DC
United States
C+
0.548
85
0.612
56
Ulsan
Republic of Korea
D
0.5456
86
0.5795
75
Oklahoma City
United States
D+
0.5448
87
0.4527
192
Manchester
United Kingdom
C
0.5445
88
0.6517
31
Riyadh
Saudi Arabia
C
0.5434
89
0.5592
89
Ningbo
China
C
0.5429
90
0.4838
154
Phoenix-Mesa
United States
C
0.5427
91
0.5667
82
Antwerp
Belgium
D+
0.5424
92
0.5606
87
Amsterdam
Netherlands
B
0.5416
93
0.607
62
Zhengzhou
China
C
0.5412
94
0.4782
159
Tampa-St. Petersburg
United States
C
0.5396
95
0.5107
126
Baton Rouge
United States
D+
0.5329
96
0.4674
173 (continued)
4
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Cincinnati
United States
C
0.5307
97
0.4216
234
Dortmund
Germany
D+
0.5296
98
0.5334
104
Changzhou
China
D+
0.5291
99
0.4802
158
Haifa
Israel
D+
0.5276
100
0.5618
85
Montreal
Canada
C+
0.5261
101
0.6408
40
Jakarta
Indonesia
C
0.5248
102
0.4229
231
Nagoya
Japan
C
0.5223
103
0.6253
48
Dongguan
China
D+
0.5223
104
0.5166
121
San Antonio
United States
C
0.5215
105
0.491
148
Hiroshima
Japan
D+
0.52
106
0.6429
36
Oslo
Norway
C+
0.5199
107
0.4838
153
Dresden
Germany
D+
0.5192
108
0.5217
113
Hague
Netherlands
D+
0.5163
109
0.5048
136
Indianapolis
United States
C
0.5155
110
0.4631
181
Provo-Orem
United States
E+
0.5147
111
0.4823
157
Hamilton
Canada
D+
0.5136
112
0.5048
135
Macao
China
D+
0.5134
113
0.4929
146
Gold Coast
Australia
D
0.5116
114
0.467
176
Kansas City
United States
D+
0.5109
115
0.4578
186
Leipzig
Germany
D+
0.5105
116
0.5053
133
Virginia Beach
United States
D
0.509
117
0.5209
115
Jedda
Saudi Arabia
D
0.5086
118
0.5089
128
Bangkok
Thailand
C+
0.508
119
0.4673
174
Brisbane
Australia
C
0.508
120
0.5251
111
Nantong
China
D+
0.5076
121
0.4217
233
Pittsburgh
United States
C
0.5073
122
0.4613
183
Melbourne
Australia
C+
0.5064
123
0.6806
27
Helsinki
Finland
C+
0.5042
124
0.5868
72
Madrid
Spain
B
0.5026
125
0.7147
18
Kaohsiung
China
D+
0.4989
126
0.5114
124
Charleston-North Charleston
United States
D+
0.4982
127
0.4407
205
Mexico City
Mexico
C
0.4981
128
0.5608
86
Hartford
United States
D+
0.4977
129
0.5605
88
Ottawa-Gatineau
Canada
C
0.4965
130
0.4652
177
Incheon
Republic of Korea
C
0.4962
131
0.6113
57
Sapporo
Japan
D+
0.4948
132
0.5582
90
Riverside-San Bernardino
United States
D
0.4939
133
0.4368
215 (continued)
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
5
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Bristol
United Kingdom
C
0.4935
134
0.432
219
Gothenburg
Sweden
D+
0.4934
135
0.4182
241
Allentown
United States
D
0.4912
136
0.3836
298
Rome
Italy
B
0.4864
137
0.6652
28
Colorado Springs
United States
D
0.4863
138
0.4963
142
Grand Rapids
United States
D
0.4861
139
0.4093
257
Lille
France
D+
0.4858
140
0.4829
155
jinan
China
C
0.4848
141
0.4407
206
Kitakyushu-Fukuoka
Japan
D
0.4846
142
0.6231
49
Milan
Italy
B
0.4839
143
0.641
39
Providence
United States
D+
0.4834
144
0.4708
169
Hefei
China
C
0.4831
145
0.4462
199
Lyon
France
C
0.4829
146
0.5072
131
Samut Prakan
Thailand
E
0.4828
147
0.4436
201
Quanzhou
China
D
0.4821
148
0.4021
268
Xiamen
China
C
0.4818
149
0.5486
94
Xi’an
China
C
0.4813
150
0.4477
197
Edmonton
Canada
C
0.48
151
0.4029
265
Rotterdam
Netherlands
C
0.4781
152
0.4754
163
Fuzhou(FJ)
China
C
0.4769
153
0.4163
246
Birmingham(US)
United States
D
0.4766
154
0.406
261
Honolulu
United States
D+
0.4765
155
0.4539
190
Santiago de Chile
Chile
C
0.4758
156
0.5378
100
Columbia
United States
C
0.4756
157
0.437
214
West Yorkshire
United Kingdom
D
0.475
158
0.5917
70
Worcester
United States
D
0.4745
159
0.5086
129
Dayton
United States
D
0.4745
160
0.4248
229
Delhi
India
C
0.4743
161
0.4044
262
San Jose
Costa Rica
D+
0.4713
162
0.5186
119
Yangzhou
China
D
0.4711
163
0.4038
263
Auckland
New Zealand
C+
0.47
164
0.5249
112
Cape Coral
United States
E+
0.4679
165
0.4406
207
Valencia
Spain
C
0.4678
166
0.5764
77
Lima
Peru
C
0.4661
167
0.5128
123
Akron
United States
D
0.4652
168
0.4102
255
Bogota
Colombia
C+
0.465
169
0.5187
118
Liverpool
United Kingdom
C
0.4647
170
0.4824
156 (continued)
6
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Medina
Saudi Arabia
D
0.4646
171
0.5172
120
Knoxville
United States
D+
0.4644
172
0.4068
258
Zhuhai
China
D+
0.4644
173
0.4554
189
Zhenjiang
China
D
0.464
174
0.4363
217
Yantai
China
D+
0.4632
175
0.4116
253
Marseille-Aix-en-Provence France
C
0.463
176
0.4438
200
Sheffield
United Kingdom
D+
0.4625
177
0.4107
254
Jerusalem
Israel
D+
0.4624
178
0.5734
78
Belfast
United Kingdom
D+
0.4602
179
0.5093
127
Taizhou(js)
China
D
0.4593
180
0.3909
285
Panama City
Panama
D+
0.4585
181
0.4173
243
Bucuresti
Romania
C
0.4585
182
0.4371
212
Venice
Italy
D+
0.458
183
0.4771
161
Sacramento
United States
D+
0.4574
184
0.3792
305
Dalian
China
C
0.4573
185
0.4527
193
Glasgow
United Kingdom
C
0.4571
186
0.5425
96
Buffalo
United States
D+
0.4555
187
0.5034
137
Manila
Philippines
D+
0.4554
188
0.3361
380
Mecca
Saudi Arabia
E+
0.4544
189
0.45
196
New Haven
United States
D+
0.4543
190
0.5069
132
Xuzhou
China
D+
0.4533
191
0.3973
278
Busan
Republic of Korea
D+
0.4526
192
0.5496
92
Warsaw
Poland
C+
0.451
193
0.3835
299
Ogden
United States
D
0.4507
194
0.461
184
Changwon
Republic of Korea
E+
0.4501
195
0.4029
264
Buenos Aires
Argentina
C+
0.4484
196
0.638
42
Nanchang
China
D+
0.4451
197
0.4199
238
Gwangju
Republic of Korea
D
0.4435
198
0.5565
91
Daejeon
Republic of Korea
D+
0.4433
199
0.583
73
Shenyang
China
C
0.4429
200
0.4614
182
Zaragoza
Spain
D
0.4426
201
0.4998
140
Adelaide
Australia
C
0.4407
202
0.5417
97
Dongying
China
D
0.4404
203
0.3777
308
Monterrey
Mexico
D+
0.4399
204
0.4021
269 (continued)
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
7
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Gebze
Turkey
D
0.4387
205
0.3863
290
Zhongshan
China
D+
0.4368
206
0.4903
149
Prague
Czech Republic
C+
0.4368
207
0.4412
203
Montevideo
Uruguay
D+
0.4365
208
0.4558
188
Astana
Kazakhstan
D
0.4359
209
0.6054
63
Shaoxing
China
D
0.4355
210
0.4027
266
Toulouse
France
C
0.4332
211
0.4409
204
Lisbon
Portugal
C
0.433
212
0.4845
152
Taichung
China
D
0.4327
213
0.5262
110
Omaha
United States
D+
0.4327
214
0.3614
330
Jiaxing
China
D
0.432
215
0.4275
222
Bologna
Italy
C
0.4285
216
0.4642
178
Memphis
United States
D+
0.4278
217
0.4362
218
Nantes
France
D+
0.4273
218
0.3897
288
Daegu
Republic of Korea
D+
0.4266
219
0.538
99
Mumbai
India
C+
0.4262
220
0.3443
357
Ankara
Turkey
C
0.4261
221
0.4269
225
Naples
Italy
C
0.4253
222
0.5487
93
Nice
France
D+
0.4242
223
0.3842
296
Liege
Belgium
D
0.4232
224
0.5021
139
Verona
Italy
D+
0.4229
225
0.4694
171
Leicester
United Kingdom
D+
0.4225
226
0.474
166
Poznan
Poland
D
0.4165
227
0.4179
242
Sarasota-Bradenton
United States
D
0.4161
228
0.3423
365
Nottingham
United Kingdom
D+
0.4159
229
0.4154
247
Izmir
Turkey
D+
0.4154
230
0.4191
239
Bordeaux
France
C
0.4149
231
0.3554
342
Changchun
China
D+
0.4149
232
0.4012
270
Budapest
Hungary
C+
0.4146
233
0.4563
187
Toulon
France
D
0.4144
234
0.3507
347
Weihai
China
D
0.4122
235
0.3887
289
Bremen
Germany
D+
0.4118
236
0.3243
405
Shizuoka-Hamamatsu M.M.A.
Japan
D
0.4116
237
0.4704
170
Rosario
Argentina
D
0.411
238
0.4262
227
Wuhu
China
D
0.4105
239
0.3394
373 (continued)
8
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Zibo
China
D
0.4098
240
0.4122
251
Rochester
United States
C
0.4093
241
0.4272
223
Hsinchu
China
D
0.4091
242
0.3771
309
Malaga
Spain
D+
0.4047
243
0.5376
101
Florence
Italy
D+
0.4045
244
0.4599
185
Guiyang
China
D+
0.4033
245
0.373
313
Quebec
Canada
D+
0.4027
246
0.4098
256
New Orleans
United States
D+
0.4006
247
0.4671
175
Genoa
Italy
D+
0.3988
248
0.4213
235
Tainan
China
D
0.3961
249
0.4748
164
Tulsa
United States
D
0.3953
250
0.3404
371
Weifang
China
D
0.3947
251
0.3674
322
Bursa
Turkey
D
0.3944
252
0.4199
237
Albany
United States
D+
0.3938
253
0.2568
576
Kumamoto
Japan
E+
0.3938
254
0.413
250
Yancheng
China
D
0.3923
255
0.3438
358
Winnipeg
Canada
D+
0.3918
256
0.3978
277
Tangshan
China
D
0.3893
257
0.3916
283
Sao Paulo
Brazil
B
0.3874
258
0.5679
80
Dammam
Saudi Arabia
D
0.3863
259
0.4767
162
Shijiazhuang
China
D+
0.385
260
0.3814
301
Santa Fe
Argentina
D
0.3818
261
0.3513
346
Wenzhou
China
D+
0.3814
262
0.3853
294
Yichang
China
D
0.3814
263
0.3281
398
Taizhou(zj)
China
D
0.381
264
0.3701
317
Torino
Italy
D+
0.3809
265
0.4965
141
Pretoria
South Africa
D
0.3805
266
0.5313
106
Kunming
China
C
0.3794
267
0.3648
324
Niigata
Japan
E+
0.3791
268
0.4403
208
Maracaibo
Venezuela
E+
0.3766
269
0.4061
260
Rio de Janeiro
Brazil
C
0.3756
270
0.4917
147
Huizhou
China
D
0.3742
271
0.3901
287
Guadalajara
Mexico
D+
0.373
272
0.3854
292
Surabaya
Indonesia
D
0.3727
273
0.3987
274
Sharjah
United Arab Emirates
D
0.3724
274
0.4201
236
Maracay
Venezuela
E+
0.3716
275
0.4025
267
Bakersfield
United States
D
0.3687
276
0.3685
320
Krakow
Poland
C
0.3682
277
0.3862
291 (continued)
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
9
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Jundiai
Brazil
E+
0.3673
278
0.3303
391
Baotou
China
D
0.3668
279
0.3301
392
Santo Domingo
Dominican Republic
D
0.3658
280
0.4368
216
Tyumen
Russian Federation
E
0.3645
281
0.3767
310
Tongling
China
D
0.3641
282
0.2571
574
Xiangyang
China
D
0.3641
283
0.3185
417
Kuwait City
Kuwait
D
0.3636
284
0.4224
232
Johannesburg
South Africa
C
0.3624
285
0.4693
172
Saint Petersburg
Russian Federation
D+
0.3621
286
0.5215
114
Bangalore
India
C
0.361
287
0.3688
319
Taiyuan
China
D+
0.3603
288
0.3995
272
Karaj
Islamic Republic of Iran
E+
0.3601
289
0.4276
221
Porto
Portugal
C
0.3597
290
0.4512
195
Huaian
China
D
0.3596
291
0.3309
390
Lodz
Poland
D
0.3595
292
0.3597
333
Nanning
China
D+
0.359
293
0.3608
331
Hohhot
China
D
0.359
294
0.3524
345
Barcelona-Puerto La Cruz
Venezuela
D+
0.3587
295
0.4535
191
Fresno
United States
D
0.3578
296
0.3364
379
Valencia(Venezuela)
Venezuela
D
0.3564
297
0.4427
202
Jining
China
D
0.356
298
0.3386
374
Ordoss
China
E+
0.3559
299
0.3259
401
Ashgabat
Turkmenistan E+
0.3556
300
0.2926
473
San Juan
Puerto Rico
D+
0.3554
301
0.4729
168
Harbin
China
C
0.3553
302
0.3561
339
Ahvaz
Islamic Republic of Iran
E+
0.3533
303
0.4471
198
Cairo
Egypt
C
0.3531
304
0.2925
474
Catania
Italy
D+
0.3508
305
0.4385
210
Almaty
Kazakhstan
D+
0.3501
306
0.3692
318
Zhoushan
China
D
0.3495
307
0.3497
349
Dhaka
Bangladesh
D+
0.3493
308
0.3049
443
Sofia
Bulgaria
C
0.3493
309
0.4634
180
El Paso
United States
D
0.3486
310
0.3728
314
Portland
United States
C
0.3483
311
0.3944
281 (continued)
10
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Oran
Algeria
D
0.3483
312
0.365
323
Johor Bahru
Malaysia
D
0.347
313
0.4396
209
Padova
Italy
D+
0.3468
314
0.3839
297
Jinhua
China
D
0.3458
315
0.3607
332
Caracas
Venezuela
D+
0.3441
316
0.4384
211
Newcastle upon Tyne
United Kingdom
E+
0.344
317
0.414
249
Luoyang
China
D
0.3432
318
0.3451
356
Adana
Turkey
D
0.342
319
0.3803
302
Huzhou
China
D
0.3419
320
0.3476
353
Porto Alegre
Brazil
D+
0.3418
321
0.4182
240
Taian
China
E+
0.3412
322
0.3479
352
Langfang
China
D
0.3411
323
0.3462
354
Antalya
Turkey
D
0.3407
324
0.3193
414
Urumqi
China
D+
0.3401
325
0.3951
280
Baku
Azerbaijan
D+
0.3392
326
0.3747
312
Zhuzhou
China
D
0.3391
327
0.3406
370
Guatemala City
Guatemala
D
0.3389
328
0.3492
350
Putian
China
E+
0.3379
329
0.3226
409
Leon
Mexico
D+
0.3375
330
0.464
179
Albuquerque
United States
D+
0.3354
331
0.3091
435
Xiangtan
China
D
0.334
332
0.3429
362
Bari
Italy
D+
0.3335
333
0.4173
244
Xuchang
China
D
0.3328
334
0.3342
385
Buraydah
Saudi Arabia
E
0.3328
335
0.3056
440
Tripoli
Libya
D
0.3318
336
0.33
395
Muscat
Oman
D
0.3318
337
0.4165
245
Tijuana
Mexico
D
0.3306
338
0.4153
248
Zagreb
Croatia
C
0.3301
339
0.3538
343
Mendoza
Argentina
D
0.3292
340
0.4263
226
Be’er Sheva
Israel
E
0.3289
341
0.3795
304
Nairobi
Kenya
C
0.3281
342
0.324
407
McAllen
United States
E+
0.3276
343
0.3414
369
Minsk
Belarus
D+
0.3274
344
0.4513
194
Amman
Jordan
D+
0.3269
345
0.4772
160
Shantou
China
D
0.3268
346
0.3556
341
Mar Del Plata
Argentina
E+
0.3263
347
0.3159
422
Jiaozuo
China
D
0.3261
348
0.353
344
Havana
Cuba
D
0.3253
349
0.4065
259 (continued)
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
11
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Ipoh
Malaysia
E+
0.3252
350
0.3678
321
Lianyungang
China
D
0.3251
351
0.3276
400
Dezhou
China
D
0.3238
352
0.3227
408
Samarinda
Indonesia
E+
0.3238
353
0.3427
364
Greater Vitória
Brazil
E
0.3227
354
0.426
228
San Luis Potosi
Mexico
D
0.3222
355
0.3783
307
Yueyang
China
D
0.3218
356
0.3185
418
Suqian
China
E+
0.3184
357
0.299
460
Cordoba
Argentina
D
0.3179
358
0.396
279
Liaocheng
China
D
0.3172
359
0.3277
399
Medellin
Colombia
D+
0.3167
360
0.401
271
Ezhou
China
E+
0.3162
361
0.3174
419
Thessaloniki
Greece
D+
0.3135
362
0.3789
306
Belo Horizonte
Brazil
D+
0.3124
363
0.3589
335
Rizhao
China
E+
0.3122
364
0.3191
416
Chennai
India
C
0.3121
365
0.3015
453
Linyi
China
D
0.3109
366
0.3125
426
Baghdad
Iraq
D
0.3107
367
0.3908
286
Binzhou
China
D
0.3101
368
0.3144
424
Haikou
China
D+
0.3098
369
0.3624
328
Curitiba
Brazil
D
0.3097
370
0.3351
382
Lanzhou
China
D+
0.3085
371
0.3435
360
Cangzhou
China
D
0.3079
372
0.3203
413
Ma’anshan
China
D
0.3073
373
0.2974
465
Hufuf-Mubarraz
Saudi Arabia
E
0.3072
374
0.2244
688
Tehran
Islamic Republic of Iran
D+
0.3072
375
0.474
167
Zaozhuang
China
E+
0.3061
376
0.3416
367
Cali
Colombia
D
0.3049
377
0.3572
337
Luanda
Angola
D
0.3035
378
0.4239
230
Riga
Latvia
C
0.303
379
0.3009
455
Jiangmen
China
D
0.3021
380
0.3241
406
Sao Jose dos Campos
Brazil
E+
0.3019
381
0.3594
334
Beirut
Lebanon
D+
0.3017
382
0.3459
355
Palermo
Italy
D+
0.3016
383
0.3917
282
Pekanbaru
Indonesia
E+
0.3016
384
0.3333
387
Yinchuan
China
D
0.3015
385
0.3381
376
Liuzhou
China
D
0.3013
386
0.2989
462
Xinyu
China
E+
0.3006
387
0.2968
466 (continued)
12
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Merida
Mexico
D
0.2999
388
0.3618
329
Villahermosa
Mexico
E+
0.2997
389
0.3356
381
Cancun
Mexico
D
0.2987
390
0.2907
477
Changde
China
D
0.2985
391
0.3006
456
San Miguel de Tucuman
Argentina
E+
0.2977
392
0.2521
599
Asuncion
Paraguay
D
0.2975
393
0.3847
295
Ribeirao Preto
Brazil
D
0.2974
394
0.3634
326
Lagos
Nigeria
D+
0.2972
395
0.3798
303
Xianyang
China
E+
0.2968
396
0.3212
412
Maoming
China
E+
0.2965
397
0.3065
439
Balikpapan
Indonesia
E+
0.2954
398
0.3053
441
Tucson
United States
C
0.2951
399
0.3416
368
Deyang
China
E+
0.2945
400
0.3034
447
Longyan
China
E+
0.2936
401
0.2696
530
Campinas
Brazil
D+
0.2934
402
0.3853
293
Santiago de Los Caballeros Dominican Republic
D
0.2934
403
0.398
276
Quito
Ecuador
D+
0.2931
404
0.3821
300
Valparaiso
Chile
D
0.293
405
0.3749
311
Queretaro
Mexico
D
0.2922
406
0.3558
340
Joinville
Brazil
E+
0.292
407
0.2975
464
Huangshi
China
E+
0.2907
408
0.302
452
Seville
Spain
D+
0.2906
409
0.3984
275
Zhangzhou
China
D
0.2898
410
0.3285
397
Wroclaw
Poland
D+
0.2893
411
0.2876
486
Zunyi
China
D
0.2893
412
0.2663
537
Benin City
Nigeria
E+
0.2892
413
0.2263
684
Torreon
Mexico
E+
0.2886
414
0.3431
361
Batam
Indonesia
E+
0.2886
415
0.3436
359
Hengyang
China
D
0.2867
416
0.3
458
Sanming
China
E+
0.2863
417
0.2606
559
Kolkata
India
D+
0.2862
418
0.2563
578
Wuhai
China
E+
0.286
419
0.1736
831
Beihai
China
D
0.2858
420
0.3032
449
Panjin
China
E+
0.2855
421
0.316
421
Ho Chi Minh City
Viet Nam
D+
0.2851
422
0.2044
743
Jieyang
China
E+
0.2844
423
0.3011
454
Denizli
Turkey
E+
0.2832
424
0.1933
787
Zhaoqing
China
D
0.2828
425
0.2957
467 (continued)
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
13
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Ufa
Russian Federation
D
0.2815
426
0.3639
325
Yulin(sx)
China
E+
0.2814
427
0.2814
498
Cape Town
South Africa
C
0.2813
428
0.4304
220
Port Harcourt
Nigeria
E+
0.2812
429
0.2851
491
Matamoros
Mexico
E+
0.2808
430
0.3348
384
Panzhihua
China
E+
0.2799
431
0.2745
517
Jiujiang
China
D
0.2799
432
0.2817
497
Durban
South Africa
D
0.2794
433
0.3725
315
Brasilia
Brazil
D+
0.2793
434
0.437
213
Karachi
Pakistan
D+
0.278
435
0.2661
539
Juarez
Mexico
D
0.278
436
0.4119
252
Kuching
Malaysia
E+
0.2778
437
0.3001
457
Heze
China
D
0.2764
438
0.2806
503
Anyang
China
D
0.2755
439
0.3077
436
Athens
Greece
C+
0.2753
440
0.5363
102
Zhanjiang
China
D
0.2753
441
0.3046
444
Ningde
China
D
0.2749
442
0.2699
528
Baoji
China
E+
0.2747
443
0.2812
500
Puyang
China
E+
0.2746
444
0.2945
471
Chenzhou
China
E+
0.273
445
0.2777
509
Hanoi
Viet Nam
D+
0.2725
446
0.2023
749
Bengbu
China
D
0.2722
447
0.284
494
Kochi
India
D
0.2719
448
0.2903
478
Xining
China
D
0.2713
449
0.3027
450
Xinxiang
China
D
0.2712
450
0.3101
432
Kaifeng
China
D
0.2711
451
0.305
442
Sorocaba
Brazil
E+
0.2711
452
0.3156
423
Toluca
Mexico
E+
0.2707
453
0.3252
404
Coimbatore
India
D
0.2695
454
0.2813
499
Yingtan
China
E+
0.2682
455
0.2981
463
Handan
China
D
0.2677
456
0.322
411
Owerri
Nigeria
E+
0.2674
457
0.1977
770
Yangjiang
China
E+
0.2671
458
0.2761
511
Zigong
China
D
0.2668
459
0.276
512
Aguascalientes
Mexico
E+
0.2662
460
0.3498
348
Saltillo
Mexico
E+
0.2658
461
0.3193
415
Samara
Russian Federation
D
0.2651
462
0.357
338
Malappuram
India
E+
0.2649
463
0.2339
656 (continued)
14
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Bandung
Indonesia
D
0.2647
464
0.3122
427
Sanya
China
D
0.2644
465
0.2912
476
Cartagena
Colombia
D
0.264
466
0.3377
377
Liupanshui
China
E+
0.264
467
0.2633
553
Yingkou
China
E+
0.2631
468
0.2417
621
Recife
Brazil
D
0.2628
469
0.3375
378
Phnom Penh
Cambodia
D
0.2627
470
0.2542
590
Erbil
Iraq
E+
0.2617
471
0.3995
273
Villavicencio
Colombia
E+
0.2613
472
0.1889
796
Pingxiang
China
E+
0.2611
473
0.2803
504
Shangrao
China
E+
0.2609
474
0.2746
516
Luohe
China
E+
0.2605
475
0.2918
475
Hebi
China
E+
0.26
476
0.281
501
Jingmen
China
E+
0.2593
477
0.2648
547
Uyo
Nigeria
E+
0.2586
478
0.1957
778
Aba
Nigeria
E+
0.2576
479
0.2106
729
Yuxi
China
E+
0.2571
480
0.2686
532
San Salvador
El Salvador
D
0.2567
481
0.3349
383
Mersin
Turkey
D
0.2566
482
0.2324
664
La Plata
Argentina
D
0.2565
483
0.2701
527
Nanyang
China
D+
0.2563
484
0.3103
431
Concepcion
Chile
D
0.2562
485
0.2019
751
Samsun
Turkey
E+
0.2551
486
0.2696
529
Guilin
China
D
0.255
487
0.2877
485
Colombo
Sri Lanka
D+
0.2545
488
0.2293
671
Chaozhou
China
E+
0.2543
489
0.2884
483
Baoding
China
D
0.2542
490
0.2885
482
Perm
Russian Federation
D
0.2538
491
0.3293
396
Semarang
Indonesia
D
0.253
492
0.2474
609
Yichun(jx)
China
E+
0.2517
493
0.2659
542
Ganzhou
China
D
0.2513
494
0.272
526
Karamay
China
E+
0.2505
495
0.2537
593
Ikorodu
Nigeria
E
0.2504
496
0.348
351
Guayaquil
Ecuador
D
0.2504
497
0.3161
420
Tbilisi
Georgia
D+
0.2503
498
0.29
479
Jilin
China
D
0.2496
499
0.3221
410
Zhoukou
China
E+
0.2496
500
0.2636
552
Makassar
Indonesia
D
0.2493
501
0.278
508 (continued)
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
15
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Lahore
Pakistan
D
0.2488
502
0.2395
632
Pingdingshan
China
D
0.2488
503
0.2883
484
Quzhou
China
D
0.2488
504
0.2648
548
Yaroslavl
Russian Federation
E
0.2485
505
0.2859
490
Neijiang
China
E+
0.2484
506
0.2284
674
Liaoyuan
China
E
0.2484
507
0.2364
646
Shangqiu
China
E+
0.2476
508
0.2655
544
Hyderabad
India
C
0.2471
509
0.2446
615
Ziyang
China
E+
0.2467
510
0.2771
510
Pune
India
C
0.2465
511
0.2847
492
Sanmenxia
China
E+
0.2463
512
0.2638
550
Loudi
China
E+
0.2462
513
0.2661
540
Mianyang
China
D
0.2451
514
0.269
531
Belgrade
Serbia
C
0.2447
515
0.358
336
Xiaogan
China
E+
0.2447
516
0.2649
545
Abuja
Nigeria
D
0.2443
517
0.3254
403
Ahmedabad
India
D
0.2441
518
0.2316
666
Huaibei
China
E+
0.2434
519
0.2731
521
Londrina
Brazil
D
0.2422
520
0.2754
514
Jingdezhen
China
E+
0.2421
521
0.2649
546
Qinhuangdao
China
D
0.2418
522
0.2953
468
Benxi
China
E+
0.2414
523
0.2722
524
Yibin
China
D
0.2414
524
0.257
575
Nanping
China
D
0.2413
525
0.2417
622
Port Elizabeth
South Africa
D
0.2412
526
0.3066
438
Culiacan
Mexico
E+
0.2412
527
0.3043
445
Luzhou
China
D
0.2411
528
0.2727
523
Zhumadian
China
E+
0.2407
529
0.2587
568
Ta’if
Saudi Arabia
E
0.2407
530
0.2442
617
Fangchenggang
China
E+
0.2406
531
0.2462
611
Hermosillo
Mexico
D
0.2403
532
0.3098
433
Yiyang
China
E+
0.2402
533
0.2588
567
Liaoyang
China
E+
0.2401
534
0.2754
515
Alexandria
Egypt
D+
0.2399
535
0.2735
519
Trujillo
Peru
E+
0.2398
536
0.2844
493
Anshan
China
D
0.2395
537
0.3256
402
Xinyang
China
D
0.2395
538
0.255
586
Arequipa
Peru
E+
0.2394
539
0.3036
446 (continued)
16
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Huainan
China
D
0.2393
540
0.2553
584
Jingzhou
China
E+
0.2392
541
0.2589
566
Palembang
Indonesia
E+
0.2374
542
0.2894
480
Tolyatti
Russian Federation
E
0.2371
543
0.2658
543
Chihuahua
Mexico
D
0.237
544
0.2757
513
Xianning
China
D
0.237
545
0.2556
583
Chuzhou
China
E+
0.2369
546
0.2517
600
Port Said
Egypt
E+
0.2366
547
0.2151
718
Songyuan
China
E+
0.2363
548
0.2663
538
Reynosa
Mexico
E+
0.2358
549
0.295
469
Shymkent
Kazakhstan
E+
0.2356
550
0.299
461
Shiyan
China
D
0.2353
551
0.2579
572
Gaza
State of Palestine
E+
0.2347
552
0.2383
637
Khartoum
Sudan
D
0.2343
553
0.2397
630
Fortaleza
Brazil
D
0.2339
554
0.3301
394
Uberlandia
Brazil
E+
0.2336
555
0.2867
488
Maturín
Venezuela
E
0.2334
556
0.2497
605
Leshan
China
E+
0.2332
557
0.2524
596
Jinzhou
China
D
0.2331
558
0.2938
472
Barnaul
Russian Federation
E
0.233
559
0.2806
502
Chittagong
Bangladesh
E+
0.2324
560
0.2545
589
Kano
Nigeria
E+
0.2323
561
0.2596
562
Wuzhou
China
E+
0.2322
562
0.2581
571
Goiania
Brazil
D
0.232
563
0.3097
434
Suining
China
E+
0.232
564
0.2523
597
Kozhikode
India
E+
0.2319
565
0.2595
563
Grande Sao Luis
Brazil
E
0.2308
566
0.2868
487
Saratov
Russian Federation
E+
0.2305
567
0.3105
429
Daqing
China
D
0.2304
568
0.3335
386
Fushun
China
D
0.2299
569
0.272
525
Belem
Brazil
D
0.2298
570
0.3105
428
Tunis
Tunisia
D+
0.2294
571
0.3397
372
Meishan
China
E+
0.2288
572
0.2541
591
Jincheng
China
E+
0.2288
573
0.2618
556
Hengshui
China
E+
0.2287
574
0.2591
564
Medan
Indonesia
D
0.2281
575
0.2669
535 (continued)
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
17
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Weinan
China
E+
0.2276
576
0.2563
579
Guangan
China
E+
0.2269
577
0.2443
616
Huanggang
China
E+
0.2265
578
0.2363
647
Ibadan
Nigeria
E+
0.2263
579
0.2056
738
San Pedro Sula
Honduras
E+
0.226
580
0.2438
618
Tegucigalpa
Honduras
D
0.226
581
0.2781
507
Puebla
Mexico
D
0.2251
582
0.3416
366
Nanchong
China
D
0.2238
583
0.2516
602
Cochabamba
Bolivia
E+
0.2237
584
0.3034
448
Dehra Dun
India
E
0.2236
585
0.2523
598
Shiraz
Islamic Republic of Iran
D
0.2227
586
0.3301
393
Xuancheng
China
E+
0.2225
587
0.2349
653
Shaoguan
China
E+
0.222
588
0.2395
633
Santa Cruz
Bolivia
D+
0.2212
589
0.3628
327
Padang
Indonesia
E+
0.221
590
0.274
518
Lishui
China
D
0.2208
591
0.2436
619
Shizuishan
China
E+
0.2208
592
0.2214
696
Xingtai
China
D
0.2201
593
0.2624
554
Krasnodar
Russian Federation
E+
0.2196
594
0.2599
561
Gaziantep
Turkey
D
0.2192
595
0.3326
388
Tongliao
China
E+
0.2191
596
0.2355
652
Manaus
Brazil
D
0.2178
597
0.3385
375
Veracruz
Mexico
D
0.2177
598
0.2222
693
Konya
Turkey
D
0.2172
599
0.1567
876
Tomsk
Russian Federation
E+
0.2171
600
0.283
495
Enugu
Nigeria
E+
0.2166
601
0.2223
691
Can Tho
Viet Nam
E+
0.2157
602
0.2145
721
Ryazan
Russian Federation
E
0.2156
603
0.2546
588
Yangquan
China
E+
0.2147
604
0.2421
620
Kollam
India
E+
0.2147
605
0.225
686
Yulin(gx)
China
E+
0.2142
606
0.2584
569
Kayseri
Turkey
D
0.2139
607
0.2365
644
Barquisimeto
Venezuela
E+
0.2133
608
0.2384
636
Mudanjiang
China
E+
0.2132
609
0.2567
577
Diyarbakir
Turkey
E+
0.2129
610
0.1988
767 (continued)
18
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Cuernavaca
Mexico
E+
0.2128
611
0.2327
663
Tonghua
China
E+
0.2128
612
0.2399
626
Eskisehir
Turkey
D
0.2118
613
0.2296
670
Suizhou
China
E+
0.2117
614
0.2187
705
Vereeniging
South Africa
E
0.2116
615
0.2343
654
Anqing
China
D
0.2112
616
0.2682
533
Celaya
Mexico
E+
0.2111
617
0.237
642
Kampala
Uganda
D
0.2108
618
0.2332
660
Suzhou (AH)
China
E+
0.2108
619
0.2361
649
Joao Pessoa
Brazil
E+
0.2107
620
0.2664
536
Kemerovo
Russian Federation
E
0.2106
621
0.2515
603
Kannur
India
E+
0.2099
622
0.2549
587
Shuozhou
China
E+
0.2099
623
0.2532
594
Ji’an
China
E+
0.2092
624
0.2369
643
Siping
China
D
0.2092
625
0.2671
534
Malang
Indonesia
E+
0.2092
626
0.2948
470
Chifeng
China
E+
0.2088
627
0.2223
690
Algiers
Algeria
D
0.2083
628
0.3704
316
Pachuca de Soto
Mexico
E
0.2079
629
0.2864
489
Pereira
Colombia
E+
0.2078
630
0.28
505
Jos
Nigeria
D
0.2076
631
0.2116
727
Tabriz
Islamic Republic of Iran
E+
0.2075
632
0.3021
451
Xalapa
Mexico
E+
0.2075
633
0.1838
805
Teresina
Brazil
E+
0.207
634
0.2641
549
Juiz De Fora
Brazil
D
0.2068
635
0.262
555
Yunfu
China
E+
0.2067
636
0.2329
662
Chizhou
China
E+
0.2065
637
0.2186
707
Oshogbo
Nigeria
E
0.2061
638
0.1795
813
Hanzhong
China
E+
0.2061
639
0.2276
679
Dazhou
China
E+
0.206
640
0.2331
661
Qingyuan
China
E+
0.206
641
0.2507
604
Yongzhou
China
E+
0.2053
642
0.2222
692
Qujing
China
E+
0.2044
643
0.2396
631
Qinzhou
China
E+
0.2042
644
0.2609
558
Jiayuguan
China
E+
0.204
645
0.1998
761
Bhiwandi
India
E
0.2039
646
0.2611
557
Anshun
China
E+
0.2037
647
0.2193
703 (continued)
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
19
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Sulaymaniyah
Iraq
E+
0.2035
648
0.299
459
Huaihua
China
E+
0.2023
649
0.2275
680
Mexicali
Mexico
E+
0.202
650
0.266
541
Orenburg
Russian Federation
E+
0.2013
651
0.2387
635
Thiruvananthapuram
India
D
0.201
652
0.2168
712
Zhangjiakou
China
D
0.201
653
0.2398
628
Chengde
China
E+
0.2006
654
0.2333
659
Cebu
Philippines
D
0.2002
655
0.245
613
Patna
India
E+
0.2001
656
0.1911
792
Warri
Nigeria
E
0.2
657
0.1774
822
Bucaramanga
Colombia
D
0.1999
658
0.1968
773
Kiev
Ukraine
C
0.1994
659
0.3428
363
Feira De Santana
Brazil
E+
0.1994
660
0.2491
606
Yan’an
China
D
0.1993
661
0.2374
639
Irkutsk
Russian Federation
E+
0.1991
662
0.2582
570
Puducherry
India
E+
0.1991
663
0.2266
682
Barranquilla
Colombia
D
0.1991
664
0.2792
506
Baise
China
E+
0.1991
665
0.215
719
Casablanca
Morocco
C
0.1987
666
0.2731
520
Datong
China
D
0.1987
667
0.248
607
Fuyang
China
D
0.1979
668
0.2255
685
Dandong
China
E+
0.1977
669
0.2397
629
Changzhi
China
E+
0.1976
670
0.2552
585
Thrissur
India
E+
0.1967
671
0.199
765
Denpasar
Indonesia
E+
0.1965
672
0.2044
742
Kazan
Russian Federation
D
0.1961
673
0.3322
389
Cuiaba
Brazil
E+
0.1956
674
0.2409
624
Florianopolis
Brazil
D
0.1955
675
0.1972
772
Jinzhong
China
E+
0.1955
676
0.2398
627
Shanwei
China
E+
0.1949
677
0.2447
614
Fuzhou(JX)
China
E+
0.1936
678
0.2266
683
Haiphong
Viet Nam
E+
0.1934
679
0.2209
699
Yuncheng
China
D
0.1929
680
0.2373
640
Campo Grande
Brazil
D
0.1924
681
0.2558
582
Da Nang
Viet Nam
E+
0.1922
682
0.2114
728
Davao
Philippines
E+
0.1919
683
0.2157
716
Shaoyang
China
E+
0.1917
684
0.2211
698 (continued)
20
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Morelia
Mexico
D
0.1912
685
0.2459
612
Cagayan de Oro
Philippines
E+
0.1911
686
0.1966
776
Abidjan
The Republic D of Cote d’ivoire
0.1907
687
0.2524
595
Tongchuan
China
E+
0.1905
688
0.1697
844
Ankang
China
E+
0.1904
689
0.2061
736
Zaria
Nigeria
E+
0.1897
690
0.2476
608
Kayamkulam
India
E
0.1894
691
0.109
965
Pointe-Noire
Congo
E+
0.1892
692
0.199
764
Bozhou
China
E+
0.1891
693
0.2185
708
Suihua
China
E+
0.189
694
0.2278
678
Ibague
Colombia
E+
0.1885
695
0.2219
695
Rajshahi
Bangladesh
E+
0.1885
696
0.2467
610
Astrakhan’
Russian Federation
E
0.1884
697
0.2591
565
Chongzuo
China
E+
0.1882
698
0.2186
706
Baishan
China
E+
0.1882
699
0.2025
748
Managua
Nicaragua
D
0.1879
700
0.2337
658
Mombasa
Kenya
E+
0.1878
701
0.2018
752
Huangshan
China
D
0.1874
702
0.2127
725
Mashhad
Islamic Republic of Iran
D
0.1873
703
0.3072
437
Port-au-Prince
Haiti
E+
0.1868
704
0.2362
648
Guigang
China
E+
0.1863
705
0.2213
697
Surat
India
D
0.1855
706
0.2005
757
General Santos City
Philippines
E
0.1853
707
0.1862
801
Ludhiana
India
E+
0.1846
708
0.2133
722
Kota
India
D
0.1844
709
0.2311
667
Namangan
Uzbekistan
E
0.1839
710
0.1329
927
Bahawalpur
Pakistan
E+
0.1833
711
0.2193
702
Ulan Bator
Mongolia
E+
0.1827
712
0.2517
601
Mangalore
India
E+
0.1815
713
0.2097
732
Tiruppur
India
E
0.1812
714
0.1685
847
Nagpur
India
D
0.1808
715
0.2015
753
Hyderabad
Pakistan
D
0.1803
716
0.1783
816
Accra
Ghana
D
0.1801
717
0.2894
481
Marrakech
Morocco
D
0.18
718
0.2341
655
Heyuan
China
E+
0.1796
719
0.2289
673 (continued)
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
21
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Ilorin
Nigeria
E+
0.1793
720
0.165
854
Acapulco
Mexico
E+
0.1792
721
0.2181
710
Visakhapatnam
India
E+
0.1786
722
0.1945
783
Meizhou
China
E+
0.1785
723
0.222
694
Kingston
Jamaica
D+
0.1781
724
0.2579
573
Onitsha
Nigeria
E
0.1781
725
0.1664
853
Asmara
Eritrea
E+
0.178
726
0.1755
827
Linfen
China
E+
0.178
727
0.239
634
Ciudad Guayana
Venezuela
E
0.1779
728
0.1883
798
Huludao
China
E+
0.1775
729
0.228
676
Durg-Bhilai Nagar
India
E+
0.1767
730
0.2377
638
Huambo
Angola
E
0.1766
731
0.2636
551
Nouakchott
Mauritania
E+
0.1765
732
0.1726
833
Akure
Nigeria
E+
0.1759
733
0.2161
713
Jiamusi
China
E+
0.1757
734
0.2156
717
Krivoi Rog
Ukraine
E
0.1756
735
0.2198
701
Baicheng
China
E+
0.1754
736
0.2051
739
Hamadan
Islamic Republic of Iran
E+
0.1754
737
0.237
641
Madurai
India
E+
0.1747
738
0.1626
858
Poza Rica
Mexico
E+
0.1744
739
0.2011
755
Asansol
India
E+
0.1739
740
0.1948
781
Tangier
Morocco
E+
0.1739
741
0.1938
785
Cucuta
Colombia
E+
0.1733
742
0.2098
731
Brazzaville
Congo
E+
0.1731
743
0.1899
795
Zhangjiajie
China
E+
0.1731
744
0.1931
788
Novokuznetsk
Russian Federation
E
0.1724
745
0.2188
704
Tashkent
Uzbekistan
D
0.172
746
0.1529
885
Hulunbuir
China
E+
0.1719
747
0.1876
799
Kitwe
Zambia
E+
0.1711
748
0.1967
775
Khabarovsk
Russian Federation
E
0.1707
749
0.1951
779
Meknes
Morocco
E+
0.1701
750
0.2131
723
Kumasi
Ghana
E+
0.1701
751
0.1974
771
Tampico
Mexico
E+
0.1699
752
0.2412
623
Shangluo
China
E+
0.1698
753
0.1951
780
Laibin
China
E+
0.1697
754
0.2036
745
Douala
Cameroon
D
0.1697
755
0.256
580 (continued)
22
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Novosibirsk
Russian Federation
D+
0.1696
756
0.2818
496
Ya’an
China
E+
0.1695
757
0.1944
784
Kaduna
Nigeria
E+
0.1681
758
0.1468
896
Rabat
Morocco
D
0.1679
759
0.1994
763
Rostov-on-Don
Russian Federation
E+
0.1673
760
0.2365
645
Vientiane
Lao People’s Democratic Republic
D
0.1673
761
0.1464
898
Indore
India
D
0.166
762
0.1579
871
Liuan
China
E+
0.1657
763
0.2178
711
La Paz
Bolivia
D
0.1653
764
0.254
592
Guwahati
India
D
0.1653
765
0.2302
668
Rawalpindi
Pakistan
E+
0.1648
766
0.1709
842
Tasikmalaya
Indonesia
E+
0.1639
767
0.2297
669
Chiclayo
Peru
E+
0.1636
768
0.2127
726
Libreville
Gabon
E+
0.1626
769
0.2359
650
Rangoon
Myanmar
E+
0.1624
770
0.1329
926
Bandar Lampung
Indonesia
E+
0.1623
771
0.1774
821
Krasnoyarsk
Russian Federation
E+
0.1621
772
0.2247
687
Izhevsk
Russian Federation
E
0.1613
773
0.2003
759
Tlaxcala
Mexico
E+
0.1611
774
0.1967
774
Harare
Zimbabwe
D
0.161
775
0.2094
733
Ulanqab
China
E+
0.1605
776
0.193
789
Chisinau
Republic of Moldova
D
0.1602
777
0.1853
804
Fuxin
China
D
0.1599
778
0.2103
730
Guangyuan
China
E+
0.1599
779
0.1795
811
Jalandhar
India
E+
0.1597
780
0.1889
797
Oaxaca
Mexico
E+
0.1595
781
0.2069
735
Maceio
Brazil
E+
0.1594
782
0.2185
709
Jodhpur
India
E+
0.1589
783
0.2019
750
Erode
India
E+
0.1587
784
0.1782
817
Qiqihar
China
D
0.1578
785
0.2128
724
Kathmandu
Nepal
D
0.1576
786
0.1987
768
Bayannur
China
E+
0.1575
787
0.1723
834
Tirupati
India
E+
0.1574
788
0.1779
818 (continued)
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
23
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Chelyabinsk
Russian Federation
E+
0.1574
789
0.2403
625
Gujranwala
Pakistan
E+
0.1574
790
0.136
922
Aracaju
Brazil
E+
0.1572
791
0.2035
747
Luliang
China
E+
0.1568
792
0.2279
677
Omsk
Russian Federation
E+
0.1568
793
0.2268
681
Rajkot
India
D
0.1567
794
0.1625
859
Dar es Salaam
United Republic of Tanzania
D
0.1565
795
0.1936
786
Bogor
Indonesia
D
0.1564
796
0.2728
522
Chaoyang
China
E+
0.156
797
0.2035
746
Hezhou
China
E+
0.1559
798
0.1904
793
Amritsar
India
E+
0.1553
799
0.1918
791
Bacolod
Philippines
E+
0.1552
800
0.1696
845
Tabuk
Saudi Arabia
E+
0.1542
801
0.1722
837
Baoshan
China
D
0.1535
802
0.2003
760
Sokoto
Nigeria
E+
0.1533
803
0.1535
881
Karbala
Iraq
E+
0.153
804
0.2157
715
Xinzhou
China
D
0.1528
805
0.2014
754
Qingyang
China
D
0.1527
806
0.1853
803
Salem
India
D+
0.1516
807
0.2056
737
Sylhet
Bangladesh
E+
0.1512
808
0.1856
802
Salvador
Brazil
D
0.151
809
0.3129
425
Volgograd
Russian Federation
E+
0.151
810
0.1785
815
Tuxtla Gutierrez
Mexico
E+
0.1509
811
0.2042
744
Vijayawada
India
E+
0.1509
812
0.1515
890
Sanliurfa
Turkey
E
0.1508
813
0.2559
581
Tiruchirappalli
India
E+
0.1507
814
0.1728
832
Kirkuk
Iraq
E+
0.1506
815
0.3105
430
Nizhny Novgorod
Russian Federation
D
0.1505
816
0.2073
734
Maiduguri
Nigeria
E+
0.1504
817
0.0935
978
Kabul
Afghanistan
E+
0.1504
818
0.1689
846
Sekondi
Ghana
E
0.1499
819
0.1313
930
WuZhong
China
E+
0.1498
820
0.1776
820
Jaipur
India
D
0.1495
821
0.1816
808
Voronezh
Russian Federation
E
0.1481
822
0.2283
675 (continued)
24
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Jinchang
China
E+
0.1481
823
0.1503
891
Tianshui
China
D
0.148
824
0.1903
794
Jamnagar
India
E+
0.1479
825
0.1582
870
Fes
Morocco
E+
0.1478
826
0.1748
829
Mysore
India
D
0.1476
827
0.1754
828
Orumiyeh
Islamic Republic of Iran
E
0.1475
828
0.2292
672
Dakar
Senegal
D
0.1469
829
0.1946
782
Jambi
Indonesia
E+
0.146
830
0.1676
851
Raurkela
India
E
0.1454
831
0.156
878
Kurnool
India
E+
0.1446
832
0.1628
857
Jamshedpur
India
E+
0.144
833
0.1772
823
Siliguri
India
E+
0.1439
834
0.1642
855
Zamboanga
Philippines
E
0.1436
835
0.1489
893
Kolhapur
India
E+
0.1428
836
0.1723
836
Natal
Brazil
D
0.1421
837
0.2157
714
Meerut
India
E+
0.1417
838
0.1684
849
Basra
Iraq
E+
0.141
839
0.2356
651
Nashik
India
E+
0.1407
840
0.1599
864
Bhubaneswar
India
D
0.1402
841
0.1995
762
Mosul
Iraq
E+
0.1397
842
0.1184
950
Santa Marta
Colombia
E+
0.1395
843
0.1875
800
Yekaterinburg
Russian Federation
E+
0.1393
844
0.2146
720
Rasht
Islamic Republic of Iran
E+
0.1391
845
0.2049
740
Vladivostok
Russian Federation
D
0.1387
846
0.1597
865
Lincang
China
E+
0.1383
847
0.1712
840
Zhaotong
China
E+
0.1379
848
0.1827
807
Hubli-Dharwad
India
E+
0.1371
849
0.1436
905
Tieling
China
E+
0.1365
850
0.2225
689
Lucknow
India
D
0.1364
851
0.1831
806
Bazhong
China
E+
0.1359
852
0.1747
830
Zhongwei
China
E+
0.1358
853
0.1594
866
Khulna
Bangladesh
E+
0.135
854
0.1787
814
Jixi
China
E+
0.1347
855
0.1807
810
Lome
Togo
D
0.1346
856
0.1958
777
Nyala
Sudan
E+
0.1339
857
0.1162
954 (continued)
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
25
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Baiyin
China
E+
0.1323
858
0.1684
848
Faisalabad
Pakistan
E+
0.132
859
0.1771
824
Agadir
Morocco
E+
0.1319
860
0.0917
980
Warangal
India
E+
0.1316
861
0.1023
971
Bokaro Steel City
India
E
0.1315
862
0.1606
860
Ulyanovsk
Russian Federation
E
0.1313
863
0.1485
894
Gwalior
India
E+
0.1309
864
0.1682
850
Latakia
Syrian Arab Republic
E
0.1306
865
0.101
973
Lijiang
China
E+
0.1302
866
0.157
874
Misratah
Libya
E
0.13
867
0.26
560
Kinshasa
Congo
D
0.13
868
0.1778
819
Nasiriyah
Iraq
E
0.1298
869
0.2006
756
Safaqis
Tunisia
E
0.1292
870
0.2047
741
Chandigarh
India
D+
0.1285
871
0.1426
906
Hechi
China
E+
0.1279
872
0.1638
856
Zhangye
China
E+
0.1278
873
0.1467
897
Srinagar
India
E+
0.1275
874
0.1452
901
Makhachkala
Russian Federation
E
0.1273
875
0.1674
852
Aurangabad
India
D
0.1272
876
0.1924
790
Qitaihe
China
E+
0.1271
877
0.1606
861
Ranchi
India
E+
0.1271
878
0.1706
843
Lusaka
Zambia
D
0.1269
879
0.1989
766
Sangali
India
E
0.1265
880
0.144
903
Shuangyashan
China
E+
0.1254
881
0.1758
826
Pu’er
China
E+
0.1245
882
0.1576
872
Esfahan
Islamic Republic of Iran
E+
0.1244
883
0.2338
657
Sana’a’
Yemen
E+
0.1241
884
0.1402
913
Islamabad
Pakistan
D+
0.1235
885
0.2207
700
Bogra
Bangladesh
E
0.1232
886
0.1271
938
Najaf
Iraq
E+
0.1231
887
0.1603
862
Wuwei
China
E+
0.1225
888
0.155
879
Kigali
Rwanda
D
0.1225
889
0.1369
920
Saharanpur
India
E+
0.1224
890
0.1485
895
Vadodara
India
D
0.1218
891
0.1564
877 (continued)
26
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Qom
Islamic Republic of Iran
E+
0.1211
892
0.2003
758
Donetsk
Ukraine
E+
0.1208
893
0.1168
953
Banjarmasin
Indonesia
E+
0.1205
894
0.1599
863
Guntur
India
E+
0.1203
895
0.1523
887
Bien Hoa
Viet Nam
E+
0.1202
896
0.1334
925
Imphal
India
E+
0.1184
897
0.1366
921
Bhopal
India
D
0.1184
898
0.1575
873
Hamah
Syrian Arab Republic
E
0.1178
899
0.1061
968
Damascus
Syrian Arab Republic
E+
0.1174
900
0.1405
911
Yerevan
Armenia
D
0.1171
901
0.1712
839
Mogadishu
Somalia
E+
0.1165
902
0.0821
987
Guyuan
China
E+
0.1165
903
0.1383
917
Pontianak
Indonesia
E+
0.1158
904
0.157
875
Muzaffarnagar
India
E+
0.1149
905
0.1462
900
Varanasi
India
E+
0.1138
906
0.1711
841
Bhavnagar
India
E+
0.1137
907
0.1276
936
Tirunelveli
India
E+
0.1135
908
0.1124
961
Solapur
India
E+
0.1129
909
0.1263
940
Dhanbad
India
E+
0.1127
910
0.1523
886
Kerman
Islamic Republic of Iran
E+
0.1126
911
0.1795
812
Cherthala
India
E
0.1116
912
0.1531
883
Sialkot
Pakistan
E+
0.1115
913
0.1723
835
Al-Raqqa
Syrian Arab Republic
E
0.111
914
0.0826
986
Belgaum
India
E+
0.1103
915
0.1277
934
Vellore
India
D
0.11
916
0.1719
838
Sukkur
Pakistan
E+
0.1094
917
0.1374
919
Lubumbashi
Congo
E+
0.1091
918
0.1405
910
Peshawar
Pakistan
E+
0.109
919
0.153
884
Agra
India
E+
0.1084
920
0.1381
918
Hegang
China
E
0.1082
921
0.1449
902
Malegaon
India
E
0.1078
922
0.1068
967
Amravati
India
E+
0.1076
923
0.126
941
Niamey
Niger
E+
0.107
924
0.1182
951
Pingliang
China
E+
0.1066
925
0.1534
882 (continued)
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
27
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Aden
Yemen
E+
0.1064
926
0.0598
997
Nellore
India
E+
0.106
927
0.1103
963
Cuttack
India
E+
0.1055
928
0.1593
867
Ardabil
Islamic Republic of Iran
E+
0.1052
929
0.1592
868
Heihe
China
E+
0.1049
930
0.1398
914
Aligarh
India
E+
0.1047
931
0.1522
888
Zanzibar
United Republic of Tanzania
E+
0.1041
932
0.1412
909
Addis Ababa
Ethiopia
D+
0.1039
933
0.1277
935
Bareilly
India
E+
0.1038
934
0.1421
907
Freetown
Sierra Leone
E+
0.1032
935
0.1184
949
Moradabad
India
E+
0.1031
936
0.134
924
Durango
Mexico
D
0.1028
937
0.1587
869
Gulbarga
India
E+
0.1028
938
0.1274
937
Kermanshah
Islamic Republic of Iran
E+
0.102
939
0.1767
825
Kanpur
India
D
0.1018
940
0.1496
892
Yazd
Islamic Republic of Iran
E+
0.1011
941
0.1394
915
Jabalpur
India
E+
0.0999
942
0.1354
923
Ujjain
India
E+
0.0988
943
0.1214
944
Mwanza
United Republic of Tanzania
E+
0.0969
944
0.123
943
Lvov
Ukraine
E
0.0968
945
0.1414
908
Ajmer
India
E+
0.0967
946
0.127
939
Suez
Egypt
E+
0.0965
947
0.1128
959
Nanded Waghala
India
E
0.0963
948
0.1187
948
Allahabad
India
E+
0.0961
949
0.1515
889
Dnipropetrovs’k
Ukraine
E
0.0958
950
0.1463
899
Zaporizhzhya
Ukraine
E
0.0956
951
0.1403
912
Bulawayo
Zimbabwe
E+
0.0956
952
0.1126
960
Kharkov
Ukraine
E+
0.0947
953
0.1814
809
Firozabad
India
E
0.0941
954
0.1174
952
Jammu
India
D
0.092
955
0.1549
880
Odessa
Ukraine
D
0.0897
956
0.132
928
Jhansi
India
E+
0.0894
957
0.1153
956 (continued)
28
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Multan
Pakistan
E+
0.089
958
0.1389
916
Jiuquan
China
E+
0.0876
959
0.1203
945
Cotonou
Benin
D
0.0875
960
0.1089
966
Salta
Argentina
E+
0.0867
961
0.1315
929
Longnan
China
E+
0.0859
962
0.1251
942
Yaounde
Cameroon
D
0.0856
963
0.1979
769
Dingxi
China
E+
0.0855
964
0.1279
933
Yichun(hlj)
China
E+
0.0848
965
0.116
955
Durgapur
India
E+
0.0846
966
0.1302
931
Quetta
Pakistan
E+
0.0829
967
0.1439
904
Mathura
India
E+
0.0827
968
0.1283
932
Bishkek
Kyrgyzstan
D
0.0814
969
0.0998
975
Ouagadougou
Burkina Faso
E+
0.0769
970
0.0984
976
Nnewi
Nigeria
E
0.076
971
0.0893
982
Bouake
The Republic E+ of Cote d’ivoire
0.0743
972
0.0875
984
Blantyre-Limbe
Malawi
D
0.0721
973
0.1025
970
Bikaner
India
E+
0.0712
974
0.1055
969
Nay Pyi Taw
Myanmar
E
0.0708
975
0.0881
983
Zahedan
Islamic Republic of Iran
E
0.0698
976
0.1191
947
Bamako
Mali
E+
0.069
977
0.1002
974
Monrovia
Liberia
D
0.0666
978
0.1202
946
Djibouti
Djibouti
E+
0.0658
979
0.1016
972
Mandalay
Myanmar
E+
0.0655
980
0.0811
988
Gorakhpur
India
E+
0.0651
981
0.1144
957
Bujumbura
Burundi
E+
0.0651
982
0.0744
991
Conakry
Guinea
E+
0.064
983
0.0903
981
Abomey-Calavi
Benin
E+
0.0631
984
0.1132
958
Hargeysa
Somalia
E
0.0612
985
0.076
989
Matola
Mozambique
E
0.0603
986
0.1105
962
Raipur
India
E+
0.0601
987
0.0958
977
Tshikapa
Congo
E
0.0577
988
0.0725
992
Antananarivo
Madagascar
D
0.0571
989
0.085
985
Sargodha
Pakistan
E+
0.0559
990
0.1094
964
Lilongwe
Malawi
E+
0.0541
991
0.0754
990
Maputo
Mozambique
D
0.0539
992
0.0701
994
Bobo Dioulasso
Burkina Faso
E+
0.0518
993
0.072
993 (continued)
1 Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019
29
(continued) City
Country
Level Economic Rank Sustainable Rank competitiveness competitiveness
Mbuji-Mayi
Congo
E
0.0483
994
0.064
996
Nampula
Mozambique
E+
0.0401
995
0.0532
999
Dushanbe
Tajikistan
E+
0.0386
996
0.0576
998
Kananga
Congo
E
0.038
997
0.0532
1000
Bukavu
Congo
E+
0.03
998
0.0527
1001
Taiz
Yemen
E+
0.0269
999
0.0325
1002
Hodeidah
Yemen
E
0.0235
1000
0.0315
1003
Bangui
Central African Republic
E+
0.019
1001
0.0164
1005
Benghazi
Libya
E+
0.0177
1002
0.232
665
homs
Syrian Arab Republic
E
0.0172
1003
0.0672
995
N’Djamena
Chad
E+
0.0121
1004
0.0214
1004
Kisangani
Congo
E
0.0085
1005
0
1006
Aleppo
Syrian Arab Republic
E+
0
1006
0.093
979
Chapter 2
The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
1750–2050 is the 300 years of great changes in the world, in which the status of the city is extraordinary. City is not only the main content of world change, but also the core force. In the 300 years, cities have changed from the world being guided by cities, to being dominated by cities, to city being the main body.
2.1 From the Micro Level, the Change of Leading Cities Causes the Basic “Cell” Change of the World The city is an important symbol of human civilization, and also a beacon to light human progress. In the 300 years from 1750 to 2050, the development of cities is the locomotive that drives the development of the world, while the advanced cities are the engine of the development of cities. The development of global advanced cities leads the world’s development direction and changes the world’s development pattern.
2.1.1 The Evolution of Global Urban Economic System: From Global Duality to Global Integration, from Commodity Trade System to Factor Trade System, and Then from Industrial Chain System to Innovation Chain System Human activities are the foundation of cities. In the 300 years from 1750 to 2050, the content, scale and structure of the activities of cities, the important gathering areas of human beings, have undergone and will undergo profound qualitative changes: from
© China Social Sciences Press 2023 P. Ni et al., The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-99-3553-6_2
31
32
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
the production, exchange and consumption of physical objects to the production, exchange and consumption of labor services, then to the production, exchange and consumption of knowledge, and even to the production, exchange and consumption of wisdom. 1. The leading cities in 1750–1850s: Development was dominated by resource processing, with knowledge innovation being carried out together. In 1750, the city began a new human activity triggered by the industrial revolution. In the 100 years from 1750 to 1850, the cities of the first industrialized countries mainly engaged in the production, exchange and consumption of resources processing products, although most of the world’s cities are still dominated by simple manual production and market trading in the traditional agricultural era. The first industrial revolution took place in British cities. Textile industry cities, metal processing industry cities, coal industry cities, transportation hub cities and trade cities rose in turn. Table 2.1 shows the rapid development of cities in the UK that rely on the advantages of resources and port location. With the export of British Industrial Revolution achievements, Germany, France, the United States and other countries have also carried out industrial revolution. Ruhr district of Germany, New York City of the United States and other cities have accepted the baptism of industrialization at this stage, and the urban industry is still dominated by industry, mining and light industry. The world’s leading industrialized cities mainly produce, exchange and consume primary commodities, metal equipment manufacturing and other industrial products (as shown in Fig. 2.1): in addition to non savings and credit intermediaries, global listed companies are mainly distributed in beverage manufacturing, textile, general merchandise, paper making, glass, industrial machinery manufacturing and other industries, mainly producing primary products and simple industrial products. Table 2.1 Industrial cities and transport hub cities in Britain after the industrial revolution Type
City
Comprehensive metropolis
London
Industry, mining
Textile industry
Manchester, Salford, Stockport, Bolton, Preston, Bollie, Blackburn, Nottingham, Liz, etc.
Metal processing industry
Birmingham, Wolverhampton, Walsall, Sheffield, etc.
Coal industry Cardiff, Swansea, Newport, Mason, winsbury, Dudley, and ironmaking Wassel, willenhower, etc. Center Transportation hub
Railway hub
Bud, Middleborough, Sheldon, swighton, Wolverton, Crewe, etc.
Port
London, Bristol, Liverpool, Newcastle; Sunderland, Portsmouth, Plymouth, etc.
Source Organize according to the data
2.1 From the Micro Level, the Change of Leading Cities Causes the Basic …
33
Fig. 2.1 The top 30 industries listed in 1750–1850. Source Sorting according to the data of Osiris’s global listed companies
In this period, although the technology of resource processing industry in advanced cities is relatively low, and innovation is not universal. However, information, knowledge, technology, culture and other non-material products had become an indispensable part of the production, exchange and consumption of advanced cities. During the first industrial revolution from 1750 to 1850, the most basic problem of human famine was solved. At the same time, the increase of production level and income stimulated more non-material demand, such as newspapers and magazines. Industry makes the line between work and leisure clear. It stimulates the demand for knowledge labor, thus stimulating the development of newspapers and magazines. The leading cities of major industrial countries in the world have established and published a large number of newspapers and magazines, such as 267 newspapers in Britain in 1821, 18 newspapers in London in 1880, more than 300 newspapers in Paris in 1892, and more than 9 million newspapers in Berlin in Germany from less than 100,000 in 1847 to 1870; there were about 400 daily newspapers and more than 3000 weekly newspapers in the United States in the mid-nineteenth century. 2. The leading cities in 1850–1950s: resources, chemical industry dominated, and information activities began to sprout. After the 1850s, the industrial structure of advanced cities began to change from the light textile industry of resource processing to the heavy industry of resource combination. In the next 100 years, advanced cities were mainly engaged in the manufacture, exchange and consumption of composite materials, and heavy chemical industry became the leading industry of cities. To some extent, the adjustment of industrial structure of leading cities had changed the type of global commodity
34 Table 2.2 Types and functions of some American cities in the twentieth century
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Types and functions
City
National comprehensive city
New York, Chicago
Specialized local central city
Baltimore, Philadelphia, Cincinnati, St. Louis, etc.
Specialized small cities
Elizabeth, Toledo, great falls, etc.
Satellite city
Pittsburgh, Forrest, etc.
Source Sorting according to western urban history
circulation, and some cities that start industrialization began to engage in resource processing activities. After the 1850s, the second industrial revolution was carried out in the cities of Britain, Germany, France, the Netherlands, Belgium, Luxembourg, Denmark and the United States. Through new construction and transformation, new industrial clusters represented by the electric power industry, chemical industry, petroleum industry and automobile industry appeared in these cities. For example, a group of emerging cities in the United States, such as Detroit, Birmingham, and Pittsburgh, the world’s steel capital, the Great Lakes city group with Chicago as the radiation center (Table 2.2). The second industrial revolution brought important changes to the industrial structure of global cities. The industrial structure of advanced cities began to shift from the light textile industry of resource processing to the heavy industry of resource integration, as shown in Fig. 2.2. From 1850 to 1950, heavy chemical industries such as power equipment, industrial machinery manufacturing, pharmaceutical manufacturing, auto parts, metal mining, semiconductors and other electronic components, and general equipment manufacturing became the leading industries, while traditional resource processing industries in advanced cities declined. At the same time, industrial machinery manufacturing, general equipment manufacturing, electrical equipment and other enterprises continue to increase, improving the level of automation of urban production, automation makes human physical strength further liberated. The invention and application of Telegraph and telephone, as well as the invention of software such as semiconductor and its electronic components, make the production, exchange and consumption of information increase constantly. From the perspective of global cities, the world’s information production, exchange and consumption are mainly concentrated in London, Europe, New York, United States, Japan, Asia and other advanced cities. The gap between global cities is relatively obvious, as shown in Fig. 2.3. In 1989, New York’s information related production, exchange and consumption exceeded ten million US dollars, followed by London and Tokyo, which reached more than 9 million US dollars and 7 million US dollars respectively.
2.1 From the Micro Level, the Change of Leading Cities Causes the Basic …
35
Fig. 2.2 The top 30 industries listed in 1850–1950. Source Sorting according to the data of Osiris’s global listed companies
Fig. 2.3 The distribution of listed enterprises engaged in global information software and hardware production and service during1850–1950. Source Sorting according to the data of Osiris’s global listed companies
36
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Fig. 2.4 The global distribution of listed companies of services producer in 2017. Source Sorting according to the data of Osiris’s global listed companies
1. The leading cities in 1950-2050s: from service led development and information led development to intelligent led development. From 1950 to 2000, the activities of leading city changed from material production, exchange and consumption to labor supply, exchange and consumption. World cities formed a pattern of leading cities engaged in services, intermediate cities engaged in manufacturing and bottom cities engaged in processing. The mode of global inter-city division of labor changes from department specialization to function specialization, which is embodied in the concentration of high value-added links such as headquarters, R & D, marketing and investment in the value chain in the central cities, and the concentration of manufacturing links with low value-added in the small and medium-sized cities. The advanced cities’ functions have been transformed into high-end services (see Fig. 2.4). The development of services producer has changed the economic structure and functional divisions of cities. The formation of global financial cities is an important manifestation of global urban functional changes, such as London, New York, Paris, Frankfurt, Tokyo, Hong Kong, Beijing, Shanghai, etc. (Fig. 2.5). From 1950 to 2000, manufacturing of computing software and its related services, special and commercial equipment, real estate and securities related industries became the leading industries of urban development, as shown in Fig. 2.6. At this stage, computer hardware and software and its service industries had developed rapidly. In addition to Tokyo, London, New York, Paris and other developed cities, which gathered a large number of related enterprises, Asian cities such as Beijing, Taipei, Mumbai, Seoul, Bangalore, Shenzhen and other cities have gained rapid rise at this stage. In 2000–2050, the activities of the leading cities will change from the provision, exchange and consumption of labor services to the production, exchange and consumption of information, knowledge and ideas. Instead of physical strength and
2.1 From the Micro Level, the Change of Leading Cities Causes the Basic …
90 Berlin
Toronto Seattle
San Francisco
Boston 60 Atlanta 30 New York
Los Angeles
Beijing
Stockholm
Seoul
Amsterdam London Paris Zurich Tel Aviv-Yafo Dublin Hong Kong Mumbai
Chicago
0 -180
-150
-120
-90
-60
-30
0 -30
30
60
Bangalore
37
90 Singapore
120
Shanghai Tokyo Hangzhou Nanjing Shenzhen Guangzhou 150
180 Sydney
Sao Paulo -60
-90 Fig. 2.5 The global distribution of global financial technology centers. Source 2018 global financial technology center index
Fig. 2.6 The top 30 industries listed in 1950–2000. Source Sorting according to the data of Osiris’s global listed companies
38
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Fig. 2.7 The distribution of knowledge intensive industries in global cities in 2017. Source Sorting according to the data of Osiris’s global listed companies
intelligence, intelligent machines provide products and services. Not only the production, exchange and consumption of software products and services become the main content of urban activities, but also the main human activities turn to the innovation of knowledge and technology. With the development of new generation information technology such as artificial intelligence and big data, the level of global urban intelligence will be improved. By 2050, intellectualization will deepen the global urban industrial division pattern, and promote the formation of a new global industrial pattern with high-end cities intelligent creation, middle-end cities intelligent manufacturing and service, low-end cities intelligent consumption and raw materials, other cities knowledge, information and service related industries. At present, the advanced industries of advanced cities, i.e. high-end manufacturing and high-end services, indicate the transformation direction of global advanced cities (Fig. 2.7). It is the common mission of countries and cities all over the world to use science and technology to serve human beings. By 2050, the trend of global urban development must be intelligent. ICT (information, communication and Technology) will make global countries and cities into an intelligent and global city. At present, intelligent manufacturing is essentially the intelligent process of manufacturing industry. It is led by the old world-class manufacturing center cities such as New York, London and Tokyo, as well as the emerging intelligent manufacturing center cities such as Suzhou, Tianjin and Foshan, as shown in Fig. 2.8. In addition, with the rapid development of automation, by 2030, the jobs of 800 million people in the world will be replaced by machines, as shown in Fig. 2.9.
2.1 From the Micro Level, the Change of Leading Cities Causes the Basic …
39
Fig. 2.8 The proportion of existing jobs likely to be replaced in global countries in 2016–2030. Data source Jobs lost, jobs gained: Workforce transitions in a time of automation by McKinsey
2019 World Intelligent Manufacturing City Potential Index
0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4
Foshan
Sydney
Osaka
Melbourne
Chongqing
Amsterdam
Houston
Birmingham
Pittsburgh
Beijing
Singapore
Seattle
Boston
Paris
Berlin
Tianjin
Suzhou
Chicago
Tokyo
Los Angeles
London
Shenzhen
Shanghai
San Francisco
New York
0.3
Fig. 2.9 The spatial distribution of some intelligent manufacturing cities in the world. Source The development trend report of world intelligent manufacturing center (2019)
2.1.2 The Size of the Leading Urban Population Ranges from Tens of Thousands to Hundreds of Thousands, Millions and Tens of Millions The population is the center of the city. Since the twentieth century, with the launch of industrialization in various countries around the world, led by leading cities, the population size of the city has exponentially increased. It is expected that the
40
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
expansion of the city will usher in a new round of acceleration. From the perspective of historical evolution, In the 300 years from 1750 to 2050, led by leading cities, the population of the city has continuously exceeded the limit, the per capita income of the city has increased significantly, and the structure of urban society has become more complex and diverse. 1. 1750–1850: The typical urban population grows from tens of thousands to hundreds of thousands. In the 100 years from 1750 to 1850, on the one hand, the population scale of advanced cities has expanded several times, up to more than 100,000 people. On the other hand, the social structure of the urban population is more diverse. Although the vast majority of the world’s population is under 100,000 people, the city is mainly business practitioner and commercial and government officials. In 1760, Leading industrialized UK leading city, with a population of more than 100,000 in London, and 12 provincial cities were below 50,000 except Brisbane. By 1801, the population of provincial cities was below 100,000, there were 5 in 5–10 million, and 8 in 20–50 thousand. By 1851, there were more than 100,000 in 7 cities, 13 in more than 50,000, and more than 300,000 in advanced cities such as Manchester, Liverpool and Glasgow. It is estimated that between 1801–1851, the UK textile industry’s population growth rate ranked first with 229%, other port cities increased by 214%, and manufacturing cities increased by 186%; individual cities are growing at even more alarming speeds, such as From 1811–1861, the population of Liverpool and Preston increased fivefold, Brighton grew sevenfold, and the textile textile center Bradford grew eightfold. As the world trade and financial center, the population of London reached 700,000 in 1801, and the population of London soared to 2.36 million in 1850. The population increased by 2.4 times between 1801 and 1850. After the First industrial revolution, the income and utility scale of ordinary people has increased compared with the Pre-industrial revolution. According to Ashton, the British national income increased nearly eight times between 1740 and 1840, and in 1867 it was about 81.11 million pounds. With the start of the industrial revolution, increased productivity has reduced the daily cost of ordinary people, such as clothing and other necessities, which enables workers to have private wealth in their spare time. According to demand—the supply of internal connections, some products such as bread during this period have a backward tilt demand curve—increased incomes that reduce people’s consumption of bread and turn to other necessities such as meat. The development of industry has stimulated the society to generate new demands on the labor force, which will inevitably improve the economic and social infrastructure, such as transportation, commercial services, and power supply. On the supply side, industrial development reduces production costs and increases productivity. This not only helps to increase output, but also improves the quality of the entire process. The demographic structure is characterized by a rapid expansion of the number of workers. The industrial revolution is often associated with a “shift in work”. Before 1700, the proportion of the employed population in the UK, which relied mainly on agriculture, declined. By the time of the first census in 1801, this was
2.1 From the Micro Level, the Change of Leading Cities Causes the Basic …
41
the first official measure, and the agricultural population was less than one-third. By 1851, this figure was less than one-fifth. After the industrial revolution began, due to the use of factory-made production, the contrast between social relations and various class forces has changed dramatically. Many people in the past invested in the construction of factories and gradually transformed into a new industrial bourgeoisie, and industrial cities developed rapidly. According to statistics quoted by British bourgeois historian Toynbee in the Lectures of the British Industrial Revolution in the Eighteenth Century, the phenomenal speed of industrial cities can be seen. Between 1760 and 1781, the famous British city of Liverpool increased from 30,000 to 552,425, Manchester from 30,000 to 393,676; Birmingham increased from 30,000 to 400,757. Although merchants and government public sector personnel are still a minority bourgeois ruler at this time, the United Kingdom has established an unparalleled industrial and commercial status. In 1840, the proportion of trade in the UK accounted for 21% of total world trade. In the same year, France accounted for 11% and the United States accounted for 10%. The working class has grown rapidly, when merchants and the public sector accounted for a small proportion of the entire social class. 2. 1850–1950: The typical urban population grows from hundreds of thousands to millions. The population of major countries in Europe and North America has grown on a large scale. During the period of 1850–1950, the industrialization wave spread to continental Europe and North America, during which many countries in Europe and North America completed the transition from the steam to the electrical age. Especially in the United States, the population increased from 5.3 million in 1800 to 76.20 million in 1900. During the same period, the land area of the United States increased from 891,000 square miles (2,307,690 square kilometers) in 1791 to 30,219,295 square feet. The double growth of population and land area provides the United States with a larger product internal market and a raw material supply market. This expansion has encouraged immigration and migration to the west, and the surge in demand for products has increased, accelerating the development of the industrial revolution in the United States. Between 1870 and 1930, the population of many important industrial cities in the United States increased by several times. Individual cities such as Los Angeles expanded by more than 100 times. In 1990, the population of Los Angeles reached 1.778 million. Chicago was still desolate in the early nineteenth century. It officially formed a city in 1837. In 1890, it crossed the population of 1 million. In 1910, it became the second largest city after New York. It can be seen from the following important industrial revolution cities that the population of major cities in Western countries has doubled (Table 2.3). At the same time, the income and scale utility of the population has changed (Table 2.4). Drawing on the population growth of other countries, during the second industrial revolution, the population of many countries achieved steady growth and national income also increased. In the nineteenth century, the industrialized countries witnessed the improvement of people’s living conditions and the sharp fall in commodity prices. The development of gas and electricity in the nineteenth century,
42
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Table 2.3 Changes in population of important cities during the second industrial revolution (Unit: thousand people)
1850
1880
1900
New York
696
1912
3437
London
2681
4767
6581
Tokyo
–
1050
1600
Moscow
365
612
1000
Excerpted from: L.S. Stavrianos: The Book of Global History
as well as the development of durable goods such as bicycles, provided effective demand. Similarly, supply responds to changing demand conditions through technological development. In the nineteenth century, urban development created demand for environmental protection, and new demand spurred the development of cheap, non-permeate pipelines (which were not yet common in the UK before 1846), draining pipes, gutters, and hydraulic components. In the late nineteenth century, the expansion of the suburbs increased the demand for supplies and services. At the time of the first US census in 1790, there were only six cities with a population of over 8,000 in the United States. From 1870 to 1920, the urban population increased from 9.9 million to 54.3 million. In 1920, the urban population was 51.4% of the national population, and in 1930 it increased to 56%, basically achieving urbanization. The contradiction between labor and capital has stimulated the expansion of the public sector. At the turn of the nineteenth and twentieth centuries, the rapid expansion of industrialization expanded the working class. In 1914, there were about 40 million workers worldwide, most of them concentrated in Western Europe and North America. The number of workers in Britain, the United States, Germany and France accounted for about three-quarters of the world’s total workers. During this period, the bourgeoisie of each country basically still treated workers in the first or even the Table 2.4 Percentage of population and income growth in major countries during the second industrial revolution Country
Period
Annual growth percentage Population
National income
Per capita income
France
1845–1950
0.1
1.5
1.4
Germany
1865–1952
1
2.7
1.5
Italy
1865–1952
0.7
1.8
1
United Kingdom
1865–1950
0.8
2.2
1.3
Russia
1870–1954
1.3
3.1
1.5
Switzerland
1865–1952
0.7
3.6
2.8
United States
1975–1952
1.7
4.1
2
Canada
1875–1952
1.8
4.1
1.9
Japan
1885–1952
1.3
4.2
2.6
2.1 From the Micro Level, the Change of Leading Cities Causes the Basic …
43
most primitive way of industrialization. Until the end of the nineteenth century, the working hours of workers in each country were not less than 12 h per working day. The actual wages of workers have risen slightly in some countries, but the growth rate is far below the increase in productivity. When the economy is sluggish, the actual wages of workers will stagnate or even fall, and the harsh labor environment will cause frequent work-related accidents. In addition, workers are also facing the threat of unemployment and semi-unemployment. Under this circumstance, some workers have waged struggles to safeguard their rights and interests, and the contradiction between labor and capital has expanded. A striking feature of the twentieth-century economy is the expansion of the government and its institutions. The expansion of such government agencies can be summarized by the “welfare state”. This term was originally created to alleviate the contradiction between labor and capital. For example, the American reform movement of the early twentieth century required the government to regulate the working and living conditions of child labor, food processing and packaging, and the working class. In the 12 years of Roosevelt’s administration, the total number of federal employees increased from more than 500,000 in 1933 to an all-time high of more than 3.5 million in 1945. It is estimated that in 1911, “every 10,000 inhabitants, there are 200 government officials in Belgium, 176 in France, 126 in Germany, 113 in the United States, and 73 in the United Kingdom.” The size of national bureaucracies and the subsequent economic growth rates have led to government debate in developed countries. Machines have increased social productivity, and labor-management conflicts have caused some social stability problems, causing the public sector to grow rapidly. 3. 1950–2050: The urban population grows from millions to ten millions. The population size of the world’s cities has exploded. When new communication technologies are integrated with new energy systems, a huge economic revolution in history will emerge. After 1950, it can be called worldwide industrialization. The world’s economy, employment, and industrial structure have undergone tremendous changes. The wide application of science and technology has increased the supply of social products. The most political and economic changes reflect the growth of the population and the expansion of the city. In 1900, the world’s total population was about 1.6 billion. In 2018, the world’s total population reached 7.631 billion. The world population has increased by nearly 3.8 times in the past 118 years. The changes in the industrial structure have rapidly transferred the population of the primary industry to the secondary and tertiary industries. As a result, the growth rate of the urban population far exceeds the growth rate of the total population, which has increased by nearly 17.8 times in the past 118 years. The proportion of urban population has also increased from 13.6% in 1900 to 55.3% in 2018. It is estimated that by 2050, the proportion of urban population will reach 68.4% (Table 2.5). During this period, the typical urban population of emerging economies soared. For example, Shanghai in China had a population of 4.288 million in 1950 and rose to 23.382 million in 2015. Shenzhen is China’s first batch of reform and opening-up areas, benefiting from policy and geographical advantages, and
44
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
population growth has doubled 3580.8 between 1950 and 2015. It is estimated that in 2050, the population of Shanghai and Shenzhen in China will exceed 35.841 million and 18.827 million respectively. The economic revolution has led to an increase in the world’s population and urbanization levels, while the per capita income and GDP of the world have also increased. The world’s per capita GDP was $451.06 in 1960 and $2530.23 in 1980. In the past 20 years, the world economy has grown by 4.6 times. By region, the per capita output value of North America during this period was higher than that of other regions. The per capita GDP of East Asia and the Pacific increased rapidly, reaching the world average in 2018 (Table 2.6). The population size utility has also changed to some extent compared to the previous two industrial revolutions. Different from the past, the first industrial revolution generally improved the quality of life, the second industrial revolution established the factory system, and truly realized the urbanization of developed countries. These two industrial revolutions greatly stimulated people’s demand for various products of life. the quality of life has been met, but the form of these two industrial revolutions is still a vertical structure, the management system is top-down, and even monopoly organizations. The flat structure adopted by the third industrial revolution, the emergence of the Internet has connected various organizations in countries, continents and even the world into a network. The most intuitive way for people to live is to browse information across the country through digital devices, and products from around the world are readily available through e-shopping platforms. New technology energy is more dependent on the development of technology, and the combination of information technology and 3D printing technology will set off a new round of technological revolution. In today’s world, there is a need for people with ideas and ideas. In short, the third revolution promoted the utility of population size. Table 2.5 World population growth list (Unit: 100 million, %) Year
Total population
1900
16.08
1950 1960
Urban population
Urban population as a percentage of the total population
2.24
13.6
25.36
7.51
28.1
30.33
10.24
32.9
1970
37.01
13.54
37.3
1980
44.58
17.54
42.2
1990
53.31
22.90
43.0
2000
61.45
28.68
46.7
2010
69.58
35.95
51.7
2020
77.95
43.79
56.2
2030
85.51
51.67
60.4
2040
92.10
59.38
64.5
2050
97.72
66.80
68.4
2.1 From the Micro Level, the Change of Leading Cities Causes the Basic …
45
Table 2.6 World per capita gross income per region by region from 1960 to 2018 (in US dollars) Year World
1960
1980
2000
2010
2018
451.06
2530.23
5491.57
9538.84
11,296.78
147.23
1162.52
4044.32
7673.74
11,132.23
82.28
262.14
447.45
1257.67
1905.77
By region East Asia and Pacific South Asia North America
2942.63
12,437.78
35,147.88
48,373.70
60,968.0
Europe and Central Asia
651.64
5780.59
11,627.68
23,572.56
25,069.77
Latin America and the Caribbean
370.91
2161.97
4389.80
9058.33
9023.50
Middle East and North Africa South Africa
-
2173.95
3066.47
7172.83
8056.95
443.00
2905.93
3032.44
7328.62
6339.57
By income High income
1390.80
9545.32
25,593.38
39,169.91
44,705.87
Middle and upper income
192.86
970.34
1967.25
6344.15
9200.45
medium income
149.93
714.32
1272.37
3916.59
5483.97
Low and medium income
–
412.57
566.62
1659.71
2218.90
Low income
–
–
314.44
638.23
811.18
The number of service workers has increased significantly, and the business group has become more extensive. At the end of the twentieth century, the change in the number of workers showed a difference from the previous two industrial revolutions. First, the number of industrial workers has decreased, and the number of workers in the service industry has increased significantly. In the United Kingdom, for example, in the employment structure of the United Kingdom from 1971 to 1996, the proportion of manufacturing workers fell from 30.6% to 18.2%, while the proportion of employees in the minerals, energy and water supply industries fell from 9.5%. To 1.1%. The manufacturing sector in Manchester, the industrial center of the UK, fell from 70% of total sales in the early 1960s to 20% in the late twentieth century. At the same time, the service industry developed rapidly. From 1971 to 1996, the proportion of UK service workers in the total number of employed people rose from 52.6% to 75.8%. To a certain extent, the proportion of service industry to GDP can also reflect the proportion of employees in the service industry. As can be seen, the trend of the UK service industry and industry as a share of GDP is in the opposite direction, and industrial workers are gradually turning to the service industry (Fig. 2.10). After the mid-twentieth century, the government’s development was expanded into macroeconomic arrangements for greater efficiency and faster growth. After the industrial revolution, the traditional duties of the government have also expanded. Therefore, according to the laws of industrialization in all countries of the world, the industrialization and urbanization of other countries in the world after the midtwentieth century will gradually stabilize the growth of the public sector employment in all countries of the world. At present, as shown in Fig. 2.11, the proportion of the
46
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0
Service industry as a share of GDP
Industry as a share of GDP
Fig. 2.10 Trends in the ratio of service industry to industry in GDP in the United Kingdom from 1801 to 2011
United Kingdom Turkey Thailand Switzerland Sweden Spain Mexico Korea Japan Ireland Hungary Greece Czech Republic 0.00%
5.00%
10.00%
15.00%
20.00%
25.00%
30.00%
35.00%
Fig. 2.11 Proportion of public sector in total employment in some countries in 2016
public sector in the majority of European countries is still higher than the proportion of the public sector in other countries. After the twenty-first century, although the merchants accounted for only a small part relative to the entire social group, the scope of the merchant group dominated by a few bourgeoisie during the previous two industrial revolutions expanded. On the one
2.1 From the Micro Level, the Change of Leading Cities Causes the Basic …
47
hand, in contrast to the changes in the entire business management system, in addition to self-employment, businessmen in the twenty-first century have a form of corporate management. On the other hand, the entrepreneurial identity that emerged through its own efforts has expanded from a middle-aged male with university education to a new era group composed of immigrants and women. The group of merchants is covered more and more widely. According to a survey by the Kauffman Foundation, the highest level of entrepreneurial activity in the United States is between 55 and 64 years old, and the proportion of businesses starting is 28%. More and more employees are looking for a way to start a business. According to the Census Bureau, among the 27 million companies in the United States, unpaid small business enterprises account for more than 70%, and annual sales are $887 billion. Small business enterprises are also flexible, can operate in low-cost locations (such as home offices), and are more flexible than large commercial companies.
2.1.3 The Space of Leading Cities Spread from Single Central Cities to Multi-Center Metropolitan Areas, Megalopolis and Metropolitan Coordination Regions Space is the carrier of the city. Historically, guided by leading cities, urban space has experienced a single-center to multi-center evolution. Today, as the process of urbanization is deepening, countries in the world have replaced the single-center and multi-center spatial structure with urban integration to promote regional division of labor and cooperation to strengthen the overall strength of the region. It has become the active choice of political power institutions in various countries. This is an inevitable outcome of the economic evolution of cities and regions. In densely populated industrialized cities, higher productivity developments tend to make cities more advanced public facilities and transportation networks than rural areas, and road density is far superior to rural areas. During the first industrial revolution, these resources and facilities were mainly located in urban centers. During the second industrial revolution, with the continuous improvement of space resources and facilities in small and medium-sized cities in developed countries, the population was concentrated in small and medium-sized cities. Since the twentieth century, globalization has deepened and developing countries around the world have successively undergo industrial revolutions. At present, resources and facilities based on developing countries are still concentrated in large and medium-sized cities, but with the spread of the Internet, the world The links between cities are becoming more and more flat, and technology resources can be shared between cities through networks. 1. 1750–1850 period: The leading city is a single center with tens of square kilometers (miles) of space. The industrial revolution has accelerated the concentration of population to cities, and the state of the city has changed. Between 1750 and 1850, the steam revolution
48
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
led to a rapid increase in productivity, and a large concentration of labor to the city, so the scale of urban space continued to expand like a snowball. Take the major European cities of London and Paris as examples, forming a single-center regional city with a space of tens of square kilometers (miles). Take the city of London as an example. Its city from west to east is only 8 km (5 miles) in 1750. By 1850 it was expanded to 24 km (15 miles), and the city area reached 62 square kilometers (24 square miles) in 1841, and further expanded to 316 square kilometers (122 square miles) in 1851, while the urban area of Paris was also From 13.4 square kilometers (5.2 square miles) in 1700 to 34.5 square kilometers (13.3 square miles) in 1850, with the expansion of urban areas, urban public resource facilities are also standing in the city center, it can be said that this time Europe mainly forms urban spatial structure features dominated by a single center. Urban public resource facilities are also becoming more and more abundant. At the same time as the rapid development of the city, some of the most necessary social public facilities have also been added in the industrial city of the United Kingdom. The first is urban architecture, mainly factory buildings and residential buildings. In order to adapt to the development of the industry, the workers’ houses and streets are also covered around the factory. The second is a variety of living andKnowledge density. In the first half of the nineteenth century, several industrial cities in England, such as Pennillas, Rosendale and Nottingham’s Trent, established water plants. Liverpool also built public baths and laundry facilities in the south of the city. The 79 staff schools in the Yorkshire Federation have affiliated libraries. The third is urban transportation. Before the industrial revolution, the traffic between British cities was still in a state of primitive backwardness. After the industrial revolution, the development of highways was far from being able to adapt to the needs of industrial raw materials transportation, and the upsurge of the canal was raised. The invention of the Stephenson locomotive in 1814 brought land traffic into the railway era. The railway between Stockton and Darlington was completed in 1825 and the railway between Manchester and Liverpool was opened in 1830. Then, in the centre of London, some trunk lines and feeder lines were built. By the time the industrial revolution was completed, most of the major railway lines had been completed. At this time, a high-density, centralized, single-center urban structure is formed. The theory of industrial cities that emerged at this time also reflects the characteristics of urban functional elements concentrated in urban centers. For example, at the end of the nineteenth century, young French architects made a clear distinction between the functional elements of industrial cities. The central part is the city center, with assembly halls, museums, exhibition halls, libraries, theaters, etc. The urban living quarters are long strips, the health and medical center is located on the north side of the uphill slope, and the industrial area is located in the southeast of the residential area. Each zone has a green belt isolation. The railway station is located near the industrial zone, and the main railway runs through the underground railway to the interior of the city. Urban traffic is advanced, with fast-tracks and test sites for aircraft launches. The
2.1 From the Micro Level, the Change of Leading Cities Causes the Basic …
49
residential neighborhood is 20 m wide and 150 m long, and each is equipped with corresponding greening to form various neighborhood units with primary schools and service facilities. 2. 1850–1950: Leading cities are multi-centers with hundreds of square kilometers (miles) of space. During the period of 1850–1950, the western countries were in the period of industrialization and post-industrial era. The development of urbanization no longer blindly pursued the growth of urban scale, but focused on the improvement of urban quality and the improvement of residential conditions and public facilities. In addition, convenient and fast transportation makes the city center more closely connected with the surrounding suburbs, and urban public facilities are distributed in a wider space, and the city is shifted from high-density concentration to low-density and contagion. Leading cities such as London and New York are gradually forming multi-centers of 100 square kilometers (miles). Take the city of London as an example. The city from west to east has further expanded from 24 km (15 miles) in 1850 to 50 in 1950. Kilometers (30 miles), the city area reached 1,186 square kilometers (458 square miles) in 1951, while the urbanization of New York City jumped from 23.6 square kilometers (9.1 square miles) in 1850 to 3,245 square meters in 1950. Kilometers (1253 square miles). Under this development trend, the public facilities of the city are distributed to a wider extent, and education and transportation have also developed profoundly during this period. The uneconomical nature of large cities is still taking place during this period, and the multi-center urban structure plan for urban diseases was raised during this period. Urban public facilities are distributed to a wider range. During this period there was the famous Crystal Palace building, the luxurious Paris Opera, the Eiffel Tower and the magnificent Trinity Church in Boston. There is also the Leeds Currency Exchange in London, the Old Railway Station in London, and the Eman Art Museum in Milan. Under the conditions of new structural technology, the building has made a huge breakthrough in the number of layers and heights. The first high-rise building was the Chicago Family Insurance Company Building, which has ten floors. During this period, the improvement of large-scale indoor open spaces such as factories, museums and railway stations was made possible through the improvement of the ironmaking process. Central and local municipal services are also expanding in terms of life and culture. Such as sewage and garbage treatment facilities, arrange urban transportation, build public toilets, houses, markets, and cultural sites such as libraries, expo, art galleries. Founded in 1851, the Crystal Palace in Hyde Park, London is mainly used for the huge international exhibition of industrial products. Wholesale markets and retail stores have also been firmly established. For example, in Prussia, the number of retailers per thousand people is twice as many as 1900 in 1850. In addition, international organizations are also established in Europe (Table 2.7). Education and transportation also experienced profound development during this period. First, there were some developments in the UK, followed by France, followed
50
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Table 2.7 Number of international organizations from the 1950s to 1910 Before 1857
1870
1880
1890
1900
1910
7
17
20
31
61
108
Source Frederick L. Nasbaum: The History of Modern European Economic Systems
by Germany and the United States. After the American Civil War, only 100 universities and secondary technical schools were established in 1865, including MIT, universities and specialized technical schools to 450. In terms of transportation, trains and airplanes have been widely used during this period. By the end of the nineteenth century, the United States had built five railway lines across the East and West. In 1913, it increased to more than 300,000 miles, equivalent to half of the total length of the world railway at that time. At the beginning of the twentieth century, in 1903, the Wright brothers invented an aircraft powered by an internal combustion engine. The emergence of aircraft, the application of automobiles and the rapid development of railways mark the arrival of a new world of transportation. The railway-based transportation industry has linked all parts of the country into a huge unified market, greatly enhancing the flow rate and process of industrial and agricultural products and other commodities, and further strengthening material exchange and personnel exchanges between cities, between urban and rural areas and between regions, while consolidating the urban system. The urban planning of London, the leading city of this period, also reflects the multi-center spatial structure of the city. At the end of the nineteenth century, the British government authorized British social activist Howard to conduct urban surveys and propose remediation plans. Howard believes that building an ideal city should make urban life and rural life attract and combine with each other like magnets. This urban–rural integration is called a rural city. Howard advocates that when any city reaches a certain size, it should stop growing, and its excess should be accepted by another neighboring city. Thus, residential areas, like cell proliferation, present a multi-center complex urban agglomeration area. The planning of the urban area of London in the 1930s absorbed the essence of the idyllic city and proposed the concept of a combined city. In 1939, Abercrombie presided over the preparation of the Greater London Plan. The plan was divided into four geographical zones from the inside to the outside within a radius of about 48 km from the center of London, namely the inner ring, the suburb, the green belt and the outer ring.. The outer ring outside the green belt is mainly used to evacuate the surplus population and industrial enterprises in Londonshire. The concept of a combined city proposed by the Greater London Plan played a role in controlling the spontaneous spread of the city of London at the time and improving the already chaotic urban environment. 3. The leading cities in the 1950s and 1950s are thousands of kilometers of urban agglomerations. In densely populated industrialized countries, urban areas with metropolitan areas as competition units have also been formed. At the same time, the information revolution broke out during this period. The developing countries have grown rapidly. A large
2.1 From the Micro Level, the Change of Leading Cities Causes the Basic …
51
number of people have flooded into cities. The secondary and tertiary industries have developed rapidly. The land for mining, commerce, housing, transportation, municipal administration and greening has increased. Its cultivated land occupying the edge of the city spreads and expands outward. The world’s leading urban agglomerations form thousands of kilometers of urban agglomerations, such as the total area of the Pacific Rim in Japan, which is about 35,000 square kilometers. The total area of the Atlantic coast of the northeastern United States, centered on New York, is 138,000 square kilometers. During this period, the cities that grew rapidly in developing countries stimulated the rapid expansion of urban space in the world. The public facilities in the city were further enriched, and the urban space was greatly expanded. Urban development in this period generally shows the structural characteristics of the metropolitan area and urban agglomeration. The public facilities in the city are further enriched. In terms of urban construction, the developed countries in the 1950s adopted new city construction and urban sub-centers for the problems of large cities, such as excessive complex pressures, traffic congestion and environmental pollution in the old city, such as Cumbernauld in the United Kingdom. Welwyn in Sweden, the new city in Japan, and Zelenograd in the Soviet Union. Since the 1960s, the Tsukuba Science City, the European and American Science Park, and the Kansai Science City have been established in the developed regions. In addition, this period has a new exploration of the construction of the city center, commercial blocks and residential areas, such as the ancient city of Rome in Italy. The commercial shopping environment has evolved from a single plane to a three-dimensional giant commercial complex that utilizes the comprehensive utilization of above-ground and underground spaces, from the ground-based pedestrian zone to the pedestrian bridge commercial area and underground commercial street of the second-floor system. In terms of living facilities, people gradually replaced manual labor with advanced equipment such as robots, electronic computers, microprocessors, CNC automatic machine tools, telex machines, and data communications. In terms of transportation methods, science and technology developed rapidly after the 1980s. Technological advancement greatly promoted the upgrading of transportation structure from two aspects: transportation demand and transportation supply, which made passenger transportation faster and more comfortable, and cargo transportation became more specialized. Overloaded. The internal structure of various modes of transportation such as expressways, luxury buses, highspeed railways, heavy-duty trains, large-scale ship-specific terminals and wide-body passenger aircraft has been significantly improved and matured. At the same time, at a higher level, the rational allocation of transportation resources and the improvement of comprehensive transportation capacity have also accelerated the adjustment of the overall structure of the comprehensive transportation system. At this time, the overall characteristics of the urban space present the structure of the metropolitan area and the urban agglomeration. In densely populated industrial countries, the dot-like aggregation pattern of large urban populations has gradually been replaced by scattered urban areas. This is a particularly important phenomenon in the development of urban population to today, and it is also a worldwide trend. An example of a major leading urban group cited by French geographer Gottman
52
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
is the urban area on the northeast coast of the United States, extending from New Hampshire in the south to Virginia, including New York, Baltimore, Philadelphia, Boston, Washington, and others. The city, the entire region is 600 miles long, 30–100 miles wide, and covers an area of 53 500 square miles, with a population of 90%. For example, in the Rhine-Ruhr area of the Federal Republic of Germany, there are 19 large and medium-sized cities in the area of 4,953 square kilometers, which is not only the heart of the Federal German economy, but also the world’s famous coal and steel base. The port city group in the Netherlands, centered on Rotterdam, Amsterdam, The Hague and Utrecht, the four largest port cities, has a city circle of about 70 km from east to west, 60 km from north to south, and an area of 3,800 square kilometers. It accounts for 35% of the total population of the Netherlands and has an average population density that is three times the population density of the rest of the Netherlands. Such giant urban belts (groups, circles) are also in the Los Angeles-San Francisco metropolitan area; in Japan, there are three major metropolitan areas of Tokyo, Osaka, and Nagoya. Since then, the global information revolution has further expanded the scope of the city’s functions. Economic globalization and informatization will realize the cooperation of communication networks and high-speed transportation in the world’s multiple independent but complementary cities, and strive for more economic and social cooperation. The cyberspace of a city changes the concept of time and space in urban physical space. The flow of capital and information flows from one city to another at an invisible speed of light. Compared with traditional urban structure, virtual urban space has greater diversity and creativity, as well as a better urban environment and more freedom of location. It is expected that by 2050, the size and structure of urban space will further present the characteristics of smart cities. The future smart city system will be able to prevent problems before and prevent and solve problems with active and targeted work methods. Government work will use data-supported performance appraisal as a driving force to continuously improve work results. Building a data-driven smart city to create the core competitiveness of urban rapid response, data sharing, and efficient service. The city is adaptable, responsive, and always relevant to all people who live, work, and visit the city. Smart cities integrate technology to accelerate, promote and change this ecosystem.
2.2 From the Perspective of Macro Structure, the Evolution of Global Urban System Determines the Change of the world’s Pattern and System In the development of human history, city is the skeleton and blood of the world, and the urban system and pattern determine the system and pattern of the world. In the 300 years from 1750 to 2050, the formation and evolution of global urban system determines the evolution of global system and pattern. The world takes the lead in the
2.2 From the Perspective of Macro Structure, the Evolution of Global Urban …
53
rise of the country and region driven by the first rising city, and the general prosperity of global cities drives the arrival of the global urban era.
2.2.1 Global Urban Economic System: From Global Duality to Global Integration, from Commodity Trading System to Factor Trading System, and Then from Industrial Chain System to Innovation Chain System Since 1750, the global economy has changed from a global urban system of primary commodities to a global system dominated by capital intensive commodities and transnational corporations as the body, and then to a global system dominated by capital flows. A global urban innovation system dominated by the exchange of knowledge, information and ideas of global cities, with technical products and paper cooperation as carriers, is emerging. Using OECD Global trade data, this report finds that the proportion of manufactured goods in Global trade products increased from 48% in 1962 to 63% in 2016, while the proportion of primary commodities decreased from 44 to 18%, which fully shows the substitution of industrial products for primary commodities. At the same time, the internal structure of industrial manufactured products has also changed significantly. The proportion of capital intensive products is relatively stable, accounting for about half of industrial manufactured products. However, the proportion of technology intensive products has gradually increased, from 6% in 1962 to 23% in 2016 (Fig. 2.12). The production of human beings has changed from supply shortage to overproduction, and people’s consumption has gradually changed from commodity oriented to service-oriented, but there is a large gap between global cities, as shown in Fig. 2.13. Figure 2.13 shows that the developed countries have changed into service stations in the global trade, and the proportion of service industry in the United States has reached 41%; while the less developed countries are still in the commodity oriented stage. 1. The global urban system was mainly centered on Western European cities in 1750–1850s, such as London and Paris, with the rise of North American cities and the relative backwardness of Asian, African and Latin American cities, forming a global trading system dominated by the cities of Western European industrial countries. The industrial revolution promoted the initial formation of the global market and the expansion of the global urban connection. The completion of the industrial revolution made the goods produced by the advanced capitalist countries flow to all parts of the world, and the funds and raw materials from all parts of the world gathered in the industrial developed countries, thus forming the global market dominated by the western developed industrial countries.
54
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
1962
2010
1990
2016
Fig. 2.12 Changes in Global trade goods since the 1960s. Note PP, IP and OP refer to primary commodities, industrial manufactured products and other commodities respectively; LP, CP, TP and OT refer to labor-intensive products, capital-intensive products, technology-intensive products and other unclassified products in industrial manufactured products respectively. In this paper, the classification is mainly based on SITC classification and Yang Rudai et al. (2007, 2008) classification standard. Source Based on OECD data)
In most parts of the world, administrative services, trade, raw material exports and other factors are important factors for global urban growth. After Britain lifted the ban on machine output in 1825, a large number of machines were exported, which had a significant impact on the industrialization of France, Germany, the United States and other countries. It took France, the United States, Germany and Japan only about 60 years, 50 years, 40 years and 30 years to complete the industrial revolution, which established the world pattern of developed industrial countries in Europe and the United States and other regions in the world with backward industries. With the export of machine equipment and products from developed industrial countries, the global urban connection has been expanded, and the pattern of East–West poles of global cities has been formed. As can be seen from Fig. 2.11, until the 1960s, Global trade was still dominated by primary commodities, while service trade was
2.2 From the Perspective of Macro Structure, the Evolution of Global Urban …
1960
2010
55
1990
2017
Fig. 2.13 Proportion of global service trade since 1960s. Source https://ourworldindata.org
in a low position. And the global trade level is at a low level. In 1850, the global trade volume was 14.5 billion mark, with a slow growth. At the same time, the global urban trade pattern has also been solidified due to the industrial revolution, and the global industrial transfer between cities is less, especially in developed countries and backward Asian, African and Latin American countries. In order to export commodities, seize raw materials and overseas markets, developed western industrial countries such as Britain and France have embarked on the road of overseas expansion, respectively plundering backward regions such as India, Southeast Asia, ancient China and Africa. These backward countries or regions are still relying on traditional manual production, so they are forced to open up to the outside world and embed into global urban commodity market. This is mainly because in most parts of Asia and Africa, the low labor cost and the lack of a large consumption base hinder the use of machines, so these regions tend to develop the original rural industry. In the face of the impact of industrial output from developed countries, the industrial system of backward countries such as Asia, Africa and Latin America has also been challenged. In a word, the connections of the global urban economic are mainly based on the export of primary commodities and the transaction
56
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
of raw materials. Capital flows between cities in some developed industrial countries. The disperse of the global urban industrial and agricultural production pattern is more obvious, and a global urban system has not yet been formed. 2. The global urban system turned to a new stage, which was dominated by European and American cities, the rapid development of North American cities, and the rise of Asian, African and Latin American cities in the 1850–1950s. The cities of European and American still occupy the advantage of manufacturing industry in Global trade, and the cities of Asian, African and Latin American are in the low-end primary product output position. The second industrial revolution, marked by the wide application of internal combustion engine and electric power, not only promoted the unprecedented development of industrial production, but also promoted more products to be sold all over the world and expanded the scope and scale of world trade rapidly, and further developed the world market. By 1950, the global trade volume had increased to about 60 billion US dollars. At the same time, the international division of labor is becoming increasingly obvious, and the international flow of population and capital and trade are gradually expanding. The invention of communication technology, tools and transportation equipment, such as telegraph, telephone, airplane and ocean going ship, further reduced the space cost between global cities and promoted the formation of global market. At this stage, some cities with advantages such as superior location and natural seaport began to rise, such as the rise of the Great Lakes city belt in the United States, Los Angeles and so on. Industrial cities in developed countries were updated through industrial structure transformation, such as the urban renewal in London and the transformation from industrial structure to service industry. On the one hand, the second industrial revolution promoted the competition and connection between the cities. The application of new technologies and the rise of new industries have promoted the significant changes in the economic development of advanced industrial countries. The trend of the socialization of capitalist production has been strengthened, the competition among enterprises has been intensified, and the concentration of production and capital has been promoted. A few enterprises adopting new technologies have crushed a large number of enterprises with backward technology, and the inflow and outflow of enterprises between cities have been enhanced. At the same time, the improvement of transportation network and communication technology has been made. It shortens the distance between cities and strengthens the economic connection between them. In addition, the second industrial revolution expanded the scale and scope of Global trade, finally established the capitalist world system, and gradually made the world as a whole. It also aggravates the imbalance of global economic development. The gap between the western developed industrial countries and the eastern backward countries is further widened. The industrial development level of the Asian, African and Latin American backward countries and regions is locked in the primary commodity stage by the developed industrial countries, mainly focusing on agriculture and mining industry. The global cities are still dominated by commodity export,
2.2 From the Perspective of Macro Structure, the Evolution of Global Urban …
57
at the same time, the internationalization of capital appears in this stage, multinational companies begin to seek to maximize profits through overseas investment, and the global cities initially form a world market dominated by commodity trade and supplemented by capital. 3. The global urban system changed from East–West segmentation to integration from 1950 to 2050. The global urban system was a segmentation system dominated by western developed countries and led by the Soviet Union from 1950 to 1990. In 1990, the global urban system gradually became integration. The global industrial division and global value chain construction of the global industrial system will be dominated by the global urban innovation system by 2050. Since the 1950s, due to international political reasons, The two camps of the East and the West centered on the United States and the Soviet Union have been formed in the world, and the pattern of two poles of global cities has been formed. However, with the disintegration of the Soviet Union in 1991, the process of global urban integration gradually accelerated, and the development of global urban multipolarity has become a new trend. The formation of global urban division network, the formation of global urban division value chain with developed countries’ cities as the leading role, the enhancement of “deindustrialization” and service-oriented trend of developed countries’ cities. The later-development countries’ cities accepting global urban industrial transfer get rapid development, especially the rapid rise of developing countries’ cities represented by China, Southeast Asia, etc., and forming a global urban division network system. Cities in developed countries have realized industrial transformation and upgrading through global industrial transfer, such as London, Paris, New York, Los Angeles and other international metropolises have successfully realized timely industrial transformation and transformation of comparative advantage with the pace of technological progress, and become the center of global finance, science and technology, and economy. The new generation of information and communication technology, represented by computer information technology, is profoundly changing the way of production and life of human beings, the development of high-tech and service economy, and the content and contact way of global urban transactions. As shown in Fig. 2.10, the proportion of primary commodities in Global trade decreased from 44 to 18%, while the proportion of technology intensive products increased from 48 to 63%, indicating the upgrading of global urban trading varieties and the upgrading of global urban industrial structure. In addition, with the increase of the proportion of services in Global trade, the proportion of trade in cities of some countries has exceeded 30% or even more than 50%. In particular, in the current information economy era, the role of knowledge and information in the global urban network is more important. Cities such as Hangzhou, Shanghai, Shenzhen along the east coast of China and Guiyang seize the opportunity of the new generation of information technology and quickly become the leading cities of the new generation of Intelligent Technology. There have been three large-scale industrial transfers in the world. The global manufacturing center has gradually shifted from the developed economies such as
58
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Fig. 2.14 The connectivity of global transnational corporations. Data source Cass global urban competitiveness database
the United States to Japan and Germany, then to the “four dragons” region in Asia, and then to the eastern coastal region of China, so as to promote China to become a “world factory”. Among them, transnational corporations are the main body to promote the strengthening of global urban linkages, as shown in Fig. 2.14. As can be seen from Fig. 2.14, the global city transnational corporations’ connection degree shows certain spatial differentiation. Cities in Europe, America, Japan and other countries are densely distributed with transnational corporations’ and have a high degree of connection with global cities. The transnational connection of cities in some Asian countries is gradually improving, such as Beijing, Shanghai, Shenzhen, Hong Kong, Mumbai in India, Bangalore in China, and Brazil in Brazil. Global urban links such as Johannesburg in Asia and South Africa have been pushed into the advanced ranks in the world, and the internal level of global urban network system has been further strengthened with the development of the new generation of information technology revolution. From 2000 to 2050, the global urban innovation system represented by big data and intelligent technology will replace the traditional global urban economic system dominated by commodity and capital flow. Technology, especially intelligent technology services and leading the global urban development are new trends, and promote the global cities to form a new intelligent division of labor pattern. By 2050, global cities will form a global innovation system dominated by major global technological cities, such as London, New York, Beijing, Tokyo, etc. (Fig. 2.15). Intelligence is an important development direction of the innovation system. The development of information and communication technology, represented by big data and artificial intelligence, has broken the traditional “limitation of space boundary”. With the formation of global urban network, human beings have entered a new era in which the intelligent city of interconnection, intercommunication and intelligence is the carrier of production and living space.
2.2 From the Perspective of Macro Structure, the Evolution of Global Urban …
59
Unit: 10000 people 180
170
160 140 120 100
120
115 104
102.4
95.7
94
89.4
85
83.4
80 60 40 20 0
Fig. 2.15 The distribution of intelligent manufacturing technology talents in global cities, top 10. Source The development trend report of world intelligent manufacturing center [2019]
In a certain process of human history development, the city is the skeleton and blood of the world, and the urban system and pattern determine the system and pattern of the world. In the 300 years from 1750 to 2050, the formation and evolution of the global urban system determined the evolution of the global system and pattern. The world’s first rise in the city to lead the country and region to rise first. The universal prosperity of global cities has brought the era of global cities.
2.2.2 Urban Scale System: From the System Dominated by Small Cities in Europe and America to the System Dominated by Big Cities Around the World The flow of economic resources has gradually broken the boundaries between countries, making the role of cities in promoting the development of the global economy more and more prominent, and then emerging in the space power to transcend the national scope and play an important role in the development of the world economy. Big city in the world. Especially since the twentieth century, the acceleration of the flow of various factors between cities has made the world’s cities more closely connected. The multi-level world city scale system led by the world’s big cities has replaced the cities dominated by small cities in Europe and America. The size structure of urban population is an important manifestation of urban development level and welfare level. The scale of cities is directly related to the level of human development and welfare. The larger scale of cities means higher levels
60
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
of human development and human welfare, because of the increasing returns and diversity. The large-scale system of the world’s cities has determined that human activities are more concentrated, and that human development levels and welfare levels continue to increase. The industrial revolution mainly involved the transfer of an unprecedented number of laborers from rural to urban areas, forming a large and large number of cities. Yale University’s 6,000-year study of urban development and urban population size shows the changing patterns of the number and size of global cities from 3700 BC to AD 2000. The number of important cities in the world is shown in Fig. 2.16. In different periods, in the 3700 BC, the number of cities in the world was very small, mainly concentrated in parts of Europe, and the population growth was slow. From the first year of AD to 1750, as the pre-modern period, the city scale slowly expanded and the city began to Europe has spread to Asia, but large-scale cities still mainly gather in Europe. Since entering the modern era in 1750, the urban population has grown rapidly. From 1750 to 1850, the first industrial revolution led to the rapid expansion of the city of the rising British nation; the second industrial revolution between 1850 and 1950 was mainly carried out in North America and continental Europe, bringing the size of the US and European cities. With greater growth, the United States has been side by side with the United Kingdom; since 1950, emerging economies have emerged, with populations mainly concentrated in large and medium-sized cities, and the population of developed economies has mainly concentrated in small and medium-sized cities, and the world urban scale system has been renewed. According to Yale University’s research, the number of cities in the world in 6,000 years has been shown in Table 2.8. 1. 1750–1850: Small cities with a focus on European cities such as the UK dominate the world city scale system. The size of the UK city is rapidly expanding and its development is unique. In the early eighteenth century, the emerging industrial cities were mainly distributed in Western Europe, where natural resources were abundant, transportation was convenient, and modern industries were suitable for development. The rise of these new cities and industrial clusters is generally a semi-urban area or a small town that does not occupy an important position in the traditional dominant urban system. They attract a large number of people due to industrial development and eventually develop into industries that transcend traditional cities. A town or a regional economic center city. At the beginning of the eighteenth century, the population of the seven counties in the south of England accounted for one-third of the population of the whole of England. After the industrial revolution began, the total population of the United Kingdom increased by 1.54 times from 1801 to 1870, including industrial clusters in the northwest and London in the south. And the suburban population increased by 2.58 times and 2.1 times respectively. It is estimated that between 1801–1851, the UK textile industry population growth rate ranked first with 229%, other port cities increased by 214%, and manufacturing cities increased by 186. %; the speed of individual cities is even more alarming. From 1811–1861, the population of Liverpool and Preston has
2.2 From the Perspective of Macro Structure, the Evolution of Global Urban …
61
Fig. 2.16 Changes in the number and scale of global cities. Source Reba, Meredith, F. Reitsma, and K. C. Seto. “Spatializing 6,000 years of global urbanization from 3700 BC to AD 2000.” Scientific Data 3(2016): 160,034
62
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Table 2.8 Statistics of the years with the highest number of global cities from 3700 BC to AD 2000 Year
1900 1800 1850 1950 1975 1750 2000 1700 1600 1925 1500 1400 1300
Number 1094 511 of city Year
484
430
393
294
293
272
238
214
1200 1851 1000 1801 1550 1650 1825 1450 1100 800
Number 147 of city
116
107
91
89
89
84
83
81
75
203
173
172
1250 1875 74
74
Source Reba, Meredith, F. Reitsma, and K. C. Seto. “Spatializing 6,000 years of global urbanization from 3700 BC to AD 2000.” Scientific Data 3(2016): 160,034
increased fivefold, Brighton has increased sevenfold, and the textile textile center Bradford has grown eightfold. The industrialization process of other developed capitalist countries started relatively late, so the scale of urban development was slow during this period. For example, between 1810 and 1840, French agricultural output accounted for about 66.5% of the country’s total output value, still playing a major role in the French economy. In 1806, the rural population of France was 23.69 million, and it increased to 26.75 million in 1846, accounting for 75.6% of the total population of France. During this period, France’s economic thinking of small farmers was deeply rooted and restricted the flow of rural population to cities. 2. 1850–1950: The scale of the world city dominated by small and medium-sized cities with European and American cities as the center of gravity. The scale of cities in Europe and North America has expanded rapidly. During the second industrial revolution, it was mainly based on the population size system of countries such as Europe and America. We mainly take Germany and the United States as examples. The German industrial revolution started during this period. In the short 29 years from 1871 to 1910, Germany adopted the advanced science and technology of Britain, France and other countries to catch up with the United Kingdom, surpassed France and realized the backward agricultural country. The transition to an advanced industrial country. During this period, the number of cities and urban population in Germany increased rapidly, and the size of the city continued to expand. Since the 1840s, there have been a number of emerging cities in Germany, mainly industrial and mining cities, such as Seldorf and Essen in the Ruhr area. These cities rely on local resource advantages and the convenience of land and water transportation to attract large amounts of investment and labor. These cities are expanding along the route and the population is increasing. As shown in Table 2.9, from 1871 to 1910, the population of cities with more than 100,000 people grew the fastest, and its share of the total population of the country increased from 4.8% to 21.3%. The cities with smaller populations have a larger decline, from 63.9 in 1871. % to 39.6% in 1910. Driven by the industrialization process, the US population scale system was also formed. The United States has contributed to the rapid expansion of a series of large
2.2 From the Perspective of Macro Structure, the Evolution of Global Urban … Table 2.9 Germany’s urban population as a percentage of the country’s population from 1871 to 1910 (%)
City size
63
1871
1910
More than 100,000
4.8
21.3
10,000–100,000 people
7.7
13.4
2,000–10,000 people
23.6
25.4
Less than 2,000 people
63.9
39.6
and medium-sized cities mainly due to the progress of the industrial revolution and the formation of monopoly organizations. Chicago was still desolate in the early nineteenth century. In 1837, the city was formally established. In 1880, the city had a population of 500,000. In 1910, it crossed the 2 million mark and became the second largest city in the United States.. Detroit is a car city, and the development of the automotive industry led to the development of oil fields in Southern California, making the western city of Los Angeles the largest refining center in the United States. The development of cities such as Birmingham and Houston is related to the development of steel and oil and automobiles. The development of the service industry and retail industry has led to the rapid expansion of cities such as Liszt and Seattle in Atlanta and the Minnie River. On the basis of the rapid increase in the number of cities, scale expansion, functional development and close interconnection, a nationwide modern urban system has been formed, mainly in the following: the density of the national urban network has increased several times; the distribution of urban areas has been improving day by day, and the cities in the past have been scarce. The western and southern regions already have a certain number of cities at all levels, gradually forming a combined city, a combination of urban and professional cities, a modern urban system combining large, medium and small cities; the function of the city is also constantly expanding (Table 2.10). Table 2.10 The number of American cities and the urban population of the United States from 1790–1950 (one, 100,000 people, %) Year
Total National population
Number of city
Population of city
Urban population as a percentage of total population
1790
3.9
24
0.2
5.1
1810
7.2
46
0.5
7.3
1830
12.9
–
1.1
8.8
1850
23.3
–
3.5
15.3
1870
39.8
663
9.9
25
1900
76.1
1737
30.2
39.6
1910
92.4
–
42
45.7
1930
123.1
–
69
56.2
1950
151.7
4741
96.5
63.6
64
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
3. 1950–2050: A large-scale, large, medium, and small-scale urban scale system that is heading for the all-round development of the world. The global population is expanding. In 1950, 70.4% of the total population lived in rural areas, 17.8% lived in urban residential areas with a population of less than 300,000, and the remaining 11.8% lived in other larger cities. Over the next three decades, the urban population increased by nearly 920 million people, from 750 million in 1950 to 1.75 billion in 1980. By 2018, the global urban population will exceed the rural population. The global urban population has grown from 1.75 billion in 1980 to 4.22 billion in 2018, and the urban population has increased from 39.3% in 1980 to 55.3% in 2018. The population of all types of cities continues to grow. Among them, the medium-sized cities have a faster population growth rate. Although the total size of megacities has been relatively small, it has increased from nearly 86 million in 1980 to 529 million today, an increase of nearly five times. However, with the acceleration of urbanization, it is expected that the proportion of rural population will fall by 13.1% by 2050 (Table 2.11). The scale of urban systems in large and medium-sized cities in emerging economies continues to expand. From the perspective of the world urban population size system, the cities of major developed countries have achieved high urbanization after the first industrial revolution and the second industrial revolution, and the population size has not increased significantly. As shown in Table 2.12, we can see that In the past 65 years, Tokyo, Osaka, New York, Los Angeles, and Paris have seen an increase in urban population between 0.5 and 2.5 times. Most of the other cities are urban populations in developing countries, and the population size has increased significantly during this period. New Delhi, Beijing, Karachi, Istanbul, Lahore and Bangalore have all experienced population growth of more than 10 times. The population growth of Dhaka and Lagos has exceeded 30 times. This reflects the trend that the scale of emerging economies is concentrated in large and medium-sized cities. It is expected that after 2035, New Delhi will surpass Tokyo to become the largest city in the world. A few cities in developed countries such as Paris and Seoul in 2050 will withdraw from the top 30 cities in the world. After the twenty-first century, the emerging urban agglomerations of East Asia have become the core strength of the world. The East Asia region of the world’s top six cities is about two seats. It mainly includes the Pacific Coast urban agglomerations of Japan’s Tokaido and China’s Yangtze River Delta urban agglomerations. “Tokaido Pacific Coast City Group” consists of three metropolitan areas: Tokyo, Nagoya, and Osaka. The total number of large, medium, and small cities is 310, including Tokyo, Yokohama Kawasaki Nagoya, Osaka, Kobe, Kyoto, and other major cities. Ten of the large cities with a population of over 1 million are located in the urban agglomeration. The three major urban agglomerations cover an area of about 100,000 square kilometers, accounting for 31.7% of the country’s total area; the population is nearly 70 million, accounting for 63.3% of the country’s total population. It brings together two-thirds of Japanese industrial and industrial employment, three-quarters of industrial output and two-thirds of national income. The Yangtze River Delta urban agglomeration centered on Shanghai is mainly composed of Shanghai, Jiangsu
751
24
32
127
67
50
450
1785
Total population of the city
Megacity (over 10 million people)
Large city (500100 million people)
Medium city (100500 million people)
Small city (500,000–1 million people)
Smaller cities (300,000-500,000 people)
Less than 300,000 people
Rural population
2346
730
87
131
244
107
55
1354
3701
1970
2704
908
114
170
336
140
86
1754
4458
1980
3277
1315
200
269
626
214
245
2868
6145
2000
2010
3363
1578
246
355
760
269
387
3595
6958
2018
3413
1750
275
415
926
325
529
4220
7633
2050
3 092
2357
384
578
1370
504
825
6680
9772
70.4
17.8
2.0
2.7
5.0
1.3
0.9
29.6
100
63.4
19.7
2.3
3.5
6.6
2.9
1.5
36.6
100
1970
1950
2536
1950
Total population
Percentage
Population
Table 2.11 Population size and percentage of cities of all sizes in the world
60.7
20.4
2.6
3.8
7.5
3.1
1.9
39.3
100
1980
53.3
21.4
3.2
4.4
10.2
3.5
4.0
46.7
100
2000
48.3
22.7
3.5
5.1
10.9
3.9
5.6
51.7
100
2010
44.7
22.9
3.6
5.4
12.1
4.3
6.9
55.3
100
2018
31.6
28.6
5.1
6.1
14.3
5.7
8.5
68.4
100
2050
2.2 From the Perspective of Macro Structure, the Evolution of Global Urban … 65
66
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Table 2.12 The growth trend of the population size of major cities in the world from 1950 to 2020 (10,000 people, 100%) 1950 Tokyo
1970
1990
2010
2015
2035
2050 (predict)
1127.5 2329.8 3253.0 3686.0 3725.6 3601.4 3954.6
Annual growth rate(1950–2015) 2.3
New Delhi
136.9
353.1
938.4 2198.8 2586.6 4334.5 4944.5
17.9
Shanghai
428.8
605.2
860.6 2031.4 2348.2 3434.1 3584.1
4.5
Mexico City
336.5
883.1 1564.2 2013.7 2134.0 2541.5 3020.7
5.3
Sao paulo
233.4
762.0 1477.6 1966.0 2088.3 2449.0 3017.6
7.9
Mumbai
308.9
641.3 1235.5 1825.7 1931.6 2734.3 2962.0
5.3
Osaka
700.5 1527.2 1838.9 1931.3 1930.5 1834.6 2331.8
1.8
Cairo
249.4
989.2 1689.9 1882.0 2850.4 2962.8
6.5
1233.8 1619.1 1608.6 1836.5 1864.8 2081.7 2163.9
0.5
New York
558.5
Beijing
167.1
442.6
678.8 1644.1 1842.1 2536.6 3070.0
10.0
Dhaka
33.6
137.4
662.1 1473.1 1759.7 3123.4 3840.5
51.4
Buenos Aires
516.6
841.6 1114.8 1424.6 1470.6 1712.7 1942.6
1.8
Kolkata
460.4
732.9 1097.4 1400.3 1442.3 1956.4 2059.4
2.1
Karachi
105.5
311.9
714.7 1261.2 1428.9 2312.8 2590.0
12.5
Istanbul
96.7
277.2
655.2 1258.5 1412.7 1798.6 2263.8
13.6
Chongqing
156.7
223.7
401.1 1124.4 1337.2 2053.1 2745.5
7.5
Rio de Janeiro
302.6
679.1
969.7 1237.4 1294.1 1481.0 1767.3
3.3
Manila
154.4
353.4
797.3 1188.7 1286.0 1864.9 2082.5
7.3
Tianjin
246.7
331.8
455.8 1015.0 1251.6 1644.6 2104.6
4.1
Los Angeles
404.6
837.8 1088.3 1216.0 1234.5 1377.8 1606.6
2.1
Lagos
32.5
141.4
476.4 1044.1 1223.9 2441.9 2725.0
36.6
Moscow
535.6
710.6
898.7 1146.1 1204.9 1376.8 1527.5
1.2
Guangzhou
10.1
104.9
154.2
324.6 1027.8 1169.5 1674.1 2108.0
Kinshasa
20.2
107.0
368.3
Shenzhen
0.3
2.2
Paris
938.2 1159.8 2668.2 3594.0
56.4
87.5 1022.3 1127.5 1518.5 1882.7
3580.8
628.3
820.8
933.0 1046.0 1073.4 1199.2
12.935
0.7
Lahore
83.6
196.4
397.0
843.2 1036.9 1911.6
25.535
11.4
Jakarta
145.2
391.5
817.5
962.6 1017.3 1368.8 1557.5
6.0
74.6
161.5
404.3
829.6 1014.1 1806.6 2414.0
12.6
Bangalore Seoul
102.1
531.2 1051.8
979.6
989.7 1363.6 1532.4
8.7
2.2 From the Perspective of Macro Structure, the Evolution of Global Urban …
67
Province, Nanjing, Suzhou, Hangzhou, Ningbo, Zhejiang Province, and Hefei, Anhui Province. It has a land area of 217,700 square kilometers and a total population. 150 million people, accounting for 2.2% and 18.5% of the country respectively. Nowadays, it is among the sixth largest urban agglomerations in the world. It is the most dynamic urban agglomeration in China.
2.2.3 Urban Space System: From Isolated Cities to Urban Agglomerations and Then to the World of Metropolitan Coordination Regions The changing response of the world urban space system is an important manifestation of the spatial scale of human activities and the level of human development. The expansion of urban spatial units from small to large, from isolation to linkage, reflects the expansion of human activity space, the expansion of human interaction, and the increase of human sharing opportunities, which determines the world’s space-divided world becomes space gathering. And the continuous world. With the acceleration of globalization, the obstacles to the capital flow space are gradually eliminated, and the city is also separated from the local space relative to the world. The original world urban space system has gradually been broken, and it is being transformed from a two-dimensional system of cities-states to a more complex three-dimensional space system between “global-state-urban agglomerations”. Therefore, from isolated cities to cities The transformation of the world system from the group to the urban continuous zone is the result of the city’s development to a certain stage. With the further expansion of the population, the population of large cities is gradually replaced by the umbrella-shaped regional cities. The regional cities include urban belts in small and medium-sized cities, and the various economic functions complement each other, and the economic development of the entire country is even The economic status that affects the whole world has a non-negligible effect, which is mainly reflected in the late stage of urban development. During the first industrial revolution, the city group with London as a single center made the UK establish a world position with strong industrial power. After the 1950s and 1960s, a number of central urban agglomerations established within the United States made the United States the first to surpass the United Kingdom to establish the most powerful economic position in the world. After 1950, the developed countries such as Britain and the United States are still the world’s industrial and commercial powers„ However, during this period, a number of urban economic development zones have emerged on a global scale, especially since the twenty-first century,
68
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
emerging economic belts established in Asia and South America, such as the Japanese Pacific Coast urban agglomeration and the Yangtze River Delta urban agglomeration. 1. 1750–1850: World Urban Space System in the UK’s Leading Isolated City. During the first industrial revolution, the UK took the lead in forming a singlecenter core area centered on Greater London. In the course of its development, a series of small towns in the suburbs that gathered the agglomeration area were included. In 1801, there were approximately 1.2 million inhabitants in the Greater London area and 15% in the outlying areas of London (populations living outside the city boundaries of London). In 1901, the population of the city of London grew to 6.2 million. At the same time, it is not only the core center of Europe, but also the core area of the world city. The pound has become an international currency. London is not only the capital, political and financial center of the United Kingdom, but also the center of world finance. It is called the “world capital”. Mainly in the following aspects: First, priority to the development of water and land transportation in the world. At the end of the eighteenth century, the United Kingdom set off a boom in the construction of the canal, and soon formed a waterway transportation network connecting the mainland and the coast. After that, the UK shifted its focus to railway construction. In 1850, it increased to more than 10,000 km. At this time, the main railway line in the UK has been completed. Second, it takes precedence over coal and iron production in countries around the world. In 1850, the output of pig iron increased to 2.29 million tons, more than double the sum of France, Germany and the United States. In 1850, British coal production increased to 50 million tons, far exceeding the total coal production of France, Germany and the United States (19 million tons). The third is its unrivalled industrial and commercial development. British industry’s share of the world’s industry reached 47% in 1840. In the same year, France accounted for 12% and the United States accounted for 9%. In 1840, it accounted for 21% of total world trade. In the same year, France accounted for 11% and the United States accounted for 10%. The UK has pushed more than half of its industrial products to the world market and has become a veritable “world workshop”. The UK is also the richest country in the world. In 1850, it had assets of 225 million pounds overseas. Its gold reserves amount to £16.6 million. As shown in Table 2.13, in 1850, the number of London residents reached 2.36 million, much larger than the population of Paris during the same period. The industrial revolution prompted the developed countries represented by the United Kingdom to export goods and compete for raw materials overseas. Countries Table 2.13 Regional central city formed during the industrial period City age
City
Year 1800
1850
1900
London
86.5
236.3
453.6
Paris
54.7
105.3
271.4
Berlin
17.2
41.9
188.9
7.9
69.6
343.7
New York
2.2 From the Perspective of Macro Structure, the Evolution of Global Urban …
69
such as Asia, Africa and Latin America became the export destinations and raw materials sources of their overseas markets, and industrial development was locked in the stage of primary commodity production. However, countries such as Asia, Africa and Latin America are still in backward agricultural production. The country’s own economy has not yet undergone an industrial revolution. The industry mainly focuses on the processing of primary commodities such as agriculture and mining, and the production is relatively scattered in rural areas where labor is cheaper. 2. 1850–1950: The world urban space system of the metropolitan urban agglomeration led by the United States After the 1950s and 1960s, the second industrial revolution broke out. The development of Europe and North America showed a leap-forward development. The industrial structure was continuously optimized, the urbanization of the region was faster, and the city’s appearance was completely new. The most striking thing is the achievements of the United States. During this period, the United States first established its own urban space system over the United Kingdom, and at the same time became the most powerful industrial status in the world. First, the urban system was established within the American city. After the 1940s, the United States began its first industrial revolution. The wide application of steam engines has made a new leap in transportation technology, which is beneficial to the development of urban and industrial cities as well as to urbanization. The economic role of the city has been strengthened, and its social nature has changed. It has changed from the original commercial and cultural center to a modern industrial base, and at the same time, it has continuously produced new industrial cities. In the first 20 years of the twentieth century, trams and elevated railways have expanded the city’s radius to more than 10 miles. Central business districts, wage-earning areas, slums, and prosperous suburbs have emerged. The US urbanization process has advanced by leaps and bounds. The number of cities has increased dramatically, the scale has expanded, and the function has developed, basically forming a nationwide modern urbanization system. At the top of the pyramid of urbanization systems are comprehensive national central cities such as New York and Chicago. They play a leading role in the national urbanization system and are the political, economic and cultural centers of the country. Located in Taki, there are thousands of specialized local central cities based on certain industries, such as Baltimore, Philadelphia, Cincinnati, etc., which are the local economic and political centers that connect the integrated city with its surrounding small towns and The intermediary role of the rural hinterland. The large-scale emergence of cities has created a large number of employment opportunities, attracting a large number of immigrants and rural populations to move to cities. From 1851 to 1919, an average of 390,000 foreign immigrants flooded into the United States each year; in 1910, about 11 million of the country’s 42 million urban population flowed from rural to urban areas. 1920 is an epoch-making year in American history. In this year, the total population of the United States reached 106.7 million, and the urban population reached 54.16 million, more than half of the country’s total population. The United States has basically achieved urbanization.
70
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
As shown in Table 2.14, these cities, as the backbone of the US local economy, play an important role in the organization of local economic operations. The world’s industrial powers that the United States has also established during this period are embodied in three aspects: First, the advanced development of heavy industry. In 1870–1913, US industrial growth reached 8.1 times, with an average annual growth rate of 4.3%. 1877–1892 was the fastest industrial development in this period, and industrial production quadrupled, with an average annual growth rate of 7.1%. Second, the advance development of the power industry. In 1882, New York established the world’s first thermal power station. In 1914, the United States had reached 9 million horsepower. At that time, electricity accounted for 30% of the total industrial power, making it the world’s first power. Third, the United States is also the world’s largest automobile kingdom. In 1913, there were 1 million cars, accounting for 1/2 of the world’s total number of cars. In 1914, the annual output of cars reached 573,000. The United States has a rising status in the world of industry. In 1870, it accounted for 23.3% of the world’s industry, 29% from 1881 to 1885, 31% in 1890, more than Britain (22%), and 35.8% in 1913, close to Britain and Germany. The sum of the three countries of France and France. In the 30–40 years after the Civil War, the United States successfully completed the historical mission of industrialization, while at the same time catching up with and surpassing the United Kingdom to become the most powerful industrial country in the world. The achievements of the United States are enormous, and these decades have been called the industrial century and the gilded age of the United States. 3. 1950–2050: Towards a global metropolitan area and a networked development space system. After 1950, although the western developed countries such as the United Kingdom and the United States were still the world’s industrial and commercial powers, there Table 2.14 Functional positioning of major cities in the United States City
Main function positioning
New York
World-class super economic city, the center of the US economy
Chicago
National economic city
Los Angeles
National economic city
San Francisco
The economic strength and radiation range of the western Pacific coast of the United States is second only to important cities in Los Angeles
Boston
New England Regional Economic Center City
Philadelphia
The economic center of the Mid-Atlantic region
Houston
The economic center of Texas and the Gulf of Mexico
New Orleans
The largest commercial and financial center in the southern United States
Seattle
The largest industrial, commercial, and transportation center in the northwestern United States
2.2 From the Perspective of Macro Structure, the Evolution of Global Urban …
71
were already many urban economic development belts in the world during this period. Especially since the twenty-first century, the economic strengths established in the Asian and South American regions have developed at the same speed and scale as the metropolitan belts previously established in the West, such as the Japanese Pacific Coast urban agglomeration and the Yangtze River Delta urban agglomeration. We first understand the hierarchical layout of cities in this period from the perspective of the global system, and then analyze the urban system within the country during this period by taking the Tokyo metropolitan area as an example.
2.2.4 Firstly, the Global Urban Scale System is Gradually Forming In the late twentieth century, Friedman believed that the world’s cities were distributed in a strip of things, from Tokyo to New York to London, forming a linear global world city circle. This global world city circle can be divided into three subsystems: one is the Asian subsystem based on Tokyo-Singapore, in which Tokyo is the world city, Singapore is the regional international city in Southeast Asia, and the second is the American subsystem. New York, Chicago and Los Angeles are major central cities, with Toronto to the north, Caracas and Mexico City to the south, and many small countries in Canada, Central America and the Caribbean to the American metropolitan area. Third, the Western European subsystem to London and Paris. The core of the Rhine Valley is the core. The southern hemisphere constitutes a subsystem centered on Johannesburg and São Paulo. Currently, internationally recognized global cities are New York, Tokyo and London. These three cities are concentrated in far more than the proportion of banks and financial institutions, especially foreign banks, and other companies engaged in financial transactions; they are also the largest concentration of the world’s largest corporate headquarters. In addition, there are about 20 global or regional central cities, including Paris, San Francisco, Los Angeles, and Mexico City (Hall, 1997). In 2016, the world urban system was renewed. There are 2 super-first-tier cities in the world, 7 strong cities in the first-line, 19 in the first-tier cities, and 21 in the first-tier weak cities. According to this list, Guangzhou has become the fifth city in China to be promoted to the Alpha level, ranking second only to Hong Kong, Beijing, Shanghai and Taipei in China (GaWC Report, 2016). Secondly, National Urban Belt System: Taking the Tokyo City Belt in Japan as an Example. Tokyo Metropolitan (City Center) refers to the central business district of Chiyoda, Chuo-ku, and Minato-ku in the center of Tokyo. National ministries. The headquarters of many embassies and major corporations. In the 1950s, with the rapid growth of the Japanese economy, the business function of the city was rapidly developed, and a highly centralized central business district was soon formed. at the same time.
72
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
The price of the land is high. The residence began to shift to the suburbs. Large-scale urban agglomerations such as single-center gathering and long-term commuting have emerged. In the early 1960s, there was a shortage of business office space in the heart of the city. The government began to realize that it was necessary to suppress the convergence of business functions to the heart of the city, and to spread the urban structure that balances work and residence. Therefore, Tokyo has proposed the idea and plan to construct the deputy center of the city and guide the transfer of the city from a single-center structure to a multi-center structure. At present, Tokyo has formed a multi-hearted urban structure including seven sub-centric cities and five nuclear cities in the Ta ma area. As shown Table 2.15, they are basically located at the intersection of the Yamanote Line (loop) and the various railway radiation lines, making full use of the traffic hub’s aggregation effect on business and people flow. The most effective of these are the two sub-centers of Shinjuku and Lin hai, which have the functions of a strong business center. They are located in the western part of the transportation hub of Tokyo. The sub-center of Tokyo is a multi-functional, highly complex area. While meeting business activities. It also has other functions such as business, culture, entertainment, and residence. For example, Shinjuku City has formed a complete layout integrating business, shopping, culture and entertainment with the Shinjuku Station Building and the east of the station as the commercial and entertainment center and the west of the station as the administrative office and business office center. On the other hand, in the twenty-first century, it emphasizes the informationization and intelligence of the new city, and the construction of the Tokyo Communication Port is an important goal for the development of a new metropolis. It is estimated that by 2050, the scale and structure of urban space will be based on the online global world city circle + national internal urban belt system, and the previous planning and design around the core cities of major metropolitan areas with the goal of regional balanced development will be converted into The superlarge metropolitan area gathered in the urban area will alleviate the imbalance of regional development in the unipolar concentration of megacities, the reliance of small and medium-sized cities on the central metropolis, and form a greater regional Table 2.15 List of world first-tier cities City level
City name
(Alpha++) Super London, New York Line Alpha+) First strong line
Singapore, Hong Kong, Paris, Beijing, Tokyo, Dubai, Shanghai
First middle line (Alpha)
Sydney, Sao Paulo, Milan, Chicago, Mexico City, Mumbai, Moscow, Frankfurt, Madrid, Warsaw, Johannesburg, Toronto, Seoul, Istanbul, Kuala Lumpur, Jakarta, Amsterdam, Brussels, Los Angeles
(Alpha-) First weak line
Dublin, Melbourne, Washington, New Delhi, Bangkok, Zurich, Vienna, Taipei, Buenos Aires, Stockholm, San Francisco, Guangzhou, Manila, Santa Fe Bogota, Miami, Luxembourg City, Riyadh, San Diego, Barcelona, Tel Aviv, Lisbon
2.3 From the Perspective of Macro Gross, Global Urban Development Has …
73
international competitiveness. At the same time, on the basis of regional consensus, promote the development of metropolises, propose planning plans to face common problems, and propose different development plans according to the different situations of metropolises and local cities, and connect them according to the actual development status of each region.
2.3 From the Perspective of Macro Gross, Global Urban Development Has Completed the Epoch-Making Transformation of Human Civilization The overall scale of global cities determines the degree of urbanization of human society, In the 300 years from 1750 to 2050, human beings will change from the rural society of urban–rural integration to the urban society of urban–rural integration.
2.3.1 Impact of Urban Industrial Development on the World Economy and Pattern 1. from 1750 to 1850, the city guided the world and the UK became the world industrial country. Before the industrial revolution, most people lived in the countryside and lived by farming and animal husbandry. The production tools were only simple handicrafts, regardless of the production power of the country or the city, such as manpower, animal power, wind power and water power. Lord, so production is limited, production efficiency is low, and people have to do a lot of agricultural production and labor for their lives. It can be seen from the Figs. 2.17 and Figs. 2.18 that before the industrial revolution, the major countries in the world, such as the United Kingdom, the United States, France, Mexico, China, India, Japan and other countries, all occupied a higher level of agricultural employment, The people of most countries are engaged in agricultural activities. However, after the industrial revolution, the factory system replaced the manual workshop, replaced the manual labor with machines, and the productivity has made a huge leap. A large number of laborers gathered in factories and cities, and urbanization and industrial production gradually occupied a dominant position. The proportion of agricultural output has gradually declined (see Figs. 2.17 and 2.18). The industrial revolution has changed the industrial structure of countries. After the industrial revolution, the proportion of agricultural employment in the UK has gradually decreased from 30% to around 20%. The proportion of the national economy has fallen to 21%, becoming the “world industrial country”, and the British cities gradually become the mainstay of the world and guide the world.
74
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Share of agriculture in employment (%) United Kingdom Netherlands Belgium
United States Sweden Spain
France Mexico
80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 1800
1850
1900
1950
2000
Fig. 2.17 Share of agricultural employment in European and American countries. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
Fig. 2.18 Agricultural output value of major countries as a share of GDP. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
2.3 From the Perspective of Macro Gross, Global Urban Development Has …
75
2. from 1850 to 1950, the city become the backbone of the world, and advanced countries completed industrialization. During the Second Industrial Revolution, the global urban industry showed that developed countries were mainly light industries, and backward countries such as Asia, Africa and Latin America mainly focused on agricultural and mining. Specifically, the second industrial revolution was qualitatively improved compared to the first industrial revolution. The most direct result was the decline in agricultural output and the rapid rise in industrial output (see Figs. 2.18 and 2.19). Industrial cities in advanced countries have begun to support the world. It can be seen from Fig. 2.18 that from 1800 to 1950, the proportion of agricultural output value in the United States, France, New Zealand, and Sweden gradually declined, especially during the second industrial revolution (1850–1950), the proportion of agricultural output value decreased rapidly. Figure 2.19 shows the proportion of industrial output in major countries to GDP. Figure 2.19 shows that developed countries were in the industrial stage from 1800 to 1950, especially during the second industrial revolution, industrial output increased rapidly, from 20 to 50%. At this time, most countries have completed industrialization, and the city as the main body of the country supports the development of the world. 3. from 1950 to 2050, the city become the world, and the service and intelligence led the world. With the advent of the third industrial revolution, the global urban landscape was directly changed. At the beginning of the third industrial revolution, United Kingdom, United States, France, New Zealand, Sweden, Mexico, Belgium, Spain and other
Fig. 2.19 Proportion of industrial output value in major countries. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
76
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
countries took the lead in the industrial revolution, the proportion of its agricultural industry began to decline rapidly from 1800 to 1950, Until 2010, it was close to zero. In Asia, Africa, China, India, Egypt, South Africa, Nigeria and other countries, the industrial revolution began in 1950, and the agricultural employment population began to gradually decrease from this time. The proportion of agricultural employment in Asian and African countries is basically above 50%. Even at 80% or more, the proportion of agricultural employment in major European and American countries has dropped below 30%, even below 20%, and global employment has led Europe and the United States to lead the Asian-African pattern (see Fig. 2.20). In addition, as can be seen from Fig. 2.19, due to the third industrial revolution, informationization and networking dominated the world. At this time, the development of industrial development began, and the output value of service industry increased. Therefore, from 1950 to 2016, industrial output accounted for Compared with the gradual reduction, the global urban pattern dominates the industrialization of Asia and Africa by the high-end service in Europe and America. In addition, the industrial revolution has also brought about a substantial increase in income. Figure 2.21 shows the change in GDP per capita from 1870 to 2016 on all continents. As can be seen from Fig. 2.21, from 1870 to 1950, the per capita GDP of all continents increased slowly, and the economic development increased rapidly from 1950 to 2016. Judging from the differences in various continents, the Share of agriculture in employment (%) 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 1950
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
Japan
China
India
Egypt
South Africa
Nigeria
Indonesia
Malaysia
Philippines
2010
Fig. 2.20 Share of agricultural employment in major Asian and African countries. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
2.3 From the Perspective of Macro Gross, Global Urban Development Has …
77
Fig. 2.21 Changes in real per capita GDP of the world. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
economic development of developed countries such as Europe and the United States is significantly ahead of other continents and is in a leading position. At this time, the city is the world, and the economic and social development of the city is the economic and social development of the world. Figure 2.22 and Fig. 2.23 show the distribution of urbanization rate and GDP in the world’s major countries in 1950 and 2016. It can be seen from Fig. 2.22 and Fig. 2.23 that there is a significant positive correlation between urbanization rate and GDP, that is, the higher the urbanization rate, the higher the level of economic development. In the future, the city’s smart manufacturing will dominate the world. In the rapid development of automation, many repetitive labor jobs in the city will be replaced by new technologies such as machines, data and automation. McKinsey Global Institute In the report “Unemployment and Employment: Labor Transformation in the Age of Automation”, it is predicted that by 2030, jobs for 800 million people worldwide will be replaced by machines. By 2030, about 70% of companies will adopt at least one form of artificial intelligence. And a large number of large companies will use a full range of technologies, artificial intelligence will bring an additional 13 trillion US dollars in growth for global economic activities, its contribution rate can be comparable to the introduction of revolutionary technologies such as the history of steam engines, including artificial intelligence and Automation technology, including robotics, will bring significant benefits to users, businesses and the economy, increase productivity and boost economic growth. In the future, the industry will develop through traditional industries such as “Internet +”, “Big Data +” and “Artificial Intelligence”, such as intelligent home appliances, automobile networking, manufacturing data, etc., and a new industry through technological breakthroughs. The development of such industries, such as cloud computing, Internet of Things, new
78
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Fig. 2.22 Urbanization rate and GDP distribution of countries in the world in 1950. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
Fig. 2.23 Urbanization rate and GDP distribution of countries in the world in 2016. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
2.3 From the Perspective of Macro Gross, Global Urban Development Has …
79
Table 2.16 Main function positioning of Tokyo Center and Sub-center Name
Main function positioning
Tokyo
Central political and economic center, international financial center
Shinjuku
The first major sub-center, the business office and entertainment center that drives the development of Jing dong
Ikebukuro
Second largest sub-center, commercial shopping, entertainment center
Ikebukuro
Transportation Hub, Information Center, Business Office, Cultural and Entertainment Center
Ueno-Asakusa
Traditional Culture Tourism Center
Osaki
High-tech Research and Development Center
Kamishi-Kurto
Business, Cultural and Entertainment Center
Binhai Sub-Center
Sub-Center International Cultural, Technology and Information Exchange Center for the Future
energy, etc., often develops or depends on specific integrated application scenarios, such as networked roads, intelligent buildings, smart home systems, smart factories, and so on. In the future, with the highly developed information technology, cities will only be linked together, and smart cities that respond quickly, share data, and efficiently serve will dominate the world. From the ranking of global urban potential in 2019 (see Table 2.16), smart cities and technology cities lead global urban development. In addition, according to the McKinsey Global Institute forecast. According to PwC, an international accounting and consulting firm, the global gross domestic product (GDP) will increase by 14% in 2030, driven by artificial intelligence, which means that by 2030, artificial intelligence will contribute 15.7 trillion to the world economy. The dollar exceeds the sum of the current economic aggregates of China and India.
2.3.2 Impact of Urban Population Development on World Urbanization In the 300 years since the development of the world from the past to the future, the global urbanization process has been slow to fast. During the two hundred years from 1750 to 1950, the global urbanization rate rose from 5.5% to 30% or so, only increased by about 25% in two hundred years, but from 100 years between 1950 and 2050, the global urbanization rate will rise from around 30% in 1950 to around 70%. The rate of growth has increased by 40% and the urbanization process has accelerated significantly (see Fig. 2.24). In addition, the process of global urbanization is still a process from local to diffusion. First, the urbanization of the UK leads to the development of European urbanization, followed by the urbanization of the United States to lead the urbanization of Europe and the United States, followed by the
80
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Urban (%) 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 1500
1550
1600
1650
1700
1750
1800
1850
1900
1950
2000
2050
Fig. 2.24 Changes in global urbanization rate from 1500 to 2050. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
urbanization process of China leading the global cities. In the end, the urbanization of India led the process of global urbanization. 1. from 1750 to 1850, UK became an urban society. The first industrial revolution brought about rapid population growth, because the productivity increase brought about by the industrial revolution would significantly improve people’s living standards, thereby bringing about an increase in population and thus providing a basis for urban development. It can be clearly seen from the figure that before the first industrial revolution, the global population showed a rise and then decline, and the global population was in a state of ups and downs. After the first industrial revolution, the global population rose from 428 million in 1750 to 650 million in 1850, the advancement of the industrialization process and the substantial increase in population have provided a solid foundation for urbanization, and the urbanization process has begun. Before the first industrial revolution, the world’s cities were very limited, and the process of urbanization was stagnant. At this time, tribes and rural areas were the foundation of a country and the center of property. Agricultural production determines the future of the country or the world. The pattern of rural dominated the world was not broken until the industrial revolution of the 1860s. The industrial revolution led to the shift of focus to the city, and the city gradually dominated the world. The industrialization and mechanization brought about by the industrial revolution have caused the rural population to flood into cities and transform into industrial labor, which has led to a rapid increase in the population and urban population. The rotational effect brought about by the industrial revolution has greatly increased agricultural productivity and completely liberated. The agricultural labor force, from 1760 to 1840, the agricultural employment rate in Europe decreased by 12%, while the industrial employment rate increased by 23%; under the motive of human self-interested behavior, the resting productivity flows
2.3 From the Perspective of Macro Gross, Global Urban Development Has …
81
back into the cities will further drive the urbanization process. Therefore, the urban population brought about by industrialization has gradually increased the importance of the city and dominated the world. As can be seen from Fig. 2.24, before the first industrial revolution, from 1500 to 1750, the global urbanization rate rose from 4% to 5.5%, and the global urbanization process basically did not advance; After the sub-industrial revolution, between 1750 and 1850, the global urbanization rate rose from 5.5% to 11%. The urbanization rate process accelerated rapidly compared to before, and the global urbanization process began. The urbanization rate in Asia and Africa has not changed during the first industrial revolution, and it has remained at around 10% and 4%. The urbanization process has not yet begun and is still in the farming society. Europe is the birthplace of the industrial revolution. During the first industrial revolution, the urbanization process began rapidly, and the urban rate rose from 10% in 1800 to 16.7% in 1850. More importantly, between 1750 and 1850, half of the UK’s population lived in cities, and UK took the lead in urbanization and became a city-state. In the 1950s and 1960s, the widespread use of steam engines made the machine industry gradually replace the factory manual, and centralized mass production gradually became the mainstream of production. The concentration of production has brought about population gathering and the birth of industrial towns. The urbanization process has followed. Taking the United Kingdom as an example (see Table 2.17), the UK was the first Western country to move toward urbanization. The level of urbanization in the UK was 17% in 1750 and 33.8% in 1801. It entered the stage of rapid urbanization and reached in 1851. 54.0%, becoming the first country in the world to achieve urbanization. In 1772, Manchester, England, had a population of only 25,000. By 1851, the city had grown to 455,000. The population of Birmingham has increased from 86,000 in 1801 to 233,000 in 1851. With the spread of the industrial revolution, urbanization has gradually emerged throughout Europe and the American continent. For example, the analysis of French professor Philippe Panshmer, French urbanization began in the 1830, and the urbanization level of the United States reached 10.8% in 1840, other countries such as Germany and Canada started the urbanization process at a later stage. 2. from 1850 to 1950, Western Europe and North America became urban areas, and cities became the main body of the world. The improvement of science and technology brought about by the second industrial revolution has led to another qualitative improvement of the global population (see Fig. 2.25). The global population has increased from 655 million to 1.59 billion in 1920, providing the basis for the acceleration of the global urbanization process. The population of the United States, Germany and Britain all rose rapidly. Especially in the second industrial revolution, the population of the United States rose rapidly from 24.13 million in 1850 to 120 million in 1920. At this time, China and India in Asia were still in an agricultural society, and the population was still slowly fluctuating. Driven by the second industrial revolution, the large-scale machinery industry in the world has developed vigorously, which has greatly promoted the specialization of labor and the formation of industrial chain, attracted more and
82
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Table 2.17 Top 30 long-term developments in global cities Rank
City
Rank
City
Rank
City
1
London
11
Toronto
21
Houston
2
Singapore
12
Geneva
22
Moscow
3
San Francisco
13
Sydney
23
Montreal
4
Amsterdam
14
Melbourne
24
New York
5
Paris
15
Zurich
25
Taipei
6
Tokyo
16
Berlin
26
Dusseldorf
7
Boston
17
Copenhagen
27
Brussels
8
Munich
18
Vienna
28
Prague
9
Dublin
19
Vancouver
29
Washington DC
10
Stockholm
20
Abu Dhabi
30
Frankfurt
Source The author is based on the 2019 Global Urban Potential Index report
20000000
15000000
10000000
5000000 1850
1860
1870
1880
1890
1900
1910
1920
Fig. 2.25 Annual increment of global population in 1850–1920. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
more farmers who originally lived in rural areas and depended on agriculture for their livelihood, promoted the aggregation of industry and population to the city, LED to the continuous expansion of the city scale and increase of the number, and also made the number and place of farmers in the total social population The proportion of urban population is decreasing, and the number and proportion of urban population are increasing, and finally the urban–rural divided world is formed. In addition, the world’s urbanization rate has reached 30%, and Western Europe and North America have become urban areas. The rapid increase of global population
2.3 From the Perspective of Macro Gross, Global Urban Development Has …
83
Urban (%) 80
20 Asia
15
Africa
Europe
60
10
40
5
20
0 1850
1860
1870
1880
1890
1900
1910
1920
1930
1940
0 1950
Fig. 2.26 Urbanization rate change in Asia, Africa and Europe from 1850 to 1950. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
and the acceleration of industrialization accelerated the process of global urbanization. The global urbanization rate increased from 11% in 1850 to 29.6% in 1950 (see Fig. 2.24). The process of global urbanization accelerated. From a regional perspective, Western Europe and North America have become urban areas, and the global urbanization process is mainly led by Europe and the United States (see Fig. 2.26). The urbanization process in Europe rose rapidly from 16.7% in 1850 to 51.7% in 1950, with the urban population exceeding the rural population. At this time, Asia and Africa are just beginning to carry out industrial revolution, and the process of urbanization is slowly starting. The urbanization rate in Asia increased from 10% in 1850 to 17.5% in 1950, and the urbanization rate in Africa increased from 4% in 1850 to 14.3% in 1950, The urbanization process is just starting. Finally, the second industrial revolution brought advanced countries into urbanization one after another. The urbanization level of advanced countries increased from 11.4% in 1850 to 52.1% in 1950. The urban population has exceeded the rural population. At this time, the major western advanced countries have realized urbanization (see Table 2.18). In 1950, the United Kingdom remained in the leading position, with its urbanization level of 79%, achieving a high degree of urbanization. The urbanization level of other developed countries, such as Germany, Austria, the United States, Canada, France, Italy, and Spain, was 64.7%, 64.6%, 64.2%, 60.9%, 55.2%, 54.1% and 51.9%, respectively. During this period, modern cities in advanced countries improved significantly, the main sign of which was the large-scale construction of urban infrastructure. 3. From 1950 to 2050, urbanization from acceleration to completion, from city-led world to city is the transformation of the world. During the third industrial revolution, the high-tech industry with information technology as the core gradually replaced heavy industry as the leading industry, and then moved from the industrial economy era to the knowledge economy era or the information economy era, which had a great impact on the world cities, and
84
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Table 2.18 Distribution of population cities in the UK (10,000 people, %)
Year
Total population Urban population Proportion of urban population
1750 766.5
130.3
17.00%
1801 1050.1
354.9
33.80%
1811 1197
438.1
36.60%
1831 1626.1
720.3
44.30%
1851 2081.7
1124.1
54.00%
Data source The author collects and organizes
100000000 90000000 80000000 70000000 60000000 50000000 40000000 1950
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
2010
2020
Fig. 2.27 Annual global population change from 1950 to 2016. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
global urbanization. The rate will increase from around 30% in 1950 to around 70% in 2050. Global urbanization will accelerate from completion to completion. The world-dominant world-to-city is the world. Thus, from 1950 to 2050, global urban development was mainly embodied in two phases. The first phase was the midurbanization of 1950–2008, the city dominated by the world; the second phase was the mid-to-late urbanization of 2008–2050, the city is the world. From a population perspective, the global population has grown from 4.77 billion in 1950 to 8.275 billion in 2008, and the global population has increased by 3.505 billion (see Fig. 2.27). The figures and figures show that in the first industrial revolution and the second industrial revolution, although the population has improved, the increase is not large. From 1750 to 1900, the global population is in a slow growth stage, and after 1900, the population experienced explosive growth; especially during the outbreak of the third industrial revolution, the global population rose rapidly. From a national perspective, the population of Germany and the United Kingdom is slowly increasing, and the number of people in the United States, the birthplace of the third industrial revolution, has been qualitatively improved. The population of the United States has risen from 160 million in 1950 to 2009. With a population of 309 million, the population has basically doubled. At this time, China and India, due to their late-comer advantage, have rapidly increased their population.
2.3 From the Perspective of Macro Gross, Global Urban Development Has …
85
Urban (%) 85 43
Asia
Africa
Europe
75
33
65
23
13 1950
55
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
2010
45 2020
Fig. 2.28 Changes in urbanization rates in Asia, Africa and Europe. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
From the perspective of urbanization process, during the third industrial revolution, global urbanization rose from 29.6% in 1950 to 50.6% in 2008. For the first time, the global urban population surpassed the rural population, which means entering the urban era. From a regional perspective (see Fig. 2.28), after the urbanization rate in Europe exceeds 50%, the urbanization process tends to be slow, and the urbanization rate in Europe rose from 51.7% in 1950 to 72.5% in 2008, especially After the urbanization process reached 70% in 1990, the urbanization process was basically stagnant. However, Asia and Africa are still in the process of accelerating urbanization. The urbanization rate in Asia rose from 17.5% in 1950 to 43.3% in 2008. The urbanization rate in Africa rose from 14.3% in 1950 to 38% in 2008. The urbanization process is still accelerating. At this time, the global urbanization process is driven by Asia and Africa. The information revolution has made Asia and Africa the engine of promoting urbanization in the world. Overall, from the first industrial revolution to the third industrial revolution (see Table 2.19), before the industrialization from 1500 to 1750, the urbanization of the United States remained basically unchanged, and the urbanization rate increased from 0.2% to 3.5%. Around the world, and after the industrial revolution, especially after the first industrial revolution, the rate of urbanization in the United States has increased rapidly, from 6% in 1800 to 64% in 1950, up to 82% in 2018, urban population. Leading the development of the United States. In contrast, China and India did not carry out the industrial revolution until 1950. They are still in the agricultural society, and their production efficiency is extremely low. Their urbanization rate changes slowly between 1500 and 1950, in the third industry. After the revolution, the urbanization rate was greatly improved. Until now, it is still in the process of urbanization. The developed countries such as Europe and the United States have already completed urbanization in the 2050s, and the developed countries have generally led the developing countries. From a regional perspective, this phenomenon is also very obvious. Europe began to urbanize in 1750. From 1850 to 1950, the urbanization process accelerated, and the overall urbanization rate exceeded 50%. By 2016, the
86
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Table 2.19 Comparison of urbanization level between developed and underdeveloped countries during the second industrial revolution (%) Year
Developed country
Underdeveloped countries
Total population
Urban population
Proportion of urban population
1850
3.52
0.4
11.4
1875
4.35
0.75
17.2
1900
5.75
1.5
1925
7.15
2.85
1950
8.13
4.23
Total population
Urban population
Proportion of urban population
9.1
0.4
4.4
9.85
0.5
5
26.1
10.75
0.7
6.5
39.9
12.35
1.15
9.3
52.1
17.07
3.09
18.1
Data source The author collects and organizes
urbanization rate has reached 76%, during the period from 1750 to 1930, the urbanization process in Asia and Africa remained basically unchanged until 1950, but the urbanization rate was far lower than that in Europe and America, so the overall pattern was from Europe and America to Asia and Africa. In the next 30 years, countries and regions with low world rates such as Asia and Africa will enter an accelerated period and complete urbanization (see Fig. 2.29, Table 2.20). Specifically, it is estimated that the level of urbanization in Africa will rise from 38% in 2008 to 59% in 2050, and the overall urbanization rate will increase by 21%; the level of urbanization in Asia will rise from 43% in 2008 to 66% in 2050. The overall urbanization rate will rise by 23%, while Europe, Oceania and the Americas are already in the late stage of urbanization, so the future will not increase much. Therefore, the acceleration and completion of urbanization in Asia and Africa will lead to the global entry into mature urban society. It is expected that the global urbanization rate will rise from 51% in 2008 to 70% in 2050 and enter urban society. In the future, developed countries will achieve a high degree of urbanization, and at the same time, population clusters will be dispersed. On the whole, since the 1950s, Western developed countries have continued to develop at a higher level on the basis of basic urbanization, and have achieved high urbanization. According to UN statistics, by 2015, the overall urbanization level of developed countries reached 78.1%, the urbanization level of Japan, Sweden, New Zealand and Australia exceeded 85%, and France, Germany and Spain exceeded 75%. The level of urbanization in countries such as The United Kingdom, the United States, Canada has reached more than 80%. It is predicted that the level of urbanization in the world will continue to increase to about 70% in 2050, and the level of urbanization in developed regions will reach 86.6%.
2.3 From the Perspective of Macro Gross, Global Urban Development Has … 95
Europe
Oceania
Northern America
South America
Africa
Asia
87 70
85
60
75
50
65
40
55 2005
2010
2015
2020
2025
2030
2035
2040
2045
30 2050
Fig. 2.29 Estimation of urbanization rate levels by region by 2050. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data Table 2.20 Urbanization rate of major countries Entity
1750
1800
1850
1900
1950
2000
2016
Brazil
9.200
22.900
36.160
81.192
86.042
Canada
7.900
37.500
60.946
79.478
81.300
China
6.000
6.600
11.803
35.877
56.736
France
9.100
8.800
14.500
55.232
75.871
79.917
Germany
5.600
5.500
10.800
67.944
74.965
77.224
10.000
17.042
27.667
33.182
7.600
India
6.400
Indonesia
2.900
12.400
42.002
53.989
Ireland
7.000
10.200
40.088
59.155
62.737
Italy
14.600
20.300
54.104
67.222
69.855
Japan
5.000
53.402
78.649
91.457
Mexico
5.800
42.655
74.722
79.577
38.338
61.716
60.178
Poland
21.900
1.000
2.500
44.087
73.350
74.164
Spain
8.600
11.100
17.300
51.920
76.262
79.840
Switzerland
4.600
3.700
7.700
67.381
73.383
73.739
15.700
24.774
64.741
74.134
39.977
64.153
79.057
81.862
Russia
9.300
1.900
Turkey
6.300
United States
6.073
14.400
15.413
Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
88
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
2.3.3 Impact of Urban Space Expansion on the World Environment and Economy 1. from 1750 and 1950, the developed urban space of a few developed countries accelerated and the global urban space began to accelerate. Urban space, especially a few developed urban spaces, led and controlled global development. After the industrial revolution began, it not only improved production efficiency, but also expanded people’s activity space. With the improvement of production efficiency, people’s activity space gradually expanded, and a few developed urban spaces led and controlled global development. Before the industrial revolution, although there was a certain degree of urban growth, at that time, social productivity was extremely low, social division of labor was extremely underdeveloped, commodities were extremely poor, and urban development was extremely slow. At that time, the main focus was on the agricultural population. The city’s attractiveness to the rural population was not obvious. Therefore, large-scale urban space has not yet been formed, and the urbanization rate is slow. The table indicates that the global urban area was only 14,104 square kilometers in 1700 years before 1700. The city’s expansion area is only 9867 square kilometers. After the first industrial revolution, the global urban space accelerated (see Table 2.21). It can be seen from the table that during the 200 years from 1700 to 1900, the urban area expanded by 32,593 square kilometers, and the total urban area expanded to 46,697 square kilometers. However, the city at this time is only a small city, and its transportation and service environment are still in the initial stage. Only the transportation infrastructure is only around the city and the factory. From a regional point of view, before the industrial revolution, some areas had a certain degree of urban growth, mainly in Europe. The Middle East and North Africa had a certain urban development foundation earlier. However, during this period, the urban area showed a retrogression. There is no huge development in the area of cities in various regions. This can also be seen from the perspective of urban land use change in various regions (see Fig. 2.30). Figure 2.30 shows the changes in urban land use in various regions from 1600 to 1850, before the first industrial revolution, from 1600 to 1750, urban land use in various regions remained basically unchanged. However, during the first industrial revolution, the amount of urban expansion in North America was the largest. In 200 years, the city expanded a total of 10,943 square kilometers, followed by Western Europe, and the city expanded to 8,574 square kilometers. Other regions, such as Central Europe, During the period of Oceania, the urban area also expanded to a certain extent, with expansion rates of 13.815 square kilometers per year and 9.93 square kilometers per year. From the perspective of urban land use, the continents during the first industrial revolution (see Table 2.22), between the first industrial revolution, urban land use in various regions showed a significant upward trend. From a national perspective (see Fig. 2.31), urban land in the world’s major countries has remained largely unchanged from 1500 to 1750, and during the first industrial revolution, urban land in major countries has rapidly increased, from The
2.3 From the Perspective of Macro Gross, Global Urban Development Has …
89
Table 2.21 Urbanization level of developed countries in major years from 1950 to 2050 (%) Country or region
2010
2015
2020
2050
World
51.6
53.9
56.2
68.4
Developed regions
77.2
78.1
79.1
86.6
Undeveloped area
46.1
49.0
51.7
65.6
United Kingdom
81.3
82.6
83.9
90.2
France
78.4
79.7
81.0
88.3
Germany
77.0
77.2
77.5
84.3
Italy
68.3
69.6
71.0
81.1
Sweden
85.1
86.6
88.0
93.2
Spain
78.4
79.6
80.8
88.0
Austria
57.4
57.7
58.7
70.9
Canada
80.9
81.3
81.6
87.3
United States
80.8
81.7
82.7
89.2
Australia
85.2
85.7
86.2
91.0
New Zealand
86.2
86.3
86.7
91.1
Japan
90.8
91.4
91.8
94.7
Data source The author collected and compiled according to the World Bank database
Total urban area per world region
2500
Asia-Stan 2000
7000
Central Europe
Eastern Africa
Northern Africa
Rest Central America
Rest South America
Southeastern Asia
Southern Africa
Western Africa
Western Europe
6000 5000
1500
4000 3000
1000
2000 500
1000 0 1600
1650
1700
1750
1800
0 1850
Fig. 2.30 Changes in urban land use by region. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
90
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Table 2.22 Characteristics of urban area expansion (Unit: square kilometers, square kilometers/ year) Year
Total urban area
Urban expansion area at each stage
Urban expansion rate
Urban land expansion Population elasticity index
0–1700
14,104
9867.00
5.80
0.98
1700–1900
46,697
32,593.00
162.97
1.36
Note The urban land expansion population elasticity index refers to the ratio of the average annual growth rate of the built-up area to the annual growth rate of the non-agricultural population, and is an indicator of the rationality of urban land expansion Data source The author collects and organizes
expansion of urban area and the per capita urban land use are more obvious (see Figs. 2.32, 2.33 and 2.34). As can be seen from Fig. 2.34, except for China, cities in major countries are expanding. It can be seen from Fig. 2.34 before the first industrial revolution, the per capita urban land use of some countries was still declining. During the first industrial revolution, the per capita urban area was basically rising, and the urban activity space was significantly expanded. 2. from 1850 to 1950, urban space expanded rapidly, Europe and North America accelerated, and global urban and rural divisions intensified (Europe and the United States are urban areas, Asian and other rural areas), and European and American cities support world development. During the second industrial revolution from 1850 to 1950, urbanization was continued in major developed countries in Europe and North America. Industrialization entered a subsequent stage, and widespread suburbanization occurred. Urban population gradually concentrated in small and medium-sized cities, and urban space 12000 10000 8000
Canada
United States
Japan
Korea
Russia
China
Brazil
India
Indonesia
Turkey
Ukraine
Mexico
6000 4000 2000 0 -2000
Expansion of urban area from 1700 to 1900
Fig. 2.31 Expansion of urban area from 1700 to 1900. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
2.3 From the Perspective of Macro Gross, Global Urban Development Has …
91
Total urban area 4000
2500
2000
1500
Brazil
Canada
China
India
Indonesia
Japan
3500 3000 2500
Russia
Turkey
Ukraine
United States
2000
1000
1500 1000
500 500 0 1500
1550
1600
1650
1700
1750
1800
0 1850
Fig. 2.32 Global per capita urban area (km2 /person) Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data 0.0001 0.00008 0.00006 0.00004 0.00002 0 1500
1550
1600
1650
1700
1750
1800
1850
1900
1950
2000
Fig. 2.33 Changes in urban land use in major countries. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
expanded rapidly. At the beginning of the twentieth century, the industrial revolution was carried out in other parts of the world, and various regions of the world had different degrees of urban expansion. However, the scale of expansion was still far lower than that of Western Europe and North America, which were dominated by developed countries (see Table 2.23). At this time, urban space has expanded rapidly, urban agglomerations have become the mainstay of the world, and transportation infrastructure, medical services, and catering services around the city have become more sophisticated. From the perspective of urban land use in various regions (Fig. 2.35), European and American cities support the development of the world. During the second industrial revolution, urban land use in all regions was on the rise, but there were some differences in different regions. Specifically, the overall urban land use of cities in
92
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
urban area per person 0.00015
0.0001
8E-05
Brazil
Canada
China
India
Russia
World
6E-05
4E-05
United States
2E-05 0.00005 1E-19
0 1500
1550
1600
1650
1700
1750
1800
-2E-05 1850
Fig. 2.34 Changes in per capita urban land use in major countries. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
Table 2.23 Urban expansion area (Unit: Square kilometer)
Area
Urban area expansion in 0–1700
Urban area expansion in 1700–1900
Central Europe
1419
2763
North America
16
10,943
Southeast Asia
290
587
Asia–Pacific
29
344
Middle East
−560
348
Other Central America
129
467
Other parts of South America
367
662
East Africa
69
112
North Africa
−125
390
Southern Africa
79
178
Western Europe
2522
8574
Oceania
49
1986
Data source The author collects and organizes
Western Europe, Central Europe and South America is rising rapidly. At this time, people’s activity space has been mainly in the city, And Africa, Asia still is still in agricultural society. In general, urban land has remained basically unchanged during the second industrial revolution. Only in the second industrial revolution and the third industrial revolution, urban land began to rise rapidly. From the national point of view (see Fig. 2.36, Table 2.24), the overall trend shows the same trend with the
2.3 From the Perspective of Macro Gross, Global Urban Development Has …
93
region. Urban land in developed countries in Europe and America has risen rapidly during the second industrial revolution, and various countries in the world have different levels of urban area. The expansion and expansion scale is still dominated by developed countries (see Table 2.24), which is more obvious from the perspective of per capita land use (see Fig. 2.37). This shows that during the second industrial revolution, the space for people in developed countries has been transferred to cities, while the space for activities in Asian and African countries is still in rural areas. At this time, cities in developed countries directly dominate the world. 3. from 1950 to 2050, the first stage, the city dominated the world, the urban space accelerated and the space efficiency accelerated. In the second stage, the city is Total urban area per world region 35000 6000
Asia-Stan Northern Africa Southeastern Asia Western Europe
4000
Central Europe Rest Central America Southern Africa
Eastern Africa Rest South America Western Africa
25000
15000
2000
5000
0 1850
1860
1870
1880
1890
1900
1910
1920
1930
1940
-5000 1950
Fig. 2.35 Changes in urban land use by region. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
Total urban area per world region 10000 8000 6000
Brazil
Canada
China
India
Indonesia
Japan
Russia
Turkey
Ukraine
United States
40000
4000
20000
2000 0 1850
1860
1870
1880
1890
1900
1910
1920
1930
1940
0 1950
Fig. 2.36 Changes in urban land use in major countries. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
94
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Table 2.24 Urban expansion area of each region from 1900 to 1950 (Unit: square kilometers) Area
Urban area expansion from 1900 to 1950
Area
Urban area expansion from 1900 to 1950
Central Europe
2313
Other parts of South America
2550
North America
36,503
East Africa
214
Southeast Asia
1432
North Africa
823
Asia–Pacific
1126
Southern Africa
1031
middle East
742
Western Europe
18,869
Other Central America
1331
Oceania
2398
Data source The author collects and organizes
urban area per person 0.0003
0.0001
Brazil China Russia United States
0.00008 0.00006
Canada India World
0.0002
0.00004 0.0001 0.00002 0 1850
1860
1870
1880
1890
1900
1910
1920
1930
1940
0 1950
Fig. 2.37 Changes in per capita urban land use in major countries. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
the world, the urban and rural space is divided into integration, the rural space is urbanized, and the countryside becomes the city. Mean area Since the third industrial revolution, developing countries have grown rapidly, and a large number of people have flooded into cities. The expansion of urban land is unstoppable. lobal cities are connected through networks. Cities are characterized by urban areas, and the city has a basis to meet all needs of people. The facilities, transportation, medical care, living services, and social services are all networked, intelligent, and integrated, and the urban space is accelerating. By the year 2000, the world urban area has expanded to 538,395 square kilometers, and the urban expansion rate has also increased in space. During the period from 1950 to 2000, the urban expansion rate reached 796.08 square kilometers per year. Moreover, since 1950, the total agricultural land in Oceania and Europe has begun to decrease, and agricultural land in Latin America and Asia has remained basically unchanged. From the point of view of per capita agricultural land, this turning point is more obvious
2.3 From the Perspective of Macro Gross, Global Urban Development Has …
95
(see Fig. 2.38). Figure 2.38 shows that per capita agricultural land has a significant turning effect around 1950. Before 1950, per capita agricultural land use increased, but after 1950, the amount of agricultural land per capita declined rapidly, indicating that the activity space for per capita agriculture has gradually decreased, and people have begun to turn to urban activities. From the perspective of changes in urban area, the urban land area of all continents has shown a rapid increase. Especially after 1950, the urban area of all continents has increased significantly (Table 2.25, see Fig. 2.39), and the same cities in Europe and America. The area is significantly larger than the urban area of Asia and Africa. The cities in all regions have begun to expand on a large scale, and their growth rate has exceeded 3 times. By 2000, the urban area expansion in Europe, America and Western Europe was still the fastest in the world (see Table 2.26). From the perspective of urban area change in major countries (see Fig. 2.40), it can be seen from Fig. 2.40 that the urban area of the United States is significantly higher than that of other countries, while other countries in the same period are basically slowly rising, especially China and India. Since there was no industrial revolution, it was still in an agricultural society at this time, and the urban area did not change significantly (see Table 2.27). Judging from the per capita urban area, the industrial revolution has caused a significant increase in the per capita urban area of each country, and people’s urban activity space has increased significantly. In general, the scope of human activities has shifted from agricultural areas to urban areas, from developed areas in Europe and America to Asian and African developing areas, and the world has gradually become a world of urban leadership. In the future, urban and rural spatial division will be integrated, rural space will be urbanized, and rural areas will become urbanized areas. In 2015–2050, according to the current per capita urban land growth rate, the scale of urban expansion in developed countries will increase by 1.9 times; according to the current per capita urban land growth rate, the scale of urban expansion in developed countries will Africa Europe (excl. Russia) Latin America and the Caribbean (excl. Brazil)
Rest of Asia (excl. India & China) Oceania 40
6
4 20 2
0 1750
0 1800
1850
1900
1950
2000
Fig. 2.38 Per capita agricultural land area of each continent. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
96
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Table 2.25 Urban expansion areas of different countries from 1900 to 1950 (Unit: Square kilometer) Country Urban area expansion from 1900 to Country 1950
Urban area expansion from 1900 to 1950
Canada
933
Brazil
2302
United States
35,570
India
2338
Japan
3162
Indonesia 702
Korea
276
Turkey
371
Russia
6761
Ukraine
2405
China
4159
Mexico
1215
Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
Total urban area per world region 20000
120000 Asia-Stan Northern Africa Southeastern Asia Western Europe
Central Europe Rest Central America Southern Africa
Eastern Africa Rest South America Western Africa
10000
0 1950
70000
1955
1960
1965
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
20000 2000
Fig. 2.39 Urban land use change by region. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
increase by 1.5 times; The land area will remain unchanged, and the scale of urban expansion in developed countries will increase by 1.1 times. In 2015–2050, according to the current growth rate of urban land, half of the existing urban land growth rate, and the existing per capita urban land remain unchanged, the scale of urban expansion in developing countries will increase by 3.7 times and 2.5 times respectively. 1.8 times. In the future, with the gradual expansion of the scale of cities and towns in developing countries, along with AI intelligence, new energy, Internet of Things, and cloud computing, urban planning is more perfect, and cities are the world.
2.4 From the Perspective of Space, the Changes of Global Cities’ …
97
Table 2.26 Changes in per capita urban area by region Year
1700
1800
1900
1950
2000
2000/1700
Asia-Stan
29
40
373
1499
5791
199.6897
Central Europe
1419
1403
4182
6495
17,088
12.04228
Eastern Africa
69
73
181
395
5853
84.82609
Northern Africa
170
158
560
1383
13,038
76.69412
Rest Central America
129
200
596
1927
8383
64.9845
Rest South America
367
311
1029
3579
16,232
44.22888
Southeastern Asia
290
398
877
2309
13,989
48.23793
Southern Africa
79
66
257
1288
9108
Western Africa
1096
978
565
1235
13,680
12.48175
Western Europe
2864
3905
11,438
30,307
83,617
29.19588
115.2911
Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
90 60 30 0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30 -60 -90
Fig. 2.40 Changes in per capita urban land use in major countries. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
2.4 From the Perspective of Space, the Changes of Global Cities’ Characteristics Determine the Evolution of world’s Characteristics The three important characteristics of human development: aggregation, connection and sharing, have significant differences in different stages. In the 300 years from 1750 to 2050, the characteristics and evolution of global cities determine the characteristics and evolution of the world.
98
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Table 2.27 Urban expansion areas of major countries in different periods from 1950 to 2000 (Unit: Square kilometer) Area
Urban area expansion from 1950 to 2000
Area
Urban area expansion from 1950 to 2000
Central Europe
10,593
Other parts of South America
12,653
North America
115,511
East Africa
5458
Southeast Asia
11,680
North Africa
11,655
Asia–Pacific
4292
Southern Africa
7820
Middle East
13,990
Western Europe
53,310
Other Central America
6456
Oceania
9438
Data source The author collects and organizes
2.4.1 The Scale and Density of Global Urban Agglomeration: From Dispersed-Concentration to Concentrated-Concentration and Then to Concentrated-Dispersion In the past 300 years, the global urban agglomeration has three stages: from decentralized agglomeration to centralized agglomeration to centralized decentralization. Each stage presents a different form, which determines the evolution of the world spatial pattern.1 The three stages of global urban agglomeration can be roughly divided into: from 1750 to 1850, due to the heterogeneity of spatial distribution of factors or population distribution, the city as a whole presents decentralized agglomeration; from 1850 to 1950, with the invention of power, telephone and telegraph, the city gradually moves towards centralized agglomeration, sharing aggregation effect; from 1950 to 2050, the city transformed the real space landscape into virtual world by means of science and technology, to some extent, and the global network division of labor promoted the city to transform to the new decentralized aggregation. 1. The leading national cities were decentralized aggregation in 1750–1850s, while the global cities were decentralized aggregation, mainly in Britain, Germany, France and other countries. The global cities form a polarization pattern of highly concentrated cities in the developed countries and scattered cities in the underdeveloped countries. Japanese cities in Asia began to rise, but their degree of aggregation is significantly lower than that in European and American countries, as shown in Fig. 2.41. By 1850, about 1 / 3 of the world’s listed companies had gathered in the cities of Britain, Germany and France, while that of Germany and the United States was 1
This report uses the data of 97,259 listed companies in the Osiris global listed company database from 1989 to 2017 to see the changes in the form, scale and density of global urban agglomeration from the perspective of industrial change and agglomeration.
2.4 From the Perspective of Space, the Changes of Global Cities’ …
99
90 60 30 0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30 -60 -90
Fig. 2.41 The distribution of global listed companies in global cities before 1850. Source Sorting according to the data of Osiris’s global listed companies
relatively low. For example, the German listed companies were mainly scattered in Frankfurt, Berlin, Essen, Hanover and other cities, which also showed that there were differences in aggregation within the developed industrial countries, showing the space of “large aggregation and small dispersion” distribution pattern. At the same time, Japan’s cities such as Osaka, Tokyo, Nagoya, Singapore, Brazil’s Brasilia and other Asian, African and Latin American cities have also achieved corresponding development, but there is a large gap with European and American countries. Therefore, before the 1950s, the global urban agglomeration presented a global spatial distribution pattern of polarization, “large agglomeration, small dispersion”. 2. From 1850 to 1950s, the cities in typical countries were centralized agglomeration and the global cities were decentralized agglomeration. The global urban industrial agglomeration shows a pattern of multipolar agglomeration from European countries during the first industrial revolution to European, North America, Asia and other global cities, as shown in Fig. 2.42. As far as global cities are concerned, there are two forms of industrial agglomeration among countries in the world: one is the highly concentrated form represented by Britain and Japan, with listed companies mainly concentrated in London, Tokyo, Paris and other big cities; the other is the coexistence of urban agglomeration and decentralization in the United States. The industrial agglomeration degree of American cities has been greatly improved. In 1950, American cities gathered more than 570 enterprises around the world, accounting for 9% of the world. However, the industrial agglomeration density of American cities is relatively low compared with that of European countries. The industrial agglomeration mainly centers on New York, Houston, Chicago and other core cities, and the rest cities are relatively evenly distributed, as shown in Fig. 2.43. During this period, the Great Lakes city economic belt with Chicago as the core has
100
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion 90 60 30 0
-180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30 -60 -90
Fig. 2.42 The distribution of global listed companies in global cities in 1850–1950. Source Sorting according to the data of Osiris’s global listed companies
been formed in the United States, and a large number of enterprises have gathered in the cities within the economic belt. At the same time, it can also be seen that cities in India, Africa, South Africa and other countries have also achieved some development, but the degree of aggregation is still at a low level compared with developed countries and regions. 3. The leading countries are centralized agglomeration in the 1950s-2050s, and cities around the world changed from centralized agglomeration to centralized decentralization. Since the 1950s, the global cities have formed a tripartite pattern of Europe, North America and Asia, as shown in Fig. 2.44. Cities in developed countries such as 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0
Fig. 2.43 The distribution of listed Companies in American cities 1850–1950. Source Sorting according to the data of Osiris’s global listed companies
2.4 From the Perspective of Space, the Changes of Global Cities’ …
101
90 60 30 0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30 -60 -90
Fig. 2.44 The distribution of global listed companies in global cities after 1950. Source Sorting according to the data of Osiris’s global listed companies
European traditional industrial powers, the United States and Japan are gathering more and more, and the gathering density is also increasing. At the same time, under the trend of global urban agglomeration, the city develops from the center periphery to the city cluster level with the center city as the core, that is to say, the city changes to centralized decentralization. At this stage, the degree of urban agglomeration in Asia is increasing, especially in the eastern coastal cities of China. In terms of global city, there are obvious differences in the degree of industrial agglomeration between different regions. As the first place of industrial revolution, European cities are mainly concentrated in London, France, Paris and other cities, while German cities are relatively scattered or balanced; while American cities develop into three Bay Economic Belts with New York, Chicago and Los Angeles as the core, and the industrial agglomeration degree in the Bay economic belt is constantly improving. At present, urban agglomeration is gradually breaking the regional restrictions, and the most competitive economic core areas in the world, such as New York, London, Paris, Tokyo, Singapore, Beijing, Hong Kong, Shanghai and other major urban agglomerations. Since the 1950s, a prominent feature of world economic development is that the development of urban agglomerations centered on big cities is gradually becoming the dominant trend of world economic development, as shown in Table 2.28. With the development of urbanization in China, the urban agglomerations represented by Beijing-Tianjin-Hebei Urban Agglomerations, Yangtze River Delta urban agglomerations, Guangdong-Hong Kong-Macao Bay area are rising, and their advantages of internal gathering, connection and sharing are gradually released.
102
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Table 2.28 Total urban area per world region Year
1500
1600
1700
1800
1900
1950
2000
Brazil
9
22
72
163
843
3145
22,168
Canada
0
0
1
7
193
1126
6030
China
4013
5762
3916
3923
2846
7005
43,199
India
942
1154
1419
1729
2615
4953
23,854
Indonesia
11
34
101
134
479
1181
8772
Japan
468
747
1104
504
1887
5049
13,450
United States
4
4
15
139
10,766
46,336
156,919
Russia
19
64
189
203
2416
9177
21,064
Turkey
120
140
134
165
292
663
5203
Ukraine
2
6
22
33
691
3096
8126
Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
2.4.2 Urban Connection: From Regional Connections to Global Connections, from “Hard Connections” of Commodity Elements to “Soft Connections” of Information and Service Elements, from Individual Connections to the Internet of Everything Since the industrial revolution, the global urban connection has experienced the transformation from the regional connection to the global interconnection (as shown in Fig. 2.45), from the commodity or raw material based goods connection to the element connection represented by capital to the soft connection such as knowledge (information) and service. The transformation of the global urban connection scope, content and way has profoundly changed the world connection. 1. The local connections of the leading cities were dominant, and the global connections were mainly goods connections of goods and raw materials in 1750–1850s. During the first industrial revolution, the biggest change in transportation field was the introduction and use of steam ships and steam locomotives, which prompted the UK, Germany and other countries to lay a dense transportation network. The development of textile industry, mining industry and metallurgical industry needs to improve the traditional means of transport in order to transport a large number of coal and ore, which set off a wave of canal excavation. By 1830, Britain had 2500 miles of canals. By 1800, Germany had about 490 km of canals. From 1836 to 1849, Bavaria opened the Ludwig canal between the Danube and the Main river. In 1850, the Oberland canal between Ostrod in East Prussia opened. The total length of artificial waterways in Germany has reached 3528 km. Therefore, the invention of the steam wheel and the digging of the canal strengthened the connection between
2.4 From the Perspective of Space, the Changes of Global Cities’ …
103
Fig. 2.45 Global commodity output by purpose, 1827–2014. Source https://ourworldindata.org
cities. At the same time, steam locomotive is applied to railway, which can transport passengers and goods faster and cheaper than highway or canal and dominate longdistance transportation. By 1838, Britain had 500 miles of railway, which increased to 6600 miles in 1850. German railway construction had made rapid progress. In 1835, the operating mileage of German railway was 6 km, in 1845, 2300 km, in 1855, 8290 km, and in 1865, 14,690 km.2 In a word, the invention and application of steam engine promoted the rise of new transportation modes by canal and railway network, and promoted the connection between domestic cities. The invention of steam steamer promoted the urban trade between countries and the expansion of overseas market, as shown in Fig. 2.46. It can be seen that before 1850, the global urban connection was mainly based on trade, and the global trade was mainly based on regional trade, with relatively less trade between regions.3 The invention of steamship broke the limitation of water space for human beings. In 1833, the steamship Royal William sailed from Nova Scotia to England, and the sea connection between cities around the world was expanded. This is conducive to the export of products from advanced industrial countries and the plunder of raw materials such as rubber, jute, oil and various metals from overseas colonies. Some Asian, African and Latin American regions have been opened to a certain extent. 2. In 1850–1950s, the national contact of typical cities was the main body, the global contact was mainly dominated by goods contact (goods contact of finished 2
The data were gathered from General history of the world. The Western European countries represented by Britain, Germany and France are the global manufacturing centers and trade centers in this period. Choosing Western European countries as reference can represent the global trade relations to some extent.
3
104
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Fig. 2.46 Trade between Western Europe and the rest of the world, 1827–1850. Source https://our worldindata.org
products and raw materials), and the global soft contact began to rise (telegraph and telephone communication). From 1850 to 1950, the global economic relations were mainly trade between North America represented by the United States and Western European developed countries represented by the United Kingdom and Germany. The relations with other mainland countries were relatively small, as shown in Fig. 2.47 and Fig. 2.48. However, with the deepening of global economic connection, Asian and South American countries have gradually developed, especially after the Second World War, the Bretton Woods system dominated by the United States has been built, the global economic integration has accelerated, and the global economic system has formed. The invention of the internal combustion engine makes the automobile enter the popularization stage, and the regional scope of the city can be continuously expanded. The popularity of cars has prompted some urban residents to choose to move to the suburbs, which has led to the emergence of urban suburbanization and changed the urban spatial structure. In the 1840s, after the American successfully used the telegraph technology in practice, it quickly spread all over the world. In the 1850s, western countries were able to lay two to three thousand fathoms of submarine power lines. In 1866, a transatlantic submarine power line was set up between Britain and the United States. In the late 1860s, tsarist Russia crossed Siberia to Vladivostok. The improvement of means of transportation and information and communication technology has reduced the cost of transportation and communication (as shown in Fig. 2.49). 3. From 1950 to 2050, global connection are dominated, and goods connection continued, but service connection and information (knowledge) connection have become more and more dominant, and individual connection became all things connected. The rapid development of transportation and communication technology, especially the rapid development of information technology since the 1990s, has brought countries and regions all over the world closer together and accelerated the international
2.4 From the Perspective of Space, the Changes of Global Cities’ …
105
Fig. 2.47 U.S. Global trade links by destination. Source https://ourworldindata.org
Fig. 2.48 Trade between rich and backward countries in the world, 1827–1950. Source https://our worldindata.org
flow of capital and raw materials. Transnational corporations and various international organizations have become powerful promoters of economic globalization. The development of new generation communication technology breaks the traditional limitation of space–time distance, and global cities enter the cyberspace, forming a global urban cyberspace connection. Since the 1950s, global cities have entered the era of information and knowledge economy. On the basis of increasing hard links, the soft links between cities have been increasing, as shown in Fig. 2.50. As can be seen from Fig. 2.23, the range of global city connection is relatively wide, presenting the global city connection pattern with cities in Europe, North
106
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Fig. 2.49 Changes in transport and communications costs, 1930–1950. Source OECD (2007), OECD Economic Outlook, Vol. 2007/1, OECD Publishing
Fig. 2.50 Publication of global inter-city cooperation papers. Source Cass urban competitiveness database
America, Asia, China, Japan and other countries as the center. Among them, London, Boston, Beijing, Paris, New York and Sao Paulo have become the cities with high global urban connection, which indicates that these cities are the regions with high degree of global urban information aggregation. By comparing the status of these cities as global economic, financial and technological centers, we can also prove that they are at the core of global urban linkages. At the same time, it can also be seen that there are obvious regional characteristics in the global urban linkages. The global urban linkages show a significant North–South gap. Cities with high urban
2.4 From the Perspective of Space, the Changes of Global Cities’ …
107
linkages are mainly distributed in the northern hemisphere, while cities in Africa and South America have relatively lower urban linkages. In addition, there are obvious spatial distribution differences within a country’s cities. For example, the global urban connectivity of Chinese cities is mainly concentrated in Beijing, Shanghai, Shenzhen and other eastern coastal global cities, while the global connectivity of other cities is relatively lower, with obvious differences.
2.4.3 Urban Sharing: From Basic Infrastructure to Public Services, from Hardware Products to Software Products, from Public Goods to Private Goods Since the industrial revolution, urban sharing has changed from basic infrastructure to public services, from hardware facilities to information knowledge sharing. By 2050, global urban sharing is characterized by diversified, standardized and largescale shared economic system, shared service facilities system dominated by shared urban public space, and high-level social sharing mechanism. 1. The basic infrastructure was shared by leading cities in 1750–1850, and the level of public service sharing was gradually improved. The industrial revolution has promoted the improvement of means of transportation. The railway transportation mileage in Britain, Germany, France and other cities has been greatly increased. At the same time, the urban road infrastructure has also been greatly improved. However, at this time, the global cities are mainly steam ships, and mainly domestic transportation, and auxiliary products export and raw materials import from foreign markets. For example, in the early days of Germany, steam ships were mainly used for transportation between domestic cities. In 1824, a Dutch steam ship went all the way back to Baharah. Three years later, regular steamship flights between Cologne and Mainz opened. In 1830, there were already 12 steamboats on the Rhine. In the 1940s, the number of steamboats dragging barges across the Dusseldorf bridge on the Caine River doubled every 2–3 years: 339 in 1843; 1073 in 1845; 2438 in 1848; 3989 in 1850. At the same time, Hamburg America post shipping company of Hamburg and North Germany Lloyd shipping company of Bremen have successively used steam ships to transport goods by sea, which to a certain extent extends the scope of global urban sharing and expands the scale of global urban sharing. During this period, the scope of global urban sharing is mainly concentrated in Britain, France, Germany and other countries with more developed industrial revolution, and the sharing of light industrial products is the main part, and the sharing scale is relatively small. During 1750–1850, the level of public service in cities around the world gradually increased, mainly in Western Europe, such as Germany, Britain, France and other cities with public service related listed companies, as shown in Fig. 2.51. These listed companies are also mainly concentrated in London, Paris, Berlin and other cities, in
108
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
10 8 6 4 2 0
Fig. 2.51 The distribution of global public service listed companies in 1750–1850. Source Sorting according to the data of Osiris’s global listed companies
addition to Toronto, Canada, Rio de Janeiro, Brazil and other cities in North America The level of public service is also constantly improving. 2. The level of urban infrastructure sharing increased, and information sharing began to improve in 1850–1950s. With the improvement of urbanization level, the scale and level of national or urban infrastructure in the world are constantly improving, as shown in Table 2.29. It can be seen from the figure that since the 1850s, the global railway infrastructure has achieved rapid development, especially in Britain, the United States, Germany and other countries with developed industrial revolution, which shows that the rapid development of industrialization and urbanization is also constantly extending the scope of urban sharing and expanding the scale of urban sharing. The urbanization rate in the Great Lakes region of the United States has increased from 14.1% in 1860 to 60.8% in 1920, which has more than tripled. This is mainly due to the completion of the railway and water transportation network connecting the northeast and the Middle Atlantic region and the Great Lakes in the 1950s, which caused the migration of immigrants to the West and capital to the West. In addition, the Great Lakes region is rich in heavy industry and agricultural resources, and immigrants and capital gather in the Great Lakes region, forming an economic circle centered on Chicago, the so-called American manufacturing belt. The invention of telephone and telegraph has promoted the information connection between cities and enterprises, the improvement of communication technology has reduced the cost of information communication between enterprises and residents, and urban information sharing has gradually increased. Taking the distribution of Listed Companies in global cities as an example, the cities with high level of global urban information service are still some developed cities in Europe and America, as shown in the figure. It can be seen from Fig. 2.52 that London, New York and Tokyo are at a high level in the global urban information service level, and the information service capacity of some cities in Africa and South America is also increasing.
2.4 From the Perspective of Space, the Changes of Global Cities’ …
109
Table 2.29 Five major foreign urban agglomerations Country
Overview of Urban Agglomerations
U.S.A
A urban agglomerations centered on New York along the Atlantic Ocean in the northeast of the United State, including Boston, New York, Philadelphia, Baltimore, Washington, etc.
USA, Canada
The Great Lakes urban agglomerations in North America centered on Chicago, including Chicago, Detroit, Cleveland, Toronto, Ottawa, Montreal, Quebec and other cities
Japan
Japan’s Pacific coast urban agglomerations centered on Tokyo, Nagoya and Osaka, including Tokyo, Yokohama, Shizuoka, Nagoya, Kyoto, Osaka, Kobe and other cities
Britain
London urban agglomerations includes cities like London, Liverpool, Manchester, Liz, Birmingham and Sheffield
France, Belgium, Netherlands, Germany
The urban agglomerations of northwest Europe centered on Paris, including Paris, Brussels, Antwerp, Amsterdam, Rotterdam, the Hague, Essen, Cologne, Dortmund, Bonn, Frankfurt, Stuttgart, etc.
Source Sorting according to the online material
Table 2.30 Comparison of European and American Railway laying mileage in the nineteenth century Unit (miles)
1840
1850
1860
1870
Britain
838
6,620
10,430
15,540
1880 17,930
1890 19,870
France
360
1,890
5,880
9,770
14,500
10,900
Germany
341
3,640
6,980
11,730
20,690
24,270
Russia
16
310
990
7,100
14,020
17,700
Other European countries
324
2,005
7,605
19,160
34,580
47,320
Total of European countries
1,879
14,465
31,885
63,300
101,720
120,060
U.S.A
2,820
9,020
30,630
53,400
93,670
156,080
Source Walter w. Rostow, World economic history: history and prospects
3. Urban basic public service sharing, knowledge, information and other soft sharing become the main trend from 1950 to 2050, and diversified sharing economic system and urban space sharing become the main trend. With the formation and development of economic globalization and global networking, the development of new generation information and communication technology has broken the limitation of traditional geographical space, and the scope of urban sharing has realized globalization. With the deepening of global urban connections, the scale of global urban sharing has been increasing. Urban sharing has changed from the traditional infrastructure such as railway, highway, shopping mall, etc. to the sharing of transportation tools, services and information based on Networking (as shown in Table 2.11). The networked sharing of urban space has become the trend of urban sharing.
110
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
10 8 6 4 2 0
Fig. 2.52 Distribution of information service listed companies in major cities from 1850 to 1950. Source Sorting according to the data of Osiris’s global listed companies
Behind the new sharing field and mode is that the development of the new generation of information technology represented by the Internet in the 1950s enhanced the supply capacity of information, data, knowledge and other elements among global cities. In the information age, the restructuring of social and economic spatial structure mainly embodies the following main carriers and regional units: global production network and global economic system, big urban aggregation and their core cities, industrial clusters are sometimes regional clusters, industrial complexes, industrial zones, new industrial zones and regional innovation systems, smart cities, etc., as shown in Fig. 2.53. Smart city has become a new carrier of urban sharing, and smart infrastructure and services have become the key to realize the sustainable development of the city. With the construction of smart city, the interconnection and intelligent sharing of everything are the new characteristics of smart city. With the development of artificial intelligence, big data and Internet of things, ubiquitous connection and real-time perception can improve the level of urban intelligent service. According to the prediction of Pricewaterhouse Coopers and other institutions, by 2025, the market size of global sharing economy is expected to increase from 15 billion US dollars in 2015 to 335 billion US dollars. At the same time, because of the huge number of Internet users, the service-oriented transformation of consumption characteristics and the gradual improvement of infrastructure built by internet giants, Chinese cities have become the leading force in the global sharing economy. By the end of 2017, there were 60 Chinese enterprises among 224 Unicorn enterprises in the world, including 31 Chinese enterprises with typical sharing economic attributes, accounting for 51.7% of the total.
2.5 From the Dynamic Mechanism, the Human Development Momentum …
111
Fig. 2.53 Comparison of evaluation indexes between smart city and other cities. Source IESE Cities in Motion Index 2018
2.5 From the Dynamic Mechanism, the Human Development Momentum Bred by Cities Determines the Appearance and Change of the Urban World The development process of the city for 300 years has many factors that determine urban development, such as demand, technology, system, elements, knowledge, resources, production interaction and self-interest motivation, but the core is demand, technology and system. Demand is the self-interested survival instinct of human beings. Its goal is to pursue the maximization of utility. It is the most important driving force for human development and the most important driving force for the origin, development and even extinction of the city. Technology is the sum of the methods, skills and means that human beings use to transform nature in nature in order to meet their own needs and desires, to follow the laws of nature, and to accumulate knowledge, experience, skills and means in the process of long-term use and transformation of nature. But also need to practice in order to find their own technical advantages, which is the necessary condition to determine human development, but also the city’s origin, development and extinction of the necessary conditions. An institution is an interactive rule, which is a kind of special knowledge and technology created by human beings. It regulates human thoughts and behaviors, solves incentives and constraints, and matches and USES resources. It has the characteristics of increasing returns to scale and loss, including property right system, interactive system and distribution system. During the three hundred years of 1750–2050, the rotation of the three core elements of demand, technology and system changed the content of urban economic activities, the size of the city’s space and the size of the city’s population. First, the
112
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Fig. 2.54 Analysis framework of urban development factors and mechanisms. Source Author
system
demand
technology
interaction
human interaction will produce a system in which human intelligence determines the scale of interaction and institutional characteristics, and interacts with spatial states by affecting the use of space resources and the impact of flow costs. Second, the human system affects the scale and depth of human intelligence and interaction, affecting the state of interaction by affecting the use of space resources and the cost of interaction. Third, the scale and depth of human interaction affect human intelligence development and institutional evolution. Finally, after the three roles meet human needs, they will generate higher new demands, which will lead to a new round of three evolution (see Fig. 2.54). On the one hand, these elements and powers are cultivated in the cities, the cities foster the developmental kinetic energy of human beings, and the cities are the containers for gathering and cultivating these forces; on the other hand, the factors and powers cultivated by these cities drive the growth of the cities and Changes determine the appearance and changes of the city, and then determine the appearance and changes of the urban world through the city. 1. The pursuit of good life is the original driving force of the urban world in 300 years. The demand of 300 years in the city dominates the demand of the world for 300 years and determines the development of the world. Human needs are not only born with the pursuit of maximum utility, but also have an internal mechanism that is constantly improving. The unsatisfied demand of mankind is the inexhaustible source of power for human development. The pursuit of a better life by mankind is the source of the origin, development and even demise of the city. Everyone’s behavior is rational and self-interested. Pursuing self-interest is the fundamental driving force for all personal economic activities. Not only natural people, but also various organizations composed of natural persons pursue their own interests. Abandoning ownership, whether private, self-owned or public, as long as it recognizes and defines the relatively independent interests of economic entities, economic entities will have a strong incentive to pursue self-interest, and thus may penetrate all social fields and destroy all high-wall barriers. Break all kinds of inherent order and change the pattern of all interests. Second, human desires promote product
2.5 From the Dynamic Mechanism, the Human Development Momentum …
113
and urban functional diversity and change urban functions. Because of the desire for a better living environment, people are forced to move from rural to urban areas; because they want better living space, the city scale is gradually expanded; world cities such as New York, Chicago, London, Tokyo, Hong Kong control the global financial lifeline. Silicon Valley has a global lifeline. Human demand determines the content of production, consumption, exchange and activities of cities for 300 years. Demand generates in cities and influences the world through cities. Urban demand determines the development of the world. 2. The technological revolution is the core driving force for the formation of the urban world in 300 years. Urban demand brings about an increase in the level of technology, and each technological innovation will bring about a substantial increase in productivity, which will often lead to the birth and prosperity of new industries, which will determine the production content, consumption content, and exchange content of the city. Urban space size and population size. People also pursue profits for self-interested motives, gather in cities and conduct activities in cities, and gradually form small towns, cities, metropolitan areas, and urban agglomerations. The urban system has gradually become a single center, multi-center, and network. From the first industrial revolution from 1750 to 1850, the second industrial revolution from 1850 to 1950, the third industrial revolution from 1950 to 2008, and the fourth industrialization after 2008. The revolution (see Table 2.31), every technological innovation has a significant change in urban economic development, activity content, space scale, population size and urban pattern (Table 2.32). 3. Market system is the key driving force for the formation of the urban world Demand and technological development drive the birth and development of the system. As a rule of human interaction, the system affects economic development performance by influencing resource allocation and subjective dynamics. No matter under any system, cities determined by the system and superior to other settlements are constantly developing, but institutional differences determine the differences in urban development. In addition, the system has only quality and quantity. The quality of the system determines the increase or decrease of the scale return. The property rights system and resource allocation effect, which determines the human behavior, the rise and fall of the city and the development of the world, since 1750, the market economy as a more advanced economic system, its formation, development and maturity affect the global urbanization from rapid to accelerated transformation, where to implement the market economic system, and where the city rises.
114
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Table 2.31 Sharing fields and companies Sharing fields
Sharing network company (domestic)
Shared network company (foreign)
Traffic sharing
Didi express: didi hitchhiker, express and Uber: provide private car service “special vehicle” Easy to use car: high end special food service
LYFT: provide private car sharing service
Daily use: one-to-one, point-to-point commuting experience
Sidecar: more pure carpooling
Ha ha carpooling: carpooling service in the same area
Flightear: Airport idle car sharing
PP car rental: online car sharing platform Zipcar: membership system sharing idle cars EHI car rental: rent out the car to the tenants in need
Wheelz: P2P car rental business for College Students Getaround: P2P car rental flat Netjets: Rental of idle private aircraft Prop: idle yacht rental
Housing sharing
Piggy rent: Chinese version of airbnb
Airbnb: short stay reservation
Ant short rent: home apartment booking website
Dogvacay: the dog version of airbnb
Tujia.com: domestic travel and holiday apartment booking website
Easynest: sharing the empty bed in the hotel Divvy: looking for roommates and sharing rooms
Diet sharing
Clothing sharing
Other sharing
Love Chef: Chinese version
Eatwise: food sharing of ancestors
Love feast and meet: domestic eat and meet friends
Plenry: eat with friends
Good chef: provide private kitchen service
Feastly: home made meal sharing
Private chef: docking with private chef
Spoonrct: the most convenient ordering service
Magic wardrobe: Sharing in the field of clothing
Rentthe runway: selected brands and fashionable dresses
Mercer: luxury package rental service (closed in 2013)
Poshmark: second hand clothing trading platform
Lazy housekeeping: high-end domestic service talents
Taskrabbit: labor employment platform (continued)
2.5 From the Dynamic Mechanism, the Human Development Momentum …
115
Table 2.31 (continued) Sharing fields
Sharing network company (domestic)
Shared network company (foreign)
Youth dish King: sell and change semi-finished clean dishes
Skillshare: sharing skills
Auntie help: quickly find a satisfied hourly worker
Handybook: integrating Home Economics
Beauty Taoist: door-to-door beauty service
Classpass: integrated gym
Carefree parking network: help find parking space Table 2.32 Comparison of previous technological revolutions Content
First industrial revolution
Second technological revolution
The third technological revolution
Time
1850s–1950s
1950s–early twentieth century
1950s–early twenty-first century
Major achievements
Extensive use of Jenny machines and steam engines
Electric power, internal combustion engine, chemical technology development, steel industry progress
Atomic energy, electronic computer, aerospace engineering, biotechnology
Country of occurrence
Britain expands to Europe and the United States
The United States, United States France, Germany and many countries simultaneously
New transportation Train, steamboat
Aircraft, car
High-speed rail, subway
New energy
Coal
Electricity, oil
Solar energy
New industrial sector
Cotton textile, machine building, transportation
Power industry, New service industry, electrical product intelligent manufacturing manufacturing, petroleum industry, automotive industry
Production organization
Factory system
Monopoly organization
Global industry chain (continued)
116
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Table 2.32 (continued) Content
First industrial revolution
Second technological revolution
The third technological revolution
Relationship between scientific research and technological revolution
Unbound
True combination
Fully integrated
Era
Steampunk era
Electrical age
Information intelligence era
Traffic
Carriage era
Steam iron era
High speed era
Communication
Letter mailing era
Telegraph era
Information interconnection era
Product
Article processing era
Age of itemization Service era, knowledge age
Main invention mark
Steam engine, shuttle, Jane spinning machine, modified steam engine, steam ship, boiler, railway, miner’s lamp, steam train, telegraph, lithography, vaccinia, urea, morphine
Telephone, car, generator, electric light, aircraft, electric power, petroleum, steel making, steam sterilization, disinfection, penicillin, antibiotics, amino acids, synthetic sulfonamides
Computers, televisions, automobiles, high-speed rail, subway, air-conditioning technology, space shuttles, civil aircraft, satellite, Internet, mobile phones, Internet of Things, artificial intelligence (AI), biological genes, cloning technology, robots
Data source The author sorted out
2.5.1 1750–1850, Demand, Technology and Institutional Rotation Effects Since 1750, on the one hand, the ever-evolving demand of mankind needs to be provided by the city. On the other hand, the population pursuing a better life is increasingly rushing to the city. It is the continuous expansion and upgrading of human needs that has driven the expansion of the city scale. The evolution of the structure and the evolution of its connotations. 1. Urban demand is reflected in food and processing consumer goods. From 1750 to 1850, in order to meet the most basic production and living needs, the urban demand is mainly reflected in food and consumer goods. Under the selfinterested demand, in order to obtain more income and production materials, the invention and manufacture of production tools began to be carried out, which led to the improvement of labor production efficiency, greatly improved the income level of the industrial part of labor, and led to the birth of new technologies. In addition, the self-interested demand has prompted a large amount of labor to be transferred
2.5 From the Dynamic Mechanism, the Human Development Momentum …
117
from the agricultural production sector to the industrial production sector, and the labor force flows from the rural areas to the cities, driving the urbanization process. 2. The steam engine technology revolution, machine production replaced manual manufacturing for the first time, and the city’s content, scale and shape changed. Due to changes in people’s needs, technological innovations have been promoted, and the way in which urban economic development has changed, and machine production has replaced manual manufacturing. After 1750, the European industrial countries represented by the United Kingdom realized the transformation from manual production to industrial production. The machine substitution manual first liberated human physical strength. The factory production of alternative workshops or manual workshops promoted the accumulation of production activities, the size of the city, Significant changes have taken place in function and morphology. The invention and improvement of mechanical production such as steam engines and textile machines, manual labor was completely replaced by mechanical production, and the production efficiency was greatly improved. Subsequently, many industrial sectors such as coal mining and metallurgy produced more and more machines, and the factory began to form. significantly promoted urban economic growth. Driven by self-interest, people gather in places with high labor productivity such as factories, and the population scale begins to expand, and the city scale begins to expand around it. Secondly, the content of the first technological revolution to promote urban activities has changed, and the endowments of energy and natural resources have determined the city, and the functional central city has been formed. The machine production brought about by the first industrial revolution made energy development possible. In order to pursue greater profits, the capitalists will set the factory in the place of origin of the means of production, and the resource-based city will be formed, so that the endowment of energy and natural resources will be decided. The content of city activities. For example, in the UK, before the Industrial Revolution, most of the industry was concentrated in the southeastern region centered on London, with East England, the southeastern part of England and West Yorkshire being the gathering place for the wool textile industry; the metallurgical industry and the metalworking industry were mainly concentrated in Birmingham., South Wales, Sheffield and Northeast Wales. In the process of industrial revolution, with the rise of the cotton textile industry, a series of small and medium-sized towns dominated by the industry have also risen. This has caused the British industrial center to move westward and northward. The economy is backward and sparsely populated. The northwest region has become the center of cotton textile industry and coal iron industry. Cities such as Manchester, salford, bolton, berry, Preston and oldham all rose with the development of cotton textile industry. The areas of slope, Worcester, south wales and Monmouth with relatively rich coal and iron resources also rose rapidly. Thirdly, the first technological revolution has led to changes in the spatial scale and population size of urban activities. The improvement of transportation technology has determined the changes in the spatial and scale of urban activities. Large cities have begun to take shape, and the improvement of medical technology has provided
118
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
guarantees for the expansion of population. In addition, in order to maximize profits, it is faster and more convenient to transport goods and raw materials, and people want to design vehicles to be modified. For example, cities such as steamboats, steam locomotives, trains and other transportation vehicles have caused the human transportation industry to enter a steam-driven era, and the space and scale of urban activities have changed. Because in the early stage of underdeveloped transportation technology, cities with basic public transportation such as walking and horse-drawn carriages can meet the corresponding scale of urban space. For example, urban residents are affected by transportation methods such as walking and carriages, resulting in residents living only. In the narrow urban center, the city size is at a low level. However, the birth of steam trains and the rapid development of the transportation industry will further strengthen the economic ties between cities and cities, cities and urban and rural areas, so that the urban economy will develop rapidly and accelerate the process of urbanization. The convenience of waterway and land transportation has reduced freight times and costs several times, strengthened economic ties between cities and between urban and rural areas, and enabled cities and towns in the status of transportation hubs to grow rapidly, which has greatly accelerated the city. Process. While the development of urban public transportation has brought convenience to people, the improvement of public transportation has facilitated the travel of residents, and the urban population and scale have been continuously expanded, which has also accelerated the process of urbanization. The exchanges between cities began to increase, which led to the city’s activity space not being confined to the interior of the city. The urban activity space spread from within the city to the city, the city scale expanded, and the big city began to form. In addition, after the industrial revolution began, with the rapid development of medicine and medical and health care, the improvement of disease prevention level brought about the expansion of the city scale. During the first industrial revolution, the invention and application of vaccinia, morphine, ipecaine, strychnine, quinine, caffeine, and chloroform also ensured a steady increase in population size and promoted the expansion of urban scale. Finally, the links between cities have strengthened and the urban system has slowly formed. The technological innovation initiated by the Atlantic Ocean in the Atlantic broke through various obstacles, broke national borders and continents, and expanded across the Atlantic to Europe, the United States and Asia. It strengthened the international division of labor, promoted international population and capital flows, and promoted the United States. The revolution, reforms of Russia, Germany and Italy, the burgeoning urbanization process in Europe and the United States began, which promoted the rise of global cities and accelerated the process of global urbanization. By the middle of the nineteenth century, the UK had become the “world factory”
2.5 From the Dynamic Mechanism, the Human Development Momentum …
119
with its advanced production technology, strong economic strength, developed transportation and possessing a vast colony. This means that the world market with the UK as the center is formed and around the world. Further strengthening of economic ties. 3. The market economy system has been preliminary established in a few countries and tried in some fields. Driven by demand and technology, the market economy system began to be established in a few countries and made initial attempts in some areas. Specifically, before the industrial revolution, the global economic structure was mainly based on agriculture, which provided limited production and exchange, which limited the spread of the market economy. Under the social structure at that time, people were seriously lacking freedom. Most people are still slaves. Religious thoughts bind people’s freedom of thought and freedom of movement and limit the development of the market economy. In addition, before the industrial revolution, the world was still a feudal society. The mutual interests of various countries and even the colonies seriously hindered the division of labor and the expansion of the market. Even in the early days of the industrial revolution, the market economy was not complete. Both the United Kingdom and the United States have slaves. With the advancement of the first industrial revolution, a large number of legal systems conducive to the protection of property rights and resource allocation were gradually established, and the system that was not conducive to market economy and trade development was abolished. For example, during the Industrial Revolution, the British abolished the apprenticeship regulations, the residence law, the highest wage law, etc., and in the latter part of the industrial revolution, abolished all restrictions on exports, and later abolished the grain regulations and navigation regulations that impeded trade, and abolished them. The bubble regulations that hinder the company’s development have promoted the development of trade. In addition, the government also handed over economic activities to the market, abolished the monopoly power of the concessionaire, canceled or lowered restrictions on import and export products, removed restrictions on prices and interest rates, and even carried out banking system reforms to ensure that the market was in a stable monetary environment. run. More importantly, the industrial revolution has promoted the formation of a modern corporate system. After the merger of the modern corporate system and the factory system, it is more convenient and easy to popularize, which is conducive to the comprehensive development of competition in the market economy. Because it disperses risks, it encourages more people. Investing, making full use of all available economic resources, the market economy has found the most effective form of production and operation organization. A series of laws and regulations have been promulgated to protect the development of modern corporate systems, such as contract law, exchange law, securities law, company law and factory law, and prohibition of stock speculation. These property rights systems and resource allocation systems have laid the foundation for the stable development of cities. In general, during the first industrial revolution, the government adopted a laissezfaire policy and implemented a freely competitive market economy. Market entry
120
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
80
Estevadeordal, Frantz, and Taylor (2003) (upper bound) (%) Estevadeordal, Frantz, and Taylor (2003) (lower bound) (%) 60
Klasing and Milionis (2014) (based on Maddison) (%) Klasing and Milionis (2014) (%) Penn World Tables (9.0) (%)
40
World Development Indicators (Rate)
20
0 1700
1750
1800
1850
1900
1950
2000
Fig. 2.55 Globalization process. Notes 1500–1820 come from Estevadeordal, Frantz, and Taylor (2003) (upper bound) (%); 1870–1940 come from Klasing and Milionis (2014) (%); 1950–2014 come from Penn World Tables (9.0) (%). Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
restrictions were gradually eliminated, and market relations developed. In the legal system, private law was recognized for private property recognition. Protection emphasizes equality before the law and adjusts the property relationship between equal subjects through human rights, private law, and civil and commercial law. Through the abolition of slavery, human rights have been guaranteed and the development of urban population has been promoted. Through the protection of modern corporate systems, property rights systems and market economic systems, the efficiency of economic operations has been improved, and the expansion of urban industries and space has been promoted. As a result, all regions where market economic systems and property rights systems are implemented, such as the United Kingdom and France, have relatively rapid economic, social, and demographic development. Countries where market economic systems and property rights systems are not operating, such as Asia, which is still in agricultural society, In Africa and other countries, their urban development is relatively slow. Figure 2.55 shows the globalization process from 1500 to 1850. It can be seen from Fig. 2.55 that during the first industrial revolution, the globalization process has accelerated significantly.
2.5.2 1850–1950, Demand, Technology and Institutional Rotation Effects 1. Urban demand is transformed into Heavy chemical products. From 1850 to 1950, after people met the basic needs of production and life, people’s demand structure gradually turned to developmental and enjoyable upgrades, prompting residents to have huge demand for heavy chemical products, leading to major changes in urban demand. The demand for the city has turned to the large-scale
2.5 From the Dynamic Mechanism, the Human Development Momentum …
121
consumption of durable consumer goods of 10,000 yuan and 100,000 yuan, such as automobiles and housing, which has driven the changes in the world’s demand. 2. The power technology revolution, the city has become the pillar of the world. Driven by urban demand, in order to meet the needs of the city and the world, the level of technology has once again been improved, and the city’s activities, urban space, urban population size and urban system have undergone new changes. First of all, the content of urban activities breaks through the time limit. The application of electricity enables the city to carry out economic activities at any time, and the heavy industry has become the dominant city. With the application of electric energy, people’s lives are no longer limited by time. People’s production efficiency and activity space have been significantly improved. With the wide application of electricity, people’s exchanges have entered the telegraph era. In the era of the first industrial revolution, this greatly reduced the limitations of time and space, and closely linked individuals. More importantly, power technology has brought about the improvement of steelmaking and ironmaking technologies, which has prompted the city to enter industrialization and enter the era of product integration, which has led to a qualitative improvement in industrial production efficiency, significantly promoted urban economic growth, and the city has become the pillar of the world. Secondly, the city’s spatial scale and population size have been further expanded, and urban agglomerations and urban belts have been formed. The invention of sterilization, disinfection, penicillin, antibiotics, synthetic sulfonamides and other drugs brought about by the second industrial revolution provided a solid foundation for the expansion of the urban population. Power brought smelting technology upgrades, steelmaking technology upgrades, and improved steel quality and output. The city’s architecture began to be cast from steel, directly changing the face of the city. The smelting industry and the power industry have been upgraded, which has promoted the innovation of the transportation industry. The railroad tracks are completely made of steel, which leads to the increase of the power and speed of the locomotives. Compared with the era of horse-drawn carriages, the automobile-iron era has further expanded the scale of the city, especially the upgrading of sailing, ships, automobiles, railways and airplanes. The space of port cities has been greatly enhanced, such as Seoul, Tokyo, Osaka, Hong Kong and Macau. New cities such as New York, Washington, London, and Los Angeles are all located in coastal areas, and the London city clusters formed in ports and coastal areas, the northwestern European urban agglomerations, the Japanese Pacific coast urban agglomerations, the Great Walls of North America, and the United States. In the northeastern Atlantic coast, urban agglomerations, urban agglomerations and urban belts are formed. With the use of aircraft, this offshore urban agglomeration has broken the pattern of global cities. Inland cities have also begun to participate in the global urban system, and global urban networks have begun to take shape. The figure shows the flight distance of non-commercial aircraft. It can be seen from Fig. 2.56 that the total flight distance has increased rapidly since the invention of the aircraft. The invention of vehicles, ships, airplanes and other means of transportation completely broke the inherent spatial form of the city and gradually expanded the size of the city.
122
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
non-commercial-flight-distance 20000 18000 16000 14000 12000 10000 8000 6000 4000 2000 0 1850
1870
1890
1910
1930
1950
Fig. 2.56 Non-commercial aircraft flight distance. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
Finally, the global single-center city system is determined. The second industrial revolution prompted developed countries to take the lead in industrialized society. The production, consumption, division of labor and cooperation of global factors have led to the formation of a global urban pattern, and the single-center urban system has been determined. In order to promote domestic commodity exchanges, European and American countries have engaged in transportation construction on a large scale. In order to expand overseas markets and commit themselves to the development of ocean transportation networks, a global transportation network has gradually formed, and a global urban system has begun to take shape. Especially in the latter part of the Second Industrial Revolution, the First World War and the Second World War accelerated the process of the weak countries becoming colonies and affiliated countries. The European and American powers brought the advanced industrial technology of Europe and America to these areas when they colonized Asia, Africa and Latin America. These countries have slowly embarked on the road of industrialization, but the cities of Asia, Africa and Latin America have become the annexes of European and American cities. The eastern cities are completely subordinate to Western cities, and the pattern of single-center cities in global cities is determined. In addition, in the second industrial revolution, emerging capital and energy-intensive industries adopted a giant factory and a large vertically integrated monopoly organization as their main industrial organization form, which also contributed to the development of the city into the metropolitan era. 3. The market economy system has developed initially in Western countries and deepened in some areas. The deepening of demand and technological revolution has led to the initial development of the market economy system, the development in the Western countries, and the deepening in some areas. This is the mature stage of the capitalist market economy.
2.5 From the Dynamic Mechanism, the Human Development Momentum …
123
In economic terms, the government intervenes more in the economy, implements social welfare policies, gradually establishes a social security system, emphasizes the concept of “socialization”, safeguards public welfare, and implements “economic democracy”, which stipulates that citizens enjoy the right to education and work. Rights and safeguard the legitimate rights and interests of workers. In the legal system, in addition to traditional public and private law, economic legislation and social law have been produced and strengthened, and the state’s intervention in the economy has been strengthened through economic laws to compensate for the shortcomings of the market mechanism. For example, capitalist countries have separately promulgated anti-monopoly laws, which promote the vitality of the market economy and the creativity of enterprises. In particular, the Industrial Revitalization Law, the Agricultural Adjustment Law, the Emergency Banking Law, and the Emergency Relief Law have implemented comprehensive intervention in economic life. In terms of the protection of private property rights, Western countries have also tightened restrictions. The state may levy or expropriate private property for the needs of the public interest, and even promote “nationalization”, which stipulates that the state can directly own enterprises and undertakings, thus making private property Absolute protection is transformed into relative protection, using state power to develop emerging industries, achieving production and capital concentration, such as: setting up state-owned enterprises, state-owned holdings, using economic instruments and economic policies, and protecting and supporting the development of emerging industries and special industries. These laws and behaviors are a key system for the dynamics of the Western market economy, self-selection and self-elimination, and incentives for corporate innovation. It enhances the vitality and internal ability of the sustainable development of the capitalist market economy and deepens the market economy. Cities in Western countries have thus developed rapidly and dominated the global urban landscape. Figures 2.57 and 2.58 show the urbanization rate of the major countries in the world in 1850 and 1900 respectively. It can be seen from the high and low urbanization rate of each country that the urbanization process of the country implementing the market economy is significantly higher than that of the eastern agricultural society.
2.5.3 1950–2050, Demand, Technology and Institutional Rotation Effects 1. Urban demand is reflected in service products, knowledge products and spiritual life products. As the demand for heavy-duty products such as development and enjoyment is met, science and technology and institutions will bring new demands and promote the development of demand, technology and systems. Therefore, between 1950 and 2050, people want to have a better culture, entertainment, and service environment, diversify the urban industry, diversify the city’s functions, and further expand the
124
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Fig. 2.57 Urbanization rate of major countries in 1850. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
Fig. 2.58 Urbanization rate of major countries in 1990. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
knowledge products after human beings have basically met the material and labor services in the future. Demand, leading to a new round of technological and institutional changes, will certainly have a new round of impact on the size, structure and content of the city. 2. Information and intelligent technology revolution, the city is the world. First of all, the content of urban activities has changed again because of the information revolution. The urban economic mode has changed from unipolar to multipolar,
2.5 From the Dynamic Mechanism, the Human Development Momentum …
125
and multi-polar industries such as service industry and smart manufacturing have led the development of cities. From the content of human activities, the content of previous human activities is mainly work, and there are few other economic activities. The development of the information technology and intelligent technology revolution has promoted the content of human activities, including telephone, text messaging, travel, video, film, games, and finance. The urban economic growth mode also has unipolar heavy chemical industry manufacturing, and turns to multi-level high-end manufacturing, service industry, artificial intelligence manufacturing, etc., such as semiconductor, Internet, computer, mobile phone, Internet of things, air conditioning, artificial intelligence and other new technology industries. It will drive urban economic development, such as Silicon Valley in the United States, Shenzhen in China, and Bangalore in India. Science and technology are driving economic development and changing the city’s connotation. Second, the city’s function has also changed, and the smart city was born. Digital information and urban integration change the city’s functions. The current city integrates digital media and entertainment, education and training, financial services, manufacturing and logistics, intelligent transportation systems, health and biological sciences, artificial intelligence and virtual reality. For example, Singapore, London, New York, San Francisco, Chicago, Seoul, Berlin, Tokyo, Barcelona, Melbourne, Dubai, Putlan, Hangzhou and other cities have the world’s leading social, public services and urban management. Intelligent manufacturing leads to the intelligent production of human beings, and the easier work of human beings will increase the employment pressure of cities, but it also creates conditions for new employment space. In addition, the production, exchange and consumption of goods shift to the production, consumption and exchange of knowledge information, and the development of information technology supports the global division of labor and proliferation of industries. Finally, the technological innovation brought about by the third information revolution has intensified population concentration and human activities, changed the scale of urban space and population size, formed a multi-center networked urban system, and the city is the world. The acceleration of global urbanization and the development of information technology and other technological innovations have an important relationship. The development of information technology has significantly improved the industrial structure of the city, and has spawned high-tech industries such as e-commerce, software services, and electronic entertainment, which has greatly attracted the gathering of talents and promoted the city. Process and urban economic development. Since the third information revolution, the world’s major scientific and technological inventions have covered human life, society, medical care, transportation and other aspects, and have had a greater impact on urban functions, urban space, and urban patterns. From the perspective of information traffic, the development of information infrastructure such as subways, high-speed rails, airplanes, and satellites has greatly expanded the city’s spatial content and narrowed the time and space of the city, resulting in the reshaping of urban space, and the metropolitan area has become the direction of urban development.. In addition, biomedicine has improved the health and longevity of urbanization, created many
126
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
employment opportunities, and promoted the development of health industry. The maturity and application of vitamins, penicillin, infectious disease prevention technology, and genetic technology have greatly improved the medical level and human life. Urban space form. 3. The market economy system is expanding globally and innovating in more fields. After the third industrial revolution, the economic systems of major countries in the world mainly included the planned economy and the market economy. However, due to the planned economy, the problem of incentives and rational allocation was not well solved, the competition of most products was weakened, and the economic entities could not be rationally regulated. The economic interests between them, and more importantly, these problems lead to a non-sustainable planned economy, which is not conducive to the long-term development of the country. Under these conditions, most countries in the world have gradually turned to the market economy system. However, some countries have imperfect market economic systems, such as property rights system and resource allocation, which will also lead to the slow development of some market economy systems. And unbalanced. When entering the late stage of the third industrial revolution, after 1990, the market economy entered the stage of globalization. In economic terms, the world’s major powers have allocated economic resources globally, and there have been phenomena such as market integration, financial internationalization, production transnationalization, and economic networking. In law, the global rules dominated by Western capitalist countries, their capital and technology. The global expansion has spread to all parts of the world, and as the status of developing countries rises, its global rules are challenged. The influence of the globalization of market economic system on the market economy of developing countries mainly involves the financial law, securities law, bill law and guarantee law for adjusting financial activities; investment law, tax law, company law and bankruptcy law that regulate the activities of market entities; Antiunfair competition law, anti-monopoly law, consumer rights protection law, product liability law; intellectual property law, technology transfer law, computer software registration law, patent law and copyright law for protecting intangible assets. In particular, WTO rules, the World Intellectual Property Rules, the rules of the World Labor Organization, and the rules of the United Nations environmental organizations have had an inestimable impact on the legal system of developing countries participating in the process of economic globalization. In this process, Western capitalist developed countries make full use of their legal rules and procedures and talent advantages to protect their domestic market interests. With the proliferation of market economic systems, which have affected every city, globalization has become an important feature of modern urban systems. Driven by the new technological revolution, especially the computer network revolution, the international division of labor has become increasingly specialized within the industry. The tremendous development of multinational corporations and multinational banks has further promoted the internationalization of capital. The internationalization of capital has directly led to the integration of the global economy. And ultimately, the city as the main body of various factors determines the future of the
2.5 From the Dynamic Mechanism, the Human Development Momentum …
127
Fig. 2.59 Relationship between economic freedom and urbanization rate in 1995. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
world. It can be seen from Fig. 2.55 that the level of globalization has increased from 20 in 1950 to 62 in 2008. The globalization process has increased rapidly and cities have participated in the global urban system. With the promotion of transportation technologies such as shipping and aviation, information technology, and other information technologies, the competition, cooperation, division of labor, and trade between cities have reached an unprecedented height. The economic activities between cities are no longer limited to distances. The advantages and disadvantages of the location and the multi-center networked urban system were formed. Figure 2.59 and Fig. 2.60 show the scatter plot between economic freedom and urbanization rate in 1995 and 2017, respectively. Overall, the higher the market economy, the higher the level of urbanization.
2.5.4 The Combination of Urban Development and Rotation 1. Technological innovation promotes institutional change and urban development. The industrial revolution has brought tremendous technological progress, promoted a tremendous leap in the development of productive forces, and caused profound changes in the social system. Before the 1950s, the European industrial countries represented by the United Kingdom and France realized the transformation from manual production to industrial production. The machine substitution manual first
128
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Fig. 2.60 Relationship between economic freedom and urbanization rate in 2017. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
liberated human physical strength. The industrial revolution was a large-scale production technology revolution that replaced large-scale machine production with manual labor and promoted a huge leap in productivity. The invention and use of steam engines has caused a series of dramatic changes in industrial production. At the same time, the leap in industrial production has led to the rise of agricultural technology and the rise and development of capitalist agriculture. The industrial revolution has greatly promoted the development of science, technology and culture. The industrial revolution has also caused profound changes in the entire society, creating two opposing classes, the industrial bourgeoisie and the proletariat. The birth of these two classes is directly worldwide. The social and institutional systems have promoted the birth of capitalism and socialism. Second, technological innovation has also changed the urban landscape and influenced the formation of modern urban systems. With the deepening and expansion of the industrial revolution, capitalist production methods have been established in advanced countries in Europe and America. Most countries in Asia, Africa and Latin America lost their resilience under the gunships of the great powers, became the colonial and semi-colonial capital of the European and American capitalist powers, became the international market of capitalism, the supply of raw materials and labor, and became the place for their investment. The paradise has become a subsidiary of the capitalist economy. The expansion of the capitalist powers has had a dual impact on the Asian, African, and Latin American countries. On the one hand, the bloody aggression and cruel colonial plunder of the great powers have caused local people to suffer serious disasters and cause long-term poverty in these areas; In the economic aggression, the powers inevitably bring advanced industrial production technology, scientific knowledge and advanced ideas into these countries
2.5 From the Dynamic Mechanism, the Human Development Momentum …
129
and regions. Thus, from the 1750s to the present, the pattern dominated by cities in western developed countries and dominated cities in western developing countries. 2. System reform promotes technological innovation and urban development. Institutional reform determines the basic principles of property rights and marketization, and provides the basis for urban development and technological innovation. Among them, the establishment of the factory system, the factory production of alternative workshops or manual workshops promoted the accumulation of production activities, expanded the size of the city, and changed the function and form of the city. Market-oriented institutional reform is the basic driving force and condition for urban development. The reform of the system is the foundation of urban development. Whether urban development or rural development, institutional reform has a decisive influence. The market-oriented reform mainly includes two aspects. First, the recognition and clarification of the relatively independent responsibility of the actors is the prerequisite for self-survival and development. Regardless of ownership, as long as they recognize and define their relatively independent and symmetrical rights and interests, economic agents can generate strong motivation to pursue selfinterest. Recognize and clarify the relatively independent responsibility of economic entities, stimulate the enthusiasm of all entities in the whole society to pursue their own interests, and make all undertakings full of vitality and vitality. At the same time, the lack of self-interest in restraint also brings problems from micro to macro, from economy to society to the environment. Secondly, it determines the decisive role of the market in resource allocation, so that all resources are effectively allocated by the invisible hand of the market, and the role of the market is maximized. Further promote technological innovation and urban development under institutional conditions and self-interested behavior. Figure 2.61 shows the number of patent applications in the United Kingdom, Ireland and New Zealand during the industrial revolution, and Fig. 2.62 shows the number of patents granted in the United States. It can be seen from Figs. 2.61 and 2.62 that the number of patent applications in the United Kingdom and the United States rose rapidly during the industrial revolution, far ahead of the rest. 3. Urban development promotes technological innovation and institutional change. In order to develop, cities must attract talents and industrial division of labor, which leads to industrial globalization and resource globalization. The division of labor can improve efficiency and bring more benefits to the city. Therefore, urban entities continue to expand the market and the scope of division of labor through technological innovation and institutional reforms, leading to a new wave of integration and division of labor around the world. The information technology revolution and the rising labor costs in developed countries have promoted the global industrial division of labor to upgrade the global industrial chain. Multinational companies are considering the maximization of profits based on the development of high-tech industries with technological innovation, and based on the value chain on a global scale. Re-layout the industrial chain to transfer technology and low value-added processing and production links to low-cost countries and regions within the country.
130
2 The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion
Number of patents awarded (patents awarded per year) 700 600 500
England
Ireland
Scotland
400 300 200 100 0 1700
1720
1740
1760
1780
1800
1820
1840
1860
Fig. 2.61 The amount of patents granted through the industrial revolution. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
Fig. 2.62 US patent grants. Data source The author sorts according to our world in data database data
Economic globalization and informatization have made the world cities increasingly connected, becoming interdependent and chained, and expanding the division of labor and cooperation between production, exchange, circulation, consumption, services, technology and product development in countries around the world. The global economic system and economic activities bring global cities closer together. As a result, the city has become a world city, a regional central city, a national central city, a specialized production and service center city, and the city has to carry out technological innovation and revolution in order to more effectively control other cities to
2.5 From the Dynamic Mechanism, the Human Development Momentum …
131
connect with other cities, such as the third. The development of information brought about by the sub-industrial revolution. From the globalization of the great voyage era 1.0 to the UK-led globalization 2.0, to the US-led globalization 3.0, the leaders of globalization rules can get more global dividends, but maintaining these rules also requires corresponding strength. The rules of globalization itself are mirror images of the relative strengths of countries in the world, and the most important of them is economic strength, followed by military strength. Therefore, this requires cities to carry out institutional reforms and adapt to new international forms. In addition, globalization, as an objective requirement of the development of human beings and social productive forces, reflects the inevitable law of the historical development of human society. It is closely related to the emergence and development of capitalism. Its basic driving force comes from the development and expansion of capital. Drive economic change and then impact the entire society. Just as the double shock wave caused by globalization to the world, the impact of globalization on the economic and social development of cities must also be twofold. The various social behaviors, including politics, culture, economy and even government behavior, will be deeply subject to capital. With the vitality of the market and the deepening of competition in the world market, the reform of production and social mechanisms will be carried out under the market regulations. The trend of world development may be tortuous but will not change, because the above mechanism is promoted by the world. Even if there is a hot war and a cold war, it will not be a long-term trend, because war cannot change these mechanisms.
Chapter 3
Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
3.1 Global Trends in Municipal Finance 3.1.1 Introduction Cities are the engine of the global economy. Both the total urban population and GDP arising from cities is rapidly increasing. Municipal finance is a key condition determining the ability of municipalities to successfully manage growth, and will thus be central to the competitiveness of cities. However, there are major differences between cities around the world in terms of their budgets and the challenges and opportunities they face. This chapter seeks to identify some of the major trends by region in terms of expenditures, revenues, challenges and positive trends. It uses data on expenditures and revenues from UN-Habitat’s Global Municipal Database (GMD). To provide and overview of challenges and positive trends, it draws upon inputs from a set of municipal finance experts for each of four regions: Africa, Asia, Europe and Latin America.
3.1.2 Why Municipal Finance? Between 2014 and 2016, the world’s 300 largest metro areas accounted for 36% of global employment but 67% of global GDP growth (Bouchet et al. 2018). More than 80% of global GDP is generated in cities (World Bank, 2019b). In developing regions, cities are the primary location for growth in the manufacturing and services sectors which drive economic structural transformation (UNECA 2017). The economic competitiveness and attractiveness of cities is shaping patterns of global private investment, growth and innovation (Peterson et al. 2018). Already more than
© China Social Sciences Press 2023 P. Ni et al., The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-99-3553-6_3
133
134
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
half the global population lives in cities, and by 2050, the world’s urban populations are projected to increase by 2.5 billion people, with nearly 90% of that growth occurring in Asia and Africa (UNDESA 2018). With their increasing share of population and economic activity, cities globally have increasing financial needs. The global cost to implement the Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs) has been estimated at US$ 5-7 trillion, with a gap of US$ 2.5 trillion in developing countries alone (UNCTAD 2014). Cities will be instrumental in meeting goals on poverty, employment, inequality, health, education, gender, infrastructure and public services, consumption and production, climate change and the environment. Cities are also the focus of Goal 11, to “Make cities and human settlements inclusive, safe, resilient and sustainable” (United Nations 2015a). According to a survey of 101 local governments in 61 countries about localizing the SDGs, finance was the most commonly cited top priority (UCLG 2018). The cost of infrastructure to maintain GDP growth globally is estimated at over 3 trillion a year to 2030 (Dobbs et al. 2013). A commonly cited figure that 1/3 of total investments should be in cities (UCLG 2007) implies that US$ 1 trillion is needed annually for global urban infrastructure investments. Municipalities are the government entities that most closely manage cities, and are well situated to respond to the specific needs of their resident populations and businesses in terms of public services, education, an enabling business environment and governance impacting the local quality of life. Municipal finance, defined as the “revenue and expenditure of local government in urban areas” (Cheeseman and Burbidge 2016, p. 5), is central to the ability of municipalities to meet those needs. However, a lack of resources, capacity and authority often constrains the ability of municipalities to meet the needs of their cities. This is especially the case in lower income countries which often have the fastest urbanizing populations and the highest urban investment needs. Furthermore, only 4% of the 500 largest cities in developing countries have been able to access international financial markets, and only 20% can access national markets, significantly constraining their ability to make growth-driving investments (UCLG 2016). Therefore, improving the state of municipal finance will be critical for development, and is a global priority according to the Addis Abba Action Agenda (United Nations 2015b).
3.1.3 Municipal Expenditures by Region UN-Habitat’s Global Municipal Database (GMD), which includes a sample of 94 cities of over 100,000 population in 49 countries, indicates average per capita expenditures at the municipal level to be US$ 1,610 globally, with municipal investment averaging US$ 277 per capita. There are differences by region. North American municipalities have the highest expenditures per capita at US$ 3,382, with an average US$ 527 per capita in investment expenditures. This is followed by municipalities in East Asia and the Pacific, with US$ 2,521 in total expenditures per capita and US$ 457 per capita in investments. Municipalities in Sub-Saharan Africa and South Asia
3.1 Global Trends in Municipal Finance
135
3,500 3,000
US$
2,500 2,000 1,500 1,000 500 East Asia and Pacific
Europe and Central Asia
Latin America and the Caribbean
Total expenditures per capita
Middle East North America and North Africa
South Asia
Sub-Saharan Africa
Investment expenditures per capita
Fig. 3.1 Municipal expenditures per capita (total and investment), regional averages ca. 2014. Data GMD, calculations by authors
have the lowest total per capita expenditures at US$ 138 and US$ 80, respectively (Fig. 3.1).
3.1.4 Municipal Revenues by Region
3,000
1
2,500
0.8
2,000
0.6
1,500 0.4
1,000
0.2
500 -
0 Middle East East Asia and Europe and Latin Pacific Central Asia America and and North Africa the Caribbean Own source revenues per capita
North America
South Asia Sub-Saharan Africa
Percent own source revenues
Own source revenues (US$)
According to data on revenues of municipalities from the GMD, per capita revenues are highest in North America and East Asia and the Pacific, at US$ 2,755 and US$ 1,649, respectively. They are the lowest in Sub-Saharan Africa and South Asia, at US$ 77 and US$ 48, respectively. As a percentage of total municipal budgets, own source revenues follow a similar pattern, with the highest percentages in North America and East Asia and the Pacific (86% and 72%, respectively), and the lowest in Sub-Saharan Africa and South Asia (39% and 49%, respectively; Fig. 3.2).
Percent own source revenues (% of municipal budget)
Fig. 3.2 Municipal revenues per capita and as a percent of municipal budgets, regional averages ca. 2014. Data GMD, calculations by authors
136
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
3.1.5 Regional Challenges and Opportunities in Municipal Finance Trends, challenges and opportunities in municipal finance differ by country and by region. Based on the data above, municipal governments in North America and East Asia have the greatest access to resources and capacity for revenue generation, while municipal governments in Africa, the Middle East and Western Asia, and South Asia have fewer resources. Municipal governments also have differing mandates and sets of responsibilities. In the Middle East, municipal budgets tend to be low, but local investments and services are more often funded from the national level. For example, in Saudi Arabia, national ministries provide education, social services and housing, leaving municipalities with more limited roles, including issuing building permits, street lighting, solid waste management and park maintenance (UN-Habitat 2012). In Jordan, the 2007 Municipal Act shifted responsibilities toward municipal councils, but in practice, the central government has privatized many of the competences that would otherwise be responsibilities of the municipalities, and actual responsibilities are limited to solid waste management, street lighting, storm water drainage, public markets and the like (OECD and UCLG 2016). Data from UN-Habitat’s Global Municipal Database confirms that the mandated budget responsibilities of municipalities in the Middle East is much lower than other regions. Municipalities in Africa, on the other hand, have low revenues and expenditures in combination with higher than average mandated responsibilities across major expenditure categories, according to GMD data. Administrative decentralization has outpaced fiscal decentralization (Ndegwa 2002), and with low capacity for revenue generation and a frequent lack of access to external debt markets, African cities are left with unfunded mandates and the inability to close gaps in service provision (UNECA 2019). Data showing the quality of services in urban areas is one indicator of the performance of municipal finance and whether funds are sufficient to meet municipal needs. Figure 3.3 shows that Sub-Saharan Africa faces the greatest urban deficits, followed by South Asia. Cities in the Middle East and North Africa, although having smaller budgets than cities in East Asia and Latin America, do not necessarily have larger service gaps due to their smaller mandates for service provision. Access to debt markets also differs between regions. Data on outstanding bonds illustrates this point (Fig. 3.4). Within Africa, only Nigerian and South African municipalities have issued bonds. In other regions, municipal bonds are more common. Three countries stand out as having between 500 and 1000 outstanding municipal bonds: Canada, Germany and the United States. Only South Korea and China have more than 1000 outstanding municipal bonds, 1331 and 3789, respectively. The vast majority of municipal bonds are issued in domestic currency, but international municipal bods also exist in 18 mostly high-income countries, with Canada and Sweden having the most outstanding international municipal bonds.
3.1 Global Trends in Municipal Finance 0
20
137 40
60
80
100
120
East Asia and Pacific Europe and Central Asia Latin America and the Caribbean Middle East and North Africa North America South Asia Sub-Saharan Africa Access to electricity, urban (% of urban population) People using at least basic sanitation services, urban (% of urban population) People using at least basic drinking water services, urban (% of urban population)
Fig. 3.3 Urban electricity, water and sanitation by region, 2015. Data World Development Indicators
Fig. 3.4 Total number of outstanding municipal bonds (domestic and international) by country as of August 2019. Data from cbonds.com; Map by authors
To better understand major challenges and positive trends in municipal finance globally, we requested input from a set of experts in four major regions: Africa, Asia, Europe and Latin America.1 Here we synthesize their ideas on key challenges and positive trends by region.
1
The names and institutions of the independent experts who provided input can be found in the Annex to this paper.
138
3.1.5.1
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
Africa2
Challenges Decentralization in Africa is still ongoing, and in many countries has faced hurdles; decentralization of responsibilities has not been fully accompanied by fiscal decentralization. Most fundamentally, the “problem of municipal finance in Africa is the gap between financial resources and municipal expenditure needs coupled by inadequate financial systems,” (A.C. Mosha, personal communication). Associated challenges fall into four main categories: low autonomy, limited access to borrowing, low capacity, and low transparency. Low autonomy constrains the sources of revenue municipalities can access and their design. Often, these sources are low yield, inelastic, or difficult to administer. While nearly all African municipalities have the legal authority to levy taxes, many lack the ability to collect as budgeted or needed. The result is heavy reliance on central transfers, which can be unpredictable and are often inadequate to meet mandated responsibilities. Africa’s municipalities also often have limited control over their expenditures. The regional or provincial level often has more authority and implements central decisions on local issues. Limited access to borrowing constrains the ability of African municipalities ability to invest in infrastructure. Few municipalities have access to capital markets and private finance, and budgets are concentrated in expenditures on staffing. Even when borrowing is available, the persistent challenge of project preparation to create bankable investment opportunities is a barrier. The low capacity of municipal governments worsens budgetary woes, resulting in poor operational and financial management. This tends to be worse in smaller and more rural municipalities. There is a lack of understanding of available revenue tools, and a lack of clarity about often overlapping subnational government responsibilities. “Competences allocated to each level of government are well defined in the Constitutions at the regional/provincial level but are not always well defined at the municipal level,” (J. Van Geesbergen, personal communication). Understaffing and too few capacity building opportunities contribute to poor financial management. Low transparency poses a problem for municipal finance in Africa because it limits the ability of citizens to hold local governments accountable. The theoretical benefits of decentralized governance hinge on a social contract between taxpayers and those elected to respond to their needs. Currently, data on municipal finance in African cities is largely unavailable to the public. “Access to reliable data not only supports good governance and improves public trust, but it also enables for better public service delivery by improving citizen engagement and providing a data-driven basis for stronger government accountability and efficiency,” (J. Van Geesbergen, personal communication).
2
Trends related to Africa were synthesized from personal communication in July of 2019 with three municipal finance experts: Liza Rose Cirolia, Aloyisus C. Mosha, & Jennifer Van Geesbergen.
3.1 Global Trends in Municipal Finance
139
Positive Trends In spite of the setbacks, fiscal decentralization is slowly moving forward, with rising acknowledgement of the importance of municipal governance in Africa. Often decentralization is being rolled out first in an experimental phase to identify and correct problems. Against the backdrop of other positive trends in urban governance, including the increasing number of National Urban Policies and widespread democratic local elections, fiscal decentralization holds promise. The sources of revenues and finance available to African municipalities are being strengthened and broadened. There have been improvements to the design of central transfers to make them more direct, increased sharing of national taxes, and establishment of subnational development funds and funds supporting infrastructure for low income communities. Land value capture is receiving increasing attention, and there have been some successful cases of its application, including improvements to property tax administration. While creditworthiness is still far off for the majority of African municipalities, many are beginning to improve financial management and transparency in an effort to eventually gain access to borrowing. Capital market are rapidly developing, and social impact investing is newly on the rise. Some municipalities have already issued bonds backed by the central government (Cape Town, Douala), and large municipalities in some countries can borrow from banks to finance infrastructure (including municipalities in Egypt, Rwanda, South Africa and Uganda). Other municipalities have been creative in accessing finance, including through private investments and PPP, and a few are making efforts to attract FDI into major transport projects. Ongoing reforms to improve financial management have included digitalization of records and processes, which hold benefits for both efficiency and transparency. For example, in Nigeria, BudgIT, a civic startup, is increasing budget transparency by making budget information accessible to the public and designing visual representations of the data for citizens with low data literacy. There are increasing legal provisions for community participation. Citizen participation is on the rise, as is women’s representation in government. Ongoing capacity building efforts, for example, South Africa’s Cities Support Programme which aims to improve the fiscal functioning of metropolitan areas through incentives, are having positive impacts.
3.1.5.2
Asia3
Challenges Asia, like Africa, is facing rapid urbanization which requires major investments in cities. Ability to mobilize the requisite funds and fiscal gaps are therefore primary concerns for Asian municipalities. In spite of decentralization, which has been 3
Trends related to Asia were synthesized from personal communication in August of 2019 with four municipal finance experts: Niño B. Alvina, KK Pandey, Ni Pengfei and Omar Siddique.
140
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
proceeding since the 1990s, many municipalities still rely heavily on transfers, which are often insufficient for needs, resulting in unfunded mandates. This issue has arisen from unbalanced decentralization processes where responsibilities have been transferred to local governments faster than powers of revenue generation. Besides basic budgetary concerns, creditworthiness and risk are also impacted by issues of unbalanced decentralization. Among municipal governments, there is still room to improve government capacity. Moreover, improvements to the local tax system, while needed, have often not been prioritized politically. Pressing issues vary. One common issue on the revenue side is adapting to the changing process of industrialization which has been impacted by trends in global technology and trade. Municipalities must generate revenue in the context of new internet-based economic activities and an increasingly digital economy. A common issue on the expenditures side is the need to give new priority to climate change adaptation, mitigation and resilience.
Positive Trends In spite of its challenges, decentralization has had a positive impact on cities, and there have been recent improvements in the rationalization of transfers from available public funds to city governments. Decentralization has been accompanied by a number of reforms and innovations. “These reforms typically consist of policies that empower local governments through rationalizing intergovernmental flows (Philippines, etc.), strengthening own revenues (Indonesia, Sri Lanka) and using specialized financial intermediaries for small and medium city financing (Philippines, Thailand, etc.). Further, recognizing that smaller and medium cities needs are perceived as too small (high transaction costs) for direct market access, many of these emerging economies have invested in structures to pool these demands and lower risks through efficient intermediation (the Indian states of Tamilnadu, Karnataka),” (O. Siddique, personal communication). Other positive trends include increasing use of PPP and credit financing for local development, as well as innovations in land-based finance. One example is Hangzhou municipality, which transformed an existing marsh with low original value into an ecological green space and was able to capture the resulting premium on the transfer of surrounding land. Digital and ICT-based systems have also had a positive impact on municipal finance in many Asian cities, with a movement toward electronic system payments and online processes for permitting, licensing and other government functions. In addition to streamlining business processes and improving the business environment, the availability of information online has been used to improve transparency of municipal finances. For example, in the Philippines, “initiatives on public expenditure tracking are gaining ground in fiscal management reporting, thereby tracing the funds from the original source to their destination or beneficiaries, and ensuring more transparency and accountability” (N. Alvina, personal communication).
3.1 Global Trends in Municipal Finance
3.1.5.3
141
Europe4
Challenges Europe’s situation is vastly different than the developing world, but municipalities are still facing challenges and innovating. Municipalities in all regions differ depending on the economy, tax system and assignment of responsibilities, but unlike most African and Asian cities, European cities are not necessarily growing rapidly and some are even shrinking. Still, urban revitalization efforts and the changing needs of infrastructure that come with digitalization require investment. This poses challenges for municipalities facing financial bottlenecks caused by local credit limitations (for example, in Germany). Even when financing is available, the capacity to produce a pipeline of bankable projects is often lacking. Even in Europe, many municipalities face funding shortfalls with increasing expenditure needs associated with social and welfare expenses and the investments needed to compete. European cities are also challenged in their ability to align their allocation of expenditures and investments to global sustainability objectives, such as implementing the SDGs and complying with climate change mitigation policies.
Positive Trends Positive trends for municipal finance in Europe include an increased awareness of the important and massive role that cities play in national infrastructure, as well as successes in controlling expenditures, and changes to tax systems. For example, Germany has generated low property tax revenues in comparison with other OECD countries due to valuations that failed to keep up with market prices, but the country is now introducing a new property tax valuation system to correct this. European municipalities are also drawing on the private sector, including through PPP and participation of volunteers in municipal projects. There are also major positive trends in terms of green finance and environmentally beneficial investments. Municipalities and institutional investors “are starting to see climate change mitigation and adaptation as part of their fiduciary duty, and some trends such as green bonds and improved reporting are demonstrating this slow trend towards better ESG [environmental, social and governance criteria] awareness” (L. Downing, personal communication). Nature-based solutions, which can bring environmental and social co-benefits are gaining traction, and tools like the SuRe® standard are being used by municipalities to improve infrastructure investments in terms of their impact on environmental sustainability and resilience. City alliances are also helping move municipal investments toward sustainability. For example, the Cities Climate Finance Leadership Alliance (CCFLA) is a platform to facilitate knowledge sharing and partnerships which impacts cities within and outside of Europe. 4
Trends related to Europe were synthesized from personal communication in July of 2019 with three municipal finance experts: Louis Downing, Pablo Nunez & Chang Woon Nam.
142
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
Latin America Challenges Latin America and the Caribbean is not different to other regions in terms in terms of municipal finance, though municipalities and cities have more capacity than in Africa, the potential for land value finance and Public private Partnership to finance local infrastructure is still limited by lack of technical expertise and absence of appropriate legal framework.
Positive Trends Decentralization has been implemented in the region and though, as indicated by expenditures and revenues and by subnational indicators (Martinez-Vasquez 2011), though those indicators shows variations among cities and countries (according to the GMD). The strengthening of regional or national developing banks supporting local infrastructure is also remarkable, these are the experience of Findeter in Colombia, Banobras in Mexico, and Caixa in Brazil., but more efforts are needed to increase the supply of resources available for local infrastructure.
3.1.6 Conclusions The overview of municipal finance synthesized from experts in the field reveals some common challenges and shared positive trends across regions. Municipal governments in all regions are challenged to find the resources and sources of finance for needed investments. Developing bankable projects is also a common challenge for municipal leaders. Climate change adaptation, mitigation and resilience are both a challenge and an emerging area of opportunity. Climate finance and green infrastructure innovations are positive developments across regions. Social impact investors and volunteers are another emerging trend that promises to leverage socially motivated actors to support the important efforts of municipal governments. In terms of financial management and transparency, digitalization is becoming more widespread, and improving access to information as well as the business environment. Importantly, there is growing global awareness of the role cities play in national economies and the investment landscape, which is contributing to increased support for improving their financial situation. There are also major differences between regions when it comes to municipal finance trends. Municipalities in Africa are the most stretched, having low per capita budgets and accounting for low shares of public revenues and expenditures while at the same time being assigned a rising share of responsibilities often without the needed increase in transfers to tackle them. African municipalities are the most heavily reliant on national transfers, and have low financial autonomy and capacity
3.1 Global Trends in Municipal Finance
143
to change their situation. However, decentralization is proceeding with the acknowledgement of the important role of cities, and there are efforts across the continent to improve creditworthiness, land value capture, budget transparency and basic financial management. Decentralization is also proceeding in Asia, with some challenges related to the transfer of responsibilities without adequate powers to fund them, but with many positive developments in terms of revenue generation, improved transfers systems, and pooled finance for smaller municipalities. Nimble adaptation to new economic and environmental trends is a challenge for Asian municipalities, but also a source of potential innovation. In Latin America and the Caribbean, progress in decentralization is improving and uneven, more efforts are needed to expand own source revenues based on land assets and land value capture that can propel revenue by property taxes and better management of public assets. European municipalities are not without challenges, but their challenges are different. They face often lower rates of population growth or even shrinkage, and must strategically orient their public expenditures to respond to changing technology to remain competitive. European municipalities are finding innovative ways to tackle dual environmental and social aims through green standards and collaborative mechanisms that facilitate smart investments. In an urbanizing world, the pressing issues of municipal finance are growing in importance. Strategically addressing the challenges and building upon the positive trends will be central to the competitiveness of cities globally.
3.1.7 Annex: Municipal Finance Experts The following people provided input for their specified global region: Africa: Liza Rose Cirolia, African Centre for Cities, University of Cape Town Aloyisus C. Mosha, BaIsago University, Gaborone, Botswana Jennifer Van Geesbergen, Independent Consultant at the Centre for African Cities Asia: Niño B. Alvina, Bureau of Local Government Finance (BLGF), Department of Finance, The Philippines Professor KK Pandey Ni Pengfei, Director of Center for City and Competitiveness, Chinese Academy of Social Sciences (CASS) Omar Siddique, Economic Affairs Officer, Sustainable Urban Development, United Nations Economic and Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific (UNESCAP)
144
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
Europe: Louis Downing, Global Infrastructure Basel Foundation Pablo Nunez, Global Infrastructure Basel Foundation Chang Woon Nam, ifo Institute Munich and University of Applied Management Ismaning Latin America: Martim O. Smolka Lincoln Institute of Land Policy
3.2 Municipal Finance, Localization of the SDGs and the Role of UCLG Figures are well-known. According to United Nations estimates, over the next 30 years, the world’s urban population is expected to increase by more than 2.5 billion reaching almost 6.5 billion people by 2050. More than 90% of this growth will be in African and Asian countries - China, India and Nigeria accounting for more than a third of the expected urban growth.5 In Africa, where urban growth is 1.5 times faster than in the rest of the world, the urban population is expected to triple to more than 1.2 billion by 2050. 75% of this growth will be concentrated in intermediary cities.6 In 2014, the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development estimated that achieving the Sustainable Development Goals would require an investment of USD 5 to 7 trillion per year by 2030, including about USD 2.5 trillion for the developing countries alone. In cities, the Cities Climate Finance Leadership Alliance estimates that global demand for low-emission, climate resilient urban infrastructure would average $5 trillion per year.7 The numbers may seem considerable (2.5 trillion USD represents roughly the total GDP of Africa today), but 5-7 trillion USD represents only about 5% of today’s world GDP in current PPP dollars and about 20% of the global savings available.8 And let us not forget either that if the necessary investments are not made to accommodate the expected urban growth, retrofitting, i.e. ex-post action to provide cities with the necessary infrastructure and facilities in response to laissez-faire, would be 3 to 9 times more expensive in Africa, according to the research conducted by Cities Alliance under the Future Cities Africa Program. Finally, let us recall that a study conducted by Cities Alliance in 2016 showed that 65% of the targets defined in the SDGs have a primarily local dimension. Specifically, “21% of the 169 targets can only be implemented with local stakeholders, 24% should
5
UNDESA, Revision of World Urbanisation Prospects, 2018 UN Habitat, State of African Cities, 2014. 7 Cities Climate Finance Leadership Alliance, The State of City Climate Finance 2015. See also UCLG (2016) GOLD IV: Co-Creating the Urban Future. 8 According to World Bank estimates, World GDP, in current PPP dollars, amounted to $136.4 trillion in 2018. 6
3.2 Municipal Finance, Localization of the SDGs and the Role of UCLG
145
be implemented with local actors and a further 20% should have a much clearer orientation towards local urban actors”.9 These few figures, briefly summarized here, show that the Sustainable Development Goals set by the international community in 2015 cannot be achieved without determined and far-reaching financial efforts in terms of capital investment. They also stress that cities must concentrate a significant part of these efforts, as illustrated by the establishment of a specific objective—SDG 11 for sustainable cities and communities—among the 17 SDGs and the adoption in Quito in 2016 of the New Urban Agenda. By stressing the importance of action at the local level, these figures finally show how much the role of local governments in development processes must be affirmed and strengthened. This last point poses many challenges. It refers to the decentralization processes implemented in countries and the sharing of powers and competences between national and local governments in public action. While decentralization processes have made significant progress in most countries of the world over the past three or four decades, situations remain extremely contrasting with regard to the political and institutional leeway given to local governments to truly assume ownership of development projects in their territories, particularly in emerging economies and the least developed countries of Asia and Africa where the needs are most acute. In these countries in particular, enhancing the role of local governments in public action also requires considerable efforts in structuring their institutional organisation and strengthening their planning and management capacities so that they can fully fulfil the missions they are expected to perform. Finally, it is crucial that they have the financial means and power to act. The issue of municipal finances is clearly a key element and that is the aspect we will develop here. Measured in terms of local finances, what can we say today about the role played by local governments in public action? What are the main challenges to be met in this regard and how is UCLG, the global platform representing local governments, working to meet them?
3.2.1 Municipal Finance: Contrasting Situations Rround the World The World Observatory on Subnational Government Finance and Investment,10 jointly set up by the OECD and UCLG, recently published its 2019 report. The report provides detailed information on the structure and organization of local governments, their main responsibilities, the nature and weight of their expenditures, revenues and
9
Misselwitz, P., & Salcedo Villanueva, J. (2015). The urban dimension of the SDGs: Implications for the New Urban Agenda. In Sustainable Development Goals and Habitat III: Opportunities for a successful New Urban Agenda (pp. 13–22). Brussels. Cities Alliance. 10 www.sng-wofi.org
146
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
debt in more than 120 countries, including 23 of the 47 least developed countries. The figures presented below are taken from the Observatory’s report and database.
3.2.2 Local Government Expenditure: Significant Differences Between High-Income and Low Income Countries In 2016, local government expenditure represented 24.1% of total public expenditure and 8.6% of GDP on an unweighted average, or US$2,505 PPP/capita for the 106 countries for which data could be collected by the Observatory. But these percentages show wide disparities between countries and regions of the world. For example, local governments’ expenditure in OECD countries averages US$5,890 PPP / capita, or 31.8% of total public expenditure and 13.4% of GDP, while it only reaches US$285 PPP / capita, or 15.7% of total public expenditure and 4% of GDP in Africa. The situation is more diversified in the Asia-Pacific region: countries such as China, India, Indonesia or Vietnam have percentages of local government expenditure as a proportion of total public expenditure equal to or greater than 50% and weights in GDP comparable to the OECD average, while the region’s least developed countries have percentages that are broadly equal to African averages. These disparities between countries and regions are often also compounded by significant fiscal imbalances within countries between metropolitan areas and intermediary cities, and between regions (Fig. 3.5). Staff costs are the most significant expense item of local governments worldwide. They represent on average 36.1% of their total expenditure, this percentage being more or less the same in all regions of the world. But very clear differences appear again when we consider the weight of this expenditure in total public staff costs: local governments’ staff costs account on average for 50.2% of total public staff costs in OECD countries, but this percentage is only 18.7% in Africa (Fig. 3.6). 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0
33.8
31.8 26.2 13.4
18.3
15.7
12
8.5
7.9
4 OECD
EU 28
24.1
22.7
Africa
% of GDP
Asia Pacific (excl. OECD)
6
8.6
Euro Asia, Latin America Total West Asia & (106 countries) Middle East
% of public expenditure
Fig. 3.5 Local Government expenditure as a share of GDP and total public expenditure 2016. Source World Observatory on Subnational Government Finance and Investment, Database, 2019
3.2 Municipal Finance, Localization of the SDGs and the Role of UCLG 60
147
50.2
50
42.3 36.6
40
34.7
27.5
30
23.7
18.7
20 10 0 OECD
EU 28
Africa
Asia Pacific (excl. OECD)
Euro Asia, West Asia & Middle East
Latin America
Total
Fig. 3.6 Share of Local Government staff costs in total public staff costs 2016. Source World Observatory on Subnational Government Finance and Investment, Database, 2019
The institutional nature of the country (federal/unitary) does not have a significant impact on this average. However, it is important to note that in federal countries, staff expenditure is higher at the state level (62% on world average for federations) than at the municipal level where human resources remain, in general, lower. Similarly, while local governments play a major role in public investment in most middle- and high-income countries - on average they account for almost 50% of public capital investment in OECD countries, almost 40% in Latin American countries - this role is much more limited in African countries or Asian least developed countries where this percentage is below 20%. That being said, in general, public investment by local governments represents only a modest share of GDP: 1.3% on average in the world, less than 1% in Africa (Fig. 3.7). Overall, as we can see, local governments around the world play a relatively significant role in public spending. Nevertheless, large gaps remain in this regard between high-income and least developed countries. Measured as a percentage, these gaps are on average in the order of 1 to 2, even 1 to 3; measured in absolute figures (in PPP US$), they reach 1 to 20 and show, were it necessary, how extremely modest the role of local governments in public action in the latter countries remains, especially in Africa and Asia, where the pace of urbanization would require a much more proactive presence. Total
1.3
Latin America
1.5
Euro Asia, West Asia & Middle East
1.2
Asia Pacific (excl. OECD)
36.6 39.3 37.3 32.8
1.6
Africa
0.9
EU 28
1.2
OECD
1.4 0
19.4 39.7 46.6 5
10
15
% of public investment
20
25
30
35
40
45
50
% of GDP
Fig. 3.7 Local Government investment as a share of GDP and total public investment 2016. Source World Observatory on Subnational Government Finance and Investment, Database, 2019
148
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
3.2.3 Local Government Revenues: Very Limited Autonomy in Most Developing Countries Local government revenues represent 25.7% of total public revenues and 8.6% of GDP on an unweighted average in the 104 countries where data could be collected by the Observatory. The differences between the various countries and regions of the world reflect the observed differences in spending: the weight of income is very modest in lower middle-income countries and the least developed countries in Africa and Asia compared to OECD or EU 28 countries. Grants and subsidies from national governments make up a little more than 50% of these revenues - they vary on average from 48.9% in OECD countries to 57.6% in African countries; the rest of local governments’ revenues, representing own resources, being composed of taxes - 33% on average - and user charges and fees—about 9% (Fig. 3.8). The analysis of the nature of income shows extremely diverse situations between countries in the different regions of the world, which refer to the histories and current contexts of the decentralization processes specific to each country (Figs. 3.9 and 3.10). For instance, in Asia Pacific countries (excluding OECD countries), national government grants and subsidies represent 70% or more of local government resources in Indonesia, Sri Lanka or the Philippines and only around 20% in India, Malaysia or Cambodia. Similarly, in Africa, national government grants and subsidies represent 90% of local government revenues in Kenya, Tanzania and Rwanda, up to 96% in Uganda, around 25% in Senegal, Namibia and Eswatini, and barely 4% in Zimbabwe. Similar situations can be found in Latin America, where the income of local governments in Peru or Mexico depends on more than 90% of central government grants and subsidies, compared to 15% in Costa Rica or 3% in Argentina. The extreme dependence of local governments on state allocations is a sign of the very limited power they are given to collect their own revenues and, often combined Total (104 countries)
50.3
Latin America
49.7
53.7
Euro Asia, West Asia & Middle East
46.3
40.6
Asia Pacific (excl. OECD)
59.4 49.6
Africa
50.4 57.6
EU 28
42.4
54.4
OECD
45.6
48.9 0%
10%
20%
30%
Grants and subsidies
40%
51.1 50%
60%
70%
80%
90% 100%
Own Revenues
Fig. 3.8 Local Government Revenues 2016. Source World Observatory on Subnational Government Finance and Investment, Database 2019
3.2 Municipal Finance, Localization of the SDGs and the Role of UCLG 100.0 90.0 80.0 70.0 60.0 50.0 40.0 30.0 20.0 10.0 0.0
7.6
92.4
7.5
92.5
3.7
5.6 28.8
23.4
71.2
76.6
Azerbaijan
96.3
94.4
Mexico
Malta
Uganda
Sri Lanka
OECD
EU 28
Africa
Asia Pacific (excl. OECD)
Grants & subsidies
149
Peru
Euro Asia, Latin America West Asia & Middle East
Own-revenue
Fig. 3.9 Top countries most dependent on grants and subsidies across regions 2016. Source World Observatory on Subnational Government Finance and Investment, Database, 2019
100.0 80.0 60.0
89.0
73.6 96.3
80.8 98.7
97.3
1.3 Jordan
2.7 Argentina
40.0 20.0 0.0
11.0
26.4
Iceland
Germany
3.7 Zimbabwe
OECD
EU 28
Africa Grants & subsidies
19.2 Malaysia
Asia Pacific (excl. Euro Asia, West OECD) Asia & Middle East Own-revenue
Latin America
Fig. 3.10 Top countries with the highest rate of own revenues across regions 2016. Source World Observatory on Subnational Government Finance and Investment, Database, 2019
with the irregularity and poor transparency of transfers, is a considerable obstacle to the exercise of their responsibilities and their ability to act. At the other extreme, the low weight of transfers and the importance of taxes (which is only in rare cases accompanied by the power to set their base and rates) can be interpreted as a lack of concern to redistribute public income to local governments and therefore as a limited consideration that national governments give to the role of local governments in public action. Certainly, situations must be analysed on a case-by-case basis and hasty interpretations must be avoided. In many countries, in Africa and Asia, decentralization has made significant progress in recent years.11 Nevertheless, it must be 11
For Africa, see UCLGA & Cities Alliance, Assessing the Institutional Environment of Local Governments in Africa, 2018, 3rd Edition. For Asia, see UCLG ASPAC, Cities Alliance and UNDP, City Enabling Environment Rating: Assessment of the countries in Asia and the Pacific, 2018.
150
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
recognized that the increase, but also the issue of stability and predictability of local government resources, remains one of the major challenges facing the developing world. And that a significant part of the solution certainly lies in strengthening the autonomy of local governments in terms of access to income.
3.2.4 Local Government Debt: Almost no Access to Debt in Low-Income Countries The debt of local governments represents 7.5% of GDP and 11.5% of total public debt in the 76 countries where data could be collected by the Observatory (Fig. 3.11). Again on this point, there are considerable differences between regions and countries. The debt of local governments represents 13% of GDP and almost 17% of total public debt on average in OECD countries (8.4% and 11.7% respectively in EU 28): it reaches up to 67% of GDP and 59% of total debt in Canada and represents more than 20% of GDP in countries such as Belgium, Germany, Spain, Switzerland, the USA or Japan and more than 20% of total public debt in Germany, Spain, Switzerland, Australia, the USA, Estonia and northern European countries such as Finland, Norway and Sweden. Conversely, it is almost nil in most African countries except South Africa and Nigeria (where it represents 4.8% and 2.9% of GDP and 9.4% and 21.2% of total public debt respectively) and in non-OECD Asia-Pacific countries where, except China and India where it reaches significant percentages (21% of GDP and 47% and 30% respectively of total public debt), it represents on average only 0.7% of GDP and 1.4% of total public debt. The inability of local governments to access financial markets in the vast majority of low-income countries has multiple causes, ranging from drastic constraints or even the prohibition of local governments from taking out loans under national legislation, and the precarious and unstable financial situation of local governments offering insufficient repayment guarantees to credit institutions, to the poor technical and Total (76 countries)
11.8
7.6
Latin America
10.4
3.5
Africa (excl. South Africa and Nigeria) Africa
0.4 0.8 1.3
Asia Pacific (excl OECD, China & India) Asia Pacific (excl. OECD)
0.7 1.4
4.4 10.6
5.7
Euro Asia, West Asia & Middle East
6.6
1.7
EU 28
11.7
8.4
OECD
16.9
13
0
2
4
% of public debt
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
% of GDP
Fig. 3.11 Local Government debt as a share of GDP and total public debt 2016. Source World Observatory on Subnational Government Finance and Investment, Database, 2019
3.2 Municipal Finance, Localization of the SDGs and the Role of UCLG
151
financial quality of projects that could be submitted for financing. Combined with their very limited income, these structural limitations in access to private financing constitute a major obstacle to the investment capacity of local governments. By limiting the ability of local governments to provide infrastructure, equipment and services, these constraints in turn limit their ability to generate their own income (via taxes and duties) and, in a sort of vicious circle, perpetuate their relegation.
3.2.5 UCLG and the Issue of Local Finances: A Renewed Strategy Drawing on a Longstanding Engagement From the very first years of its creation in 2004, UCLG, the global network of cities and local, metropolitan and regional governments, has made the issue of municipal finance a key dimension of its action agenda. A Committee on Local Finance and Development bringing together more than 40 mayors and representatives of national associations of local governments was set up in 2005. In a UCLG Policy Paper on Local Finance12 published in 2007, the Committee identified the financing needs of urbanization, proposed a set of recommendations to strengthen the financial power of local governments to meet the related challenges and outlined a roadmap for UCLG’s support action. In 2010, UCLG’s second Global Report of the Observatory on Decentralisation and Local Democracy—Gold II, was devoted to Local Government Finance: The Challenges of the 21st Century. The report provides an in-depth analysis of the fiscal decentralisation architecture in more than 110 countries.13 In 2016, a first pilot report of the Global Observatory on Local Finances, Subnational Governments around the world - Structure and Finance, prepared in partnership with the OECD, was a major step forward in engaging local governments and their association in the production of reliable, harmonised and comparable data on subnational government finance.14 All this effort, combined with advocacy activities carried out within the framework of the Global Task Force of Local and Regional Governments facilitated by UCLG, has contributed significantly to the international community’s thinking and positions on the role of cities and local governments in global development agendas. They have made it possible to inform and monitor the evolution of the institutional and financial environment of the Addis Ababa Action Agenda on Financing for Development Article 34 which stresses the importance of financing at sub-national level,15 or the specific financial aspects of the implementation of the New Urban Agenda.16
12
UCLG, Policy Paper on Local Finance, 2007. UCLG, Local Government Finance : The Challenges of the 21st Century, Gold II, 2010. 14 UCLG, OECD, AFD, Subnational Governments around the World—Structure and Finance. A first contribution to the Global Observatory on Local Finances, 2016. 15 United Nations, Addis Ababa Action Agenda—Financing for Development, 2015. 16 See Habitat III Policy Paper, 5—Municipal Finance and Local Finance Systems, 2016. 13
152
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
Moreover, in 2016, at its World Congress in Bogota, UCLG adopted a mediumterm strategy for 2016-202217 that places the “localisation” of the global development agendas at the heart of its action. The strategy calls for renewed public action, whose “model must be built from the territories and within the framework of a renewed dialogue across the different spheres of government”. The renewal of the “Cities and Territories Financing Model” is a cornerstone of the Bogota Commitment and has led to the development of a specific strategy on “Localising Financing in Support of Sustainable Urbanisation” which was adopted by the organisation’s Executive Bureau at its meeting in Strasbourg in May 2018. In close collaboration with the Global Fund for Cities Development (FMDV), which is now an integral part of UCLG, this “localisation of financing” strategy is gradually being implemented. Today, it structures UCLG’s action on the issue. The strategy for localising financing in support of sustainable urbanization has four main dimensions that relate to the four strategic modalities of action developed by UCLG to place local governments at the heart of the implementation of global agendas: information, monitoring and reporting; advocacy and awareness-raising; learning; and implementation.
3.2.6 Information, Monitoring and Reporting: The World Observatory on Local Government Finance and Investment The production and availability of information and data on local finances are essential prerequisites for action. In many countries, particularly the least developed countries, despite the existence of legal frameworks requiring financial documentation to be made public, problems related to data availability are prevalent. In particular, subnational budget data are often not publicly available, incomplete, unconsolidated or outdated. Accurate situational understanding is a key element in helping to make the case for proposing solutions for change on an informed basis. Moreover, the dissemination and public availability of this information is a necessary condition for public debate between all relevant stakeholders. Without clear, reliable and transparent information, it is unlikely that any recommendations for action can be produced that are both collectively designed and evidence-based. Box 1 Open-Government and Budget Transparency In recent years, an increasing number of local and regional governments around the world have been engaged in advancing reforms in line with the principles of open government by incorporating this new governance model into their administrations’
17
UCLG, Strategic priorities 2016-2022.
3.2 Municipal Finance, Localization of the SDGs and the Role of UCLG
153
and political agendas. They are developing new tools and solutions to facilitate access to local information and engage citizens, civic organizations and the private sector as strategic partners with whom to work towards achieving more effective and accountable local institutions. In Aragon (Spain), innovative solutions have been introduced to reduce administrative costs in the short term and gain trust and democratic legitimacy in the longer term. In Tshwane (South Africa), the city government promotes the use of open data and new technologies to improve the quality of and access to public services. Lastly, Montevideo (Uruguay) was one of the pioneers in Latin America in developing an open data strategy. Its local government later collaborated with Uruguay’s Electronic Government and Information Society Agency to define the 2018-2020 Open Government National Action Plan.
This is the objective of the World Observatory on Subnational Government Finance and Investment. A joint initiative of UCLG and the OECD, with the support of a range of partners including UNCDF, the French Development Agency, the Council of Europe Development Bank and the DeLog network, this observatory offers a unique database providing standardised and comparable information on multi-level governance and municipal finance in over 120 countries. Some of the data from this Observatory has been presented in the first part of this article and we see how useful they can be in assessing the diversity of situations in the world and in informing thinking on the evolution of national policies in this field. Each of the 120 + country fact sheets that the Observatory has collected also provides detailed qualitative information and comments on country-specific situations that constitute a major source of knowledge and possible cross learning opportunities.
3.2.7 Advocacy and Awareness-Raising: The Malaga Global Coalition for Municipal Finance Advocacy and awareness-raising on the international scene have been a structuring dimension of UCLG’s strategy on local finance since the beginning. Following the adoption of the Addis Ababa Action Agenda on Financing for Development, UCLG has been consistently involved in ensuring that the voice of local governments is heard at the conferences convened annually by the United Nations to monitor the implementation of the Agenda. Progress was achieved in 2018, in connection with the review of SDG 11 by the High Level Political Forum. Nonetheless, the 2019 report of the Inter Agency Task Force on Financing for Development, focusing on national financing strategies for the different development agendas, did not fully take into account the ‘missing link’: local public finance. The adoption of the UCLG strategy on local finance led to a new initiative in this regard: the establishment of the Malaga Global Coalition for Municipal Finance.
154
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
Punctuated by an annual event, first held in April 201818 and then in October 2019 in Malaga (Spain), at the invitation of the Mayor of the city, the Malaga Global Coalition for Municipal Finance aims to advocate for structural changes in the global financial ecosystem to make it more favorable to cities and local governments. Promoted by UNCDF and UCLG with the support of FMDV, in close collaboration with Cities Alliance and UN Habitat, the coalition is designed as a platform for dialogue between mayors and national associations of local governments and their political and institutional partners: national governments, the private sector, bilateral and multilateral cooperation organizations, development banks and international financial institutions. Its objective is to promote public policy objectives that facilitate and strengthen access to finance for local governments. It is intended to consolidate advocacy work by developing a shared rationale for the changes needed in the institutional environment for local governments to take action in a more effective way. A rationale in which fiscal decentralization is no longer seen as a zero-sum game in which states lose what local governments win, but rather as a win-win process for all, in the interest of achieving sustainable development.
3.2.8 Mutual Learning: The Establishment of a Community of Practice Established and convened for the first time in Madrid, at the UCLG Executive Bureau in November 2018, the Community of Practice is a follow-up to the city exchange and networking initiatives that were initially initiated under the Committee on Local Finance and Development. Complementary to the professional networks and facilitation work carried out by UCLG’s regional sections—the network of African City Chief Financial Officers led by UCLG Africa, the network of experts on local finance led by CEMR or the dialogue initiative on metropolitan finance led by Metropolis for example—the main objective of the Community of Practice is to provide a forum for sharing experiences and mutual learning on innovative practices developed by cities on local finance. On this basis, it is also intended to contribute to advocacy work by helping to structure positions and recommendations on the localisation of financing to be carried out on the global stage, and more generally to guide the implementation and monitoring of UCLG’s strategy on the localisation of financing as a whole. The Community of Practice is conceived as a space for dialogue, intended to meet in a flexible way, on the initiative of cities or partners wishing to exchange on their practices to inform and enrich future action. At the time of writing, two meetings of the Community of Practice are scheduled, one on the initiative of the City of Paris in October 2019 to discuss the fiscal and regulatory tools that cities have put in place to fight against the financialisation of housing, the other, led by the South 18
See https://www.uclg.org/en/media/news/uclg-co-organized-high-level-policy-dialogue-transf orm-municipal-finance-malaga.
3.2 Municipal Finance, Localization of the SDGs and the Role of UCLG
155
African Association of Local Governments (SALGA), with the support of the African Development Bank, at the UCLG World Congress in Durban in November 2019, to discuss the role of national and international development finance institutions in supporting cities’ access to financial markets. Box 2 Generating municipal revenues for capital investment: The potential of land value capture In and around growing cities, development rights can be powerful levers for financing infrastructure. As is the case in Chinese cities, land-based financing—particularly land leasing to property developers—can be a major source of revenue for city governments. It includes selling development rights and permissions to land-owners or the increase in densities or change in land uses. Capturing a share of the increasing value of urban land is a political rather than technical process. This appears clearly from an analysis of experiences in Africa (Addis Ababa, Harare and Nairobi) or Latin America (Bogota, Medellin, São Paulo and Rosario) where a wide range of urban development instruments have been developed to generate revenues to help finance infrastructure and social housing in areas with scarce public services, as well as for public works in general.
3.2.9 Implementation: The launch of the Africa Territorial Agency and the Creation of the International Municipal Investment Fund The investments required to provide cities with the infrastructure and equipment necessary for their development are, as we have seen, considerable. According to the IMF, additional annual capital spending to achieve the 2030 Agenda in 121 emerging market economies and low-income developing countries would amount to 2.6 trillion US dollars (2.5 percent of the 2030 world GDP). Looking at the region-by-region investment gap, the Asia-Pacific region has the largest global additional spending requirement, estimated at 1.5 percent of 2030 world GDP. Sub-Saharan Africa has the second largest additional spending requirement, estimated at 0.4 percent of 2030 world GDP.19 The resources cities can now mobilize for these purposes on the basis of their resources are very limited. Official development assistance (around USD 147 billion
19
IMF, Fiscal Policy and Development: Human, Social, and Physical Investment for the SDGs, 2019.
156
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
in 201720 ) or migrant remittances (USD 529 billion in 201821 ) contribute to investment efforts but are far from sufficient. One of the major challenges facing cities in many rapidly urbanising countries today, particularly in Africa and Asia, is their access to capital markets to finance such infrastructure and facilities. It is on this theme that UCLG has chosen to take concrete action by launching two initiatives, one in Africa and the other at the global level. In Africa, the Africa Territorial Agency, inspired by the experience of Agence France Locale, aims to set up a cooperative fund financed by an initial investment from the continent’s main cities (initially some twenty cities) to raise additional resources from financial institutions and capital markets to finance their investments. A call for expressions of interest was launched by UCLG Africa in January 2019 to mobilise a first group of cities and local governments to be its founding members. At the global level, UCLG, in collaboration with the FMDV and in partnership with UNCDF, is currently setting up an International Municipal Investment Fund. In a first pilot phase, the Fund aims to support investment projects in around ten cities. It will offer technical assistance to finalize the project preparation, provide the necessary support for the city to meet the conditions for access to financial markets, support the financing of the project with a loan in local currency up to 30% of its cost and help the city to mobilize the remaining necessary financing through development financial institutions and on private capital markets. In a context of expanding and increasingly mature financial markets, these two initiatives aim to help bridge the gap between cities’ investment needs and their access to these markets. They want to show that it is possible for cities to mobilize private reimbursable resources to finance their development, set examples and learn from them to trigger a virtuous dynamic of transformational change. At the heart of the global development agendas, the urban issue is a key challenge. Financing cities, especially the upcoming urban explosion in African and Asian countries, requires bold action by all actors at all levels. Meeting the considerable challenges of providing the necessary infrastructure, equipment and services requires giving local governments real power to act. The inequalities in access to resources that we observe today from one country to another, and from one city to another, must be brought to light on the international scene and at national levels to be discussed, fought and remedied. The experience of local governments must be disseminated and shared. Increased funding and innovation in resource access mechanisms are essential. This is what UCLG, the global voice of local governments, intends to contribute to. This is what the international community and all spheres of government must address in a determined manner if we are to achieve the compelling objectives of the New Urban Agenda and the 2030 Agenda for Sustainable Development over the next ten years.
20
See https://www.oecd.org/newsroom/development-aid-stable-in-2017-with-more-sent-to-poo rest-countries.htm. 21 See https://www.worldbank.org/en/news/press-release/2019/04/08/record-high-remittancessent-globally-in-2018.
3.3 Subnational Finance in Latin American and the Caribbean: Recent …
157
Fig. 3.12 Public expenditure: subnational government as a percentage of total government. Source Eguino H and Radics A [2018]
3.3 Subnational Finance in Latin American and the Caribbean: Recent Trends and Challenges 3.3.1 Evolution of the Decentralization and Subnational Finance The decentralization process in the Latin American and Caribbean (LAC) countries has gathered momentum since the 1980s. As a result, subnational governments22 have become increasingly important in the provision of public goods and services that are critical for economic and social development. In fact, the subnational governments’ share of consolidated public expenditures almost doubled between 1985 and 2010, from 13 to 25%, and it has remained at this level up to the present time (2015) (see Fig. 3.12). Political decentralization has followed a similar path: since 1997, municipal mayors in all LAC countries have been elected by popular vote, whereas in 1980 this was the case in only six countries.23 Practically all LAC countries have made efforts over the past three decades to bring government closer to the citizens through greater decentralization to subnational governments and/or territorial deconcentration of the central government. The motives behind fiscal decentralization have been diverse and, in certain cases, concurrent. They include democratization, which created demands for greater political and fiscal autonomy at the subnational level (Arzaghi and Henderson 2005); the economic crisis of the 1980s, which led some countries to transfer spending functions to subnational governments within a context of structural adjustment (Rezende and Veloso 2012); and second-generation institutional reforms, particularly since the mid-1990s, which transferred responsibilities to subnational governments in an effort to make the
22
The paper uses the term “Subnational Governments” to refer both to the intermediate level of government and the municipal level. The intermediate level includes: States in México and Argentina, Provinces in Argentina and Departments in the rest of the region. 23 There are no municipal mayors in Barbados or Suriname as this level of government does not exist.
158
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
public sector more efficient (Lora 2007)24 (IDB, 2018). An important contributing factor in the growth of subnational expenditures during the first decade of this century was the boom in the extractive industries, primarily mining and hydrocarbons, which boosted transfers of tax revenue from these industries to subnational governments (ECLAC 2012). These transfers are characterized by high levels of volatility, which are directly associated with changes in international prices for natural resources. Average spending by subnational governments in LAC conceals pronounced differences among countries based on historical patterns and economic, population, and geographical size.25 While more than 40% of consolidated expenditures in Brazil and Argentina were executed at the subnational level in 2015, the equivalent figure in Costa Rica, Honduras or Panamá was below 5% (see Fig. 3.13).26 In general, the countries of the region can be classified into three main groups: (i) federal, such as Argentina, Brazil, and Mexico; (ii) unitary with a high level of decentralization (above 30%), such as Bolivia, Colombia, Ecuador, and Peru; and (iii) unitary with a low levels of decentralization, such as Guatemala, Chile, Paraguay, Uruguay, and the Central American and Caribbean nations.27 LAC has roughly 17,500 subnational governments offering a variety of public management capacities. Of this total, 2% falls into the intermediate level of government, the rest are municipal governments (see Table 3.1).28 The intermediate level has greater relevance with respect to the delivery of services in the region’s largest countries, particularly in Argentina and Brazil, which have significant own-source revenues.29 In the rest of the countries of the region, the delivery of subnational services is primarily the responsibility of municipal governments. The subnational level of government is highly diverse, with differences not only among but also within countries. This is particularly pronounced at the municipal level. LAC is an increasingly urban region, with eight out of every ten inhabitants residing in cities. However, just 11% of municipalities in the region—all of them urban—account for more than two thirds of the entire population, while roughly 24
For the more structural determinants of fiscal decentralization (e.g. geography), see Canavire et al. (2016). 25 The size of the subnational public sector tends to be greater in larger countries, yet subnational governments in small countries perform essential government functions for the well-being of the population. 26 For a comparative examination of the size, structure, and financing of subnational governments worldwide, see OECD/United Cities and Municipal government (2016). 27 Under a federal system, the constitution guarantees the permanence and independence of subnational governments and grants them their own legislative, executive, and judicial powers. Under a unitary system, subnational governments usually lack constitutional sovereignty, and the central government determines which decision-making powers are devolved to them. Both concepts are ideals in a continuum within which countries are classified on the basis of the constitutional sovereignty granted to subnational governments (Britannica 2014). 28 In six of the region’s countries there are two levels of municipal government, and in Haiti there are three. 29 Bolivia, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Peru, and Venezuela are examples of other countries where intermediate governments are responsible for important subnational services, despite being highly dependent on central government transfers.
3.3 Subnational Finance in Latin American and the Caribbean: Recent …
159
Fig. 3.13 Subnational government as % of total government (circa 2015). Source Sector Framework Document of Fiscal Decentralization and Subnational Governments [IDB 2018]
50% of municipal governments have less than 10,000 inhabitants each (Eguino et al. 2010). This reality poses challenges not only for urban municipalities, which manage services that must be coordinated with other subnational entities, but also for rural areas, where most municipalities are concentrated, and which have small populations and limited administrative capacity (Martínez-Vázquez 2010).30 Most municipalities are responsible for services that include garbage collection and street sweeping and cleaning; local transportation; maintenance of parks and gardens; public lighting; and the issuance of construction and operating licenses (Eguino et al. 2010). In addition, both municipalities and intermediate-level governments (if any) carry out public investment projects in sectors such as roads and transportation, water and sanitation, productive infrastructure, tourism, health, and education, and are subsequently responsible for the operation and maintenance of these projects.31 In fact, the share of subnational governments in the execution of public investment has grown over the past decade in several countries in the region, and now exceeds 50% of consolidated public investment in some countries (see Table 3.2).
30
The number of municipalities has proliferated in some countries, partly due to the incentive of a guaranteed minimum level of transfers. This has been the case in the Dominican Republic in particular, where the total number of municipal governments has increased by more than 150% over the last 20 years. This creates difficulties in leveraging economies of scale and delivering services efficiently (Martínez-Vázquez et al. 2017). 31 In several of the region´s largest countries, subnational governments also have responsibilities in the area of citizen security. See Citizen Security and Justice SFD (IDB 2017).
160
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
Table 3.1 Number of subnational governments in LAC by level of government and country Country
Number of intermediate governments
Number of municipal governments
Number of subnational governments
Argentina
24
2,218
2,242
Brazil
27
5,570
5,597
Bahamas
0
32
32
Belize
0
203
203
Costa Rica
7
81
88
Dominican Republic
32
392
422
Ecuador*
22
221
243
El Salvador
14
262
276
Guatemala
22
340
362
Guyana
10
146
156
Haiti*
10
182
192
Honduras
18
298
316
0
14
14
Nicaragua
17
153
170
Panama
14
78
92
Paraguay
18
254
271
Suriname
0
10
10
Trinidad and Tobago
0
15
15
Uruguay
19
112
131
Mexico
32
2,464
2,496
Bolivia
9
339
348
Chile
15
345
360
Colombia
33
1,101
1,134
Peru
26
1,871
1,897
Venezuela
23
337
360
392
17,038
17,427
Jamaica
Total Source IDB (2018)
Health and education services significantly affect the size of the subnational public sector, accounting on average for more than 40% of total expenditures (ECLAC 2011b). The largest countries in the region are the ones that have assigned these functions to subnational governments. In Argentina and Peru, these services are for the most part provided by intermediate levels of government; in Colombia, primary responsibility falls to the municipal governments; in Brazil, Mexico, and Venezuela, different levels of government have concurrent responsibilities (Martínez-Vázquez 2010). Subnational government autonomy in managing these services tends to be related to the governments, capacity to generate their own revenue. However, this is
3.3 Subnational Finance in Latin American and the Caribbean: Recent …
161
Table 3.2 Subnational Public Investment (% of all public investment) % Public Investment (2014)
Argentina*
Brasil
Colombia
México** (2013)
Perú**
Central Government
36.4
24.8
67.9
23.9
35.4
Subnational Governments
Intermediate Governments
45.5
43.0
6.5
50.2
19.8
Municipal Governments
18.2
32.2
25.6
23.4
44.0
Number of Subnational Governments Intermediate Governments
Argentina
Brazill
Colombia
México
Perú
24
27
33
32
26
Municipal Governments
2,171
5,570
1,122
2,438
1,838
Total
2,195
5,597
1,155
2,470
1,864
Source Based on OECD & BID (2016) and IERAL (2017)
not the case in all countries: the provinces of Argentina, which have significant own revenues, have greater control over management than Peru’s regional governments, which are funded almost entirely through transfers. In Mexico, however, states have traditionally been largely autonomous in the management of education services, despite being highly dependent on transfers.32
3.3.2 Recent advances and challenges Over the last four years (2015-2018), several LAC countries have made headway in the processes of decentralization. In Chile, for instance, the constitution was reformed in late 2016 to allow the democratic election of regional governors from 2020 onwards (intermediate level of government), thus replacing the institutional figure of the provincial governor appointed by the central government. That country also passed two laws in late 2017 governing the popular election of regional government authorities, accompanied by the transfer of powers to those entities.33 In October 2015, Panama enacted a law that decentralizes public administration, with the following key features: the transfer of real property tax revenue to the municipalities based on redistributive criteria; the strengthening of capacities in the area of public investment management; the gradual transfer of functions to the municipalities through the 32
By implementing the Fondo de Aportaciones para la Nómina Educativa y Gasto Operativo [Conditional Transfer Fund for Education Payroll and Operational Expenses] (FONE), the central government has asserted greater control over the teacher payroll it finances (see IDB 2014b). 33 New powers have been transferred in the areas of productive and industrial development, social and human development, and transportation and infrastructure; a procedure has been established allowing the regions to require new powers in future from the central government; and metropolitan areas can now be created in the country’s main conurbations.
162
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
accreditation of capabilities; and institutional piloting of the process by the National Decentralization Department. A second characteristic of the period has been the end of the boom in transfers to subnational governments linked to extractive industries, particularly in Andean countries. This phenomenon helps to explain the recent stagnation in growth in the size of the subnational public sector (see Fig. 3.5). Thirdly, in terms of the fiscal sustainability of subnational governments, Mexico has made progress by approving, a legal fiscal responsibility framework for federal and municipal entities, which is helping to boost transparency in the recording of subnational debt and, mitigate the incipient fiscal risks that certain subnational governments have exhibited (Rasteletti and Acosta 2016). In Argentina, the Fiscal Responsibility Law was reformed at the end of 2017 with the imposition of a ceiling on growth in current expenditure; this complements the signing of a fiscal pact between the three levels of government, aimed at ensuring fiscal sustainability and reducing distortionary taxes.34 Expanding the analysis to encompass the last 15 years, advances have been made but the traditional challenges that have characterized the decentralization process in the region have also intensified. On one hand, there has been significant improvement in the fiscal sustainability of subnational governments, particularly in Argentina, Brazil, and Colombia, where subnational debt contributed to bouts of macrofiscal instability in the late 1990s and early 2000s. In particular, the implementation of fiscal rules for subnational governments in Brazil and Colombia served as a model for the development of subnational fiscal responsibility frameworks in other countries of the region. On the other hand, and despite these advances, there is still a need to continue the timely monitoring of subnational fiscal risks-for example, in countries experiencing higher volatility in their transfers (particularly Andean region) or in which subnational debt is a concern (Argentina and Brazil). In addition, one of the traditional challenges in the sector persists: the subnational governments’ high dependence on transfers within the financing structure (ECLAC 2011c). Between 2000 and 2015, average expenditures by subnational governments rose by more than two percentage points of GDP.35 However, this rise was primarily due to higher transfers and, to a lesser extent, to the subnational governments own resources. From a comparative viewpoint, the financing structure of subnational governments in the LAC region stands in contrast with its counterparts not only in OECD countries but also in other regions with a relatively similar development level, such as Asia (see Fig. 3.14).
34
Argentina is aiming at reducing the importance of distortionary taxes on economic activity. As a consequence, the country is giving a renewed importance to underused sources of revenues such as the property taxes. 35 The information in Table 2 is a specific contribution of this SFD in view of the limited transparency of subnational finances in the region. It draws on the subnational fiscal database that IFD/FMM has been developing in recent years, as well as a questionnaire completed by specialists in that division who live and/or work in the vast majority of countries in the region. This has made it possible to describe and analyze recent decentralization trends in those countries.
3.3 Subnational Finance in Latin American and the Caribbean: Recent …
163
Fig. 3.14 Subnational government transfers as % of financing for subnational expenditure in the regions of the world (Source IMF Government Finance Statistics, 2016)
This high dependence on transfers reduces subnational governments incentives for accountability, efficient management, and fiscal responsibility, and it reflects weaknesses in the relationship between the different levels of government. At the same time, the performance of subnational governments is also affected by the context of low institutional capacity, limited transparency, and weak capacities for monitoring subnational management. Accordingly, the main challenge for the decentralization and subnational governments is to foster the development of institutional capacities and a suitable incentive structure for more efficient and effective subnational management in LAC, thus helping to improve the quality of life for all citizens. This requires building institutional capacities to tackle four major problems: (i) weak intergovernmental arrangements; (ii) subnational governments with deficient expenditure management and service delivery; (iii) subnational governments with low generation of own revenue and poor access to financing; and (iv) subnational governments with limited management transparency and accountability.
3.3.2.1
Weak intergovernmental arrangements
The problem of weak intergovernmental arrangement is threefold. First, the mismatch between responsibility (expenditures) and abilities (revenues). A poor combination of these two elements causes coordination problems among the different levels of government. For example, an ambiguous spending responsibility causes inefficient expenditures in key sectors, such as education, health, etc. Second, the process of fiscal decentralization (taxing powers) to subnational governments is slow, particularly with respect to intermediate levels of government. This exacerbates the dependence on transfers, except for Argentina and Brazil (where the intermediate levels have broad tax bases). The reason behind the slowness is that tax powers assigned to subnational governments are usually enshrined in national law and, in certain
164
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
cases, the constitution (for example, in Brazil) (Martínez-Vázquez 2010). Third, the design of intergovernmental transfer systems is out of date, especially in terms of addressing the horizontal imbalances that are characteristic of the region. LAC’s high territorial and economics inequality translate into major differences in the ability to generate own-source revenues. However, transfer only provide a limited offset to the inequalities among subnational governments (Beramendi 2012). While many transfer systems incorporate redistributive criteria related to population, rurality, and/or poverty, these criteria are insufficient to close regional gaps (Muñoz et al. 2017; Beramendi et al. 2017). Faced with the political difficulty of modifying their transfer regimes, such as by updating distribution criteria, countries often create new mechanisms and thereby add to the systems’ complexity. In order to mitigate information asymmetry, collaboration between different levels of governments aimed at capitalizing on shared technological solutions can help to reduce asymmetries in institutional capacity at the subnational level. Besides, the creation of spaces for discussion and periodic updating of the distribution criteria for transfers, based on simple systems with clear operating rules, would be an important step toward improving intergovernmental coordination institutions. Although the deconcentrating process is complex and require heavy cost-benefit analysis, the process itself can be an opportunity to evaluate reform options, particularly for those intermediate-level governments with greater ability to raise own-source revenues (IDB 2013a; Fretes Cibils and Ter-Minassian 2015). To optimize the transfer system, the introduction of equalization transfer systems would not only address regional gaps but would also create a platform for determining and periodically updating resource allocation formulas in the territory. It is critical that rules of the platform be simple, transparent, and consistent with the compliance capacities of subnational governments. Exhaustive and continuous monitoring by the central government, with credible and timely corrective action are also recommended (Urrea 2010)
3.3.2.2
Subnational governments with deficient expenditure management and service delivery
Many subnational governments in LAC are deficient in managing expenditures and providing services. This is partly the result of very disparate initial conditions (DNP 2017). For example, municipalities that have larger populations and more average years of schooling (and therefore a trained workforce) typically show higher levels of public investment execution (Loayza et al. 2014) and better indicators of public expenditure efficiency (Herrera and Francke 2007). Similarly, in municipalities with lower literacy levels and higher levels of poverty and inequality, the productivity of public spending on education is relatively lower (Tavares and de Cavalcanti 2014, and Machado 2013). Nonetheless, large variations in management capacity and development results - even between municipalities with similar initial conditions - reveals the usefulness of differentiated policies and the identification of good practices for subnational governments that lag behind (DNP 2017). In the Brazilian states there is a weak correlation between the relative efficiency of spending on education and
3.3 Subnational Finance in Latin American and the Caribbean: Recent …
165
both state spending per capita on education and state GDP per capita. This suggests that simply having more funds does not guarantee better outcomes, unless they are accompanied by improvements in the management of service quality (Boueri et al. 2014). Talking about the management of the subnational public investment cycle (planning, formulation, execution and ex post evaluation), we also find that LAC subnational governments are in a poor situation. This category of spending is of increasing importance, with considerable potential to help reduce territorial gaps in socioeconomic development. Intermediate level governments have an important role to play in this area by adopting a territorial approach to coordinate their own investments with those of the municipalities. Additionally, the ability of subnational governments to attract investment is affected by constraints that limit opportunities for economic development, including export promotion. The poor quality of services helps to create transaction costs in the relationship between subnational governments and citizens. Except for Brazil and Mexico, the development of public-private partnerships and the private sector’s role in providing services to the subnational government level is incipient (Infrascope 2013), limiting its potential to promote capacities, contribute to poverty reduction, and generate equity. In all these respects, central government support is critical, particularly for subnational governments with limited capacity and high poverty and inequality rates. Significant constraints on improving the quality of subnational expenditures include the weak development of the Public Financial Management (PFM) and limited implementation of management models to strengthen centers of government, which foster coordination of government priorities by directly supporting subnational government authorities. In many subnational entities there are also weaknesses in administrative processes, which usually lack the support of basic management tools. Despite advances in the region in modernizing national PFM systems over the past two decades, development of these systems at the subnational level lags. In terms of coverage, worth noting are the cases of Peru, where the PFM-System has been implemented by all subnational governments (IDB 2010a); Guatemala, where all municipalities are connected to a national system (including an own-source revenue management module); and Brazil, where a PFM-System is in operation in all states and has recently been modernized in half of them (Pimenta 2015). This limited development extends to other PFM systems, such as electronic public procurement (aimed at simplifying procedures and improving subnational capacities), payroll, and asset management (including real estate). There is also the challenge of ensuring that the PFM systems are used by the subnational authorities as a management tool rather than primarily as a central government control mechanism. There is limited development of a professionalized civil service, including competitive staff compensation policies that can better attract, retain, and motivate skilled employees in the context of a fiscally sustainable payroll. Development of the civil service should be accompanied by a sustainable improvement in the technical capacities of public officials, which in many LAC countries are limited as regards both subnational government officials and the government teams that manage the decentralization process at the central level. In this respect, the resident technical assistance
166
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
approach used in Peru’s subnational governments—including capacity evaluations and the transfer of skills and knowledge through daily work with subnational officials—was ultimately more effective in the area of public investment management than short-term informational training. This effort has been accompanied by a deconcentration of central government technical officials to the regions, helping to make the improvement in subnational capacities more sustainable (IDB 2012a).
3.3.2.3
Subnational Governments with Low Generation of Own Revenue and Poor Access to Financing
If subnational governments are to reduce their dependence on transfers, they must improve their capacity to generate own-source revenues. This hinges on the allocation of tax bases and tax rates at the subnational level (part of intergovernmental arrangements) and on the subnational governments’ efforts to maximize their tax bases, service charges, and other sources of funds. In this regard, own-source revenue collection by subnational governments in LAC falls short of its potential. This is evidenced by the limited development of instruments to capture increased property values stemming from public investments, as well as low recovery of service costs and weak management of subnational government assets and real property for sale and lease. Also worth noting is the under collection of the real estate property tax, for which average revenue barely amounted to 0.4% of GDP in 2015 - just over one third of the OECD figure (see Fig. 3.15). This problem has been brought about by factors specific to subnational management, as well as by central government restrictions. The former includes outdated land registries and taxpayer records; limited automation of revenue collection functions; limited capabilities for calculating tax and municipal levy amounts; and insufficient oversight efforts. Regarding the last of these factors, the political cycle influences
Fig. 3.15 Property tax collection, 2000 and 2015 LAC vs. OECD (as a percentage of GDP) (Source Bonet, Muñoz, and Pineda [2014])
3.3 Subnational Finance in Latin American and the Caribbean: Recent …
167
local fiscal efforts in several countries, particularly in election years. Consequently, there is a need to reinforce the autonomy of tax administration at the subnational level and to promote its digitization. In addition, there is scant central government support for subnational governments in their management of own-source revenue, partly because in many countries this function is not sufficiently prioritized. As a result, and about property taxes, the periodic appraisals designed to bring real estate values closer to market value are outdated. Similarly, public records are not integrated with municipal property records (IDB 2013a). Furthermore, subnational governments receive limited technical assistance, which is focused on urban entities with greater revenue collection potential and low management capacity, and possibly also rural subnational governments with high per capita income (Sepúlveda and MartínezVázquez 2012). In view of the gap in revenue collection between LAC and OECD countries, especially with regard to property taxes, there is a need to strengthen the payment culture, improve land registry and tax administration systems, and undertake the investments required to bring subnational revenue collection closer to its potential. An additional challenge facing subnational governments is their limited access to financing, which restricts their ability to quickly roll out the social benefits of public investment and expand their opportunities for development. Indeed, there are subnational governments that, while having access to debt financing in a context of fiscal responsibility, are constrained by a lack of capacity, institutional limitations, and an absence of institutional mechanisms. Weaknesses in PFM - including planning, budget management, public investment, and debt management capacities -have an impact on this challenge (as does the limited generation of own-source revenues). In some cases, subnational governments accumulate old debts to other public entities (for example, social security) that prevent them from accessing the market (Llempén et al. 2010). In most cases, weak generation of own-source revenue limits the amount that can be borrowed. In addition, many subnational governments are too small to be considered eligible for credit, despite the existence of instruments that make it possible to pool the resources of multiple entities into a single transaction Moreover, central government support is insufficient in some countries to provide subnational governments with the technical assistance they require to be restored to financial health and subsequently access the market. This is largely due to a lack of information and monitoring capacity in the Ministries of Finance, which limits the ability to classify subnational governments according to their creditworthiness. In this regard, one of the benefits of the effective implementation of fiscal responsibility frameworks in Brazil and Colombia is the central government’s increased ability to understand the state of subnational public finances - particularly in the case of the larger subnational governments. This makes it possible to approve debt transactions with a low risk of default. Subnational governments with limited management transparency and accountability. Finally, there is limited management transparency in subnational governments. In most countries the availability of information is either incipient or restricted.
168
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
Only two countries, Brazil and Peru, make subnational financial information available that is considered sound. Second, the problem of opacity at the subnational level is well recognized by citizens and carries a considerable cost. A survey reveals that along with lack of citizen security, lack of municipal government transparency has become one of their most serious problems (IDB 2014e). The opacity means a significant transfer loss, for example irregularities in the use of local funds affected between 2 and 8% of all transfers audited over the last decade (Ferraz and Finan 2011; Brollo et al. 2013). In municipalities where education transfers were improperly used, basic school supplies are scarce, the quality of education (as measured by standardized tests) is lower, and students are more likely to drop out (Ferraz et al. 2012). Additionally, improper government actions are also accountable for these problems. Programs to promote accountability are still either uncommon or their scope extends only to the municipal administration or executive branch. Such programs are particularly necessary in view of the increase in transfers linked to nonrenewable natural resources, where the evidence points to greater problems with irregularities in the municipalities that benefit most from these resources (Caselli and Michaels 2013; Ferraz and Monteiro 2010; Maldonado 2011). Lastly, monitoring and evaluation of subnational management is insufficient. In Peru, financial audits by the Comptroller General’s Office barely cover 2.4% of the municipalities (IDB 2013d) and in El Salvador, despite the fact that all municipalities are required to undergo external financial audits, only one out of a representative sample of 10 municipalities fulfilled this requirement (World Bank 2010b). It is worth noting the Colombia experience in enhance transparency. Colombia’s royalties mapping system has helped to improve the transparency of subnational governments in executing royalty funds linked to the extractive industries. This allows monitoring of the public investment plans of subnational governments financed with royalty funds. Meanwhile, Brazilian’s experience can be valuable as well. Federal and state auditing offices supported implementation of the Fiscal Responsibility Law, created communities of practice, and expanded their audit activities to include operational audits and audits to evaluate efficiency in the use of funds.
3.4 Municipal Finance in Africa with Special Focus on Botswana 3.4.1 Introduction Cities are the defining form of human organization in the twenty-first century. In 1980, just 1.7 billion people lived in cities. By 2050, the world’s urban population will swell to 6.4 billion. By the end of this century, 80–90% of humanity is expected to be city dwellers. The vast majority of tomorrow’s urban growth will occur in the medium-sized and large sprawling cities of Africa and Asia. And since many cities are urbanizing before they industrialize, the slum population is set to double in the
3.4 Municipal Finance in Africa with Special Focus on Botswana
169
next decade. While everyone agrees that cities are growing in size and scale, there’s a worrying silence about what they will look like, much less how they will be financed (Robert Mugger et al. 2019). Municipal finance is about the revenue and expenditure decisions of municipal governments. It covers the sources of revenue that are used by municipal governments—taxes (property, income, sales, excise taxes), user fees, and intergovernmental transfers. According to Mugger, there is a tremendous supply of capital potentially available for financing cities. Much of it is tied to pension, sovereign and insurance funds and endowments. There are also growing numbers of impact investors who are eager to invest in socially and environmentally responsible projects while generating a decent return. Likewise, multinational development banks are also getting into the game, many of them seeking to de-risk investments for private investors, foster public–private partnerships and provide concessional finance, particularly for lower-income and emerging market cities. Cities themselves are actively exploring domestic sources of financing, including municipal bonds, privatizing under-used assets, securitization and eve crowd sourcing. The bottom line is that cities in developed and underdeveloped settings alike underestimate the opportunities to access finance. The truth is that they can deploy a host of regulatory instruments to shape market characteristics to their advantage. It is against this background that this chapter outlines and discusses the experience of municipal financing in Botswana. The paper starts off by first by providing the background on the state of local government administration in Botswana highlighting on the responsibilities of the municipalities in urban development and service delivery. The next section looks at financing capital expenditure from different sources, like own revenue resources, government transfers, the private sector, borrowing and also capital markets. After this the paper moves on to look at infrastructure financing, industrial development and the role of FDIs, and public, private partnerships in municipal development. Finally, the paper provides a brief summary of the challenges and opportunities of municipal finance and lessons to be learnt from Botswana’s experience.
3.4.2 Municipal Finance: Botswana: Overview Botswana, is located at the center of Southern Africa, positioned between South Africa, Namibia, Zambia, and Zimbabwe. One of the world’s poorest countries at independence in 1966, it rapidly became one of the world’s development success stories. Significant mineral (diamond) wealth, good governance, prudent economic management and a relatively small population of slightly more than two million, have made it an upper middle-income country (WB: https://www.worldbank.org/en/ country/botswana/overview). Since gaining independence from the United Kingdom, Botswana has been one of the world’s fastest growing economies, averaging 5% per annum over the past decade. Real economic growth accelerated to 4.4% in 2018 (the fastest growth rate
170
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
in the last five years) and is projected to remain at around 4% up to 2021. The population in 2019 is estimated at 2.30 million, up slightly from 2014’s 2.04 million, which ranks 145th in the world. The country is also one of the world’s most sparsely populated countries with a population density of just 3 people per square kilometer. (World Bank 2019a). Gaborone is the largest city in Botswana, and also the capital. The population in Gaborone is approximately 232,000. More than 10% of the population lives in the capital. The majority of the population in Botswana lives within 100 km of Gaborone. Other major towns include Francistown, Lobatse, Selebi-Phikwe, Jwaneng and Sowa township, In Botswana, 61% of the population resides in urban areas, and the country is currently urbanizing at an annual rate of 2.3%.
3.4.2.1
Administrative and Constitutional and Legal Frameworks
There are sixteen administrative districts and associated councils in Botswana. The general duties of Councils can be summarized as “to exercise its powers so as to secure and promote the health, order and good government of the area for which it has been established”. (Cap 40:01/02; 29). The main duties of the councils are to provide the following services: - Primary education, public health and sanitation, roads, social welfare and community development and primary health care. The urban centres have experienced unprecedented growth over the years causing a strain in financial resources (Eustice, J.B 2001) (GOB (1987) (Mosha A.C. (2001). There are two main categories of current revenue for local government authorities in Botswana. (i) “Own Revenue”, which includes taxes, user fees and various licences, and transfers from the central government in the form of grants and revenues sharing. Unlike other countries, the municipalities are yet given the right to borrow to finance investments in local capital infrastructure.
3.4.3 Financing Urban Development 3.4.3.1
Planning and Budgeting
In general, municipal local authorities are funded through the Revenue Support Grant, known as Deficit Grants from the central government, Own Revenue Sources and Development Grants for major government projects in the municipalities. Currently the Deficit Grant accounts for 64% of urban council’s revenue. In addition, Councils receive 100% of their development funds in form of grants from the Central Government. Councils have legal powers to collect certain taxes, levies and fees in order to defray their operating expenses. With a few exceptions, they are discouraged from trying to raise revenue by embarking upon potentially profit making businesses, for example, provision of rental housing or public transport due to potential problems.
3.4 Municipal Finance in Africa with Special Focus on Botswana
3.4.3.2
171
Main Sources of Municipal Revenue
Botswana’s Local Government Act (Cap 40.01.) defines the duties, functions and responsibilities of the local authorities. It also stipulates the sources of their finances by making approvals for each authority, depending on sources identified (from the wide range of sources they have as options). Revenue finance is raised to meet the local authorities’ recurrent expenditures while capital finances are raised to carry out capital works, such as roads, water and sewerage expansion, housing, street lighting etc. These municipal authorities are funded through four mechanisms, namely Own Revenue Sources that include land-based revenues (property tax and rates) and on non-land based revenues such as, tax on provision of goods and services etc.; Revenue Support Grants (RSG); loans from the Public Debt Service Fund; and Capital Development Grants from the centre (Derek J. Hudson (1993). The main concern is the low levels of municipal “own revenues”. In the table below, it is shown that between 2009–2014/15(latest available complete figures), annual urban own sources ranged from a low of 15.8% to 36.5% as against RSG that ranged between 64–84.2%, hence a dependency syndrome. Further, more often than not, the RSG is apportioned more funds than the development budget. In 2012/13, for example, 78% the Ministry of Local Government and Rural Development was allocated to recurrent expenditure and only 22% to development expenditure to be shared among all the councils. (MLGRD 2016). This does not seem to adhere to the universal norm of 70:30 apportionment rules between the recurrent and development budgets indicating that the big portion of the budget goes towards administration, and salaries at the expense of capital projects (Table 3.3). Table 3.3 Urban Councils Recurrent Budgets (US$): Revenue Support Grant (RSG) and Own Source 2009/10 & 2013/2014 Urban Councils
2009/10
2013/14
Own Source
%
RSG
%
Francistown
3,794,988.2
14.2
22,972,133.8
85.8
Gaborone
9,643,210.2
22.6
32,890,542.6
77.4
Jwaneng
1,850,398.5
15.3
10,179,355.8
84.7
Lobatse
2,484,202.9
2.4
16,827,927.9
97.6
Selebi Phikwe
1,618,930.6
10.4
13,999,388.2
89.6
Sowa Town
291,468.2
5.6
4,929,486.3
Total
19,242,017.3
15.8
101,798,834.8
Own Source
%
RSG
%
4,456,912
24.5
13,728,191
75.5
11,453,996
40.5
16,760,343
59.5
1,640,792
20.2
6,491,222
79.8
1,497,953
13.2
9,766,547
86.8
1.628,584
15.7
8,709,692
84.3
94.4
437,527
11.8
3,277,960
88.2
84.2
21,115,748
20.9
58,727,956
79.1
Source MLGRD (2016): Department of Local Government Finance and Procurement
172
3.4.3.3
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
External Revenue Sources: Revenue Support Grant from Central Government
The Revenue Support Grants or deficit grants is the difference between the local authority’s agreed estimates of expenditure and anticipated revenue from local sources and government subsidies. This grant is subject to a high degree of control from the centre. The grant has been fluctuating between a high of 84.2% in 2009/10 to 2013/14. The grant has been rising over the years due to increased demand to operate and maintain the huge infrastructure that had been put up under this fund from all the municipalities and towns. This fact has caused the resources of the municipalities to be spread more thinly in both human and financial terms. This situation is not healthy for political accountability to the electorate. The role of central government finance is also significant in that it finances the bulk of the Councils expenditure on capital account. This is partly due to the fact that the Councils are not permitted to borrow on the open market.
3.4.3.4
Own Revenue Sources
While the revenue from the RSG is high, that from own sources was quite modest. The total revenue of the six municipalities in 2014 was US$10,955,089 out which property rates was US$7,392,837 and the rest was revenue from other sources that totaled US$. 3,562,250. Thus, rates alone accounted for 67.4% of the total own revenue budget, whilst other sources accounted for 32.6%. (MLGRD 2016). This obviously means that the bulk of the revenue for the municipalities came from rates. Rates are property tax levied on land and buildings. However, the Councils do send the money to central government for central allocation on a formula basis. This means that unlike other countries, municipalities do not benefit from their rates. The other revenue incomes include among others, such as plan perusal fees, abattoir fees, insurance commission, lease rentals, sanitation fees and so forth.
3.4.3.5
Property Rates and Service Levies
The table below shows city revenue from property rates and service levies and other taxes. Rates are composed of land rents on property owned by individuals, companies or the government, including parastatals and rates on buildings (i.e. developed property). Other property taxes levied by municipalities also include a levy on transfer of property and some betterment taxes. Rates are a property tax and all those who own property or plots in the city area, whether developed or undeveloped, have to pay. Rates on undeveloped plots are levied at four times of the rates for developed plots. Higher rates are charged due to the government policy of discouraging speculation in land and encouraging plot owners to develop them as quickly as possible. However, this is ineffective in deterring speculation as those with high disposable income have been snapping up such land for development of flats or town houses.
3.4 Municipal Finance in Africa with Special Focus on Botswana
173
Table 3.4 Actual “own revenue” from various sources–2014 Local municipality
Property rates
%
Revenue from other sources
%
Total
Francistown
1,041,549.7
59.6
704,448.9
40.4
1,745,998.7
Gaborone
4,516,738.6
91.6
410,147.9
8.4
4,926,886.5
Jwaneng
613,740.7
61.4
639,562.8
38.6
1,270,565.6
Lobatse
458,172.1
32.1
970,471.9
68.8
1,428,644.0
Selibe Phikwe
647,218.1
50.3
639,562.8
49.7
1,286,781.0
72,334.3
24.4
223,878.5
75.4
296,212.8
Sowa Source MLGRD, 2016
As shown in Table 2, in 2014, for the six municipalities total “Own Revenue” was US1,270,565 of which $613,747 (49.7%) was from rates and US$ 639,562 (50.3%) was from other sources like service levies, tax on the provision of goods and services (Business licences and fees), plan perusal fees. However this figure could rise further if municipalities could make more efforts in collecting funds. Unfortunately, a source like rates is inelastic as sometimes the valuation rolls are incomplete, hence depriving the municipalities a major source of income. Further, central government and parastatal organisations are supposed to pay rates to the municipalities, but they do not do so hence, denying the municipalities substantial sums of money. There has also been a problem of ratepayers not receiving their bills, as the Department of Lands had at times not updated their records. Later, however, the department did engage consultants to update property records. It is worth mentioning that city residents also pay income tax to the government revenue offices. This is taxed at progressive rates from 5 to 25%. Gained from the disposal of immovable property (Table 3.4).
3.4.3.6
Rates and Service Levy Debtors/ Defaulters
Although the municipalities have managed to raise quite substantial revenue funds from rates and service levies, it is common practice to find many city dwellers owing the various municipalities vast sums of money. The sums involved have been rising year by year. For example, in the year 2014, rates debts for the six cities and towns were US$10,777,426, whereas service levies debts stood at US$2,044,970.9 (MLGRD 2016). There are many factors that contributed to this state of affairs. To start with, the procedure for collection and recovery of late arrears is generally poor. Enforcement is both time consuming and cumbersome, as follow up measures are not clearly defined. However, efforts are being made time and again to recover rates arrears. Written notices are normally sent to all defaulting ratepayers. Reminders are issued to all plot owners who have not paid their full rates within the allowed period of four months from the date of the invoice, reminding them that they will be liable to pay interest. After issue of another reminder, a Demand Notice is then sent. If rates still
174
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
Table 3.5 Rates & service levy debts: Urban councils -2014: Us Dollars Municipality
Rates
Service levies
Amount
Percentage
Amount
Percentage
Francis town
6,186,087.0
87.2
905,935.40
12.8
Gaborone
3,840,905.8
88.3
508,456.4
11.7
Jwaneng
199,360.9
79.9
50,066.4
20.1
Lobatse
328,115.3
57.8
239,888.6
42.2
Selibe Phikwe
251,914
42.6
338,643.9
57.4
64.5
15,968.9
35.5
Sowa
28,957.2
Source MLGRD, Department of Local Government Finance and Procurement
remain unpaid, then the case is referred to debt collector/attorney for further legal action of collection of rates. In such an event the defaulter has to pay legal costs in addition to the rates. For long outstanding debts, provision is normally made to attach property to recover the debt. Recently, the Council adopted yet another innovative idea of collecting debts by publishing the names of defaulters in the national press. The collection of rates is not administratively difficult and it merely requires a highly determined administration to achieve low default rates (Table 3.5).
3.4.3.7
Overall Assessment.
The main conclusion from the above clearly shows that there is heavy reliance on transfers from central government and on rates, which by the way are less economically efficient than on land tax, and difficulty in collection enforcement. This does not augur well for the municipalities as they have no enough resources of their own. Year after year, mayors and town directors have been recommending that they should be raising more own funds, but these have been mere words and no action. The only step that has been taken is the computerization of their accounting processes which include accounting, human resources and land management. This has been extended to include the rates and payroll accounts. To-date it can safely be said that computerization has brought positive impacts as it has led to increased efficiency and transparency in the various councils.
3.4.3.8
Management of Financial Resources
All municipalities do prepare, on a yearly basis, budget estimates containing the required expenditure, the expected income from internal sources, and the required deficit grants to cover the shortfall. Various reviews of the municipalities’ accounts show that the councils follow procedures of accountability and tendering quite well. This is in contrast to some municipalities in Africa where corruption and mismanagement of funds is endemic. Further, financial controls official discussions revealed
3.4 Municipal Finance in Africa with Special Focus on Botswana
175
that the City Treasurer’s Departments always use normal accounting and financial control, plus restrictions of votes. All councils do internal auditing of their accounts. All local authorities in Botswana are required to report upon the progress of projects implementation each quarter to Ministries. The reports cover both financial and physical status. It is encouraging to observe that this procedure has been regularly followed by all the councils. Finally the councils have all computerized all their core processes which include accounting, human resources and land management. This has been extended to include the rates and payroll accounts. To-date it can safely be said that computerization has brought positive impacts as it has led to increased efficiency and transparency in the various councils.
3.4.3.9
Infrastructure Financing
The rapid urbanization Botswana has experienced has been straining the already overstretched infrastructure and created complex problems for local governments. All along much of the municipal infrastructure has been in the hands of government or through its parastatals for water supply, road transport, telecommunications etc. The government has invested heavily in infrastructure in almost all areas of the country with tarred roads reaching most areas. Since the 1980s, the gap between demand and supply for basic infrastructure sectors (including power generation and distribution, water and sanitation, telecommunications and transport) has been rapidly growing in country. While demand has massively increased due to strong population growth as well as high rates of urbanization, supply has remained constant or has even decreased. For some time now, Botswana has been warming up to the idea of using private funds to fund infrastructure, for example, using pension funds for investing in infrastructure and commerce. A good example is a huge regional shopping mall (Airport Junction Mall) to the north of Gaborone city that has been financed using workers’ pension funds. Currently, this mall is the biggest in the whole country. Again, much of the new central business district in Gaborone and also that of Francistown city has been built by using private funds and FDI. The main players are big property developers like Turnstar Holdings Jamal Builders and others. TIME Projects Botswana has also been involved in urban land servicing in partnership with the Gaborone City Council for housing construction. Such initiatives should be replicated in other towns in Botswana. Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) for infrastructure development. Due to its status as a middle income country, Botswana has struggled to attract FDI in the last ten years due to stringent conditions of doing business. However, with the coming of the new president, he has eased this by making it easier for businesses to set up shop in the country. According to UNCTAD, FDI inflows in Botswana rose from USD 177 million in 2017 to USD 230 million in 2018. This is mostly due to an increase in automotive FDI. The total stock of FDI in Botswana reached to USD 4.82 billion in 2018, estimated at 25.4% of the country’s GDP (World Investment Report 2019, UNCTAD) (https://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLib rary/wir2019_en.pdf). The mining sector attracts most of the FDI. However, investments in the services industry (insurance and banking) have been growing in recent years. FDI primarily comes from the Southern African Customs Union (SACU), the
176
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
European Free Trade Association (EFTA), Canada and Zimbabwe. Other inflows come from China, India and Pakistan. Most municipalities benefit from these FDI as investors spend substantial funds in the cities (https://www.ceicdata.com/en/indica tor/botswana/foreign-direct-investment--of-nominal-gdp).
3.4.3.10
Industrial Financing
Industrial development in Botswana is rather on the low side. Much of the industry that is seen in urban areas is mainly packaging and fabrication, beer and soft drinks brewing and little else. Much of this is run by the private sector. In order to boost industrial production the government has introduced many reforms to enable investors to do business in Botswana. One initiative has been the establishment of Special Economic Zones in four of the main towns of Gaborone, Francistown, Selebi-Phikwe and Lobatse. It is anticipated that this initiative will see these centres as hubs for industrial development. Both investors and the municipalities will pump money into these centres to boost exports as well as to provide employment which the country needs very badly.
3.4.3.11
Public/Private Partnerships
All municipalities have in a number of instances embarked on implementation of the government’s policy on privatization (approved by Parliament in April 2000) by way of outsourcing certain activities to the private sector in order to provide essential services in their municipalities. Among the services the Councils have privatised in the past include is solid waste removal, collection of debts, employment of private security guards in a number of schools and leasing out of public transport routes to private operators. They are also working mechanisms of forging partnerships with the private sectors in the areas of parking arrangements, development and running of markets and waste collection and management. Secondly, the private sector plays a very important role in land delivery in the city. In 1994, government declared its intention to involve the private sector in property development especially in the provision of serviced residential land through the Presidential Directive Cab 9/94. The private sector’s participation in urban land servicing is anchored around providing secondary and tertiary services to peripherally serviced blocks of plots at their own cost. The services are later handed over to the responsible authorities free of charge to facilitate future maintenance. Blocks of plots are allocated to developers through a competitive tender system. Successful developers are then required to pay for all infrastructure costs needed to develop land to the specified standard. Blocks of plots have been allocated to private developers in several parts of the municipalities. For example in Gaborone land was allocated in Block 5, block 6, Maruapula and Tsholofelo. (GCC-Draft UDP2, pg.40).
3.4 Municipal Finance in Africa with Special Focus on Botswana
177
3.4.4 Municipal Finance Challenges and Lessons Learnt The major financial challenges facing Botswana’s local and urban councils stem largely from (a) the lack of financial autonomy and power; (b) low levels of “Own Resources” and (c) low cost recovery. The lack of autonomy and power means that councils have to take whatever central government gives them as revenue both for development as well as for recurrent expenditure in the form of support grants for which they have little say in the final figures. Further, there is always a mismatch between the recurrent budget and the development budget. As for own revenues, it is evident that the Councils do not have significant independent sources of revenue and even these resources are inadequate and inelastic. For example, the city of Gaborone in 2011/12 had estimated to make P6mil from interest arrears, but fell short by P3.3mil; had hoped to make P4.7mil interest in its investments but managed only P42,000; made only P228,000 from sanitation fees as opposed to a projection of P3.7mil and had a shortfall of P944 for SHHA service charges and P2.7mil for housing rent and P1.3mil for trade licences.(Sunday Standard, 23rd June 2012'' ). Cost recovery is poor because many Councils have not developed implementation guidelines and monitoring mechanisms. To compound this problem, many urban Councils are facing escalating debts particularly those of rates, building material loans and service arrears. For example, Francistown City Council managed to recover only P 13 988 652.46 (US$1,398,865.2) as compared to the P 29 583 474.11(US$2,958,347.4) owed to it for rates during the financial year 2006/2007. In the same year, the Council was also owed P 747 768 (US$74,776.8) on account of building material loans and P 2 194 642 (US$219,464.2) on service levy. Much of this can be attributed to low incomes and unaffordability on the part of the beneficiaries.
3.4.5 Conclusion: Most Pressing Priorities in Financing Botswana’s Towns and Cities in the Future Financing city development in Botswana, just like the rest of the world will take skill and acumen. The municipalities will have to use both traditional and innovative methods of city financing if they are to succeed like in developed countries. As noted above, municipalities in Botswana are likely to continue to suffer in the long run on the two fronts viz: dependency on central government and low own financial resources for budget sustainability. Since the government budget is increasingly becoming constrained new strategies have to be adopted in the new Urban Agenda to improve the situation. The following are key recommendations:Firstly, Botswana cities and towns must strive to be more independent financially. They need to seek local financing capacity while capitalising on all resources available from multilaterals, bilaterals, central and local governments. The municipalities should seek new and innovative sources of finance including, municipal bonds, bank
178
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
loans and the like which are hardly being utilized at the moment. In the continent, very few cities are using bonds or taking massive bank loans. Secondly, the municipal leaders need to increase their capacity. In the case of Botswana, the money is there, but packaging bankable projects is difficult. It takes sophistication and financial knowledge to reach well-balanced financing structures, which requires better education, networking and capacity building that is not available in most municipalities today. By all means, greater efforts should be put in collecting revenues owed to the councils by defaulters. It should be realized that increased cost recovery enhances the financial autonomy of the Councils and reduces dependency on Central Government, overtime. Therefore, if done rigorously this will support the Councils by making them sustainable in the long run. As the sustainability of service provision in the long term should depend on the extent of cost sharing between government and the beneficiaries of such services, implementation and monitoring of cost sharing measures need beefing up. Cost recovery thus provides the fiscal basis for further expansion. Councils should step up public education on cost recovery. Thirdly, as far as infrastructure financing is concerned, Botswana should look into taping money from land value capture as an instrument of harnessing development funds. As has already been seen, infrastructure demand in Botswana has been growing rapidly, notably in the urban transport sector where new roads are constantly been built or old ones being widened as experienced in the major cities of Gaborone and Francistown. The unfortunate thing is that land values along these new roads spike but the Councils do not reap betterment tax from them. Hence, accessing sufficient funding in a timely manner is crucial for the development of public transport. One innovative and increasingly accepted way to fund public transport in many countries and cities like Shenzhen in China today is through Land Value Capture finance (LVC). Urban infrastructure investment induces increases in land value, thus it is possible to recover the capital costs of urban investment by capturing some or all of the increments in land value resultant from the investment; this may be accomplished through a fiscal mechanism such as land value finance (tax, incentives, development agreements). This model leverages partnerships between the public sector, road transport companies and developers to coordinate planning and financing of new roads and adjacent real estate developments. Fiscal decentralisation reform, based on the subsidiarity principle, may be the pivotal point in the implementation of land value capture in the country because the revenue generated by land value capture can be earmarked by local authorities to fund urban expenditure. Fourthly, the towns and cities of this country need to be balanced in their development approach, especially the capital city Gaborone and Francistown facing rapid growth and globalisation. These cities must balance the desire to grow economically with the need to address critical environmental and social equity concerns, whilst being sensitive to local needs and promoting inclusivity. For the small to mediumsized towns like Selebi Phikwe, Jwaneng, Sowa and Lobatse, it is important to tap into all external resources – including grants, subsidies, credit guarantees and more.
3.5 Charges to Building Rights: A Notable Value Capture Experience …
179
3.5 Charges to Building Rights: A Notable Value Capture Experience from Brazil36 Land value capture (LVC) provides a mechanism for communities to recover financial windfalls accruing to landowners from public investments in infrastructure and services or from beneficial changes in land use norms and regulations. This progressive public financing option is gaining noteworthy traction in nations worldwide. This chapter argues that a major new value capture tool—charges for building rights— can be a significant source of public revenue. This type of fee has the advantage not only of generating much-needed financing for urban infrastructure and services, but also of addressing a fundamental social equity issue in land policy. After outlining the arguments for value capture and providing a brief history of its application, the chapter describes the highly successful implementation of building rights charges in São Paulo, Brazil. This case study also illustrates how this tool can be used to increase local administrative capacity to invest in urban infrastructure and services as well as in social housing.
3.5.1 The Case for Value Capture Rapid urbanization, especially in developing countries, creates mounting demand for costly infrastructure and services to support the mix of gated communities and high-end developments competing for space with informal settlements at the urban fringe. The stakes are high when it comes to land price increases resulting from public infrastructure investments, including roads, water, sewerage, and electricity. According to a report from the Asia Development Bank Developing Asia will need to invest $26 trillion from 2016 to 2030, or $1.7 trillion per year, if the region is to maintain its growth momentum, eradicate poverty, and respond to climate change (climate-adjusted estimate).37 This amounts to about to 5% of projected GDP of Asian countries (excluding China). McKinsey in turn, estimates the urban infrastructure investment need from 2013 to 2030 in cities at over $45 trillion!.38 In the meantime, the Trump administration unveiled a $1.5 trillion infrastructure 10 years plan in 2018 designed to repair and upgrade the country’s aging infrastructure.39 Similar numbers can be quoted to most countries, in special the less developed ones. For the latter an additional stress is 36
The present article is a slightly modified version of an earlier version published as “Charges to Building Rights: Brazil’s Successful Experiment with Value Capture” (WP/18/05 – ATI) Working Paper South Africa, 2018. 37 https://www.adb.org/publications/asia-infrastructure-needs. 38 Cited in Financing the Growth of Cities by By Clare Romanik, Urban Resilience Adviser, USAID Urban Links Media Scan 6/1/2017. 39 https://www.fool.com/investing/how-to-invest-in-infrastructure-stocks.aspx.
180
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
noted as the cost of a materials (cement, steel etc.) and machinery (metro digging machines and the like) tends to be the same if not higher in less developer than in developed countries whereas their per capita income is a fraction of that in the more developed countries. Thus, the ‘fiscal effort’ in less developed countries is much higher! All in all, a $1 trillion a year is needed just to properly support the influx of 200,000 people moving to cities every day with proper infrastructure and services for water, sanitation, transport, and green. (Triveno, L. and Smolka M.O 017) With the general rejection to any additional tax burden one is urged to think more creatively about alternative funds to meet the above challenges. The encouraging news is that land value increment resulting from investments in areas lagging in the supply of urban infrastructure and services are often much higher than the cost of such interventions. In other words, management capacity under the proper legal and institutional framework may account for a substantive share of feasible solution for the above conundrum. In effect the ADB estimates that the land value increment ($3.4 Billion) resulting from Manila’s new metro line combined with the density rezoning of the affected areas to be 5 times as much as the cost of the investment.40 Similarly, investments the revitalization, green areas, and urban infrastructure and services provisions in cities as Quetzaltenango in Guatemala and Xalapa, México have been shown to generate land valorizations (Blanco et al. 2017). Planners who share responsibility for some of this haphazard growth are learning the potential land value increases associated to land use regulations and, more importantly, the significant redistribution of wealth that accompanies public interventions. The so-called urban multiplier effect—the increased value of land when converted from rural to urban use—is typically more than 4:1. Data collected globally on urbanization by Angel and Mayo (1996), and more recently in countries across Latin America (Bouillon 2012), confirm this order-of-magnitude increase in parcel prices. In São Paulo’s high-end areas, the value that developers are willing to pay for the right to build at a floor area ratio (FAR) of two or three (rather than the basic FAR of one) may fetch well over US$1,500.—per square meter (Sandroni 2011). In another example, conversion of land from residential to commercial use - in areas like El Chico in Bogota, Colombia - raised prices by an average of 50% (from $2,143 to $3,214 per sqm) in high strata areas and about 30% in median median-income neighborhoods. In an area in the north of Bogota planned for 140,000 housings through 32 ‘partial plans’ comprehending 1,800 has plots designated for residential use at a FAR of 2.2 are valued at $1285 per sqm whereas a similar one for commercial and offices at and FAR of 2.7 the price is well over $2,500. (Borrero 2018). Value capture policies provide a way to recover these large land value increments and to use this new revenue not only to pay for public investments in infrastructure and social housing, but also improve local land use management practices. The social justice argument for value capture is that all taxpayers bear the costs of providing 40
https://businessmirror.com.ph/2019/06/02/a-genie-called-lvc/.
3.5 Charges to Building Rights: A Notable Value Capture Experience …
181
adequate transportation, water and sewage systems, and open space to meet more intensive land use, but only certain landowners reap the benefits. Under the equity principle that the public sector cannot favor one citizen over another, public investments and regulations affecting land values must be uniform across a city. If they are not, the government must take measures to redistribute the benefits and burdens of those investments and regulations. Capturing incremental land value for the benefit of society can take a variety of forms, including taxes, contributions, fees, exactions, and regulatory charges (Smolka and Amborski 2007; Smolka 2013). These tools vary from explicit (such as betterment contributions) to implicit (such as land leasing, land banking, and expropriation). Other options include land readjustment, which involves negotiations with landowners that would potentially benefit from an urbanization project, and exactions, which are fees paid for specific land use concessions or flexibility. The revenues collected by value capture tools are included in the municipal budget and are typically managed by the local treasury secretary, although some proceeds may take the form of in-kind compensation.
3.5.2 Growing Popularity of Land Value Capture The notion of paying for the benefits of public investments was well established as early as the Roman Empire, and countries from Europe to the Far East have used a variety of value capture tools ever since that time. Recent applications include a newly granted right in England to tax the increase in value from the rezoning of land, and charges in France for building rights over and above a certain baseline density. In Spain, municipalities capture part of the value increase of urban expansion by requiring landowners to cede some serviced building plots to the municipality, provide the land needed for infrastructure, and pay the costs of service provision, overhead, and a profit margin (Muñoz Gielen 2010). In Latin America, Colombia’s Law 388 of 1997 and the Brazil’s Statute of the Cities of 2001 set the parameters for much of the legislation passed elsewhere in the region. Colombia’s Law 388 introduced the notion that public actions that improve urban land uses, including air space, give the public the right to participate in the resulting land value increments. The law also specifies the sources of these benefits— conversion of rural land to urban uses, changes to zoning and density regulations, and higher allowable rates of land occupation—and the share that local or district councils may take from those sources. National and local legislation throughout Latin America now includes provisions for some form of value capture. Several factors account for this growing popularity. The global trend toward fiscal decentralization—giving municipalities greater fiscal autonomy but also greater responsibility for service provision—has pushed local governments to find new revenue sources. Meanwhile, cities around the world face the challenge of funding a growing backlog of infrastructure improvements. Indeed, in the United States alone, the gap in infrastructure investment has been estimated at over $3.6 trillion. With
182
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
governments also under pressure to address social inequalities, value capture tools provide a way to mobilize new and more flexible funds to finance special public programs.
3.5.3 Relationship of Value Capture to Property Taxation Property taxes may be a form of value capture in that, aside from taxing building values, they apply to accumulated increments in land value. This fact has led to the misconception that implementing value capture tools is “on top of” property taxes and thus represents double taxation. But as the Brazilian Supreme Court has ruled, value capture is not a tax but rather a charge imposed for the use of “additional building rights that are not part of the owner’s assets but a public good that belongs to the city as a whole” (Rabello de Castro 2012, 18). In essence, one cannot be taxed for something one does not own. Similarly, to a land value tax, charges for additional building rights fall entirely on landowners, do not distort the economics of land use decisions, and do not generate the excess burden (deadweight loss) common to most taxes (Oates and Schwab 2009). Another advantage of value capture tools is that they have the potential to fully capture the value of public expenditures for infrastructure and service improvements, changes in norms and regulations affecting land uses, and other locational attributes that are capitalized in land prices, while property taxes do not. Lastly, from the strict point of raising overall local public revenues the property tax is likely to be more effective than value capture. In effect, the former may be accomplished with better fiscal practices as for example updating existing cadasters and value maps, review of exemptions, improving taxpayers’ compliance incentives and the like. The weak technical expertise to promote such improvements reinforced by the unpopularity of the property tax and mounting resistance to any increase in the overall tax burden creates though a barrier to count much on property tax reforms to raise local revenues. The non-tributary nature of most value capture tools - in especial those associated to charges to building rights - added to its designation for capital expenditures is attractive to local authorities eager to promote large scale urban redevelopments projects especially in degraded areas and/or investments in urban infrastructure or in social housing in general.
3.5.4 Evolution of Charges for Building Rights in São Paulo As noted earlier, exactions compel landowners to make cash or in-kind contributions in exchange for special approvals to develop or build on their land. These contributions may be stipulated through subdivision or development agreements or negotiated on an individual basis. While exactions are the most common land-based financing tool used around the world, officials are often unaware that they are a form of value
3.5 Charges to Building Rights: A Notable Value Capture Experience …
183
Fig. 3.16 Owners of the two buildings shown here, located in Curitiba, Brazil, both paid for the right to build at densities above the basic FAR of about six stories. The building design on the left highlights the area for which building rights were charged © Gislene Pereira
capture. For example, linkage operations are a type of exaction, allowing developers to build at a higher density or floor area ratio (FAR) in exchange for contributions toward affordable housing or other community benefits. In Brazil, building charges have evolved over time from ad hoc exactions into set fees calculated according to predefined criteria and applied to all properties in a specific area. In 2014, the City of São Paulo instituted a basic FAR of 1 that gives all landowners the same building rights, and a maximum FAR that ranges from 1 to 4 depending on city zoning. By setting a universal basic FAR and charging for any additions to that FAR, the city managed to split the interests of developers and landowners, practically eliminating major legal appeals to charges for additional building rights (Outorga Onerosa do Direito de Construir, OODC). These charges are based on the notion that the right to develop land at densities above the basic FAR must be bought from the public as the legitimate owner of those rights. OODC also applies to other types of administrative changes that yield more profitable land uses, such as conversions from rural to urban uses or the rezoning of areas for renovation or commercial purposes.41 The value that developers are willing to pay for these additional building rights is substantial. In São Paulo’s high-end neighborhoods, for example, the charges for building structures that are two or three times higher than the basic FAR are often well over US$500 per additional square meter (Sandroni 2011 op. cit.) (Fig. 3.16). To get a sense of the revenues to be generated from building rights charges, take the following concrete case (simplified for exposition purposes). A developer is interested in a plot of land with 3,200 square meters (at US$6.4 million), and the 41
A variant of charges for such changes in building rights is given by the 1997 Law 388 in Colombia through the Participación en Plusvalías instrument, whereby 30 to 50 percent of the assessed increased land values resulting from administrative actions may also be subject to partial recovery by the public. (Maldonado Copello M M, Smolka M O 2003).
184
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
goal is to build a structure of 8,000 square meters based on the maximum FAR of 2.5. This implies an additional area of 4,800 square meters (1.5 additional FAR × 3,200 sqm). The right to build at this higher density to be acquired for US$9.6 million, or at a cost of US$2,000 per additional buildable square meter. This is the amount the developer would have to pay for another neighboring plot of land with 4,800 square meters and a FAR of 1 to be able to build at the same density. In practice, the formula for calculating building charges is of course more complicated. The developer built a 27-story structure of 16,500 square meters, since about 8,500 square meters of the area used for garage, terraces, and other uses are considered as “non-computable.” That is, the additional 4,800 sqms (additional FAR of 1.5) is net of all these uses. Moreover, the assessed value of land, that goes into the formula to calculate the compensation, is often short from the full market value. That is, aside from a neighboring plot may not be available the additional building rights (virtual plots) are usually acquired at lower than the imputed value for such benchmark plot. In addition, from the developer’s perspective, building at higher density on the original 3,200 square-meter plot may be more profitable depending on economies of scale and other factors related to high-rise versus low-rise designs. To get a sense of the revenues to be generated from building rights charges, take the simplified case of a developer buying a parcel with 3,200 square meters priced at $6.4 million. The goal is to build a structure of 8,000 square meters based on the maximum FAR for the area of 2.5. To do so, the developer has to buy the rights to build at that higher density by adding the cost of 4,800 square meters (1.5 additional FAR × 3,200 sqm) to the purchase price.??? The US$2,000 charge per additional buildable square meter brings the total cost of the parcel to US$9.6 million. This is the amount it would cost the developer to buy a neighboring plot of land with 4,800 square meters and a FAR of 1 to build at the desired density. In practice, the formula for calculating building charges is of course more complicated. Say the developer in this case builds a 27-story structure of 16,500 square meters, but about 8,500 square meters of the area are used for a garage, terraces, and other “non-computable” uses, i.e., the additional 4,800 square meters of buildable space is net of these uses. From the developer’s perspective, building at higher density on the original 3,200 square-meter plot may be more profitable than buying a larger plot depending on economies of scale and other factors related to high-rise versus low-rise designs. The redistributive power of OODCs is considerable. The $9.6 million collected for this single project could subsidize some 320 new units of social housing. In other words, the cost of each of the 32 additional luxury apartments would pay for 10 low-income housing units. The City of São Paulo collected more than US$1 billion in payments from building rights from 2006 to 2017. But even accounting for the slowdown in collections during Brazil’s recent recession, revenues from OODCs have fallen far short of their potential for several reasons. In particular, the city did not set a universal basic FAR until recently, and the cadaster values used to bench building charges are known to be vary in accuracy according to zones not rarely falling below 30 percent of the full market value. Moreover, discounting factors applied for certain structures (e.g.,
3.5 Charges to Building Rights: A Notable Value Capture Experience …
185
environmentally sustainable buildings), exemptions for social housing and other noncomputable areas of a high-rise (often above 50% of the total area as in lobby hall, playgrounds, balconies etc.), further reduce the potential net collection on public sales of building rights. At their full potential, revenues from additional building charges could account for well over 50 percent of local investment capacity adding at least 40 percent to the amount currently allocated to social housing and urban infrastructure. When sales of Certificates of Additional Potential Construction Bonds (CEPACs) are included, the pool of funds available for public investments would be even higher.
3.5.5 São Paulo’s Success with CEPACs Certificates of Additional Potential Construction Bonds (CEPACs) are a special form of building rights charges that are used to finance urban operations (UOs), i.e., largescale projects in delimited areas and supported by improved infrastructure. These redevelopment projects typically have building rights over and above those imposed by existing zoning ordinances. Unlike OODC payments that are managed from the general fund, CEPAC revenues must be invested in infrastructure and social housing within the UO area. CEPACs are an ingenious answer to the difficult task of valuing building rights because the cost of the bonds is based on how much developers are willing to pay for those additional rights in a competitive market. The bonds are issued by the municipality and regulated by the Comissão de Valores Mobiliários (CVM, the Brazilian equivalent of the US Securities and Exchange Commission) and then sold by electronic auction in the São Paulo Stock Exchange. CEPACS were sanctioned by the Brazilian Land Development Act of 2001 and implemented in 2004. CEPACs offer some noteworthy advantages. First of all, they address the difficult issue of assessing the market value of the increment resulting from public investments in UOs, and they reduce the transaction costs involved in negotiating the impacts of the project on individual properties. In addition, CEPAC auctions help local administrations anticipate the funds they need to invest in urban infrastructure and services in the redevelopment project. Moreover, selling CEPACs in tranches makes it possible to monitor and finely calibrate the market. The fact that the funds are earmarked also reinforces developers’ confidence in the system and prevents legal appeals. Auctions of CEPACs may be public (to acquire development rights) or private (as a currency with which to pay contractors). The face value of a new offering of CEPACs starts with the value from the previous auction. In the seven auctions for the Faria Lima UO, for example, the offered value started at US$550 in 2004 and ended at US$2,100 in 2010. Values for the Agua Espraiada UO increased from US$172 in 2004 to US$636 in 2012. All CEPACs offered were sold in 8 of the 15 auctions, and bidders paid large premiums in 9 of those auctions. Counting the revenues from just these two UOs, the city raised more than US$2.7 billion.
186
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
CEPACss have been used to finance a variety of infrastructure investments and social programs. For example, revenues helped to put to defray US$150 million of the costs for the São Paulo’s new Ouro metro line and supported construction of an iconic bridge that cost over US$100 million. Some $57 million of the CEPAC funds were also used to develop new homes for 552 families from Jardim Edith, a slum located in one of the city’s most expensive areas. to new social housing in a neighboring area. Although São Paulo has been the most successful, other Brazilian cities have also issued CEPACs. For instance, all of the building rights issued for the Porto Maravilha revitalization project in Rio de Janeiro’s old port area were sold to a single buyer, the Real Estate Development Fund created by Caixa Econômica Federal (CEF), the Brazilian social and housing bank. Law 101 of November 2009 had authorized issuing 6,436,722 CEPACs for a total of 4,089,502 square meters of additional building rights at a cost US$1.75 billion. The municipality of Rio de Janeiro thus obtained substantial upfront funds to cover the costs of redevelopment. In addition, responsibility for auctioning CEPACS for this project in the future falls to CEF rather than the city. CEPACs are also partially funding the ‘Linha Verde’ UO in Curitiba (Soffiatti 2012). This project involved converting a congested national highway into an urban avenue, including extension of a bus rapid transit line, addition of new green areas, and increases to land use density. For this US$600 million investment, a municipal decree in 2012 authorized the release of 4,830,000 CEPACs and a minimum initial price of US$100 per CEPAC. The first auction attracted 18 bidders for the 141,588 bonds offered, and a group of three bidders associated with a shopping center development acquired 70 percent of the CEPACs.
3.6 Conclusions Value capture policies and tools are undeniably gaining new acceptability around the world. Initiatives to experiment with the basic economic principles behind value capture have grown in both number and innovation, and value capture tools are often being used in combination with traditional revenue-generation efforts. Public authorities are beginning to realize that they can raise substantial revenues to support the public good from the beneficiaries of their administrative decisions. They can negotiate and charge for changes in land use rights to generate those revenues, while also promoting a fairer distribution of the social costs and private benefits of urbanization. It is however important to notice that successful application of the charge to building rights bears heavily on the local administration capacity of the public to enforce zoning and other land use regulation codes. A stagnant property market would obviously offer no opportunity to apply such tools. Similarly a mot much may be expected from sprawling low density cities that may at best recover some land value increments from the conversion of rural to urban or the changes of residential to commercial uses. In such cases local authorities would better rely
References
187
on other value capture tools such as land readjustment, betterment contributions or direct exactions applied to specially favored land developers. Although the actual dollar value of revenues generated from value capture is still relatively small, the examples of São Paulo’s application of OODC to high-end individual projects and the auctioning of building rights through CEPACs show that the potential payoffs are significant. At the same time, the impact of value capture policies on real estate development has been minimal and developers’ willingness to pay is directly linked to perceived benefits. In sum, tools like the charges to building rights are meant to cities experimenting vigorous vertical growth promoted by independent (from landowners’) developers seeking profits from innovative building processes and products rather than speculative operations with land. Note that charges to building rights fall in essence on the landowner having no major bearing on developers. The only difference being that rather than paying the land value increment resulting from a higher FAR to the landowner the developer now pays for the ‘city’ the legitimate owner of the ‘created land’ supported by the investments in urban infrastructure and services paid by the collectivity! Changing from a regime where landowners capitalize unearned income from public investments to one where private benefits are balanced with social costs requires a major cultural shift—one that is likely to meet significant resistance. But the future of cities now depends on developing effective land-based tools to finance urban development, and planners and local treasuries alike should consider adding value capture instruments to their toolboxes. Indeed, improved understanding of the links between public investments and increases in land value is an essential part of building new fiscal and planning cultures that will strengthen collection of property taxes and other local revenues while improving urban management overall.
References Angel, S., and Stephen K. M. 1996. Enabling Policies and their Effects on Housing Sector Performance: A Global Comparison. Presented at the Habitat II Conference, Istanbul, Turkey (June). Arzaghi, M. and J. V. Henderson. 2005. Why Countries are Fiscally Decentralizing. Journal of Public Economics, 89(2005): 1157-1189. Beramendi, P. 2012. The Political Geography of Inequality: Regions and Redistribution. Cambridge University Press. Beramendi, P., M. Rogers, and A. Diaz Cayeros. 2017. Barriers to Egalitarianism: Distributive Tensions in Latin American Federations. Latin American Research Review 52(4): 529–551. Blanco B., Andrés G. Moreno M., Nancy, Vetter, David M., Vetter. Marcia F. 2017. The Potential of Land Value Capture for financing urban projects: methodological considerations and case studies IADB Monograph; 494. Bonet, J., A. Muñoz, and C. Pineda. 2014. El potencial oculto – Factores determinantes y oportunidades del impuesto a la propiedad inmobiliaria en América Latina. Bonet, Muñoz, and Pineda, editors. IDB.
188
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
Bouchet, M, Liu, S, Parilla, J & Kabbani, N. 2018. Global Metro Monitor, 2018. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution. Bouillon, Cesar Patricio. 2012. Room for development: Housing markets in Latin America and the Caribbean. Hampshire, UK: Palgrave Macmillan Ltd. for Inter-American Development Bank. Boueri, R., C. Mac Dowell, E. Pineda, and F. Bastos. 2014. Analysis of Public Spending. An Evaluation Methodology for Measuring the Efficiency of Brazilian State Spending on Education. Discussion paper IDB-DP-361. IDB. Borrero Ochoa, Oscar. 2018. Economia Urbana Y Plusvalia Del Suelo, Editorial Bhandar, Bogota Colombia, primera edición. “Botswana: Investing in Botswana”. Foreign direct investment Investment framework and opportunities Lloyds Bank. Britannica. 2014. Constitutional Law. Unitary and federal systems. Encyclopedia Britannica, online edition. Brollo, F., T. Nannicini, R. Perotti, and G. Tabellini. 2013. The Political Resource Curse. American Economic Review, 103(5): 1759–1796, August. Canavire, G., J. Martínez Vázquez, and B. Yedgenov. 2016. Re-examining the Determinants of Fiscal Decentralization: What is the Role of Geography? Journal of Economic Geography. Caselli, F. and Micheals, G. 2013. Do Oil Windfalls Improve Living Standards? Evidence from Brazil. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 5, pages 208-238. Cheeseman, N. and Burbidge, D. 2016. “Principles of municipal finance.” in Kamiya, M & Zhang, LY (eds.), Finance for City Leaders Handbook: Improving municipal finances to deliver better services [2nd Ed.], pp. 4–15. Nairobi: UN-Habitat. Derek J. Hudson. 1993. Increasing the Own Source Revenues and Fiscal Authority/Accountability of Local Authorities: A Preliminary Review of some Alternatives. Derek J. Hudson. 1994. Financial Arrangements for local Government- Some Comments on the Botswana Situation. A Paper presented at the sub-regional workshop sponsored by Frederick Ebert Stiftung in co-operation with SADC 1 - 3 Dec. 1994. DNP. 2017. Nueva medición del desempeño municipal. Primer informe de resultados 2016. DNP, Colombia. Dobbs, R., Pohl, H., Lin, D. Y., Mischke, J., Garemo, N., Hexter, J., Matzinger, S., Palter, R. and Nanavatty, R. 2013. Infrastructure Productivity: How to save $1 trillion a year. New York: McKinsey Global Institute. ECLAC. 2011b. Macroeconomic Challenges of Fiscal Decentralization in Latin America in the Aftermath of the Global Financial Crisis. J. P. Jiménez and T. Ter-Minassian. ECLAC. ECLAC. 2011c. El financiamiento de los gobiernos subnacionales en América Latina: Un análisis de casos. J. C. Gómez Sabaini and J. P. Jiménez. ECLAC. 2012. The Inter-governmental Allocation of Revenue from Natural Resources: Finding a Balance between Centripetal and Centrifugal Pressure. Chapter 10 in “Decentralization and Reform in Latin America,” edited by Brosio and Jiménez, ECLAC. Egner, B. 1987. The District Councils and decentralization, 1978–1986. A consultancy report to SIDA. Mimeo. Eguino, H. A., Porto, C. Pineda, M. Garriga, and W. Rosales. 2010. Estudio de las características estructurales del sector municipal en América Latina. Discussion paper IDB-DP-145. IDB. Eguino, H.,and Radics, A. 2018. Next Steps for Decentralization and Subnational Governments In Latin America and the Caribbean. IDB. Eustice, J. B. Financial Management and revenues of Local Authorities: A Report of the Local Government Structure Commission. Ferraz, C. and Finan, F. 2011. Electoral Accountability and Corruption: Evidence from the Audits of Local Governments. American Economic Review 101: 1274–311. Ferraz, C. and Monteiro, J. 2010. Does oil make leaders unaccountable? Evidence from Brazil’s offshore oil boom, mimeo PUC-Rio. Ferraz, C. F., Finan, and D. Moreira. 2012. Corrupting Learning. Journal of Public Economics 96(9-10): 712–726.
References
189
Fretes Cibils V, Ter-Minassian T. Descentralizando los ingresos fiscales en América Latina: por qué y cómo[J]. Washingon, DC: BID, (2015). Gail Hurley. 2018. Meeting the Urban Finance Challenges. UNDP- Posted on February 13, 2018. Gaborone City Council. 2000. Urban Development Plan 2 pg.40) Government Printer, Gaborone Government of Botswana. 1991. National Development Plan 7 - Government Printer, Gaborone. Government of Botswana. 1987. Local Governments (district Councils) Chapter 40:01, Government Printer, Gaborone. https://www.ceicdata.com/en/indicator/botswana/foreign-direct-invest ment--of-nominal-gdp FDI Investment in Botswana. Herrera, P. and Francke, P. 2007. Análisis de la eficiencia del gasto municipal y de sus determinantes. Pontífica Universidad Católica del Perú. Lima, Peru. IDB. 2010a. Peru—Modernization of the Public Financial Administration System to Improve Public Resource Programming, Execution, and Reporting. Loan proposal PE-L1087. IDB. IDB. 2012a. Peru—Improvement of Territorial Public Investment Management. Loan proposal PEL1101. IDB. IDB. 2013a. Development in the Americas—More than Revenue: Taxation as a Development Tool. Corbacho, Fretes Cibils, and Lora, eds. Chapter 5—“Local Taxes for Local Development.” IDB. IDB. 2013d. Peru—Improving the National Control System for Effective Public Management and Integrity. Loan proposal PE-L1132. IDB. IDB. 2014b. Mexico. Public Finance Strengthening Program. ME-L1144. IDB. IDB. 2014e. Mega-Cities & Infrastructure in Latin America: What its people think. BR-121. IDB. IDB. 2017. Citizen Security and Justice. https://www.iadb.org/en/citizen-security/citizen-securityand-justice. IDB. 2018. Fiscal Decentralization and Subnational Governments. Document GN-2813–8. IDB. IERAL. 2017. Informe de Coyuntura del IERAL. Edición Nº 1028, 23 de Febrero de 2017. IERAL&Fundación Mediterránea. Infrascope. 2013. Evaluando el entorno para las asociaciones público-privadas en ALC. Guía del índice y metodología. Economist Intelligence Unit. Llempén, Z., E. Morón, and C. Seminario. 2010. Descentralización y desempeño fiscal subnacional: el caso de Perú. In “Descentralización and sostenibilidad fiscal subnacional: los casos de Colombia y Perú.” Del Valle and Galindo, editors, IDB. Lloyds Bank Trade. 2019. “Botswana: Investing in Botswana” Foreign direct investment framework and opportunities. Loayza, N., J. Rigolini, and O. Calvo-González. 2014. More Than You Can Handle: Decentralization and Spending Ability of Peruvian Municipalities. Policy Research Working Paper, August 2011, World Bank. Lora, E. 2007. The State of State Reform in Latin America, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Maldonado Copello M M, Smolka M O. 2003. Using value capture to benefit the poor: The Usme project in Colombia[J]. Land Lines, 15(3): 15–17. Machado, F. 2013. Decentralization and Accountability: The Curse of Local Underdevelopment. IDB Working Paper Series IDB-WP-397. Maldonado, Copello, Maria, Mercedes. 2008. La Ley 388 de 1997 en Colombia: Algunos puntos de tensión en el proceso de su implementación. Arquitectura, Ciudad y Entorno, Ano III, 7 (Junio). Barcelona, Spain. Maldonado, S. 2011. Resource Windfalls and Corruption: Evidence from Peru. Unpublished manuscript. U.C. Berkeley. Martínez-Vázquez, J. 2010. Local Public Finances in the Latin America Region. In GOLD II, “Second Global Report on Decentralization and Local Democracy—Local Government Finance: The Challenges of the 21st Century.” United cities and local governments. Martinez-Vasquez. 2011. “Municipal Finances in Latin America: Features, Issues, and Prospects”. International Studies Program. Working Paper 11–07; April 2011. Andrew Young School of Policy Studies. Georgia State University. Atlanta, Georgia, US.
190
3 Experience & Methods of Global Municipal Finance
Martínez-Vázquez, J. and C. Sepúlveda. 2012. Intergovernmental Transfers: A Policy Reform Perspective. Chapter 9 in “Decentralization and reform in Latin America,” edited by Brosio and Jiménez, ECLAC. MLGRD. Department of Local Government Finance and Procurement (2016). Annual Accounts. Government Printer, Gaborone. Mosha A. C. 2001. “Local Democracy and Decentralisation in Botswana”—Report prepared for the Global Campaign for Good Governance, UN-HABITAT, Nairobi, Kenya. Mosha A. C. 2002. “Decentralization in Botswana: Situation Assessment and Policy Review”. Paper submitted to the Local Government Review Commission. Gaborone, Botswana. Mosha A. C. 2010. Challenges of Municipal Finance in Africa with special reference to Gaborone city, Botswana- UN-Habitat, Nairobi, Kenya Muñoz Gielen, Demetrio. 2010. Capturing value increase in urban redevelopment: A study of how the economic value increase in urban redevelopment can be used to finance the necessary public infrastructure and other facilities. Lieden, The Netherlands: Sidestone Press. Muñoz, A. E. Pineda, and A. Radics. 2017. Descentralización fiscal y disparidades regionales en América Latina: el potencial de las transferencias de igualación. December 2017, IDB. Ndegwa, Stephen N. 2002. Decentralization in Africa: A Stocktaking Survey. Africa Region Working Paper Series no. 40. Washington D.C.: World Bank. Oates, Wallace E., and Robert M. Schwab. 2009. The Simple Analytics of Land Value Taxation. In Land Value Taxation: Theory, Evidence, and Practice, eds. Richard F. Dye and Richard W. England, 57–72. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy. Olowu D. 2002. The Political Economy of Fiscal Decentralisation in Africa. OECD & UCLG. 2016. Subnational Governments Around the World: Structure and finance. Paris: OECD. OECD/United Cities and Local Government. 2016. Subnational Governments Around the World. OECD/United Cities and Local Government. Peterson, E. R., Hales, M., Peña, A. M., Dessibourg-Freer, N. (2018). 2018 Global Cities Report: Learning from the East: Insights from China’s urban success. Chicago: A.T. Kearney. Pimenta, C. 2015. Desafíos and propuestas para la gestión financiera pública de los estados Brasileños. Mimeo, IDB. Rabello de Castro, Sonia. 2012. Faculty profile. Land Lines 24(1): 18–19. Rasteletti, A. and J. Acosta. 2016. Evaluación de los efectos de la Ley de Disciplina Financiera de las Entidades Federativas y Municipios sobre los Resultados Fiscales y Estimación del Ahorro Financiero Fiscal. Cambridge University Press. Reyes, Fernando. 1980. El sistema de valorizacion y sus implicaciones economicas. Thesis. Bogotá, Colombia: Universidad de Bogotá Jorge Tadeo Lozano. Rezende, F. and J. Veloso. 2012. Intergovernmental Transfers in Subnational Finances. Chapter 8 in “Decentralization and Reform in Latin America,” edited by Brosio and Jiménez, ECLAC. Sandroni, Paulo Henrique. 2011. Urban value capture in São Paulo using a two-part approach: Created land (solo criado) and sale of building rights (outorga onerosa do direito de construir): An analysis of the impact of the basic coefficient of land use as a tool of the 2002 Master Plan. Working Paper. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy. Smolka, Martim O., and David Amborski. 2007. Value Capture for Urban Development: An InterAmerican Comparison. Working Paper. Cambridge, USA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy. Smolka, Martim O. 2013 Implementing Value Capture in Latin America: Policy and Tools for Urban Development, Policy Focus Report, Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, June. Soffiatti, Rubens Valério Franco. 2012. A contribuição de melhoria como instrumento de recuperação da Mais-Valia Fundiária Urbana: Estudo de caso Eixo Urbano “Linha Verde.” Masters Thesis. Curitiba, Paraná, Brasil: Pontifícia Universidade Católica Do Paraná, Escola de Arquitetura e Design, Programa de Pós-Graduação em Gestão Urbana. Tavares, I. and de Cavalcanti. 2014. Government Spending on Early Childhood in Brazil: Equity and Efficiency Challenges. Background paper for the Development in the Americas report on the early years. Inter-American Development Bank, Washington, D.C.
References
191
Triveno, L. and Smolka M.O. 2017 Budget-Strapped Cities are Creating Financing—Out of thin air, Sustainable Cities. http://blogs.worldbank.org/sustainablecities 09/18/2017 UCLG. 2007. UCLG Support Paper on Local Finance. Barcelona: United Cities and Local Governments. UCLG. 2016. GOLD IV: Co-Creating the Urban Future – The agenda of metropolises, cities and territories. Barcelona: United Cities and Local Governments. UCLG. 2018. Towards the Localization of the SDGs. Barcelona: United Cities and Local Governments. UNCTAD. 2014. World Investment Report 2014: Investing in the SDGs: An action plan. Geneva: United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. UNDESA. 2018. World Urbanization Prospects, 2018 Revision. Available at https://population.un. org/wup/ UNECA. 2017. Economic Report on Africa 2017: Urbanization and Industrialization for Africa’s Transformation. Addis Ababa: United Nations Economic Commission for Africa (UNECA). UNECA. 2019. The State of Urbanization in Africa: The Role of Cities in Domestic Resource Mobilization. Addis Ababa: United Nations Economic Commission for Africa (UNECA). UNCTAD. 2019a. World Investment Report 2019a, United Nations Publication Issued by the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, Geneva. UNCTAD. 2019b. World Investment Report 2019b, United Nations Publication Issued by the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, Geneva. UN-Habitat. 2012. “Saudi Arabia—Urban Economy: Enhancing Local Capacity for Efficient Urban Economy and Municipal Finance” [Blog post]. https://unhabitat.org/saudi-arabia-urban-eco nomy/ United Nations. 2015a. Transforming our World: The 2030 agenda for sustainable development. New York: United Nations. United Nations. 2015b. Addis Ababa Action Agenda of the Third International Conference on Financing for Development. New York: United Nations. Urrea, N. 2010. Descentralización y disciplina fiscal subnacional en Colombia. Presentation on the case of Colombia in the workshop on fiscal rules for macroeconomic stability, Lima, Peru. World Bank. 2010b. Project Appraisal Document on a Proposed Loan to the Republic of El Salvador for a Local Government Strengthening Project. Project ID-P118026. World Bank. 2019a. Economic Report 2019a. Washington, USA. World Bank. 2019b. Urban Development. [web page]. https://www.worldbank.org/en/topic/urband evelopment/overview World Bank. 2019c. https://www.worldbank.org/en/country/botswana/overview “Botswana Overview” 2019.
Chapter 4
Global Urban Economic Competitiveness Performance
Leading cities are particularly important for the competitiveness of global cities. The report shows that influenced by the decline in the average urban competitiveness of China, the United States and Europe, the average global urban competitiveness slightly declined. This also indicates that if the trade war between major countries continues, it will not only weaken the urban competitiveness of each country, but also weaken the global urban competitiveness and welfare.
4.1 Top 20 Cities: Fierce Competition Makes the Position Fluctuate Greatly, Global Comprehensive Centers and Technology Centers have Generally Improved, while Specialized Cities and Manufacturing Centers Declined Overall Overall, the top 20 cities in the world are highly competitive, with significant changes in rankings (16 cities have changed, with a maximum change of 4 ranking). The global integrated center and technology center have generally improved, and the professional and manufacturing cities have declined overall. According to the Global Urban Competitiveness Report 2019, New York, London, Singapore, Shenzhen, San Jose, Tokyo, San Francisco, Munich, Los Angeles, Shanghai, Dallas, Houston, Hong Kong, Dublin, Seoul, Boston, Beijing, Guangzhou, Miami, and Chicago rank globally Top 20. Table 4.1 shows the spatial distribution of the top 20 cities in the world. At the same time, the top 20 cities in the global economic competitiveness ranked relatively stable, and the rankings of 14 cities remained unchanged or rising, with only 6 cities ranking down. Table 4.2 shows the ranking changes in the city’s economic competitiveness.
© China Social Sciences Press 2023 P. Ni et al., The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-99-3553-6_4
193
194
4 Global Urban Economic Competitiveness Performance
Table 4.1 Top 20 cities in the global economic competitiveness Rank
City
Country
1
New York
America
2
London
United states
3
Singapore
Singapore
4
Shenzhen
5
San Jose
6 7
Poor ranking with 2018
Rank
City
Country
Poor ranking with 2018
0
11
Dallas-Fort Worth
America
1
1
12
Houston
America
−2
−1
13
Hong Kong
China
−2
China
0
14
Dublin
Ireland
2
America
0
15
Seoul
South Korea
0
Tokyo
Japan
2
16
Boston
America
2
San Francisco-Oakland
America
0
17
Beijing
China
2
8
Munich
Germany
−2
18
Guangzhou
China
−4
9
Los Angeles
America
0
19
Miami
America
−2
10
Shanghai
China
3
20
Chicago
America
1
Source CCC of CASS
Table 4.2 Top 20 city ranking changes No change in rank
Rise 1 bit
Rise 2 bit
Rise 3 bit
New York, Shenzhen, San Jose, San Francisco, Los Angeles, Seoul
London, Dallas, Chicago
Tokyo, Dublin, Boston, Beijing
Shanghai
Decrease 1 bit Decrease 2 bit
Decrease 4 bit
Singapore
Guangzhou
Munich, Houston, Hong Kong
Source CCC of CASS
In terms of sub-index rankings, the economic growth in San Francisco, Shanghai, Dallas, Houston, Guangzhou, and Chicago has declined slightly, and the rankings in New York, Singapore, and Miami have not changed; The economic density of Shenzhen, San Jose, San Francisco, Los Angeles, Shanghai, Houston, Hong Kong, Guangzhou and Miami has declined slightly, and the rankings of Singapore and Munich have not changed. Table 4.3 gives a statistical description of the economic competitiveness of the top 20 cities in the world. The performance of the top 20 cities in the world has intensified. Compared with 2018, the standardization index of economic increment and economic competitiveness of the top 20 cities in the world declined slightly in 2019, indicating that the overall lead has slowed down. The standard deviation and coefficient of variation of economic increments were expanded from 0.091 and 0.103 in 2018 to 0.116 and
4.2 Top 200 Cities: Europe Has More Cities Declined in the Ranking While …
195
Table 4.3 Descriptive statistics on the economic competitiveness of the top 20 cities in the world Economic Economic Economic Economic Economic Economic increment increment density density competitiveness competitiveness 2019 2018 2019 2018 2019 2018 mean
0.757
0.888
0.775
0.739
0.807
0.878
median
0.78
0.92
0.78
0.738
0.793
0.884
variance
0.116
0.091
0.115
0.115
0.061
0.064
Coefficient 0.153 of variation
0.103
0.148
0.156
0.076
0.072
minimum
0.523
0.697
0.557
0.542
0.721
0.796
maximum
1
1
1
1
1
1
Source CCC of CASS
0.153 in 2019, respectively. The coefficient of variation of economic competitiveness output increased from 0.072 in 2018 to 0.076, indicating an increase in internal differentiation.
4.2 Top 200 Cities: Europe Has More Cities Declined in the Ranking While Asia Has More Cities Improved Compared with 2018, 200 cities were led by North America in 2019, and some cities in Europe and Asia declined. Table 4.4 shows the results of the top 200 cities in the world. The results in Table 4.4 show that the decline in the economic competitiveness of European cities accounts for a maximum of 54.2%, the proportion of economic competitiveness in South American cities decreases by a minimum of 25%, and the decline of Asian cities is 31% less than that of North America is 35.2%, Less than the average of the top 200 cities fell by 38.5%. Figure 4.1 shows the spatial distribution of the competitiveness rankings of the top 200 cities in 2018 and 2019. Figure 4.1 shows the spatial distribution of economic growth and economic density rankings in the top 200 cities in 2018 and 2019.1 Figure 4.1 shows the spatial distribution of economic growth and economic density rankings for the top 200 cities in 2018 and 2019. Figure 4.1 shows that compared with 2018, the number of European cities in the world’s top 200 cities has declined more than the rising number, while the level of economic competitiveness in Asian cities has increased more than the number of declines. The level rises and falls by the same amount in North America cities.
1
The circle indicates a drop, the solid point indicates a rise, the large circle or large point indicates a large change, and the small circle or small dot indicates a small change. The same below.
71
4
48
6
North America
South America
Europe
Oceania
Source CCC of CASS
200
71
Asia
total
total
change
Number
0
8
122
1
0
4
3
constant
3
29
3
47
40
Rise
70
3
18
1
20
28
Decline
35%
50%
37.5%
25%
28.2%
39.4%
Decrease ratio
Economic growth (compared to 2018)
116
3
24
3
45
41
Rise
12
0
6
0
3
3
constant
72
3
18
1
26
27
Decline
36%
0.50%
37.5%
25%
32.4%
38%
Decrease ratio
Economic density (compared to 2018)
Table 4.4 Comparison of the top 200 cities’ economic competitiveness upgrade
112
3
21
3
39
46
Rise
11
0
1
0
7
3
constant
77
3
26
1
25
22
Decline
38.5%
50%
54.2%
25%
35.2%
31%
Decrease ratio
Economic competitiveness (compared to 2018)
196 4 Global Urban Economic Competitiveness Performance
4.2 Top 200 Cities: Europe Has More Cities Declined in the Ranking While …
197
Fig. 4.1 Global top 200 cities competitiveness performance
Table 4.5 Descriptive statistics on the economic competitiveness of the top 200 cities in the world Economic increment 2019
Economic increment 2018
Economic increment 2019
Economic increment 2018
0.56
0.62
0.527
0.594
0.593
0.657
0.56
0.636
variance
0.107
Coefficient of variation
0.19
0.115
0.104
0.11
0.186
0.176
0.167
minimum maximum
0.443
0.471
0.481
0.512
1
1
1
1
0.639
0.707
0.715
0.782
0.606
0.684
0.685
0.745
variance
0.099
0.101
0.088
0.092
Coefficient of variation
0.156
0.143
0.123
0.117
minimum
0.528
0.573
0.61
0.669
maximum
1
1
1
1
mean median
mean median
Top200 cities
Top100 cities
Top150 cities
Top500 cities
Source CCC of CASS
Table 4.5 gives descriptive statistics on the economic competitiveness of the top 200 cities in the world. It is not difficult to find that the average competitiveness of the top 200, 150, 100, and 50 global cities has dropped from 0.62, 0.657, 0.707, and 0.782 to 0.56, 0.593, 0.639, and 0.715, respectively, and the coefficient of variation is from 0.186, 0.167, 0.143 and 0.117 expanded to 0.19, 0.176, 0.156 and 0.123, respectively. And the competition and differentiation between cities increased.
198
4 Global Urban Economic Competitiveness Performance
4.3 Top 10 Urban Agglomerations: Northern California Has the Highest Average and Rhein-Ruhr Has the Smallest Internal Difference Figure 4.2 shows the top ten urban clusters including Seoul Capital Area, Northeast Megalopolis, United States, Western Metropolitan Region United States, Northern California Megaregion, Mumbai Metropolitan Region, London-Liverpool Corridor, Yangtze River Delta, Pearl River Delta, Netherlands-Belgium Metropolitan Region and Rhine-Ru Metropolitan Region An annual comparison of the performance of the city’s economic competitiveness. From Fig. 4.2, we can see that the economic competitiveness of the world’s top ten urban clusters is intensifying, and the urban clusters in East Asia, Western Europe and North America show significant differentiation. Table 4.6 shows the statistical description of 10 urban clusters in Seoul Capital Area, Northeast Megalopolis, United States, Western Metropolitan Region United States, Northern California Megaregion, Mumbai Metropolitan Region, LondonLiverpool Corridor, Yangtze River Delta, Pearl River Delta, Netherlands-Belgium Metropolitan Region and Rhine-Ruhr Metropolitan Region. It can be seen from Table 4.6 that the average economic competitiveness of the northern California Megaregion is 0.707, the lowest value of the urban competitiveness of the Mumbai Megaregion region is 0.241, and the variance of the Rhein-Ruhr urban cluster variance and the coefficient of variation were 0.051 and 0.085, the variance and coefficient of variation of the Seoul metropolitan area were 0.197 and 0.31, respectively. At the same time, the ranks of the Northern California Megaregion have risen and range increased. The Seoul Capital area, the Yangtze River Delta and the Pearl River Delta ranked higher but range smaller, while the northeastern US Megaregion, the Midwestern Megaregion, and the London-Liverpool Corridor, Netherlands-Belgian
Fig. 4.2 Spatial distribution of the world’s top 10 urban cluster
0.471
0.121
variance
0.495
mean
Yangtze River Delta
0.549
Coefficient of variation
median
0.132
variance
0.199
0.241
mean
Mumbai Metropolitan Region
0.137
Coefficient of variation
median
0.077
variance
0.556
0.561
mean
Midwest Megalopolis, U.S
0.31
Coefficient of variation
median
0.197
variance
0.636
0.636
Seoul Capital Area
median
mean
Economic increment 2019
0.127
0.515
0.544
0.529
0.137
0.22
0.26
0.138
0.086
0.63
0.623
0.276
0.186
0.676
0.676
Economic increment 2018
Pearl River Delta
London-Liverpool Corridor
Northern California Megaregion
Northeast Megalopolis, U.S
Table 4.6 Statistical description of the economic competitiveness of 10 typical urban clusters in the world
0.121
0.471
0.495
0.281
0.15
0.479
0.532
0.306
0.216
0.828
0.707
0.256
0.159
0.583
0.622
Economic increment 2019
0.127
0.515
0.544
0.247
0.148
0.557
0.599
0.333
0.259
0.929
0.78
0.203
0.138
0.656
0.682
(continued)
Economic increment 2018
4.3 Top 10 Urban Agglomerations: Northern California Has the Highest … 199
0.245
Coefficient of variation
Source CCC of CASS
0.121
variance
0.471
0.495
Netherlands-Belgian Metropolitan Region
mean
median
0.245
Economic increment 2019
Coefficient of variation
Table 4.6 (continued)
0.233
0.127
0.515
0.544
0.233
Economic increment 2018
Rhine-Ruhr Metropolitan Region
0.085
0.051
0.604
0.598
0.245
Economic increment 2019
0.068
0.046
0.688
0.679
0.233
Economic increment 2018
200 4 Global Urban Economic Competitiveness Performance
4.4 Three Main Economies: China Has More Cities Declined in the Ranking …
201
Metropolitan Region and the Rhine-Ruhr urban clusters have declined but are range smaller. The overall level of the Mumbai Metropolitan Region is poor but the rankings is stable.
4.4 Three Main Economies: China Has More Cities Declined in the Ranking, While Some European Cities Have Declined Steeply China, the United States and the European Union are the three engines of world economic development, and the changes in the level of urban economic power have attracted worldwide attention. Table 4.7 shows the results of the upgrade and competition of the three major economies in China, the United States and the European Union. Judging from the changes in urban economic competitiveness, the overall level of competitiveness of the three major economies in China, the United States and Europe has declined. The number of cities in the United States has less declined, and the number of cities in China has large declined. Compared with 2018, China’s urban economic increment, economic density, and economic competitiveness fell by 82.8%, 27.1%, and 62.5%, respectively. The decline in urban economic increment, economic density, and economic competitiveness in the United States was 29.3%, 37.3% and 36%, The EU’s urban economic increment, economic density and economic competitiveness fell by 37.5%, 37.5% and 47.5%, respectively. As a result, the number of cities in China’s urban economic increment and economic competitiveness has declined more than in the United States and the European Union. In order to more intuitive to see the economic increment and economic density of the three major economies. Figure 4.3 shows the comparison of the economic increment and economic density rankings of China, the United States and the European Union. It can be seen from Fig. 4.3 that the number of cities in the United States is decreasing, and the number of cities in China is decreasing. The level of urban competitiveness of the three major economic centers in China, the United States and the European Union varies widely. Table 4.8 gives a comparison of the statistical characteristics of urban economic competitiveness levels in China, the United States, and the European Union. The overall level of economic competitiveness of China and the United States has declined to a small extent, and the EU cities have experienced a large decline, and the Sino-US divides the EU to converge. Table 4.8 shows that the average economic competitiveness of China, the United States, and the European Union in 2019 decreased from 0.382, 0.603, and 0.536 in 2018 to 0.291, 0.545, and 0.476, respectively, and the EU declined significantly. At the same time, the competitiveness of cities in China and the United States has intensified, and the variation and coefficient of variation has slightly increased from 0.451 and 0.239 to 0.46 and 0.248, respectively. However, the overall differentiation of EU urban competitiveness has slowed down, and the coefficient of variation has dropped from 0.271 to 0.252.
6
25
122
European Union
Total
Source CCC of CASS
0
49
America
4
2
48
China
constant
Rise
Change
278
15
22
241
Decline
0.68.5%
0.37.5%
0.29.3%
0.82.8%
Decrease ratio
Economic growth (compared to 2018)
122
21
44
206
Rise
6
4
3
6
constant
278
15
28
79
Decline
0.30%
0.37.5%
0.37.3%
0.27.1%
Decrease ratio
Economic density (compared to 2018)
Table 4.7 Comparison of the changes in the economic competitiveness of the three major countries (regions)
164
20
41
103
Rise
14
1
7
6
constant
228
19
27
182
Decline
0.56.2%
0.47.5%
0.36%
0.62.5%
Decrease ratio
Economic competitiveness (compared to 2018)
202 4 Global Urban Economic Competitiveness Performance
4.5 Global Pattern: The Overall Level Has Declined, but the Divergence …
203
Fig. 4.3 China, the U.S and Europe economic growth (left) and economic density (right)
Table 4.8 Comparison of economic competitiveness of cities in China, the United States and the European Union Economic increment 2019
Economic increment 2018
Economic increment 2019
Economic increment 2018
0.291
0.328
0.545
0.603
median
0.254
variance
0.134
0.294
0.515
0.573
0.148
0.135
0.144
Coefficient of variation
0.46
0.451
0.248
0.239
minimum
0.085
0.089
0.295
0.326
0.84
0.932
1
1
0.479
0.526
–
–
0.46
0.497
–
–
variance
0.121
0.142
–
–
Coefficient of variation
0.252
0.271
–
–
minimum
0.275
0.145
–
–
maximum
0.876
0.933
–
–
mean
China
maximum mean median
Europe Union
America
–
Source CCC of CASS
4.5 Global Pattern: The Overall Level Has Declined, but the Divergence Has Narrowed. Table 4.9 gives a comparison table of the economic competitiveness levels of 1006 cities around the world. Compared with 2018, the average value of global urban economic competitiveness in 2019 decreased from 0.325 to 0.239, and the variance and coefficient of variation decreased from 0.186 and 0.571 to 0.166 and 0.568,
204
4 Global Urban Economic Competitiveness Performance
respectively. At the same time, the overall level of economic growth between cities has declined, but the economic density has risen slightly, and the economic increment and economic density between cities have intensified. Figure 4.4 shows the spatial distribution of the economic competitiveness of 1006 cities around the world. Figure 4.4 shows that cities with large global economic competitiveness and output are still mainly concentrated in Western Europe and North America. The number and size of cities with stronger economic competitiveness in East Asia is smaller than that in Western Europe and North America. From the perspective of upgrading the competitiveness of global cities, Europe and African cities have risen more and fallen less, while cities in Asia and North America have fallen more and risen less. Table 4.10 shows the results of the upgrade of the global economic competitiveness level. Table 4.9 Comparison table of economic competitiveness levels of 1006 cities in the world Economic Economic Economic Economic Economic Economic increment increment density density competitiveness competitiveness 2019 2018 2019 2018 2019 2018 mean
0.337
0.537
0.38
0.363
0.293
0.325
median
0.304
0.504
0.33
0.318
0.249
0.286
variance
0.103
0.092
0.201
0.191
0.166
0.186
Coefficient 0.307 of variation
0.172
0.529
0.527
0.568
0.571
minimum
0
0
0
0
0
0
maximum
1
1
1
1
1
1
Source CCC of CASS
Fig. 4.4 Spatial distribution of economic competitiveness output of 1006 cities worldwide
448
213
78
26
66
62
3
global
Asia
North America
South America
Africa
Europe
Oceania
Source CCC of CASS
Number of cities rising in ranking
region
0
2
0
1
4
2
10
Number of cities with the same ranking
4
62
36
48
49
349
548
Number of cities falling in ranking
57.1%
49.2%
35.3%
64%
37.4%
61.9%
54.5%
Rate of cities in the ranking declined
Economic growth (compared to 2018)
3
90
42
31
63
330
559
Number of cities rising in ranking
0
8
4
1
5
13
31
Number of cities with the same ranking
4
28
56
43
63
222
416
Number of cities falling in ranking
57.1%
22.2%
54.9%
57.3%
48.1%
39.3%
41.4%
Rate of cities in the ranking declined
Economic density (compared to 2018)
Table 4.10 Global urban economic competitiveness level upgrade comparison results
3
73
56
31
62
230
455
Number of cities rising in ranking
0
2
2
0
8
14
26
Number of cities with the same ranking
4
51
44
44
61
321
525
Number of cities falling in ranking
57.1%
22.2%
54.9%
57.3%
48.1%
39.3%
41.4%
Rate of cities in the ranking declined
Economic competitiveness (compared with 2018)
4.5 Global Pattern: The Overall Level Has Declined, but the Divergence … 205
206
4 Global Urban Economic Competitiveness Performance
Table 4.10 shows that the decline in urban economic increment in South America, Asia and Oceania accounted for 64%, 61.9% and 57.1% respectively higher than the global average of 54.5%, and the economic density of cities in North America, Africa and Oceania decreased 48.1%, 54.9%, and 57.1%, respectively, were higher than the global average of 41.4%, while the competitiveness of cities in North America, South America, and Oceania fell by 48.1%, 57.3%, and 57.1%, respectively, which were higher than the global average of 41.1%.
4.6 Global Sub-Regional Pattern: Northern China and Eastern Europe Declined While Southern China and India Rose in Ranking From the perspective of space, 100 degrees west longitude, 20 degrees east longitude and 110 degrees east longitude has become the watershed of urban economic competitiveness convergence area, and the level of economic competitiveness of high cities has risen to rise between 25–55 degrees north latitude, and other regions have differentiated significantly. Figure 4.5 shows the spatial distribution of global urban economic competitiveness by three meridians at the sub-regional level. It can be seen from Fig. 4.5 that the eastern city of 110 degrees west and 110 degrees east of 110 degrees east longitude is obviously superior to the western city, while the western city of 20 degrees east longitude is obviously superior to the eastern city, and the rectangular area between 25–55 degrees north latitude forms a city cluster. And the rectangular area between 25–55 degrees north latitude forms a watershed of the advantages and disadvantages of urban economic competitiveness. Not only that, the cities on both sides of the west longitude 100 degrees, the east longitude 20 degrees and the east longitude 110 degrees are obviously changing, and
Fig. 4.5 Spatial distribution of global urban competitiveness upgrade comparison
4.6 Global Sub-Regional Pattern: Northern China and Eastern Europe …
207
the competitiveness rankings of the cities of northern South America, Eastern Europe and West Asia converge. Table 4.11 shows the comparison of urban competitiveness between high-competitive regions and low-competitive regions in the world. From Fig. 4.5 and Table 4.11, the cities with increasing global competitiveness are mainly distributed in the west coast cities of the United States on the west side of 100 degrees west longitude, the western European cities at 20 degrees east longitude, and the 110–140 degree cities of China, Japan and south Korea in east longitude. And the latitude is concentrated between 25–55 degrees. In fact, the top 200 cities and the top 500 cities in the global urban economic competitiveness are all distributed in the rectangular box of Fig. 4.5. In order to more intuitively see the upgrade of the competitiveness of 1006 cities around the world, Fig. 4.6 shows the spatial distribution of the competitiveness of global cities. Affected by various factors such as abundant water resources, stable economic environment and political environment, and a livable climate, the western coastal cities of the United States, the western European cities near the prime meridian, and the coastal cities of East Asian, Chinese, Japan and South Korea have become economic increment. And the main gathering region for economic density upgrades. The difference is that Fig. 4–6 shows a comparison of annual changes in economic increment and economic density in 1006 cities around the world. Table 4.11 and Fig. 4.6 show that the coastal areas between 25–55 degrees north latitude, 100 degrees west of west longitude, 20 degrees east longitude, and east longitude 110 degrees are high-city competitiveness level gathering areas, and high. The overall mean of economic increment, high economic density and high economic competitiveness is 1.423, 1.559 and 1.626 times of the overall mean of low economic increment, low economic density and low economic competitiveness, respectively. The coefficient of variation is also small overall., leading the global urban competitiveness spatial pattern.
Table 4.11 Global sub-regional city competitiveness upgrade comparison results High economic growth region
low economic growth region
High economic density area
Low High economic low economic economic competitiveness competitiveness density area area area
mean
0.437
0.307
0.502
0.322
0.369
0.257
median
0.404
0.225
0.495
0.288
0.348
0.227
variance
0.168
0.101
0.218
0.164
0.179
0.147
Coefficient 0.32 of variation
0.301
0.434
0.508
0.486
0.571
minimum
0.185
0
0.067
0
0.052
0
maximum
1
0.801
1
0.86
1
0.861
Source CCC of CASS
208
4 Global Urban Economic Competitiveness Performance
Fig. 4.6 Comparison of annual changes in global economic growth (left) and economic density (right)
Chapter 5
Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
5.1 Local Factors 5.1.1 Overall Pattern of Local Factors 5.1.1.1
Overview of Leading Cites
The United States, China, and Japan guide the pattern of local factor competitiveness. The top three local factor competitiveness companies in the world are Shenzhen, New York and Mumbai, and the index is also in the first echelon, all above 0.9, leading the local factor competitiveness. Among the top 20, the United States occupies 5 cities, China occupies 2 cities, Japan occupies 2 cities, and others such as India, Malaysia, the United Kingdom, Singapore, Mexico, South Africa, Turkey, Russia, Australia and Canada each occupy 1 city; Asia occupies 10 cities, North America occupies 7 cities, Europe occupies 2 cities, and Oceania occupies 1 city. The overall performance is dominated by Asia and North America (Table 5.1). From the perspective of the top 100 local factors, Asia has the largest number of top 100, occupying 45 cities, followed by North America and Europe, and again South America, Africa, Oceania; from the index, the top 100 within North America Has the strongest competitiveness index, followed by Asia, while Africa’s top 100 local factors have the weakest competitiveness (Table 5.2).
5.1.1.2
Overall Spatial Pattern
Europe and North America dominate the top 100 pattern. From a regional perspective, 3 of the 7 sample cities in Oceania are among the top 100, followed by Europe, 15.87% of the 126 sample cities are among the top 100, and North America again, with 15.27% of the sample The cities are among the top 100, again South America and Asia. 9.33 and 7.96% of the sample cities are among the top 100, © China Social Sciences Press 2023 P. Ni et al., The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-99-3553-6_5
209
210
5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Table 5.1 Local factors indicator top 20 cities in the world Area
Country
City
Index
Global rank
Asia
China
Shenzhen
1.000
1
North America
United States
New York
0.971
2
Asia
India
Mumbai
0.913
3
North America
United States
Chicago
0.894
4
Asia
China
Shanghai
0.883
5
Asia
Malaysia
Kuala Lumpur
0.857
6
Europe
United Kingdom
London
0.851
7
Asia
Singapore
Singapore
0.842
8
Asia
Korea
Seoul
0.828
9
North America
United States
Washington, DC
0.825
10
North America
United States
Philadelphia
0.821
11
Asia
Japan
Kitakyushu–Fukuoka Metropolitan Area
0.818
12
North America
Mexico
Mexico City
0.815
13
Africa
South Africa
Johannesburg
0.813
14
North America
United States
Boston
0.810
15
Asia
Turkey
Istanbul
0.804
16
Asia
Japan
Tokyo
0.802
17
Europe
Russia
Moscow
0.795
18
Oceania
Australia
Sydney
0.791
19
North America
Canada
Toronto
0.790
20
Source CCC of CASS Table 5.2 Distribution of local factors indicator top 100 cities by area in the world Area
N
Mean
Coefficient of variation
Best city
Index
Global rank
Asia
45
0.724
0.120
Shenzhen
1.000
1
North America
20
0.733
0.137
New York
0.971
2
South America
7
0.714
0.075
Sao Paulo
0.776
25
Oceania
3
0.690
0.135
Sydney
0.791
19
Europe
20
0.697
0.099
London
0.851
7
Africa
5
0.686
0.109
Johannesburg
0.813
14
Source CCC of CASS
5.1 Local Factors
211
the lowest is Africa, and only 4.9% of the sample cities are among the top 100. From the perspective of the index, Oceania is the highest, followed by North America, Europe and South America, which are higher than the global average, and finally Asia and Africa, which are lower than the global average. From the perspective of differentiation, Oceania and North America are the least differentiated, and Asia and Africa are the most differentiated. Judging from the distribution type of each region, the overall distribution in Africa, South America, Asia, and Europe is relatively close, and the overall distribution in North America is relatively superior (see Figs. 5.1, 5.2 and 5.3; Table 5.3). The exchange index is generally low and highly differentiated. From the perspective of sub-indicators, the overall level of financing convenience index and thesis index are relatively high, at 0.618 and 0.547, respectively, followed by the labor force index, youth population index, and patent index. From the perspective of differentiation, the exchange index has the most serious differentiation, with a coefficient of variation of 2.783, followed by the patent index and the youth population index. The dissertation index has the lowest differentiation, with a coefficient of variation of 0.318. In addition, the optimal cities for each indicator are also significantly different, namely San Jose, New York, Beijing, Tokyo, Bukavu, Jakarta (Table 5.4). 90
60
30
0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
-30
-60
-90
Fig. 5.1 Spatial distribution of local factors indicators worldwide. Source CCC of CASS
180
212
5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness 90
60
30
0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30
-60
-90
4
Fig. 5.2 Spatial distribution of local factors indicators in the world’s top 100 cities. Source CCC of CASS
Global 3
Asia Europe
2
SAmerica Africa
0
1
Density
NAmerica
0
.2
.4
.6
.8
1
Local Elements
Fig. 5.3 The nuclear density map of the local element index of global cities. Source CCC of CASS
5.1 Local Factors
213
Table 5.3 Distribution of local factors indicator by area in the world Area
N
Mean
Coefficient of variation
Asia
565
Proportion of top 100 cities (%) 7.96
0.402
0.345
North America
131
15.27
0.519
0.237
South America
75
9.33
0.418
0.307
Oceania
7
42.86
0.584
0.209
Europe
126
15.87
0.429
0.347
Africa
102
4.90
0.347
0.398
Global
1006
–
0.417
0.346
Source CCC of CASS
Table 5.4 Statistical description of sub-indicators of local factors in global cities
Local factors
Mean
Coefficient of variation
Best city
Financing convenience
0.618
0.319
San Jose
Exchange index 0.075
2.783
New York
Thesis index
0.547
0.318
Beijing
Patent index
0.276
0.829
Tokyo
Youth 0.349 population ratio
0.407
Bukavu
Labor force index
0.331
Jakarta
0.451
Source CCC of CASS
5.1.2 Local Element Country Pattern 5.1.2.1
The Overview G20 Countries
China and the United States have relatively high proportions at all levels, and dominate the local factor structure. In terms of the distribution of the top 50 countries in the G20 countries, China has 9 cities in the top 50, and the United States and the EU have 6 cities in the top 50, followed by Canada and India. From the top 100, China has the most, China has the most 19 cities, followed by the United States with 15 cities, and again with the EU with 12 cities; from the top 101–200, the pattern is consistent with the top 100; and from the top 201–500, China is the most, followed by India, again the United States and Mexico; from the top 500, China has the largest share, accounting for 27.8%, followed by the United States and India. In general, China and the United States have a relatively high proportion at all levels and dominate the local factor structure. Before the EU is mainly distributed in the top 200, India is mainly distributed after 200, and other cities are distributed at all levels (Table 5.5).
214
5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Table 5.5 Distribution of local element index ranking in national sample cities Country
Proportion of top 50 cities (%)
Proportion of top 100 cities (%)
Proportion of 101–200 (%)
Proportion of 201–500 (%)
Proportion of top 500 cities (%)
France
2.0
1.0
0.0
0.3
0.4
United States
12.0
15.0
28.0
9.3
14.2
2.0
1.0
0.0
3.7
2.4
China
18.0
19.0
31.0
29.7
27.8
Turkey
2.0
1.0
2.0
1.7
1.6
Italy
0.0
0.0
1.0
0.0
0.2
Russia
2.0
1.0
1.0
1.0
1.0
Japan
4.0
3.0
2.0
0.0
1.0
Canada
6.0
3.0
2.0
1.3
1.8
Australia
2.0
2.0
2.0
0.7
1.2
Germany
0.0
5.0
2.0
0.3
1.6
Korea
4.0
2.0
0.0
2.0
1.6
India
6.0
7.0
5.0
15.7
11.8
Indonesia
2.0
1.0
0.0
1.0
0.8
Argentina
0.0
1.0
0.0
0.3
0.4
Mexico
2.0
1.0
4.0
8.3
6.0
Brazil
4.0
3.0
0.0
3.0
2.4
Saudi Arabia
2.0
1.0
0.0
0.3
0.4
South Africa
2.0
1.0
3.0
0.3
1.0
EU
12.0
12.0
6.0
2.3
5.0
G20
80.0
78.0
89.0
80.3
81.6
Non-G20
20.0
22.0
11.0
19.7
18.4
United Kingdom
The local factor competitiveness of G20 countries is significantly better than that of non-G20 countries. According to the analysis of the local factor index and coefficient of variation of G20 countries, Canada, Australia, the United States, South Africa and other countries have the strongest local factor competitiveness, Indonesia, Russia, Saudi Arabia, Italy and other countries have the weakest local factor competitiveness, while G20 countries The local factor competitiveness of China is basically higher than that of non-G20 countries. Only Russia, Saudi Arabia and Italy have lower local factor competitiveness than non-G20 countries. From the perspective of coefficient of variation, Mexico, the United States, Canada, Australia and other countries have the lowest degree of differentiation, and the overall local factor competitiveness is relatively uniform. China, France, Japan, Saudi Arabia and
5.1 Local Factors
215
Table 5.6 Statistical description of local element indicators in national sample cities of G20 Country
N
Index
Coefficient of variation
Best city
Global rank
France
9
0.391
0.372
Paris
31
United States
75
0.553
0.212
New York
2
United Kingdom
12
0.489
0.240
London
7
China
291
0.398
0.337
Shenzhen
1
Turkey
16
0.428
0.294
Istanbul
16
Italy
13
0.304
0.319
Milan
131
Russia
33
0.368
0.269
Moscow
18
Japan
10
0.501
0.417
Kitakyushu–Fukuoka Metropolitan Area
12
Canada
9
0.589
0.216
Toronto
20
Australia
6
0.569
0.223
Sydney
19
Germany
13
0.517
0.254
Berlin
57
Korea
8
0.546
0.276
Seoul
9
India
100
0.435
0.240
Mumbai
3
Indonesia
20
0.378
0.281
Jakarta
36
Argentina
9
0.384
0.327
Buenos Aires
61
Mexico
35
0.467
0.189
Mexico City
13
Brazil
32
0.405
0.306
Sao Paulo
25
Saudi Arabia
9
0.341
0.446
Riyadh
44
South Africa
6
0.552
0.296
Johannesburg
14
EU
40
0.499
0.322
Barcelona
22
G20
739
0.434
0.322
Shenzhen
1
Non-G20
267
0.371
0.399
Kuala Lumpur
6
Source CCC of CASS
other countries have the highest degree of differentiation, and the overall gap is large. The differentiation of local factor competitiveness in G20 countries is also more serious, only lower than that of France, Japan and Saudi Arabia. Overall, it shows that G20 countries are significantly better than non-G20 countries (Table 5.6).
5.1.2.2
The Overview Representative Country
According to the intercontinental division, the focus here is to select Asia, China, Japan, Europe, the United Kingdom, North America, the United States, South America, Brazil, Africa, South Africa, and Oceania, Australia for comparative
216
5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
research. Generally speaking, the financing convenience index, youth population index and labor force index are relatively close. The paper index and the patent index show a higher index and a more balanced distribution. From the perspective of the financing convenience index, the United States and Australia have the highest indexes, respectively 0.929 and 0.888, and Japan and Brazil have the lowest indexes, only 0.544 and 0.442; from the perspective of the coefficient of variation, the degree of differentiation of financing convenience in each country Both are relatively low, below 0.1, which is relatively balanced. From the perspective of the exchange index, Japan has the highest average population of 0.393, followed by Australia. In addition, the overall average of other countries is low; from the perspective of differentiation, China has the most serious differentiation, with a coefficient of variation of 8.501, followed by India, up to 7.114, and finally the United Kingdom, the United States, Brazil and other countries. From the perspective of the paper index, Australia, the United Kingdom and Japan have the highest indexes, and China and India have the lowest indexes; China and India are also more severely divided, and the distribution of cities is uneven. The United Kingdom and Japan have the lowest coefficients of variation and the overall distribution is also More balanced. This shows that the distribution of countries with higher mean is also more balanced. From the perspective of the patent index, Japan has the highest level, followed by the United States, the United Kingdom, and Australia, and the lowest is India and Brazil. The performance of the patent index is generally consistent with the paper index. The higher the index, the more balanced the distribution. From the perspective of the youth population index and the labor force index, except for Japan’s youth population index is relatively low and the division is more serious, the indexes of other countries are relatively close, and the relative gap is not large (Table 5.7).
5.2 Living Environment 5.2.1 Overall Pattern of Living Environment Index 5.2.1.1
Overview of Leading Cites
Asia cities account for nearly half of the top 20 cities. In terms of the distribution of the top 20 cities in the global living environment on all continents, Asia has 9 seats, Europe has 5 seats, North America has 4 seats, Oceania and South America have 1 seat each. In terms of the national dimension, Japan alone has 6 seats, followed by the US with 4 seats. Table 5.8 Top 20 cities of living environment index. More than 90% of the top 100 cities of living environment index are concentrated in North America, Europe and Asia, with absolute level close to each other and small fluctuation range. Comparing the mean value and coefficient of
Source CCC of CASS
Local element
Total labor force
Youth population ratio
Patent index
Thesis index
Exchange index
Financing convenience
0.398
0.337
CoV
0.344
CoV
Mean
0.446
0.409
Mean
0.362
CoV
0.598
CoV
Mean
0.296
0.318
CoV
Mean
0.509
8.501
Mean
0.013
CoV
0.064
CoV
Mean
0.589
Mean
China
0.212
0.553
0.293
0.484
0.018
0.255
0.264
0.589
0.206
0.685
3.196
0.077
0.029
0.929
United States
0.240
0.435
0.330
0.439
0.015
0.452
1.203
0.143
0.313
0.509
7.114
0.015
0.046
0.733
India
0.417
0.501
0.443
0.556
2.935
0.051
0.218
0.702
0.103
0.742
1.070
0.393
0.017
0.544
Japan
Table 5.7 Statistical analysis of sub-indicators of local element in representative countries
0.240
0.489
0.283
0.474
0.001
0.184
0.156
0.575
0.089
0.754
3.464
0.074
0.021
0.741
United Kingdom
0.296
0.552
0.261
0.559
0.068
0.499
0.314
0.404
0.360
0.588
2.449
0.129
0.040
0.592
South Africa
0.306
0.405
0.336
0.490
0.000
0.387
0.737
0.220
0.166
0.611
3.164
0.071
0.040
0.442
Brazil
0.223
0.569
0.246
0.511
0.000
0.246
0.225
0.546
0.112
0.771
2.449
0.137
0.016
0.888
Australia
5.2 Living Environment 217
218
5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Table 5.8 Living environment top 20 cities Content
Country
City
Index
Ranking
Asia
Japan
Tokyo
1.000
1
Asia
Japan
Hiroshima
0.976
2
Asia
Japan
Osaka
0.965
3
Asia
Singapore
Singapore
0.930
4
Asia
Japan
Kitakyushu-Fukuoka
0.920
5
South America
Argentina
Buenos Aires
0.917
6
Europe
Italy
Rome
0.905
7
Europe
Germany
Munich
0.904
8
North America
U.S.A.
Chicago
0.888
9
North America
U.S.A.
Houston
0.883
10
Europe
Germany
Berlin
0.876
11
Asia
Japan
Sapporo
0.874
12
Asia
Japan
Shizuoka–Hamamatsu M.M.A.
0.860
13
North America
U.S.A.
Philadelphia
0.857
14
Oceania
New Zealand
Auckland
0.857
15
Asia
India
Bangalore
0.853
16
Asia
China
Taipei
0.851
17
Europe
Ireland
Dublin
0.851
18
Europe
U.K.
London
0.850
19
North America
U.S.A.
New York–Newark
0.850
20
Source CCC of CASS
variation of the top 100 cities and all 1006 samples, we can find that the mean level of the top 100 cities is significantly higher than the global average and the coefficient of variation is significantly lower than the global average. In terms of the continental distribution of the top 100 cities, North America accounts for nearly 40%, while North America, Europe and Asia together account for more than 90%, with obvious concentration. From the perspective of the leading cities in all continents, Europe, North America, Asia, Oceania and South America all rank in the top 20 globally, while Cape Town, the best city in Africa, ranks only 61st in the world (Table 5.9).
5.2.1.2
Overall Spatial Pattern
Oceania, Europe and North America lead the world. From the average of global urban living environment indicators, the urban living environment in Oceania, Europe and North America is relatively developed, the living environment in Africa is relatively weak, and the degree of living environment in Asia and South America is in the middle. In terms of the coefficient of variation, the fluctuation range of the living
5.2 Living Environment
219
Table 5.9 The continent distribution in the top 100 cities of living environment index Content
Sample
Mean
Coefficient of variation
Leading cities
Index
Ranking
North America
39
0.808
0.040
Chicago
0.888
9
Europe
30
0.805
0.049
Rome
0.905
7
Asia
24
0.836
0.088
Tokyo
1.000
1
South America
4
0.833
0.076
Buenos Aires
0.917
6
Oceania
2
0.825
0.054
Auckland
0.857
15
Africa
1
0.792
–
Cape Town
0.792
61
Global
1006
0.569
0.259
Tokyo
1.000
1
Source CCC of CASS
environment index of cities in Oceania, Europe and North America is small, while that of African cities is more outstanding. In terms of the proportion of global top 100 cities in all continents, North America and Oceania account for nearly 30%, leading the world, with only 4–5% in South America and Asia, and less than 1% in Africa (Figs. 5.4 and 5.5; Table 5.10). According to the sub indicators of living environment, 1006 sample cities are mainly concentrated in the climate livable areas, which do relatively well in the protection of natural and cultural heritage, and the cost of living in most cities is 90
60
30
0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30
-60
-90
Fig. 5.4 Spatial distribution of living environment indexes of 1006 cities in the world. Source CCC of CASS
220
5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness 90
60
30
0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30
-60
-90
Fig. 5.5 Spatial distribution of living environment indexes in the top 100 cities in the world. Source CCC of CASS.
Table 5.10 Continental distribution of global urban living environment indicators Content
Sample
Proportion of top 100 cities (%)
Mean
Coefficient of variation
North America
131
29.77
0.689
0.151
Oceania
7
28.57
0.712
0.135
Africa
102
0.98
0.401
0.355
South America
75
5.33
0.564
0.222
Europe
126
23.81
0.679
0.140
Asia
565
4.25
0.546
0.235
Global
1006
9.94
0.569
0.259
Source CCC of CASS
in a reasonable range. However, environmental and ecological problems are more prominent, and the resource capacity of medical and health-care needs to be strengthened. Golf, as a sport that needs a good natural environment and a certain economic foundation, helps to measure the balance of economic level, natural environment and healthy life. However, we can find that the overall performance of global cities in this indicator is relatively weak, and the differentiation is great. It shows that high-quality development still has a long way to go (Fig. 5.6 and Table 5.11).
5.2 Living Environment
221
Fig. 5.6 Density map of global urban living environment index. Source CCC of CASS
Table 5.11 Statistical description of sub indicators of living environment index
Living environment
Mean
Coefficient of variation
Leading cites
Heritage protection
0.622
0.295
Tokyo
Medical and health-care
0.530
0.286
Hyderabad
Climate comfort
0.654
0.271
Pereira
Environmental pollution
0.317
0.265
Singapore
Ecological excellence
0.481
0.412
Chicago
Cost of living
0.910
0.194
(Non-unique)
Golf course
0.202
1.075
Tokyo
Source CCC of CASS
5.2.2 National Pattern of Living Environment Index 5.2.2.1
Overview of G20 Countries
Cities in Japan, the United States, and Europe lead the world, and Chinese cities are poised to take off. Among the top 20 cities of living environment index, Japan has led the way with 30% of the global top 20, followed by the United States with 20% and the EU with 20%. Among the top 100, the United States has the highest number of cities, up to 36%, the EU as a whole has 22%, and Japan has 10%. Among the top 101–200, the United States, the European Union and China account for 21, 20 and 19%, respectively. Among the top 201–500, the number of Chinese cities is the highest, reaching 38%, followed by the European Union, which accounts for 8%, and Mexico which accounts for 7%. Among the top 500, Chinese cities hold the highest proportion, reaching 28%, followed by the United States and the European Union, which account for 14 and 13%, respectively. Saudi Arabia has no cities in
222
5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
the top 500 (Table 5.12). From the distribution of rankings, we can see that cities in developed economies such as Japan, the United States and the European Union are still in the leading position, but China’s leading cities have already ranked among the forefronts in the world, and there are a lot of reserves in the middle and upper level stage. Table 5.12 Ranking and distribution of living environment index of G20 sample cities Country
Proportion of top 20 cities (%)
Proportion of top 100 cities (%)
Proportion of top 101–200 cities (%)
Proportion of top 201–500 cities (%)
Proportion of top 500 cities (%)
China
5.0
6.0
19.0
38.0
28.0
U.S.A.
20.0
36.0
21.0
5.0
14.0
European Union
20.0
22.0
20.0
8.0
13.0
Mexico
0.0
1.0
3.0
7.0
5.0
India
5.0
1.0
5.0
6.0
5.0
Russian
0.0
1.0
1.0
6.0
4.0
Brazil
0.0
2.0
1.0
4.0
3.0
10.0
8.0
3.0
1.0
3.0
Italy
5.0
7.0
4.0
1.0
3.0
Indonesia
0.0
0.0
4.0
3.0
2.0
Turkey
0.0
2.0
0.0
3.0
2.0
U.K.
5.0
5.0
6.0
0.0
2.0
Japan
Germany
30.0
10.0
0.0
0.0
2.0
Canada
0.0
2.0
4.0
1.0
2.0
Republic of Korea
0.0
3.0
1.0
1.0
2.0
France
0.0
1.0
2.0
2.0
2.0
Argentina
5.0
2.0
1.0
1.0
1.0
Australia
0.0
1.0
2.0
1.0
1.0
South Africa
0.0
1.0
0.0
1.0
1.0
Saudi Arabia
0.0
0.0
0.0
0.0
0.0
G20 countries
90.0
95.0
88.0
85.0
88.0
Non-G20 countries
10.0
5.0
12.0
15.0
12.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
Global
Source CCC of CASS
5.2 Living Environment
223
In general, the average living environment of non G20 cities is still lower than that of G20 cities, and the degree of internal differentiation is higher. Comparing the living environment of G20 countries, it is found that in terms of the mean value, cities in Japan, Germany, Italy, the United Kingdom and the United States have obvious advantages, while cities in India, Brazil, China, Saudi Arabia and Russia have relatively poor performance. According to the coefficient of variation of living environment, the fluctuation range of cities in Britain, Russia, Japan and Italy is relatively small, while that in Saudi Arabia, Argentina and France is relatively large. From the perspective of the best cities, 8 cities in G20 countries are listed in the top 20 in the world, and 18 cities are within the top 100 (Table 5.13). Table 5.13 Statistical description of living environment index of G20 sample cities Country
Mean
Coefficient of variation
Leading cities
Ranking
Japan
0.8877
0.0825
Tokyo
1
Germany
0.7751
0.0951
Munich
8
Italy
0.7563
0.0840
Rome
7
U.K.
0.7538
0.0736
London
19
U.S.A.
0.7507
0.0954
Chicago
9
European Union
0.7266
0.0974
Dublin
18
Argentina
0.7266
0.1467
Buenos Aires
6
Republic of Korea
0.7020
0.1089
Seoul
49
Canada
0.6966
0.0963
Vancouver
53
Australia
0.6884
0.1142
Melbourne
60
South Africa
0.6691
0.1101
Cape Town
61
Indonesia
0.6600
0.0866
Bandung
106
France
0.6529
0.1220
Paris
55
Turkey
0.6488
0.1166
Antalya
69
India
0.6464
0.0990
Bangalore
16
Mexico
0.6413
0.0976
Mexico City
29
Brazil
0.6404
0.1150
Sao Jose dos Campos
28
China
0.6370
0.0874
Guangzhou
87
Russian
0.6293
0.0779
Moscow
88
Saudi Arabia
0.4156
0.1658
Jeddah
636
G20 countries
0.6098
0.1947
Tokyo
1
Non-G20 countries
0.4559
0.3503
Singapore
4
Global
0.5690
0.2591
Tokyo
1
Source CCC of CASS
224
5.2.2.2
5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Overview of Representative Countries
We choose China, Japan and India in Asia, Britain in Europe, the United States in North America, Brazil in South America, South Africa in Africa and Australia in Oceania for comparative study. In general, the performance of Japanese cities in the living environment is relatively good. The UK and the US have long and short boards respectively. However, the overall level of emerging economies still needs to be improved, and each sub indicators has a large internal differentiation. From the perspective of the heritage protection, the level of representative countries is good. Japan’s performance is particularly prominent and the fluctuation is very small, while the fluctuation of the United States is slightly larger. From the perspective of medical and health-care, Japan leads, Australia is slightly weaker. China is at a moderately low level and there is still much room for improvement. In terms of climate comfort, cities in Japan and Australia have better performance, while India and the United Kingdom have lower comfort levels. From the perspective of coefficient of variation, cities in Japan, the United Kingdom, and Australia have relatively small fluctuations. From the perspective of environmental pollution, the advantages of cities in Japan and the U.K. are obvious, but the difference between cities in Japan is greater than that in the U.K. India and China have more pressure in environmental pollution and there are large fluctuations between cities. In terms of ecological excellence, cities in the United States, the United Kingdom, and Japan is better, and cities of Brazil, South Africa, and India needs to be improved. From the perspective of cost of living, the problems in Brazil are more obvious, and the division between India and China is relatively large. From the perspective of golf courses, Japan and the United Kingdom are leading, Brazil, India and China are relatively backward, and the gap between cities is relatively large (Table 5.14).
5.3 Soft Environment 5.3.1 Overall Pattern of Software Environment 5.3.1.1
Head City Overview
The head cities of global software environment are unevenly distributed across continents. According to the distribution of the top 20 cities in the global software environment on all continents, North America has 10 seats, Asia has 7 seats, Europe has 2 seats and Oceania has 1 seat. Among them, U.S.A. occupies 8 seats, followed by Canada, Japan and China, each occupying 2 seats (Table 5.15).
5.3 Soft Environment
225
Table 5.14 Statistical analysis of sub indicators of living environment in representative countries Australia
Brazil
U.S.A.
South Africa
Japan
India
U.K.
China
Heritage protection
Mean
0.638
0.745
0.681
0.669
0.825
0.703
0.683
0.729
CV
0.137
0.126
0.165
0.151
0.102
0.135
0.149
0.135
Medical and health-care
Mean
0.489
0.656
0.553
0.530
0.761
0.828
0.542
0.522
CV
0.322
0.160
0.168
0.216
0.076
0.127
0.167
0.129
Climate comfort
Mean
0.792
0.754
0.755
0.743
0.799
0.651
0.690
0.756
CV
0.073
0.139
0.112
0.068
0.048
0.173
0.032
0.112
Environmental pollution
Mean
0.382
0.360
0.373
0.333
0.447
0.277
0.416
0.279
CV
0.061
0.087
0.102
0.104
0.216
0.216
0.153
0.257
Ecological excellence
Mean
0.598
0.488
0.714
0.443
0.652
0.422
0.647
0.572
CV
0.404
0.254
0.260
0.115
0.265
0.235
0.186
0.135
Cost of living
Mean
0.977
0.894
0.979
0.979
0.964
0.928
0.962
0.926
CV
0.022
0.044
0.010
0.006
0.026
0.102
0.053
0.157
Mean
0.391
0.148
0.499
0.481
0.736
0.265
0.626
0.246
CV
0.313
1.284
0.294
0.273
0.178
0.681
0.140
0.747
Mean
0.688
0.640
0.751
0.669
0.888
0.646
0.754
0.637
CV
0.114
0.115
0.095
0.110
0.083
0.099
0.074
0.087
Golf course Living environment index
Source CCC of CASS
Among the top 100 cities in the global software environment, more than 90% of the top 100 cities in the global software environment are concentrated in North America, Europe and Asia, with the mean value close and a small fluctuation range. Comparing the mean value and coefficient of variation of the top 100 cities and the whole sample, we can find that the mean level of the top 100 cities is significantly higher than the global average, while the coefficient of variation is significantly lower than the global average. In terms of the intercontinental distribution of the former 100 cities, North America accounts for nearly 40%, while North America, Europe and Asia together account for more than 95%, with obvious concentration. The leading cities in North America, Europe, Asia and Oceania are New York-Newark, London, Tokyo and Auckland, ranking 4, 5, 1 and 11 in the world in terms of the best software environment cities in all continents (Table 5.16).
5.3.1.2
Overall Spatial Pattern
The cities with superior global software environment are mainly concentrated in North America, Oceania and Europe. According to the mean value of intercontinental distribution of global urban software environment, urban software environment is relatively strong in Oceania, North America and Europe, relatively weak
226
5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Table 5.15 Software environment index top 20 cities in the world Continent
Country
City
Index
Ranking
Asia
Japan
Tokyo
1.000
1
Asia
Singapore
Singapore
0.998
2
Asia
China
Hong Kong
0.991
3
North America
U.S.A.
New York–Newark
0.981
4
Europe
U.K.
London
0.954
5
Asia
China
Taipei
0.939
6
North America
U.S.A.
Los Angeles–Long Beach–Santa Ana
0.932
7
Asia
Republic of Korea
Seoul
0.919
8
Asia
Japan
Osaka
0.910
9
North America
Canada
Toronto
0.901
10
Oceania
New Zealand
Auckland
0.898
11
North America
U.S.A.
Boston
0.890
12
North America
U.S.A.
Seattle
0.889
13
North America
U.S.A.
San Diego (US)
0.875
14
North America
Canada
Calgary
0.868
15
North America
U.S.A.
Chicago
0.866
16
Asia
United Arab Emirates
Dubai
0.865
17
Europe
Germany
Munich
0.864
18
North America
U.S.A.
Portland
0.861
19
North America
U.S.A.
San Francisco–Oakland
0.861
20
Source CCC of CASS
Table 5.16 The intercontinental distribution of the top 100 cities in the world Continent
Sample
Mean
Coefficient of variation
Best city
Index
Ranking
North America
39
0.827
0.058
New York–Newark
0.981
4
Europe
26
0.805
0.049
London
0.954
5
Asia
33
0.841
0.076
Tokyo
1.000
1
Oceania
2
0.845
0.090
Auckland
0.898
11
Global
1006
0.529
0.318
Tokyo
1.000
1
Source CCC of CASS
in Africa, and moderate in Asia. In terms of coefficient of variation, the fluctuation range of software environment in Oceania and European cities is relatively small, while that in African cities is relatively large. In terms of the proportion of the top 100 global cities in all continents, North America and Oceania account for nearly
5.3 Soft Environment
227 90
60
30
0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30
-60
-90
Fig. 5.7 Spatial distribution of software environment indicators in 1006 cities around the world. Source CCC of CASS
30%, leading the world, followed by 20.63% in Europe, only about 6% in Asia, and 0% in Africa and South America (Figs. 5.7 and 5.8; Table 5.17). The mean value and fluctuation range of sub indicators of global urban software environment are quite different. In terms of sub indicators of software environment, 1006 sample cities do relatively well in terms of business convenience, followed by social security, economic freedom and property protection. The problem of cultural inclusion and Knowledge density is more prominent. Cultural inclusion reflects the ability of a city to carry new things. Excellent cultural inclusion brings new opportunities to the development of a city. Knowledge density contain the city’s accumulation and historical charm. However, we can find that the overall performance of global cities in these two indicators is relatively weak, and the differentiation is great (Fig. 5.9 and Table 5.18).
228
5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness 90
60
30
0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30
-60
-90
Fig. 5.8 Spatial distribution of software environment indicators in the top 100 cities in the world. Source CCC of CASS
Table 5.17 Intercontinental distribution of global urban software environment indicators Continent
Sample
Proportion of top 100 cities (%)
Mean
Coefficient of variation
North America
131
29.77
0.677
0.217
Oceania
7
28.57
0.762
0.098
Africa
102
0.00
0.320
0.390
South America
75
0.00
0.408
0.380
Europe
126
20.63
0.655
0.172
Asia
565
5.84
0.517
0.253
Sum
1006
9.94
0.529
0.318
Source CCC of CASS
5.3.2 National Structure of Software Environment 5.3.2.1
Overview of G20 Countries
Cities in U.S.A., China, Japan and Canada lead the world, U.S.A., China and the European Union have an absolute advantage in the number of top cities in the
5.3 Soft Environment
229
Fig. 5.9 Kernel density of global urban software environment indicators. Source CCC of CASS
Table 5.18 Statistical description of sub indicators of global urban software environment Software environment
Mean
Coefficient of variation
Best city
Social security
0.554
0.298
Shizuoka–Hamamatsu M.M.A.
Economic freedom
0.551
0.251
Hong Kong
Cultural inclusion
0.301
0.817
Manila
Property protection
0.519
0.396
San Jose
Knowledge density
0.347
0.637
Moscow
Business convenience
0.631
0.235
Singapore
Source CCC of CASS
software environment ranking of G20 countries. Comparing the ranking of urban software environment of G20 countries, it is found that in the top 20 cities in the world, U.S.A. leads by 40%, followed by China, Japan and Canada by 10% and the European Union by 5%. Among the top 100 cities in the global software environment, U.S.A. accounts for the highest number of cities, up to 32%, China accounts for 14%, and the third is the European Union, accounting for 13%. U.S.A., European Union and China account for 37, 23 and 15% of the top 101–200 cities in the global software environment. Among the top 201–500 cities in the global urban software environment, China has the highest number of cities, accounting for 37%, followed by the European Union, accounting for 11%, followed by Russia, accounting for 10%. Among the top 500 cities in the global urban software environment, the proportion of Chinese cities is the highest, reaching 28%, followed by U.S.A. and the European
230
5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Union, accounting for 15 and 14%, respectively. Argentina has the least number of cities in the top 500, only 2. From the ranking distribution, we can see that U.S.A., China and the European Union are in absolute advantage (Table 5.19). Generally speaking, the average value of software environment in Non-G20 cities is still lower than that in G20 cities, and the degree of internal differentiation is serious. Comparing the urban software environment of G20 countries, it is found that in terms of the average value of software environment, the cities of Japan, Germany, U.K., U.S.A., Republic of Korea, Canada and Australia have obvious advantages, while the cities of Argentina, India and Brazil have relatively Table 5.19 Ranking and distribution of software environment indicators of sample cities in G20 countries Country
Top 20 proportion (%)
Top 100 proportion (%)
China
10
14
15.0
37.0
28.0
U.S.A.
40
32.0
37.0
2.0
15.0
European Union
5.0
13.0
23.0
11.0
14.0
Mexico
0.0
0.0
1.0
7.0
4.0
India
0.0
0.0
0.0
5.0
3.0
Russian
0.0
1.0
1.0
10.0
6.0
Brazil
0.0
0.0
0.0
1.0
1.0
Germany
5.0
3.0
10.0
0.0
3.0
Italy
0.0
0.0
3.0
3.0
3.0
Indonesia
0.0
0.0
1.0
5.0
3.0
Turkey
0.0
0.0
3.0
4.0
3.0
U.K.
5.0
8.0
3.0
0.0
2.0
Japan
10.0
10.0
0.0
0.0
2.0
Canada
10.0
7.0
2.0
0.0
2.0
Republic of Korea
5.0
6.0
2.0
0.0
2.0
France
0.0
1.0
0.0
3.0
2.0
Argentina
0.0
0.0
0.0
1.0
0.0
Australia
0.0
1.0
4.0
0.0
1.0
South Africa
0.0
1.0
0.0
1.0
1.0
Saudi Arabia
0.0
0.0
2.0
2.0
2.0
G20
85.0
93.0
94.0
86.0
89.0
Non-G20
15.0
7.0
Global
100.0
100.0
Source CCC of CASS
Proportion of 101–200 (%)
Proportion of 201–500 (%)
Top 500 proportion (%)
6.0
14.0
11.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
5.3 Soft Environment
231
Table 5.20 Statistical description of software environment indicators of G20 sample cities Country
Mean
Coefficient of variation
Best city
Ranking
Japan
0.8523
0.0708
Tokyo
1
Germany
0.7532
0.0667
Munich
18
Italy
0.6561
0.0814
Milan
133
U.K.
0.7999
0.0681
London
5
U.S.A.
0.7645
0.0905
New York–Newark
4
European Union
0.6906
0.1168
Munich
18
Argentina
0.4476
0.1691
Buenos Aires
286
Republic of Korea
0.7968
0.0774
Seoul
8
Canada
0.8160
0.0631
Toronto
10
Australia
0.7387
0.0653
Sydney
73
South Africa
0.5359
0.1647
Cape Town
251
Indonesia
0.5670
0.1089
Jakarta
186
France
0.6344
0.1229
Paris
72
Turkey
0.6078
0.1198
Istanbul
130
India
0.4565
0.1496
Delhi
236
Mexico
0.5347
0.1158
Mexico City
188
Brazil
0.4254
0.1149
Sao Jose dos Campos
248
China
0.5380
0.1798
Hong Kong
3
Russian
0.5760
0.1074
Moscow
62
Saudi Arabia
0.6312
0.1098
Riyadh
109
G20
0.5793
0.2341
Tokyo
1
Non-G20
0.3886
0.4353
Singapore
2
Global
0.5287
0.3175
Tokyo
1
Source CCC of CASS
poor performance. In terms of the coefficient of variation of software environment, the fluctuation range of cities in Japan, Germany, Italy, U.K., U.S.A., Republic of Korea, Canada and Australia is relatively small, while that in Argentina, South Africa and China is relatively large. From the perspective of the best cities, 17 cities in G20 countries have entered the top 20 in the world, and 93 cities have entered the top 100 in the world software environment (Table 5.20).
5.3.2.2
Overview of Representative Countries
According to the intercontinental division, China, Japan and India in Asia, the U.K. in Europe, U.S.A. in North America, Brazil in South America, South Africa in Africa and Australia in Oceania are mainly selected for comparative study. In general, Japanese cities have advantages in all sub indicators of software environment,
232
5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
while the overall level of emerging economies is still low, and there is a large internal differentiation in all sub indicators. From the mean of social security, Japan has a high degree of social security and little fluctuation„ and Brazil’s social security problems are obvious. From the mean of economic freedom, Australia and U.K. are far ahead, while the U.S.A. is slightly weaker. China is at a medium level and still has a lot of room for progress. From the mean of cultural inclusion, Japan has a high degree of cultural inclusion, while India and China have a low degree of cultural inclusion. In terms of coefficient of variation, the fluctuation range of Japanese cities is relatively small. From the mean of property protection, Australia, Japan and U.K. have obvious urban advantages. India is in the middle low level and the fluctuation range among cities is large. From the perspective of Knowledge density, U.K. cities are better, and Knowledge density in India and China need to be improved. From the mean of business convenience, the U.S.A. is the leading city, while Brazil, South Africa and India are relatively backward (Table 5.21).
5.4 Hard Environment 5.4.1 Overall Pattern of Hardware Environment 5.4.1.1
Head City Overview
Top 20 global cities hardware environment: Western Europe and North America occupy an overwhelming advantage, and the gap between cities is small. According to the 2019 Global City Economic Competitiveness Report, the top 10 seats in the global cities hardware environment are Amsterdam, Lisbon, Dusseldorf, Vancouver, Paris, Vienna, Brussels, Frankfurt, Sydney and Kansas City, followed by 10–20 for Philadelphia, Dallas, Melbourne, Atlanta, London, Singapore, Baltimore, Hamburg and Cincinnati. Table 5.22 shows the hardware environment index and ranking of the top 20 cities in the global hardware environment. As can be seen from Table 5.22, from a spatial perspective, Western Europe and North America occupy 9 seats and 8 seats respectively, accounting for up to 85%, so Western Europe and North America occupy an overwhelming advantage in the competitiveness of the hardware environment. At the same time, the standardization index of the top 20 global hardware environment in cities decreased from 1 to 0.920, only a decrease of nearly 8%. The decrease was relatively small, and the difference in hardware environment between cities was relatively weak.
Source CCC of CASS
Whole software environment
Business convenience
Cultural facilities
Property protection
Cultural inclusion
Economic freedom
Social security
0.739 0.065
Coefficient of variation
0.041
Coefficient of variation
Mean
0.781
0.423
Mean
0.301
Coefficient of variation
0.023
Coefficient of variation
Mean
0.943
0.274
Coefficient of variation
Mean
0.437
0.022
Mean
0.864
Coefficient of variation
0.992
Coefficient of variation
Mean
0.607
Mean
Australia
0.115
0.425
0.034
0.481
0.511
0.347
0.076
0.505
0.394
0.422
0.076
0.412
0.338
0.308
Brazil
0.091
0.765
0.047
0.804
0.329
0.515
0.043
0.897
0.264
0.557
0.042
0.775
0.262
0.506
U.S.A.
Table 5.21 Statistical analysis of sub indicators of representative national software environment
0.165
0.536
0.017
0.573
0.514
0.496
0.069
0.610
0.314
0.527
0.064
0.591
0.205
0.206
South Africa
0.071
0.852
0.054
0.758
0.263
0.642
0.026
0.929
0.186
0.672
0.026
0.735
0.116
0.856
Japan
0.150
0.457
0.009
0.614
0.733
0.250
0.090
0.482
1.225
0.137
0.083
0.455
0.214
0.578
India
0.068
0.800
0.050
0.799
0.200
0.629
0.031
0.914
0.219
0.554
0.030
0.822
0.116
0.539
U.K.
0.180
0.538
0.028
0.708
0.768
0.224
0.125
0.538
0.907
0.248
0.133
0.517
0.148
0.644
China
5.4 Hard Environment 233
234
5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Table 5.22 Top 20 cities in the global urban hardware environment City
Country
Continent
Index
Ranking
Amsterdam
Netherlands
Europe
1.000
1
Lisbon
Portugal
Europe
0.985
2
Dusseldorf
Germany
Europe
0.974
3
Vancouver
Canada
North America
0.969
4
Paris
France
Europe
0.968
5
Vienna
Austria
Europe
0.961
6
Brussels
Belgium
Europe
0.960
7
Frankfurt am Main
Germany
Europe
0.959
8
Sydney
Australia
Oceania
0.956
9
Kansas City
U.S.A.
North America
0.951
10
Philadelphia
U.S.A.
North America
0.948
11
Dallas–Fort Worth
U.S.A.
North America
0.945
12
Melbourne
Australia
Oceania
0.941
13
Atlanta
U.S.A.
North America
0.940
14
London
U.K.
Europe
0.936
15
Singapore
Singapore
Asia
0.931
16
Toronto
Canada
North America
0.926
17
Baltimore
U.S.A.
North America
0.925
18
Hamburg
Germany
Europe
0.921
19
Cincinnati
U.S.A.
North America
0.920
20
Source CCC of CASS
5.4.1.2
Overall Spatial Pattern
The overall pattern of the top 100 global cities hardware environment: Asia is struggling to catch up, South America and Africa lag behind. Among the top 100 cities in the global cities hardware environment, the number of European cities occupies up to 45 seats, North America and Asia occupy 37 seats and 15 seats respectively, accounting for about half of the top 100 cities. Oceania has 3 seats and is mainly concentrated in Australia. Africa and South America both have 0 seats, which is quite different from other regions. Table 5.23 gives a statistical description of the top 100 cities in the global hardware environment. It can be seen from Table 5.23 that Amsterdam has the strongest competitiveness in the hardware environment in Europe, and the standardization index is 1, Vancouver in North America, Sydney in Oceania, and Singapore in Asia are 0.969, 0.956, and 0.931, respectively. The competitiveness is relatively strong. Table 5.24 shows the intercontinental distribution of the global urban hardware environment. In the global urban hardware environment, the pattern of duopoly in Europe and North America continues. Among the top 100 cities, Europe and North America
5.4 Hard Environment
235
Table 5.23 Top 100 cities in the global cities hardware environment Region
Sample
Mean
CV
Best city
Index
Global rank
North America
37
0.869
0.061
Vancouver
0.969
4
Oceania
3
0.901
0.091
Sydney
0.956
9
Europe
45
0.881
0.061
Amsterdam
1
1
Asia
15
0.833
0.041
Singapore
0.931
16
Africa
0
0
0
–
–
–
South America
0
0
0
–
–
–
Total
1006
0.871
0.062
Amsterdam
1
1
Source CCC of CASS
Table 5.24 Intercontinental distribution of global city hardware environmental indicators Region
Sample
Proportion of top 100 cities (%)
Mean
Coefficient of variation
North America
131
28.24
0.869
0.061
Oceania
7
42.86
0.901
0.091
Europe
126
35.71
0.881
0.061
Asia
565
2.65
0.84
0.049
Africa
102
0
0
0
South America
75
0
0
0
Total
1006
9.94
0.540
0.334
Source CCC of CASS
occupy 45 seats and 37 seats respectively, accounting for 45 and 35% of the total of the top 100 cities. Within the region, the top 100 cities in Europe and North America accounted for 35.71 and 28.42% of the sample cities respectively, and the average of the top 100 cities was 0.881 and 0.869, both exceeding 0.85, while the coefficient of variation was only 0.061. The difference is that neither South American nor African cities are among the top 100 in the world. Figure 5.10 shows the spatial distribution of the hardware environment index of 1006 cities in the world. Figure 5.10 shows that the cities with the most competitive cities hardware environment in the world are mainly concentrated in Western Europe and North America, while the eastern coastal regions of Asia are relatively competitive, but the city hardware environment in South America and Africa is significantly weaker. Figure 5.11 shows the spatial distribution of the hardware competitiveness of the world’s top 100 cities. It can be more clearly seen from Figure 5.11 that the top 100 cities in the global urban hardware environment are mainly concentrated in North America and Western Europe, and the distribution density of cities in the Western European region with a higher level of urban hardware environment competitiveness is significantly greater
236
5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Fig. 5.10 Spatial distribution map of global urban hardware environment index. Source CCC of CASS
Fig. 5.11 Spatial distribution map of hardware environment index of the world’s top 100. Source CCC of CASS
5.4 Hard Environment Table 5.25 Descriptive statistics of hardware indicators of 1006 cities worldwide
237
Sub-index
Mean
Coefficient of variation
Best city
Traffic congestion
0.584
0.22
Muscat
Power adequacy
0.64
0.374
London and so on
Information accessibility
0.408
0.543
Bologna
Shipping convenience
0.838
0.186
Sydney
Airport index
0.45
0.44
Atlanta
0.211
Beijing et al
Natural disaster 0.793 index Source CCC of CASS
than that in North America. There are only sporadic cities in East Asia and Oceania, while South Africa and South America are completely blank. Ease of access to information determines the future. The global cities hardware environment competitiveness level is composed of 6 sub-indices including traffic congestion, power adequacy, information accessibility, shipping convenience, airport index and natural disaster index. Table 5.25 gives the descriptive statistics of the hardware environment sub-indicators of 1006 cities worldwide. From Table 5.25, it can be seen that the average difference between the hardware environment sub-indices of 1006 cities in the world is relatively small, and the average value of the convenience of shipping is 0.838 at the maximum, indicating that shipping is still the main transportation route between cities around the world. At the same time, the maximum coefficient of variation of information accessibility between cities is 0.543, that is, the ability to obtain information between cities is an important factor that affects the competitiveness of the city’s hardware environment, and also an important factor that determines the future competitiveness of cities. The difference is that Figure 5.12 shows the kernel density estimation map of the hardware environment of global cities on different continents. From Figure 5.12, it can be seen that the kernel density map of the hardware environment of African cities in the global cities is closest to the normal distribution, the peak of the South American cities is relatively large, and the difference in the competitiveness level of the hardware environment is relatively small. The difference is that the kernel density maps of North America and Europe are both negatively skewed, and there is a large difference between the urban hardware environment, and although the overall competitiveness of the hardware environment is high in Europe and North America, there is a certain number of hardware environments. Poor cities make the gap between cities larger.
5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
0
1
Density
2
3
238
0
.2
.4 .6 Hardware environment kdensity Global kdensity Europe kdensity NAmerica
.8
1
kdensity Asia kdensity africa kdensity SAmerica
Fig. 5.12 Kernel density map of global urban hardware environment sub-index
5.4.2 National Pattern of Hardware Environment 5.4.2.1
G20 Country Profile
The distribution of the hardware environment in different countries: the United States, Germany, France, Britain and Canada have great advantages. At the national level, the spatial distribution of cities with strong competitiveness in the global hardware environment is remarkable. In terms of the top 20 cities with the strongest hardware environment in the world, the United States, Germany, France, the United Kingdom and Canada account for 30, 15, 5, 5 and 5% of the total respectively. Table 5.26 shows the level distribution of the competitiveness level of hardware environment in different countries. It can be seen from Table 5.26 that among the top 100 cities in the world, the United States accounts for 31.25%, the United Kingdom, Germany, and Italy account for more than 5%, while China, South Korea, Japan, India, Russia, Australia, and Canada account for more than 1%. Of the top 101–200 cities, the United States accounts for 18%, and China, South Korea, France, and Mexico account for more than 5%. Among the top 201–500 cities, China accounts for 26%, India accounts for 13%, and the United States, Mexico, and Brazil account for more than 5%. Among the top 500 cities, China has the highest share of 17.2%, followed by the United States with 14.2%, and Indian cities with more than 5%.
5.4 Hard Environment
239
Table 5.26 Rank distribution of city hardware environment competitiveness in different countries Country
Top 20 (%)
Top 20–80 (%)
Top 101–200 (%)
Top 201–500 (%)
Top 500 (%)
China
0.00
2.50
6.00
26.00
17.20
Republic of Korea
0.00
1.25
5.00
0.67
1.60
Japan
0.00
3.75
0.00
1.67
1.60
India
0.00
3.75
1.00
13.00
8.60
Indonesia
0.00
0.00
3.00
2.67
2.20
Saudi Arabia
0.00
0.00
0.00
1.67
1.00
Turkey
0.00
0.00
1.00
0.67
0.60
Russian
0.00
1.25
1.00
3.00
2.20
U.K.
5.00
8.75
2.00
0.33
2.20
France
5.00
0.00
6.00
0.00
1.40
15.00
6.25
3.00
0.00
2.20
0.00
5.00
4.00
1.33
2.40
10.00
30.00
22.00
6.00
13.20
Germany Italy Europe Union South Africa
0.00
0.00
1.00
1.00
0.80
Australia
10.00
1.25
3.00
0.00
1.20
U.S.A.
30.00
31.25
18.00
7.33
14.20
Canada
5.00
3.75
3.00
0.00
1.40
Mexico
0.00
0.00
5.00
5.00
4.00
Brazil
0.00
0.00
1.00
5.33
3.40
Argentina
0.00
0.00
0.00
1.33
0.80
95.00
82.50
74.00
76.67
77.80
G20 Non G20 Total
5.00
17.50
26.00
23.33
22.20
100.00
100.00
100.00
100.00
100.00
Source CCC of CASS
In terms of G20 countries and non-G20 countries, the top 20 cities account for 95% of G20 countries, top 21–100, 101–200, and 201–500 cities account for 82.5, 74 and 76.67% of G20 countries, respectively, much higher than the proportion of non-G20 cities.
5.4.2.2
Representative Country Profile
Germany is the most balanced and Russia is the most diverse. There are also large differences in the competitiveness levels of urban hardware environments among major countries around the world. Table 5.27 gives a statistical description of the
240
5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
hardware competitiveness of cities in major countries and the ranking of the best cities. Among the major countries in the world, the average level of the German city hardware environment represented by Dusseldorf is 0.859, and the minimum coefficient of variation is 0.095, which is the smallest difference between cities in all countries, followed by Canada, Australia, and the United Kingdom. Compared with France and other countries, the hardware environment difference between cities within the country is relatively small. The difference is that the average value of the hardware environmental competitiveness of Russian cities represented by Moscow is 0.460. Not only is it ranked lower in the main countries, but the coefficient of variation of 0.359 is the largest among the main countries, so the overall hardware environment of the Russian cities is poor. , And the hardware environment gap between cities is large. Table 5.27 Descriptive statistics of city hardware environmental competitiveness in major countries Country
Mean
Coefficient of variation
Best city
Global rank
China
0.455
0.265
Taipei
81
Republic of Korea
0.748
0.1
Seoul
37
Japan
0.671
0.194
Tokyo
55
India
0.512
0.213
Chennai
67
Indonesia
0.568
0.248
Jakarta
126
Saudi Arabia
0.542
0.082
Riyadh
354
Turkey
0.486
0.187
Istanbul
183
Russian
0.46
0.359
Moscow
48
U.K.
0.78
0.217
London
15
France
0.777
0.117
Paris
5
Germany
0.859
0.095
Dusseldorf
3
Italy
0.742
0.118
Milan
28
Europe Union
0.706
0.255
Amsterdam
1
South Africa
0.6
0.192
Johannesburg
105
Australia
0.803
0.164
Sydney
9
U.S.A.
0.763
0.143
Kansas City
10
Canada
0.817
0.104
Toronto
17
Mexico
0.581
0.214
Monterrey
101
Brazil
0.515
0.174
Curitiba
200
Argentina
0.505
0.301
La Plata
252
G20
0.546
0.32
Amsterdam
1
Not G20
0.521
0.378
Singapore
16
Total
0.539
0.336
Amsterdam
1
Source CCC of CASS
5.4 Hard Environment
241
Convergence in developed countries, dispersion in developing countries. The degree of traffic congestion, power adequacy, access to information, shipping convenience, airport index and natural disaster index all determine the competitiveness level of the urban hardware environment. The advantages of the sub-indicators of the hardware environment in developed countries such as the United States and the United Kingdom are converging, and the sub-indicators of the hardware environment in developing countries are still dividing. Table 5.28 gives descriptive statistics of 6 sub-indicators of city hardware environment in major countries. Traffic congestion in cities in Australia, the United States, Japan and the United Kingdom is relatively serious. The average value of U.K. city traffic congestion is 0.641 at the maximum, and the coefficient of variation of 0.221 is only lower than that of South Africa. The most serious difference with the U.K. traffic congestion index is that the average power adequacy of U.K. cities is at most 0.973, and the minimum coefficient of variation is 0.052. At the same time, the highest average value of U.K. shipping convenience is 0.937, and the smallest coefficient of variation is 0.042. Therefore, the relative advantages of electricity adequacy and shipping convenience in U.K. cities are obvious, which helps the overall competitiveness of the U.K. cities hardware environment. U.S. cities have better access to information, with the mean being the highest in major countries of 0.77, but the coefficient of variation of 0.099 is slightly higher than 0.088 in the U.K. The highest airport index in Australia is 0.757 among the major countries, and the minimum coefficient of variation is 0.314. The highest average natural disaster index in Brazilian cities is 0.897, but the coefficient of variation is slightly less than 0.092 in the United Kingdom among the major countries. The sub-indicators of developing countries such as South Africa and India are more severely differentiated and have obvious disadvantages. Table 5.28 Descriptive statistics of sub-indicators of city hardware environment in major countries Sub-indicators Statistics Australia Brazil U.S.A. South Japan India Africa
China U.K.
Traffic congestion
Mean
0.623
0.52
0.628
0.481
0.606 0.555 0.538
0.641
CV
0.165
0.171
0.181
0.221
0.027 0.191 0.167
0.198
Power adequacy
Mean
0.947
0.778
0.795
0.826
0.825 0.629 0.52
0.973
CV
0.095
0.234
0.216
0.109
0.165 0.232 0.368
0.052
Information accessibility
Mean
0.622
0.385
0.77
0.343
0.543 0.33
0.324
0.702
CV
0.264
0.197
0.099
0.254
0.214 0.499 0.602
0.088
Shipping convenience
Mean
0.806
0.473
0.865
0.86
0.946 0.858 0.882
0.937
CV
0.302
0.358
0.157
0.116
0.064 0.095 0.116
0.042
Airport index
Mean
0.757
0.364
0.619
0.568
0.609 0.384 0.385
0.573
CV
0.314
0.396
0.454
0.408
0.394 0.392 0.479
0.399
Mean
0.79
0.897
0.843
0.744
0.581 0.838 0.808
0.821
CV
0.092
0.094
0.14
0.206
0.376 0.157 0.132
0.068
Natural disaster index
Source CCC of CASS
242
5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
5.5 Global Contacts 5.5.1 Overall Pattern of Global Contacts 5.5.1.1
Overview of the Head City
North America, Europe and Asia stand at the top of the global connected cities. Analyzing the distribution of the top 20 cities in the world, they are all located in North America, Europe and Asia, 7 cities in North America, 6 in Europe and 7 in Asia (Table 5.29). Among the top 100 cities in the global connection, there is a small gap between continents in terms of mean value and difference. Among them, North America and Europe have the highest mean value of global urban linkages, and North America Table 5.29 Global contact indicators top 20 cities in the world Region
Country
City
Index
Rank
North America
U.S.A.
New York–Newark
1.000
1
Asia
China
Beijing
0.986
2
Europe
France
Paris
0.976
3
Europe
U.K.
London
0.974
4
Asia
China
Shanghai
0.961
5
North America
U.S.A.
Chicago
0.952
6
Asia
Turkey
Istanbul
0.948
7
Europe
Spain
Madrid
0.936
8
Europe
Netherlands
Amsterdam
0.923
9
Asia
Singapore
Singapore
0.907
10
Asia
Hong Kong, China
Hong Kong
0.901
11
Europe
Italy
Milan
0.897
12
North America
Canada
Toronto
0.894
13
North America
U.S.A.
Dallas–Fort Worth
0.891
14
Europe
Russia
Moscow
0.888
15
North America
U.S.A.
Atlanta
0.886
16
North America
U.S.A.
Washington, DC
0.885
17
Asia
The United Arab Emirates
Dubai
0.877
18
North America
U.S.A.
Los Angeles–Long Beach–Santa Ana
0.864
19
Asia
Japan
Tokyo
0.859
20
Source CCC of CASS
5.5 Global Contacts
243
Table 5.30 Intercontinental distribution of the top 100 cities in the world Region
Sample
Mean
CV
Best city
Index
Rank
Asia
37
0.787
0.099
Beijing
0.986
2
Europe
30
0.806
0.103
Paris
0.976
3
North America
24
0.811
0.097
New York
1.000
1
South America
4
0.812
–
Sao Paulo
0.778
88
Oceania
4
0.777
–
Sydney
0.846
21
Global
1006
0.348
0.644
New York
1.000
1
Source CCC of CASS
has the lowest coefficient of urban variation. From the perspective of the best cities in global linkages of all continents, in Europe, North America, Asia, Oceania and South America, the best cities are Paris, New York, Beijing, Sydney and Sao Paulo respectively, with corresponding rankings of 3, 1, 2, 21 and 88 (Table 5.30).
5.5.1.2
Overall Spatial Pattern
European, North American and Asian Cities lead in global connectivity. In terms of the mean value characteristics of the intercontinental distribution of global urban linkages, the global linkages of cities in Oceania, Europe and North America are relatively strong, while the global linkages of cities in Africa and Asia are relatively weak. In terms of the coefficient of variation of the intercontinental distribution of global urban linkages, the fluctuation range of urban global linkages in Oceania is relatively small, and that in Asia is relatively large. In terms of the proportion of global top 100 cities in all continents, Oceania and Europe have a higher proportion of global top 100 cities, while South America and Asia have a lower proportion of global top 100 cities (Figs. 5.13 and 5.14; Table 5.31). In terms of the mean value of the sub indicators of global connection, the financial enterprise connection and scientific research connection of global cities are relatively high, and the number of air routes of global cities is relatively low. In terms of the coefficient of variation of the sub indicators of global connection, the fluctuation range of the global city financial enterprise connection and technology enterprise connection is relatively large, and the fluctuation range of the Information contact degree and Scientific research connection is relatively small. Among the five sub indicators, Paris, New York, London, Beijing and Singapore each have one of the top indicators in the world (Fig. 5.15 and Table 5.32).
244
5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
90
60
30
0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30
-60
-90 Fig. 5.13 Spatial distribution of global connection indicators of 1006 cities in the world. Source CCC of CASS
5.5.2 Global Connection Country Pattern 5.5.2.1
Overview of G20 Countries
There is a large gap between the number of cities in emerging and developed economies. Among them, China, the United States and the European Union occupy an absolute advantage in the number of top cities in the global contact ranking. In terms of the proportion of the top 20 and top 100 global cities, China and the United States and EU are relatively large. From the perspective of the former 20 cities, Italy, U.K., Turkey, Canada and Russia each have one city ranks in the list, while other countries have no cities in the top 20 in the world. Among them, China accounts for the highest proportion of 201–500 cities, far higher than other countries. The proportion of G20 cities in the top 20, top 100, 101–200 and 201–500 is far higher than that of non G20 cities (Table 5.33). Further analysis on the mean value and volatility of global urban linkages in G20 countries. Cities in France, Germany, Italy and the United Kingdom have obvious advantages in terms of the average of global connections, while those in India, Brazil, Saudi Arabia and Russia have relatively poor performance. According to the coefficient of variation of global connection, the fluctuation range of cities in Germany, France and Canada is relatively small, while that in Turkey, Saudi Arabia and India is relatively large (Table 5.34).
5.5 Global Contacts
245
90
60
30
0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30
-60
-90 Fig. 5.14 Spatial distribution of global connectivity indicators of the top 100 cities in the world. Source CCC of CASS
Table 5.31 Intercontinental distribution of global urban connectivity indicators Region
Sample
>100%
Mean
CV
Asia Europe
565
6.55%
0.317
0.614
126
23.81%
0.461
0.573
North America
131
18.32%
0.571
0.492
South America
75
5.33%
0.406
0.695
Oceania
7
57.14%
0.680
0.314
Africa
102
0.00%
0.331
0.241
Global
1006
9.94%
0.348
0.644
Source CCC of CASS
5.5.2.2
Overview of representative countries
This paper focuses on the comparative study of China, Japan and India in Asia, the United Kingdom in Europe, the United States in North America, Brazil in South America, South Africa in Africa and Australia in Oceania. In general, the United States, the United Kingdom, India and Australia are relatively leading in the sub
246
5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Fig. 5.15 Nuclear density map of global urban connectivity indicators Source CCC of CASS Table 5.32 Statistical description of sub indicators of global urban linkages Global connectivity
Mean
CV
Best city
Number of air lines
0.130
1.248
Paris
Information contact degree
0.347
0.635
New York
Scientific research connection
0.428
0.626
London
Contact degree of financial enterprises
0.429
1.610
Beijing
Contact degree of science and technology enterprises
0.293
1.331
Singapore
Source CCC of CASS Table 5.33 Ranking distribution of global contact indicators of sample cities in G20 countries Country
>20 (%)
>100 (%)
101–200 (%)
201–500 (%)
>500 (%)
China
30.0
23.0
21.0
45.6
35.8
U.S.A
30.0
19.0
25.0
7.3
13.0
European Union
20.0
24.0
13.0
6.0
12.6
Mexico
0.0
1.0
0.0
2.3
1.4
India
0.0
4.0
1.0
3.7
3.4
Germany
0.0
4.0
3.0
2.0
2.4
Italy
5.0
2.0
1.0
2.7
2.2
UK
5.0
3.0
2.0
2.0
2.2
Brazil
0.0
1.0
1.0
2.3
2.0
Japan
5.0
1.0
1.0
1.7
1.4
France
5.0
2.0
4.0
1.0
1.8
Canada
5.0
4.0
1.0
1.3
1.8
Russia
5.0
1.0
0.0
2.0
1.0 (continued)
5.5 Global Contacts
247
Table 5.33 (continued) Country
>20 (%)
>100 (%)
The Republic of Korea
0.0
1.0
0.0
1.3
1.0
Indonesia
0.0
1.0
0.0
2.3
1.8
Turkey
5.0
2.0
0.0
0.7
0.6
Australia
0.0
3.0
2.0
0.7
1.0
Argentina
0.0
1.0
0.0
0.0
0.2
South Africa
0.0
0.0
2.0
0.3
0.6
Saudi Arabia
0.0
1.0
1.0
1.0
0.2
G20 countries
85.0
86.0
69.0
84.0
81.4
Non G20 countries
15.0
14.0
31.0
16.0
18.6
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
Global
101–200 (%)
201–500 (%)
>500 (%)
Source CCC of CASS Table 5.34 Statistical description of global contact indicators of G20 sample cities Country
Mean
CV
Best city
Rank
France
0.6069
0.3020
Paris
3
U.S.A
0.5755
0.3526
New York
1
European Union
0.5881
0.3341
Paris
3
U.K.
0.5643
0.3656
London
4
China
0.2739
0.4019
Beijing
2
Turkey
0.4495
0.8952
Istanbul
7
Italy
0.4810
0.4285
Milan
12
Russia
0.2105
0.8630
Moscow
15
Japan
0.4031
0.5735
Tokyo
20
Canada
0.6299
0.2829
Toronto
13
Australia
0.6492
0.3458
Sydney
24
Germany
0.5846
0.0996
Berlin
27
Korea
0.3699
0.5844
Seoul
38
India
0.1988
0.9166
Bombay
40
Indonesia
0.3848
0.2964
Jakarta
59
Argentina
0.4522
0.3294
Buenos Aires
91
Mexico
0.2373
0.6119
Mexico city
87
Brazil
0.2586
0.6788
Sao Paulo
33
Saudi Arabia
0.1980
0.9383
Riyadh
121
South Africa
0.4008
0.5429
Johannesburg
107
G20 countries
0.3748
0.5874
New York–Newark
1
Non G20 countries
0.2741
0.7963
Singapore
10
Global
0.3481
0.6436
New York–Newark
1
Source CCC of CASS
248
5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
indicators of global links, while the level of new sub indicators of developing countries such as Brazil and South Africa is relatively low, and the degree of differentiation is relatively high. In terms of the average number of air routes, the United Kingdom is dominant, while Brazil’s cities are relatively poor. From the coefficient of variation of the number of air routes, the fluctuation range of cities in U.K. and Australia is relatively small. From the average of information contact degree, the city information contact degree of India and Japan is relatively low, and that of Australia, the United States and the United Kingdom is relatively high. According to the coefficient of variation of information connection, the fluctuation range of cities in Japan and Australia is relatively small, while that in India and South Africa is relatively large. From the mean value of scientific research connection degree, U.K. and Australia are relatively dominant; from the coefficient of variation of scientific research connection degree, the fluctuation range of cities in Japan and Australia is relatively small. In terms of the mean value of financial enterprise connection degree, China and Australia are relatively dominant; in terms of the coefficient of variation of financial enterprise connection degree, the fluctuation range of cities in China and the United States is relatively small. From the mean value of the degree of connection of technology enterprises, the United States and India are relatively dominant; from the coefficient of variation of the degree of connection of technology enterprises, the fluctuation range of cities in the United States and U.K. is relatively small. From the mean value of the overall situation of the global connection, the United States and the United Kingdom are relatively dominant; from the coefficient of variation of the overall situation of the global connection, the urban volatility of the United States and the United Kingdom is relatively small (Table 5.35).
5.6 Industrial Quality 5.6.1 Overall Pattern of Industrial Quality 5.6.1.1
Head City Profile
The global industrial quality of the head city intercontinental distribution is uneven. From the distribution of the top 20 cities in all continents, all of them are concentrated in North America, Europe and Asia. Among them, the number of top 20 cities in North America is 6, the number of cities in Europe is 7, and the number of cities in Asia is 7 (Table 5.36). In the world’s top 100 industrial quality cities, the average of cities across the continent is relatively close. Among them, the average value of urban industrial
Source CCC of CASS
Global connectivity
Contact degree of science and technology enterprises
Contact degree of financial enterprises
Scientific research connection
Information contact degree
Number of air lines
0.379 0.408
CV
2.065
CV Mean
0.152
0.007
CV Mean
0.760
0.771
Mean
0.272
CV
0.313
CV Mean
0.448
1.070
CV Mean
0.140
Mean
China
0.353
0.576
0.575
0.612
0.328
0.633
0.300
0.680
0.356
0.554
1.059
0.206
U.S.A.
0.916
0.199
0.704
0.338
1.514
0.578
0.720
0.319
0.743
0.249
1.423
0.053
India
Table 5.35 Statistical analysis of sub indicators of global links of representative countries
0.574
0.403
0.555
0.594
1.115
0.352
0.202
0.650
1.427
0.152
1.197
0.135
Japan
0.366
0.564
0.748
0.531
0.671
0.484
0.337
0.752
0.471
0.547
0.496
0.318
U.K.
0.543
0.401
1.549
0.280
0.808
0.493
0.254
0.629
0.523
0.315
0.760
0.154
South Africa
0.679
0.259
1.806
0.178
2.469
0.102
0.444
0.502
0.476
0.356
1.054
0.073
Brazil
0.722
0.320
0.513
0.671
0.508
0.692
0.166
0.815
0.230
0.661
0.537
0.188
Australia
5.6 Industrial Quality 249
250
5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Table 5.36 Industry quality indicators top 20 cities Continent
Country
City
Index
Ranking
Asia
Japan
Tokyo
1.000
1
North America
USA
New York–Newark
0.889
2
Europe
UK
London
0.829
3
Asia
China
Beijing
0.814
4
Europe
France
Paris
0.775
5
North America
USA
San Francisco–Oakland
0.772
6
Asia
China
Taipei
0.760
7
North America
USA
Boston
0.730
8
Europe
Switzerland
Zurich
0.714
9
Asia
South Korea
Seoul
0.711
10
North America
USA
Chicago
0.695
11
Asia
China
Hong Kong
0.681
12
North America
USA
Los Angeles–Long Beach–Santa Ana
0.680
13
Europe
Netherlands
Amsterdam
0.676
14
Europe
Russia
Moscow
0.673
15
Europe
Sweden
Stockholm
0.673
16
Europe
Germany
Frankfurt am Main
0.673
17
Asia
Singapore
Singapore
0.666
18
North America
Canada
Toronto
0.665
19
Asia
China
Shanghai
0.657
20
Source CCC of CASS
quality in Europe and Asia is the highest, the average value of urban industrial quality in South America is the lowest, and the average value of urban industrial quality in North America and Oceania is the middle. Europe, North America, Asia, Oceania and South America are London, New York, Tokyo, Sydney and São Paulo, respectively. The global ranking is 3rd, 2nd, 1st, 25th and 38th (Table 5.37).
5.6.1.2
Overall Spatial Pattern
Cities with high industrial quality are concentrated in Europe, North America and Asia. In terms of intercontinental distribution, the industrial quality of cities in North America, Oceania and Europe is relatively high, the proportion of top 100 cities is also high, the industrial quality of African cities is generally weak, no city has entered the top 100 list, the industrial quality of Asian and South American cities is in the middle, and only a small number of cities have entered the top 100 list (Figs. 5.16, 5.17 and 5.18; Table 5.38).
5.6 Industrial Quality
251
Table 5.37 Intercontinental distribution of top 100 cities in the world Region
Sample
Mean
Coefficient of variation
Optimal cities
Index
Ranking
Asia
29
0.605
0.183
Tokyo
1.000
1
Europe
28
0.618
0.130
London
0.829
3
North America
34
0.573
0.164
New York
0.889
2
South America
5
0.568
0.062
São Paulo
0.609
38
Oceania
4
0.578
0.124
Sydney
0.648
25
Global
100
0.595
0.158
Tokyo
1.000
1
Source CCC of CASS 90
60
30
0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30
-60
-90
Fig. 5.16 Spatial distribution of industrial quality indicators in 1006 cities. Source CCC of CASS
The average value and fluctuation range of the sub-index of global urban industsrial quality are quite different. From the average value of industrial quality sub-index, the average labor productivity of global cities is relatively high, and the average value of transnational scientific and technological enterprises is relatively low. From the coefficient of variation of industrial quality sub-index, the fluctuation range of transnational science and technology enterprises is relatively large, and the fluctuation range of labor productivity is relatively small. Among the five sub-indicators, the best cities of transnational banks, transnational technology enterprises, transnational corporations, labor productivity, and university index are Taipei, Tokyo, New York, San Jose and New York (Table 5.39).
252
5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness 90
60
30
0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30
-60
-90
0
1
2
3
4
5
Fig. 5.17 Spatial distribution of industrial quality indicators in top 100 cities. Source CCC of CASS
0
.2
.4 .6 industrial quality Global Europe SAmerica
.8
1
Asia NAmerica Africa
Fig. 5.18 Nuclear density map of global urban industrial quality indicators. Source CCC of CASS
5.6 Industrial Quality
253
Table 5.38 Intercontinental distribution of industrial quality indicators in global cities Region
Sample
Mean
Coefficient of variation
Asia
565
Top 100 cities (%) 5.13
0.224
0.576
Europe
126
22.22
0.378
0.430
North America
131
25.95
0.383
0.400
South America
75
6.67
0.262
0.452
Oceania
7
57.14
0.505
0.220
Africa
102
0.00
0.174
0.578
Global
1006
9.94
0.264
0.580
Source CCC of CASS
Table 5.39 Statistical description of sub-index of global urban industrial quality Industrial quality
Mean
Coefficient of variation
Optimal cities
Transnational banks
0.080
2.070
Taipei
Multinational science and technology enterprises
0.008
6.186
Tokyo
Transnational corporations
0.331
0.763
New York
Labour productivity
0.545
0.339
San José
University index
0.190
1.155
New York
Source CCC of CASS
5.6.2 National Pattern of Industrial Quality 5.6.2.1
G20 Country Profiles
Emerging economies are still lower than advanced economies in the number of leading cities in global industrial quality, and China and the United States occupy an absolute advantage in the number of top cities in G20 countries. Among the top 20 cities in the world, China and the United States accounted for 20 and 25%, respectively. Germany, Italy, the United Kingdom, Japan, France, Canada, Russia and South Korea each had one city in the list. Among the top 100 cities in the world, the proportion of American cities is as high as 27%, followed by China, accounting for 12%. Among the world’s top 101–200 cities, the number of cities in the United States is the highest, up to 22%, followed by China, accounting for 14%. before the global urban industrial quality. Among the top 500 cities in the world, the proportion of Chinese cities is the highest, reaching 24.4%, followed by the United States, accounting for 14.8% (Table 5.40). Overall, the average value of urban industrial quality in emerging economies is still lower than that in developed economies, and the degree of internal differentiation is higher than that in developed economies. In terms of the mean value of industrial quality, the cities of Australia, Canada and Japan have obvious advantages, and the
254
5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Table 5.40 Distribution of industrial quality indicators G20 national sample cities Country
Top 20 (%)
Top 100 (%)
101–200 (%)
201–500 (%)
Top 500 (%)
China
20.0
12.0
14.0
32.0
24.4
United States of America
25.0
27.0
22.0
8.3
14.8
Mexico
0.0
1.0
0.0
6.0
3.8
India
0.0
1.0
2.0
2.3
2.0
Germany
5.0
5.0
4.0
1.3
2.6
Italy
0.0
2.0
6.0
1.7
2.6
UK
5.0
2.0
5.0
1.7
2.4
Brazil
0.0
1.0
3.0
5.0
3.8
Japan
5.0
3.0
4.0
1.0
2.0
France
5.0
1.0
0.0
2.7
1.8
Canada
5.0
4.0
3.0
0.7
1.8
Russia
5.0
1.0
1.0
4.3
3.0
South Korea
5.0
1.0
0.0
2.3
1.6
Indonesia
0.0
1.0
0.0
1.0
0.8
Turkey
0.0
1.0
0.0
1.3
1.0
Australia
0.0
3.0
2.0
0.3
1.2
Argentina
0.0
1.0
0.0
1.0
0.8
South Africa
0.0
0.0
1.0
1.3
1.0
Saudi Arabia Total
0.0
1.0
1.0
0.7
0.8
80.0
68.0
68.0
75.0
72.2
Source CCC of CASS
cities of India and Indonesia have relatively poor performance. From the coefficient of variation of industrial quality, cities in Germany, Australia, Italy and Canada fluctuate less, while cities in Saudi Arabia, Russia, Indonesia, Argentina and India fluctuate more. According to the best cities of industrial quality in G20 countries, 5 cities have entered the top 20 industrial links in the world, 18 cities have entered the top 100 industrial quality in the world, and 19 cities have entered the top 200 industrial quality in the world (Table 5.41).
5.6.2.2
Representative Country Profiles
According to the intercontinental division, here focus on Asia’s China-Japan India, Europe’s Britain, North America’s United States, South America’s Brazil, Africa’s South Africa, Oceania’s Australia for comparative research. Generally speaking, cities in advanced economies have more obvious advantages in the sub-index of industrial quality, and there is a large internal differentiation in each sub-index of
5.6 Industrial Quality
255
Table 5.41 G20 statistical description of national sample city industrial quality index Country
Mean
Coefficient of variation
Optimal cities
Ranking
France
0.4050
0.3488
Paris
5
United States of America
0.4500
0.2839
New York
2
UK
0.4334
0.3190
London
3
China
0.2409
0.4388
Beijing
4
EU
0.4567
0.2580
London
3
Turkey
0.2258
0.4807
Istanbul
55
Italy
0.4112
0.2136
Milan
26
Russia
0.2283
0.4514
Moscow
15
Japan
0.4918
0.4039
Tokyo
1
Canada
0.4855
0.2020
Toronto
19
Australia
0.5084
0.2392
Sydney
25
Germany
0.4757
0.2338
Frankfurt
17
South Korea
0.3650
0.3976
Seoul
10
India
0.1413
0.5982
Mumbai
48
Indonesia
0.1959
0.4655
Jakarta
66
Argentina
0.2462
0.5222
Buenos Aires
56
Mexico
0.2266
0.3950
Mexico City
54
Brazil
0.2501
0.4165
São Paulo
38
Saudi Arabia
0.2662
0.5706
Riyadh
34
South Africa
0.3028
0.3887
Johannesburg
117
G20
0.2706
0.5449
Tokyo
1
Non G20
0.2191
0.6636
Zurich
9
Global
0.2640
0.5800
Tokyo
1
Source CCC of CASS
cities in emerging economies. From the cross-border banking index, the average value of urban industrial quality in Japan and Australia is higher, and the coefficient of variation of urban industrial quality in China, India and Brazil is relatively high. From the cross-border technology enterprise index, the average value of Japanese cities is higher, and the coefficient of variation of China, India and Brazil is higher. According to the MNC index, the urban mean of the United States and Britain is higher, and the coefficient of variation of Brazil, China and South Africa is higher. From the labor productivity index, the average value of cities in the United States, Japan and Australia is higher, and the coefficient of variation is higher in China and India. From the university index, the average of British and Australian cities is higher, and the coefficient of variation of India and Brazil is higher (Table 5.42).
Source CCC of CASS
Industrial quality
University index
Labour productivity
Transnational corporations
Multinational science and technology enterprises
Transnational banks
0.241 0.439
Coefficient of variation
1.340
Coefficient of variation
Mean
0.121
0.172
Coefficient of variation
Mean
0.542
0.535
Mean
0.298
Coefficient of variation
5.487
Coefficient of variation
Mean
0.005
2.188
Coefficient of variation
Mean
0.062
Mean
China
0.284
0.450
0.663
0.455
0.056
0.861
0.354
0.544
2.711
0.032
1.147
0.140
USA
0.598
0.141
0.904
0.089
0.179
0.360
1.534
0.128
6.701
0.001
3.282
0.036
India
Table 5.42 Statistical analysis of sub-indicators of industrial quality in representative countries
0.404
0.492
0.523
0.416
0.047
0.804
0.405
0.487
2.257
0.139
0.637
0.334
Japan
0.319
0.433
0.236
0.638
0.047
0.788
0.447
0.502
3.144
0.027
2.090
0.102
UK
0.389
0.303
0.642
0.303
0.107
0.519
0.587
0.490
–
0.000
2.449
0.055
South Africa
0.417
0.250
0.799
0.232
0.118
0.533
0.748
0.305
3.935
0.001
2.549
0.050
Brazil
0.239
0.508
0.158
0.680
0.035
0.846
0.350
0.651
1.595
0.008
0.107
0.194
Australia
256 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic …
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
257
Country
U.S.A.
U.K.
Singapore
China
U.S.A.
Japan
U.S.A.
Germany
U.S.A.
China
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
China
Ireland
Republic of Korea
U.S.A.
China
China
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
City
New York–Newark
London
Singapore
Shenzhen
San Jose
Tokyo
San Francisco–Oakland
Munich
Los Angeles–Long Beach–Santa Ana
Shanghai
Dallas–Fort Worth
Houston
Hong Kong
Dublin
Seoul
Boston
Beijing
Guangzhou
Miami
Chicago
20
19
18
17
16
15
14
13
12
11
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
Economic competitiveness
4
32
45
39
15
9
27
28
56
83
5
58
76
70
17
114
1
8
7
2
Local factors
9
47
87
192
23
49
18
108
10
57
197
36
8
130
1
73
162
4
19
20
Living environment
16
49
88
38
12
8
44
3
34
50
47
7
18
20
1
41
59
2
5
4
Soft environment
228
134
209
138
46
37
21
300
131
12
182
132
56
59
55
173
86
16
15
27
Hard environment
6
32
29
2
26
38
22
11
23
14
5
19
34
39
20
122
37
10
4
1
Global contacts
(continued)
11
111
60
4
8
10
24
12
44
31
20
13
21
6
1
69
76
18
3
2
Industrial quality
258 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Country
France
Germany
Israel
U.S.A.
China
Sweden
U.S.A.
Germany
Japan
Canada
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
Germany
U.S.A.
Switzerland
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
Australia
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
Turkey
City
Paris
Frankfurt am Main
Tel Aviv–Yafo
Seattle
Suzhou
Stockholm
Philadelphia
Stuttgart
Osaka
Toronto
Baltimore
Bridgeport–Stamford
Dusseldorf
San Diego
Geneva
Atlanta
Cleveland
Perth
Denver–Aurora
Detroit
Istanbul
(continued)
41
40
39
38
37
36
35
34
33
32
31
30
29
28
27
26
25
24
23
22
21
Economic competitiveness
16
122
106
175
115
80
435
161
179
243
97
20
59
71
11
49
63
86
277
90
31
Local factors
75
211
199
473
84
26
194
50
138
144
40
161
3
41
14
63
201
46
440
93
55
Living environment
130
150
24
172
121
75
99
14
141
159
127
10
9
119
39
94
92
13
185
100
72
Soft environment
183
25
152
168
99
14
44
258
3
116
18
17
79
41
11
66
482
144
236
8
5
Hard environment
7
77
43
118
124
16
103
150
141
303
63
13
120
96
62
35
100
44
99
168
3
Global contacts
(continued)
55
73
177
114
82
37
32
35
57
127
96
19
42
63
79
16
250
40
39
17
5
Industrial quality
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic … 259
Country
China
China
China
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
Germany
U.S.A.
Germany
Austria
United Arab Emirates
U.S.A.
China
Germany
U.S.A.
Switzerland
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
Denmark
U.S.A.
City
Nanjing
Wuhan
Taipei
Charlotte
Nashville–Davidson
Minneapolis–Saint Paul
Berlin
Austin
Hamburg
Vienna
Abu Dhabi
Raleigh
Chengdu
Cologne
Las Vegas
Zurich
Salt Lake City
Richmond
Copenhagen
Orlando
(continued)
61
60
59
58
57
56
55
54
53
52
51
50
49
48
47
46
45
44
43
42
Economic competitiveness
158
101
155
154
84
221
581
52
178
102
99
72
110
57
82
149
150
48
120
54
Local factors
42
124
99
149
80
157
44
119
34
773
27
21
32
11
71
24
59
17
419
257
Living environment
113
51
129
70
54
125
105
165
63
27
35
101
37
43
69
180
71
6
86
65
Soft environment
34
32
142
26
39
90
108
391
305
275
6
19
198
23
214
249
157
81
443
279
Hard environment
79
65
176
159
48
140
291
28
193
113
42
52
76
27
104
115
49
64
51
41
Global contacts
(continued)
151
29
93
74
9
165
149
101
80
45
27
70
88
102
103
133
94
7
64
77
Industrial quality
260 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Country
Russian
Australia
China
China
Spain
U.K.
China
U.S.A.
Canada
Belgium
United Arab Emirates
Canada
Qatar
Germany
China
U.S.A.
Japan
U.S.A.
Germany
China
City
Moscow
Sydney
Hangzhou
Wuxi
Barcelona
Birmingham
Changsha
Milwaukee
Vancouver
Brussels
Dubai
Calgary
Doha
Hannover
Qingdao
Columbus
Sendai
Louisville
Essen
Chongqing
(continued)
81
80
79
78
77
76
75
74
73
72
71
70
69
68
67
66
65
64
63
62
Economic competitiveness
73
543
199
626
130
143
113
509
43
46
137
157
174
128
287
22
182
95
19
18
Local factors
94
179
102
38
39
191
66
804
367
570
203
53
202
112
143
79
251
160
101
88
Living environment
179
190
115
40
67
151
154
168
15
17
231
25
131
157
96
143
139
90
73
62
Soft environment
855
118
117
322
250
423
35
156
33
197
7
4
68
637
36
40
286
472
9
48
Hard environment
46
334
184
557
129
81
256
93
91
18
31
61
272
72
80
21
170
47
24
15
Global contacts
(continued)
119
292
121
113
72
95
132
28
104
59
23
67
156
164
161
78
302
87
25
15
Industrial quality
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic … 261
Country
China
Malaysia
China
U.S.A.
Republic of Korea
U.S.A.
U.K.
Saudi Arabia
China
U.S.A.
Belgium
Netherlands
China
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
Germany
China
Israel
Canada
City
Tianjin
Kuala Lumpur
Foshan
Washington, DC
Ulsan
Oklahoma City
Manchester
Riyadh
Ningbo
Phoenix-Mesa
Antwerp
Amsterdam
Zhengzhou
Tampa–St. Petersburg
Baton Rouge
Cincinnati
Dortmund
Changzhou
Haifa
Montreal
(continued)
101
100
99
98
97
96
95
94
93
92
91
90
89
88
87
86
85
84
83
82
Economic competitiveness
30
341
306
606
105
248
140
177
109
786
119
171
44
209
256
340
10
98
6
29
Local factors
163
404
326
171
54
65
187
289
172
151
353
245
759
98
68
222
129
189
175
270
Living environment
31
216
259
200
60
170
196
181
95
225
64
187
109
66
120
91
22
229
138
134
Soft environment
154
104
383
94
20
88
113
368
1
65
297
410
354
24
72
164
193
364
22
261
Hard environment
50
318
313
264
155
217
131
95
9
342
83
146
121
58
236
608
17
364
70
60
Global contacts
(continued)
47
187
347
238
68
220
214
146
14
120
209
128
34
71
116
303
41
342
30
83
Industrial quality
262 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Country
Indonesia
Japan
China
U.S.A.
Japan
Norway
Germany
Netherlands
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
Canada
China
Australia
U.S.A.
Germany
U.S.A.
Saudi Arabia
Thailand
Australia
China
U.S.A.
City
Jakarta
Nagoya
Dongguan
San Antonio
Hiroshima
Oslo
Dresden
Hague
Indianapolis
Provo–Orem
Hamilton
Macao
Gold Coast
Kansas City
Leipzig
Virginia Beach
Jedda
Bangkok
Brisbane
Nantong
Pittsburgh
(continued)
122
121
120
119
118
117
116
115
114
113
112
111
110
109
108
107
106
105
104
103
102
Economic competitiveness
112
133
153
21
841
387
588
53
476
576
232
625
132
586
450
41
648
147
33
142
36
Local factors
105
338
294
48
636
141
81
25
181
531
78
693
58
312
206
70
2
35
264
67
210
Living environment
53
280
111
128
197
146
175
85
230
314
87
274
98
116
135
81
46
82
204
21
186
Soft environment
31
390
93
122
384
84
165
10
336
75
135
284
45
85
97
29
398
64
233
206
126
Hard environment
112
349
85
30
528
538
198
163
695
185
439
466
156
404
299
73
399
136
130
229
59
Global contacts
(continued)
75
343
58
36
166
291
197
85
275
256
203
326
109
152
201
51
229
175
245
65
66
Industrial quality
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic … 263
Country
Australia
Finland
Spain
China
U.S.A.
Mexico
U.S.A.
Canada
Republic of Korea
Japan
U.S.A.
U.K.
Sweden
U.S.A.
Italy
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
France
China
Japan
City
Melbourne
Helsinki
Madrid
Kaohsiung
Charleston–North Charleston
Mexico City
Hartford
Ottawa–Gatineau
Incheon
Sapporo
Riverside–San Bernardino
Bristol
Gothenburg
Allentown
Rome
Colorado Springs
Grand Rapids
Lille
Jinan
Kitakyushu–Fukuoka
(continued)
142
141
140
139
138
137
136
135
134
133
132
131
130
129
128
127
126
125
124
123
Economic competitiveness
12
272
682
285
358
600
372
726
328
391
197
251
196
207
13
245
413
81
100
96
Local factors
5
395
428
136
111
7
153
120
183
514
12
253
254
122
29
293
82
56
176
60
Living environment
68
213
284
118
110
142
279
167
61
164
29
76
117
160
188
195
30
78
55
122
Soft environment
82
471
110
174
269
71
87
51
52
696
217
221
54
129
171
295
438
58
43
13
Hard environment
301
117
183
247
254
25
646
251
101
586
435
333
138
246
87
202
223
8
75
36
Global contacts
(continued)
148
106
252
230
239
92
380
145
150
397
179
366
147
221
54
208
269
22
43
33
Industrial quality
264 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Country
Italy
U.S.A.
China
France
Thailand
China
China
China
Canada
Netherlands
China
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
Chile
U.S.A.
U.K.
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
India
Costa Rica
China
City
Milan
Providence
Hefei
Lyon
Samut Prakan
Quanzhou
Xiamen
Xi’an
Edmonton
Rotterdam
Fuzhou (FJ)
Birmingham
Honolulu
Santiago de Chile
Columbia
West Yorkshire
Worcester
Dayton
Delhi
San Jose
Yangzhou
(continued)
163
162
161
160
159
158
157
156
155
154
153
152
151
150
149
148
147
146
145
144
143
Economic competitiveness
324
506
40
263
217
299
126
79
260
430
172
507
238
94
91
180
871
488
50
176
131
Local factors
306
127
145
142
337
31
30
243
121
64
276
298
190
208
560
168
213
195
413
125
52
Living environment
250
263
236
210
189
26
124
166
83
147
214
148
42
126
137
318
291
209
183
145
133
Soft environment
342
461
420
92
223
141
278
853
285
196
688
42
61
405
186
339
63
106
427
190
28
Hard environment
312
169
54
277
704
615
111
160
224
252
149
279
237
55
84
344
711
94
89
204
12
Global contacts
(continued)
323
125
290
260
318
365
108
49
122
86
274
160
91
110
99
261
709
202
142
105
26
Industrial quality
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic … 265
Country
New Zealand
U.S.A.
Spain
Peru
U.S.A.
Colombia
U.K.
Saudi Arabia
U.S.A.
China
China
China
France
U.K.
Israel
U.K.
China
Panama
Romania
Italy
U.S.A.
City
Auckland
Cape Coral
Valencia
Lima
Akron
Bogota
Liverpool
Medina
Knoxville
Zhuhai
Zhenjiang
Yantai
Marseille–Aix-en-Provence
Sheffield
Jerusalem
Belfast
Taizhou (JS)
Panama City
Bucuresti
Venice
Sacramento
(continued)
184
183
182
181
180
179
178
177
176
175
174
173
172
171
170
169
168
167
166
165
164
Economic competitiveness
191
952
144
266
164
442
375
364
528
189
195
127
258
461
360
26
253
38
383
777
62
Local factors
96
133
209
164
451
123
423
169
427
150
384
350
90
897
188
348
261
184
249
342
15
Living environment
79
207
182
317
300
123
239
93
473
292
307
272
112
222
84
226
178
294
212
256
11
Soft environment
62
109
130
338
428
70
147
133
195
392
309
304
80
477
89
394
73
737
203
119
188
Hard environment
180
620
106
157
350
276
295
335
109
206
331
327
225
796
240
45
562
68
119
947
74
Global contacts
(continued)
204
315
178
90
450
195
191
253
212
248
340
241
180
478
225
81
259
124
224
574
97
Industrial quality
266 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Country
China
U.K.
U.S.A.
Philippines
Saudi Arabia
U.S.A.
China
Republic of Korea
Poland
U.S.A.
Republic of Korea
Argentina
China
Republic of Korea
Republic of Korea
China
Spain
Australia
City
Dalian
Glasgow
Buffalo
Manila
Mecca
New Haven
Xuzhou
Busan
Warsaw
Ogden
Changwon
Buenos Aires
Nanchang
Gwangju
Daejeon
Shenyang
Zaragoza
Adelaide
(continued)
202
201
200
199
198
197
196
195
194
193
192
191
190
189
188
187
186
185
Economic competitiveness
210
814
293
225
355
104
61
471
458
66
37
169
185
608
64
203
283
311
Local factors
265
230
115
292
156
235
6
495
272
140
85
357
214
879
117
320
45
95
Living environment
103
220
191
58
136
260
286
162
199
77
33
321
215
227
217
114
52
153
Soft environment
114
292
421
264
115
588
734
180
212
50
107
478
100
599
176
401
53
370
Hard environment
147
678
97
464
644
137
66
924
692
71
245
296
362
829
110
266
108
88
Global contacts
(continued)
153
186
182
282
336
198
56
379
350
53
206
367
184
607
89
205
155
112
Industrial quality
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic … 267
Mexico
Turkey
China
Czech Republic 207
Uruguay
Kazakhstan
China
France
Portugal
China
U.S.A.
China
Italy
U.S.A.
France
Republic of Korea
India
Turkey
Italy
Monterrey
Gebze
Zhongshan
Prague
Montevideo
Astana
Shaoxing
Toulouse
Lisbon
Taichung
Omaha
Jiaxing
Bologna
Memphis
Nantes
Daegu
Mumbai
Ankara
Naples
222
221
220
219
218
217
216
215
214
213
212
211
210
209
208
206
205
204
203
China
Dongying
Economic competitiveness
Country
City
(continued)
744
135
3
282
732
186
805
363
262
425
51
560
428
598
525
193
75
492
103
720
Local factors
227
260
438
86
341
77
62
224
104
103
137
147
170
361
167
72
232
782
378
493
Living environment
266
177
247
74
246
163
232
206
107
23
155
245
328
359
412
48
198
520
238
367
Soft environment
96
399
83
170
159
57
95
189
112
457
2
161
530
661
143
128
317
571
101
728
Hard environment
244
215
40
387
171
192
222
338
187
443
90
153
294
521
189
57
191
767
323
614
Global contacts
(continued)
240
215
48
262
235
139
118
296
129
219
50
257
255
349
123
61
431
601
228
273
Industrial quality
268 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Country
France
Belgium
Italy
U.K.
Poland
U.S.A.
U.K.
Turkey
France
China
Hungary
France
China
Germany
Japan
Argentina
China
China
U.S.A.
China
City
Nice
Liege
Verona
Leicester
Poznan
Sarasota-Bradenton
Nottingham
Izmir
Bordeaux
Changchun
Budapest
Toulon
Weihai
Bremen
Shizuoka–Hamamatsu M.M.A.
Rosario
Wuhu
Zibo
Rochester
Hsinchu
(continued)
242
241
240
239
238
237
236
235
234
233
232
231
230
229
228
227
226
225
224
223
Economic competitiveness
345
138
200
159
309
694
526
384
935
24
376
596
145
373
374
519
447
911
838
791
Local factors
196
113
305
469
217
13
226
155
674
132
502
237
215
76
43
242
177
89
280
248
Living environment
56
57
277
306
744
36
184
346
396
158
173
235
176
80
132
192
102
201
313
254
Soft environment
289
98
226
466
313
486
49
356
259
47
548
145
591
78
202
191
111
103
201
194
Hard environment
197
282
253
339
591
371
310
420
487
56
133
265
517
233
472
346
269
305
721
243
Global contacts
(continued)
211
268
288
433
389
154
210
330
327
100
168
243
338
207
414
265
246
157
263
251
Industrial quality
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic … 269
Country
Spain
Italy
China
Canada
U.S.A.
Italy
China
U.S.A.
China
Turkey
U.S.A.
Japan
China
Canada
China
Brazil
Saudi Arabia
China
Argentina
China
China
City
Malaga
Florence
Guiyang
Quebec
New Orleans
Genoa
Tainan
Tulsa
Weifang
Bursa
Albany
Kumamoto
Yancheng
Winnipeg
Tangshan
Sao Paulo
Dammam
Shijiazhuang
Santa Fe
Wenzhou
Yichang
(continued)
263
262
261
260
259
258
257
256
255
254
253
252
251
250
249
248
247
246
245
244
243
Economic competitiveness
334
643
610
136
913
25
117
349
290
872
211
350
371
304
535
942
229
226
139
846
874
Local factors
302
228
37
347
922
776
394
166
425
33
333
297
332
131
83
91
100
414
304
74
174
Living environment
303
324
486
249
271
724
275
89
339
45
152
221
336
140
28
281
161
106
342
218
242
Soft environment
743
467
605
260
589
414
604
121
413
550
439
538
495
69
473
247
239
192
519
172
185
Hard environment
357
175
669
142
840
33
211
208
379
844
199
710
410
227
283
598
293
267
134
320
258
Global contacts
(continued)
373
247
508
249
443
38
393
192
496
333
236
461
454
144
188
163
196
216
258
231
217
Industrial quality
270 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Country
China
Italy
South Africa
China
Japan
Venezuela
Brazil
China
Mexico
Indonesia
United Arab Emirates
Venezuela
U.S.A.
Poland
Brazil
China
Dominican Republic
Russian
China
China
City
Taizhou (ZJ)
Torino
Pretoria
Kunming
Niigata
Maracaibo
Rio de Janeiro
Huizhou
Guadalajara
Surabaya
Sharjah
Maracay
Bakersfield
Krakow
Jundiai
Baotou
Santo Domingo
Tyumen
Tongling
Xiangyang
(continued)
283
282
281
280
279
278
277
276
275
274
273
272
271
270
269
268
267
266
265
264
Economic competitiveness
230
190
573
782
449
803
416
522
843
239
218
118
116
35
667
845
173
123
745
423
Local factors
500
526
263
200
717
422
231
374
937
853
266
319
134
92
958
22
118
236
51
256
Living environment
363
419
289
762
362
738
171
149
1000
156
223
400
287
364
1001
32
202
285
194
312
Soft environment
904
424
905
330
835
446
277
323
487
210
178
139
796
453
184
293
590
524
343
481
Hard environment
416
498
716
273
268
675
145
679
838
834
284
216
377
102
968
841
78
611
231
289
Global contacts
(continued)
453
482
416
143
293
670
264
346
493
189
392
316
401
190
328
222
223
317
199
390
Industrial quality
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic … 271
Country
Kuwait
South Africa
Russian
India
China
Iran
Portugal
China
Poland
China
China
Venezuela
U.S.A.
Venezuela
China
China
Turkmenistan
Puerto Rico
China
Iran
Egypt
City
Kuwait City
Johannesburg
Saint Petersburg
Bangalore
Taiyuan
Karaj
Porto
Huaian
Lodz
Nanning
Hohhot
Barcelona–Puerto La Cruz
Fresno
Valencia
Jining
Ordoss
Ashgabat
San Juan
Harbin
Ahvaz
Cairo
(continued)
304
303
302
301
300
299
298
297
296
295
294
293
292
291
290
289
288
287
286
285
284
Economic competitiveness
55
630
181
148
958
884
649
237
405
213
327
357
599
331
749
393
69
60
124
14
534
Local factors
490
929
518
299
930
628
354
942
246
986
328
274
239
406
275
822
352
16
139
285
970
Living environment
478
802
234
704
902
424
366
1004
144
1006
332
219
203
351
330
839
282
241
174
357
374
Soft environment
213
791
760
38
315
670
425
479
266
595
607
778
388
357
102
838
429
91
617
105
74
Hard environment
98
860
86
165
630
328
250
783
691
589
181
116
270
356
82
751
148
69
205
107
132
Global contacts
(continued)
136
686
173
84
372
403
301
281
299
360
308
300
314
616
138
759
297
183
137
117
244
Industrial quality
272 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Country
Italy
Kazakhstan
China
Bangladesh
Bulgaria
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
Algeria
Malaysia
Italy
China
Venezuela
U.K.
China
Turkey
China
Brazil
China
China
Turkey
China
City
Catania
Almaty
Zhoushan
Dhaka
Sofia
El Paso
Portland
Oran
Johor Bahru
Padova
Jinhua
Caracas
Newcastle upon Tyne
Luoyang
Adana
Huzhou
Porto Alegre
Taian
Langfang
Antalya
Urumqi
(continued)
325
324
323
322
321
320
319
318
317
316
315
314
313
312
311
310
309
308
307
306
305
Economic competitiveness
567
569
233
468
265
216
440
524
397
268
284
905
635
891
219
444
337
85
386
183
943
Local factors
439
69
458
533
351
258
408
268
571
829
148
109
273
839
97
449
216
205
499
705
193
Living environment
464
244
402
446
674
401
310
331
104
993
373
257
228
943
19
97
295
884
460
467
377
Soft environment
815
582
125
646
419
418
520
516
120
207
534
166
77
329
30
241
549
745
299
984
244
Hard environment
162
581
281
500
571
427
596
186
454
196
401
154
663
360
105
393
67
161
409
257
462
Global contacts
(continued)
321
533
447
545
193
457
732
305
171
52
442
170
294
423
98
329
141
266
437
115
287
Industrial quality
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic … 273
Country
Azerbaijan
China
Guatemala
China
Mexico
U.S.A.
China
Italy
China
Saudi Arabia
Libya
Oman
Mexico
Croatia
Argentina
Israel
Kenya
U.S.A.
Belarus
Jordan
China
City
Baku
Zhuzhou
Guatemala City
Putian
Leon
Albuquerque
Xiangtan
Bari
Xuchang
Buraydah
Tripoli
Muscat
Tijuana
Zagreb
Mendoza
Be’er Sheva
Nairobi
McAllen
Minsk
Amman
Shantou
(continued)
346
345
344
343
342
341
340
339
338
337
336
335
334
333
332
331
330
329
328
327
326
Economic competitiveness
107
776
286
758
87
515
692
170
273
609
894
867
339
705
584
223
108
446
779
517
336
Local factors
381
673
314
740
496
882
365
135
477
712
359
906
627
165
534
240
554
523
331
362
609
Living environment
456
205
255
268
517
311
711
265
372
273
946
305
589
340
355
169
358
514
509
378
262
Soft environment
341
523
542
149
660
585
914
137
240
187
246
451
298
175
320
227
328
575
692
782
306
Hard environment
358
194
280
771
143
724
697
125
577
372
489
933
503
418
314
311
304
421
255
214
200
Global contacts
(continued)
514
134
169
492
130
337
474
174
364
135
377
695
512
176
374
289
272
452
167
395
280
Industrial quality
274 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Country
Argentina
China
Cuba
Malaysia
China
China
Indonesia
Brazil
Mexico
China
China
Argentina
China
Colombia
China
Greece
Brazil
China
India
China
Iraq
City
Mar Del Plata
Jiaozuo
Havana
Ipoh
Lianyungang
Dezhou
Samarinda
Greater Vitória
San Luis Potosi
Yueyang
Suqian
Cordoba
Liaocheng
Medellin
Ezhou
Thessaloniki
Belo Horizonte
Rizhao
Chennai
Linyi
Baghdad
(continued)
367
366
365
364
363
362
361
360
359
358
357
356
355
354
353
352
351
350
349
348
347
Economic competitiveness
390
583
74
559
68
921
382
129
496
510
321
674
214
669
743
774
134
332
558
467
784
Local factors
914
392
182
479
471
510
703
262
685
212
626
456
300
601
442
561
528
234
657
512
269
Living environment
876
457
276
565
617
499
531
267
602
618
472
399
389
903
380
436
441
333
755
476
836
Soft environment
215
433
67
652
347
60
435
245
503
272
369
767
314
326
387
656
554
282
335
573
358
Hard environment
230
367
92
457
391
374
508
212
388
554
456
473
352
846
788
483
413
900
660
460
755
Global contacts
(continued)
309
344
162
376
304
242
521
232
548
345
665
541
335
768
565
582
613
412
735
528
736
Industrial quality
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic … 275
Country
China
China
Brazil
China
China
China
Saudi Arabia
Iran
China
Colombia
Angola
Latvia
China
Brazil
Lebanon
Italy
Indonesia
China
China
China
Mexico
City
Binzhou
Haikou
Curitiba
Lanzhou
Cangzhou
Ma’anshan
Hufuf-Mubarraz
Tehran
Zaozhuang
Cali
Luanda
Riga
Jiangmen
Sao Jose dos Campos
Beirut
Palermo
Pekanbaru
Yinchuan
Liuzhou
Xinyu
Merida
(continued)
388
387
386
385
384
383
382
381
380
379
378
377
376
375
374
373
372
371
370
369
368
Economic competitiveness
322
612
438
396
686
893
254
767
369
249
904
187
725
42
875
487
563
151
278
351
787
Local factors
400
639
225
511
798
233
802
28
291
152
863
313
567
356
940
731
563
503
373
221
516
Living environment
264
513
413
482
414
323
746
248
371
233
975
296
494
561
361
404
452
334
553
405
511
Soft environment
211
581
843
540
267
265
124
611
291
352
426
287
274
770
409
235
626
800
200
506
465
Hard environment
361
580
484
203
491
481
164
787
492
195
319
359
592
178
795
378
468
123
228
190
499
Global contacts
(continued)
418
572
334
331
517
276
62
385
369
200
194
313
662
227
641
404
310
213
363
352
547
Industrial quality
276 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Country
Mexico
Mexico
China
Argentina
Paraguay
Brazil
Nigeria
China
China
Indonesia
U.S.A.
China
China
Brazil
Dominican Republic
Ecuador
Chile
Mexico
Brazil
China
City
Villahermosa
Cancun
Changde
San Miguel de Tucuman
Asuncion
Ribeirao Preto
Lagos
Xianyang
Maoming
Balikpapan
Tucson
Deyang
Longyan
Campinas
Santiago de Los Caballeros
Quito
Valparaiso
Queretaro
Joinville
Huangshi
(continued)
408
407
406
405
404
403
402
401
400
399
398
397
396
395
394
393
392
391
390
389
Economic competitiveness
165
520
270
192
326
621
241
849
495
194
715
319
406
77
729
571
869
702
592
462
Local factors
589
488
252
727
295
527
255
296
481
154
786
321
459
316
525
303
664
322
399
409
Living environment
670
785
290
390
799
797
668
552
537
108
376
411
409
845
899
695
881
417
415
408
Soft environment
655
400
155
492
879
593
334
930
818
416
373
733
663
431
476
469
253
783
349
430
Hard environment
429
870
343
337
179
572
302
649
560
158
386
510
306
151
715
287
808
568
681
879
Global contacts
(continued)
456
356
370
455
172
394
283
413
438
181
486
650
536
126
405
306
811
519
426
520
Industrial quality
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic … 277
Country
Spain
China
Poland
China
Nigeria
Mexico
Indonesia
China
China
India
China
China
China
Viet Nam
China
Turkey
China
Russian
China
South Africa
Nigeria
City
Seville
Zhangzhou
Wroclaw
Zunyi
Benin City
Torreon
Batam
Hengyang
Sanming
Kolkata
Wuhai
Beihai
Panjin
Ho Chi Minh City
Jieyang
Denizli
Zhaoqing
Ufa
Yulin (SX)
Cape Town
Port Harcourt
(continued)
429
428
427
426
425
424
423
422
421
420
419
418
417
416
415
414
413
412
411
410
409
Economic competitiveness
470
125
400
537
298
691
201
34
908
759
873
23
898
469
728
480
589
464
530
448
854
Local factors
719
61
398
336
259
623
375
126
501
431
907
180
318
433
370
452
650
330
207
283
282
Living environment
922
251
492
388
384
261
598
448
481
672
661
326
590
426
459
422
944
504
193
391
240
Soft environment
386
307
717
332
346
747
600
163
296
441
470
302
915
893
327
361
934
754
158
584
366
Hard environment
903
126
430
758
585
891
394
166
556
417
685
144
512
382
777
954
894
490
219
396
336
Global contacts
(continued)
424
233
480
422
578
739
690
140
587
507
543
226
469
470
829
510
818
458
267
440
254
Industrial quality
278 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Country
Mexico
China
China
South Africa
Brazil
Pakistan
Mexico
Malaysia
China
China
Greece
China
China
China
China
China
Viet Nam
China
India
China
China
City
Matamoros
Panzhihua
Jiujiang
Durban
Brasilia
Karachi
Juarez
Kuching
Heze
Anyang
Athens
Zhanjiang
Ningde
Baoji
Puyang
Chenzhou
Hanoi
Bengbu
Kochi
Xining
Xinxiang
(continued)
450
449
448
447
446
445
444
443
442
441
440
439
438
437
436
435
434
433
432
431
430
Economic competitiveness
257
404
162
531
47
418
820
308
645
280
67
224
607
367
227
89
313
163
721
856
565
Local factors
715
492
271
659
114
587
749
315
388
401
325
743
676
247
556
390
159
301
307
475
646
Living environment
407
567
299
526
410
485
506
505
469
352
429
568
634
211
502
573
463
512
387
527
700
Soft environment
281
876
218
792
251
809
615
941
579
475
76
459
738
224
564
365
645
216
674
895
541
Hard environment
307
220
463
398
167
434
624
509
447
369
53
432
525
640
570
127
241
368
526
637
883
Global contacts
(continued)
487
286
319
506
107
483
648
473
500
368
46
550
703
419
362
185
158
307
312
531
788
Industrial quality
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic … 279
Country
China
Brazil
Mexico
India
China
China
Nigeria
China
China
Mexico
Mexico
Russian
India
Indonesia
China
Colombia
China
China
Brazil
Cambodia
Iraq
City
Kaifeng
Sorocaba
Toluca
Coimbatore
Yingtan
Handan
Owerri
Yangjiang
Zigong
Aguascalientes
Saltillo
Samara
Malappuram
Bandung
Sanya
Cartagena
Liupanshui
Yingkou
Recife
Phnom Penh
Erbil
(continued)
471
470
469
468
467
466
465
464
463
462
461
460
459
458
457
456
455
454
453
452
451
Economic competitiveness
956
231
365
890
796
269
457
281
453
561
300
378
538
637
650
359
859
156
240
660
401
Local factors
861
836
286
349
803
640
281
106
823
466
564
173
694
355
903
520
630
410
486
603
682
Living environment
901
732
759
493
685
421
491
258
852
243
392
298
591
534
918
427
475
471
468
745
455
Soft environment
787
243
766
150
846
255
609
669
586
533
633
324
823
375
689
771
602
319
169
372
700
Hard environment
419
249
389
330
535
633
363
238
845
587
702
794
524
461
927
370
597
408
622
821
326
Global contacts
(continued)
381
270
353
375
619
658
532
358
888
515
476
408
513
657
742
499
552
599
530
503
586
Industrial quality
280 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Country
Colombia
China
China
China
China
China
Nigeria
Nigeria
China
El Salvador
Turkey
Argentina
China
Chile
Turkey
China
Sri Lanka
China
China
Russian
Indonesia
City
Villavicencio
Pingxiang
Shangrao
Luohe
Hebi
Jingmen
Uyo
Aba
Yuxi
San Salvador
Mersin
La Plata
Nanyang
Concepcion
Samsun
Guilin
Colombo
Chaozhou
Baoding
Perm
Semarang
(continued)
492
491
490
489
488
487
486
485
484
483
482
481
480
479
478
477
476
475
474
473
472
Economic competitiveness
518
549
330
379
708
329
690
619
215
627
539
320
620
601
634
762
835
739
795
481
684
Local factors
178
339
417
445
447
223
267
524
453
538
482
450
323
921
913
386
763
681
311
565
548
Living environment
283
385
369
620
516
375
316
315
462
821
344
720
440
931
926
490
675
727
639
563
863
Soft environment
625
708
857
355
242
878
521
436
650
252
706
643
804
464
583
817
397
331
922
911
511
Hard environment
422
545
365
519
177
286
743
740
285
593
735
271
325
804
912
634
467
446
480
655
970
Global contacts
(continued)
680
449
465
679
131
341
655
322
542
712
715
295
505
827
760
575
646
664
678
556
676
Industrial quality
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic … 281
Country
China
China
China
Nigeria
Ecuador
Georgia
China
China
Indonesia
Pakistan
China
China
Russian
China
China
China
India
China
India
China
China
City
Yichun (JX)
Ganzhou
Karamay
Ikorodu
Guayaquil
Tbilisi
Jilin
Zhoukou
Makassar
Lahore
Pingdingshan
Quzhou
Yaroslavl
Neijiang
Liaoyuan
Shangqiu
Hyderabad
Ziyang
Pune
Sanmenxia
Loudi
(continued)
513
512
511
510
509
508
507
506
505
504
503
502
501
500
499
498
497
496
495
494
493
Economic competitiveness
653
924
93
918
65
831
969
499
753
663
623
88
622
798
160
264
482
863
689
459
741
Local factors
649
530
128
736
219
671
658
696
416
484
654
420
317
656
436
710
380
894
890
309
448
Living environment
529
657
345
665
270
616
659
593
350
447
397
489
301
544
224
208
867
935
536
562
549
Soft environment
710
627
345
722
140
807
751
719
148
546
407
536
208
449
902
263
450
374
746
885
498
Hard environment
542
600
114
395
135
575
375
574
737
594
565
182
324
553
347
292
274
762
661
405
561
Global contacts
(continued)
561
624
285
659
279
787
569
704
551
537
563
284
526
713
388
298
234
906
383
635
790
Industrial quality
282 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Country
China
Serbia
China
Nigeria
India
China
Brazil
China
China
China
China
China
South Africa
Mexico
China
China
Saudi Arabia
China
Mexico
China
China
City
Mianyang
Belgrade
Xiaogan
Abuja
Ahmedabad
Huaibei
Londrina
Jingdezhen
Qinhuangdao
Benxi
Yibin
Nanping
Port Elizabeth
Culiacan
Luzhou
Zhumadian
Ta’if
Fangchenggang
Hermosillo
Yiyang
Liaoyang
(continued)
534
533
532
531
530
529
528
527
526
525
524
523
522
521
520
519
518
517
516
515
514
Economic competitiveness
888
381
274
931
949
548
456
434
312
936
491
940
184
780
646
547
242
236
751
111
385
Local factors
569
418
432
529
805
644
637
288
415
284
576
602
329
489
557
746
198
539
837
241
480
Living environment
566
610
302
627
309
626
496
525
539
640
677
423
356
577
749
501
319
914
691
341
383
Soft environment
395
897
712
824
508
603
958
509
532
761
950
613
772
622
474
570
681
707
667
222
757
Hard environment
477
610
617
384
803
566
414
807
641
616
609
506
348
425
785
479
297
376
431
152
366
Global contacts
(continued)
466
549
382
555
637
725
638
462
402
501
524
640
475
573
459
602
398
428
733
218
484
Industrial quality
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic … 283
Country
Egypt
Peru
China
China
Peru
China
China
Indonesia
Russian
Mexico
China
China
Egypt
China
Mexico
Kazakhstan
China
State of Palestine
Sudan
Brazil
City
Alexandria
Trujillo
Anshan
Xinyang
Arequipa
Huainan
Jingzhou
Palembang
Tolyatti
Chihuahua
Xianning
Chuzhou
Port Said
Songyuan
Reynosa
Shymkent
Shiyan
Gaza
Khartoum
Fortaleza
(continued)
554
553
552
551
550
549
548
547
546
545
544
543
542
541
540
539
538
537
536
535
Economic competitiveness
366
927
837
314
806
484
865
832
735
347
344
808
574
572
275
121
424
651
541
78
Local factors
599
789
933
455
917
728
672
948
651
808
204
454
568
594
733
819
600
324
783
692
Living environment
741
750
819
570
854
768
559
868
543
622
395
360
647
474
532
638
453
445
603
528
Soft environment
528
841
412
896
504
537
868
483
596
801
821
308
199
721
273
992
765
732
535
123
Hard environment
668
403
982
436
862
756
552
887
424
451
810
907
690
452
450
753
507
444
738
232
Global contacts
(continued)
325
609
562
497
916
471
654
869
594
651
396
595
682
511
702
647
663
320
660
420
Industrial quality
284 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Country
Brazil
Venezuela
China
China
Russian
Bangladesh
Nigeria
China
Brazil
China
India
Brazil
Russian
China
China
Brazil
Tunisia
China
China
China
Indonesia
City
Uberlandia
Maturín
Leshan
Jinzhou
Barnaul
Chittagong
Kano
Wuzhou
Goiania
Suining
Kozhikode
Grande Sao Luis
Saratov
Daqing
Fushun
Belem
Tunis
Meishan
Jincheng
Hengshui
Medan
(continued)
575
574
573
572
571
570
569
568
567
566
565
564
563
562
561
560
559
558
557
556
555
Economic competitiveness
338
862
785
810
202
685
408
166
640
824
514
836
557
881
318
317
800
746
656
966
740
Local factors
366
730
616
595
238
371
521
784
385
541
434
579
340
491
832
497
508
605
470
953
472
Living environment
386
678
600
676
394
842
416
322
381
832
480
541
766
515
936
948
477
500
601
1003
826
Soft environment
219
385
679
830
238
577
864
742
762
555
484
744
403
929
949
686
497
444
858
502
867
Hard environment
248
548
573
354
174
754
397
465
882
815
729
629
699
623
781
892
809
412
564
827
790
Global contacts
(continued)
697
553
529
671
311
415
400
444
747
837
700
734
435
566
808
652
628
491
468
754
460
Industrial quality
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic … 285
Country
China
China
China
Nigeria
Honduras
Honduras
Mexico
China
Bolivia
India
Iran
China
China
Bolivia
Indonesia
China
China
China
Russian
Turkey
China
City
Weinan
Guangan
Huanggang
Ibadan
San Pedro Sula
Tegucigalpa
Puebla
Nanchong
Cochabamba
Dehra Dun
Shiraz
Xuancheng
Shaoguan
Santa Cruz
Padang
Lishui
Shizuishan
Xingtai
Krasnodar
Gaziantep
Tongliao
(continued)
596
595
594
593
592
591
590
589
588
587
586
585
584
583
582
581
580
579
578
577
576
Economic competitiveness
638
498
658
761
593
521
585
267
748
770
443
454
853
362
152
346
552
394
678
821
880
Local factors
549
426
290
662
895
412
327
684
397
396
725
308
429
464
110
343
468
647
474
620
588
Living environment
608
354
253
479
628
487
337
843
465
625
811
582
951
439
348
873
917
913
535
624
632
Soft environment
683
597
808
614
730
630
507
919
720
698
892
616
989
779
448
768
460
321
822
716
608
Hard environment
618
718
531
546
493
511
725
173
423
440
761
964
671
476
298
321
426
757
433
555
341
Global contacts
(continued)
661
617
411
634
603
540
729
278
516
744
810
683
589
627
361
324
407
546
558
722
620
Industrial quality
286 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Country
Brazil
Mexico
Turkey
Russian
Nigeria
Viet Nam
Russian
China
India
China
Turkey
Venezuela
China
Turkey
Mexico
China
Turkey
China
South Africa
China
Mexico
City
Manaus
Veracruz
Konya
Tomsk
Enugu
Can Tho
Ryazan
Yangquan
Kollam
Yulin (GX)
Kayseri
Barquisimeto
Mudanjiang
Diyarbakir
Cuernavaca
Tonghua
Eskisehir
Suizhou
Vereeniging
Anqing
Celaya
(continued)
617
616
615
614
613
612
611
610
609
608
607
606
605
604
603
602
601
600
599
598
597
Economic competitiveness
432
953
773
855
590
950
279
755
879
823
580
719
411
417
775
516
677
504
472
276
474
Local factors
721
487
825
619
476
562
391
457
435
968
606
611
779
814
461
698
905
613
542
604
666
Living environment
716
458
835
613
347
692
650
488
522
1005
278
619
571
498
393
829
929
442
293
533
786
Soft environment
205
691
380
695
910
903
237
774
724
553
517
777
514
621
648
406
709
977
671
500
908
Hard environment
747
534
750
544
822
635
595
985
639
958
782
530
956
407
1002
858
909
812
406
776
453
Global contacts
(continued)
821
621
890
633
708
692
789
701
728
472
581
681
876
527
805
868
924
583
481
509
432
Industrial quality
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic … 287
Country
Uganda
China
Brazil
Russian
India
China
China
China
Indonesia
China
Algeria
Mexico
Colombia
Nigeria
Iran
Mexico
Brazil
Brazil
China
China
Nigeria
City
Kampala
Suzhou (AH)
Joao Pessoa
Kemerovo
Kannur
Shuozhou
Ji’an
Siping
Malang
Chifeng
Algiers
Pachuca de Soto
Pereira
Jos
Tabriz
Xalapa
Teresina
Juiz De Fora
Yunfu
Chizhou
Oshogbo
(continued)
638
637
636
635
634
633
632
631
630
629
628
627
626
625
624
623
622
621
620
619
618
Economic competitiveness
858
783
826
764
737
348
412
555
335
388
707
714
659
848
673
252
542
768
734
703
234
Local factors
865
632
519
555
621
277
716
795
368
498
780
597
186
622
424
675
634
760
737
753
799
Living environment
941
579
497
848
896
484
773
942
540
503
953
555
252
715
578
644
801
418
871
693
780
Soft environment
606
942
847
649
704
377
788
750
494
276
181
756
845
714
971
526
789
790
496
452
411
Hard environment
889
442
674
385
904
943
819
688
801
739
210
625
709
448
602
543
684
886
855
290
201
Global contacts
(continued)
898
577
761
597
885
801
828
889
850
782
357
523
688
791
710
612
737
778
858
568
387
Industrial quality
288 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Country
China
China
China
China
China
China
China
India
China
Iraq
China
Mexico
Russian
India
China
China
Philippines
India
Nigeria
Colombia
Ukraine
City
Hanzhong
Dazhou
Qingyuan
Yongzhou
Qujing
Qinzhou
Jiayuguan
Bhiwandi
Anshun
Sulaymaniyah
Huaihua
Mexicali
Orenburg
Thiruvananthapuram
Zhangjiakou
Chengde
Cebu
Patna
Warri
Bucaramanga
Kiev
(continued)
659
658
657
656
655
654
653
652
651
650
649
648
647
646
645
644
643
642
641
640
639
Economic competitiveness
244
255
760
398
591
485
445
288
817
478
939
978
724
829
980
370
441
727
466
701
716
Local factors
116
517
874
522
185
575
465
250
402
875
546
624
652
884
904
551
446
678
278
699
478
Living environment
444
507
961
524
406
449
425
432
349
545
664
880
742
889
636
435
521
633
370
530
609
Soft environment
376
256
560
515
713
887
906
254
678
776
997
882
798
417
505
658
854
739
440
850
840
Hard environment
139
734
949
537
309
262
471
828
979
726
522
478
676
752
567
659
402
664
329
515
536
Global contacts
(continued)
237
467
813
809
448
386
391
848
757
436
689
554
693
926
588
707
495
711
666
785
672
Industrial quality
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic … 289
Country
Brazil
China
Russian
India
Colombia
China
Morocco
China
China
China
China
India
Indonesia
Russian
Brazil
Brazil
China
China
China
Viet Nam
China
City
Feira De Santana
Yan’an
Irkutsk
Puducherry
Barranquilla
Baise
Casablanca
Datong
Fuyang
Dandong
Changzhi
Thrissur
Denpasar
Kazan
Cuiaba
Florianopolis
Jinzhong
Shanwei
Fuzhou (JX)
Haiphong
Yuncheng
(continued)
680
679
678
677
676
675
674
673
672
671
670
669
668
667
666
665
664
663
662
661
660
Economic competitiveness
463
582
899
420
323
605
822
439
731
426
294
778
665
368
146
882
247
429
655
352
861
Local factors
661
377
537
545
403
334
513
668
364
633
515
344
704
663
653
421
631
430
591
504
617
Living environment
615
824
576
721
630
743
864
269
368
451
508
510
629
645
320
751
569
683
547
596
897
Soft environment
711
288
899
362
638
303
861
447
257
393
598
780
718
653
167
945
480
220
946
703
759
Hard environment
547
723
583
648
605
706
937
631
843
714
626
437
582
518
128
603
590
775
708
470
816
Global contacts
(continued)
629
749
706
716
623
339
502
271
908
771
534
494
764
488
159
614
479
796
525
504
835
Industrial quality
290 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Country
Brazil
Viet Nam
Philippines
China
Mexico
Philippines
Cote d’ivoire
China
China
Nigeria
India
Congo
China
China
Colombia
Bangladesh
Russian
China
China
Nicaragua
Kenya
City
Campo Grande
Da Nang
Davao
Shaoyang
Morelia
Cagayan de Oro
Abidjan
Tongchuan
Ankang
Zaria
Kayamkulam
Pointe-Noire
Bozhou
Suihua
Ibague
Rajshahi
Astrakhan
Chongzuo
Baishan
Managua
Mombasa
(continued)
701
700
699
698
697
696
695
694
693
692
691
690
689
688
687
686
685
684
683
682
681
Economic competitiveness
460
827
959
919
917
813
628
974
811
968
794
664
937
718
316
901
307
711
756
513
629
Local factors
697
701
754
593
580
788
584
881
775
960
911
872
544
695
806
578
229
724
411
287
687
Living environment
813
823
518
764
353
932
599
731
643
977
803
937
612
841
877
649
420
554
466
655
833
Soft environment
666
832
944
820
947
828
632
802
612
901
651
795
829
731
434
592
312
957
884
344
693
Hard environment
670
485
373
505
850
917
973
551
619
766
1000
513
638
308
235
1001
730
656
955
496
764
Global contacts
(continued)
564
351
639
596
774
911
871
784
786
631
823
645
752
724
399
694
498
604
649
610
592
Industrial quality
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic … 291
Country
China
Iran
Haiti
China
India
Philippines
India
India
Uzbekistan
Pakistan
Mongolia
India
India
India
Pakistan
Ghana
Morocco
China
Nigeria
Mexico
India
City
Huangshan
Mashhad
Port-au-Prince
Guigang
Surat
General Santos City
Ludhiana
Kota
Namangan
Bahawalpur
Ulan Bator
Mangalore
Tiruppur
Nagpur
Hyderabad
Accra
Marrakech
Heyuan
Ilorin
Acapulco
Visakhapatnam
(continued)
722
721
720
719
718
717
716
715
714
713
712
711
710
709
708
707
706
705
704
703
702
Economic competitiveness
302
562
671
704
604
220
479
228
668
377
644
657
977
271
305
930
167
915
995
380
699
Local factors
363
389
828
610
494
850
923
742
793
372
669
967
956
880
566
794
638
769
797
774
310
Living environment
557
592
933
719
431
763
870
523
810
546
778
795
879
614
772
666
398
726
978
816
594
Soft environment
699
578
825
913
389
146
631
513
445
268
562
701
965
580
437
415
363
856
490
886
769
Hard environment
876
719
888
650
607
234
278
707
824
820
658
962
853
651
773
997
459
654
455
749
316
Global contacts
(continued)
891
861
945
605
741
332
844
874
910
518
429
806
982
943
887
800
726
783
840
838
622
Industrial quality
292 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Country
China
Jamaica
Nigeria
Eritrea
China
Venezuela
China
India
Angola
Mauritania
Nigeria
China
Ukraine
China
Iran
India
Mexico
India
Morocco
Colombia
Congo
City
Meizhou
Kingston
Onitsha
Asmara
Linfen
Ciudad Guayana
Huludao
Durg-Bhilai Nagar
Huambo
Nouakchott
Akure
Jiamusi
Krivoi Rog
Baicheng
Hamadan
Madurai
Poza Rica
Asansol
Tangier
Cucuta
Brazzaville
(continued)
743
742
741
740
739
738
737
736
735
734
733
732
731
730
729
728
727
726
725
724
723
Economic competitiveness
883
632
799
602
742
292
654
700
957
923
687
907
997
414
922
964
876
1006
866
92
527
Local factors
952
820
750
848
908
467
867
844
547
854
870
954
871
928
689
982
581
971
941
505
369
Living environment
969
775
438
723
808
790
860
635
831
588
927
924
991
849
642
1002
621
996
967
560
581
Soft environment
952
933
340
379
318
456
883
972
764
851
677
959
1006
566
642
925
918
725
569
127
563
Hard environment
823
806
899
941
769
848
861
604
875
520
885
779
793
802
540
851
541
910
893
172
621
Global contacts
(continued)
667
941
905
953
882
929
904
750
779
632
862
836
748
966
570
600
606
972
976
277
677
Industrial quality
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic … 293
Country
China
Russian
Uzbekistan
China
Zambia
Russian
Morocco
Ghana
Mexico
China
China
Cameroon
Russian
China
Nigeria
Morocco
Russian
Lao
India
China
Bolivia
City
Zhangjiajie
Novokuznetsk
Tashkent
Hulunbuir
Kitwe
Khabarovsk
Meknes
Kumasi
Tampico
Shangluo
Laibin
Douala
Novosibirsk
Ya’an
Kaduna
Rabat
Rostov-on-Don
Vientiane
Indore
Liuan
La Paz
(continued)
764
763
762
761
760
759
758
757
756
755
754
753
752
751
750
749
748
747
746
745
744
Economic competitiveness
212
972
303
614
763
353
675
723
343
536
815
886
422
788
733
830
419
801
486
825
896
Local factors
437
582
720
509
220
596
766
643
577
801
706
796
535
855
756
707
997
862
558
752
441
Living environment
886
550
667
892
327
403
945
712
297
982
687
662
605
800
709
450
820
597
783
483
651
Soft environment
998
644
350
991
310
136
969
870
983
587
888
806
248
231
556
980
793
927
890
294
920
Hard environment
693
475
411
549
486
340
871
381
263
242
677
488
789
800
921
902
854
428
300
934
380
Global contacts
(continued)
410
762
851
406
421
409
922
625
384
425
765
776
816
933
897
522
535
538
354
489
814
Industrial quality
294 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Country
India
Pakistan
Indonesia
Peru
Gabon
Myanmar
Indonesia
Russian
Russian
Mexico
Zimbabwe
China
Republic of Moldova
China
China
India
Mexico
Brazil
India
India
City
Guwahati
Rawalpindi
Tasikmalaya
Chiclayo
Libreville
Rangoon
Bandar Lampung
Krasnoyarsk
Izhevsk
Tlaxcala
Harare
Ulanqab
Chisinau
Fuxin
Guangyuan
Jalandhar
Oaxaca
Maceio
Jodhpur
Erode
(continued)
784
783
782
781
780
779
778
777
776
775
774
773
772
771
770
769
768
767
766
765
Economic competitiveness
554
421
802
455
399
594
932
465
985
208
494
766
501
781
954
998
765
864
523
296
Local factors
800
840
550
146
690
618
691
443
821
540
218
382
387
641
483
648
830
635
834
586
Living environment
718
595
894
288
777
694
656
542
548
919
461
443
325
329
855
956
789
604
857
753
Soft environment
629
664
849
917
639
810
862
179
894
572
567
665
987
283
729
875
635
812
690
797
Hard environment
981
864
830
703
923
643
686
288
613
578
963
987
728
736
221
627
992
532
712
523
Global contacts
(continued)
893
845
591
812
920
717
803
417
630
434
865
758
430
745
464
355
723
842
969
719
Industrial quality
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic … 295
Country
China
Nepal
China
India
Russian
Pakistan
Brazil
China
Russian
India
Tanzania
Indonesia
China
China
India
Philippines
Saudi Arabia
China
Nigeria
Iraq
China
City
Qiqihar
Kathmandu
Bayannur
Tirupati
Chelyabinsk
Gujranwala
Aracaju
Luliang
Omsk
Rajkot
Dar es Salaam
Bogor
Chaoyang
Hezhou
Amritsar
Bacolod
Tabuk
Baoshan
Sokoto
Karbala
Xinzhou
(continued)
805
804
803
802
801
800
799
798
797
796
795
794
793
792
791
790
789
788
787
786
785
Economic competitiveness
356
987
747
553
868
934
402
877
976
545
512
310
613
698
790
676
564
540
944
897
661
Local factors
645
972
973
444
887
585
670
765
607
107
583
573
598
660
758
985
506
625
847
552
835
Living environment
733
905
959
722
437
699
701
734
735
308
890
673
379
586
834
846
382
669
702
564
580
Soft environment
881
735
976
924
672
936
510
939
682
907
740
512
928
673
485
837
799
527
940
619
758
Hard environment
642
837
931
494
890
940
877
665
652
400
188
383
951
606
720
826
898
733
559
727
569
Global contacts
(continued)
718
878
947
804
684
656
925
770
767
615
451
675
775
674
884
983
584
772
626
714
642
Industrial quality
296 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Country
China
India
Bangladesh
Brazil
Russian
Mexico
India
Turkey
India
Iraq
Russian
Nigeria
Afghanistan
Ghana
China
India
Russian
China
China
India
Morocco
City
Qingyang
Salem
Sylhet
Salvador
Volgograd
Tuxtla Gutierrez
Vijayawada
Sanliurfa
Tiruchirappalli
Kirkuk
Nizhny Novgorod
Maiduguri
Kabul
Sekondi
WuZhong
Jaipur
Voronezh
Jinchang
Tianshui
Jamnagar
Fes
(continued)
826
825
824
823
822
821
820
819
818
817
816
815
814
813
812
811
810
809
808
807
806
Economic competitiveness
670
695
395
982
618
250
941
887
261
752
490
988
431
839
289
579
683
333
860
141
315
Local factors
767
686
667
866
393
346
924
886
955
927
279
969
614
807
680
553
383
463
677
748
777
Living environment
556
703
679
725
338
343
698
887
976
939
237
895
654
575
660
623
304
728
930
752
681
Soft environment
408
493
943
898
628
351
736
311
848
675
153
668
488
576
301
280
811
316
852
230
926
Hard environment
748
911
645
558
315
213
458
857
501
920
797
759
814
1005
935
852
884
495
977
218
579
Global contacts
(continued)
919
914
763
644
427
576
721
902
636
915
446
849
880
781
727
863
571
359
777
539
668
Industrial quality
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic … 297
Country
India
Iran
Senegal
Indonesia
India
India
India
India
Philippines
India
Brazil
India
Iraq
India
India
Iraq
Colombia
Russian
Iran
Russian
China
City
Mysore
Orumiyeh
Dakar
Jambi
Raurkela
Kurnool
Jamshedpur
Siliguri
Zamboanga
Kolhapur
Natal
Meerut
Basra
Nashik
Bhubaneswar
Mosul
Santa Marta
Yekaterinburg
Rasht
Vladivostok
Lincang
(continued)
847
846
845
844
843
842
841
840
839
838
837
836
835
834
833
832
831
830
829
828
827
Economic competitiveness
789
647
616
679
497
945
301
354
975
508
452
570
920
577
295
681
857
840
575
633
297
Local factors
747
335
711
708
732
944
360
772
976
888
590
507
536
787
778
912
910
574
961
761
244
Living environment
765
430
865
335
572
949
558
574
921
806
847
641
688
747
866
714
862
519
878
875
584
Soft environment
986
270
866
803
702
544
684
333
623
773
657
499
785
547
727
865
813
860
723
559
501
Hard environment
516
673
976
441
839
975
666
700
988
527
563
680
984
993
969
938
999
584
239
916
732
Global contacts
(continued)
766
371
839
445
921
847
923
795
590
841
753
687
960
959
798
949
957
740
490
870
901
Industrial quality
298 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Country
China
India
China
India
China
China
Bangladesh
China
Togo
Sudan
China
Pakistan
Morocco
India
India
Russian
India
Syrian
China
Libya
Congo
City
Zhaotong
Hubli-Dharwad
Tieling
Lucknow
Bazhong
Zhongwei
Khulna
Jixi
Lome
Nyala
Baiyin
Faisalabad
Agadir
Warangal
Bokaro Steel City
Ulyanovsk
Gwalior
Latakia
Lijiang
Misratah
Kinshasa
(continued)
868
867
866
865
864
863
862
861
860
859
858
857
856
855
854
853
852
851
850
849
848
Economic competitiveness
713
1002
709
989
493
809
842
436
550
433
902
910
914
928
816
769
909
205
955
409
834
Local factors
957
925
407
947
726
608
902
785
762
833
812
918
891
679
729
915
755
745
723
532
770
Living environment
984
970
671
923
807
495
817
585
433
779
646
971
859
717
954
680
710
648
663
652
706
Soft environment
974
755
834
568
748
232
565
694
177
574
938
1001
271
844
962
827
966
404
522
359
953
Hard environment
275
881
345
895
952
897
998
942
873
632
415
744
390
657
948
317
438
322
502
930
482
Global contacts
(continued)
544
944
669
989
977
822
955
879
867
794
685
899
463
834
930
567
855
817
769
951
773
Industrial quality
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic … 299
Country
Iraq
Tunisia
India
China
China
India
Russian
India
China
India
Zambia
India
China
China
Iran
Yemen
Pakistan
Bangladesh
Iraq
China
Rwanda
City
Nasiriyah
Safaqis
Chandigarh
Hechi
Zhangye
Srinagar
Makhachkala
Aurangabad
Qitaihe
Ranchi
Lusaka
Sangali
Shuangyashan
Pu’er
Esfahan
Sana’a
Islamabad
Bogra
Najaf
Wuwei
Kigali
(continued)
889
888
887
886
885
884
883
882
881
880
879
878
877
876
875
874
873
872
871
870
869
Economic competitiveness
603
642
971
951
188
819
415
926
996
852
246
477
999
235
878
325
828
990
198
578
992
Local factors
946
858
983
843
718
892
791
629
885
768
984
665
792
846
771
900
810
592
379
856
979
Living environment
365
696
947
968
607
986
637
739
708
788
814
754
770
653
583
774
730
705
587
793
958
Soft environment
685
981
985
964
337
948
975
967
786
325
982
676
396
654
371
463
988
990
262
378
680
Hard environment
636
662
922
980
209
653
792
449
689
995
261
717
696
878
957
778
332
504
207
818
1005
Global contacts
(continued)
598
792
872
964
439
698
864
691
815
918
348
824
738
940
903
559
730
720
441
931
866
Industrial quality
300 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Country
India
India
Iran
Ukraine
Indonesia
India
Viet Nam
India
India
Syrian
Syrian
Armenia
Somalia
China
Indonesia
India
India
India
India
India
India
City
Saharanpur
Vadodara
Qom
Donetsk
Banjarmasin
Guntur
Bien Hoa
Imphal
Bhopal
Hamah
Damascus
Yerevan
Mogadishu
Guyuan
Pontianak
Muzaffarnagar
Varanasi
Bhavnagar
Tirunelveli
Solapur
Dhanbad
(continued)
910
909
908
907
906
905
904
903
902
901
900
899
898
897
896
895
894
893
892
891
890
Economic competitiveness
475
502
546
568
389
771
844
947
983
427
722
1001
342
688
511
489
812
697
615
222
551
Local factors
813
816
713
926
642
934
572
818
1002
876
992
993
358
709
615
811
781
460
859
345
864
Living environment
798
812
796
434
729
748
631
758
980
454
888
950
684
874
840
682
470
781
776
551
883
Soft environment
558
640
634
539
594
814
726
916
970
151
367
961
422
601
290
518
162
204
931
402
921
Hard environment
745
928
917
936
780
906
701
694
849
260
713
996
705
774
811
926
731
989
842
722
741
Global contacts
(continued)
859
927
917
932
973
965
743
780
952
378
793
991
860
877
825
938
833
854
934
643
853
Industrial quality
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic … 301
Country
Iran
India
Pakistan
Syrian
India
India
Pakistan
Congo
Pakistan
India
China
India
India
Niger
China
Yemen
India
India
Iran
China
India
City
Kerman
Cherthala
Sialkot
Al-Raqqa
Belgaum
Vellore
Sukkur
Lubumbashi
Peshawar
Agra
Hegang
Malegaon
Amravati
Niamey
Pingliang
Aden
Nellore
Cuttack
Ardabil
Heihe
Aligarh
(continued)
931
930
929
928
927
926
925
924
923
922
921
920
919
918
917
916
915
914
913
912
911
Economic competitiveness
503
1004
717
631
617
961
696
797
532
772
925
505
483
906
818
361
544
1003
757
712
556
Local factors
815
841
702
714
849
987
751
980
873
869
893
722
790
963
974
612
485
1006
945
919
809
Living environment
822
606
804
828
782
990
757
972
707
827
686
794
893
988
910
767
792
965
885
805
736
Soft environment
968
836
955
715
455
381
877
618
794
432
697
624
636
880
753
529
468
960
763
360
889
Hard environment
791
683
946
667
915
836
474
514
929
983
550
612
647
880
994
742
990
944
533
932
768
Global contacts
(continued)
942
746
881
856
950
1001
807
799
912
939
820
873
819
756
958
802
928
997
846
948
831
Industrial quality
302 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Country
Tanzania
Ethiopia
India
Sierra Leone
India
Mexico
India
Iran
India
Iran
India
India
Tanzania
Ukraine
India
Egypt
India
India
Ukraine
Ukraine
Zimbabwe
City
Zanzibar
Addis Ababa
Bareilly
Freetown
Moradabad
Durango
Gulbarga
Kermanshah
Kanpur
Yazd
Jabalpur
Ujjain
Mwanza
Lvov
Ajmer
Suez
Nanded Waghala
Allahabad
Dnipropetrovs’k
Zaporizhzhya
Bulawayo
(continued)
952
951
950
949
948
947
946
945
944
943
942
941
940
939
938
937
936
935
934
933
932
Economic competitiveness
900
938
870
410
903
736
639
793
792
706
533
672
204
595
666
291
624
804
566
750
851
Local factors
916
543
405
739
824
935
700
462
817
757
889
827
883
738
734
376
964
826
860
845
978
Living environment
940
756
784
690
761
851
818
689
858
838
769
771
740
815
809
428
844
955
856
872
938
Soft environment
705
687
561
647
752
225
900
662
1004
775
620
973
491
963
552
874
869
749
909
525
935
Hard environment
1003
925
874
835
991
770
805
866
869
863
765
859
799
817
908
798
825
865
901
259
961
Global contacts
(continued)
696
886
611
970
962
907
956
608
961
967
984
875
946
896
935
579
978
618
975
593
963
Industrial quality
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic … 303
Country
Ukraine
India
India
Ukraine
India
Pakistan
China
Benin
Argentina
China
Cameroon
China
China
India
Pakistan
India
Kyrgyzstan
Burkina Faso
Nigeria
Cote d’ivoire
Malawi
City
Kharkov
Firozabad
Jammu
Odessa
Jhansi
Multan
Jiuquan
Cotonou
Salta
Longnan
Yaounde
Dingxi
Yichun (HLJ)
Durgapur
Quetta
Mathura
Bishkek
Ouagadougou
Nnewi
Bouake
Blantyre-Limbe
(continued)
973
972
971
970
969
968
967
966
965
964
963
962
961
960
959
958
957
956
955
954
953
Economic competitiveness
168
929
807
754
963
407
693
500
994
392
437
597
892
885
912
587
680
652
403
850
529
Local factors
896
966
995
990
899
852
868
842
920
838
764
831
158
898
857
962
950
655
735
965
559
Living environment
928
904
973
912
837
891
861
737
787
697
957
791
853
898
538
869
850
713
611
825
760
Soft environment
641
954
741
610
462
842
951
442
826
805
353
994
937
160
956
545
871
557
543
489
659
Hard environment
497
966
905
833
355
698
986
945
672
601
353
539
599
392
469
682
856
831
445
939
760
Global contacts
(continued)
653
980
987
883
485
892
909
913
826
852
832
843
557
560
731
857
974
894
751
985
937
Industrial quality
304 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Country
India
Myanmar
Iran
Mali
Liberia
Djibouti
Myanmar
India
Burundi
Guinea
Benin
Somalia
Mozambique
India
Congo
Madagascar
Pakistan
Malawi
Mozambique
Burkina Faso
Congo
City
Bikaner
Nay Pyi Taw
Zahedan
Bamako
Monrovia
Djibouti
Mandalay
Gorakhpur
Bujumbura
Conakry
Abomey-Calavi
Hargeysa
Matola
Raipur
Tshikapa
Antananarivo
Sargodha
Lilongwe
Maputo
Bobo Dioulasso
Mbuji-Mayi
(continued)
994
993
992
991
990
989
988
987
986
985
984
983
982
981
980
979
978
977
976
975
974
Economic competitiveness
970
916
847
451
730
636
1000
473
993
1005
889
833
967
662
895
946
259
738
710
962
641
Local factors
1004
991
744
931
959
683
1000
741
939
996
932
878
1005
975
688
994
949
989
938
901
851
Living environment
995
920
952
916
908
962
994
658
963
983
911
966
979
906
907
964
981
900
882
934
830
Soft environment
872
932
891
996
873
999
993
382
454
1003
348
833
1005
784
859
781
234
458
831
229
912
Hard environment
971
965
226
784
913
576
972
746
813
896
914
529
867
847
967
868
772
588
786
953
973
Global contacts
(continued)
1003
988
477
895
986
705
999
755
979
1004
797
673
995
992
994
981
900
830
936
993
968
Industrial quality
5.7 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic … 305
Country
Mozambique
Tajikistan
Congo
Congo
Yemen
Yemen
Central African
Libya
Syrian
Chad
Congo
Syrian
City
Nampula
Dushanbe
Kananga
Bukavu
Taiz
Hodeidah
Bangui
Benghazi
Homs
N’Djamena
Kisangani
Aleppo
(continued)
1006
1005
1004
1003
1002
1001
1000
999
998
997
996
995
Economic competitiveness
984
973
960
979
986
948
965
933
206
991
611
981
Local factors
998
1001
977
1003
877
951
988
936
981
999
909
943
Living environment
925
998
987
915
960
985
999
997
989
992
909
974
Soft environment
863
995
978
979
551
816
819
923
839
1000
531
1002
Hard environment
763
960
351
919
687
832
1004
872
978
950
628
959
Global contacts
996
1006
580
990
585
954
1002
998
1005
1000
699
971
Industrial quality
306 5 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness
Chapter 6
Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness Performance
6.1 Top 20 Cities: Europe Holds the Most Seats, While Asia Has the Highest Mean Value The top 20 cities in the world for sustainable competitiveness basically include the central cities of the world’s major cities and developed countries. There are five cities in the United States, nine in Western Europe, including three in Germany and two in Spain. The rest are cities in East Asia, China, Japan, Korea and Singapore share six positions. It is not difficult to find that all the top 20 cities represent the characteristics and development of the country. These top world cities can be regarded as a symbol of the development and achievements of the whole country (Fig. 6.1 and Table 6.1). The spatial distribution of the top 20 cities is all in the northern hemisphere, near the 120 degrees and the prime meridian in the east and west hemispheres. The geographical distance distribution is divided into two parts: East Asia, Western Europe and North America. The East Asian cities are characterized by coastal exportoriented economic centers. The cities of Western Europe are relatively concentrated, and they are the capitals or economic centers of various countries. The North American cities are divided into two parts: the east coast the west coast, which constitutes the center of economic activity of the United States (Table 6.2). Among the top 20 cities, Asian cities outperform Europe and the United States in both the average and the median, and they are balanced in terms of both high-income population growth and density. Relatively speaking, the high-income population density of North American cities is slightly behind, while Europe Cities are underperforming in terms of high-income population growth, but overall East Asia, North America and Western Europe represent the culmination and peak of sustainable urban competitiveness.
© China Social Sciences Press 2023 P. Ni et al., The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-99-3553-6_6
307
308
6 Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness Performance
60
30
0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30
-60
Fig. 6.1 Spatial distribution of the top 20 cities in the Global Sustainable Competitiveness Index. Source CCC of CASS
6.2 Top 200 Cities: Asia Holds the Most Seats and Europe Has the Highest Mean Value Among the top 200 cities in the 2019 Global Sustainable Competitiveness Index, Asian cities have the largest number of 65 cities, with a mean value of 0.618 and a coefficient of variation of 0.183, indicating that Asia is the fastest growing region in the world, with a strong upward trend, but at the same time It should also be noted that the average value of cities entering Asia in the top 200 is relatively low, and only exceeds the number of non-comparable South America and Africa, indicating that sustainable competitiveness needs to be further improved. North America and Europe are close behind, with 60 cities and 58 cities entering the top 200. The average and coefficient of variation of global sustainable competitiveness in Europe and North America are basically the same. Europe performs slightly better than the United States According to the distribution of the top 200 cities in the global sustainable competitiveness index given in Table 6.3, the intercontinental differences in the development of global core cities are small (Fig. 6.2). Regardless of the continent and country, these cities constitute the core cities and development centers of the region. The overall distribution of the top 200 cities, Asia-Europe and North America are three-legged, the average value is basically the same, and the coefficient of variation is not much different, indicating that between continents, Within the continent, the convergence of the competitiveness of key cities around the world is a major trend, which is in contrast to the large differences between the average city and different regions (Table 6.4). Among the top 200 cities, the gap in sustainable competitiveness of Asian cities has emerged, but the high-income population growth rate is relatively low. North
Chicago
United States
England
America
France
China Hong Kong
Japan
America
America
North America
Europe
North America
Europe
Asia
Asia
North America
North America
Source CCC of CASS
Los Angeles
Japan
Asia
Osaka
Hong Kong
Paris
San Francisco
London
New York
Tokyo
Singapore
Singapore
Asia
City
Nation
Intercontinental
0.8285
0.8386
0.8532
0.8894
0.8930
0.8955
0.9135
0.9570
0.9984
1
Index
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
Ranking
Table 6.1 Top 20 cities in the Global Sustainable Competitiveness Index
Europe
Asia
Europe
North America
Europe
Europe
Asia
Europe
Europe
Europe
Intercontinental
Germany
China
Spain
United States
Germany
Germany
Korea
Sweden
Russia
Spain
Nation
Frankfurt
ShenZhen
Madrid
Boston
Stuttgart
Munich
Seoul
Stockholm
Moscow
Barcelona
City
0.7887
0.7905
0.7918
0.7934
0.7957
0.8019
0.8047
0.8075
0.8135
0.8160
Index
20
19
18
17
16
15
14
13
12
11
Ranking
6.2 Top 200 Cities: Asia Holds the Most Seats and Europe Has the Highest … 309
310
6 Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness Performance
Table 6.2 Regional statistics of Top 20 cities in the Global Sustainable Competitiveness Index Continent
Index
No
Mean
Std. dev
Min
median
Max
Asia
Sustainable competitiveness
6
0.889
0.008
0.791
0.871
1
High-income population growth
6
0.786
0.020
0.584
0.786
0.988
High-income population density
6
0.820
0.017
0.661
0.829
1
Sustainable competitiveness
5
0.863
0.004
0.793
0.839
0.957
High-income population growth
5
0.886
0.012
0.734
0.872
1
High-income population density
5
0.672
0.007
0.532
0.698
0.745
Sustainable competitiveness
9
0.825
0.002
0.789
0.808
0.914
High-income population growth
9
0.671
0.017
0.522
0.660
0.879
High-income population density
9
0.818
0.005
0.73
0.797
0.926
Sustainable competitiveness
20
0.854
0.005
0.789
0.822
1
High-income population growth
20
0.759
0.023
0.522
0.751
1
High-income population density
20
0.782
0.012
0.532
0.786
1
North America
Europe
Total
Source CCC of CASS Table 6.3 Distribution of the top 200 cities in the Global Sustainable Competitiveness Index region
Sample
Mean
Coefficient of variation
Optimal city
Index
World Ranking
Asia
65
0.618
0.183
Singapore
1
1
Europe
58
0.634
0.170
London
0.914
4
North America
60
0.633
0.171
New York
0.957
3
South America
8
0.578
0.116
Buenos Aires
0.707
42
Oceania
7
0.632
0.133
Melbourne
0.754
27
Africa
2
0.554
0.088
Pretoria
0.589
106
Global
200
0.626
0.171
Source CCC of CASS
6.3 Top 10 Urban Agglomerations: Seoul Has the Highest Mean Value …
311
70
40
10
-180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-20
-50
Fig. 6.2 Spatial distribution of the top 200 cities in the Global Sustainable Competitiveness Index. Source CCC of CASS
American cities and European cities are better at high-income population density, while the advantages in high-income population growth are not obvious. It is not difficult to find that the core cities in Europe and the United States have been developing for a long time, and their status is relatively stable, while Asian cities are showing a situation of rapid convergence and catch-up.
6.3 Top 10 Urban Agglomerations: Seoul Has the Highest Mean Value, and Rhein-Ruhr is Best Balanced From the perspective of important urban agglomerations, the strength of the US and British urban agglomerations is prominent. The average value is above the average of all urban agglomerations and the level is uniform. The strength is still strong. Although the urban agglomerations of developing countries such as China and India are large in scale, the sustainable development indexes of central cities and surrounding cities are too large and the standard deviation is large. The cities within the three major urban agglomerations of the United States have balanced urban development and high average value. The sustainable competitiveness of China and India’s urban agglomerations has a clear single-core model. The urban centers of the urban agglomerations are prominent, ranking no less than the urban agglomeration cities of developed countries. Due to the small number of cities in Seoul city cluster, the average sustainable competitiveness index is in a leading position. And urban agglomerations in China, India and other developing countries are large in size, the
312
6 Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness Performance
Table 6.4 Regional statistics of Top 200 cities in the Global Sustainable Competitiveness Index Continent
Index
No
Mean
Std. dev
Min
median
Max
Asia
Sustainable competitiveness
65
0.618
0.113
0.494
0.594
1
High-income population growth
65
0.487
0.137
0.211
0.449
0.988
High-income population density
65
0.629
0.111
0.405
0.61
1
Sustainable competitiveness
60
0.633
0.108
0.502
0.621
0.957
High-income population growth
60
0.519
0.177
0.251
0.47
1
High-income population density
60
0.625
0.092
0.45
0.614
0.832
Sustainable competitiveness
8
0.578
0.067
0.502
0.571
0.707
High-income population growth
8
0.48
0.11
0.309
0.484
0.635
High-income population density
8
0.564
0.039
0.517
0.553
0.641
Sustainable competitiveness
7
0.632
0.084
0.517
0.6
0.754
High-income population growth
7
0.533
0.143
0.287
0.552
0.706
High-income population density
7
0.608
0.055
0.498
0.63
0.655
Sustainable competitiveness
58
0.634
0.108
0.492
0.598
0.914
High-income population growth
58
0.435
0.139
0.221
0.417
0.879
High-income population density
58
0.71
0.102
0.501
0.716
0.926
Sustainable competitiveness
2
0.554
0.049
0.52
0.554
0.589
High-income population growth
2
0.425
0.022
0.409
0.425
0.441
High-income population density
2
0.575
0.065
0.529
0.575
0.622
Sustainable competitiveness
200
0.626
0.107
0.492
0.596
1
High-income population growth
200
0.482
0.152
0.211
0.451
1
High-income population density
200
0.647
0.107
0.405
0.631
1
North America
South America
Oceania
Europe
Africa
Total
Source CCC of CASS
6.4 Three Main Economics: The United States and the European Union Far …
313
70
40
10
-180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-20
-50
Fig. 6.3 Spatial distribution of the top ten urban agglomerations in the world. Source CCC of CASS
gap between central cities and surrounding cities is obvious and the development is unbalanced. And among the urban agglomeration in Europe, the rhine-ruhr urban agglomeration has the lowest standard deviation, which shows the equilibrium of development in the western European countries (Fig. 6.3). From the geographical location, the distribution of urban agglomerations is basically consistent with the distribution characteristics of the 20 major cities, indicating that the formation of urban agglomerations has higher requirements for the leadership of single-nuclear cities. In addition, it is difficult for smaller countries to form urban agglomerations in the true sense, such as South Korea. Singapore, therefore, the urban agglomeration also shows the dual characteristics of urban agglomeration and priority development of core cities (Table 6.5).
6.4 Three Main Economics: The United States and the European Union Far Surpass China, and the Development of US Cities is of Potential In the urban competitiveness system, large cities have a high proportion and have the greatest impact on global cities. From the analysis of economic influence, we regard the EU as a whole, so that 439 cities in China, the EU and the United States have entered the urban competitiveness index, which is close to half of the total number of 1006 cities. The overall performance of the EU is not inconsistent with that of the United States. It is reflected in the higher mean value of the sustainable
314
6 Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness Performance
Table 6.5 Sustainable Competitiveness Index of the top ten urban agglomerations in the world Urban Agglomeration index
Mean
Std. dev
Mi
Median
Max
Seoul Metropolitan Group
Sustainable competitiveness
0.741
0.09
0.677
0.741
0.805
High-income population growth
0.632
0.191
0.498
0.632
0.767
High-income population density
0.705
0.028
0.685
0.705
0.725
Sustainable competitiveness
0.7
0.141
0.522
0.681
0.957
High-income population growth
0.598
0.242
0.336
0.601
1
High-income population density
0.666
0.101
0.463
0.692
0.766
Sustainable competitiveness
0.585
0.122
0.467
0.538
0.828
High-income population growth
0.471
0.164
0.248
0.448
0.841
High-income population density
0.586
0.127
0.463
0.595
0.832
Sustainable competitiveness
0.678
0.24
0.42
0.719
0.895
High-income population growth
0.646
0.21
0.456
0.611
0.872
High-income population density
0.578
0.241
0.302
0.688
0.745
Sustainable competitiveness
0.266
0.099
0.177
0.253
0.381
High-income population growth
0.135
0.053
0.08
0.133
0.195
High-income population density
0.346
0.127
0.218
0.335
0.494
Sustainable competitiveness
0.667
0.179
0.455
0.712
0.914
High-income population growth
0.487
0.244
0.248
0.513
0.859
High-income population density
0.717
0.092
0.574
0.772
0.79
Sustainable competitiveness
0.446
0.13
0.242
0.446
0.733
High-income population growth
0.342
0.127
0.134
0.326
0.622
Northeastern urban agglomeration
Midwestern United States
Northern California City Group
Mumbai City Group
London–Liverpool City Group
Yangtze River Delta City Group
(continued)
6.4 Three Main Economics: The United States and the European Union Far …
315
Table 6.5 (continued) Urban Agglomeration index
Mean
Std. dev
Mi
Median
Max
0.463
0.114
0.276
0.475
0.701
0.531
0.146
0.328
0.543
0.791
High-income population growth
0.403
0.112
0.268
0.374
0.584
High-income population density
0.555
0.162
0.323
0.595
0.843
Sustainable competitiveness
0.614
0.061
0.56
0.591
0.7
High-income population growth
0.335
0.1
0.239
0.29
0.474
High-income population density
0.774
0.04
0.72
0.78
0.828
Sustainable competitiveness
0.601
0.062
0.527
0.59
0.673
High-income population growth
0.385
0.1
0.234
0.381
0.496
High-income population density
0.699
0.031
0.644
0.717
0.719
Sustainable competitiveness
0.54
0.175
0.177
0.535
0.957
High-income population growth
0.415
0.193
0.08
0.377
1
High-income population density
0.559
0.163
0.218
0.572
0.843
High-income population density Pearl River Delta City Sustainable Group competitiveness
Rhine-Ruhr urban agglomeration
Netherlands-Belgian city group
Total
Source CCC of CASS
competitiveness index. There is still a large gap between China and European and American cities. The urban development of China and the United States and Europe can be regarded as the growth stage and mature stage of the urban development life cycle. From the perspective of the average sustainable competitiveness index, the United States is the highest. From the average point of view, the United States is the best, the coefficient of variation is the lowest, showing strong sustainable competitiveness, while the average of China is relatively low, but the gap is not obvious. In addition, China has a large population and enters the sustainable competitiveness index. There are many cities, and the disadvantages of small cities in terms of competitiveness are obvious. However, the level of urbanization and central cities in the United States is higher, and fewer cities are entering the city. The EU is comparable to the United States in terms of mean and internal differences, and the history of EU cities is much
316
6 Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness Performance
longer. The EU as a whole shows a strong sustainable competitive advantage. In the US-Europe comparison, the US has a higher cumulative average, indicating that the development potential of American cities is greater than that of Europe. In general, the sustainable competitiveness of Chinese cities has not yet reached the optimal level, and the US and EU cities are still at the peak of sustainable competitiveness of global cities (Figs. 6.4, 6.5, 6.6 and Table 6.6). We further analyzed the two main factors that constitute sustainable competitiveness, namely the mean value and the standard deviation of the high-income population growth and high-income population density. From the perspective of the mean value of sustainable competitiveness index, Europe and the United States are in the same level (the ratio of the US and the European average is 1:0.994), but there are differences in the high-income population growth and the density. The EU cities perform better at the high-income population density, while the advantage of high-income population growth of US is dominant. As mentioned above, as the urbanization process has not yet been fully realized, compared with the US and Europe, Chinese cities are relatively low in terms of the overall sustainable competitiveness and the two indicators (three indicators of China are only 57%, 54%, 59% of that of the US). However, in terms of standard deviation, although the number of Chinese cities far exceeds that of Europe and the United States, the internal standard deviation of Chinese cities is not much different. To a certain extent, it shows that China’s urban development is relatively balanced overall, especially for the comprehensive increase, the difference between American cities. Great, indicating that there is a large difference in the speed of development in American cities. Although the overall development potential is huge, too much concentration in a few core cities may lead to the variability of the future development of the US urban system (Table 6.7). 70
40
10 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-20
-50
Fig. 6.4 Spatial distribution of sustainable competitiveness in China, US and EU. Source CCC of CASS
6.4 Three Main Economics: The United States and the European Union Far …
317
0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 CN
EU
sustainable competitiveness index
US
TOTAL
Comprehensive increment
Comprehensive density Fig. 6.5 Mean values of sustainable competitiveness in China, US, and EU. Source CCC of CASS
0.2 0.18 0.16 0.14 0.12 0.1 0.08 CN
EU
US
TOTAL
standard deviation of sustainable competitiveness index standard deviation of Comprehensive increment standard deviation of Comprehensive density Fig. 6.6 Comparison of sustainable competitiveness in China, US and EU. Source CCC of CASS
318
6 Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness Performance
Table 6.6 Comparison of the US and Europe’s Global Sustainable Competitiveness Index Nation
Mean
Standard deviation
Coefficient of variation
Highest ranking
Optimal city
China
0.326
0.11
0.337
7
Hong Kong
America
0.568
0.139
0.245
3
New York
EU
0.565
0.132
0.234
4
London
Source CCC of CASS
Table 6.7 China-US European Cities Sustainable Competitiveness Index Nation
Index
Number Mean Std. dev Min
China
Sustainable competitiveness
284
EU
0.326 0.11
0.128 0.301
0.791
High-income population growth 284
0.25
0
0.226
0.651
High-income population density 284
0.338 0.111
0.078 0.319
0.843
Sustainable competitiveness
0.096
80
0.565 0.132
0.319 0.543
0.914
High-income population growth 80
0.378 0.141
0.154 0.349
0.879
High-income population density 80
0.641 0.131
0.373 0.629
0.926
America Sustainable competitiveness
Total
Median Max
75
0.568 0.139
0.285 0.547
0.957
High-income population growth 75
0.457 0.186
0.198 0.398
1
High-income population density 75
0.569 0.125
0.302 0.571
0.832
Sustainable competitiveness
439
0.411 0.166
0.128 0.375
0.957
High-income population growth 439
0.309 0.149
0
1
High-income population density 439
0.433 0.175
0.078 0.388
0.269
0.926
Source CCC of CASS
6.5 Global Pattern: North American and Western European Cities Perform Well and with Small Divergence, While Asian Cities Stay in Low Level and with Significant Internal Difference In terms of the distribution of global sustainable competitive cities in the world, the number of Asian cities is far ahead of the rest of the continents, but the average is slightly behind the world average, and the average values of North America and Europe are much higher than the world average. The mean for North America is 0.501 and that for Europe is 0.526, which is at the top of global sustainable competitiveness. And the coefficient of variation is relatively lower, indicating that the differences between European and American cities are small. The average value of Asia is only 0.34, and the coefficient of variation is 0.429, which indicates that the level of urban development in the continent is quite different, but it also shows that some central cities in Asian cities are rising rapidly, and vigorous development promotes sustainable competitiveness to a higher level (Table 6.8).
6.5 Global Pattern: North American and Western European Cities Perform …
319
Table 6.8 Urban distribution of Global Sustainable Competitiveness Index Region
Sample
Mean
Var
Optimal city
Index
Ranking
Asia
565
0.34
0.429
Singapore
1
1
Europe
126
0.526
0.405
London
0.9135
4
North America
131
0.501
0.307
New York
0.9570
3
South America
75
0.394
0.299
Buenos Aires
0.7068
42
Oceania
7
0.608
0.090
Melbourne
0.754
27
Africa
102
0.253
0.482
Pretoria
0.589
106
World average
1006
0.381
0.459
Source CCC of CASS
Figure 6.7 shows the spatial distribution of global sustainable competitiveness in 1006 cities around the world. North America’s economic power in Western Europe is still strong, and it is still the gathering place of the strongest global sustainable competitive cities. It can be clearly seen that global sustainable competitive cities are concentrated in North America and Western Europe (Table 6.9). 70
40
10 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-20
-50
Fig. 6.7 Spatial distribution of global sustainable competitiveness in 1006 cities around the world. Source CCC of CASS
320
6 Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness Performance
Table 6.9 Overall distribution of Global Sustainable Competitiveness Index Continent
Index
Number
Mean
Std. dev
Min
Median
Max
Asia
Sustainable competitiveness
565
0.34
0.146
0.041
0.312
1
High-income population growth
565
0.219
0.138
0
0.203
0.988
High-income population density
565
0.31
0.148
0.035
0.282
1
Sustainable competitiveness
131
0.501
0.154
0.077
0.508
0.832
High-income population growth
131
0.387
0.18
0.129
0.35
1
High-income population density
131
0.492
0.162
0.176
0.483
0.957
Sustainable competitiveness
75
0.394
0.118
0.09
0.389
0.641
High-income population growth
75
0.261
0.109
0.091
0.232
0.635
High-income population density
75
0.363
0.112
0.146
0.35
0.707
Sustainable competitiveness
7
0.608
0.055
0.498
0.63
0.655
High-income population growth
7
0.533
0.143
0.287
0.552
0.706
High-income population density
7
0.632
0.084
0.517
0.6
0.754
Sustainable competitiveness
126
0.526
0.213
0.134
0.563
0.926
High-income population growth
126
0.324
0.149
0.02
0.298
0.879
High-income population density
126
0.471
0.185
0.129
0.473
0.914
Sustainable competitiveness
102
0.253
0.122
0
0.25
0.622
High-income population growth
102
0.132
0.096
0
0.108
0.441
High-income population density
102
0.213
0.113
0
0.216
0.589
Sustainable competitiveness
1006
0.381
0.175
0
0.347
1
High-income population growth
1006
0.251
0.159
0
0.222
1
High-income population density
1006
0.35
0.173
0
0.311
1
North America
South America
Oceania
Europe
Africa
Total
Source CCC of CASS
6.6 Global Sub-regional Pattern: Coastal Cities and Cities Located …
321
6.6 Global Sub-regional Pattern: Coastal Cities and Cities Located in Temperate Zone Are Leading From the spatial distribution of global city competitiveness (Figs. 6.8, 6.9, 6.10), 120 degrees west longitude, 70 degrees west longitude (American east and west coast), 10 degrees east longitude to 10 degree west longitude (Western European countries) and the east longitude 110–140 degrees (China, Japan and South Korea) become the key areas of urban economic competitiveness distribution. At the same time, the top cities in the above regions are mostly at 25–55 degrees north latitude. We have drawn Fig. 6.8 as the standard. It is not difficult to find that most of the world’s top 200 cities and the top 500 cities are located in the above-mentioned fields. These areas generally have the following characteristics: First, they are the intersection of the mainland and the ocean, which can be observed in either the US or the Europe, indicating that the integration of mainland resources and marine resources will bring sustainable growth to urban development. Second, there are strong and stable countries or inter-state organizations to provide guarantee for the development of the city. After that, we draw the nuclear density estimation map of the full sample, the top 200 cities and 500 cities with the latitude and longitude as the distribution axis, and it is easy to find the characteristics of the above distribution. At the same time, we can notice that with the increase of the city ranking, the western hemisphere countries. The proportion of cities is rising, and in terms of latitude, the advantages of the northern hemisphere countries are always obvious and gradually strengthened (Figs. 6.9, 6.10 and Table 6.10).
70
40
10
-180
-120
-60
0
60
120
-20
-50
Fig. 6.8 Sub-regional distribution of sustainable competitiveness. Source CCC of CASS
180
322
6 Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness Performance
Fig. 6.9 Distribution of sustainable competitiveness—Longitude. Source CCC of CASS
Fig. 6.10 Distribution of sustainable competitiveness—Latitude. Source CCC of CASS
6.6 Global Sub-regional Pattern: Coastal Cities and Cities Located …
323
Table 6.10 Global urban sub-regional Sustainable Competitiveness Index Nation
Index
Number Mean Std. dev
High sustainable Sustainable 342 competitiveness competitiveness area High-income 342 population growth
0.439 0.169 0.102
0.408
0.998
0.331 0.16
0.014
0.288
1
0.462 0.175 0.132
0.433
0.908
Sustainable 664 competitiveness
0.304 0.156 0
0.267
1
High-income population growth
664
0.209 0.142 0
0.18
0.872
High-income population density
664
0.34
0.16
0
0.312
1
Sustainable 1006 competitiveness
0.35
0.173 0
0.311
1
High-income population growth
1006
0.251 0.159 0
0.222
1
High-income population density
1006
0.381 0.175 0
0.347
1
High-income population density Other areas
Total
Minimum Median Maximum
342
Source CCC of CASS
As can be seen from Table 6.10, in the above-mentioned region, the sustainable competitiveness is 0.439, which is much ahead of 0.304 in other regions, and the average number has increased by nearly 50%, especially the Comprehensive increment, exceeding 50%, which means that cities in this region are not only more sustainable, but also have more impact on Comprehensive increment. It should be noted that in the above sub-regions, the respective coefficients of variation are relatively small, indicating that the differences in cities in their respective regions are not large and belong to a stable state.
Chapter 7
Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
7.1 Economic Vitality 7.1.1 Overall Pattern of Global Urban Economic Vitality 7.1.1.1
Introduction of Global Urban Economic Vitality Distribution
The degree of intercontinental distribution equilibrium of the leading cities of global urban economic vitality needs to be improved. From the perspective of intercontinental distribution of Top 20 cities in the global urban economic vitality, all cities are concentrated on North America, Europe and Asia. Among them, there exist the largest number of cities of global urban economic vitality in North America among the Top 20 around the world, with a total of 12, the followed is European cities with a total of 6, and the remaining 2 cities are all located in Asia. Singapore ranks first all over the world (Table 7.1). In general, the intercontinental distribution of leading cities of global urban economic vitality is more concentrated on continents with stronger economic basement and greater economic development potential. Among the Top 100 of global urban economic vitality, the means of the economic vitality of cities in all continents except South America and Africa are close to each other, but there exist significant differences of the economic vitality among Top 100 cities within continents. As can be seen from Table 7.2, 57 cities in North America rank in Top 100, with which is the largest number. No cities in South America and Africa rank in Top 100, which indicates that there exist great differences of the economic vitality among cities in these continents and developed regions. Specifically, it can be seen that the mean of the economic vitality in the world are close to each other. Among them, the means of Asian cities are relatively higher, while those of Oceania cities are relatively lower. By observing the coefficient of variation, it can be seen that there exist significant differences of the economic vitality among cities in each continent. Among them, the coefficient of variation of cities in Oceania, North America and Europe are lower than Top 100 cities in the world. There are © China Social Sciences Press 2023 P. Ni et al., The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-99-3553-6_7
325
326
7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Table 7.1 Top 20 cities of global urban economic vitality in the world Region
Country
City
Standardized index World ranking
Asia
Singapore
Singapore
1.0000
1
North America United States
Bridgeport-Stanford 0.9441
2
North America United States
San Jose
0.9432
3
Europe
Norway
Oslo
0.9291
4
Europe
Switzerland
Geneva
0.9045
5
Europe
Ireland
Dublin
0.8937
6
North America United States
Cleveland
0.8891
7
North America United States
San Francisco
0.8888
8
North America United States
Hartford
0.8873
9
North America United States
Salt Lake City
0.8857
10
Asia
Macao
0.8821
11
North America United States
Macao, China
Richmond
0.8816
12
North America United States
Baltimore
0.8787
13
North America United States
Baton Rouge
0.8771
14
North America United States
Milwaukee
0.8746
15
North America United States
罗利
0.8743
16
Europe
Stockholm
0.8742
17
North America United States
Sweden
Boston
0.8736
18
Europe
Germany
Munich
0.8695
19
Europe
United Kingdom London
0.8678
20
Source CCC of CASS
large differences of Asian cities, which indicate the degree of the economic vitality equilibrium of Top 100 cities in Asian needs to be improved. From the better cities of the economic vitality in each continent, Singapore in Asia, Bridgeport-Stamford in North America, Oslo in Europe and Gold Coast in Oceania rank first, second, fourth and twenty-fifth in the global ranking respectively.
7.1.1.2
Urban Spatial Distribution of Global Urban Economic Vitality
The distribution of global urban economic vitality is mainly concentrated on Asia, North America and Europe. From the perspective of the proportion of Top 100 cities all the world in various continents, there exist no cities in Africa and South America in the Top 100 around the world. The proportions of Top 100 cities of global urban economic vitality in Asia and Europe are relatively low, but are relatively higher in Oceania and North America. From the perspective of means of global urban economic vitality, the values of global urban economic vitality of cities in Oceania, North America and Europe are higher than the average level of global cities, and the
7.1 Economic Vitality
327
Table 7.2 Intercontinental distribution of Top 100 cities in global urban economic vitality Region
Sample
Mean
Coefficient of variation
Better city
Standardized index
World ranking
Asia
12
0.8431
0.0676
Singapore
1.0000
1
Europe
26
0.8327
0.0437
Oslo
0.9291
4
North America
57
0.8389
0.0398
Bridgeport-Stanford
0.9441
2
South America
0
0
0
–
0
0
Africa
0
0
0
–
0
0
Oceania
5
0.8301
0.0348
Gold Coast
0.8587
25
Global
100
0.8374
0.0443
Singapore
1.0000
1
Source CCC of CASS
Table 7.3 Intercontinental distribution of global urban economic vitality Region
Sample
Proportion of top 100 cities
Mean
Coefficient of variation
Asia
565
0.0212
0.5326
0.2483
Europe
126
0.2063
0.6132
0.2712
North America
131
0.4351
0.7119
0.2096
South America
75
0.0000
0.4783
0.2360
Africa
102
0.0000
0.3649
0.3799
Oceania
7
0.7143
0.8155
0.0422
Global
1006
0.0994
0.5470
0.3028
Source CCC of CASS
values of global urban economic vitality of cities in Africa and South America are significantly lower than the average level of global cities. Asian cities are relatively close to the average level of global cities in the indicator. From the perspective of coefficients of variation of global urban economic vitality, the differences in global urban economic vitality between Oceanian and North American cities are small, which is significantly lower than the differences of global urban economic vitality among all cities. The differences in global urban economic vitality among African cities are relatively large, but differences in European, Asian, and South American cities are at a moderate level (Table 7.3). Observing Figs. 7.1 and 7.2, it can be seen that the cities with strong global urban economic vitality in the world are mainly concentrated on North America, Western Europe and Eastern Asia. The cities in these regions mostly have strong economic development strength, sufficient vitality and great development momentum. The intercontinental distributions of most cities of Top 100 in the world are mainly concentrated on developed regions and countries with good economic development foundations such as North America and Western Europe which indicates cities in
328
7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness 90
60
30
0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30
-60
-90
Fig. 7.1 Spatial distribution of global urban economic vitality of 1006 cities worldwide. Source CCC of CASS
these regions with great economic development foundation and relatively stable development are also show the great vitality in the future. The number of cities distributed in other regions is relatively small. There exist great differences in the means of sub-indicators of global urban economic vitality and the degree of difference among global cities. From the mean of the sub- indicators of global urban economic vitality, the mean of global urban business convenient degree is relatively high, the mean of proportion of global urban young people is relatively low, the means of global urban property right protection, the density of economic growth and labor productivity are at a moderate level, which reflect the levels of global urban business convenient degree are normal higher, but the gap of global urban young people are relatively larger, which needs to be paid attention. From the coefficients of variation of sub-indicators of global urban economic vitality, the difference in the proportion of global urban young people is relatively large, the differences in global urban business convenient degree and the density of economic growth among cities are relatively small, and the differences in global urban property right and labor productivity are at the moderate level. Among the five sub-indicators, there exist two indicators of San Jose that are in the top of the world, while Ulsan, Bukavu and Macau are also in the top of the world in perspective of some indicators (Table 7.4 and Fig. 7.3).
7.1 Economic Vitality
329 90
60
30
0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30
-60
-90
Fig. 7.2 Spatial distribution of global urban economic vitality of Top 100 cities. Source CCC of CASS
Table 7.4 Statistical descriptions of the sub-indicators of global urban economic vitality
Economic vitality
Mean
Coefficient of variation
Better city
Business convenient degree
0.7174
0.2348
Ulsan
Property rights protection
0.5189
0.3963
San Jose
Proportion of young people
0.3488
0.4075
Bukavu
Density of economic growth
0.4985
0.2528
Macao
Labor productivity
0.5454
0.3390
San Jose
Source CCC of CASS
7.1.2 Pattern of Global Urban Economic Vitality 7.1.2.1
Introduction of G20
The number of cities in emerging economies at the top of global urban economic vitality is significantly lower than cities in developed economies, and there exist absolute advantages of cities in traditionally developed countries in the proportion of cities in top rankings of global urban economic vitality among G20. The comparison of rankings of global urban economic vitality of cities in G20 shows that, the number of cities in America, The U.K. and Germany ranks in the Top three, the number of
7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness NAmerica
SAmerica
Africa
Europe
Asia
2
3
Global
0
1
Density
4
5
330
0
.2
.4
.6
.8
1
Economic Vitality Fig. 7.3 Nuclear density map of global urban economic vitality. Source CCC of CASS
cities in EU ranks fourth. The number of leading cities in China is relatively small and there is no city of other country in Top 20 in G20. In the proportion of Top 100 in global urban economic vitality rankings, the proportion of Top 100 cities in the U.S. is relatively high, up to 70.67%, and urban economic vitalities occupy the leading position. The proportion of Australia is followed with 66.7%, cities in emerging economies like Mexico, India, Brazil, Russia are all not in Top 100 in the world. In the proportion of Top 101–200 of global urban economic vitality, the proportion of Japanese cities is relatively high, accounting for 80%. The proportion of Korean cities is followed with 62.5%, but there are not cities in Mexico, India, Italy, Brazil, Russia and Argentina are the Top 101–200. Therefore, the cities with higher economic vitality are dominated in developed economies. In the proportion of Top 201–500 cities of global urban economic vitality, the proportion of French cities is highest, which is 88.9%, the proportion of South African cities rank the second, which is 83.3%, the economic vitality rankings of most cities in emerging economies are concentrated on this range. In the proportion of Top 500 of global urban economic vitality, the proportion of Top 500 cities in most developed economies such as the U.S.A, Germany, the U.K, and Japan is 100%, which show obvious advantages of global urban economic vitality. On the whole, the economic vitality rankings of cities in G20 are more forward compared with cities in non-G20, and the urban economic vitality of these cities is more vigorous (Table 7.5). On the whole, the means of global urban economic vitality of cities in emerging economies are generally lower than that in developed economies, but the degree of internal differentiation are higher than cities in developed economies. By comparing global urban economic vitality of cities in G20, it is found that in terms of the means, cities in the U.S. rank first, and there exist apparent advantages of cities
7.1 Economic Vitality
331
Table 7.5 Distribution of global urban economic vitality in sample cities of G20 Country
Proportion of top 20 (%)
Proportion of top 100 (%)
Proportion of 101–200 (%)
Proportion of 201–500 (%)
Proportion of top 500 (%)
China
0.34
2.06
11.00
46.05
59.11
United States
16.00
70.67
28.00
1.33
100.00
EU
4.41
23.53
16.18
48.53
88.24
Mexico
0.00
0.00
0.00
54.29
54.29
India
0.00
Germany
7.69%
Italy
0.00
0.00
28.00
28.00
53.85
38.46
7.69
100.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
61.54
61.54
United Kingdom
8.33
58.33
41.67
0.00
100.00
Brazil
0.00
0.00
0.00
28.13
28.13
Japan
0.00
10.00
80.00
10.00
100.00
France
0.00
0.00
11.11
88.89
100.00
Canada
0.00
44.44
55.56
0.00
100.00
Russia
0.00
0.00
0.00
9.09
9.09
Korea
0.00
12.50
62.50
25.00
100.00
Indonesia
0.00
0.00
5.00
40.00
45.00
Turkey
0.00
0.00
6.25%
50.00
56.25
Australia
0.00
66.67
33.33
0.00
100.00
Argentina
0.00
0.00
0.00
22.22
22.22
South Africa
0.00
0.00
16.67
83.33
100.00
Saudi Arabia
0.00
0.00
11.11
77.78
88.89
G20
2.30
12.45
12.58
35.18
60.22
Non-G20
1.12
3.00
2.62
15.73
21.35
Global countries
1.99
9.94
9.94
29.82
49.70
42.19
367.43
441.98
762.60
1472.01
Total
Source CCC of CASS
in developed economies or regions like Australia and the U.K. However, global urban economic vitality of cities in emerging economies such as Brazil, Russia and Argentina shows relatively poor performance. From the coefficient of variation of cities in G20, there exist smaller differences among cities in developed economies such as France, U.K, and Australia with the higher mean in the economic vitality. However, there exist larger differences among cities in emerging economies, such as China and Argentina in economic activity. It is noteworthy that there exists a large
332
7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
difference in economic vitality among EU cities, which indicates that the differences in economic development among EU cities are obvious and cannot be ignored. From the economic vitality of better cities in G20, the better cities in most of the developed economies of G20 rank Top 60 in the world except France and Italy. In emerging economies, better cities of China perform well in terms of global urban economic vitality, Macao ranks 11th in the world, the rankings of better cities in other countries are behind 100, and the gap with developed economies is obvious, which needs to be strengthened. On the whole, the mean of global urban economic vitality of cities in G20 is significantly higher than that of non-G20, and the difference of global urban economic vitality between cities is relatively small, so the economic development is progressing steadily (Table 7.6). Table 7.6 Statistical description of global urban economic vitality of sample cities in G20 Country
Mean
Coefficient of variation
Better city
World ranking
U.S.A
0.8153
0.0617
Bridgeport-Stamford
2
Australia
0.8125
0.0452
Gold Coast
25
U.K
0.8060
0.0416
London
20
Canada
0.7986
0.0442
Hamilton
21
Germany
0.7926
0.0612
Munich
19
Japan
0.7300
0.0600
Kitakyushu-Fukuoka
52
Korea
0.7225
0.0641
Ulsan
62
France
0.6786
0.0182
Paris
192
EU
0.6767
0.1685
Dublin
6
South Africa
0.6360
0.0864
Pretoria
159
Saudi Arabia
0.6204
0.1172
Medina
195
China
0.5648
0.1915
Macao
11
Turkey
0.5481
0.1411
Gebze
180
Italy
0.5444
0.0754
Venice
353
Mexico
0.5426
0.0977
Villahermosa
282
Indonesia
0.5268
0.1442
Balikpapan
199
India
0.5065
0.1274
Delhi
255
Brazil
0.4965
0.1275
Jundiai
242
Russia
0.4614
0.1497
Tyumen
257
Argentina
0.4708
0.1755
Rosario
467
G20
0.5954
0.2274
Bridgeport-Stamford
2
Non-G20
0.4128
0.4067
Singapore
1
Global countries
0.5470
0.3028
Singapore
1
Source CCC of CASS
7.1 Economic Vitality
7.1.2.2
333
Introduction of Representative Countries
According to the continental division, this paper choose China, Japan and India in Asia, the U.K in Europe, the U.S. in North America, Brazil in South America, South Africa and Australia in Oceania for comparative study. In general, cities in developed countries among representative countries show more obvious advantages in the subindicators of global urban economic vitality, while the sub-indicators of global urban economic vitality of cities in emerging economies show great internal differentiation. From the mean of business convenient degree, there exist higher means and obvious advantages of cities in developed countries such as the U.K, the U.S.A, Australia and Japan, while the means of cities in Brazil and South Africa are lower relatively. From the coefficient of variation of business convenient degree, there exist small differences among cities in developed countries such as Australia, Japan, the U.K and the U.S in business convenient degree, while the differences are large among cities in China, India, Brazil and South Africa. Among them, the difference in business convenient degree between Chinese cities is the largest, and the business environment of each city needs to be further improved in China. From the mean of property rights protection, the means of global urban property rights protection in Australia, Japan, the U.K and the U.S. are at the leading positions, which indicate that cities in developed countries also have a strong sense of property rights protection, while the means of urban property rights protection in cities in India, Brazil and China are relatively low. From the coefficient of variation of property rights protection, there exist apparent differences among cities in developed countries such as Japan and Australia in property rights protection, which indicates the degrees of property rights protection are generally high, while there exist large differences among cities in China and India in property rights protection, and each city has its own development degree in property rights protection. From the mean of the proportion of young people, the means of proportion of young people of South African, Indian, Brazilian and Chinese cities are relatively high, and the advantages of young labor force in the cities are prominent, but the mean of proportion of young people of cities in Japan is the lowest, and the gap of young labor force is relatively large. From the coefficient of variation of the proportion of young people, it is worthy to note that the difference of the proportion of young people in Japanese cities is the largest, and the degree of distribution equilibrium of young people in Japanese cities needs to be paid attention to. From the mean of density of economic growth, the mean of the density of economic growth of cities in UK are highest, which shows obvious advantages, while mean of cities in China are lowest. From the coefficient of variation of global urban density of economic growth, there are great differences among Chinese cities, which show obvious differences in economic development levels among the cities. The difference in density of economic growth among cities in South Africa is smallest, and the overall economic development foundations of South African cities are relatively great. From the mean of labor productivity, the means of labor productivity of cities in developed countries, such as the U.S., the U.K., Australia and Japan, are higher while those in emerging economies, such as Brazilian and India, are lower. From
334
7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
the coefficient of variation of labor productivity, the differences of labor productivity among cities in emerging economies such as China and India are larger, while those of developed countries such as Australia, The U.K., Japan and the U.S. are smaller, with generally high urban productivity. On the whole, the means of global urban economic vitality in traditional developed countries are at the leading position, and the differences among cities are smaller, while the cities in emerging economies are the opposite (Table 7.7). From the perspective of overall pattern of global urban economic vitality indicators, the degree of intercontinental distribution equilibrium of the leading cities of global urban economic vitality needs to be improved, which mainly concentrated on North America and Europe with developed economic, and Asia with great economic development momentum. There exist better economic foundation and development trend in these cities, so they are steady development and less affected by the external economic environment. However, it is worth noting that economic development vitality on all continents is relatively close, but it is significant different of development level among the Top 100 in global urban economic vitality index. From the perspective of each continent, there exist higher levels of urban economic vitality in traditionally developed regions such as Oceania, North America, and Europe, and the development levels among the cities are relatively close and more balanced, which occupy the forefront of global urban economic vitality. However, the urban economic vitality in African or South American countries is relatively low and it is obviously different among the cities in global urban economic vitality, so the balances of economic vitality among the cities need to be improved. Especially, global urban economic vitality in Asian countries is at the intermediate level, but due to the different levels of urban economic development among countries on the continents, it is obvious different in urban economic development levels. In the future, it is should be paid attention to the balance of urban economic development and enhance the overall level of urban economic competitiveness. With the gradual progress of economic integration, cities in the member countries of G20 rank higher in global urban economic vitality than those in non-member countries, the economic development vitality of the cities is relatively sufficient, and the equilibrium degree of the economic vitality among cities in member countries is higher than those of non-member countries. Among G20, the economic vitality of cities in emerging economies is significantly lower than that in developed economies, and the degree of differentiation between the cities is greater than that of developed economies. Therefore, it is of great importance to realize coordinated and common development of urban economy. From the sub-indicators of global urban economic vitality of the cities in representative countries, in the cities of most developed countries, except for the lower mean of the proportion of young people, the means of other indicators are relatively higher, and the differences among cities are significantly lower than that of cities in emerging economies. However, in the cities of emerging economies, the proportion of young people is relatively higher, which indicates the urban labor forces are relatively abundant, but the means of other sub-indicators are lower. In global urban economic vitality, cities in the U.S. show obvious leading advantages and good urban
Source CCC of CASS
Economic vitality
Labor productivity
Density of economic growth
Proportion of young people
Property rights protection
Business convenient degree
0.5648 0.1915
Coefficient of variation
0.1720
Coefficient of variation
Mean
0.5419
0.2208
Coefficient of variation
Mean
0.4264
0.4089
Mean
0.3616
Coefficient of variation
0.1255
Coefficient of variation
Mean
0.5381
0.0775
Coefficient of variation
Mean
0.8124
Mean
China
0.0617
0.8153
0.0557
0.8610
0.2154
0.5006
0.0178
0.2552
0.0431
0.8969
0.0373
0.8901
U.S.A
0.1274
0.5065
0.1794
0.3601
0.2132
0.5088
0.0151
0.4517
0.0900
0.4822
0.0640
0.7094
India
0.0600
0.7300
0.0467
0.8037
0.1510
0.5545
2.9346
0.0512
0.0260
0.9294
0.0233
0.8184
Japan
Table 7.7 Statistical analysis of sub-indicators of global economic vitality of representative countries
0.0416
0.8060
0.0468
0.7876
0.1220
0.5965
0.0010
0.1837
0.0311
0.9138
0.0271
0.8951
U.K
0.0864
0.6360
0.1073
0.5193
0.0612
0.5959
0.0682
0.4991
0.0693
0.6096
0.0560
0.6621
South Africa
0.1275
0.4965
0.1179
0.5327
0.1935
0.5105
0.0000
0.3868
0.0764
0.5048
0.0602
0.5485
Brazil
0.0452
0.8125
0.0354
0.8456
0.2076
0.4990
0.0000
0.2464
0.0232
0.9433
0.0206
0.8612
Australia
7.1 Economic Vitality 335
336
7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
development situation. After years of reform in Japan, the foundation and vitality of urban economic growth have been steadily consolidated and strengthened, but the proportion of young people is relatively small, so the large gap of urban young labor force needs to be paid attention to. As an emerging economy, Chinese cities have a good momentum of economic vitality and development. However, there are great differences among cities in the economic vitality. In the future, Chinese cities should make efforts to make up for their shortcomings in achieving balanced development and achieve high-quality economic development.
7.2 Environmental Thoroughness 7.2.1 Overall Pattern of Environmental Toughness 7.2.1.1
Overview of the Head City
Europe leads the world. From the distribution of the top 20 cities of global environmental toughness in all continents, Europe occupies 12 seats, North America 6 seats and Asia 2 seats. In terms of national dimension, Germany has 6 seats, followed by the United States (Table 7.8). More than 90% of the top 100 cities of global environmental toughness are concentrated in North America, Europe and Asia. Comparing the mean value and coefficient of variation of the top 100 cities and all the samples, we can find that the mean level and coefficient of variation of the top 100 cities are significantly higher than the global level. In terms of the intercontinental distribution of the former 100 cities, Europe accounts for 42%, while North America, Europe and Asia together account for more than 90%, with obvious concentration. From the perspective of the best cities with environmental toughness in all continents, the leading cities in Europe, North America and Asia are all in the top 20 in the world, while the best cities in Oceania, Africa and South America are all over 30 in the world (Table 7.9).
7.2.1.2
Overall Spatial Pattern
Oceania, North America and Europe lead the world. According to the mean distribution of global urban environmental toughness, the urban environmental toughness of Oceania, North America and Europe is relatively good, that of Africa and Asia is relatively weak, and that of South America is in the middle. In terms of coefficient of variation, the fluctuation range of environmental toughness in Africa, Europe and Asia is relatively small, while that in Oceania cities is relatively large. In terms of the proportion of the world’s top 100 cities in all continents, Europe and North America account for more than 40%, leading the world, with only 13% in Asia, and less than 3% in Africa, Oceania and South America (Table 7.10, Figs. 7.4 and 7.5).
7.2 Environmental Thoroughness
337
Table 7.8 Environmental toughness index top 20 cities in the world Region
Country
City
Index
World ranking
Europe
Germany
Stuttgart
1.000
1
Europe
Austria
Vienna
0.965
2
Europe
Germany
Hannover
0.959
3
Europe
Germany
Munich
0.958
4
Asia
Singapore
Singapore
0.939
5
North America
Puerto Rico
San Juan
0.924
6
Europe
Switzerland
Geneva
0.920
7
Europe
Germany
Dusseldorf
0.916
8
Asia
Hong Kong, China
Hong Kong
0.910
9
Europe
Sweden
Gothenburg
0.905
10
Europe
Germany
Frankfurt am Main
0.894
11
North America
U.S.A
Kansas City
0.892
12
Europe
Portugal
Lisbon
0.888
13
Europe
Switzerland
Zurich
0.881
14
Europe
Greece
Thessaloniki
0.878
15
North America
U.S.A
Baton Rouge
0.875
16
Europe
Germany
Berlin
0.865
17
North America
U.S.A
Allentown
0.862
18
North America
U.S.A
Baltimore
0.861
19
North America
U.S.A
Knoxville
0.860
20
Source CCC of CASS Table 7.9 Intercontinental distribution of the top 100 cities in the world in terms of environmental toughness index Region
Sample Mean value Coefficient of Optimal city Index World ranking variation
Europe
42
0.846
15.452
Stuttgart
1.000
1
North America 40
0.819
25.285
San Juan
0.924
6
Asia
13
0.826
16.412
Singapore
0.939
5
Oceania
2
0.811
20.481
Melbourne
0.839
34
Africa
2
0.806
29.209
Algiers
0.825
44
South America 1
0.781
–
Brasilia
0.781
98
Global
0.544
3.337
1006
Source CCC of CASS
338
7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Table 7.10 Intercontinental distribution of global urban environmental toughness index Region
Sample
Proportion of top 100 cities (%)
Mean value
Coefficient of variation
Asia
565
13
0.484
3.837
North America
131
40
0.683
5.332
South America
75
1
0.583
4.129
Oceania
7
2
0.763
16.573
Europe
126
42
0.680
3.799
Africa
102
2
0.490
3.140
total
1006
9.94
0.544
3.337
Source CCC of CASS 90
60
30
0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30
-60
-90
Fig. 7.4 Spatial distribution of environmental toughness index of 1006 cities in the world. Source CCC of CASS
The mean value and fluctuation range of the sub indicators of global urban environmental toughness are quite different. According to the sub indicators of environmental toughness, 1006 sample cities are mainly concentrated in areas with less natural disasters, and the climate comfort and power abundance of all cities are at a high level. At present, global cities have low scores in environmental pollution degree and ecological diversity, which indicates that global cities still face great challenges in environmental pollution control and ecological diversity maintenance (Table 7.11 and Fig. 7.6).
7.2 Environmental Thoroughness
339 90
60
30
0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30
-60
-90
Fig. 7.5 Spatial distribution of environmental toughness index of the top 100 cities in the world. Source CCC of CASS
Table 7.11 Statistical description of sub-index of global urban environmental toughness
Environmental toughness
Mean value
Coefficient of variation
Optimal city
Traffic congestion 0.584
4.539
Muscat
Power abundance
0.640
2.676
(Not unique)
Ecological diversity
0.482
2.429
Chicago
Climate comfort
0.654
3.685
Pereira
Environmental pollution degree
0.317
3.768
Singapore
Natural disaster
0.793
4.731
(Not unique)
Source CCC of CASS
7.2.2 National Pattern of Environmental Toughness 7.2.2.1
Overview of G20 Countries
European Union and American cities lead the world, and Chinese cities are emerging. Comparing the ranking of urban environmental toughness of G20 countries, it is found that among the top 20 cities in the world, the European Union leads
340
7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Fig. 7.6 Kernel density map of global urban environmental toughness index. Source CCC of CASS
by 50%, followed by Germany by 30% and the United States by 25%. Among the top 100 cities in global urban environmental toughness, EU has the highest proportion, accounting for 35% and the United States 33%. The EU and the US account for 23% and 17% of the top 101–200 global cities in terms of environmental toughness. Among the top 201–500 cities in global urban environmental toughness, China has the highest proportion, reaching 29%. Among the top 500 cities in global environmental toughness, China has the highest proportion, accounting for 18.2%, followed by the United States and the European Union, accounting for 14.4% and 13.8% respectively. From the ranking distribution, we can see that cities in developed economies such as the European Union and the United States are still in the leading position, but a few of China’s top cities have ranked among the world’s top (Table 7.12). In general, the average environmental toughness of non G20 cities is still lower than that of G20 cities, but the degree of internal differentiation is lower. Comparing the urban environmental toughness of G20 countries, it is found that Germany, EU, Australia, UK and France have obvious advantages in the mean value of environmental toughness, Cities of China, Turkey Russia, India and Saudi Arabia performed relatively poorly. According to the coefficient of variation of environmental toughness, cities in Mexico, Argentina, India, Russia and Saudi Arabia fluctuated less, while those in Australia, Italy, Germany, Britain, Canada and France fluctuated more. From the perspective of the best cities, three cities in G20 countries are in the top 20 in the world, and 11 cities are in the top 100 in the world in terms of environmental toughness (Table 7.13).
7.2 Environmental Thoroughness
341
Table 7.12 Ranking and distribution of environmental toughness index of G20 sample cities Country
Top 20 (%)
Top 100 proportion (%)
Proportion of 101–200 (%)
Proportion of 201–500 (%)
Top 500 proportion (%)
China
5
4
0
29
18.2
U.S.A
25
33
17
7.3
14.4
EU
50
35
23
3.7
13.8
Mexico
0
0
6
5.3
4.4
India
0
0
1
7.7
4.8
Russia
0
0
1
3
2
Brazil
0
1
6
7
5.6
Germany
30
13
0
0
2.6
Italy
0
3
8
0.7
2.6
Indonesia
0
0
0
3
1.8
Turkey
0
0
0
1.7
1
Britain
0
5
6
0.3
2.4
Japan
0
2
5
1
2
Canada
0
6
2
0.3
1.8
South Korea
0
3
1
1.3
1.6
France
0
3
4
0.7
1.8
Argentina
0
0
4
1
1.4
Australia
0
2
4
0
1.2
South Africa
0
0
1
1.3
1
Saudi Arabia
0
0
0
0.3
0.2
G20 countries
80
91
77
73.3
77.6
Non G20 countries
20
9
23
26.7
22.4
Global whole
100
100
100
100
100
Source CCC of CASS
7.2.2.2
Overview of Representative Countries
According to the intercontinental division, China, Japan and India in Asia, the United Kingdom in Europe, the United States in North America, Brazil in South America, South Africa in Africa and Australia in Oceania are mainly selected for comparative study. In general, Australian and British cities have advantages in various sub indicators of environmental toughness, while the overall level of emerging economies is still low.
342
7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Table 7.13 Statistical description of environmental toughness index of G20 cities Country
Mean value
Optimal city
World ranking
China
0.497
Coefficient of variation 5.436
Hong Kong
9
U.S.A
0.732
6.878
Kansas City
12
EU
0.781
8.938
Stuttgart
1
Mexico
0.576
4.840
Tutela Gutierrez
163
India
0.442
3.654
Mangalore
164
Russia
0.458
3.100
Yaroslavl
173
Brazil
0.631
6.138
Brasilia
98
Germany
0.877
13.777
Stuttgart
1
Italy
0.741
15.721
Padua City
53
Indonesia
0.514
6.351
Samarinda
290
Turkey
0.460
5.207
Bursa
431
Britain
0.766
13.124
Belfast
26
Japan
0.721
9.319
Sapporo
76
Canada
0.753
13.120
Vancouver
73
South Korea
0.731
8.661
Weishan
31
France
0.759
11.699
Lille
28
Argentina
0.627
4.593
Rosario
130
Australia
0.776
23.901
Melbourne
34
South Africa
0.593
7.259
Durban
172
Saudi Arabia
0.322
2.857
Jeddah
500
G20 countries
0.562
3.563
Stuttgart
1
Non G20 countries
0.494
2.957
Singapore
5
Global whole
0.544
3.337
Stuttgart
1
Source CCC of CASS
From the perspective of traffic congestion, Britain, the United States and Australia are in the leading position, while emerging economies such as China, India and South Africa perform poorly. Australia and the UK are in a leading position in terms of power abundance, but there is a large gap between their cities. From the perspective of ecological diversity, the United States and the United Kingdom are in the leading position, while emerging economies such as Brazil, South Africa and India perform poorly. In terms of climate comfort, Australia and Japan have obvious urban advantages, but there is a large gap between them. From the perspective of environmental pollution degree, cities in various countries generally have low scores, which indicates that environmental pollution is a common problem in urban development, especially in China and India. From the perspective of natural disasters, cities in various countries generally score higher (Table 7.14).
Source CCC of CASS
Environmental toughness as a whole
Natural disaster
Environmental pollution degree
Climate comfort
Ecological diversity
Power abundance
Traffic congestion
Coefficient of variation
Mean value
Coefficient of variation
Mean value
Coefficient of variation
Mean value
Coefficient of variation
23.901
0.776
10.914
0.790
16.406
0.382
13.650
0.792
2.472
Coefficient of variation
Mean value
0.598
10.544
Mean value
Coefficient of variation
0.947
6.069
Coefficient of variation
Mean value
0.623
Mean value
Australia
5.881
0.491
8.322
0.814
5.239
0.266
5.319
0.709
4.775
0.526
2.787
0.510
5.988
0.539
China
7.259
0.593
4.855
0.744
6.431
0.317
16.245
0.741
9.623
0.441
9.169
0.826
4.519
0.482
South Africa
Table 7.14 Statistical analysis of sub-index of environmental toughness of representative countries
3.654
0.442
6.363
0.838
2.605
0.227
2.754
0.526
4.846
0.416
4.320
0.629
5.249
0.555
India
6.138
0.631
10.607
0.897
14.685
0.355
5.459
0.717
4.176
0.478
4.275
0.779
5.846
0.520
Brazil
9.319
0.721
2.656
0.581
4.626
0.447
20.843
0.799
3.777
0.652
6.071
0.825
36.432
0.606
Japan
6.878
0.732
7.122
0.843
9.817
0.373
8.939
0.752
3.706
0.706
4.629
0.795
5.535
0.628
U.S.A
13.124
0.766
14.626
0.821
6.390
0.410
4.823
0.652
5.642
0.648
19.234
0.973
5.057
0.641
Britain
7.2 Environmental Thoroughness 343
344
7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Table 7.15 The top 20 world cities by social inclusion indicators Region
Country
City
Index
World rank
Asia
Japan
Tokyo
1.0000
1
Asia
Korea
Seoul
0.9785
2
Europe
Czech Republic
Prague
0.9609
3
Asia
Japan
Osaka
0.9564
4
Asia
Taiwan, China
Taipei
0.9547
5
Asia
Japan
Shizuoka-Hamamatsu M.M.A.
0.9323
6
Asia
Japan
Kitakyushu-Fukuoka
0.9218
7
Asia
Japan
Sapporo
0.9200
8
Asia
Taiwan, China
Tainan
0.9199
9
Asia
Japan
Niigata
0.9086
10
Asia
Korea
Busan
0.9043
11
Asia
Japan
Nagoya
0.8954
12
Asia
Taiwan, China
Kaohsiung
0.8928
13
Asia
Japan
Kumamoto
0.8917
14
Asia
Taiwan, China
Taichung
0.8911
15
Europe
Poland
Warsaw
0.8817
16
Europe
Romania
Bucuresti
0.8756
17
Asia
Saudi Arabia
Riyadh
0.8729
18
Asia
Korea
Daejeon
0.8706
19
Asia
Thailand
Bangkok
0.8704
20
Source CCC of CASS
7.3 Social Inclusion 7.3.1 General Landscape of Social Inclusion 7.3.1.1
Overview of the Head City
Asia and Europe lead the world, and Asian cities dominate absolutely. The top 20 cities of global social inclusion show obvious polarization in global distribution, with 17 Asian cities and 3 European cities, indicating that Asian cities are ahead of other cities in terms of social inclusion. In terms of national dimension, Japan has 8 seats, followed by Taiwan, China, with 4 cities (Table 7.15). The distribution of social inclusion of top 100 cities worldwide is uneven across continents, and the mean and fluctuation range of social inclusion on each continents are different. On the one hand, from the perspective of the world’s top 100 cities, the global intercontinental distribution of social inclusion shows a pattern of “leading in Asia, following in Europe and North America, lagging behind
7.3 Social Inclusion
345
Table 7.16 Intercontinental distribution of social inclusion of top 100 cities worldwide Region
Sample
Mean
CV
Optimal city
Index
World rank
N. America
10
0.8040
0.0234
New York
0.8469
37
Europe
27
0.8122
0.0564
Bragg
0.9609
3
Asia
60
0.8432
0.0682
Tokyo
1.0000
1
S. America
2
0.8061
0.0149
Sao Jose dos Campos
0.8146
46
Oceania
1
0.7966
–
Auckland
0.7966
66
Africa
0
–
–
Cairo
0.6518
288
Global
1006
0.5526
0.3025
Tokyo
1.0000
1
Note CV is the abbreviation of coefficient of variation Source CCC of CASS
in South America, Oceania and Africa”. Asian cities account for 60% of the top 100 cities in the world, while European and North American cities account for 27% and 10% respectively. From the perspective of the best cities, the global cities lead the continents, of which Tokyo, Japan’s social inclusion is in an absolute dominant position, 36 higher than New York. On the other hand, except for Africa, the mean of social inclusion of the top 100 cities in the world is relatively small. Among them, the social inclusion of African cities is lower than that of other continents, and Cairo, as the best city, is lower than the average of other continents. In addition, the fluctuation of social inclusion in each continent is relatively small, and the coefficient of variation in Asia and Europe is relatively large, which indicates that there are certain differences between the cities in the two continents (Table 7.16).
7.3.1.2
Global Urban Spatial Landscape of Social Inclusion
The intercontinental distribution of global urban social inclusion shows a hierarchical distribution, with significant differences between intercontinental and intracontinental cities. The intercontinental distribution of global urban social inclusion is shown in Table 7.17, Figs. 7.7 and 7.8. According to the proportion of the top 100 cities, it can be judged that the overall global social inclusion shows a gradual decreasing pattern with higher levels in Europe and Oceania, followed by Asia and North America, and lower levels in South America and Africa. In comparison, the mean of social inclusion index of cities in Europe, Oceania and North America is relatively high, and the difference between cities in the continent is relatively small, and the coefficient of variation is lower than the global average. Although Asian cities are absolutely ahead of the top 100 in terms of social inclusion, the social inclusion index of the remaining cities is relatively low, with an average of 0.0018 higher than the global mean and 0.1345 lower than the highest European mean, indicating that the overall advantage is not obvious. At the same time, the coefficient of variation of urban social inclusion in Asia is relatively large, which indicates that there are
346
7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
some differences in urban social inclusion within Asia. Finally, the social inclusion of African cities is lower than the global average, and there are large internal differences. The mean and fluctuation range of the sub-indicators of global urban social inclusion are quite different. On average, the cost of living is high and the cultural inclusion is low. The former has the lowest coefficient of variation and the latter has the highest coefficient of variation, which indicates that the difference in cost of living is relatively small, but there is a large difference in cultural inclusion. In addition, the coefficient of variation of medical health is relatively large, indicating that there is a large gap between cities in the world. From the perspective of the best cities, Tokyo and Shizuoka-Binsong metropolitan area in Japan have three leading Table 7.17 Intercontinental distribution of social inclusion of cities worldwide Region
Sample
N. America
131
Oceania
7
Africa S. America
Proportion of top 100 cities (%)
Mean
CV
7.63
0.6200
0.1660
14.29
0.6414
0.1358
102
0.00
0.3243
0.4212
75
2.67
0.4944
0.2834
Europe
126
21.43
0.6889
0.1357
Asia
565
10.62
0.5544
0.2808
Global
1006
9.94
0.5526
0.3025
Source CCC of CASS 90
60
30
0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30
-60
-90
Fig. 7.7 Spatial distribution of social inclusion indicators of 1006 cities worldwide. Data Source CCC of CASS
7.3 Social Inclusion
347 90
60
30
0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30
-60
-90
Fig. 7.8 Spatial distribution of social inclusion indicators of the top 100 cities worldwide. Data Source CCC of CASS
Table 7.18 Statistical description of sub-indicators of global urban social inclusion
Social inclusion
Mean
CV
Optimal city
Heritage protection
0.6224
0.2947
Tokyo
Social security
0.5545
0.2982
Shizuoka-Hamamatsu M.M.A.
Social equity 0.5139
0.2616
Bragg
Cost of living
0.9097
0.1938
Konya
Cultural inclusion
0.3085
0.8007
Sao Jose dos Campos
Medical health
0.4117
0.4077
Tokyo
Source CCC of CASS
indicators in the world, and their social inclusion is relatively high (Table 7.18 and Fig. 7.9).
348
7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Fig. 7.9 Kernel density of global urban social inclusion indicators
7.3.2 National Pattern of Social Inclusion 7.3.2.1
Overview of G20 Countries
The social inclusion of cities in Japan, the European Union and the United States is relatively high, while that in China is relatively strong. It can be seen from Table 7.33 that Japan’s urban social inclusion ranks first in the world, with 10 cities ranking within 100 (actually within 30 in the world); the mean of Japan’s urban social inclusion is 0.9151, 39.6% higher than the global average, and the coefficient of variation is 84.9% lower than the global average, indicating that there is little difference in social inclusion among Japanese cities. European cities and the United States are the second most socially inclusive cities, ranking in the top 500 cities in the world. Among them, 22 cities in the European Union rank in the top 100 in the world, with an average of 0.15 points higher than the global average. Urban social inclusion in emerging countries is relatively low, and urban social inclusion in China is relatively strong as a whole. There are 27 cities in the top 100, but more than 2/3 of them are still behind the global 500. The average urban social inclusion is 0.5735, only 0.02 points higher than the global average; and the coefficient of variation is 0.2025, which is at a high level among countries in the world. In Brazil, South Africa and other countries, urban social inclusion is relatively low, especially in South Africa, where only one city has entered the global 500; its average social inclusion is lower than the global average (Table 7.19).
7.3 Social Inclusion
349
Table 7.19 Distribution of social inclusion indicators of sample cities in G20 countries Country
Proportion of top 20 cities (%)
Proportion of top 100 cities (%)
Proportion of 101–200 cities (%)
Proportion of 201–500 cities (%)
Proportion of top 500 cities (%)
China
20.00
27.00
18.00
31.33
27.80
U.S.A
0.00
5.00
15.00
13.33
12.00
15.00
22.00
24.00
4.20
13.20
Mexico
0.00
0.00
4.00
6.67
4.80
India
0.00
1.00
4.00
5.67
4.40
Germany
0.00
3.00
8.00
0.67
2.60
Italy
0.00
2.00
5.00
2.00
2.60
U.K.
0.00
2.00
5.00
1.67
2.40
Brazil
0.00
1.00
0.00
1.67
1.20
Japan
40.00
10.00
0.00
0.00
2.00
France
0.00
0.00
1.00
2.33
1.60
Canada
0.00
5.00
2.00
0.67
1.80
Russia
0.00
2.00
5.00
8.00
6.00
Korea
15.00
7.00
1.00
0.00
1.60
Indonesia
0.00
0.00
4.00
3.00
2.60
Turkey
0.00
4.00
3.00
2.33
2.80
Australia
0.00
0.00
0.00
1.67
1.00
Argentina
0.00
1.00
2.00
1.00
1.20
S. Africa
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.33
0.20
Saudi Arabia
5.00
4.00
2.00
1.00
1.80
95.00
90.00
88.00
85.33
86.80
5.00
10.00
12.00
14.67
13.20
100.00
100.00
100.00
100.00
100.00
European Union
G20 Non-G20 Global whole
Source CCC of CASS
Urban social inclusion in G20 countries is higher than that in non G20 countries, and the internal differentiation is relatively small. From the distribution of urban social inclusion in G20 and non-G20 countries in each ranking segment, urban social inclusion in G20 countries is completely superior to that in non-G20 countries, with absolute advantages. Among the top 100 cities in the world, 90% are from G20 countries, and 86.8% are from the top 500 countries. Specifically, the average urban social inclusion of G20 countries is 0.1682 points higher than that of non-G20 countries, and the former’s coefficient of variation is lower than the latter’s
350
7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Table 7.20 Statistical description of social inclusion indicators of G20 sample cities Country
Mean
CV
Optimal city
World rank
China
0.5735
0.2025
Taipei
5
U.S.A
0.6349
0.1460
New York
37
European Union
0.7288
0.1146
Czech Republic
3
Mexico
0.5869
0.1467
Mexico city
113
India
0.4716
0.2643
Bangalore
96
Germany
0.7360
0.0769
Berlin
21
Italy
0.7151
0.0630
Milan
74
U.K.
0.7055
0.0677
West Yorkshire
75
Brazil
0.5051
0.1818
Sao Jose dos Campos
46
Japan
0.9151
0.0458
Tokyo
1
France
0.6130
0.1303
Paris
168
Canada
0.7521
0.0958
Toronto
44
Russia
0.6373
0.1178
Moscow
36
Korea
0.8456
0.0874
Seoul
2
Indonesia
0.6094
0.1554
Jakarta
105
Turkey
0.6836
0.1561
Istanbul
38
Australia
0.6155
0.0958
Adelaide
218
Argentina
0.6098
0.1652
Buenos Aires
65
S. Africa
0.4875
0.2416
Cape Down
304
Saudi Arabia
0.7358
0.1247
Riyadh
18
G20
0.5969
0.2279
Tokyo
1
Non-G20
0.4287
0.4276
Bangkok
20
Global whole
0.5526
0.3025
Tokyo
1
Source CCC of CASS
0.1997, which indicates that the urban social inclusion of non-G20 countries is low, and the internal differentiation is relatively significant (Table 7.20).
7.3.2.2
Overview of Representative Countries
The sub-indicators of social inclusion of representative countries are quite different, and Japan’s social inclusion is relatively strong. In addition to the cost of living, the biggest difference of other indicators of social inclusion among the representative countries is more than 2 times. Japan (0.6741) with the largest cultural inclusion is 4.9 times that of India (0.1371) with the lowest one. The difference between the representative countries is more significant. The sub indicators of social inclusion in Japan are relatively strong, with the other five indicators ranking first
7.4 Scientific and Technological Innovation
351
Table 7.21 Statistical analysis of sub-indicators of social inclusion in representative countries Australia Brazil
U.S.A
S. Africa
Japan
India
U.K.
China
Heritage Mean 0.6381 protection CV 0.1369
0.6587 0.6712 0.6017 0.8252 0.4842 0.6699 0.6534
Social security
Mean 0.6064
0.3080 0.5064 0.2057 0.8556 0.5786 0.5395 0.6439
CV
0.0993
0.3374 0.2616 0.2049 0.1156 0.2141 0.1166 0.1476
Social equity
Mean 0.4685
0.4264 0.4202 0.3355 0.7255 0.4617 0.6230 0.5476
CV
0.0659
0.0537 0.2286 0.0508 0.0774 0.1540 0.1346 0.1725
Living cost
Mean 0.9766
0.8995 0.9790 0.9806 0.9642 0.9338 0.9645 0.9563
CV
0.0219
0.0404 0.0098 0.0074 0.0258 0.0846 0.0510 0.1168
Cultural inclusion
Mean 0.4410
0.4481 0.5832 0.5286 0.6741 0.1371 0.5808 0.2406
CV
0.2297
0.3748 0.2239 0.2825 0.0978 1.1765 0.1624 0.8847
Medical health
Mean 0.4950
0.3911 0.5803 0.5211 0.8426 0.4716 0.6463 0.3459
CV
0.2660
0.3046 0.2270 0.3240 0.1040 0.2906 0.1402 0.3720
Social inclusion
Mean 0.6155
0.5051 0.6349 0.4875 0.9151 0.4716 0.7055 0.5735
CV
0.1818 0.1460 0.2416 0.0458 0.2643 0.0677 0.2025
0.0958
0.1839 0.1860 0.3113 0.1022 0.4635 0.1608 0.1838
Source CCC of CASS
in the representative countries except for the cost of living. China’s social inclusion is above the global average level, but there is a certain gap between China and Japan, the world’s leading country. Among them, medical health ranks the lowest among the representative countries, with a gap of nearly 0.5 points between China and Japan. India and South Africa are relatively low in social inclusion, with the lowest representative countries in both sub rankings (Table 7.21).
7.4 Scientific and Technological Innovation 7.4.1 Overall Pattern of Scientific and Technological Innovation 7.4.1.1
Head City Overview
The top cities of global scientific and technological innovation are unevenly distributed across continents. The top cities of global scientific and technological innovation are unevenly distributed across continents. From the distribution of the top 20 cities of global scientific and technological innovation on all continents, they are all concentrated in North America, Asia and Europe, among which, the number of top 20 cities of North America scientific and technological innovation is the largest,
352
7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
9 are shortlisted cities, followed by Asia, 7 are shortlisted cities, and the number of European shortlisted cities is the smallest, 4 in total (Table 7.22). Among the top 100 cities of global scientific and technological innovation, the average value and fluctuation range of cities in Asia and North America are relatively close. Among them, the average value of urban scientific and technological innovation in North America and Asia is the highest, the average value of urban scientific and technological innovation in South America is the lowest, and the average value of urban scientific and technological innovation in Europe and Oceania is in the middle. From the perspective of the best cities of science and technology innovation in all continents, the corresponding best cities in Asia, North America, Europe, Oceania and South America are Tokyo, New York, London, Sydney and Sao Paulo, respectively, ranking first, second, fourth, 44th and 59th in the world (Table 7.23). Table 7.22 Top 20 cities in the world in science and technology innovation indicators Regional
National
City
Index
Ranking
Asia
Japan
Tokyo
1
1
N. America
U.S.A
New York
0.96
2
Asia
China
Beijing
0.955
3
Europe
U.K
London
0.928
4
N. America
U.S.A
San Francisco
0.888
5
Europe
France
Paris
0.883
6
Asia
Korea
Seoul
0.875
7
N. America
U.S.A
Boston
0.871
8
Asia
China
Shanghai
0.853
9
N. America
U.S.A
Chicago
0.841
10
Asia
Japan
Osaka
0.832
11
N. America
U.S.A
Seattle
0.829
12
N. America
U.S.A
Los Angeles
0.825
13
Asia
Singapore
Singapore
0.8
14
N. America
Canada
Toronto
0.796
15
Asia
China
Taipei
0.78
16
N. America
U.S.A
Philadelphia
0.775
17
Europe
Germany
Munich
0.769
18
N. America
U.S.A
Austin
0.767
19
Europe
Russia
Moscow
0.766
20
Source CCC of CASS
7.4 Scientific and Technological Innovation
353
Table 7.23 Intercontinental distribution of the top 100 cities in the world Regional
Sample
Mean value
Coefficient variation
Optimal city
Index
Ranking
Asia
27
0.713
0.156
Tokyo
1
1
Europe
31
0.696
0.104
London
0.928
4
N. America
35
0.716
0.125
New York
0.96
2
S. America
3
0.648
0.019
Sao Paulo
0.665
59
Oceania
4
0.674
0.049
Sydney
0.705
44
Global
1006
0.311
0.602
Tokyo
1
1
Source CCC of CASS
7.4.1.2
Overall Spatial Pattern
Cities with advanced level of scientific and technological innovation are mainly concentrated in Europe, North America and Asia. According to the average distribution of global urban science and technology innovation, urban science and technology innovation is relatively developed in Oceania, Europe and North America, relatively weak in Africa, and moderate in Asia and South America. According to the coefficient of variation of the intercontinental distribution of global urban scientific and technological innovation, the fluctuation range of urban scientific and technological innovation in Oceania is relatively small, that in Asia and Africa is relatively large, and that in Europe, North America and South America is in the middle. In terms of the proportion of the top 100 global cities in all continents, no city in Africa has entered the top 100 in science and technology innovation. The proportion of the top 100 cities in science and technology innovation in South America and Asia is relatively low. The proportion of the top 100 cities in science and technology innovation in Oceania is relatively high. The proportion of the top 100 cities in science and technology innovation in Europe and North America is in the middle (Table 7.24, Figs. 7.10 and 7.11). Table 7.24 Intercontinental distribution of global urban science and technology innovation indicators Regional
Sample
Mean value
Coefficient variation
Asia
565
Europe
126
4.78
0.262
0.599
24.60
0.477
0.352
N. America
131
26.72
S. America
75
4.00
0.449
0.460
0.3
Oceania
7
0.461
57.14
0.591
0.212
Africa Global
102
0.00
0.194
0.628
1006
9.94
0.311
0.602
Source CCC of CASS
Proportion of top 100 cities (%)
354
7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness 90
60
30
0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30
-60
-90
Fig. 7.10 Spatial distribution of scientific and technological innovation indicators in 1006 cities around the world. Source CCC of CASS
The average value of the sub indicators of global urban science and technology innovation is generally low, and the fluctuation range is quite different. In terms of the average value of the sub indicators of scientific and technological innovation, except that the paper index of global cities is greater than 0.5, the average value of other sub indicators of scientific and technological innovation is less than 0.5, and the University index and scientific and technological enterprise index are relatively low, and the performance of the Knowledge density and patent index of global cities is in the middle. From the variation coefficient of the sub indicators of scientific and technological innovation, the fluctuation range of the scientific and technological enterprise index and University index is relatively large, the fluctuation range of the paper index is relatively small, and the fluctuation range of the patent index and Knowledge density is in the middle. Among the five sub indicators, Tokyo ranks first in the world in three indicators, New York, Moscow and Tokyo in one indicator (Table 7.25 and Fig. 7.12).
7.4 Scientific and Technological Innovation
355 90
60
30
0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30
-60
-90
Fig. 7.11 Spatial distribution of scientific and technological innovation indicators of the top 100 cities in the world. Source CCC of CASS
Table 7.25 Statistical description of sub indicators of global urban science and technology innovation
Technological innovation
Mean value
Coefficient variation
Optimal city
Patent index
0.276
0.829
Tokyo
Paper index
0.547
0.318
Beijing
Technology enterprise index
0.125
1.5
Tokyo
University index
0.19
1.154
New York
Cultural facilities
0.347
0.637
Moscow
Technological innovation
0.311
0.602
Tokyo
Source CCC of CASS
356
7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Fig. 7.12 Core density map of global urban science and technology innovation indicators. Source CCC of CASS
7.4.2 National Pattern of Scientific and Technological Innovation 7.4.2.1
G20 Country Profile
The number of emerging economies in the top cities of global technological innovation is still lower than that of developed economies, and China and the United States occupy an absolute advantage in the number of top cities in the G20 countries’ technological innovation rankings. By comparing the ranking of urban science and technology innovation in G20 countries, it is found that among the top 20 cities in the world, 3 cities in China, 8 cities in the United States, 2 cities in Japan, 1 city in Germany, the United Kingdom, France, Canada, Russia and South Korea, and no cities in other countries are in the top 20. Among the top 100 cities in terms of scientific and technological innovation in the world, the United States has the highest proportion, up to 20%, followed by China, accounting for 10%. Indonesia, South Africa and Saudi Arabia do not have any cities in the top 100 cities in the world. Among the top 101–200 cities in terms of scientific and technological innovation in the world, China and the United States have no significant difference. China accounts for 13% of the top 101–200 cities. No city in Mexico or Argentina has entered the top 101–200 cities in the world. The number of Chinese cities accounts for 24.67% of the top 201–500 cities in global scientific and technological innovation, far higher than 9% of the United States. Neither the United Kingdom nor Canada has any cities in the top 201–500 cities in the world. Among the top 500 cities in terms of scientific and
7.4 Scientific and Technological Innovation
357
technological innovation in the world, China has the highest proportion, accounting for 20.8%, followed by the United States, accounting for 14.2%. South Africa and Saudi Arabia have the lowest proportion, accounting for no more than 1% (Table 7.26). Overall, the average value of urban technological innovation in emerging economies is still lower than that in developed economies, and the degree of internal differentiation is higher than that in developed economies. By comparing the urban science and technology innovation in G20 countries, it is found that in terms of the average value of science and technology innovation, cities in Canada, Japan, Britain, Germany and Australia have obvious advantages, while cities in India, Indonesia, Saudi Arabia and Mexico have relatively poor performance. In terms of the coefficient of variation of scientific and technological innovation, the fluctuation range of cities in Canada, Germany and Italy is relatively small, while that in Saudi Arabia, China and India is relatively large. From the perspective of the best cities of Table 7.26 Ranking and distribution of scientific and technological innovation indicators of G20 sample cities National
Top 20 proportion (%)
Top 100 Proportion (%)
Proportion of 101–200 (%)
Proportion of 201–500 (%)
Top 500 proportion (%)
China
15.00
17.00
13.00
24.67
20.80
U.S.A
40.00
28.00
16.00
9.00
14.20
Mexico
0.00
1.00
0.00
5.00
3.20
India
0.00
1.00
6.00
8.33
6.40
Germany
5.00
5.00
7.00
0.33
2.60
Italy
0.00
4.00
4.00
1.67
2.60
U.K
5.00
4.00
8.00
0.00
2.60
Brazil
0.00
2.00
1.00
4.67
3.40
Japan
10.00
3.00
5.00
0.67
2.00
France
5.00
1.00
3.00
1.67
1.80
Canada
5.00
6.00
3.00
0.00
1.80
Russia
5.00
1.00
2.00
7.00
4.80
Korea
5.00
2.00
4.00
0.67
1.60
Indonesia
0.00
0.00
1.00
1.67
1.20
Turkey
0.00
1.00
1.00
3.67
2.60
Australia
0.00
3.00
2.00
0.33
1.20
Argentina
0.00
1.00
0.00
2.00
1.40
South Africa
0.00
0.00
2.00
1.00
1.00
Saudi Arabia 总计
0.00
0.00
1.00
0.67
0.60
95.00
80.00
79.00
73.00
75.80
Source CCC of CASS
358
7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Table 7.27 Statistical description of scientific and technological innovation indicators of G20 sample cities National
Mean value
Coefficient variation
Optimal city
Ranking
France
0.492
0.339
Paris
6
U.S.A
0.542
0.325
New York
2
U.K
0.594
0.204
London
4
China
0.263
0.591
Beijing
3
Turkey
0.324
0.396
Istanbul
57
Italy
0.537
0.202
Rome
35
Russia
0.32
0.344
Moscow
20
Japan
0.6
0.306
Tokyo
1
Canada
0.642
0.140
Toronto
15
Australia
0.574
0.223
Sydney
44
Germany
0.582
0.165
Munich
18
Korea
0.552
0.268
Seoul
7
India
0.216
0.560
Bombay
80
Indonesia
0.222
0.438
Jakarta
186
Argentina
0.329
0.381
Buenos Aires
72
Mexico
0.249
0.438
Mexico city
78
Brazil
0.309
0.422
Sao Paulo
59
Saudi Arabia
0.244
0.595
Riyadh
102
South Africa
0.392
0.458
Cape Down
120
Global
0.327
0.582
Tokyo
1
Source CCC of CASS
science and technology innovation in the G20 countries, 9 cities rank in the top 20 of the world’s science and technology innovation, 16 cities rank in the top 100 of the world’s science and technology innovation, and 19 cities rank in the top 200 of the world’s science and technology innovation (Table 7.27).
7.4.2.2
Overview of Representative Countries
According to the intercontinental division, China, Japan and India in Asia, the United Kingdom in Europe, the United States in North America, Brazil in South America, South Africa in Africa and Australia in Oceania are mainly selected for comparative study. In general, developed economies have more advantages in the sub indicators of scientific and technological innovation, and the sub indicators of emerging economies have greater internal differentiation. From the average value of patent index, Japan, the United States and the United Kingdom have developed urban science and technology innovation, while India and
7.5 External Contacts
359
Brazil have relatively poor urban science and technology innovation. According to the coefficient of variation of sci-tech innovation index, the fluctuation range of urban sci-tech innovation in Britain, Japan and Australia is relatively small, while that in India and Brazil is relatively large. n terms of the average paper index, the cities of Australia, Britain and Japan have higher paper index, while the cities of India and China have lower paper index. According to the coefficient of variation of paper index, the fluctuation range of urban paper index in Britain, Japan and Australia is relatively small, while that in South Africa, China and India is relatively large. From the average value of technology enterprise index, Japan and the United States have obvious urban advantages, while India and Brazil have low technology enterprise index; from the coefficient of variation of technology enterprise index, the fluctuation range of cities in the United States and Australia is relatively small, while that in India and Brazil is relatively large. From the average of University index, the City University index of India and China is lower, while that of Australia, Britain and the United States is higher. According to the coefficient of variation of University index, the fluctuation range of cities in Australia and Britain is relatively small, while that in China and India is relatively large. From the average of the Knowledge density index, the urban advantages of Britain and Japan are obvious, while that of China and India are not good. From the coefficient of variation of Knowledge density index, the fluctuation range of cities in Britain and Japan is relatively small, while that in China and India is the largest (Table 7.28).
7.5 External Contacts 7.5.1 Overall Pattern of External Contacts 7.5.1.1
Overview of the Head City
The head city of global external contact continent distribution is uneven. In terms of the distribution of the top 20 cities in the world in each continent, they are all concentrated in North America, Europe and Asia. Among them, the number of the top 20 cities in North America is the highest, with 8 cities in the list, followed by 7 cities in Europe, and the number of Cities in Asia is the lowest, with 5 cities in total (Table 7.29). Among the top 100 cities in the world, the average and fluctuation range of cities in each continent are close. The mean values of North America and Europe were the highest, South America the lowest, and Asia and Oceania the middle. From the perspective of the best cities with external connections on all continents, Europe, North America, Asia, Oceania and South America are Paris, New York, Beijing,
Source CCC of CASS
Technological innovation
Cultural facilities
University index
Technology enterprise index
Paper index
Patent index
0.263 0.591
Coefficient variation
0.768
Coefficient variation
Mean value
0.224
1.34
Coefficient variation
Mean value
0.121
2.083
Mean value
0.07
Coefficient variation
0.318
Coefficient variation
Mean value
0.509
0.598
Coefficient variation
Mean value
0.296
Mean value
China
0.325
0.542
0.329
0.515
0.663
0.455
0.698
0.297
0.206
0.685
0.264
0.589
U.S.A
0.56
0.216
0.734
0.25
0.904
0.089
2.587
0.045
0.313
0.509
1.203
0.143
India
0.306
0.6
0.263
0.642
0.523
0.416
0.94
0.344
0.103
0.742
0.218
0.702
Japan
0.204
0.594
0.2
0.629
0.236
0.638
1.03
0.22
0.089
0.754
0.156
0.575
U.K
Table 7.28 Statistical analysis of representative national scientific and technological innovation sub indicators
0.458
0.392
0.514
0.496
0.642
0.303
1.568
0.109
0.36
0.588
0.314
0.404
South Africa
0.422
0.309
0.511
0.347
0.799
0.232
2.172
0.064
0.166
0.611
0.737
0.22
Brazil
0.223
0.574
0.422
0.301
0.158
0.68
0.803
0.267
0.112
0.771
0.225
0.546
Australia
360 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
7.5 External Contacts
361
Table 7.29 Global contact indicators top 20 cities in the world Region
Country
City
Index
Rank
European
French
Paris
1.000
1
North America
United States
New York
0.978
2
European
U.K.
London
0.961
3
Asia
China
Beijing
0.932
4
European
Netherlands,
Amsterdam
0.928
5
Asia
Turkey
Istanbul
0.914
6
Asia
China
Shanghai
0.890
7
European
Spain
Barcelona
0.890
8
European
Italy
Milan
0.889
9
North America
United States
Chicago
0.885
10
North America
United States
Atlanta,
0.883
11
European
Spain
Madrid
0.882
12
North America
United States
Dallas-Fort Worth
0.881
13
North America
United States
Los Angeles
0.873
14
North America
United States
In Houston
0.871
15
European
Russia
Moscow
0.865
16
North America
United States
Washington, D.C.
0.863
17
Asia
Singapore
Singapore
0.862
18
Asia
Japan
Tokyo
0.859
19
North America
Canada
Toronto
0.852
20
Source CCC of CASS
Sydney and Bogota respectively, ranking first, second, fourth, 21st and 88th in the world (Table 7.30). Table 7.30 Intercontinental distribution of external connections among the top 100 global cities Region
Sample
Mean
CV
Best city
Index
Rank
Asia
25
0.781
0.089
Beijing
0.932
4
Europe
44
0.787
0.089
Paris
1.000
1
North America
25
0.806
0.085
New York
0.978
2
South America
2
0.712
–
Bogota
0.713
88
Oceania
4
0.769
0.083
Sydney
0.847
21
Global
1006
0.444
0.411
Paris
1.000
1
Source CCC of CASS
362
7.5.1.2
7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Overall Spatial Pattern
The most developed cities in the world are in Europe, North America and Asia. From the mean characteristics of the intercontinental distribution of global cities, the cities in Oceania, Europe and North America have relatively developed external connections, while those in Africa are relatively weak, and those in Asia and South America are in the middle. In terms of the variation coefficient of global cities’ external contact distribution, Oceania cities’ external contact fluctuation range is small, Africa cities’ external contact fluctuation range is large, and North America, Europe, Asia and South America cities’ external contact fluctuation range is in the middle. In terms of the proportion of the global top 100 cities in each continent, no African city ranks in the top 100 in terms of external connections. The proportion of the top 100 cities in South America and Asia is relatively low, the proportion of the top 100 cities in Oceania and Europe is relatively high, and the proportion of the top 100 cities in North America is in the middle (Table 7.31, Figs. 7.13 and 7.14). The mean value and fluctuation range of the sub-index of external links of global cities are quite different. According to the mean value of the sub-index of external contact, the shipping convenience of global cities is relatively high, the aviation convenience of global cities is relatively low, and the enterprise connection, information connection, information access convenience and scientific research connection of global cities are in the middle. In terms of the coefficient of variation of the sub-index of external contact, the fluctuation range of global urban aviation convenience is relatively large, the fluctuation range of global urban shipping convenience is relatively small, and the fluctuation range of global urban enterprise connection degree, information connection degree, information access connection degree and scientific research connection degree is in the middle. New York leads the world in three of the six sub-indices, while Paris, London and Sydney each have one (Table 7.32 and Fig. 7.15). Table 7.31 Intercontinental distribution of indicators of global city external linkages Region
Sample
Asia
565
Europe
126
North America
131
South America
75
Oceania
7
Africa Global Source CCC of CASS
Proportion of top 100 cities (%)
Mean
CV
4.40
0.406
0.370
34.90
0.582
0.371
19.10
0.571
0.294
2.70
0.406
0.360
57.10
0.680
0.190
102
0.00
0.331
0.471
1006
9.94
0.444
0.411
7.5 External Contacts
363
90
60
30
0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30
-60
-90 Fig. 7.13 Spatial distribution of external contact indicators for 1006 cities in the world. Source CCC of CASS 90
60
30
0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30
-60
-90
Fig. 7.14 Spatial distribution of external linkages indicators of the top 100 cities in the world. Source CCC of CASS
364
7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Table 7.32 A statistical description of the sub-index of global city external contact Global connectivity
Mean
CV
Best city
Degree of enterprise connection
0.586
0.550
New York
Degree of information contact
0.347
0.635
New York
Information accessibility
0.408
0.543
Sydney
Shipping convenience
0.838
0.186
New York
Aviation convenience
0.130
1.248
Paris
Degree of scientific research connection
0.428
0.626
London
External contact degree
0.444
0.411
Paris
Source CCC of CASS
Fig. 7.15 SA nuclear density map of global city external linkages indicators. Source CCC of CASS
7.5.2 The Pattern of Countries with Foreign Contacts 7.5.2.1
Overview of the Head City
The number of cities in the global head of external contact of emerging economies is still lower than that of developed economies, and China and the United States have an absolute advantage in the number of cities in the top ranking of external contact of G20 countries. Rankings of the G20 countries city outside contact is found, in front of the global city outside contact number 20 in the proportion of China and the United States are two cities, Italy, Britain, Turkey, Japan, France, Canada, Russia, each has a city, no other countries into the global top 20 cities. Among the top 100 global cities in terms of external connections, the United States has the highest proportion, accounting for 20%, followed by China, accounting for 10%. Argentina, South Africa and Saudi Arabia do not have a single city in the top 100. Among the global cities in the top 101–200, the United States has the highest number of cities, accounting for 25%, followed by China, accounting for
7.5 External Contacts
365
17%. Mexico, South Korea and Indonesia do not have any cities in the top 101–200. Among the top 201–500 global cities in terms of the number of foreign contacts, Chinese cities account for the highest proportion (37.7%), followed by the United States (8.7%), and no German city ranks in the top 201–500. Among the top 500 global cities with external connections, Chinese cities account for the highest proportion, reaching 28%, followed by the US with 14.2%, and South Africa and Saudi Arabia with the lowest proportion, accounting for less than 1% (Table 7.33). On the whole, the average of external connections of cities in emerging economies is still lower than that of developed economies, and the degree of internal differentiation is higher than that of developed economies. A comparison of external linkages among G20 countries found that cities in France, Germany, Italy and the UK had significant advantages over cities in India, Brazil and Russia in terms of average external linkages. In terms of the coefficient of variation of external links, cities in Germany, Italy and Canada have a small fluctuation range, while cities Table 7.33 The ranking distribution of external contact indicators of Cities in G20 countries Country
>20 (%)
>100 (%)
101–200 (%)
201–500 (%)
>500 (%)
China
10.0
10.0
17.0
37.7
28.0
United States
10.0
20.0
25.0
8.7
14.2
European Union
25.0
33.0
26.0
3.0
13.6
Mexico
0.0
1.0
0.0
5.0
3.2
India
0.0
5.0
2.0
2.7
3.0
Russia
0.0
7.0
6.0
0.0
2.6
Brazil
5.0
4.0
7.0
0.7
2.6
Germany
5.0
7.0
3.0
0.7
2.4
Italy
0.0
0.0
1.0
3.0
2.0
Indonesia
5.0
1.0
2.0
2.3
2.0
Turkey
5.0
4.0
4.0
0.3
1.8
U.K.
5.0
4.0
3.0
0.7
1.8
Japan
5.0
1.0
1.0
2.3
1.8
Canada
0.0
1.0
0.0
2.3
1.6
South Korea
0.0
1.0
0.0
2.0
1.4
The French
5.0
2.0
1.0
1.3
1.4
Argentina
0.0
3.0
1.0
0.7
1.2
Australia
0.0
0.0
1.0
1.3
1.0
South Africa
0.0
0.0
1.0
1.0
0.8
Saudi Arabia
0.0
0.0
1.0
1.0
0.8
G20 countries
80.0
87.0
82.0
76.7
79.8
Non G20 countries
20.0
13.0
18.0
23.30
20.2
100.0
100.0
100.0
World as a whole Source CCC of CASS
100.0
100.0
366
7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Table 7.34 Statistical description of external contact indicators of G20 sample cities Country
Mean
CV
Best city
Rank
France
0.7134
0.1825
Paris
1
United States
0.6404
0.2192
New York
2
U.K.
0.6914
0.2130
London
3
China
0.4455
0.2445
Beijing
4
Turkey
0.4495
0.3955
Istanbul
6
Italy
0.6900
0.1443
Milan
9
Russia
0.3276
0.5071
Moscow
16
Japan
0.5659
0.2236
Tokyo
19
Canada
0.6958
0.1405
Toronto
20
Australia
0.6717
0.2070
Sydney
21
Germany
0.7131
0.0996
Berlin
24
South Korea
0.5479
0.2296
Seoul
27
India
0.3013
0.4952
Mumbai
54
Indonesia
0.3848
0.2964
Jakarta
71
Argentina
0.4522
0.3294
Buenos Aires
91
Mexico
0.4133
0.3209
Mexico City
99
Brazil
0.3548
0.4274
Sao Paulo
124
Saudi Arabia
0.3807
0.3870
Riyadh
128
South Africa
0.5239
0.2457
Johannesburg
141
European Union
0.7068
0.1401
Paris
1
G20 countries
0.4691
0.3818
Paris
1
Non G20 countries
0.3746
0.4659
Singapore
18
Global
0.4440
0.4113
Paris
1
Source CCC of CASS
in Russia, Brazil and India have a large fluctuation range. In terms of the best cities in G2O countries, 9 cities are in the top 20, 16 cities are in the top 100, and 19 cities are in the top 200 (Table 7.34).
7.5.2.2
Overview of Representative Countries
According to the continental division, the focus here is to choose China, Japan and India in Asia, the United Kingdom in Europe, the United States in North America, Brazil in South America, South Africa and Australia in Oceania for comparative study. In general, cities in developed economies have more obvious advantages in the sub-index of external relations, while cities in emerging economies have greater internal differentiation in each sub-index.
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable …
367
According to the mean value of the index, cities in Britain, Australia and the United States are highly connected to the outside world, while those in India and Brazil are relatively poor. In terms of the coefficient of variation of the index, cities in Australia, The United Kingdom and the United States have a small fluctuation range of external contact, while cities in India and Brazil have a large fluctuation range of external contact. In terms of the mean value of corporate connectivity, Australia, Japan and the United States have a higher degree of corporate connectivity, while India and Brazil have a lower degree of corporate connectivity. In terms of the coefficient of variation of enterprise connection, the urban enterprise connection degree of China, Japan and Australia fluctuates slightly, while that of India and Brazil fluctuates greatly. From the mean of the degree of information contact, cities in India and Japan have a low degree of information contact, while cities in Australia, the United States and the United Kingdom have a high degree of information contact. From the variation coefficient of information connection degree, cities in Japan and Australia have a small fluctuation range, while cities in India and South Africa have a large fluctuation range. From the mean value of information access convenience, American and U.K. cities have obvious advantages. According to the coefficient of variation of information access convenience, the fluctuation range of American and U.K. cities is small, while that of Chinese cities is the largest. From the average value of shipping convenience, Japanese and U.K. cities have obvious advantages. In terms of the variation coefficient of shipping convenience, cities in Japan and Britain fluctuate less, while cities in Brazil fluctuate more. From the mean value of aviation convenience, the city advantages of THE UK and the US are obvious, the city advantages of the UK are obvious, and the city performance of Brazil is relatively poor. From the coefficient of variation of aviation convenience, cities in Britain and Australia fluctuate less. From the mean of scientific research linkages, the cities of Britain and Australia have obvious advantages. From the coefficient of variation of scientific association degree, cities in Japan and Australia fluctuate less (Table 7.35).
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Source CCC of CASS
External contact
Enterprise connection
Degree of scientific research connection
Aviation convenience
Shipping convenience
Information accessibility
Degree of information contact
0.446 0.245
CV
0.102
CV Mean
0.686
0.771
Mean
0.272
CV
1.070
CV Mean
0.140
0.116
CV Mean
0.882
0.602
Mean
0.324
CV
0.313
CV Mean
0.448
Mean
China
0.219
0.640
0.204
0.774
0.300
0.680
1.059
0.206
0.157
0.865
0.099
0.770
0.356
0.554
U.S.A
0.495
0.301
1.068
0.283
0.720
0.319
1.423
0.053
0.093
0.872
0.456
0.352
0.743
0.249
India
Table 7.35 Statistical analysis of sub-index of external contact of representative countries
0.224
0.566
0.108
0.796
0.202
0.650
1.197
0.135
0.064
0.946
0.214
0.543
1.427
0.152
Japan
0.213
0.691
0.325
0.770
0.337
0.752
0.496
0.318
0.042
0.937
0.088
0.702
0.471
0.547
U.K.
0.246
0.524
0.496
0.724
0.254
0.629
0.760
0.154
0.116
0.860
0.254
0.343
0.523
0.315
South Africa
0.427
0.355
0.645
0.567
0.444
0.502
1.054
0.073
0.358
0.473
0.197
0.385
0.476
0.356
Brazil
0.207
0.672
0.124
0.868
0.166
0.815
0.537
0.188
0.302
0.806
0.264
0.622
0.230
0.661
Australia
368 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Country
Singapore
Japan
U.S.A.
U.K.
U.S.A.
France
China
Japan
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
Spain
Russian
Sweden
Republic of Korea
Germany
Germany
U.S.A.
Spain
China
Germany
City
Singapore
Tokyo
New York-Newark
London
San Francisco-Oakland
Paris
Hong Kong
Osaka
Los Angeles-Long Beach-Santa Ana
Chicago
Barcelona
Moscow
Stockholm
Seoul
Munich
Stuttgart
Boston
Madrid
Shenzhen
Frankfurt am Main
20
19
18
17
16
15
14
13
12
11
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
Sustainable competitiveness
42
24
324
18
83
19
213
17
272
118
84
122
224
98
192
8
20
29
183
1
Economic vitality
11
85
230
157
1
4
259
48
387
83
356
417
141
9
75
255
184
278
106
5
Environmental thoroughness
188
98
53
81
157
67
2
272
36
115
192
55
4
151
168
72
83
37
1
41
Social inclusion
92
33
29
8
69
18
7
24
20
50
10
13
11
22
6
5
4
2
1
14
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
158
56
12
26
67
34
27
52
16
8
10
14
103
31
1
48
3
2
19
18
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 369
Country
U.S.A.
Canada
China
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
Germany
Australia
Italy
China
U.S.A.
U.K.
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
Australia
Japan
U.K.
China
Italy
Canada
U.S.A.
City
Philadelphia
Toronto
Taipei
Houston
Miami
Berlin
Melbourne
Rome
Shanghai
Seattle
Manchester
Atlanta
San Jose
Cleveland
Sydney
Hiroshima
Birmingham
Beijing
Milan
Montreal
Dallas-Fort Worth
(continued)
41
40
39
38
37
36
35
34
33
32
31
30
29
28
27
26
25
24
23
22
21
Sustainable competitiveness
75
134
385
223
55
146
88
7
3
97
60
31
201
388
119
153
61
49
140
112
50
Economic vitality
115
162
137
716
139
90
126
112
198
47
108
295
458
114
34
17
256
272
68
190
49
Environmental thoroughness
144
56
74
50
255
26
291
467
110
334
186
123
47
100
302
21
223
176
5
44
231
Social inclusion
27
47
46
3
104
181
44
61
90
21
53
12
9
35
52
38
77
23
16
15
17
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
13
38
9
4
50
280
21
122
154
11
36
32
7
23
42
24
33
15
57
20
35
External contacts
370 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Country
Argentina
Austria
Israel
U.S.A.
Germany
Switzerland
Japan
Japan
U.S.A.
Denmark
Germany
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
Australia
U.S.A.
Republic of Korea
China
U.S.A.
Malaysia
Canada
City
Buenos Aires
Vienna
Tel Aviv-Yafo
Denver-Aurora
Hamburg
Zurich
Nagoya
Kitakyushu-Fukuoka
Baltimore
Copenhagen
Hannover
Salt Lake City
San Diego
Perth
Washington, D.C.
Incheon
Suzhou
Raleigh
Kuala Lumpur
Vancouver
(continued)
61
60
59
58
57
56
55
54
53
52
51
50
49
48
47
46
45
44
43
42
Sustainable competitiveness
92
96
16
99
179
113
26
53
10
79
72
13
52
128
45
116
41
123
57
617
Economic vitality
73
171
148
532
279
432
133
238
134
3
24
19
102
225
14
43
146
29
2
405
Environmental thoroughness
69
175
196
23
35
158
442
80
204
236
122
358
7
12
107
78
139
367
32
65
Social inclusion
28
97
75
148
165
39
169
26
67
116
42
36
149
62
40
51
159
260
45
72
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
51
66
168
182
453
17
283
108
153
86
41
30
313
183
45
43
47
102
37
91
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 371
Country
Netherlands
Kazakhstan
Switzerland
Belgium
U.S.A.
China
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
U.K.
Germany
Finland
Republic of Korea
Turkey
Republic of Korea
U.S.A.
Spain
Israel
U.S.A.
Brazil
U.S.A.
City
Amsterdam
Astana
Geneva
Brussels
Detroit
Guangzhou
Austin
Orlando
West Yorkshire
Cologne
Helsinki
Daejeon
Istanbul
Ulsan
Richmond
Valencia
Jerusalem
Columbus
Sao Paulo
Bridgeport-Stamford
(continued)
81
80
79
78
77
76
75
74
73
72
71
70
69
68
67
66
65
64
63
62
Sustainable competitiveness
2
527
63
163
293
12
62
281
178
82
85
102
37
68
138
71
149
5
291
95
Economic vitality
25
252
109
104
200
72
31
505
282
211
69
81
60
323
293
80
66
7
159
40
Environmental thoroughness
195
824
279
425
147
390
93
38
19
58
135
75
339
134
57
632
97
322
225
61
Social inclusion
269
59
70
135
208
100
225
57
95
41
151
111
126
19
37
60
63
87
426
34
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
360
124
107
145
69
136
363
6
284
53
105
423
63
59
40
79
22
64
782
5
External contacts
372 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Country
U.S.A.
China
Qatar
Israel
Mexico
Belgium
U.S.A.
Saudi Arabia
Japan
Republic of Korea
Republic of Korea
Italy
China
U.S.A.
U.K.
Australia
United Arab Emirates
Republic of Korea
City
Phoenix-Mesa
Nanjing
Doha
Haifa
Mexico City
Antwerp
Hartford
Riyadh
Sapporo
Gwangju
Busan
Naples
Xiamen
Milwaukee
Glasgow
Adelaide
Dubai
Daegu
(continued)
99
98
97
96
95
94
93
92
91
90
89
88
87
86
85
84
83
82
Sustainable competitiveness
225
23
94
111
15
139
595
177
181
174
286
9
131
436
130
304
136
145
Economic vitality
124
865
125
101
51
303
95
87
41
76
1000
33
55
512
27
610
510
805
Environmental thoroughness
34
33
218
131
407
140
203
11
86
8
18
556
130
113
389
88
29
265
Social inclusion
139
230
125
89
137
121
108
146
182
166
102
223
207
78
133
238
43
177
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
263
25
148
94
176
117
72
203
386
330
128
240
162
99
187
81
55
76
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 373
Country
Chile
Spain
Greece
China
Germany
U.S.A.
South Africa
Germany
China
China
China
Australia
New Zealand
Germany
Russian
U.S.A.
Canada
U.S.A.
Colombia
Costa Rica
Saudi Arabia
City
Santiago de Chile
Malaga
Athens
Wuxi
Dortmund
Louisville
Pretoria
Essen
Tianjin
Foshan
Taichung
Brisbane
Auckland
Dresden
Saint Petersburg
Virginia Beach
Calgary
Las Vegas
Bogota
San Jose
Medina
(continued)
120
119
118
117
116
115
114
113
112
111
110
109
108
107
106
105
104
103
102
101
100
Sustainable competitiveness
195
263
321
135
33
51
473
147
43
125
203
158
155
106
159
22
54
172
360
331
249
Economic vitality
973
292
832
350
297
45
689
23
214
136
314
239
549
21
653
54
63
373
189
178
678
Environmental thoroughness
76
283
243
235
52
396
77
101
66
357
15
126
59
170
544
344
287
24
370
116
198
Social inclusion
391
306
124
221
64
387
170
134
48
84
205
271
88
224
203
144
187
246
66
289
129
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
476
253
88
111
129
340
120
174
74
96
265
338
87
68
235
225
151
279
44
146
241
External contacts
374 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Country
China
China
Peru
China
Germany
U.S.A.
U.K.
Saudi Arabia
U.S.A.
China
France
U.S.A.
Germany
Ireland
Canada
Netherlands
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
Belgium
Spain
Italy
City
Dongguan
Wuhan
Lima
Kaohsiung
Dusseldorf
Tampa-St. Petersburg
Belfast
Jedda
Worcester
Hangzhou
Lyon
New Haven
Leipzig
Dublin
Hamilton
Hague
Buffalo
Charlotte
Liege
Zaragoza
Torino
(continued)
141
140
139
138
137
136
135
134
133
132
131
130
129
128
127
126
125
124
123
122
121
Sustainable competitiveness
575
268
202
48
78
89
21
6
144
46
216
230
56
253
65
115
32
186
392
226
101
Economic vitality
175
210
150
339
375
74
96
64
37
116
135
551
111
500
26
71
8
244
651
904
249
Environmental thoroughness
119
160
326
249
427
85
229
62
143
714
269
40
768
54
152
508
165
13
247
28
137
Social inclusion
82
229
302
142
243
210
143
31
167
79
154
25
213
708
152
199
172
193
155
32
257
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
289
248
227
39
179
214
170
29
164
198
49
78
370
355
169
121
77
230
160
113
181
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 375
Country
U.S.A.
China
China
U.S.A.
China
Brazil
U.S.A.
China
U.S.A.
Japan
Portugal
Norway
China
France
U.K.
U.S.A.
China
China
Jordan
Italy
Saudi Arabia
City
Colorado Springs
Chengdu
Qingdao
Nashville-Davidson
Macao
Rio de Janeiro
San Antonio
Zhongshan
Minneapolis-Saint Paul
Sendai
Lisbon
Oslo
Ningbo
Lille
Liverpool
Provo-Orem
Changzhou
Zhengzhou
Amman
Venice
Dammam
(continued)
162
161
160
159
158
157
156
155
154
153
152
151
150
149
148
147
146
145
144
143
142
Sustainable competitiveness
356
353
652
271
234
28
86
212
214
4
90
167
81
133
151
581
11
27
218
193
35
Economic vitality
998
155
880
453
327
160
110
28
447
32
13
179
84
245
88
557
91
50
444
521
232
Environmental thoroughness
202
124
125
90
172
816
141
435
84
132
89
27
185
48
187
258
649
264
43
49
193
Social inclusion
572
285
251
145
278
593
180
228
204
54
106
130
101
282
114
76
344
258
99
65
259
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
427
232
217
192
366
368
84
147
200
60
62
349
112
229
133
233
215
109
166
89
341
External contacts
376 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Country
Netherlands
China
China
U.K.
Iran
Puerto Rico
U.S.A.
Japan
Italy
South Africa
U.S.A.
Thailand
U.S.A.
Australia
Canada
Italy
Mexico
Bulgaria
U.S.A.
China
City
Rotterdam
Tainan
Changsha
Leicester
Tehran
San Juan
Providence
Shizuoka-Hamamatsu M.M.A.
Verona
Johannesburg
Baton Rouge
Bangkok
New Orleans
Gold Coast
Ottawa-Gatineau
Bologna
Leon
Sofia
Indianapolis
Shenyang
(continued)
182
181
180
179
178
177
176
175
174
173
172
171
170
169
168
167
166
165
164
163
Sustainable competitiveness
476
77
565
346
424
69
25
105
298
14
264
395
173
76
573
596
100
198
205
91
Economic vitality
485
145
400
522
161
86
97
347
543
16
316
92
215
61
6
929
58
468
284
70
Environmental thoroughness
42
240
156
403
181
369
594
452
20
456
575
103
6
461
684
399
292
68
9
94
Social inclusion
140
136
163
290
85
93
329
220
81
156
127
176
164
103
216
150
188
138
162
171
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
167
180
80
286
46
93
358
173
28
238
141
177
390
201
252
310
119
157
323
98
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 377
U.S.A.
Italy
U.S.A.
Hungary
Uruguay
China
U.S.A.
Venezuela
U.S.A.
China
Belarus
Portugal
Saudi Arabia
China
Iran
China
France
Thailand
Venezuela
Czech Republic 203
Ogden
Florence
Kansas City
Budapest
Montevideo
Zhuhai
Honolulu
Barcelona-Puerto La Cruz
Oklahoma City
Dalian
Minsk
Porto
Mecca
Xi’an
Ahvaz
Hefei
Marseille-Aix-en-Provence
Samut Prakan
Valencia
Prague
202
201
200
199
198
197
196
195
194
193
192
191
190
189
188
187
186
185
184
183
U.S.A.
Pittsburgh
Sustainable competitiveness
Country
City
(continued)
267
964
284
227
156
330
261
219
366
426
364
66
944
47
80
401
171
73
450
74
103
Economic vitality
123
363
182
143
631
996
576
957
65
319
467
77
370
144
291
118
131
12
120
209
142
Environmental thoroughness
3
975
159
790
102
783
39
70
238
104
31
277
996
245
162
297
22
211
120
384
233
Social inclusion
73
215
891
173
86
584
56
477
112
206
115
226
315
227
372
256
83
141
160
446
30
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
58
401
508
73
135
893
165
830
82
186
139
210
333
569
308
246
65
175
178
657
101
External contacts
378 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Country
France
U.S.A.
China
U.S.A.
Japan
Malaysia
Italy
Venezuela
Romania
Brazil
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
Dominican Republic
China
U.S.A.
U.K.
South Africa
Iran
China
U.S.A.
City
Toulouse
Charleston-North Charleston
jinan
Cape Coral
Niigata
Johor Bahru
Catania
Caracas
Bucuresti
Brasilia
Columbia
Riverside-San Bernardino
Santo Domingo
Zhenjiang
Memphis
Bristol
Cape Town
Karaj
Jiaxing
Rochester
(continued)
223
222
221
220
219
218
217
216
215
214
213
212
211
210
209
208
207
206
205
204
Sustainable competitiveness
107
251
344
274
30
104
148
790
175
58
488
244
963
576
250
188
70
379
34
245
Economic vitality
57
369
812
317
62
52
361
237
857
208
98
117
243
218
99
174
22
703
180
105
Environmental thoroughness
266
92
796
304
222
454
224
432
315
325
342
17
846
257
318
10
755
161
666
311
Social inclusion
236
346
528
120
74
174
300
366
537
49
252
214
276
268
336
250
888
96
309
194
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
140
264
833
213
70
218
314
487
306
115
417
104
260
126
393
376
861
212
205
131
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 379
Country
United Arab Emirates
Turkey
Argentina
Argentina
Brazil
U.S.A.
Angola
Indonesia
Kuwait
China
U.S.A.
Italy
United Arab Emirates
Turkey
China
Turkey
Brazil
Sweden
Poland
Panama
City
Abu Dhabi
Ankara
Mendoza
Rosario
Greater Vitória
Dayton
Luanda
Jakarta
Kuwait City
Nantong
Cincinnati
Genoa
Sharjah
Bursa
Nanchang
Izmir
Porto Alegre
Gothenburg
Poznan
Panama City
(continued)
243
242
241
240
239
238
237
236
235
234
233
232
231
230
229
228
227
226
225
224
Sustainable competitiveness
452
243
141
416
262
184
320
114
459
93
185
655
512
903
44
433
467
551
464
39
Economic vitality
385
107
10
488
434
492
431
961
158
36
386
748
795
357
38
119
130
861
473
872
Environmental thoroughness
212
79
228
535
64
274
108
155
270
284
169
142
105
861
656
915
481
356
82
30
Social inclusion
295
209
113
242
284
168
378
425
248
55
280
599
186
602
217
716
404
454
118
281
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
114
257
191
239
195
261
299
402
142
161
381
116
71
776
328
946
276
420
100
125
External contacts
380 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Country
Italy
Oman
China
U.K.
Mexico
U.K.
Japan
China
Mexico
China
U.K.
U.S.A.
Canada
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
Cuba
Venezuela
U.S.A.
India
China
City
Bari
Muscat
Fuzhou(FJ)
Nottingham
Tijuana
Newcastle upon Tyne
Kumamoto
Zibo
Juarez
Yantai
Sheffield
Akron
Quebec
Grand Rapids
Knoxville
Havana
Maracaibo
Birmingham
Delhi
Yangzhou
(continued)
263
262
261
260
259
258
257
256
255
254
253
252
251
250
249
248
247
246
245
244
Sustainable competitiveness
229
255
59
956
362
64
67
132
36
110
176
422
204
189
157
368
109
246
297
397
Economic vitality
440
855
46
353
181
20
122
93
35
149
438
443
509
491
309
329
79
424
183
147
Environmental thoroughness
128
127
509
952
592
359
338
163
626
232
145
566
184
14
316
414
189
138
71
267
Social inclusion
325
123
219
766
480
128
270
122
264
161
314
476
320
265
189
470
105
239
362
255
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
351
75
281
604
591
224
302
236
359
61
311
510
413
403
545
441
155
242
292
130
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 381
Country
Republic of Korea
Canada
China
Venezuela
China
Mexico
China
Colombia
China
Iraq
Indonesia
Spain
Dominican Republic
Canada
China
Argentina
China
U.S.A.
Italy
China
City
Changwon
Edmonton
Shaoxing
Maracay
Quanzhou
Monterrey
Changchun
Medellin
Taiyuan
Erbil
Surabaya
Seville
Santiago de Los Caballeros
Winnipeg
Xuzhou
Cordoba
Urumqi
Portland
Palermo
Tangshan
(continued)
283
282
281
280
279
278
277
276
275
274
273
272
271
270
269
268
267
266
265
264
Sustainable competitiveness
211
738
127
499
623
279
126
517
606
444
763
164
381
513
315
182
947
288
121
143
Economic vitality
563
286
78
669
212
470
100
380
229
498
917
528
201
881
187
381
368
449
82
202
Environmental thoroughness
252
208
114
458
199
307
129
700
153
117
500
273
327
99
194
173
961
216
60
106
Social inclusion
352
244
91
299
349
263
158
545
201
335
710
245
231
117
279
374
796
423
71
316
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
322
150
97
448
268
343
243
362
197
407
348
228
267
220
255
301
583
275
144
439
External contacts
382 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Country
China
China
Iraq
China
France
China
Turkey
Poland
Mexico
Brazil
China
Paraguay
France
Italy
U.S.A.
Poland
Ecuador
China
Turkey
Nigeria
Israel
City
Chongqing
Taizhou(JS)
Baghdad
Huizhou
Nantes
Weihai
Gebze
Krakow
Guadalajara
Campinas
Wenzhou
Asuncion
Nice
Padova
Allentown
Warsaw
Quito
Shijiazhuang
Adana
Lagos
Be’er Sheva
(continued)
304
303
302
301
300
299
298
297
296
295
294
293
292
291
290
289
288
287
286
285
284
Sustainable competitiveness
162
892
405
335
636
328
38
547
217
618
524
469
396
345
180
241
231
194
886
154
470
Economic vitality
360
310
559
727
574
154
18
53
262
127
446
205
302
170
448
454
129
320
635
408
836
Environmental thoroughness
690
728
299
217
352
16
761
230
261
397
301
462
308
63
807
280
392
215
782
256
87
Social inclusion
748
283
382
211
274
58
399
107
273
568
292
192
310
153
469
400
233
348
393
450
94
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
317
204
543
196
226
83
494
138
85
551
277
300
202
132
761
400
137
498
307
361
134
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 383
Country
U.S.A.
Greece
Mexico
China
China
Russian
Chile
Azerbaijan
China
U.S.A.
South Africa
Algeria
China
Kazakhstan
India
U.S.A.
Malaysia
China
Algeria
China
Russian
City
Sacramento
Thessaloniki
San Luis Potosi
Dongying
Hsinchu
Tyumen
Valparaiso
Baku
Guiyang
El Paso
Durban
Algiers
Taizhou(ZJ)
Almaty
Bangalore
Bakersfield
Ipoh
Weifang
Oran
Kunming
Ufa
(continued)
325
324
323
322
321
320
319
318
317
316
315
314
313
312
311
310
309
308
307
306
305
Sustainable competitiveness
519
361
711
458
108
137
296
406
314
906
310
165
228
348
258
257
117
221
312
736
161
Economic vitality
342
407
289
658
217
367
222
934
480
44
172
325
389
280
442
758
224
450
263
15
94
Environmental thoroughness
375
112
726
241
498
534
96
281
282
804
722
207
436
121
729
310
25
298
378
331
221
Social inclusion
373
202
570
308
671
443
110
319
421
390
313
328
272
293
377
402
98
574
321
232
222
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
426
199
327
473
437
559
90
627
256
254
251
464
237
316
325
824
118
723
249
184
194
External contacts
384 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Country
Brazil
Bolivia
China
Mexico
U.S.A.
China
China
Poland
Brazil
Brazil
Serbia
Colombia
Russian
China
Mexico
China
France
Croatia
China
China
Argentina
City
Ribeirao Preto
Santa Cruz
Haikou
Merida
Omaha
Nanning
Jinhua
Lodz
Sao Jose dos Campos
Belo Horizonte
Belgrade
Cali
Samara
Harbin
Queretaro
Shantou
Bordeaux
Zagreb
Jiaozuo
Hohhot
Santa Fe
(continued)
346
345
344
343
342
341
340
339
338
337
336
335
334
333
332
331
330
329
328
327
326
Sustainable competitiveness
497
265
336
340
233
248
384
548
569
357
383
674
333
299
313
495
87
350
316
731
378
Economic vitality
383
531
441
30
39
270
165
982
572
336
193
268
231
390
344
644
59
207
445
1003
226
Environmental thoroughness
182
248
507
45
271
386
201
174
167
395
91
475
46
150
268
148
246
177
364
580
885
Social inclusion
341
343
546
147
237
380
481
132
340
342
183
253
414
266
354
241
198
416
331
109
644
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
309
354
607
143
127
380
262
189
661
290
149
397
588
295
431
244
258
347
288
270
415
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 385
Country
France
Mexico
China
Guatemala
Nigeria
China
China
China
Lebanon
China
India
China
Indonesia
China
Mexico
China
Ukraine
Indonesia
U.S.A.
Mexico
China
City
Toulon
Aguascalientes
Zhoushan
Guatemala City
Ikorodu
Taian
Huzhou
Langfang
Beirut
Luoyang
Mumbai
Yancheng
Batam
Lanzhou
Torreon
Xiangtan
Kiev
Samarinda
Sarasota-Bradenton
Puebla
Zaozhuang
(continued)
367
366
365
364
363
362
361
360
359
358
357
356
355
354
353
352
351
350
349
348
347
Sustainable competitiveness
498
683
129
240
791
309
349
292
374
371
332
554
754
222
200
386
808
863
169
427
208
Economic vitality
394
343
67
290
349
423
611
786
341
597
789
663
191
465
321
616
429
667
234
264
227
Environmental thoroughness
449
253
149
572
219
438
343
381
443
286
227
242
394
366
285
361
958
324
540
234
474
Social inclusion
683
296
364
775
184
355
857
185
912
411
80
317
247
498
398
471
993
407
500
581
493
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
526
216
382
878
172
247
647
297
790
399
54
304
188
223
416
616
710
484
450
388
320
External contacts
386 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Country
U.S.A.
U.S.A.
China
U.S.A.
Tunisia
China
China
Brazil
China
Colombia
Brazil
U.S.A.
Philippines
Mexico
Brazil
El Salvador
Mexico
China
China
Indonesia
Turkey
City
Tucson
McAllen
Zhuzhou
Tulsa
Tunis
Wuhu
Jining
Manaus
Yinchuan
Cartagena
Recife
Fresno
Manila
Villahermosa
Curitiba
San Salvador
Matamoros
Xuchang
Daqing
Pekanbaru
Gaziantep
(continued)
388
387
386
385
384
383
382
381
380
379
378
377
376
375
374
373
372
371
370
369
368
Sustainable competitiveness
631
277
160
238
307
492
642
282
510
168
645
372
306
714
447
170
583
124
393
210
196
Economic vitality
760
745
901
452
430
299
138
307
743
240
418
275
680
959
628
396
257
56
556
199
529
Environmental thoroughness
250
571
385
573
650
574
372
423
95
480
595
537
587
695
329
303
387
368
421
810
214
Social inclusion
420
631
460
542
923
449
307
738
262
339
298
474
322
327
403
358
218
254
337
788
68
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
452
807
558
504
911
472
335
729
106
332
547
274
378
590
375
324
234
222
374
357
190
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 387
Country
Russian
China
Brazil
China
Iran
Brazil
Libya
Russian
China
China
China
China
China
China
Nigeria
Mexico
Germany
China
Kenya
China
China
City
Kazan
Huaian
Jundiai
Baotou
Shiraz
Fortaleza
Tripoli
Perm
Zhangzhou
Yichang
Liaocheng
Lianyungang
Ordoss
Anshan
Abuja
Toluca
Bremen
Jiangmen
Nairobi
Dezhou
Putian
(continued)
409
408
407
406
405
404
403
402
401
400
399
398
397
396
395
394
393
392
391
390
389
Sustainable competitiveness
259
563
283
377
206
504
889
577
317
237
474
252
319
572
807
780
713
287
242
359
750
Economic vitality
382
755
856
365
42
251
788
493
741
594
609
701
481
599
89
333
930
864
132
539
843
Environmental thoroughness
553
419
724
312
146
453
873
376
398
354
582
251
319
406
597
642
671
306
539
263
183
Social inclusion
684
559
197
502
178
350
497
408
914
397
507
412
475
365
473
323
441
447
801
516
261
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
500
553
345
428
185
862
312
537
315
536
466
389
470
404
497
614
815
585
792
319
465
External contacts
388 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Country
China
China
China
China
Turkey
Mexico
China
China
China
China
Ecuador
China
Argentina
Brazil
China
Brazil
China
Indonesia
Brazil
Russian
Iraq
City
Jilin
Handan
Xianyang
Cangzhou
Antalya
Saltillo
Rizhao
Xiangyang
Yueyang
Ezhou
Guayaquil
Panjin
Mar Del Plata
Sorocaba
Binzhou
Salvador
Linyi
Bandung
Belem
Saratov
Kirkuk
(continued)
430
429
428
427
426
425
424
423
422
421
420
419
418
417
416
415
414
413
412
411
410
Sustainable competitiveness
910
651
727
653
660
819
500
438
611
400
801
142
478
266
273
390
352
338
285
671
403
Economic vitality
825
724
242
524
763
194
573
266
167
235
326
328
613
725
404
719
807
632
598
655
922
Environmental thoroughness
802
382
715
191
405
633
486
578
603
430
490
676
408
349
472
377
51
422
402
416
164
Social inclusion
910
369
510
330
486
311
540
557
455
767
375
856
538
536
729
472
405
624
633
386
179
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
818
918
663
337
344
430
479
728
811
481
336
492
592
617
562
725
326
572
408
471
419
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 389
Country
China
China
Mexico
Brazil
U.S.A.
China
Iran
South Africa
China
Saudi Arabia
Indonesia
China
Bangladesh
China
Mexico
Peru
China
Bolivia
China
China
Iran
City
Nanyang
Xinxiang
Hermosillo
Goiania
Albuquerque
Anyang
Mashhad
Port Elizabeth
Maoming
Buraydah
Balikpapan
Kaifeng
Dhaka
Zhanjiang
Culiacan
Arequipa
Deyang
Cochabamba
Beihai
Xining
Tabriz
(continued)
451
450
449
448
447
446
445
444
443
442
441
440
439
438
437
436
435
434
433
432
431
Sustainable competitiveness
737
347
260
678
295
209
442
355
926
456
199
232
318
280
845
429
166
716
419
334
703
Economic vitality
808
661
308
828
511
995
351
371
947
657
694
925
463
472
907
571
219
196
752
639
768
Environmental thoroughness
551
568
801
865
483
601
466
309
546
465
374
133
401
786
736
697
380
562
345
492
410
Social inclusion
422
435
707
790
640
726
679
515
234
438
881
800
675
448
429
353
304
535
417
389
332
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
902
598
499
835
747
595
456
392
207
371
797
904
564
502
825
435
250
516
538
273
271
External contacts
390 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Country
China
India
China
Latvia
China
Malaysia
China
Iraq
China
Kazakhstan
China
China
Brazil
China
China
China
China
Mexico
Indonesia
China
China
City
Huangshi
Chennai
Jieyang
Riga
Changde
Kuching
Hengyang
Sulaymaniyah
Suqian
Shymkent
Liuzhou
Yingtan
Joinville
Ma’anshan
Xinyu
Zhaoqing
Qinhuangdao
Reynosa
Malang
Puyang
Jinzhou
(continued)
472
471
470
469
468
467
466
465
464
463
462
461
460
459
458
457
456
455
454
453
452
Sustainable competitiveness
686
483
514
477
278
308
239
236
439
190
294
735
303
854
493
150
608
410
235
370
152
Economic vitality
466
544
783
469
530
474
420
411
271
397
564
585
525
685
707
152
751
267
332
306
504
Environmental thoroughness
520
447
180
867
365
333
607
441
615
640
409
835
426
350
478
276
411
111
489
166
721
Social inclusion
437
778
556
873
345
514
691
465
357
889
532
886
670
803
482
490
456
190
818
119
575
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
398
716
733
342
445
523
638
318
721
567
599
987
455
817
462
488
609
193
461
92
512
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 391
Country
Turkmenistan
Egypt
China
China
Mexico
India
Georgia
Indonesia
Ghana
China
China
China
China
Poland
Brazil
Brazil
Mexico
Russian
Nigeria
India
Peru
City
Ashgabat
Cairo
Luohe
Sanya
Cancun
Kochi
Tbilisi
Palembang
Accra
Baoding
Chaozhou
Pingdingshan
Guilin
Wroclaw
Grande Sao Luis
Uberlandia
Pachuca de Soto
Yaroslavl
Port Harcourt
Pune
Trujillo
(continued)
493
492
491
490
489
488
487
486
485
484
483
482
481
480
479
478
477
476
475
474
473
Sustainable competitiveness
460
441
839
546
533
526
676
431
521
564
329
729
557
461
269
256
337
197
394
799
455
Economic vitality
717
671
579
173
188
428
277
168
732
422
337
791
197
315
439
261
652
374
414
793
273
Environmental thoroughness
673
210
883
320
515
739
767
73
313
433
586
323
884
707
154
244
213
552
789
288
785
Social inclusion
672
191
763
451
562
511
794
200
359
547
669
318
301
643
294
277
954
700
830
175
919
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
391
95
580
718
715
703
964
209
305
582
446
449
321
683
221
396
331
519
434
123
772
External contacts
392 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Country
China
Russian
Russian
China
China
India
China
China
Russian
China
China
Colombia
Colombia
Honduras
Indonesia
China
China
China
China
Mexico
Brazil
City
Bengbu
Tomsk
Novosibirsk
Jiujiang
Yulin(SX)
Coimbatore
Baoji
Hebi
Barnaul
Heze
Pingxiang
Pereira
Barranquilla
Tegucigalpa
Makassar
Chenzhou
Ziyang
Yangjiang
Zigong
Chihuahua
Londrina
(continued)
514
513
512
511
510
509
508
507
506
505
504
503
502
501
500
499
498
497
496
495
494
Sustainable competitiveness
555
486
409
365
587
322
463
624
632
454
247
692
640
389
300
289
207
435
835
599
423
Economic vitality
345
744
708
399
656
570
359
364
506
269
568
676
304
456
690
455
527
620
988
955
552
Environmental thoroughness
679
340
675
482
770
661
305
645
637
764
600
685
412
735
434
400
469
363
278
388
491
Social inclusion
428
525
569
858
817
727
494
505
445
467
828
603
522
799
596
288
809
567
196
297
534
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
560
557
637
412
534
496
620
597
377
880
770
660
973
463
742
750
571
518
490
968
495
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 393
Country
China
China
China
Indonesia
Egypt
Morocco
China
Indonesia
China
China
China
China
Argentina
China
Turkey
China
China
China
China
China
Indonesia
City
Liaoyang
Shangrao
Panzhihua
Padang
Alexandria
Casablanca
Huaibei
Bogor
Luzhou
Benxi
Fushun
Ganzhou
La Plata
Ningde
Samsun
Longyan
Mianyang
Yuxi
Anqing
Siping
Medan
(continued)
535
534
533
532
531
530
529
528
527
526
525
524
523
522
521
520
519
518
517
516
515
Sustainable competitiveness
677
847
829
376
590
529
380
387
813
668
421
679
490
743
375
545
793
479
373
699
449
Economic vitality
416
496
554
526
730
561
490
660
151
769
569
412
790
638
471
128
479
548
281
567
372
Environmental thoroughness
330
691
446
517
360
543
190
524
588
493
506
477
591
220
542
533
428
314
678
604
579
Social inclusion
419
523
610
664
360
654
573
544
361
487
464
663
561
430
583
275
195
560
699
734
807
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
411
524
535
485
440
690
563
365
544
505
478
561
635
373
578
159
206
795
820
552
421
External contacts
394 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Country
Brazil
China
China
Pakistan
China
Mexico
China
Russian
China
China
China
China
China
Brazil
China
Angola
China
China
China
Brazil
China
City
Joao Pessoa
Zunyi
Songyuan
Karachi
Loudi
Mexicali
Yichun(JX)
Tolyatti
Shangqiu
Xiaogan
Jingdezhen
Jingmen
Quzhou
Teresina
Sanmenxia
Huambo
Zhoukou
Liupanshui
Xingtai
Juiz De Fora
Jincheng
(continued)
556
555
554
553
552
551
550
549
548
547
546
545
544
543
542
541
540
539
538
537
536
Sustainable competitiveness
531
633
766
369
708
977
411
733
432
425
391
650
786
598
712
597
367
858
562
453
719
Economic vitality
566
260
784
503
546
936
623
384
497
728
523
944
608
203
691
993
590
520
750
746
246
Environmental thoroughness
644
746
503
855
530
950
672
854
545
518
641
692
669
391
445
531
569
413
598
547
800
Social inclusion
667
439
609
947
744
987
909
687
594
686
632
709
841
618
808
774
722
291
811
512
665
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
676
865
615
602
612
857
640
1000
568
641
418
570
671
685
540
298
579
171
642
528
994
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 395
Country
India
China
China
Libya
Russian
Nigeria
India
China
Russian
China
China
China
China
Russian
China
China
Jamaica
China
China
U.S.A.
China
City
Bhiwandi
Qinzhou
Sanming
Misratah
Krasnodar
Kano
Kozhikode
Hengshui
Astrakhan’
Jingzhou
Yiyang
Zhumadian
Yulin(GX)
Irkutsk
Wuzhou
Shiyan
Kingston
Tongling
Yibin
Albany
Mudanjiang
(continued)
577
576
575
574
573
572
571
570
569
568
567
566
565
564
563
562
561
560
559
558
557
Sustainable competitiveness
794
120
446
40
399
468
552
669
666
525
404
619
777
664
276
900
661
935
402
440
323
Economic vitality
641
331
867
348
221
595
662
989
712
575
711
798
875
753
346
870
849
819
537
602
415
Environmental thoroughness
590
557
702
457
701
532
513
630
732
611
570
444
317
760
620
928
136
906
510
612
974
Social inclusion
645
212
648
518
131
434
757
379
656
835
668
488
621
724
636
548
367
1002
703
571
998
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
677
156
789
458
163
491
700
785
632
717
680
486
908
506
764
601
432
866
514
629
698
External contacts
396 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Country
India
China
Cameroon
Turkey
Brazil
China
China
China
China
India
Russian
Bangladesh
Cambodia
China
Bolivia
China
China
Cote d’ivoire
China
China
India
City
Kolkata
Weinan
Douala
Sanliurfa
Campo Grande
Xianning
Huainan
Changzhi
Xinyang
Kannur
Ryazan
Chittagong
Phnom Penh
Meishan
La Paz
Karamay
Shuozhou
Abidjan
Leshan
Suining
Dehra Dun
(continued)
598
597
596
595
594
593
592
591
590
589
588
587
586
585
584
583
582
581
580
579
578
Sustainable competitiveness
270
734
491
765
187
191
848
644
578
945
658
301
620
343
418
351
726
752
904
739
607
Economic vitality
413
545
852
355
311
674
984
670
820
772
683
378
718
486
553
962
781
967
392
534
902
Environmental thoroughness
464
559
495
938
737
705
567
693
448
845
328
815
564
521
561
617
619
459
945
653
289
Social inclusion
746
694
787
521
930
743
392
682
468
623
508
823
458
549
520
529
513
782
635
777
235
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
822
744
649
379
613
888
438
531
352
515
957
732
668
689
387
530
659
843
475
353
110
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 397
Country
Argentina
China
Mongolia
China
Russian
China
Venezuela
Brazil
China
Nigeria
Indonesia
Bangladesh
China
Mexico
Philippines
China
India
China
Saudi Arabia
Honduras
China
City
San Miguel de Tucuman
Chuzhou
Ulan Bator
Nanchong
Kemerovo
Qingyuan
Maturín
Feira De Santana
Datong
Zaria
Semarang
Rajshahi
Fangchenggang
Morelia
Cebu
Shanwei
Hyderabad
Guangan
Ta’if
San Pedro Sula
Lishui
(continued)
619
618
617
616
615
614
613
612
611
610
609
608
607
606
605
604
603
602
601
600
599
Sustainable competitiveness
434
612
358
516
549
305
682
630
327
917
445
830
496
675
985
567
662
591
649
520
742
Economic vitality
645
276
840
607
340
362
502
258
398
726
659
759
722
216
377
516
906
734
903
709
140
Environmental thoroughness
522
830
178
725
118
751
239
371
759
870
205
953
699
806
990
259
417
415
609
647
636
Social inclusion
503
896
905
926
157
872
586
466
929
661
527
626
565
732
992
598
501
530
820
677
649
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
459
346
769
621
152
503
350
329
521
914
424
821
611
995
809
245
989
593
673
395
854
External contacts
398 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Country
China
China
China
Mexico
Brazil
Russian
China
China
China
China
Sudan
China
Pakistan
China
China
Russian
Venezuela
State of Palestine
India
China
City
Yangquan
Yingkou
Nanping
Tampico
Cuiaba
Chelyabinsk
Tonghua
Jinzhong
Zhangjiakou
Dandong
Khartoum
Qujing
Lahore
Shaoguan
Linfen
Orenburg
Barquisimeto
Gaza
Durg-Bhilai Nagar
Yan’an
(continued)
639
638
637
636
635
634
633
632
631
630
629
628
627
626
625
624
623
622
621
620
Sustainable competitiveness
290
448
341
994
697
817
588
809
382
961
722
559
412
725
857
684
667
789
505
215
Economic vitality
642
542
274
501
535
684
699
756
666
775
558
749
596
507
873
508
233
648
220
550
Environmental thoroughness
589
949
899
973
254
511
418
300
585
548
379
473
555
687
373
703
608
527
440
730
Social inclusion
620
755
761
908
555
798
637
305
771
384
712
582
614
837
356
730
768
563
739
911
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
566
891
749
724
988
694
394
266
594
874
467
619
653
670
779
847
832
554
269
482
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 399
Country
China
Iran
Mexico
China
Turkey
Russian
China
China
Haiti
China
Gabon
Iraq
China
China
South Africa
Morocco
India
Iran
Nicaragua
China
Uganda
City
Yuncheng
Hamadan
Celaya
Ji’an
Kayseri
Rostov-on-Don
Liaoyuan
Huanggang
Port-au-Prince
Suzhou (AH)
Libreville
Basra
Tongliao
Xuancheng
Vereeniging
Marrakech
Malappuram
Esfahan
Managua
Chengde
Kampala
(continued)
660
659
658
657
656
655
654
653
652
651
650
649
648
647
646
645
644
643
642
641
640
Sustainable competitiveness
489
462
864
890
326
511
414
616
609
920
988
646
990
580
407
821
691
539
544
745
553
Economic vitality
195
799
879
974
457
402
391
584
739
910
484
779
483
757
482
283
731
767
166
915
737
Environmental thoroughness
882
424
528
526
921
341
932
599
576
864
818
674
918
455
718
290
226
550
837
752
558
Social inclusion
410
566
580
478
878
492
940
765
825
797
920
741
863
650
942
436
395
855
689
676
655
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
451
422
444
855
871
293
773
414
565
845
581
454
285
517
384
541
589
691
735
886
684
External contacts
400 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Country
China
China
Mexico
Turkey
Libya
India
India
India
Indonesia
Turkey
Sri Lanka
Iran
China
China
Russian
China
China
China
China
China
Russian
City
Dazhou
Yunfu
Cuernavaca
Mersin
Benghazi
Ahmedabad
Kota
Guwahati
Tasikmalaya
Eskisehir
Colombo
Orumiyeh
Heyuan
Neijiang
Voronezh
Huludao
Luliang
Suihua
Hanzhong
Huaihua
Omsk
(continued)
681
680
679
678
677
676
675
674
673
672
671
670
669
668
667
666
665
664
663
662
661
Sustainable competitiveness
843
812
635
884
537
759
861
413
475
827
899
718
707
487
428
566
922
518
574
601
760
Economic vitality
970
845
773
935
517
475
640
577
665
618
338
894
614
884
990
723
619
713
204
519
591
Environmental thoroughness
347
720
614
734
618
716
295
662
762
712
383
209
741
748
625
171
880
351
596
485
750
Social inclusion
409
836
666
945
941
697
333
731
802
628
240
413
925
415
484
406
762
396
499
860
753
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
996
678
675
682
713
643
356
693
708
919
219
600
477
549
758
425
945
727
507
751
665
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 401
Country
India
China
Nigeria
China
India
Russian
Saudi Arabia
China
China
Nigeria
China
Mexico
China
Colombia
China
China
China
Viet Nam
Pakistan
Ukraine
Pakistan
City
Puducherry
Fuzhou(JX)
Benin City
Fuyang
Kollam
Krasnoyarsk
Hufuf-Mubarraz
Tieling
Chifeng
Enugu
Yongzhou
Veracruz
Meizhou
Ibague
Shizuishan
Guigang
Shaoyang
Haiphong
Islamabad
Krivoi Rog
Bahawalpur
(continued)
702
701
700
699
698
697
696
695
694
693
692
691
690
689
688
687
686
685
684
683
682
Sustainable competitiveness
823
850
865
542
681
787
254
538
592
508
723
875
776
841
311
773
275
853
779
756
339
Economic vitality
874
582
742
241
869
625
499
330
565
634
824
977
809
514
854
945
636
617
892
782
305
Environmental thoroughness
778
638
336
681
659
811
828
754
512
494
664
934
639
765
262
337
713
581
935
631
660
Social inclusion
728
936
286
844
785
970
784
831
653
533
804
783
662
832
887
324
776
587
833
870
651
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
804
605
272
936
704
709
644
954
539
511
639
894
626
429
748
759
956
603
879
587
706
External contacts
402 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Country
China
Russian
China
China
China
China
Brazil
Mexico
China
India
Nigeria
Brazil
Iraq
Philippines
China
Egypt
China
Russian
Viet Nam
India
Morocco
City
Anshun
Novokuznetsk
Suizhou
Chongzuo
Chizhou
Bozhou
Maceio
Acapulco
Liuan
Thiruvananthapuram
Akure
Natal
Karbala
Davao
Jiamusi
Port Said
Baise
Yekaterinburg
Can Tho
Ludhiana
Meknes
(continued)
723
722
721
720
719
718
717
716
715
714
713
712
711
710
709
708
707
706
705
704
703
Sustainable competitiveness
482
466
485
880
602
615
781
695
915
871
856
363
894
605
844
772
437
540
430
758
614
Economic vitality
393
586
248
905
776
688
896
589
814
334
740
324
747
733
296
675
515
580
646
437
592
Environmental thoroughness
844
667
862
275
744
897
745
355
817
773
942
346
484
479
766
628
682
836
719
504
784
Social inclusion
629
617
805
444
895
795
698
884
838
312
754
440
931
871
742
900
875
839
918
611
745
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
907
856
844
577
586
863
739
734
903
892
852
787
480
745
846
622
522
574
532
826
714
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 403
Country
China
China
Peru
Nigeria
Viet Nam
Nigeria
China
Colombia
India
Zimbabwe
Russian
Mexico
China
India
Nigeria
China
Iran
Tunisia
Indonesia
Viet Nam
Mexico
City
Qiqihar
Huangshan
Chiclayo
Jos
Da Nang
Aba
Fuxin
Cucuta
Mangalore
Harare
Nizhny Novgorod
Oaxaca
Ankang
Salem
Ibadan
Baicheng
Rasht
Safaqis
Denpasar
Ho Chi Minh City
Tuxtla Gutierrez
(continued)
744
743
742
741
740
739
738
737
736
735
734
733
732
731
730
729
728
727
726
725
724
Sustainable competitiveness
751
824
626
715
833
586
918
535
836
680
840
826
354
639
907
870
528
893
698
522
837
Economic vitality
163
186
421
358
729
971
401
604
787
643
228
287
164
871
693
841
153
846
715
754
991
Environmental thoroughness
613
260
237
840
772
652
823
814
658
197
109
839
541
902
708
900
348
916
827
431
584
Social inclusion
824
267
789
705
613
814
554
287
821
576
303
541
553
892
589
696
693
692
956
588
496
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
877
211
838
801
993
679
372
231
707
771
687
555
870
848
730
837
469
697
760
339
654
External contacts
404 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Country
China
China
Brazil
China
Viet Nam
India
Chile
Kenya
India
China
Mexico
Iraq
India
Iran
Russian
China
China
India
Morocco
Congo
India
City
Laibin
Chaoyang
Aracaju
Baishan
Hanoi
Jodhpur
Concepcion
Mombasa
Nagpur
Xinzhou
Poza Rica
Nasiriyah
Surat
Qom
Izhevsk
Baoshan
Jiayuguan
Bhubaneswar
Rabat
Pointe-Noire
Thrissur
(continued)
765
764
763
762
761
760
759
758
757
756
755
754
753
752
751
750
749
748
747
746
745
Sustainable competitiveness
550
936
600
593
325
822
795
908
704
914
641
659
556
451
302
543
816
603
814
891
622
Economic vitality
494
478
121
850
555
603
536
958
601
908
785
562
965
253
206
983
192
897
250
647
581
Environmental thoroughness
362
984
439
468
797
769
393
710
538
925
853
763
519
907
523
501
200
404
727
698
829
Social inclusion
792
975
334
433
877
509
483
605
431
906
967
558
432
749
418
638
249
948
720
850
915
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
695
662
303
666
740
652
979
872
406
991
829
756
765
850
442
686
259
405
961
655
777
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 405
Country
Zambia
Turkey
Nepal
Cameroon
Nigeria
Ghana
Brazil
Colombia
Mexico
Zambia
Philippines
Togo
Nigeria
Russian
China
India
Senegal
India
China
Morocco
Tanzania
City
Lusaka
Diyarbakir
Kathmandu
Yaounde
Owerri
Kumasi
Florianopolis
Bucaramanga
Tlaxcala
Kitwe
Cagayan de Oro
Lome
Uyo
Khabarovsk
Shangluo
Asansol
Dakar
Visakhapatnam
Ya’an
Tangier
Dar es Salaam
(continued)
786
785
784
783
782
781
780
779
778
777
776
775
774
773
772
771
770
769
768
767
766
Sustainable competitiveness
934
503
571
536
811
481
796
700
802
690
515
494
705
532
746
902
764
987
862
706
849
Economic vitality
312
288
780
883
406
322
818
999
627
318
366
721
254
113
156
213
900
265
682
803
960
Environmental thoroughness
893
704
776
335
937
863
821
565
924
838
602
983
353
668
516
869
904
849
471
525
963
Social inclusion
394
772
681
595
401
885
816
615
848
723
962
951
601
491
368
750
864
718
600
706
517
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
474
849
468
881
606
958
460
722
934
457
754
628
966
364
369
869
922
527
410
806
443
External contacts
406 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Country
Turkey
China
China
India
India
India
China
China
Congo
Colombia
India
Venezuela
China
Colombia
Philippines
Bangladesh
China
Republic of Moldova
Mexico
India
City
Denizli
Zhangjiajie
Ulanqab
Aurangabad
Amritsar
Patna
Hezhou
Tianshui
Brazzaville
Villavicencio
Jalandhar
Ciudad Guayana
Hulunbuir
Santa Marta
General Santos City
Sylhet
Qingyang
Chisinau
Xalapa
Lucknow
(continued)
806
805
804
803
802
801
800
799
798
797
796
795
794
793
792
791
790
789
788
787
Sustainable competitiveness
757
530
579
408
949
523
720
480
997
502
398
951
701
828
628
560
694
770
769
484
Economic vitality
994
169
103
736
891
294
622
972
938
738
313
797
817
705
822
858
987
762
853
821
Environmental thoroughness
463
549
450
749
805
677
606
651
993
799
933
951
680
852
529
476
696
670
616
206
Social inclusion
371
564
463
619
717
972
652
939
989
690
903
876
592
725
577
695
453
958
917
479
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
433
938
367
762
778
805
860
596
436
975
766
720
803
752
631
951
905
618
542
901
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 407
Country
China
India
Ukraine
China
China
Iran
Nigeria
Bangladesh
Russian
Pakistan
India
India
Congo
China
Indonesia
Nigeria
India
Pakistan
Iran
China
Eritrea
City
Zhaotong
Jaipur
Kharkov
Jixi
Guangyuan
Kerman
Oshogbo
Khulna
Volgograd
Hyderabad
Erode
Tirupati
Kinshasa
WuZhong
Bandar Lampung
Warri
Jamshedpur
Faisalabad
Kermanshah
Shuangyashan
Asmara
(continued)
827
826
825
824
823
822
821
820
819
818
817
816
815
814
813
812
811
810
809
808
807
Sustainable competitiveness
1000
873
912
897
621
806
702
771
993
443
417
874
838
972
895
860
610
885
973
741
810
Economic vitality
461
895
924
654
714
583
489
801
946
697
668
887
837
839
593
949
765
560
706
695
804
Environmental thoroughness
896
775
771
723
898
981
321
868
976
605
833
877
294
876
927
563
648
753
502
293
826
Social inclusion
974
988
524
543
607
966
827
862
747
678
819
338
424
713
991
427
773
826
388
326
933
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
970
814
898
608
783
897
726
489
667
784
969
208
705
920
851
816
731
696
788
294
651
External contacts
408 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Country
India
Morocco
China
China
India
Mauritania
China
Pakistan
India
Saudi Arabia
India
Armenia
China
India
Pakistan
India
China
Philippines
Afghanistan
India
China
City
Mysore
Fes
Bazhong
Wuhai
Tiruchirappalli
Nouakchott
Bayannur
Sialkot
Kolhapur
Tabuk
Vellore
Yerevan
Lincang
Varanasi
Rawalpindi
Ranchi
Tongchuan
Bacolod
Kabul
Tiruppur
Baiyin
(continued)
848
847
846
845
844
843
842
841
840
839
838
837
836
835
834
833
832
831
830
829
828
Sustainable competitiveness
665
457
940
627
342
693
911
761
688
834
415
744
465
866
749
887
558
220
855
638
561
Economic vitality
898
513
978
876
540
842
868
859
673
433
451
851
588
650
878
810
621
477
792
403
301
Environmental thoroughness
643
859
941
683
891
792
794
536
875
420
832
470
627
879
717
908
665
780
694
842
621
Social inclusion
952
984
719
934
960
769
660
591
916
370
461
622
608
874
969
928
579
963
982
531
442
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
664
798
576
674
282
794
799
887
646
334
719
859
921
633
688
819
823
737
533
753
755
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 409
Country
India
India
Indonesia
Russian
Nigeria
Nigeria
India
China
India
India
India
India
China
Iraq
Indonesia
India
Russian
China
India
Iran
Mexico
City
Meerut
Gwalior
Jambi
Makhachkala
Onitsha
Ilorin
Siliguri
Hechi
Kurnool
Madurai
Rajkot
Bokaro Steel City
Qitaihe
Najaf
Banjarmasin
Nashik
Vladivostok
Zhongwei
Cuttack
Ardabil
Durango
(continued)
869
868
867
866
865
864
863
862
861
860
859
858
857
856
855
854
853
852
851
850
849
Sustainable competitiveness
788
883
728
589
797
657
818
932
798
568
582
507
501
896
570
923
928
905
724
656
643
Economic vitality
811
933
770
833
354
950
298
1004
388
704
686
547
981
778
587
860
863
672
912
866
916
Environmental thoroughness
429
706
819
858
497
437
686
943
892
957
655
743
757
711
788
923
946
505
583
756
881
Social inclusion
452
616
840
659
383
578
764
781
977
986
495
625
946
924
868
702
997
758
829
751
812
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
483
972
699
623
493
873
746
947
701
952
763
884
931
573
982
895
867
941
520
983
610
External contacts
410 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Country
India
India
China
India
China
Indonesia
Turkey
India
India
China
India
Nigeria
China
India
Pakistan
Uzbekistan
India
India
India
India
India
City
Jamnagar
Indore
Pu’er
Bhopal
Lijiang
Pontianak
Konya
Vadodara
Raurkela
Wuwei
Jammu
Sokoto
Pingliang
Cherthala
Peshawar
Tashkent
Dhanbad
Guntur
Aligarh
Allahabad
Vijayawada
(continued)
890
889
888
887
886
885
884
883
882
881
880
879
878
877
876
875
874
873
872
871
870
Sustainable competitiveness
637
815
768
629
753
931
909
472
748
954
709
721
509
762
710
792
506
783
767
778
471
Economic vitality
698
877
975
761
696
800
664
427
720
1005
605
914
838
679
862
710
777
626
615
649
624
Environmental thoroughness
560
740
813
803
808
624
809
940
774
965
488
738
956
296
179
742
610
514
822
747
577
Social inclusion
641
526
627
760
721
376
550
957
865
880
590
907
996
462
381
867
815
539
937
504
950
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
624
940
885
930
810
681
648
883
630
913
584
839
971
656
385
712
447
509
658
409
900
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 411
Country
China
India
Philippines
Russian
India
Nigeria
China
Lao
Ukraine
India
India
China
India
Pakistan
India
India
India
Ukraine
Tanzania
Congo
Syrian
City
Jinchang
Kanpur
Zamboanga
Ulyanovsk
Saharanpur
Kaduna
Zhangye
Vientiane
Dnipropetrovs’k
Muzaffarnagar
Srinagar
Hegang
Sangali
Quetta
Hubli-Dharwad
Chandigarh
Bareilly
Lvov
Zanzibar
Lubumbashi
Damascus
(continued)
911
910
909
908
907
906
905
904
903
902
901
900
899
898
897
896
895
894
893
892
891
Sustainable competitiveness
916
979
868
950
782
594
604
933
541
803
673
648
879
831
785
943
670
876
747
846
717
Economic vitality
435
766
538
606
943
426
352
921
436
913
630
885
379
969
847
997
931
285
612
976
834
Environmental thoroughness
988
980
992
499
890
332
622
820
866
787
872
895
635
688
733
913
920
487
634
731
793
Social inclusion
457
902
922
485
842
351
658
714
1000
953
634
971
904
704
786
869
879
489
961
347
791
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
791
793
1004
546
977
278
925
802
909
625
868
960
556
550
501
876
827
939
985
896
634
External contacts
412 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Country
Ukraine
Yemen
China
Iran
Pakistan
China
India
Pakistan
Rwanda
India
Pakistan
India
India
Viet Nam
Myanmar
Uzbekistan
Ukraine
Argentina
Ghana
India
India
City
Zaporizhzhya
Sana’a’
Heihe
Yazd
Multan
Guyuan
Agra
Sukkur
Kigali
Imphal
Gujranwala
Jabalpur
Moradabad
Bien Hoa
Rangoon
Namangan
Odessa
Salta
Sekondi
Durgapur
Mathura
(continued)
932
931
930
929
928
927
926
925
924
923
922
921
920
919
918
917
916
915
914
913
912
Sustainable competitiveness
800
755
685
952
968
852
957
654
775
804
913
625
585
859
851
867
924
888
939
991
948
Economic vitality
886
600
300
702
806
764
954
177
953
968
844
518
223
956
826
794
927
979
942
911
578
Environmental thoroughness
903
825
926
460
496
912
663
798
967
777
917
887
922
889
709
856
874
646
623
969
593
Social inclusion
604
639
994
519
385
990
657
847
834
813
894
806
851
893
701
854
646
506
921
551
752
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
796
935
853
738
841
981
296
813
917
842
929
831
548
974
736
775
650
889
781
767
927
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 413
Country
China
India
Ethiopia
India
India
Bangladesh
India
India
India
China
Tanzania
India
China
Liberia
Iran
India
Sierra Leone
Iraq
Niger
India
Ukraine
City
Dingxi
Belgaum
Addis Ababa
Bhavnagar
Gulbarga
Bogra
Ajmer
Solapur
Amravati
Longnan
Mwanza
Ujjain
Jiuquan
Monrovia
Zahedan
Nanded Waghala
Freetown
Mosul
Niamey
Firozabad
Donetsk
(continued)
953
952
951
950
949
948
947
946
945
944
943
942
941
940
939
938
937
936
935
934
933
Sustainable competitiveness
919
784
842
941
869
740
937
927
825
730
901
820
672
696
732
967
689
634
925
647
805
Economic vitality
236
889
923
637
541
940
926
462
941
827
918
831
774
771
848
909
629
948
185
410
835
Environmental thoroughness
657
964
966
919
911
781
841
989
451
812
860
871
894
886
758
909
851
848
850
791
654
Social inclusion
459
980
849
759
647
1003
674
552
899
927
897
861
715
793
853
955
846
597
363
810
680
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
962
928
636
959
780
963
786
529
645
899
998
757
932
937
890
950
906
923
287
967
672
External contacts
414 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Country
Sudan
China
India
India
Benin
Egypt
Zimbabwe
India
Mozambique
India
Pakistan
India
Benin
India
Syrian
India
Malawi
India
Djibouti
Syrian
Mali
City
Nyala
Yichun(HLJ)
Jhansi
Gorakhpur
Abomey-Calavi
Suez
Bulawayo
Tirunelveli
Matola
Nellore
Sargodha
Kayamkulam
Cotonou
Malegaon
Hamah
Bikaner
Blantyre-Limbe
Warangal
Djibouti
Latakia
Bamako
(continued)
974
973
972
971
970
969
968
967
966
965
964
963
962
961
960
959
958
957
956
955
954
Sustainable competitiveness
962
938
965
584
877
832
970
663
921
534
966
687
958
613
929
882
971
881
774
942
978
Economic vitality
376
419
986
692
487
951
893
964
247
409
687
823
464
495
460
459
633
920
1001
952
899
Environmental thoroughness
960
978
968
689
944
857
991
779
878
936
947
831
970
795
931
843
910
955
929
901
905
Social inclusion
733
882
976
673
612
845
999
983
642
981
740
901
1004
756
883
685
780
898
822
932
770
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
743
912
990
948
575
980
976
864
383
978
965
882
836
933
834
774
525
924
926
808
942
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 415
Country
Kyrgyzstan
Burkina Faso
India
Nigeria
Syrian
Morocco
Guinea
Nigeria
Myanmar
Cote d’ivoire
Madagascar
Syrian
Somalia
Myanmar
Somalia
Malawi
Burundi
Congo
Burkina Faso
Mozambique
Syrian
City
Bishkek
Ouagadougou
Raipur
Maiduguri
Aleppo
Agadir
Conakry
Nnewi
Nay Pyi Taw
Bouake
Antananarivo
Al-Raqqa
Mogadishu
Mandalay
Hargeysa
Lilongwe
Bujumbura
Tshikapa
Bobo Dioulasso
Maputo
homs
(continued)
995
994
993
992
991
990
989
988
987
986
985
984
983
982
981
980
979
978
977
976
975
Sustainable competitiveness
984
981
930
986
974
878
1005
969
989
959
992
872
960
983
980
420
995
953
898
946
976
Economic vitality
939
802
830
928
1006
963
985
890
882
1002
888
816
335
937
425
176
796
700
681
735
813
Environmental thoroughness
1000
888
982
1004
1002
959
977
834
1005
998
939
987
930
994
948
554
999
954
629
979
847
Social inclusion
913
606
890
1006
959
859
985
737
978
1005
711
943
949
965
944
630
843
866
736
688
585
Scientific and technological innovation
(continued)
949
291
986
1001
999
741
984
943
812
953
702
992
916
875
711
915
828
944
800
669
513
External contacts
416 7 Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness
Yemen
Tajikistan
Mozambique
Congo
Congo
Yemen
Yemen
Chad
Central African 1005
Congo
Aden
Dushanbe
Nampula
Kananga
Bukavu
Taiz
Hodeidah
N’Djamena
Bangui
Kisangani
1006
1004
1003
1002
1001
1000
999
998
997
996
Congo
Mbuji-Mayi
Sustainable competitiveness
Country
City
(continued)
1004
1002
1006
1003
1001
955
999
982
975
996
998
Economic vitality
919
533
980
829
815
395
966
992
476
932
677
Environmental thoroughness
1003
971
962
1001
986
995
997
985
914
972
1006
Social inclusion
968
964
935
973
852
938
1001
979
735
779
995
Scientific and technological innovation
1003
840
692
997
955
1006
1002
858
768
910
1005
External contacts
7.6 Ranking of Explanatory Indicators of Global Urban Sustainable … 417
Chapter 8
A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
8.1 Introduction 8.1.1 Global City Classification is an Important Theoretical and Practical Problem The process of globalization makes cities in different countries and regions form a global urban system with increasingly close ties. However, there are still significant differences in the global urban system. With the development of science and technology, the upgrading of globalization and the increasing complexity of global industrial divisions, the relationship between different cities in the global urban system is increasingly flattened and networked. The argument proposed by Friedmann (1986) in last century that some cities have the “command and control” function for other cities in the global economic system still has a strong insight into the deep understanding of the internal hierarchical structure of current global urban system. Therefore, the study of global urban classification is still necessary for cities, countries and the whole world. It is of great theoretical significance to study the global urban classification. In the global urban system, the flows of products and factors between cities have broken the limits of national boundaries, which makes the study of global urban functional system more complex. Especially with the divisions of global value chain, the development of global production network and the advent of the intelligent era, the internal hierarchical structure of global cities has undergone significant changes. The research of global urban classification involves the theory of urban functional system, the theory of urban spatial interaction, etc., which has been the hot topics of urban economics, spatial economics and economic geography. At the same time, how to understand and explain the new trend in the development of global urban system is also an important and developing problem. It is also of great practical significance to study the global urban classification. First, with the arrival of the urban world, the global urban system is the skeleton and © China Social Sciences Press 2023 P. Ni et al., The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-99-3553-6_8
419
420
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
blood of the global system. It is very important to understand the global urban system and its development trend. Second, the analysis of the differences and inequalities within the global urban system from a more comprehensive perspective has important reference value for us to understand the challenges in the global urbanization development and promote the sustainable development of global cities. Third, in the urban world, cities have become an important space carrier of a country’s competitiveness. Therefore, the study of global city classification has a direct reference role for a country to recognize its position in the global urban system, and then to reveal the country’s global position. Finally, for a specific city, to understand the specific status of a city in the global urban system from the functional perspective can provide decision-making reference and theoretical basis for relevant decision makers to make more competitive and sustainable policies based on the city level. In a word, the problem of global city classification is an important problem that all countries, cities and other relevant decision-makers are concerned about.
8.1.2 There Are New Changes in the Development of Global Urban System As human beings gradually enter into the global and intelligent urban society, the connotation, function, form, pattern and impacts of cities have changed or are undergoing profound changes, which makes it necessary for us to analyze and understand the global urban system from a new framework. Economic globalization is still advancing in twists and turns, and is constantly reshaping the relationship between cities. At present, the connotation of globalization has changed from the globalization of commodity trade, production and service trade to the globalization of scientific and technological innovation. According to Friedman’s book, the world is flat, globalization has entered the stage of 3.0. In the new stage of globalization, in addition to the traditional finance, scientific and technological innovation has become more important in determining the role of cities in the division of global value chain and global production network. In this process, the internal structure of global urban system will be reconstructed, and some new cities will rise, so it is necessary to study the new trends of global urban system. Cities will dominant the future world. After the world’s urbanization rate is over 50% in 2008 for the first time, the global urbanization continues to accelerate. According to the world urbanization prospects released by the UN in 2018, by 2050 the global urbanization rate is expected to reach 68%, and the world will soon enter a mature urban world. Therefore, the study of global urban system is closely related to the overall welfares of human society. With the rapid development of information, network and intelligence technology, human beings have stepped into the intelligent urban society, and the functions and forms of cities are undergoing a turning change. Driven by the new technology, cities will no longer be limited to the production, exchange and consumption of
8.1 Introduction
421
“hard materials” represented by tangible products, but the role of “soft materials” represented by intangible products such as information, knowledge and ideas will become more important in urban development. This change in urban functions is causing changes in urban morphology and the internal functional structure of the global urban system. The hierarchical relationship in the global urban system is weakening, while the network relationship is strengthening. It brings new challenges for us to classify the global cities.
8.1.3 The Theory of Global City and Its System Needs New Further Development The research on global urban system has a long history and includes rich literature. There are roughly two stages: Researches in the first stage mainly study global cities from the perspective of agglomeration degree. In essence, global cities are regarded as a spatial agglomeration economy. Therefore, the more population, industry and other factors a city agglomerates, the higher its rank in the global urban system. The early urban and regional economics mainly studies cities from the perspective of agglomeration, such as the central place theory proposed by Christaller and Lösch. Regional economics, new urban economics and new economic geography under the neoclassical framework all emphasize the importance of urban agglomeration (Henderson, 1974; Fujita and Ogawa, 1982; Fujita and Krugman, 1995). Therefore, cities can be classified by their economic agglomeration (Commendatore et al., 2017) and population agglomeration (Zhong et al., 2017). In the classic study of global city, Friedmann’s “world city” theory emphasizes the “command and control” function of high-rank global cities in the global economic system and measure a city’s rank using the agglomeration of multinational companies and their branches. Sassen’s “global city” theory mainly uses the agglomeration degree of advanced productive services to classify global cities. In essence, the above research mainly studies global cities and their systems from the perspective of agglomeration. The second stage of researches is mainly based on the new phenomenon that the global urban system increasingly form a more closely connected network system with the development of globalization and classifies the global cities from the perspective of connection degree. Its core is to regard the global urban system as a network system. Therefore, if a city is more closely connected with other cities, its position in the global urban system will be more important. Taylor (2001) based on his “interlocking model”, uses the distribution of “advanced productive services” such as banking, insurance, law, consulting management, advertising and accounting firms to measure a city’s global connections. Based on the above idea, the GaWC has conducted a lot of researches on global city classification. Another representative theory of global city classification based on connection degree is the theory of “flow space” proposed by Castells (1996), which emphasizes the role of information flow. Derudder et al.
422
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
(2003) studies the classification of 234 cities in the world under this idea. It should be noted that the research of global city classification based on connection needs to use relational data. The relational data selected by scholars are often different. For example, Esparza and Krmenec (2000) uses trade flow data, Jung et al. (2008) uses traffic flow, Derudder and Witlox (2008) use aviation flow to measure the connection between cities. Although the above research provides a theoretical basis for the classification of global cities, there are still following problems. First, there is a lack of strict logic in the classification framework. Global cities have rich connotation, including a wide range of dimensions, and the existing research on global city classification based on the degree of agglomeration and connection emphasizes the different aspects of global cities. In order to classify global cities accurately, we must establish a more general analysis framework. Second, when we grade global cities, it is one-sided to only consider the degree of connection or the degree of agglomeration. Only using the degree of agglomeration to grade global cities will overestimate the impact of scale factors on urban grades. Especially in the current global production network, cities in developed countries tend to transfer the low-end and labor-intensive sectors in the industrial chain to the cities in developing countries. At this time, the employment and industrial scale of cities in developing countries may be larger. However, due to their inferior position in the division of global value chain, the rank of cities in developing countries may not be greatly improved. Only considering the degree of connection may overestimate the position of some hub type or special functional cities in the global city system. For example, although the cities that are aviation hubs have a high flow of people and logistics, their local economic scale may not be increased in the same proportion. Only considering the degree of connection will overestimate their city rank. Tourism cities tend to have a high flow of people, but their overall industrial development level is not necessarily high. Third, it did not absorb new developments in practices, especially considering the new connotation of cities under new technology. With the increase of human knowledge, the progress of technology and the change of production mode, the factors that determine the degree of urban agglomeration and connection are no longer limited to the traditional tangible products and factors, and the role played by intangible factors and products such as knowledge, information and service is increasingly obvious. Therefore, it is necessary to design a more scientific and comprehensive global city classification framework. In view of this, we decided to release the classification of 1006 cities with a population of more than 500,000 in the world. These 1006 cities cover 6 continents and 136 countries or regions, including 565 Asian cities, 126 European cities, 131 North American cities, 102 African cities, 75 South American cities and 7 Oceanian cities, which basically include the main cities in different regions of the world today. Based on the existing researches, the innovation and improvement of the global urban classification framework in this report are as follows. First, from the perspective of elasticity of substitution, we propose a more general theoretical framework for global urban classification based on the degree of agglomeration and connection. Second, we design a new empirical framework and index system for global urban
8.2 Theory and Method
423
classification considering both the agglomeration and connection. Third, because of the significant changes in the connotation of cities in the intelligent era, we simultaneously consider the intangible “soft” factors and the tangible “hard” factors in the global urban classification framework. Fourth, when selecting the indicators to measure the agglomeration and connection degree, we emphasize not only the traditional financial factors but also the scientific and technological innovation factors.
8.2 Theory and Method 8.2.1 The Theoretical Framework of Global City Classification: An Analysis Based on Elasticity of Substitution The rank of a city in the global urban system is closely related to its position in the global urban industrial system. With the development of global value chain and global production network, the industrial relationship between global cities is increasingly close. Therefore, global cities will also form a functional system due to the industrial divisions. Hence, the more difficult a city is to be replaced by other cities in the global urban functional system, the higher its rank in the global urban system. Specifically, the elasticity of substitution of a city is determined by the factors it agglomerates and the products it produces. First, the more scarce the factors agglomerated in a city are, the lower the elasticity of substitution of the factors is. Hence, the city’s functions are more difficult to be replaced in the urban system. The factors here include natural environment, geographical location, labor force, land, capital, technology and so on. For example, if a city has a good geographical location to make it a key node in the transportation network, then the city’s elasticity of substitution is lower, and it is easier to be at a higher rank in the global urban system. For example, large cities often have higher efficiency because they can agglomerate more skilled labor (Davis and Dingel, 2014; Behrens et al., 2014), and the skilled labor they agglomerate cannot be replaced by the low skilled labor of other cities, which will lead to the high rank of large cities in the urban system. Second, cities that produce products with low elasticity of substitution tend to have higher rank. In the urban system, there will be a hierarchy formed by heterogeneous products (Duranton and Puga, 2001, 2005). When the substitution elasticity of products produced by one city is higher, it means that its market share is more easily replaced by other cities. Especially when there exists transportation cost, the market competitiveness of products with high elasticity of substitution will decline faster with the increase of transportation distance, so the economic hinterland of cities producing products with high elasticity of substitution will be smaller. Hence, their rank in the global urban system will be lower. The theoretical analysis of Fujita
424
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
et al. (1999) shows that, given the location of the central city, the products with low demand elasticity are more difficult to be replaced by other products, so the cities producing the products with low demand elasticity are more likely to appear in the location closer to the central city. In reality, cities agglomerate different industries and factors, so the rank of a city in the global urban system depends on the total substitution elasticity of all industries and factors in the global production system. Cities with lower substitution elasticity have a higher rank in the global urban system. We define the elasticity of substitution of a city as a function of the following variables: Si = f ( A, R)
(8.1)
In the above formula, Si is the substitution elasticity of the city, A and R is the agglomeration and connection degree of a city respectively. In the global urban system, the so-called agglomeration degree refers to the number of global highend factors agglomerated by the city. Because the substitution elasticity of high-end factors is often lower, so if a city agglomerates more global high-end factors, then the city is more difficult to be replaced by other cities, and its rank is higher. The so-called connection degree is to measure one city’s elasticity of substitution from the perspective of network topology. When a city has a high centrality in the global production network, it shows that the city is a key node in the global production network and has an irreplaceable function in maintaining the stability of the whole global network. Therefore, cities with high degree of connection have higher rank. Based on above analysis, in order to measure the degree of agglomeration and connection more comprehensively, we further divide the degree of agglomeration into two dimensions: hard agglomeration and soft agglomeration, and the degree of connection into two dimensions: hard connection and soft connection. Among them, all “hard” factors refer to tangible products or factors, such as population, enterprises, etc.; all “soft” factors refer to intangible products or factors, such as knowledge, information, etc. This new classification framework for global cities can solve the problems when only considering the degree of agglomeration or connection. Figure 8.1 reports the conceptual framework of global city classification.
8.2.2 Index System and Data Source According to Fig. 8.1, we design a global city classification index system, as shown in Table 8.1. The global city classification index system designed in this report is composed of three levels of indexes. The synthesis method of the indexes is as follows:
8.2 Theory and Method
425
hard agglomeration agglomeration soft agglomeration Rank of Cities hard connection connection soft connection Fig. 8.1 Conceptual framework of global city classification. Source Compiled by the Author
Table 8.1 Index system of global city classification Level 1 index
Level 2 index
Level 3 index
Agglomeration
Hard agglomeration
High end industry agglomeration (enterprise) High income population agglomeration (population)
Soft agglomeration
Patent agglomeration Paper agglomeration
Connection
Hard connection
Aviation connection (population) Multinational corporations’ connection (enterprises)
Soft connection
Information connection Knowledge connection
Source compiled by the Author
Si = Ai + Ri Ai = Ah i + Asi
(8.2)
Ri = Rh i + Rsi In the above formula, Si is the global city grade score of city i, Ai is the agglomeration degree of city i, Ri is the connection degree of city i, Asi is the soft agglomeration degree, Ah i is the hard agglomeration degree, Rh i is the hard connection degree and Rsi is the soft connection degree. See Table 8.1 for details. We use the simple arithmetic average to calculate each index. We normalized each indicator in Table 8.1 as 0–1, and the calculation method is as follows: S=
X − Min(X ) Max(X ) − Min(X )
(8.3)
426
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
In the above formula, X is the original score of each indicator and S is the score after normalization. The specific calculation methods and data sources of each indicator are as follows: (1) High-end industry agglomeration. This index is calculated based on the distribution of global top corporate headquarters in banking, technology and other industries. Specifically, we use the number of global top 1000 bank headquarters, global top 1000 technology headquarters, Forbes 2000 corporate headquarters (excluding technology and financial enterprises), the number of global top 75 financial multinational company headquarters (excluding those overlapping with the front), and the number of global top 25 financial multinational companies (excluding those overlapping with the front) headquarters in each city. (2) High income population agglomeration. We measure it using the number of people whose annual income is more than $20,000, we get the data from the EIU database. (3) Patent agglomeration. We measure it using the number of patent applications in each city. The data is from the database of world intellectual property organization. (4) Paper agglomeration. We measure this index using the total amount of papers published in each city and collect the data from Web of Science. (5) Aviation connection. We measure this index using the city’s number of international flight. The data comes from each city’s airport websites, Wikipedia and IAA websites. (6) Multinational corporations’ connection. According to the distribution of the headquarters and branches of 175 advanced productive service enterprises in the world, including law, management consulting, accounting, finance and advertising, we calculate it using the GaWC method. (7) Information connection. Measured by a city’s search heat on Google, the data comes from google trends. (8) Knowledge connection. Measured by the number of papers published by cities in cooperation with other cities. We use the top 100,000 literatures with the highest citation in 2017 from the web of science website. The sample is 1006 cities in the world. If there is no special statement, all indicators are annual data in 2017.
8.2.3 City Classification Method At present, the clustering method is the most commonly used method in the study of city classification. Because the clustering method can identify different sub-group in the whole sample relatively accurately. The clustering method can be further divided into hierarchical clustering and non-hierarchical clustering. Compared with non-hierarchical clustering, the advantage of hierarchical clustering method is that it
8.3 Empirical Analysis
427
does not need to specify the number of clusters in advance. The hierarchical clustering method can use the dendrogram to display the hierarchical structure in samples, so the conclusion is relatively objective. Therefore, after using the indicator system in Table 8.1 to get scores of each city in the sample, we then use the hierarchical clustering method to classify the whole sample. Taking the bottom-up method as an example, hierarchical clustering method first calculate the linkages between sample points and then merge the nearest points into the same class each time, and then calculate the linkages between the classes, and again merge the nearest classes into a large class. On this basis, we constantly merges until only one class is left.
8.3 Empirical Analysis 8.3.1 Global City Centrality Classification The number of global cities is the smallest, and the number of regional gateway cities is the largest. According to the results of hierarchical clustering, the global city system is a multi-level nested structure, As can be seen from Fig. 8.2, 1006 cities worldwide according to city level can be divided into 3 layers, 2 category (Strong international cities and weak international cities), 5 grades (A, B, C, D, E) 10 levels in total (A+, A, B+, B, C+, C, D+, D, E+, E). The first category is strong international cities, which can be divided into: firstclass global cities (A), second-class international hub cities (B); third-class international gateway cities (C); second category is weak international cities, which can be divided into: the fourth is the regional hub city (D); the fifth is the regional gateway city (E). The number of A+ cities is 3; the number of A cities is 2; the number of B+ cities is 3; the number of B cities is 26; and the number of C+ cities and C cities are 29 and 96 respectively. Similarly, the number of D+ cities is 122; the number of D cities is 266; the number of E+ cities and E cities is 389 and 70 respectively.
Fig. 8.2 Global city classification. Source Compiled by Author
428
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
8.3.2 An Analysis of the Characteristics of the Overall Classification of Global Cities The higher the degree of agglomeration and connection, the stronger the hardness and softness, the higher the city level. From Table 8.2, it can be seen that the total number of all cities is 1006, and the mean value of the city grade score is 0.2565, the standard variance is 0.1327, and the coefficient of variation is 0.5172. The mean value of D+ and above cities is higher than that of all cities, and A+ city is the highest, which is 0.9635. Similarly, the coefficient of variation of E+ and above cities is smaller than that of all cities, and the coefficient of variation of A level cities is the smallest, indicating that the internal difference of this type of cities is small; the coefficient of variation of E level cities is the largest, which is 0.5172, indicating that the internal development difference of this type of cities is large. As shown in Fig. 8.3, the higher the level, the darker the color, and the higher level cities are mainly distributed in the northern hemisphere. The number of high level cities in Europe, North America and Asia is much higher than that in other continents. See the following for specific analysis.
8.3.2.1
Composition and Characteristics of a Cities
Cities in Asia, Europe and North America scored the highest. It can be seen from Table 8.3 that there are only 3 A+ cities, New York-Newark, London and Tokyo, which belong to United States of America, United Kingdom and Japan respectively. From the continental perspective, North America, Europe and Asia occupy 1 seat Table 8.2 Global city classification City level
Number of cities
Mean value
Standard deviation
Coefficient of variation
A+
3
0.9635
0.0320
0.0332
A
2
0.9052
0.0006
0.0006
International hub city (B)
B+
3
0.7585
0.0178
0.0234
B
26
0.6423
0.0464
0.0723
International gateway city (C)
C+
29
0.5322
0.0251
0.0471
C
96
0.4185
0.0354
0.0845
Regional hub city (D)
D+
122
0.3269
0.0181
0.0553
D
266
0.2429
0.0244
0.1003
Regional gateway city (E)
E+
389
0.1769
0.1900
0.1072
E
70
0.0776
0.0404
0.5208
1006
0.2565
0.1327
0.5172
Global city (A)
All cities Source CCC of CASS
8.3 Empirical Analysis
429
90
60
30
0 -180
-120
-60
0
60
120
180
-30
-60
-90 Fig. 8.3 Distribution of global cities. Source Compiled by Author
Table 8.3 A+ cities
City level
City
Country
Continent
A+ Cities
New York-Newark
United States of America
North America
London
United Kingdom Europe
Tokyo
Japan
Asia
Source CCC of CASS
respectively, which shows that the comprehensive strength of North America, Europe and Asia is strong. From the perspective of characteristics, New York-Newark and London belong to high agglomeration and high connection cities, and Tokyo belongs to high agglomeration and middle connection cities; from the perspective of softness and hardness, all of them belong to strong hardness and strong softness cities. It shows that the higher the degree of agglomeration and connection, the stronger the hardness and softness, the stronger the comprehensive strength of the city. From Table 8.4, it can be seen that there are only 2 cities of A, Beijing and Paris, which belong to China and France respectively. From the continental perspective, Asia and Europe occupy 1 seat respectively, which shows that the overall comprehensive strength of Asian and European cities is constantly improving. From the perspective of characteristics, Beijing and Paris belong to high agglomeration and high connection cities; from the perspective of softness and hardness, both belong to strong hardness and strong softness cities. It shows that the higher the
430
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
Table 8.4 A cities
City level
City
Country
Continent
A cities
Beijing
China
Asia
Paris
France
Europe
Source CCC of CASS
degree of agglomeration and connection, the stronger the hardness and softness, the stronger the overall strength of the city.
8.3.2.2
Composition and Characteristics of B Cities
The comprehensive strength of Asian cities is constantly improving. The number of B+ cities is 3. As can be seen from Table 8.5, B+ cities include Seoul, Shanghai and Chicago, which are respectively subordinate to Republic of Korea, China and United States of America. From the continental perspective, Asian cities occupy 2 seats and North American cities occupy 1 seat, indicating that the comprehensive strength of Asian cities is constantly improving. From the perspective of characteristics, Seoul is a high agglomeration middle connection city; Shanghai and Chicago are middle agglomeration middle connection cities; from the perspective of softness and hardness, all of them are middle hardness and strong softness cities. It shows that the degree of connection and hardness of the three cities need to be strengthened. B city is 28. From Table 8.6, it can be seen that B cities mainly include Sydney, Dublin, Vienna, Sao Paulo, etc., and their countries are Australia, Ireland, Austria, Brazil, etc.; from the perspective of the continent of representative cities, European cities occupy 9 seats, Asian cities and North American cities occupy 4 seats and 2 seats respectively, and Oceania and South American cities occupy 1 seat respectively. The overall comprehensive strength of cities in Oceania and South America needs to be strengthened. From the perspective of characteristics, B cities are generally the middle agglomeration and middle connection city; from the perspective of softness and hardness, most of them are middle hardness and strong softness cities. It shows that the degree of agglomeration, connection and hardness of grade B cities need to be strengthened. Table 8.5 B+ cities
City level
City
Country
Continent
B+ cities
Seoul
Republic of Korea
Asia
Shanghai
China
Asia
Chicago
United States of America
North America
Source CCC of CASS
8.3 Empirical Analysis Table 8.6 B cities
431
City level
City
Country
Continent
B cities
Sydney
Australia
Oceania
Dublin
Ireland
Europe
Vienna
Austria
Europe
Sao Paulo
Brazil
South America
Brussels
Belgium
Europe
Munich
Germany
Europe
Moscow
Russian Federation
Europe
Amsterdam
Netherlands
Europe
Toronto
Canada
North America
Boston
United States of America
North America
Osaka
Japan
Asia
Stockholm
Sweden
Europe
Istanbul
Turkey
Asia
Madrid
Spain
Europe
Singapore
Singapore
Asia
Milan
Italy
Europe
Hong Kong
China
Asia
……
……
……
Note Due to the large Number of B cities, one representative city in each country is selected, …… represents a city without listing in B city. The following tables are the same Source CCC of CASS
8.3.2.3
Composition and Characteristics of C Cities
C grade cities need to improve connection and hardness. The number of C+ cities is 29. As can be seen from Table 8.7, C+ cities mainly include Melbourne, Buenos Aires, Dubai, Warsaw, etc., the countries are Australia, Argentina, United Arab Emirates, Poland, etc.; from the perspective of the continent of representative cities, European cities occupy 9 seats, Asian cities occupy 5 seats, and North American, Oceania and South American cities occupy 2 seats respectively, indicating that European and Asian cities have obvious advantages in C+ cities. From the aspect of characteristics, C+ cities belong to middle agglomeration and middle connection city; from the perspective of softness and hardness, most of them belong to the weak hardness and middle softness cities. It is indicated that C+ cities need to be strengthened in terms of agglomeration, connection and hardness. The number of C cities is 96. As can be seen from Table 8.8, C cities mainly include Brisbane, Abu Dhabi, Cairo, Rio de Janeiro, etc., the countries are Australia, United Arab Emirates, Egypt, Brazil, etc.; from the perspective of the continent of
432 Table 8.7 C+ city
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
City level
City
Country
Continent
C+ cities
Melbourne
Australia
Oceania
Buenos Aires Argentina
South America
Dubai
United Arab Emirates
Asia
Warsaw
Poland
Europe
Copenhagen
Denmark
Europe
Frankfurt am Main
Germany
Europe
Helsinki
Finland
Europe
Bogota
Colombia
South America
Montreal
Canada
North America
Prague
Czech Republic
Europe
Kuala Lumpur
Malaysia
Asia
Seattle
United States of America
North America
Oslo
Norway
Europe
Zurich
Switzerland
Europe
Bangkok
Thailand
Asia
Athens
Greece
Europe
Auckland
New Zealand
Oceania
Budapest
Hungary
Europe
Mumbai
India
Asia
Guangzhou
China
Asia
……
……
……
Source CCC of CASS
representative cities, European cities occupy 15 seats, Asian cities occupy 9 seats, African cities occupy 4 seats, North America and Oceania occupy 3 seats and 1 seat respectively, indicating that the comprehensive strength of African cities in C cities is gradually increasing. From the aspect of characteristics, C cities generally belong to the middle agglomeration and low connection types; from the perspective of softness and hardness, most of them belong to the weak hardness and middle softness type. It is indicated that C cities need to improve connection and hardness.
8.3 Empirical Analysis Table 8.8 C cities
433
City level
City
Country
Continent
C cities
Brisbane
Australia
Oceania
Abu Dhabi
United Arab Emirates
Asia
Cairo
Egypt
Africa
Rio de Janeiro Brazil
South America
Sofia
Bulgaria
Europe
Krakow
Poland
Europe
Stuttgart
Germany
Europe
Lyon
France
Europe
Incheon
Republic of Korea
Asia
Rotterdam
Netherlands
Europe
Vancouver
Canada
North America
Doha
Qatar
Asia
Zagreb
Croatia
Europe
Nairobi
Kenya
Africa
Riga
Latvia
Europe
Bucharest
Romania
Europe
Charlotte
United States of America
North America
Lima
Peru
South America
Casablanca
Morocco
Africa
Mexico City
Mexico
North America
Johannesburg
South Africa
Africa
Lisbon
Portugal
Europe
Nagoya
Japan
Asia
Geneva
Switzerland
Europe
Belgrade
Serbia
Europe
Riyadh
Saudi Arabia
Asia
Ankara
Turkey
Asia
Kiev
Ukraine
Europe (continued)
434
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
Table 8.8 (continued)
City level
City
Country
Continent
Valencia
Spain
Europe
Bologna
Italy
Europe
Delhi
India
Asia
Jakarta
Indonesia
Asia
Manchester
United Kingdom Europe
Santiago de Chile
United States of America
North America
Hangzhou
China
Asia
……
……
……
Source CCC of CASS
8.3.2.4
Composition and Characteristics of D Cities
D grade cities need to improve their connection and hardness. The number of D+ cities is 122. As can be seen from Table 8.9, D+ cities mainly include Baku, Alexandria, Addis Ababa, Karachi, etc., and the countries are Azerbaijan, Egypt, Ethiopia, Pakistan, etc.; from the perspective of the continent of representative cities, Asian cities occupy 19 seats, European cities occupy 11 seats, and African, North American and South American cities occupy 4 seats, 7 seats and 6 seats respectively, indicating that African and South American cities are gradually increasing in D+ cities. From the aspect of characteristics, like the C level cities, D+ cities generally belong to the middle agglomeration and low connection types; from the perspective of softness and hardness, most of them belong to the weak hardness and middle softness types. It is indicated that D+ cities need to improve connection and hardness. The number of D cities is 266. From Table 8.10, it can be seen that the D cities mainly include Gold Coast, Algiers, Cordoba, Muscat, etc., and the countries are Australia, Algeria, Argentina, Oman, etc.; from the perspective of the continent of representative cities, Africa has the most cities, accounting for 23 seats; followed by Asia, accounting for 22 seats; South America, Europe and North America Cities occupy 9, 8 and 7 seats respectively, which shows that African and Asian cities have a large number of D cities, and their comprehensive strength needs to be improved. From the perspective of characteristics, most of D cities belong to the type of middle agglomeration and low connection; from the perspective of softness and hardness, most of them belong to the type of weak hardness and weak softness. It shows that the degree of connection, hardness and softness need to be improved in D cities.
8.3 Empirical Analysis
435
Table 8.9 D+ cities City level
City
Country
Continent
D+ cities
Baku
Azerbaijan
Asia
Alexandria
Egypt
Africa
Addis Ababa
Ethiopia
Africa
Karachi
Pakistan
Asia
Panama City
Panama
North America
Campinas
Brazil
South America
Minsk
Belarus
Asia
Antwerp
Belgium
Europe
San Juan
Puerto Rico
North America
Wroclaw
Poland
Europe
Santa Cruz
Bolivia
South America
Cologne
Germany
Europe
Novosibirsk
Russian Federation
Europe
Quito
Ecuador
South America
Nantes
France
Europe
Manila
Philippines
Asia
Medellin
Colombia
South America
San Jose
United States of America
North America
Tbilisi
Georgia
Asia
Almaty
Kazakhstan
Asia
Busan
Republic of Korea
Asia
Hague
Netherlands
Europe
Hamilton
Canada
North America
Beirut
Lebanon
Asia
Milwaukee
United States of America
North America
Dhaka
Bangladesh
Asia
Guadalajara
Mexico
North America
Lagos
Nigeria
Africa
Hiroshima
Japan
Asia
Gothenburg
Sweden
Europe
Colombo
Sri Lanka
Asia
Tunis
Tunisia
Africa
Izmir
Turkey
Asia
Barcelona-Puerto La Cruz
Venezuela
South America (continued)
436
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
Table 8.9 (continued) City level
City
Country
Continent
Montevideo
Uruguay
South America
Malaga
Spain
Europe
Tehran
Iran (Islamic Republic of)
Asia
Kingston
Jamaica
North America
Thessaloniki
Greece
Europe
Tel Aviv-Yafo
Israel
Asia
Florence
Italy
Europe
Kolkata
India
Asia
Belfast
United Kingdom
Europe
Amman
Jordan
Asia
Ho Chi Minh City
Viet Nam
Asia
Dongguan
China
Asia
……
……
……
Source CCC of CASS
8.3.2.5
Composition and Characteristics of E Cities
E grade cities need to improve the degree of agglomeration, connection, hardness and softness. The number of E+ cities is 389. From Table 8.11, it can be seen that E+ cities mainly include Kabul, Mar del Plata, Suez, Faisalabad, etc., and the countries are including Afghanistan, Argentina, Egypt, Pakistan, etc.; from the perspective of the continent of representative cities, Africa has the largest number of cities, accounting for 27 seats; followed by Asian cities, accounting for 24 seats; Cities in South America, North America and Europe occupy 6, 4 and 3 seats respectively. It can be seen that, similar to D level cities, African and Asian cities have a large number of E+ cities. From the aspect of characteristics, most of the E+ cities mainly belong to the type of low agglomeration and low connection; from the aspect of softness and hardness, they belong to the type of weak hardness and weak softness. It shows that E+ cities need to improve their agglomeration and connection, hardness and softness. The number of E cities is 70. From Table 8.12, it can be seen that E cities mainly include Huambo, Victoria, Tyumen, and Zamboanga, etc., and the countries are including Angola, Brazil, Russian Federation, Philippines, etc.; from the perspective of the continent of representative cities, Asian cities account for the most, accounting for 15 seats; African cities account for 8 seats; South America, Europe and North America cities account for 2,2,1 seats respectively. It shows that the internal differentiation of Asian cities is serious, including the top cities with A+ level and the relatively underdeveloped cities with E level. The internal differentiation problem deserves attention.
8.3 Empirical Analysis
437
Table 8.10 D cities City level
City
Country
Continent
D cities
Gold Coast
Australia
Oceania
Algiers
Algeria
Africa
Cordoba
Argentina
South America
Muscat
Oman
Asia
Sharjah
United Arab Emirates
Asia
Luanda
Angola
Africa
Lahore
Pakistan
Asia
Asuncion
Paraguay
South America
Curitiba
Brazil
South America
Liege
Belgium
Europe
Cotonou
Benin
Africa
Poznan
Poland
Europe
La Paz
Bolivia
South America
Lomé
Togo
Africa
Santo Domingo
Dominican Republic
North America
Kazan
Russian Federation
Europe
Guayaquil
Ecuador
South America
Toulon
France
Europe
Cebu
Philippines
Asia
Kinshasa
Congo
Africa
Cartagena
Colombia
South America
Astana
Kazakhstan
Asia
Havana
Cuba
North America
Ulsan
Republic of Korea
Asia
Accra
Ghana
Africa
Phnom Penh
Cambodia
Asia
Harare
Zimbabwe
Africa
Bishkek
Kyrgyzstan
Asia
Tegucigalpa
Honduras
North America
Douala
Cameroon
Africa
Kuwait City
Kuwait
Asia
Abidjan
The Republic of Cote d’ivoire
Africa
Kigali
Rwanda
Africa
Monrovia
Liberia
Africa
Johor Bahru
Malaysia
Asia
Blantyre-Limbe
Malawi
Africa (continued)
438
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
Table 8.10 (continued) City level
City
Country
Continent
Vientiane
Lao People’s Democratic Republic
Asia
Tripoli
Libya
Africa
Antananarivo
Madagascar
Africa
Tulsa
United States of America
North America
Chisinau
Republic of Moldova
Europe
Rabat
Morocco
Africa
Maputo
Mozambique
Africa
Puebla
Mexico
North America
Pretoria
South Africa
Africa
Managua
Nicaragua
South America
Kathmandu
Nepal
Asia
Abuja
Nigeria
Africa
Kitakyushu-Fukuoka
Japan
Asia
Dakar
Senegal
Africa
San Salvador
El Salvador
North America
Medina
Saudi Arabia
Asia
Dar es Salaam
United Republic of Tanzania
Africa
Khartoum
Sudan
Africa
Bursa
Turkey
Asia
Zaragoza
Spain
Europe
Valencia
Spain
Europe
Guatemala City
Guatemala
North America
Yerevan
Armenia
Asia
Kampala
Uganda
Africa
Baghdad
Iraq
Asia
Tashkent
Uzbekistan
Asia
Odessa
Ukraine
Europe
Mashhad
Iran (Islamic Republic of)
Asia
Kochi
India
Asia
Surabaya
Indonesia
Asia
West Yorkshire
United Kingdom
Europe
Lusaka
Zambia
Africa
Valparaiso
Chile
South America
Hsinchu
China
Asia
……
……
……
Source CCC of CASS
8.3 Empirical Analysis Table 8.11 E+ cities
439
City level
City
Country
Continent
E+ Cities
Kabul
Afghanistan
Asia
Mar Del Plata
Argentina
South America
Suez
Egypt
Africa
Faisalabad
Pakistan
Asia
Gaza
State of Palestine
Asia
Uberlandia
Brazil
South America
Abomey-Calavi
Benin
Africa
Cochabamba
Bolivia
South America
Ouagadougou
Burkina Faso
Africa
Bujumbura
Burundi
Africa
Tomsk
Russian Federation
Europe
Asmara
Eritrea
Africa
Davao
Philippines
Asia
Brazzaville
Congo
Africa
Pereira
Colombia
South America
Port-au-Prince
Haiti
North America
Libreville
Gabon
Africa
Lilongwe
Malawi
Africa
San Pedro Sula
Honduras
North America
Conakry
Guinea
Africa
Kumasi
Ghana
Africa
Mombasa
Kenya
Africa
Shymkent
Kazakhstan
Asia
Benghazi
Libya
Africa
Changwon
Republic of Korea
Asia
Djibouti
Djibouti
Africa
Bulawayo
Zimbabwe
Africa
Bouake
The Republic of Cote d’ivoire
Africa
Bamako
Mali
Africa
Nouakchott
Mauritania
Africa
Ipoh
Malaysia
Asia (continued)
440 Table 8.11 (continued)
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
City level
City
Country
Continent
Provo-Orem
United States of America
North America
Ulan Bator
Mongolia
Asia
Chittagong
Bangladesh
Asia
Arequipa
Peru
South America
Mandalay
Myanmar
Asia
Fes
Morocco
Africa
Nampula
Mozambique
Africa
Toluca
Mexico
North America
Niamey
Niger
Africa
Ibadan
Nigeria
Africa
Niigata
Japan
Asia
Freetown
Sierra Leone
Africa
Nyala
Sudan
Africa
Mogadishu
Somalia
Asia
Dushanbe
Tajikistan
Asia
Mecca
Saudi Arabia
Asia
Mwanza
United Republic of Tanzania
Africa
Denizli
Turkey
Asia
Ashgabat
Turkmenistan
Asia
Maracaibo
Venezuela
South America
Kharkov
Ukraine
Europe
Damascus
Syrian Arab Republic
Asia
Sana’a’
Yemen
Asia
Erbil
Iraq
Asia
Kerman
Iran (Islamic Republic Asia of)
Varanasi
India
Asia
Padang
Indonesia
Asia
Newcastle upon Tyne
United Kingdom
Europe
Da Nang
Viet Nam
Asia
N’Djamena
Chad
Africa (continued)
8.3 Empirical Analysis Table 8.11 (continued)
441
City level
City
Country
Continent
Bangui
Central African Republic
Africa
Kitwe
Zambia
Africa
Baoji
China
Asia
……
……
……
Source CCC of CASS
From the perspective of characteristics, almost all E cities belong to the type of low agglomeration and low connection; from the perspective of softness and hardness, they belong to the type of weak hardness and weak softness. It shows that E cities need to strengthen their agglomeration and connection, hardness and softness.
8.3.3 Global City Types with Characteristics of Agglomeration and Connection Agglomeration is the premise of connection, and it is difficult to achieve a higher level of connection at a low level of agglomeration. Cluster method is used to divide the types of agglomeration and connection into three categories (high, middle and low) respectively. By combining 1006 cities in the world, according to the types of agglomeration and connection, they can be divided into nine categories (high agglomeration and high connection, high agglomeration and middle connection, high agglomeration and low connection, middle agglomeration and high connection, middle agglomeration and middle connection, middle agglomeration low connection, low agglomeration and high connection, low agglomeration and middle connection, low agglomeration and low connection). Among them, the number of cities with high agglomeration and high connection is 4; the number of cities with high agglomeration and middle connection is 3; the number of cities with high agglomeration and low connection is 1; the number of cities with middle agglomeration and middle connection, middle agglomeration and low connection and low agglomeration and low connection are 91, 329 and 578 respectively. The number of other cities is 0. It can be seen from Table 8.13 that the number of cities with low agglomeration and low connection type is the largest, indicating that agglomeration and connection are positively related, and that cities with low agglomeration and high connection; low agglomeration and middle connection types are all 0, indicating that agglomeration is the premise of connection, and it is difficult to achieve high-level connection with a low level of agglomeration. The mean value of agglomeration degree of all cities is 0.2026, the standard deviation is 0.1160, and the coefficient of variation is 0.5725; the mean value of connection degree is 0.2703, the standard deviation is 0.1433, and the coefficient of
442 Table 8.12 E cities
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
City level
City
Country
Continent
E cities
Huambo
Angola
Africa
Greater Vitória Brazil
South America
Tyumen
Russian Federation
Europe
Zamboanga
Philippines
Asia
Kisangani
Congo
Africa
Bogra
Bangladesh
Asia
Vereeniging
South Africa
Africa
Matola
Mozambique
Africa
Pachuca de Soto
Mexico
North America
Nay Pyi Taw
Myanmar
Asia
Sekondi
Ghana
Africa
Misrata
Libya
Africa
Warri
Nigeria
Africa
Ta’if
Saudi Arabia
Asia
Hargeysa
Somalia
Asia
Safaqis
Tunisia
Africa
Sanliurfa
Turkey
Asia
Samut Prakan
Thailand
Asia
Ciudad Guayana
Venezuela
South America
Lvov
Ukraine
Europe
Hodeidah
Yemen
Asia
Namangan
Uzbekistan
Asia
Nasiriyah
Iraq
Asia
Homs
Syrian Arab Republic
Asia
Zahedan
Iran (Islamic Republic of)
Asia
Be’er Sheva
Israel
Asia
Kayamkulam
India
Asia
Hegang
China
Asia
……
……
……
Source CCC of CASS
0
91
329
Middle agglomeration and high connection
Middle agglomeration and middle connection
Middle agglomeration and low connection
Low agglomeration 0 and high connection
1
High agglomeration and low connection
–
0.2726
0.3897
–
0.6648
0.7757
3
High agglomeration and middle connection
Mean value of agglomeration degree
0.7545
City quantity
High agglomeration 4 and high connection
City type
–
0.0599
0.0879
–
–
0.1958
0.0863
Standard deviation of agglomeration degree
Table 8.13 City types by agglomeration and connection degree
–
0.2197
0.2256
–
–
0.2524
0.1144
Coefficient of variation of agglomeration degree
–
0.2902
0.5864
–
0.4277
0.7335
0.9788
Mean value of connection degree
–
0.0814
0.1061
–
–
0.0141
0.0151
–
0.2804
0.1809
–
–
0.0193
0.0155
(continued)
Standard deviation Coefficient of of connection degree variation of degree of connection
8.3 Empirical Analysis 443
0
578
1006
Low agglomeration and middle connection
Low agglomeration and low connection
All cities
Note – Means none Source CCC of CASS
City quantity
City type
Table 8.13 (continued)
0.2026
0.1257
–
Mean value of agglomeration degree
0.1160
0.0399
–
Standard deviation of agglomeration degree
0.5725
0.3174
–
Coefficient of variation of agglomeration degree
0.2703
0.2016
–
Mean value of connection degree
0.1433
0.0701
–
0.5302
0.3475
–
Standard deviation Coefficient of of connection degree variation of degree of connection
444 8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
8.3 Empirical Analysis
445
variation is 0.5302. It can be seen that the coefficient of variation (agglomeration degree and connection degree) of all types of cities does not exceed the coefficient of variation of all cities. From the perspective of agglomeration degree, the mean value of high agglomeration and high connection and high agglomeration and middle connection cities are higher than that of other types of cities, indicating that these cities have obvious advantages in agglomeration economy; the mean value of low agglomeration and low connection cities is the smallest, and the coefficient of variation is the largest, indicating that the agglomeration economy is at a relative disadvantage, and the internal urban development differences are large. From the aspect of connection degree, the mean value of high agglomeration and high connection cities is much higher than that of other types of cities, which indicates that such cities have high connection degree with the outside world and strong economic development ability. In the same way, the mean value of low agglomeration and low connection cities is the smallest, and the coefficient of variation is the largest, which indicates that the economic connection degree is in a relative disadvantage, and the internal urban development difference is large.
8.3.3.1
Cities with High Agglomeration and High Connection and Their Distribution
European cities have strong comprehensive strength in high agglomeration and high connection. The number of high agglomeration and high connection cities is 4. From Table 8.14, it can be seen that high concentration and high connection cities include New York-Newark, London, Beijing and Paris, which are respectively subordinate to United States of America, United Kingdom, China and France; the population of New York-Newark and Beijing is more than 20 million, and that of London and Paris is more than 12 million. The per capita GDP of these cities is generally high, especially New York-Newark is as high as $89,135.75, while Beijing is as low as $18,748.91; from the perspective of the continent, European cities occupy 2 seats, North American and Asian cities occupy 1 respectively, which shows that European cities have strong comprehensive strength in high agglomeration and high connection. Table 8.14 High agglomeration and high connection cities City type
City
Country
Continent
High agglomeration and high New York-Newark United States of America North America connection
Source CCC of CASS
London
United Kingdom
Europe
Beijing
China
Asia
Paris
France
Europe
446
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
Table 8.15 High agglomeration and middle connection cities City type
City
Country
Continent
High agglomeration and middle connection
Tokyo
Japan
Asia
Seoul
Republic of Korea
Asia
Hong Kong
China
Asia
Source CCC of CASS
8.3.3.2
Cities with High Agglomeration and Middle Connection and Their Distribution
Asian cities have strong comprehensive strength in high agglomeration and middle connection. It can be seen from Table 8.15 that the cities in high agglomeration and middle connection include Tokyo, Seoul and Hong Kong, which are respectively subordinate to Japan, Republic of Korea and China; the population of Tokyo and Seoul are all over 25 million, and Hong Kong is 7.4 million. The per capita GDP of these cities is generally high, especially Hong Kong is as high as $47,264.37, while Seoul is low as $29,417.38; from the perspective of the continent, all three cities belong to In Asia, it shows that Asian cities have a strong comprehensive strength in the aspect of degree in high agglomeration and middle connection, and also emphasizes that Asian cities should enhance the ability of connection degree.
8.3.3.3
Cities with High Agglomeration and Low Connection and Their Distribution
Osaka needs to improve its soft and hard connection. From Table 8.16, it can be seen that high concentration and low connection cities only include Osaka, which belongs to Japan; Osaka has a population of more than 20 million and a per capita GDP of $46,538.61, which belongs to Asia, indicating that Osaka needs to improve its soft and hard connection. Table 8.16 High concentration and low connection cities City type
City
Country
Continent
High agglomeration and low connection
Osaka
Japan
Asia
Source CCC of CASS
8.3 Empirical Analysis
8.3.3.4
447
Cities with Middle Agglomeration and Middle Connection and Their Distribution
European and Asian cities need to improve the degree of agglomeration and connection. There are 91 cities of middle agglomeration and middle connection. As can be seen from Table 8.17, the cities of middle agglomeration and middle connection mainly include Sydney, Dublin, Vienna, Dubai etc., and the countries are including Australia, Ireland, Austria, the United Arab Emirates, etc.; the average population size of these cities is 6.837 million, and the average GDP per capita is $42,924.92. From the perspective of the continent of representative cities, Europe has the largest number of cities, occupy 25 seats; next are Asian cities, occupy 10 seats; third are North America, South America and Africa cities, occupy 4 seats respectively, Oceania occupy 2 seats, which shows that European cities have strong comprehensive strength in middle agglomeration and middle connection, but also need to improve the degree of agglomeration and connection.
8.3.3.5
Cities with Middle Agglomeration and Low Connection and Their Distribution
Asian cities have a large number of cities with middle agglomeration and low connection. The number of cities with middle agglomeration and low connection is 329. From the observation of Table 8.18, it can be seen that the cities of middle agglomeration and low connection mainly include Adelaide, Cordoba, Abu Dhabi, Alexandria etc., and the countries are including Australia, Argentina, United Arab Emirates, Egypt, etc.; the average population size of such cities is 3.407 million, and the average GDP per capita is $25,423.55; from the perspective of the continent of representative cities, Asia has the largest number of cities with 18 seats, followed by Europe with 12 seats, South America with 8 seats, North America, Africa and Oceania with 6, 5 and 1 seats respectively, indicating that Asian cities have a large number of middle agglomeration and low connection, and need to improve their soft hard connection.
8.3.3.6
Cities with Low Agglomeration and Low Connection and Their Distribution
Asian cities need to pay attention to urban differentiation while enhancing their agglomeration and connection. The number of cities with low agglomeration and low connection is the largest, 578. From the observation of Table 8.19, it can be seen that the low concentration and low connection cities mainly include Gold Coast, Algiers, Baku, Muscat, etc., and the countries are belong to are Australia, Algeria, Azerbaijan, Oman, etc. the per capita GDP of these cities is generally low, with an average of $7112.58 and an average population of 1.945 million. In terms of the continent to which the representative cities belong, African cities are the most, accounting
448
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
Table 8.17 Middle agglomeration and middle connection cities City type
City
Country
Continent
Middle agglomeration and middle connection
Sydney
Australia
Oceania
Dublin
Ireland
Europe
Vienna
Austria
Europe
Dubai
United Arab Emirates
Asia
Buenos Aires
Argentina
South America
Cairo
Egypt
Africa
Panama City
Panama
North America
Sao Paulo
Brazil
South America
Brussels
Belgium
Europe
Copenhagen
Denmark
Europe
Warsaw
Poland
Europe
Sofia
Bulgaria
Europe
Munich
Germany
Europe
Moscow
Russian Federation
Europe
Amsterdam
Netherlands
Europe
Helsinki
Finland
Europe
Bogota
Colombia
South America
Lyon
France
Europe
Toronto
Canada
North America
Prague
Czech Republic
Europe
Kuala Lumpur
Malaysia
Asia
Doha
Qatar
Asia
Zagreb
Croatia
Europe
Bucuresti
Romania
Europe
Nairobi
Kenya
Africa
Chicago
United States of America
North America
Oslo
Norway
Europe
Mexico City
Mexico
North America
Johannesburg
South Africa
Africa
Lima
Peru
South America
Casablanca
Morocco
Africa
Lisbon
Portugal
Europe
Stockholm
Sweden
Europe
Zurich
Switzerland
Europe
Istanbul
Turkey
Asia (continued)
8.3 Empirical Analysis
449
Table 8.17 (continued) City type
City
Country
Continent
Bangkok
Thailand
Asia
Riyadh
Saudi Arabia
Asia
Belgrade
Serbia
Europe
Kiev
Ukraine
Europe
Madrid
Spain
Europe
Singapore
Singapore
Asia
Athens
Greece
Europe
Auckland
New Zealand
Oceania
Budapest
Hungary
Europe
Milan
Italy
Europe
Mumbai
India
Asia
Jakarta
Indonesia
Asia
Manchester
United Kingdom
Europe
Shanghai
China
Asia
……
……
……
Note Due to the large number of middle agglomeration and middle connection, one representative city in each country is selected. The following tables are the same Source CCC of CASS
for 39 seats; Asian cities are the second, accounting for 33 seats; South American and North American cities are the third, accounting for 10 and 9 seats respectively; European and Oceanian cities are the 3 and 1 respectively, indicating that African and Asian cities have a large number of low agglomeration and low connection cities, and the degree of agglomeration and connection need to be strengthened. At the same time, it also shows that Asian cities are seriously divided, including the relatively developed cities in high agglomeration and high connection and the underdeveloped cities in low agglomeration and low connection.
8.3.4 Differences Types in Global City from the Perspective of “Hard” and “Soft” The development gap between softness and hardness cities is large, and the softness can change the hardness to a certain extent. Using clustering method, the types of hardness (hard agglomeration + hard connection) and softness (soft agglomeration + soft connection) are divided into three categories (strong, middle and weak)respectively. By combining 1006 cities in the world, according to the types of hardness and softness, they can be divided into nine categories (strong hardness and strong softness, strong hardness and middle softness, strong hardness and weak
450
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
Table 8.18 Middle agglomeration and low connection cities City type
City
Country
Continent
middle agglomeration and low connection
Adelaide
Australia
Oceania
Cordoba
Argentina
South America
Abu Dhabi
United Arab Emirates
Asia
Alexandria
Egypt
Africa
Karachi
Pakistan
Asia
Campinas
Brazil
South America
Minsk
Belarus
Asia
Antwerp
Belgium
Europe
San Juan
Puerto Rico
North America
Krakow
Poland
Europe
Santa Cruz
Bolivia
South America
Hannover
Germany
Europe
Santiago de Chile
United States of North America America
Novosibirsk
Russian Federation
Europe
Quito
Ecuador
South America
Manila
Philippines
Asia
Marseille-Aix-en-Provence
France
Europe
Medellin
Colombia
South America
Almaty
Kazakhstan
Asia
Incheon
Republic of Korea
Asia
Rotterdam
Netherlands
Europe
Calgary
Canada
North America
Riga
Latvia
Europe
Beirut
Lebanon
Asia
Dhaka
Bangladesh
Asia
Rabat
Morocco
Africa
Austin
United States of North America America
Guadalajara
Mexico
North America
Cape Town
South Africa
Africa
Lagos
Nigeria
Africa
Tunis
Tunisia
Africa
Colombo
Sri Lanka
Asia (continued)
8.3 Empirical Analysis
451
Table 8.18 (continued) City type
City
Country
Continent
Gothenburg
Sweden
Europe
Medina
Saudi Arabia
Asia
Nagoya
Japan
Asia
Ankara
Turkey
Asia
Barcelona-Puerto La Cruz
Venezuela
South America
Montevideo
Uruguay
South America
Valencia
Spain
Europe
Tehran
Iran (Islamic Republic of)
Asia
Kingston
Jamaica
North America
Thessaloniki
Greece
Europe
Yerevan
Armenia
Asia
Jerusalem
Israel
Asia
Florence
Italy
Europe
Chennai
India
Asia
Bristol
United Kingdom
Europe
Ho Chi Minh City
Viet Nam
Asia
Santiago de Chile
United States of North America America
Wuhan
China
Asia
……
……
……
Source CCC of CASS
softness, middle hardness and strong softness, middle hardness and middle softness, middle hardness and weak softness, weak hardness and strong softness, weak hardness and middle softness, weak hardness and weak softness). It can be seen from Table 8.20 that the number of strong hardness and strong softness cities is 5; the number of middle hardness and strong softness cities is 16; the number of middle hardness and middle softness cities is 11; the number of weak hardness and strong softness, weak hardness and middle softness and weak hardness and weak softness cities are 16, 331 and 627, respectively. The number of other cities (strong hardness and middle softness, strong hardness and weak softness, middle hardness and weak softness) is 0. It shows that the hardness is not completely related to the softness. The softness can be strong if it hardness is weak, but hardness is difficult to be strong if it softness is weak. To some extent, the softness can change the hardness. The mean value hardness of all cities is 0.0782, the standard deviation is 0.1272, and the coefficient of variation is 1.6255; it can be seen that the coefficient of variation of weak hardness and weak softness cities (hardness) exceeds the coefficient of variation of all cities, indicating that there is a large difference in their internal
452
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
Table 8.19 Low agglomeration and low connection cities City type
City
Country
Continent
Low agglomeration and low connection
Gold Coast
Australia
Oceania
Algiers
Algeria
Africa
Baku
Azerbaijan
Asia
Muscat
Oman
Asia
Kabul
Afghanistan
Asia
Mendoza
Argentina
South America
Suez
Egypt
Africa
Addis Ababa
Ethiopia
Africa
Luanda
Angola
Africa
Faisalabad
Pakistan
Asia
Asuncion
Paraguay
South America
Gaza
State of Palestine
Asia
Natal
Brazil
South America
Cotonou
Benin
Africa
Cochabamba
Bolivia
South America
Ouagadougou
Burkina Faso
Africa
Santo Domingo
Dominican Republic
North America
Lome
Togo
Africa
Bujumbura
Burundi
Africa
Ufa
Russian Federation
Europe
Guayaquil
Ecuador
South America
Asmara
Eritrea
Africa
Cebu
Philippines
Asia
Kinshasa
Congo
Africa
Cali
Colombia
South America
Tbilisi
Georgia
Asia
San Jose
United States of America
North America
Havana
Cuba
North America
Port-au-Prince
Haiti
North America
Shymkent
Kazakhstan
Asia
Tegucigalpa
Honduras
North America
Bishkek
Kyrgyzstan
Asia
Conakry
Guinea
Africa
Djibouti
Djibouti
Africa
Accra
Ghana
Africa (continued)
8.3 Empirical Analysis
453
Table 8.19 (continued) City type
City
Country
Continent
Phnom Penh
Cambodia
Asia
Libreville
Gabon
Africa
Harare
Zimbabwe
Africa
Douala
Cameroon
Africa
Abidjan
The Republic of Cote d’ivoire
Africa
Kuwait City
Kuwait
Asia
Monrovia
Liberia
Africa
Vientiane
Lao People’s Democratic Republic
Asia
Mombasa
Kenya
Africa
Tripoli
Libya
Africa
Kigali
Rwanda
Africa
Antananarivo
Madagascar
Africa
Blantyre-Limbe
Malawi
Africa
Johor Bahru
Malaysia
Asia
Bamako
Mali
Africa
Nouakchott
Mauritania
Africa
El Paso
United States of America
North America
Ulan Bator
Mongolia
Asia
Chittagong
Bangladesh
Asia
Arequipa
Peru
South America
Mandalay
Myanmar
Asia
Chisinau
Republic of Moldova
Europe
Marrakech
Morocco
Africa
Maputo
Mozambique
Africa
Tijuana
Mexico
North America
Port Elizabeth
South Africa
Africa
Managua
Nicaragua
South America
Kathmandu
Nepal
Asia
Niamey
Niger
Africa
Abuja
Nigeria
Africa
Dakar
Senegal
Africa
San Salvador
El Salvador
North America
Freetown
Sierra Leone
Africa (continued)
454
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
Table 8.19 (continued) City type
City
Country
Continent
Dammam
Saudi Arabia
Asia
Khartoum
Sudan
Africa
Mogadishu
Somalia
Asia
Dushanbe
Tajikistan
Asia
Samut Prakan
Thailand
Asia
Dar es Salaam
United Republic of Tanzania
Africa
Safaqis
Tunisia
Africa
Antalya
Turkey
Asia
Guatemala City
Guatemala
North America
Ashgabat
Turkmenistan
Asia
Kampala
Uganda
Africa
Maracaibo
Venezuela
South America
Odessa
Ukraine
Europe
Tashkent
Uzbekistan
Asia
Damascus
Syrian Arab Republic
Asia
Sana’a’
Yemen
Asia
Baghdad
Iraq
Asia
Mashhad
Iran (Islamic Republic of)
Asia
Tel Aviv-Yafo
Israel
Asia
Jaipur
India
Asia
Surabaya
Indonesia
Asia
Amman
Jordan
Asia
Lusaka
Zambia
Africa
N’Djamena
Chad
Africa
Valparaiso
Chile
South America
Bangui
Central African Republic
Africa
Huainan
China
Asia
……
……
……
Source CCC of CASS
development; the mean value softness of all cities is 0.4157, the standard deviation is 0.1500, and the coefficient of variation is 0.3607, and it can be seen that the coefficient of variation of all types of cities (softness) is not exceeded the coefficient of variation of all cities. It can be observed from Table 8.20 that, in terms of hardness, the mean value of strong hardness and strong softness cities is 0.8652, which is higher than that of other types of cities, indicating that such cities have absolute advantages in hard
8.3 Empirical Analysis
455
Table 8.20 City types by hard and soft degree City type City quantity
Mean value of hardness degree
Standard deviation of hardness degree
Coefficient of variation of hardness degree
Mean value of softness degree
Standard deviation of softness degree
Coefficient of variation of softness degree
Strong hardness and strong softness
5
0.8652
0.1102
0.1273
0.9493
0.0565
0.0595
Strong hardness and middle softness
0
–
–
–
–
–
–
Strong 0 hardness and weak softness
–
–
–
–
–
–
Middle hardness and strong softness
16
0.5599
0.0785
0.1402
0.7649
0.0331
0.0432
Middle hardness and middle softness
11
0.4742
0.0280
0.0590
0.6425
0.0682
0.1061
Middle 0 hardness and weak softness
–
–
–
–
–
–
Weak hardness and strong softness
0.3147
0.1096
0.3484
0.7765
0.0560
0.0722
16
(continued)
456
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
Table 8.20 (continued) City type City quantity
Mean value of hardness degree
Standard deviation of hardness degree
Coefficient of variation of hardness degree
Mean value of softness degree
Standard deviation of softness degree
Coefficient of variation of softness degree
Weak hardness and middle softness
331
0.1176
0.0975
0.8289
0.5395
0.0776
0.1439
Weak 627 hardness and weak softness
0.0259
0.0425
1.6432
0.3241
0.0812
0.2507
All cities 1006
0.0782
0.1272
1.6255
0.4157
0.1500
0.3607
Note – Means none Source CCC of CASS
agglomeration and hard connection; the minimum mean value of weak hardness and weak softness cities is 0.0259, and the maximum coefficient of variation is 1.6432, indicating that such cities are relatively inferior in hard agglomeration and hard connection, and there are great differences in internal urban development. From the aspect of softness degree, the mean value of strong hardness and strong softness cities is 0.9493, which is much higher than other types of cities, indicating that such cities have absolute advantages in soft agglomeration and soft connection. Similarly, the mean value of weak hardness and weak softness cities is the smallest, 0.3241; the coefficient of variation is the largest, 0.2507, which shows that such cities are in a relative disadvantage in soft agglomeration and soft connection, and there are great differences in internal urban development.
8.3.4.1
Strong Hardness and Strong Softness Cities and Their Distribution
European and Asian cities have strong strength in terms of strong hardness and strong softness. The number of strong hardness and strong softness cities is 5. From Table 8.21, it can be seen that strong hardness and strong softness cities include New York-Newark, London, Tokyo, Beijing and Paris, which are respectively subordinate to United States of America, United Kingdom, Japan, China and France; the per capita GDP of such cities is generally high, especially New York-Newark is as high as $89,135.75; the lowest is Beijing, which is $18,748.91. In terms of population scale, Tokyo has a maximum of 42 million people, while London and Paris have a relatively smaller population scale, with an average of 12.2733 million people. From the continental perspective, European and Asian cities occupy 2 seats respectively,
8.3 Empirical Analysis
457
Table 8.21 Strong hardness and strong softness cities City type
City
Country
Continent
Strong hardness and strong softness
New York-Newark
United States of America
North America
London
United Kingdom
Europe
Tokyo
Japan
Asia
Beijing
China
Asia
Paris
France
Europe
Source CCC of CASS
and North American cities occupy 1, indicating that European and Asian cities have strong comprehensive strength in terms of strong hardness and strong softness.
8.3.4.2
Middle Hardness and Strong Softness Cities and Their Distribution
European and Asian cities have strong comprehensive strength in middle hardness and strong softness type. The number of middle hardness and strong softness cities is 16. From the observation of Table 8.22, it can be seen that the middle hardness and strong softness cities mainly include Sydney, Seoul, Moscow, Toronto etc., and the countries are including Australia, Republic of Korea, Russian Federation, Canada, etc.; the per capita GDP of such cities is relatively high, with an average of $48,568.57 and an average population of 10.8055 million. From the perspective of the continent to which the representative cities belong, the cities of Asia and Europe occupy 4 seats respectively; the cities of North America occupy 2 seats; the cities of South America and Oceania occupy 1 seat respectively, indicating that the comprehensive strength of the cities of Europe and Asia is strong in the middle hardness and strong softness cities.
8.3.4.3
Middle Hardness and Middle Softness Cities and Their Distribution
European cities have strong comprehensive strength in middle hardness and middle softness types. The number of middle hardness and middle softness cities is 11. From the observation of Table 8.23, it can be seen that the middle hardness and middle softness cities mainly include Brussels, Dublin, Vienna, Dubai, etc. the countries they belong to are Belgium, Ireland, Austria, United Arab Emirates, etc. the average per capita GDP of such cities is $61,986.53, the highest is $93,831.45 of Switzerland; the population scale is small, the average is 4.5551 million; from
458
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
Table 8.22 Middle hardness and strong softness cities City type
City
Country
Continent
Middle hardness and strong softness
Sydney
Australia
Oceania
Seoul
Republic of Korea
Asia
Moscow
Russian Federation
Europe
Toronto
Canada
North America
Amsterdam
Netherlands
Europe
Sao Paulo
Brazil
South America
Chicago
United States of America
North America
Singapore
Singapore
Asia
Madrid
Spain
Europe
Istanbul
Turkey
Asia
Milan
Italy
Europe
Hong Kong
China
Asia
……
……
……
Note Due to the large number of middle hardness and strong softness cities, one representative city in each country is selected. The following tables are the same Source CCC of CASS
Table 8.23 Middle hardness and middle softness cities City type
City
Country
Continent
Middle hardness and middle softness
Brussels
Belgium
Europe
Dublin
Ireland
Europe
Vienna
Austria
Europe
Dubai
United Arab Emirates
Asia
Munich
Germany
Europe
Dallas-Fort Worth
United States of America
North America
Taipei
China
Asia
Zurich
Switzerland
Europe
Bangkok
Thailand
Asia
……
……
……
Source CCC of CASS
the perspective of representative cities of continent, European cities occupy 5 seats; Asian cities occupy 3 seats; North America occupies 1 seat, which indicates that European cities have strong comprehensive strength in middle hardness and middle softness cities.
8.3 Empirical Analysis
459
Table 8.24 Weak hardness and strong softness cities City type
City
Country
Continent
Weak hardness and strong softness
Melbourne
Australia
Oceania
Berlin
Germany
Europe
Boston
United States of America
North America
Stockholm
Sweden
Europe
Rome
Italy
Europe
Barcelona
Spain
Europe
Osaka
Japan
Asia
Guangzhou
China
Asia
……
……
……
Source CCC of CASS
8.3.4.4
Weak Hardness and Strong Softness Cities and Their Distribution
European cities have strong comprehensive strength in weak hard and strong soft cities. The number of weak hardness and strong softness cities is 16. From Table 8.24, it can be seen that the weak hardness and strong softness cities mainly include Melbourne, Berlin, Boston, Stockholm, etc. the countries they belong to are Australia, Germany, United States of America, Sweden, etc. the per capita GDP of these cities is relatively high, with an average of $55,408.17, and the population scale is relatively small, with an average of 6.7884 million. From the perspective of the continent of representative cities, European cities occupy 4 seats; Asian cities occupy 2 seats; North America and Oceania occupy 1 seat respectively, which shows that European cities have strong comprehensive strength in weak hardness and strong softness cities, but also need to improve their hard agglomeration and hard connection.
8.3.4.5
Weak Hardness and Middle Softness Cities and Their Distribution
European cities have a large number of cities of weak hardness and middle softness types. The number of weak hardness and middle softness cities is 331. From Table 8.25, it can be seen that the weak hardness and middle softness cities mainly include Brisbane, Buenos Aires, Abu Dhabi, Cairo, etc. the countries they belong to are Australia, Argentina, the United Arab Emirates, Egypt and so on. The average per capita GDP of such cities is $27,886.25, and the population scale is small, with an average of 3.8277 million people. From the perspective of the continent of representative cities, European cities are the largest, accounting for 24 seats, followed by Asian cities, accounting for 18 seats, South America, accounting for 9 seats, North America, Africa and Oceania respectively accounting for 5, 5 and
460
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
2 seats, which shows that European cities have a large number of weak hardness and middle softness cities, so it is urgent to improve the degree of hard agglomeration and hard connection. Table 8.25 Weak hardness and middle softness cities City type
City
Country
Continent
Weak hardness and middle softness
Brisbane
Australia
Oceania
Buenos Aires
Argentina
South America
Abu Dhabi
United Arab Emirates
Asia
Cairo
Egypt
Africa
Karachi
Pakistan
Asia
Rio de Janeiro
Brazil
South America
Sofia
Bulgaria
Europe
Minsk
Belarus
Asia
Antwerp
Belgium
Europe
San Juan
Puerto Rico
North America
Warsaw
Poland
Europe
Copenhagen
Denmark
Europe
Santa Cruz
Bolivia
South America
Stuttgart
Germany
Europe
Quito
Ecuador
South America
Novosibirsk
Russian Federation
Europe
Lyon
France
Europe
Helsinki
Finland
Europe
Manila
Philippines
Asia
Bogota
Colombia
South America
Tbilisi
Georgia
Asia
Incheon
Republic of Korea
Asia
Rotterdam
Netherlands
Europe
Montreal
Canada
North America
Prague
Czech Republic
Europe
Kuala Lumpur
Malaysia
Asia
Doha
Qatar
Asia
Zagreb
Croatia
Europe (continued)
8.3 Empirical Analysis
461
Table 8.25 (continued) City type
Source CCC of CASS
City
Country
Continent
Bucuresti
Romania
Europe
Riga
Latvia
Europe
Nairobi
Kenya
Africa
Beirut
Lebanon
Asia
Denver-Aurora
United States of America North America
Lima
Peru
South America
Casablanca
Morocco
Africa
Mexico City
Mexico
North America
Oslo
Norway
Europe
Johannesburg
South Africa
Africa
Lisbon
Portugal
Europe
Nagoya
Japan
Asia
Geneva
Switzerland
Europe
Belgrade
Serbia
Europe
Gothenburg
Sweden
Europe
Riyadh
Saudi Arabia
Asia
Tunis
Tunisia
Africa
Colombo
Sri Lanka
Asia
Ankara
Turkey
Asia
Barcelona-Puerto La Cruz
Venezuela
South America
Kiev
Ukraine
Europe
Montevideo
Uruguay
South America
Valencia
Spain
Europe
Athens
Greece
Europe
Auckland
New Zealand
Oceania
Budapest
Hungary
Europe
Tehran
Iran (Islamic Republic of) Asia
Kingston
Jamaica
North America
Jerusalem
Israel
Asia
Bologna
Italy
Europe
Mumbai
India
Asia
Jakarta
Indonesia
Asia
Manchester
United Kingdom
Europe
Santiago de Chile
United States of America North America
Chengdu
China
Asia
……
……
……
462
8.3.4.6
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
Weak Hardness and Weak Softness Cities and Their Distribution
Asian cities have a large number of weak hardness and weak softness cities, with serious internal differentiation. The number of weak hardness and weak softness cities is 627. From the observation of Table 8.26, it can be seen that weak hardness and weak softness cities mainly include Gold Coast, Algiers, Kabul, Mendoza, etc., and their countries are Australia, Algeria, Afghanistan, Argentina, etc. The per capita GDP of such cities is generally low, with an average of $7861.22 and a small population of 2.1165 million. In terms of the continent to which the representative cities belong, African cities are the most, accounting for 39 seats; Asian cities are the second, accounting for 37 seats; South American and North American cities are the third, accounting for 10 seats respectively; European and Oceanian cities are 5 and 1 seats respectively, indicating that African and Asian cities have a large number of weak hardness and weak softness cities, which need to be strengthened; meanwhile, the internal differences is serious Asian cities, including the relatively developed cities with strong hardness and strong softness, and the underdeveloped cities with weak hardness and weak softness.
8.3.5 Classification of Chinese Cities There are no global cities in Chinese cities, with the largest number of regional gateway cities. The situation of Chinese cities in the global city classification is shown in Table 8.27, where the number of A+ cities is 0; the number of A cities is 1; the number of B+ cities is 1; the number of B cities is 2; the number of C+ cities and C cities are 4 and 18, respectively. Similarly, the number of D+ cities is 22; the number of D cities is 100; the number of E+ cities and E cities are 141 and 2, respectively. The total number of Chinese cities is 291, and the mean value score of city rank is 0.2379, the standard variance is 0.0992, and the coefficient of variation is 0.4170. The mean value of D and above cities is higher than that of Chinese cities, and A+ city is the highest, which is 0.9056. Similarly, the coefficient of variation of all types of cities is smaller than that of Chinese cities, and the coefficient of variation of E cities is the smallest, which indicates that the internal differences of these cities are small; the coefficient of variation of B cities is the largest, which is 0.1611, which indicates that the internal development differences of these cities are large.
8.3.5.1
Composition and Characteristics of a Cities
Beijing has the highest score of city level. There is no A+ level city in China. As can be seen from Table 8.28, there is only 1 A City, Beijing. From the perspective of characteristics, Beijing is a high agglomeration and high connection city; from the
8.3 Empirical Analysis
463
Table 8.26 Weak hardness weak softness cities City type
City
Country
Continent
Weak hardness and middle softness
Gold Coast
Australia
Oceania
Algiers
Algeria
Africa
Kabul
Afghanistan
Asia
Mendoza
Argentina
South America
Baku
Azerbaijan
Asia
Muscat
Oman
Asia
Sharjah
United Arab Emirates
Asia
Suez
Egypt
Africa
Addis Ababa
Ethiopia
Africa
Luanda
Angola
Africa
Faisalabad
Pakistan
Asia
Panama City
Panama
North America
Asuncion
Paraguay
South America
Gaza
State of Palestine
Asia
Goiania
Brazil
South America
Cotonou
Benin
Africa
Cochabamba
Bolivia
South America
Ouagadougou
Burkina Faso
Africa
Lome
Togo
Africa
Bujumbura
Burundi
Africa
Santo Domingo
Dominican Republic
North America
Saint Petersburg
Russian Federation
Europe
Guayaquil
Ecuador
South America
Toulon
France
Europe
Asmara
Eritrea
Africa
Cebu
Philippines
Asia
Kinshasa
Congo
Africa
Cali
Colombia
South America
San Jose
United States of America
North America (continued)
464
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
Table 8.26 (continued) City type
City
Country
Continent
Havana
Cuba
North America
Almaty
Kazakhstan
Asia
Port-au-Prince
Haiti
North America
Changwon
Republic of Korea
Asia
Tegucigalpa
Honduras
North America
Bishkek
Kyrgyzstan
Asia
Conakry
Guinea
Africa
Djibouti
Djibouti
Africa
Accra
Ghana
Africa
Phnom Penh
Cambodia
Asia
Libreville
Gabon
Africa
Harare
Zimbabwe
Africa
Douala
Cameroon
Africa
Abidjan
The Republic of Cote d’ivoire
Africa
Kuwait City
Kuwait
Asia
Monrovia
Liberia
Africa
Vientiane
Lao People’s Democratic Republic
Asia
Mombasa
Kenya
Africa
Tripoli
Libya
Africa
Kigali
Rwanda
Africa
Antananarivo
Madagascar
Africa
Blantyre-Limbe
Malawi
Africa
Johor Bahru
Malaysia
Asia
Bamako
Mali
Africa
Nouakchott
Mauritania
Africa
Birmingham
United States of America
North America
Ulan Bator
Mongolia
Asia
Dhaka
Bangladesh
Asia
Arequipa
Peru
South America
Mandalay
Myanmar
Asia
Chisinau
Republic of Moldova
Europe (continued)
8.3 Empirical Analysis
465
Table 8.26 (continued) City type
City
Country
Continent
Fes
Morocco
Africa
Maputo
Mozambique
Africa
Tijuana
Mexico
North America
Port Elizabeth
South Africa
Africa
Managua
Nicaragua
South America
Kathmandu
Nepal
Asia
Niamey
Niger
Africa
Lagos
Nigeria
Africa
Kitakyushu-Fukuoka
Japan
Asia
Dakar
Senegal
Africa
San Salvador
El Salvador
North America
Freetown
Sierra Leone
Africa
Dammam
Saudi Arabia
Asia
Khartoum
Sudan
Africa
Mogadishu
Somalia
Asia
Dushanbe
Tajikistan
Asia
Samut Prakan
Thailand
Asia
Dar es Salaam
United Republic of Tanzania
Africa
Safaqis
Tunisia
Africa
Antalya
Turkey
Asia
Guatemala City
Guatemala
North America
Ashgabat
Turkmenistan
Asia
Caracas
Venezuela
South America
Kampala
Uganda
Africa
Odessa
Ukraine
Europe
Tashkent
Uzbekistan
Asia
Damascus
Syrian Arab Republic
Asia
Yerevan
Armenia
Asia
Sana’a’
Yemen
Asia
Baghdad
Iraq
Asia
Mashhad
Iran (Islamic Republic of)
Asia
Tel Aviv-Yafo
Israel
Asia (continued)
466
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
Table 8.26 (continued) City type
City
Country
Continent
Ahmedabad
India
Asia
Surabaya
Indonesia
Asia
Amman
Jordan
Asia
Newcastle upon Tyne
United Kingdom
Europe
Ho Chi Minh City
Viet Nam
Asia
Lusaka
Zambia
Africa
N’Djamena
Chad
Africa
Concepcion
Chile
South America
Bangui
Central African Republic
Africa
Hohhot
China
Asia
Source CCC of CASS
Table 8.27 Global city classification of Chinese cities City level Global city (A)
Number of cities
Mean value
Standard deviation
Coefficient of variation
A+
0
–
–
–
A
1
0.9056
–
–
International hub city (B)
B+
1
0.7527
–
–
B
2
0.6616
0.1066
0.1611
International gateway city (C)
C+
4
0.5297
0.0294
0.0556
C
18
0.4183
0.0391
0.0934
Regional hub city (D)
D+
22
0.3235
0.0136
0.0421
D
100
0.2421
0.0241
0.0995
Regional gateway city (E)
E+
141
0.1772
0.0183
0.1031
E
2
0.1305
0.0011
0.0088
291
0.2379
0.0992
0.4170
Chinese city Source CCC of CASS
perspective of softness and hardness, it is a strong hardness and strong softness city. It shows that the higher the degree of agglomeration and connection, the stronger the hardness and softness, the stronger the overall strength of the city. Table 8.28 A cities
City level
City
Country
Continent
A cities
Beijing
China
Asia
Source CCC of CASS
8.3 Empirical Analysis Table 8.29 B+ cities
467
City level
City
Country
Continent
B+ cities
Shanghai
China
Asia
Source CCC of CASS
Table 8.30 B cities
City level
City
Country
Continent
B cities
Hong Kong
China
Asia
Taipei
China
Asia
Source CCC of CASS
8.3.5.2
Composition and Characteristics of B Cities
B level cities have obvious differences in agglomeration and softness. It can be seen from Table 8.29 that the number of B+ cities is 1, Shanghai. From the aspect of characteristics, Shanghai belongs to the cities with middle agglomeration and middle connection, and from the aspect of softness and hardness, it belongs to the cities with middle hardness and strong softness. It shows that the degree of agglomeration, connection and the hardness of Shanghai need to be strengthened. As can be seen from Table 8.30, the number of B cities is 2, Hong Kong and Taipei. From the perspective of characteristics, Hong Kong belongs to the high agglomeration and middle connected city; Taipei belongs to the middle agglomeration and middle connected city; from the perspective of softness and hardness, Hong Kong belongs to the middle hardness and strong softness city; Taipei belongs to the middle hardness and middle softness city. It shows that there are obvious differences in the degree of agglomeration and the degree of softness in B cities.
8.3.5.3
Composition and Characteristics of C Cities
C grade cities need to improve the hardness. The number of C+ cities is 4. As can be seen from Table 8.31, the C+ cities include Guangzhou, Shenzhen, Chengdu and Nanjing. From the perspective of characteristics, C+ cities all belong to middle agglomeration and middle connected; from the perspective of softness and hardness, only Chengdu is a weak hardness and middle softness city, and the other three cities are weak hardness and strong softness cities. It shows that the hardness of C+ cities needs to be strengthened. The number of C cities is 18. From Table 8.32, it can be seen that C cities mainly include Hangzhou, Wuhan, Tianjin, Chongqing, etc. In terms of characteristics, C cities generally belong to the type of middle agglomeration and low connection; in terms of softness and hardness, most of them belong to the type of weak hardness and middle softness. It shows that C cities needs to improve the degree of connection and hardness.
468
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
Table 8.31 C+ cities
City level
City
Country
Continent
C+ cities
Guangzhou
China
Asia
Shenzhen
China
Asia
Chengdu
China
Asia
Nanjing
China
Asia
Source CCC of CASS
Table 8.32 C cities
City level
City
Country
Continent
C cities
Hangzhou
China
Asia
Wuhan
China
Asia
Tianjin
China
Asia
Chongqing
China
Asia
Xi’an
China
Asia
Qingdao
China
Asia
Changsha
China
Asia
Xiamen
China
Asia
Hefei
China
Asia
Dalian
China
Asia
Shenyang
China
Asia
Jinan
China
Asia
Zhengzhou
China
Asia
Kunming
China
Asia
Suzhou
China
Asia
Harbin
China
Asia
Fuzhou(FJ)
China
Asia
Ningbo
China
Asia
Source CCC of CASS
8.3.5.4
Composition and Characteristics of D Cities
D grade cities need to improve their connection and hardness. The number of D+ cities is 22. From Table 8.33, it can be seen that the D+ cities mainly include Changchun, Wuxi, Shijiazhuang, Taiyuan, etc. In terms of characteristics, D+ cities belong to the type of middle agglomeration and low connection; in terms of softness and hardness, they belong to the type of weak hardness and middle softness. It shows that D+ cities need to improve the connection and hardness. The number of D cities is 100. From Table 8.34, it can be seen that D cities mainly include Xinzhu, Guilin, Taizhong, Luoyang, etc. From the perspective of characteristics, most of the cities of D belong to the type of middle agglomeration
8.3 Empirical Analysis Table 8.33 D+ cities
469
City level
City
Country
Continent
D+ cities
Changchun
China
Asia
Wuxi
China
Asia
Shijiazhuang
China
Asia
Taiyuan
China
Asia
Nanchang
China
Asia
Guiyang
China
Asia
Nanning
China
Asia
Lanzhou
China
Asia
Zhuhai
China
Asia
Urumqi
China
Asia
Dongguan
China
Asia
Kaohsiung
China
Asia
Wenzhou
China
Asia
Haikou
China
Asia
Nanyang
China
Asia
Xuzhou
China
Asia
Nantong
China
Asia
Changzhou
China
Asia
Foshan
China
Asia
Macao
China
Asia
Yantai
China
Asia
Zhongshan
China
Asia
Source CCC of CASS
and low connection; from the perspective of softness and hardness, most of them belong to the type of weak hardness and middle softness. It shows that the city of D needs to improve its connection and hardness.
8.3.5.5
Composition and Characteristics of E Cities
E grade cities need to improve the degree of agglomeration, connection, hardness and softness. The number of E+ cities is 141. As can be seen from Table 8.35, E+ cities mainly include Baoji, Suqian, Huangshi, Chifeng, etc. From the perspective of characteristics, E+ cities belong to the type of low agglomeration and low connection; from the perspective of softness and hardness, they belong to the type of weak hardness and weak softness. It shows that E+ cities need to improve their agglomeration and connection, hardness and softness. It can be seen from Table 8.36 that the number of E cities is 2, Hegang and Liaoyuan. From the aspect of characteristics, all E cities belong to the type of low
470 Table 8.34 D cities
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
City level
City
Country
Continent
D cities
Hsinchu
China
Asia
Guilin
China
Asia
Taichung
China
Asia
Luoyang
China
Asia
Yinchuan
China
Asia
Yangzhou
China
Asia
Hohhot
China
Asia
Jilin
China
Asia
Zhenjiang
China
Asia
Lianyungang
China
Asia
Weifang
China
Asia
Huizhou
China
Asia
Mianyang
China
Asia
Anyang
China
Asia
Yancheng
China
Asia
Shantou
China
Asia
Tangshan
China
Asia
Quanzhou
China
Asia
Xining
China
Asia
Jiaxing
China
Asia
Zibo
China
Asia
Weihai
China
Asia
Handan
China
Asia
Tainan
China
Asia
Xiangyang
China
Asia
Note There are many cities of D level, so only 25 cities are selected as representatives. The following table is the same Source CCC of CASS
agglomeration and low connection; from the aspect of softness and hardness, they belong to the type of weak hardness and weak softness. It shows that E cities need to strengthen their agglomeration and connection, hardness and softness.
References Table 8.35 E+ cities
Table 8.36 E cities
471
City level
City
Country
Continent
e+ cities
Baoji
China
Asia
Suqian
China
Asia
Huangshi
China
Asia
Chifeng
China
Asia
Huanggang
China
Asia
Jingzhou
China
Asia
Qingyuan
China
Asia
Qinzhou
China
Asia
Taian
China
Asia
Lijiang
China
Asia
Suining
China
Asia
Loudi
China
Asia
Putian
China
Asia
Chengde
China
Asia
Rizhao
China
Asia
Longyan
China
Asia
Hanzhong
China
Asia
Karamay
China
Asia
Ordoss
China
Asia
Baoji
China
Asia
Zaozhuang
China
Asia
Jinzhong
China
Asia
Dandong
China
Asia
Zhangjiajie
China
Asia
Meizhou
China
Asia
Meishan
China
Asia
City level
City
Country
Continent
E cities
Hegang
China
Asia
Liaoyuan
China
Asia
Source CCC of CASS
References Behrens, K., Duranton, G., & Robert-Nicoud, F. (2014). Productive cities: Sorting, selection, and agglomeration. Journal of Political Economy, 122(3), 507–553. Castells, M. (1996). The rise of the network society (Vol. 1). Malden, MA: Blackwell.
472
8 A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification
Commendatore, P., Kubin, I., Mossay, P., & Sushko, I. (2017). The role of centrality and market size in a four-region asymmetric new economic geography model. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 27(5), 1095–1131. Davis, D. R., & Dingel, J. I. (2014). The comparative advantage of cities (No. w20602). National Bureau of Economic Research. Derudder, B., & Witlox, F. (2008). Mapping world city networks through airline flows: Context, relevance, and problems. Journal of Transport Geography, 16(5), 305–312. Derudder, B., Witlox, F., & Catalano, G. (2003). Hierarchical tendencies and regional patterns in the world city network: a global urban analysis of 234 cities. Regional Studies, 37(9), 875–886. Duranton, G., & Puga, D. (2001). Nursery cities: Urban diversity, process innovation, and the life cycle of products. American Economic Review, 91(5), 1454–1477. Duranton, G., & Puga, D. (2005). From sectoral to functional urban specialisation. Journal of Urban Economics, 57(2), 343–370. Esparza, A. X., & Krmenec, A. J. (2000). Large city interaction in the US urban system. Urban Studies, 37(4), 691–709. Friedmann, J. (1986). The world city hypothesis. Development and Change, 17(1), 69–83. Fujita, M., & Krugman, P. (1995). When is the economy monocentric? von Thünen and Chamberlin unified. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 25(4), 505–528. Fujita, M., & Ogawa, H. (1982). Multiple equilibria and structural transition of non-monocentric urban configurations. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 12(2), 161–196. Fujita, M., Krugman, P., & Mori, T. (1999). On the evolution of hierarchical urban systems1. European Economic Review, 43(2), 209–251. Henderson, J. V. (1974). The sizes and types of cities. American Economic Review, 64(4), 640–656. Jung, W.-S., Wang, F., & Stanley, H. E. (2008). Gravity model in the Korean highway. EPL (Europhysics Letters), 81(4), 48005. Sassen, S. (1991). The Global City: New York, London, Tokyo. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Taylor, P. J. (2001). Specification of the world city network. Geographical Analysis, 33(2), 181–194. Zhong, C., Schläpfer, M., Müller Arisona, S., Batty, M., Ratti, C., & Schmitt, G. (2017). Revealing centrality in the spatial structure of cities from human activity patterns. Urban Studies, 54(2), 437–455.
Appendix
Theory and Method of Urban Competitiveness Evaluation City, in the process of development, relaying on the internal organization efficiency and the external economic advantage which are formed by its factor endowments and space foundation, needs to create more values and acquire various resource rent in a rapid and extensive way by means of attracting, controlling and transforming resources and dominating the market, so as to continuously provide and maximize the benefits for its residents, known as the competitive level of the city. In terms of time and level, urban competitiveness can be divided into short-term competitiveness and long-term competitiveness. Short-term competitiveness is the ability to use direct factors and environment to create current wealth, while longterm competitiveness is the ability to use basic factors and environment to create wealth and provide utility sustainably. In the short term, the composition of economic competitiveness is the urban business environment; In the long run, the component of sustainable competitiveness is urban living environment. The relationship between the two is shown in Fig. A.1. On this basis, this report intends to build the following urban competitiveness model: urban sustainable competitiveness determines urban economic competitiveness through explanatory variables of economic competitiveness, and urban economic competitiveness further influences urban sustainable competitiveness through explanatory variables of economic competitiveness.
© China Social Sciences Press 2023 P. Ni et al., The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-99-3553-6
473
474
Appendix
Urban utility: performance of sustainable competitiveness
Urban value: performance of economic competitiveness
Direct factors and environment: composition of economic competitiveness
Basic factors and environment: composition of sustainable competitiveness Fig. A.1 The relationship between urban sustainable competitiveness urban economic competitiveness. Source CCC of CASS
Urban Economic Competitiveness Determining Mechanism and Definition of Urban Economic Competitiveness The city is an informal open organization composed of people, private sector, quasipublic sector, and public sector. In cities, enterprises organize their employees to create and provide private products and services to local and external markets, and public sectors organize employees to create and provide localized public goods and services, which together constitute a relatively independent complex in urban space. The determination of the competitiveness of a single city: In fact, the business choice of a company depends on the environmental conditions of its location, and the business choice of the enterprise also determines the level of added value of the enterprise. In a city, the local elemental environment and the external environment that can be effectively utilized determine the size, structure, and efficiency of the city’s industrial system (including industry and industry links), and the industrial system determines the urban value creation. The combination of the factors which influence the operation of enterprise group determines the industry choice of the enterprise group and determines the level of added value of the enterprise group. Comparison of global urban competitiveness: under the background of global integration, there are a large number of urban areas around the world with different endowments and costs in terms of subject quality and factor environment, as well as different distances and costs to approach and utilize factor environment outside cities. Under the open economic system, the difference of comparative advantages between cities caused by different factor environments leads to the industrial differences and division of labor among urban regions, which determines the scale, level,
Appendix
475
structure and efficiency of the corresponding urban industrial system, and thus the value created by cities is also very different. From the perspective of enterprises, a globalized company may layout its global industrial chain according to the factors and environmental conditions of different cities around the world, so as to form its global value chain. From the perspective of cities, under the global urban system, the system composed of environmental systems of various global urban elements determines the industrial network system of global cities, and the industrial network system among global cities determines the global value chain system. Global competition and change of patterns: as population, enterprises and some important factors of production between cities are fluid, differences in urban factor environments lead to differences in potential benefits. Therefore, there is not only division of labor, cooperation and trade among relevant cities, but also complex and diverse competition. Urban competition leads to the flow and allocation of resources and elements between cities following the principle of maximizing the interests of the subject, and the economic system tends to the general equilibrium including the balance of urban space. However, due to the change of the elements and environment between cities and the subjective quality, the reconfiguration of resources, elements and industries in space will be caused, and the process of the original general equilibrium is often interrupted and tends to a new equilibrium. Figure A.2 simplifies the process: A city forms its open factor environment system, cultivates its open industrial system and creates its value system by attracting the element, industry and wealth of B and C, using the factor environment of B and C and cooperating with their industries. The value system and industrial system of A city, in global competition, are also element systems which in turn affect the city itself which also applies to city B and C. In the cooperation and competition between cities in factor environment, industrial system and value gains, through the decision and reaction of factor environment, industrial system and value gains, the competitiveness of many cities is decided simultaneously and the pattern is changing constantly. According to the mechanism of city competition and development, the global competitiveness of a city can be understood as the ability of a city, in the process of cooperation, competition and development and compared with other cities, to attract, scramble for, control, and transform resources, occupy market and create value in a Fig. A.2 The determination mechanism of urban economic competitiveness. Source compiled by the author
A Value
C
Industry
B
476
Appendix
Table A.1 The revealed index system of global urban economic competitiveness Content
Data source
Economic increment
1.1 Increment of GDP
The average increment of GDP in five consecutive years 2012–2017, base year 2018, data from EIU
Economic density
1.2 GDP per square kilometers
The total GDP of urban administrative district in 2017 divided by the area, and adjusted by GDP per capita, data from EIU and CCC of CASS
Source CCC of CASS
faster, more efficient and more sustainable way to provide benefits for its residents (Ni PengFei, 2013). According to mechanism and definition, urban economic competitiveness can be divided into revealed (performance or output) competitiveness and composite (interpretative or input) competitiveness. For the economic competitiveness of cities, on the one hand, from the perspective of input, the elements and environment of each city are very different; on the other hand, from the perspective of output, the output of each city, namely the value created, can be compared with the unified standard.
The Revealed Framework and Index System of Economic Competitiveness According to the above definition, competitiveness, from the revealed or output aspect, is mainly expressed as the scale, level and growth of a city in terms of creating value and capturing economic rents within its space scope. According to the index minimization principle, economic density (GDP per capita) is an appropriate indicator of the efficiency and level of value creation, while economic increment (the difference between the current year’s GDP and the previous year’s GDP, considering the stability of the data, taking the average of the increment of the past 5 year’s GDP) is an appropriate indicator of the scale and growth rate of value creation. These two indexes can be used to synthesize an indicator reflecting the explained variables of economic competitiveness (Table A.1).
The Interpretive Framework and Index System of Economic Competitiveness Based on the perspective of the comprehensive environment of the elements and the theoretical model of the national economic cycle, this paper establishes a model of urban competitiveness including six potential variables: GUECJ = βLFJ + γLEJ + δSEJ + εHEJ + GCJ + αIQJ
(1)
Appendix
477
In the above equation, LF refers to local factors, including talents, science and technology and financial factors, is the main force of urban competition and development and the driving force for determining competitiveness. LE stands for living environment, refers to the local demand, reflecting the size of local demand and consumption capacity which is also a driving force of urban competitiveness. SE, soft environment, includes system, culture and social security, which affects the cost of urban production and transaction. HE, hard environment, includes infrastructure and ecological environment, which is the basic condition of doing business and determines the convenience of doing business. GC, global connection, encompasses the soft and hard connections between the city and the external environment, which determines the city’s ability to use external factors and demands. IQ refers to the quality of enterprises, which is the overall status of enterprises and industries of the city, including the status of large enterprises and industrial clusters. Enterprises and industries are the mainstays of urban development and competition. Those 6 variables have different contributions and functions to urban competitiveness, but each is indispensable. This model is centered on the enterprise (industry), taking the internal and external connection as the main line, communication system as the foundation, supply and demand as the content, and integrated the main body and the environment, the supply and demand, the stock and the increment, the software and the hardware, the internal and external and other factors that affect the competitiveness. The above six latent variables refer to six aspects, each of which accommodates many specific urban competitiveness factors. In accordance with the principle of grasping key factors and data availability, this article selects 35 indicators in 6 aspects to construct an interpretive indicator system for urban competitiveness (Table A.2).
Urban Sustainable Competitiveness Determining Mechanism and Definition of Urban Sustainable Competitiveness The decision mechanism of sustainable competitiveness of cities is basically the same as that of economic competitiveness. The difference is that sustainable competitiveness is a long-term mechanism and economic competitiveness is short-term. Therefore, the factors and environment that determine sustainable competitiveness are more fundamental and indirect, while the results of demonstrating urban sustainable competitiveness are more top-level and direct (Fig. A.3). Urban sustainable competitiveness refers to the ability of a city to enhance its advantages in economy, society, ecology, innovation, global connection and other aspects, and to seek systematic optimization to continuously meet the complex and advanced welfare utility of citizens. According to the mechanism and definition, urban sustainable competitiveness can be divided into revealed (performance or output) competitiveness and composition (interpretative or input) competitiveness. For the sustainable competitiveness
Quantity of museums
Medical & Health-care organizations per capita
Calculated by days of comfort temperature, annual precipitation, days of disastrous weather and days of good visibility
Calculated by PM2.5, CO2 emissions per capita and SO2 emissions per capita
The combined proportion of 10 types of land-forms such as forests, lakes, grasslands, rivers, farmland, glaciers and tundra, etc
House price/ income
Quality of Golf course
2.1 Heritage protection
2.2 Medical & Health-care
2.3 Climate comfort
2.4 Environmental pollution
2.5 Ecological diversity
2.6 Cost of living
2.7 Golf Course
Labor force (15–59)
(continued)
Crawler data from Google map
Data from Numbeo
Extraction data
Extraction data
Extraction data
Crawler data from Google map
Crawler data from Google map
Calculated by EIU data
Website search and calculation
Website search and calculation
1.6 Labor force
Quality of patents
1.4 Patent index
2. Living environment
Number of published papers
1.3 Paper index
Website search and calculation
Calculated by EIU data
Calculated by exchange transaction amount data
1.2 Stock exchange index
World Bank
Source
1.5 Youth population Percentage of Youth (20–29) ratio
Credit availability index of Doing Business report revised by city
1.1 Financing convenience
1. Local factors
Indicator content
Secondary indicator
Primary indicator
Table A.2 Global urban economic competitiveness interpretive index system
478 Appendix
Network speed
Distance to Top100 big port
Comprehensive evaluation of infrastructure of airport
Calculated according to the historical data of 6 kinds of natural disasters
4.3 Information accessibility
4.4 Shipping convenience
4.5 Airport index
4.6 Natural Disaster index
Results of Doing Business report adjusted by crawler data of public opinions on city’s business convenience
3.6 Business convenience
Calculated by night light data
Quality of library / city area
3.5 Knowledge density
4.2 Power adequacy
World Intellectual Property Report revised by city
3.4 Property Protection
Numbeo traffic data adjusted by crawler data of public opinions on traffic topic
Calculated by number of Starbucks, McDonald and Walmart
3.3 Cultural inclusion
4.1 Traffic congestion
Index of Economic Freedom revised by city
3.2 Economic freedom
4. Hardware environment
Crime rate
3.1 Social security
3. Software environment
Indicator content
Secondary indicator
Primary indicator
Table A.2 (continued)
(continued)
Columbia University World Bank
Extraction data
Website search and calculation
Crawler data
Extraction data
Numbeo.com Crawler data
World Bank Crawler data
Crawler data from Google map
World Intellectual Property Report
Crawler data from Google map
Index of Economic Freedom report
Data from Numbeo
Source
Appendix 479
Aggregate calculation of HQ distribution data of Forbes’ 2000 enterprises
GDP/labor force (15–59)
Grading of the best university in each city and adjusted by the quality of universities and colleges in each city
6.3 Enterprise connection
6.4 Labor productivity
6.5 University index
Source CCC of CASS
Aggregate calculation of HQ distribution data of top 1000 technology enterprises
6.2 Multinational Technology enterprises
connection degree calculation of distribution data of 25 technology multinational companies
5.5 Technology enterprise connections
Aggregate calculation of HQ distribution data of top 1000 banks
connection degree calculation of distribution data of 75 financial multinational companies Website search and calculation
5.4 Financial enterprise connections
6.1 Multinational Banks
Connection degree calculation of number of cooperative papers published
5.3 Research connections
6. Enterprise quality
Google trends & Baidu trends
5.2 Information connection
Website search and crawler data from Google map
Calculated by EIU data
Website search and calculation
Website search and calculation
Website search and calculation
Website search and calculation
Crawler data
Crawler data
Website search and calculation
Number of air lines
5.1 Airline index
Source
5. Global connections
Indicator content
Secondary indicator
Primary indicator
Table A.2 (continued)
480 Appendix
Appendix
481
Fig. A.3 The determination mechanism of urban sustainable competitiveness. Source compiled by the author
A Populat -oin utility
C
B
Elements
Fundamental environment
of cities, on one hand, from the perspective of input, it is the fundamental environment, with more long-term significance, that determines future development and competition; on the other hand, from the perspective of output, it is the population situation, with more long-term significance, that indicates future competition and development.
The Revealed Framework and Index System of Sustainable Competitiveness According to the definition of sustainability, from the perspective of performance or output, sustainable competitiveness is mainly manifested as the scale, level and growth of a city’s residents’ welfare utility within its space scope. According to the index minimization principle, high-income population density (the average highincome population size) is an appropriate indicator of high welfare utility, while highincome population growth (or the growth rate and size of high-income population, considering the stability of the data, taking the average of the past 5 year’s data) is an appropriate indicator of the scale and growth rate of utility creation. These two indexes can be used to synthesize an indicator reflecting the explained variables of sustainable competitiveness (Table A.3). Table A.3 The revealed indicator system of global urban sustainable competitiveness Content
Data source
High-income 1.1 Annual The average annual growth rate of high-income population from population growth of 2012 to 2017, base year 2018, data from EIU growth high-income population High-income 1.2 The high-income population in the urban administrative region in population High-income 2017 divided by the administrative area, and adjusted by GDP per density population capita. data from EIU and CCC of CASS per squared kilometers Source CCC of CASS
482
Appendix
The Interpretive Framework and Index System of Sustainable Competitiveness According to the above mechanisms and definitions, a sustainable competitive city should be: a vibrant business city; an innovation-driven knowledge city; a socially inclusive harmonious city; an environmentally friendly eco-city; and a globally connected international city. Based on this, a model of urban sustainable competitiveness including five explanatory variables is constructed: GUSCJ = αEVJ + γERJ + δSCJ + βTIJ + ECJ
(2)
From which, GUSCJ , EVJ , ERJ , SCJ , TIJ , ECJ , represent global urban sustainable competitiveness, economic vitality, environmental resilience, social inclusion, technological innovation, and external connections. Economic vitality mainly refers to the entrepreneurial environment and entrepreneurial performance. Economic vitality mainly refers to entrepreneurial environment and entrepreneurial performance, which is the foundation of sustainable competitiveness. Environmental resilience, including ecological environment and infrastructure, is the hardware basis for urban sustainable development. Social inclusion includes a variety of soft environments such as security, integrity, inclusiveness and social order. It reflects the capacity of social mobilization and social integration and is the software foundation for urban sustainable development. Scientific and technological innovation mainly refers to the innovation atmosphere and conditions, which is the ultimate driving force and inexhaustible driving force of urban development. External connections determine the extent to which cities are involved and influenced globally (Table A.4).
Sample Selection and Stratification Definition of City A city in economics refers to a contiguous geographical area with considerable area, economic activity, and household concentration that produces economies of scale in private enterprises and the public sector. A modern city usually refers to a cluster of urban residents with high degree of urbanization. Certainly, different countries and regions have different definitions of the city according to various needs. According to the research needs of this report, the project team defines the city as a combined area including a central city as the core and the surrounding regions. Therefore, the definition of the project team emphasizes the city in the sense of a metropolitan areas, not in the sense of an administrative region. It should be noted that, based on the availability of data, there are only statistical data on the level of administrative regions for some sample cities, such as some sample cities in China. Unless otherwise stated, the sample cities in this paper are all cities in terms of metropolitan area.
Calculated according to the historical data of 6 kinds of natural disasters
(continued)
Columbia University World Bank
Extraction data
2.6 Natural Disaster index
Calculated by days of comfort temperature, annual precipitation, days of disastrous weather and days of good visibility
2.4 Climate comfort
Extraction data
Extraction data
The combined proportion of 10 types of land-forms such as forests, lakes, grasslands, rivers, farmland, glaciers and tundra, etc.
2.3 Ecological diversity
Extraction data
Numbeo.com Crawler data
Calculated by EIU data
Calculated by EIU data
Calculated by EIU data
World Intellectual Property Report
World Bank Crawler data
Source
2.5 Environmental Calculated by PM2.5, CO2 emissions per capita and SO2 emissions per capita pollution
Calculated by night light data
GDP/labor force (15–59)
1.6 Labor productivity
2.2 Power abundance
Economic density (GDP/area) change in 5 years
1.4 Economic density growth
Numbeo traffic data adjusted by crawler data of public opinions on traffic topic
Percentage of Youth (20–29)
1.3 Youth population ratio
2.1 Traffic congestion
World Intellectual Property Report revised by city
1.2 Property Protection
2. Environment resilience
Results of Doing Business report adjusted by crawler data of public opinions on city’s business convenience
1.1 Business convenience
1. Economic vitality
Indicator content
Secondary ndicator
Primary indicator
Table A.4 Global urban sustainable competitiveness interpretive index system
Appendix 483
4. Sci & Tech innovation
Number of published papers
HQ distributions of sic & tech enterprises
Grading of the best university in each city and adjusted by the quality of universities and colleges in each city
Quantity of libraries / city area
4.3 Tech enterprises index
4.4 University index
4.5Knowledge density
Medical & Health-care organizations per capita
3.6 Medical & Health-care
4.2 Paper index
Calculated by number of Starbucks, McDonald and Walmart
3.5 Cultural inclusion
Quantity of patents
House price/ income
3.4 Cost of living
4.1 Patent index
Crawler data from Twitter & Micro-blog
(continued)
Crawler data from Google map
Website search and crawler data from Google map
Website search and calculation
Website search and calculation
Website search and calculation
Crawler data from Google map
Crawler data from Google map
Data from Numbeo
Data from Numbeo
Crawler data from Google map
Gini coefficient
Quantity of museums
Source
3.3 Social equity
3.1Heritage protection
3. Social Inclusion
Indicator content
3.2 Social security Crime rate
Secondary ndicator
Primary indicator
Table A.4 (continued)
484 Appendix
Google trends & Baidu trends
Network speed
Distance to Top100 big port
Number of air lines
Connection degree calculation of number of cooperative papers published
5.2 Information connection
5.3 Info accessibility
5.4 Shipping convenience
5.5Airline index
5.6 Research connections
Source CCC of CASS
Multinational corporations’ connection
5.1 Enterprise connection
5. Global connections
Indicator content
Secondary ndicator
Primary indicator
Table A.4 (continued)
Crawler data
Website search and calculation
Website search and calculation
Crawler data
Crawler data
Website search and calculation
Source
Appendix 485
486
Appendix
Sample Cities The selection of sample cities is the basis for conducting research on urban sustainable competitiveness. In order to ensure the breadth and typicality of the research, the sample cities studied in this project are based on the “World Urbanization Outlook” issued by the United Nations Department of Economics and Affairs in 2015. Excluding samples of urban population less than 500,000, and combined with the specific circumstances of China and some other countries. In the end, 1006 cities were selected. In terms of spatial distribution, samples of this report involve cities in 135 countries and regions from 6 continents. These 1006 cities basically cover cities in different fields and different stages of development in the world today. For specific list of cities and countries, please refer to Chapter 1.
Data Collection The Global Urban Competitiveness Report is a research project that requires high quality and quantity of data. A data collection group and an AI & big data group were set up and started working from April 2019. After nearly half a year of search and collation, it achieved an ideal indicator coverage. The data used in the report mainly comes from four sources, including governmental statistic agencies; international statistic agencies; reports and survey data from international research institutions and companies; big data from web crawlers. For specific information, please refer to Tables A.1, A.2, A.3, and A.4 of the Appendix.
Method of Calculation Method of Index Data Standardization The dimensions of each index data of city competitiveness are different. First, all index data have to be nondimensionalized. Objective indexes are divided into single objective indexes and comprehensive objective indexes. For the nondimensionalization of original data of the single objective indexes, this paper mainly adopts four methods: standardization, indexation, threshold value method and percentage level method. − The standardized calculation formula is: X i = (xiQ−2x) , X i is the converted value of xi , xi is the original data, x is the average value, Q 2 is the variance, and X i is the standardized data. The calculation formula of the exponential method is: X i = xx0ii , X i is the converted value of xi , xi is the original data, x0i is the maximum value, and X i is the exponent.
Appendix
487
i −x Min ) The calculation formula of the threshold value is: X i = (x(xMax− , X i is the x Min ) converted value of xi , xi is the original data, x Max is the largest sample value, and x Min is the smallest sample value。 ni The calculation formula of the percentage level method is: X i = (ni +N , X i is i) the converted value of xi , xi is the original data„ n i is the number of samples with values less then xi , and Ni is the number of sample values greater than or equal to xi except xi . The nondimensionalization of synthesizing the raw data of objective indexes is: first, to quantify the individual indexes in the composition, and then weight the comprehensive index value by means of the equal weight method.
Calculation Method of Variable of Urban Competitiveness Calculation Method of Revealed Variable of Economic and Sustainable Competitiveness In terms of economic density: taking into account the deviation of GDP per squared kilometers, the annual GDP per capita of the current year is used as the correction factor to carry out the non-linear weighted comprehensive correction. The so-called nonlinear weighted synthesis method (or "multiplication" synthesis method) refers wj x j for comprehensive evaluation. to the application of nonlinear models g = Therein w j is the weight coefficient and x j represents the relevant indicator. Regarding the economic increment: considering the volatility of economic growth, the index was expressed as the average of the past five years GDP increment. In terms of high-income population density: taking into account the deviation of the average number of high-income population, the annual GDP per capita of the current year is used as the correction factor to carry out the non-linear weighted comprehensive correction. The so-called nonlinear weighted synthesis method (or “multiplication” synthesis method) refers to the application of nonlinear models w g = x j j for comprehensive evaluation. Therein w j is the weight coefficient and x j represents the relevant indicator. Regarding the high-income population growth: considering the fluctuation of population growth and negative population growth, the index is composited with standardized population size of sample cities in the base year and the standardized population growth rate in the past 5 consecutive years.
Calculation Method of Interpretative Variable of Economic and Sustainable Competitiveness Although the interpretative indexes of urban competitiveness designed in the report are secondary index, in fact, including the original index, the system of interpretative urban competitiveness index has 3 levels. When the tertiary index synthesizes the secondary index and the secondary index synthesizes the primary index, the method
488
Appendix
of standardization and equal weight addition is adopted. The standardization method is described above. Its formula is: z il = z il j j
where, z il represents each of the secondary indexes, and z il j represents each of the tertiary indexes. Zi =
z il
l
where, Z i represents each of the primary indexes, and z il represents each of the secondary indexes.
Special Statements The global urban competitiveness assessment system is based on the research model of Chinese urban competitiveness report by Dr. Ni Pengfei and combined with the latest trend of urban development in the world. However, the global competitiveness assessment system and measurement methods are different from the China urban competitiveness report.
Afterwords
The Global Urban Competitiveness Report 2019–2020 (GUCR) is a joint work by nearly 100 experts from Chinese and foreign universities, authoritative statistical agencies and R&D departments of companies. The year-long project was initiated by Dr. Ni Pengfei from National Academy of Economic Strategy, CASS and Marco Kamiya of UN-HABITAT. The theoretical framework, indicator system, research framework and conclusions of the Global Urban Competitiveness Report 2019–2020 were decided by Dr. Ni Pengfei and Marco Kamiya. Mr. Guo Jing, Deputy Editor-inChief from School of Government Management (Shenzhen University) was responsible for project coordination, data collection and processing and summary. He also written a part of the report. As for urban competitiveness, this report divides into two parts: economic competitiveness and sustainable competitiveness, and designs different index systems to measure the economic competitiveness and sustainable competitiveness of 1,006 cities around the world. Based on the relationship between global city competitiveness and municipal finance, this report has prepared the theme report of global municipal finance experience and methods. The draft of the report is written by the author after refining the theory, collecting data, measuring and drawing conclusions. The contributors of each chapter are: Chapter 1: Ranking of Global Urban Competitiveness 2019, collectively organized by the research group; Chapter 2: The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion, Ni Pengfei, Li bo (Tianjin University of Technology), Ma Hongfu (Tianjin University of Finance and Economics), Xu Haidong (National Academy of Economic Strategy, CASS); Chapter 3: Experience and Methods of Global Municipal Financing, Marko Kamia (UN-Habitat), Liz Paterson Guntner (UN-habitat), Serge Allou (UCLG World Secretariat), Luc Aldon (UCLG World Secretariat), Huáscar Eguino (IDB), Axel Radics (IDB), Mosha.A.C (University of Botswana), Martim O. Smolka (Senior fellow of Lincoln Institute of Land Policy); Chapter 4: Global Urban Economic Competitiveness Performance, Xu haidong (National Academy of Economic Strategy, CASS); Chapter 5: Explanatory indicators of Global Urban Economic Competitiveness, Gong Weijin (National
© China Social Sciences Press 2023 P. Ni et al., The World: 300 Years of Urbanization Expansion, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-99-3553-6
489
490
Afterwords
Academy of Economic Strategy, CASS); Chapter 6: Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness Performance Guo Jinhong (School of Economics, Nankai University); Chapter 7: Explanatory indicators of Global Urban Sustainable Competitiveness, Li qihang (Shandong University of Finance and Economics); Chapter 8: A New Set of Standards for Global City Classification, Cao qingfeng (Tianjin University of Finance and Economics), Guo Jinhong (School of Economics, Nankai University); Appendix: Ni pengfei, Guo Jing (School of Government Management, Shenzhen University). The measurement data of the whole report was completed by the research group under the leadership of Ni Pengfei. Last but not least, we would like to express our gratitude to all entities and individuals involved in the support for their support and contribution. Marco Kamiya, Ni Pengfei Nonmember 3, 2019