Neoliberal resilience: lessons in democracy and development from Latin America and Eastern Europe 9780691201603


225 22 23MB

English Pages [365] Year 2020

Report DMCA / Copyright

DOWNLOAD PDF FILE

Table of contents :
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_001_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_002_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_002_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_003_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_003_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_004_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_004_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_005_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_005_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_006_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_006_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_007_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_007_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_008_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_008_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_009_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_009_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_010_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_010_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_011_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_011_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_012_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_012_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_013_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_013_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_014_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_014_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_015_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_015_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_016_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_016_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_017_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_017_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_018_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_018_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_019_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_019_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_020_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_020_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_021_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_021_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_022_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_022_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_023_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_023_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_024_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_024_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_025_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_025_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_026_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_026_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_027_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_027_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_028_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_028_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_029_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_029_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_030_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_030_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_031_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_031_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_032_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_032_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_033_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_033_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_034_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_034_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_035_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_035_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_036_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_036_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_037_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_037_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_038_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_038_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_039_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_039_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_040_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_040_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_041_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_041_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_042_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_042_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_043_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_043_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_044_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_044_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_045_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_045_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_046_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_046_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_047_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_047_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_048_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_048_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_049_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_049_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_050_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_050_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_051_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_051_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_052_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_052_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_053_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_053_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_054_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_054_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_055_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_055_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_056_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_056_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_057_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_057_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_058_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_058_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_059_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_059_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_060_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_060_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_061_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_061_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_062_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_062_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_063_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_063_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_064_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_064_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_065_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_065_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_066_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_066_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_067_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_067_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_068_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_068_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_069_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_069_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_070_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_070_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_071_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_071_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_072_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_072_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_073_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_073_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_074_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_074_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_075_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_075_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_076_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_076_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_077_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_077_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_078_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_078_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_079_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_079_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_080_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_080_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_081_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_081_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_082_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_082_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_083_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_083_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_084_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_084_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_085_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_085_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_086_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_086_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_087_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_087_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_088_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_088_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_089_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_089_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_090_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_090_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_091_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_091_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_092_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_092_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_093_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_093_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_094_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_094_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_095_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_095_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_096_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_096_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_097_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_097_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_098_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_098_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_099_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_099_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_100_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_100_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_101_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_101_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_102_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_102_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_103_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_103_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_104_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_104_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_105_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_105_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_106_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_106_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_107_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_107_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_108_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_108_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_109_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_109_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_110_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_110_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_111_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_111_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_112_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_112_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_113_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_113_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_114_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_114_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_115_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_115_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_116_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_116_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_117_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_117_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_118_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_118_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_119_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_119_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_120_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_120_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_121_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_121_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_122_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_122_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_123_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_123_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_124_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_124_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_125_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_125_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_126_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_126_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_127_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_127_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_128_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_128_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_129_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_129_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_130_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_130_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_131_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_131_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_132_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_132_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_133_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_133_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_134_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_134_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_135_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_135_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_136_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_136_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_137_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_137_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_138_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_138_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_139_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_139_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_140_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_140_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_141_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_141_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_142_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_142_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_143_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_143_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_144_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_144_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_145_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_145_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_146_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_146_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_147_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_147_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_148_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_148_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_149_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_149_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_150_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_150_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_151_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_151_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_152_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_152_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_153_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_153_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_154_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_154_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_155_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_155_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_156_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_156_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_157_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_157_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_158_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_158_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_159_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_159_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_160_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_160_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_161_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_161_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_162_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_162_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_163_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_163_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_164_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_164_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_165_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_165_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_166_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_166_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_167_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_167_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_168_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_168_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_169_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_169_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_170_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_170_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_171_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_171_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_172_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_172_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_173_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_173_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_174_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_174_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_175_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_175_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_176_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_176_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_177_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_177_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_178_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_178_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_179_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_179_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_180_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_180_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_181_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_181_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_182_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_182_2R
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_183_1L
2020 Madariaga - Neoliberalism resilience_Página_183_2R
Recommend Papers

Neoliberal resilience: lessons in democracy and development from Latin America and Eastern Europe
 9780691201603

  • 0 0 0
  • Like this paper and download? You can publish your own PDF file online for free in a few minutes! Sign Up
File loading please wait...
Citation preview

Neoliberal Resilience LESSONS IN DEMOCRACY AND DEVELOPMENT FROM LATIN AMERlCA AND EASTERN EUROPE

ALDO MADARIAGA

PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PllESS PllINCETON Õ' OXFORD

Copyright O l.020 by Princeton University Press

llequesu for permiss!on to reproduce material from th!s wor:k should be sent to permissions@prublicity: Kate Farquhar-Thomson, Kate Hensley Copyeditor: Jzy Boggis

-Àcket/Cover Credit: Shutterstock

"lhis book has been composed in Arno ..:Fnnted on acid-free paper. oo

~ted in the United States ofAmerica ..:ILCl ·9 8 7 6

s

4 3 .. 1

CU\l/E PROVEEDOR:

LLS t1 &

No. DE FACTU~A:

~ ';s-o

No. DE Sl3Ti=:/..k

d f 3 ;i_ 'i /..IJ

H8 'lJ" ___ H335

CLASIF!Cf,C;Oi'I:

(ai_

~po Jc!J8

To Malú, Domingo, and Matilde

200308 CONTENTS

Preface ix 1

The Puzzling Resilience ofNeoliberalism

2

Ex.plaining the Resilience ofNeoliberalism

25

3 Neoliberal Policies and SupportingActors

51

4 Neoliberal Resilience and the Crafting of Social Blocs

5 Creating Support: Privatization and Business Power

135

6 Blocking Opposition: Political Representation and Limited Democracy

176

7 Locking-in Neoliberalism: Independent Central Banks and

8

Fiscal Spending Rules

216

Lessons: Neoliberal Resilience and the Future ofDemocracy

249

List oflnterviews Bibliography

btdex 315

269 273

PREFACE

Chile went through the most extreme moment of political turmoil since Pinochet's dictatorship. During the last two weeks of October 2019, the world saw images of Chilean streets crammed by protestors, metro stations on fire, crowds looting supermarkets, and military forces deployed throughout the country-an image that revived the troubled 197os in everyone's memory. This carne as a surprise to manywho saw Chile as a poster child of free markets and di:mocratic stability. ln fact, liberal elites worldwide have exhaustively cited the Chilean example in order to justify neoliberalism and rnarket-conforming econorri.ic reforms. Much of this praise is based on objective i.mprovements: almost uninterrupted economic growth, controlled inflation and nscal accounts, rapidly falling poverty rates and Latin America's highest income _per capita; a stable party system, strong institutions, low corruption leveis, and low levels of civil unrest-all of which helped the country lead economic and political freedom rankings. For ordinary Chilean citizens, however, the rise in Santiago's metro fare that sparked the protests carne as the strawthat broke the camel's back. ln fact, the motto quickly becarne "it is not about 30 pesos [ the amount of the fare rise equivalent to less than USD 5 cents] ... it is about 30 years." Against this backdrop, one must think about what lies beneath Chile's "awakening" and what it means in tennsofthe troubled relationship between neoliberalisrn and democracy. The key to understanding "Chile's awakening," as·many have observed, is its extreme inequalities. 1he best-known part of this are Chile's extreme socioeconomic inequalities embed.ded in the country's neoliberal development model, which has produced stark income and wealth concentration, privatized social services, and extreme urban segregation. Equally significant, although less known, are Chile's stark political inequalities and outright deficits in democratic representation, which are also directly connected with neoliberalism as I demonstrate in this book. BETWEEN LATE 2019 AND l!ARLY 2010,

ix

X

PR.EFACE

Chile's transition to democracy was, to put it mildly, peculiar. Chile retumed to democracy with a political constitution written by Pinochet and voted for under a state of siege. Through a series of institutional mechanisms that I carefully analyze-among which, electoral laws and malapportionment, unelected veto players, congressional supermajorities for key legislation-the Pinochet Constitution granted a quasi-permanent veto power to the proPinochet business and political elite. Chile's political system not only blocked representation for those who demanded more transformative changes, but also helped demobilize society, disconnect parties from their voters, and ultimately detach the political elite from the general public. We now know that this constrained democracy was nota peculiarity of the Chilean case but a core part of the global neoliberal political project Limiting democracy has been the best way of safeguarding neoliberalism from its opponents. And for more than thirty years, this was successful in Chile. ln this context, the country's months-long "awakening" shows the limits and longterrn effects of a constrained democracy and the perils of Chilean-style neoliberal modernization, providing important lessons for those countries that have followed its example. After months of intense demonstrations that included a constitutional "state of emergency," the toll is as encouraging as tragic. October 25 2.019 wi1l be remembered as "Chile's largest march," when dose to a fifth of the country's population-between 1.2and1.5 millionin the capital alone-protested to the chant of"Oh, Chile has woken up!" demanding that the military return to the barracks as well as substantive policy and política! changes. Demonstrators were able to force into the public debate severa! topics that were outside the goverrunent program of right-wing president Sebastián Piiiera but that remained longstanding demands among the population, namely, reforrns to Chile's privatized and highly segregated pension, healthcare, and education systems, and a referendum to decide whether to change or maintain the current Constitution passed during Pinochet's dictatorship. As this book goes to press, Chileans are deciding on the future of their política! and institutional system as never before in the country's republica.ll history. Moreover, if the "approve" vote wins, it will be the first l!iJne that the country's political constitution has been written by a constitutional assem.bly either partially or entirely composed by people elected especially for that task. lt is not hard to foresee the possibility of a profound transformation of the country's political and economic order under these conditions.

PB.EPACE

xi

At the sarne time, however, following the October events repression by the police and military has reached leveis unseen in democratic times. Thousands~ of protesters have been wounded and tens of thousands arrested. Four international independent human rights organizations visited the country ( the United Nations High Commissioner for Human Rights, the Interamerican Human Rights Commission, Amnesty Intemational, and Human Rights Watch) confirming "regularn and ·serious" human rights abuses against protesters and detainees and urging the government to reform the police.' As of January 2019, the National Institute for Human Rights presented more than one thousand judicial actions against the country's security forces, including allegations of torture, rape, and murder.• As of today, police abuses continue while protests maintain their frequencyand radicalness. ln this scenario, rightwing groups have been calling on the government for .firmer action against rioters and to boycott the constitutional referendum under grounds that the state cannot guarantee social order. They also appeal to middle- and lowerclass voters who fail to see the connection between the change of the Constitution and the rapid amelioration of their immeruate socioeconomic conditions and play on their fear that transforming the country's çore institutions will only worsen their already fragile situation. Consequently, four months after the start of the protests, in February 2020 no significant advances had been made in the "social agenda" of reforms while new laws condemning protestors and increasing repression capacities were under way. lt is clear that Chile has finallywoken up after along neoliberal night. What is less clear is the future it has woken up to. Although it seems unlikely that the For the respective reports, see "Report of the Mission to Chilet 30 October-22 November United Nations Hwnan Rights, Of!ice ofthe High Commissioner, https:/ /www.ohchr .org/Documents/Countries/CL/Report_Crule_2011,)_EN.pdf; "Chile: Deliberate Policy to Injure Protesters Points to Responsibility of 'Ih.ose in Command,· Amnesty Intemational, https:/ /www.amnesty.org/ en/latest/ news/2019 November chile-responsable-politica-deliberada-para-danar-manifestantes/; "IACHR Condemns the Excessive Use ofF01ce during Social Protests in·Chile, Expresses Its Grave Concem atthe High Number o.fReported Human Rights Violations, and Rejects All Fonns ofViolence,• Inter-American Commission on Hum.an Rights, http:/ /www.oas.org/ en/iachr/media_ center/PReleases/2019 /317.asp; •Chile: Police Refonns Needed in the Wake of Protests," Human Rights Watch, https:/ /www.hrw.org/news/2019/11 /26/chile-police-reforms-needed-wake-protests. 2 Naomi Larsson, •Beaten, Mutilated and Forced to Undress: Inside Chile's Brutal Police Crackdown against Protesters,• Independent, january :16, 2020, https://www.independent. co.uk/news/world/americas/chile-protest-police-violence-nudity-human-rights-a92946S6 .html. 1

2019,•

Xii

PRBPACB

countrywill rapidly fall into chaos and ungovemability, it is equally unlikely that its leaders will respond in a timely and effective manner to the demands from the street. The quest for a middle ground may bring light-a revitalized dernocracy and a new development model under a new social and political pact-but also more shadow-renewed democratic constraints shielding neoliberalism and extending its morbid consequences. ln this fluid but highly consequential scenario, this book offers keys to understand the mechanisms underpinning the resilience of neoliberalism and what we can expect from attempts at radically altering them through democratic means. Beyond this unexpected tum of events, and thinking about the parallelism between the Chilean story and that of other countries at the other end of the world, it is good to remember how the interest in the relationship between neoliberalism and democracy carne aboul ln many ways, I started writing this book in 2008 when 1 visited EastCentral Europe for the fust time. I had just finished a fixed employment contract at the United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (ECLAC) in Santiago, Chile, where 1 worked analyzing social policy in Latin America and got more acquainted with the organization's history and discourse on dependency and development. 'Ihere, 1understood that the concem over social policy should not overlook a bigger and more fundamental concem for economic structures as a crucial elemen~ determining the possible pattems of economic and social development. This got me interested in other economic policies, notably industrial policy. ln August of that year 1 travelled with my friend Mario Acufia, to Prague, Cracow, Bratislava, Budapest, and Zagreb. 1was quickly intrigued by the strange feeling of new and old, progress and decay, hope and despair. This experience, and encouragement from Manuel Riesco, motivated me to enroll in a Masters program at the Central European University in Budapest in 2010-2ou-with the bep.efit ofhindsight, a life-changing experience. ln Budapest, 1 became aware of the relationship between Latin America and Eastern Europe in terms of development, and the possible links with Latin American ECLAC-based structuralist and dependency schools. A couple of years later, while on parental leave for the birth of my son Domingo, 1 carne across a book by Ivan Berend on Eastem Europe's history of economic dependency, its embrace of communism as a way out of it, and its retum to the periphery of capitalism after the fall of communism. 1 remember feeling itwas a closing of a circle-or perhaps the start of a new one.

Plll!PACE

xiü

1his book was made possible by the help, encouragement, and support of many people. I would like to start by thanking the three people who have been, crucial sources of inspiration and support for this project. Wolfgang Streeck believed in this project from the first moment. His critica! scholarship and engaged research have been a constant sowce of leaming. Becoming acquainted with Béla Greskovits's work on the political economy of policy reforms and development and bis comparison between Eastem Europe and Latin America made all this start to happen. Béla's writings with Dorothee Bohle have provided a key benchmark for comparativists of capitalist diversity outside the· capitalist core. Not least, Doro's advice and encouragement, and her perceptive criticism, have been a constant source of intellectual challenge and stimulus. Parts of this book were presented and received valuable feedback at different stages at the REPAL Conference ( 2013), the University !Jf Tallinn ( 2013 ), the European University lnstitute (2018), the Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies (2018), the Polish Acaderny of Sciences {2018), and the Political Econorny Rese~ch Group (PERG) at the Central European University ( 2018). A nwnber of people read parts of the argument at different points in time, and some took the time to read and comment on entire chapters and even the whole manuscript: thanks to Bruno Amable, Juan Bogliaccini, Dorothee Bohle, Tomás Bril-Mascarenhas, Lászlo Bruszt,Juan Carlos Castillo, Sebastián Etchemendy, Carlos Freytes, Béla Greskovits, Juan Pablo Luna, Antoine Maillet, Daniel Mertens, Cristóbal Rovira Kaltwasser, Eduardo Silva, Alex Spielau, Tomás Undurraga, Wolfgang Streeck, Anna Z:ibkowicz, and Zbigniew Zólkiewski for their insightful comments and suggestions. Others took the time to share impressions on the content and form of this work at clifferent stages, including SabinaAvdagic,JensBeckert, Martin Hõpner,Julius Horvath, Guglielmo Meardi, Eduardo Olivares, Gabriel Palma, and Ben Ross Schneider. Many other people contributed directly or indirectly to the :final product. My younger brother Andrés Madariaga provided truly invaluable support and research assistance for chapter 3; Carlos Sandov.U, Sebastián Zarricueta (INE Chile), and Leandro Cabello (ECLAC) helped with data issues, while Ewelina Laskowska helped with Polish translations. Marcin Serafin, Lukasz Pawlowski, and Alo Raun helped navigate the vagaries of Polish and Estonian politics and sodety. Sofia Rivera provided superb editing assistance. During my field research in Eastem Europe and Latin America, several people helped me get in touch with scholars and public figures, contacts that

:riv

PREFACE

helped me gain access to other high policymaking positions. For this 1thank Daniela Astudillo1 Zosia Boni1 Michal Boni, Jorge Cauas, Ingrid Gerling, Rosario Montero, Marcin Serafin1 Lukasz Pawlowski, Alo Raun, Alan Sikk, Aleks Szczerbiak, Lüsa Talvig, andMiguel Torres. Nicolás Chemywas kind enough to give me access to the Archivos de Historia Oral (AHO) interview archive at the Gino Germani Institute in Buenos Aires. Sharing fieldwork in Argentina with Raimundo Frei was an experience in itself Some of the material presented here has appeared in two published articles: "Mechanisms ofNeoliberal Resilience: Comparing Exchange Rates and Industrial Policy in Chile and Estonia," Socio-Economic Review 15 (3): 637-660; and "Business Power and the Minimal State: The Defeat oflndustrial Policy in Chile," The Journal of Development Studies 55( 6): 1047-1066, with Tomás Bril-Mascarenhas. Although this book expands and revises this material and puts it in the context of a different theoretical focus, I thank the joumals involved and my co-author Tomás Bril-Mascarenhas for their permission to reproduce extracts of them here. This book is partly based on my PhD studies at the Max Planck Institute for the Study ofSocieties in Cologne, Germany, between 2011 and 2015. During my stay at the Max Planck, 1benefited from the good friendship and excellent scholarly advice of a number of colleagues. Special thanks to Jens Beckert, Helen Callaghan, Matias Dewey, Lea Elsãsser, Nina Engwicht, Timur Ergen, lrina Espalia, Felipe González, Martin Hõpner, Annette Hübschle, Daniel Mertens, Markus Lang, Mardn Serafin, Christine Trampusch, Christian Tribowski, Annin Schãfer, and Wolfgang Streeck for their support. Jürgen Lautwein and Susanne Hilbring provided superb financial and library resources. The first draft of the book was completed at the Centro de Investigación y Docencia Econónúcas ( CIDE) in Mexico City, which provided excellent research facilities anda friendly academic environment Manythanks to Bianca Heredia and my colleagues at the Programa Interdisciplinario sobre Política y Prácticas Educativas (PIPE) for making my stay in Mexico a most pleasant one. Research funding for this project carne from the Max Planck Society and in the later stages, from the Center for Social Conflict and Cohesion Studies (COES) (ANID/FONDAP/15130009) andfromaANID-MaxPlanck.Society joint research project (ANID /PCI/MAX PLANCK INSTITUTE FORTHE STUDY OF SOCIETIES/MPG190012). The Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies and the Max: Planck Partner Group for the Sociology of Econonú e Life funded a short research stay to present rny book in September

PREFACE

XV

Budapest, and Warsaw. Finally, I thank Sarah Caro and Hannah Paul from Princeton University Press for supporting this project and guid-_ ing me through it. My deepest gratitude goes to my family, who encouraged me to leave home to explore new horizcins, but always with an eye towards retuming and telling my story. To myparents who taught me the importance ofhard work and most especially, to mywife Malú, and my children Domingo and Matilde, who provided the inspirational touch. They are what keep me in motion. 2018 in Cologne,

Mexico City and Santiago, January 2019 and February 2020

NEOLIBERAL RESILIENCE

1

The Puzzling Resilience of Neoliberalism As you will understand, it is possible for a dictator to govem in a liberal way. And it is also possible for a democracy to govem with a total lack of liberalism. Personally, I prefer aliberal dictator to a democratic government lacking in liberalism. -P.A. HAYEK TO A REPORTBR. Q.UOTED IN FAJl.RANT 1 MCPHAIL, AND BEl.GER 20U 1 521

DURING THE LATE AFTERNOON of September 71 1986, a militarized cell from the Chilean Commwúst Party tried to k.ill General Augusto Pinochet. Pinochet was known worldwide for having participated in the bloody putsch against the democratically elected president Salvador Allende in 1973, and as the leader of the repressive military dictatorship that ensued and th.at backed the first large-scale experiment in neoliberal policymaking in the world On that September aftemoon, the Com.munist cell attacked Pinochet's convoy with heavy artillery as he was returning from his country l;iouse near Santiago. Five agents of Pinochet's guard were killed and another eleven severely wounded. Pinochet escaped almost wiscathed. Although this was without doubt hís most remarkable escape, it was far from the only challenge Pinochet survived Years before the assassination attempt, in the mid-197os Pinochet explicitly broke the pact of succession in what was then a military junta, successfully maneuvering to oust the other members of the junta and instituting a series of regulations that made him the

l

CHAPTEll 1

dictatorship's strongman. lt was a true "coup inside the coup" (Valdivia 2003). Not only this: he devised a constitutional formula for government succession that secured his long-term oversight of Chilean politics even in the event of a return to democracy. Two years after the assassination attempt, in October 1988, a united political opposition-wíth the help of intemational pressure-defeated Pinochet in a referendum, forcing a return to democratic rule after seventeen years of dictatorship. However, even as the new authorities took ofli.ce, Pinochet managed to remain commander-in-chief of the army for another ten years, controlling the process of dernocratization through the constant menaces of a military takeover. Ten years later, in September 1998, Pinochet was captured in London and faced extradition to Spain, where he was charged with the morder of Spanish citizens during his dictatorship. After two years of legal procedures, the British authorities released Pinochet, alleging that the former strongmannow 84 and wíth visible signs of physical and mental deterioration-could not stand a trial. But when Pinochet returned to Santiago, he stood up from his wheelchair, greeted his fanatic followers with his walking sticlc, and walked out of the airport, to the astonishment ofthe local and international press. He lived cornfortably in his mansion in Santiago until he died seven years later. lhe association between a political system based on permanent repression anda public philosophy premised on the idea ofindividualliberty has puzzled scholars ever since the Chilean experience under Pinochet. Some of the most ardent supporters of neoliberalism have felt compelled to excuse, on theoretical grounds, such an embarrassing historical coincidence. After advising the Chilean military junta in 1975, Milton Friedman argued that economic liberalization was a precondition for political liberalization, and that political freedom was in tum necessary for the long-term maintenance of economic freedom, therefore highlighting the temporary nature of Pinochet's rule (Friedman 1982). Others, however, have felt that the two are much more intertwíned than commonly thought. Thus1 for Friedrich Hayek a limited dictatorship was a better safeguard for individual liberty than an unlirnited democracy (Farrant, Mcphail, ;md Berger 2012). ln this book largue that the connection between neoliberal economics and less-than-liberal political regimes is not only a philosophical digression but is in fact rooted in history. Pinochet's story conveys, if somewhat cruelly, the idea that neoliberalism's durability is not just abou t good or bad economic policymaking: the countries

THI! PUZZLING Rl!SILI.BNCE OF NEOLIBBllALISM

3

where neoliberalism has survived the longest are those that designed their democratic institutions in such a way as to constrain the possibilityof switch- ,~ ing to other policies. ln this sense, the Chileanneoliberal trajectorywas nota peculiarity, but part of a political project with diverse historical experiences supporting the idea that protecting free markets-and its beneliciariesrequired encroaching on democracy. 1his book joins several recent works that show the connection between constrained democracies and the neoliberal political project ( Slobodian 2018; Maclean 2017 ). We know nowthat since its beginnings, the neoliberal thought collective found democracy-a political system giving voice to the masses and incentivizing the competition for their vote-to be the main threat to its political project Not only this: as Slobodian convincingly argues, neoliberalism "developed precisely as a response to the growth of mass democracy" (2018, 34). Unlike these works, this book is not an exercise in the history of neoliberal thinking about democracy; rather, it studies the politics behind neoliberalism's continuity over time-its resilience-as a process intimately connected with the gradual erosion of democracy. lt tracks neoliberal resilience and democratic erosion in four Latin American and Eastern European countries with diverse trajectories: Argentina, Chile, Estonia, and Poland. 1 argue that neoliberalism remained resilient where it was able to reduce the representative component of democracy, maintaining free and competitive elections but bending the policy outcomes of those elections to the maintenance of neoliberalism. Neoliberalism survived in its purest form in those countries where it was protectedfrom democracy. 1 Resilience, a concept commonly associated with engineering science, psychology, and community studies, denotes the capacity of an object, person, or group to withstand external perturbations (Madariaga 20171 n. i; Schmidt and Thatcher 2013, 13-16). The typical response of a resilient body is to alter some of its properties in order to accommodate the externai perturbation without changing its core composition and nature. In the case of neolibenlism, the concept of resilience has been used to describe neoliberalism's "ctmtinuity ... over time, its dominance over competitors, and its survival against powerful 1. A review of The Calculus of Consent, one of the key books of James Buchanan, the founder of the Virginia school of neoüberalism, in the joumal of the Cato Institute praised it precisely for offering guidance on ªprotecting capitalism from democracy" (MacLean 20171 81 ). We will come back at lhe key role of Buchanan's thinking in this story of neoliberal resilience in chapter :i..

4

CHAPTBR l

challenges and rivalsn (Schmidt and Thatcher 20131 xvii). 2 Books aboµt the resilience of neoliberalism (particularly those published after the 2007-2008 crisis) tend to focus on overarching trends; 1 instead establish the limits of neoliberalim's resilience through a clear operationalization of its policy goals and concrete policy altematives (see Crouch 2011; Duménil and Lévy 2011; Grauwe 2017; Kotz 2015; Mirowski 2013). l identifywhich countries maintained their neoliberal trajectories over time, when they departed from neoliberalism's core dictates, and whether those departures were enduring or not. ln addition, unlike the focus of most works on advanced capitalist economies, l argue that to analyze the resilience of neoliberalism it is important to look outside the capitalist core, particularly at the history of over three decades of neoliberalism in Latin America and Eastem Europe. As will become clear, the specific conditions under which neoliberalism was adopted in these regions facilitated the connection between resilient neoliberalism and constrained democracy. 1 demonstrate that cop.nection in three ways. First, 1 study the actors and coalitions that supported the establishment of neoliberalism and defended its continuity over time, using a mixed quantitative and qualitative strategy (chapters 3 and 4). Second, I investigate the mechanisms that eroded democracy and allowed these actors to maintain their grip on public policy changes (chapters 5, 6, and 7). Here, 1 contrast cases where neoliberalism remained resilient (Chile and Estonia) with cases where it was contested and even temporarily replaced (Poland and Argentina). Finally, 1 consider the consequences ofthe continued resilience of neoliberalism for the future of democracy. By doing this, 1 engage with the current literature on the crisis of democracy, the rise of populism, and their relationship with neoliberal economics, reflecting on how different experiences of neoliberal resilience pose different threats and paths toward democratic erosion. Neoliberalism's resilience-and contestation of the neoliberal projectradically altered these four countries' patterns ofdemocratic competition and representation, generating specific paths toward democratic hollowing and/ or backsliding.3 Understanding the specific paths by which neoliberalism eroded democratic institutions, and how domestic political actors reacted to those erosions, is crucial to understanding how populist movements are tak2. For a diJferent usage associated with the resilience ofsocieties tó neoliberalism, see Hall and Lamont (2013). 3- For the foanulation of the hollowing of democracy, see Mair (1013). Greskovits (1015) provides an insightful discossion differentiating democracy's "hollowing" from its "backsliding.•

THE PUZZLlNG RESILIENCB OP NEOLJBBRALISM

S

ing root today, and whether populism threatens democracy or has the potential to cure it (see Mair 2013; Mudde and Rovira Kaltwasser 2013b; Rovira Kaltwasser 2014). 'lhe rest of this introduction proceeds as follows. First, I define what I understand by neoliberalism and state the problem of neoliberalism.'s resilience in length, the puzzlement that arose after the events that followed the 2.007-2008 financial aisis, and justify my focus on the Latin American and Eastem European experiences. Second, I develop the book's argument about the connection between neoliberalism's resilience and the erosion of democracy. ln tum, 1show howthis argument contributes to the existing literature on neoliberalism. Finally, I describe the book's methodological aspects and structure.

The "Strange Non-Death" ofNeoliberalism4 What Is Neoliberalism? Neoliberalism is an oft-invoked but ill-defined concept (Boas and Gans-Morse 2.009; Cahill and Konings 2017; Crouch 2.011; Connell and Dados 2014-; Maillet 2015; Steger and Roy 2010 ). While it is useful and neces5ary to understand some of the most pressing problems of contemporary societies and economies, the polysemy of the concept makes it necessary to define clearly what we understand by it before undertaking an empirical study. ln tum, I analyze three com.mon definitions of neoliberalism, their respective foci when analyzing neoliberalism's continuity or resilience, and justify my own choice. One fust definition of neoliberalism understands it as a policy paradigm, that is, as "a framework of ideas and standards that speci.6.es ... the goals of policy ... the kind ofinstrurnents that can be used to attain them, ... [and the] nature of the problems they are meant to be addressingD (Hall 19931 279). Following this, Comei Ban refers to neoliberalism as a "set ofhistorically contingent and intellectually hybrid" ( 2016, 10) economic ideas, including prescriptions from neoclassical economics, monetarism, and supply-side economics, that aim at increasing the power of markets-and the corporations operating in them-in the allocation of goods and services and the reduction of discretionary govemment interventions to make them credible with market actors. Neoliberalism does not preclude State intervention, and often even requires it; however, it gives business ( epitomized as impersonal "markets") the power to decide which interventions are desirable and which are not. 4. See Crouch {1011).

6

CHAPTER 1

For less developed economies, neoliberalism has been associated with promoting policies that "get the prices right: ln other words, they open markets, eliminate price distortions and regulations, and bar discretionary government intervention in the economy through tariffprotections, industrial policies, and state ownership of companies (see Plehwe 2009; Saad-Filho 2005; Wtlliamson 199ob). Authors working with this definition of neoliberalism tend to look at the factors affecting the survival of neoliberal ideas over time when analyzing neoliberalism's resilience (Ban 2016; Blyth 2013; Mirowski 2013; Schmidt and Thatcher 2013). An alternative to this approach conceives neoliberalism as a policy regime: it is the set of policies in the neoliberal paradigm that are embedded in the interests ofspecific societal groups or classes in specific national contexts (Cahill 2014; Crouch 2011; Streeck 2014; Wylde 2012). 1his definition of neoliberalism requires an understanding of the societal actors and coalitions who benefit from it and give it their political support lt seelcs to explain neoliberalism's resilience in terms of the political-institutional characteristics and incentives of party systems that mak.e coalitions more or less prone to rnaintaining neoliberal policies over time (Flores-Macias 2012; Madariaga 2017; Roberts 2015)1 and business-state relations that increase the influence of neoliberal businesses in policymaking (Bril-Mascarenhas and Madariaga 2019; Bril-Mascarenhas and Maillet 2019; Culpepper 2010; Fairfield 2015a; Hacker and Pierson 2010 ). Yet a third treatment of neoliberalism comes from Marxist analyses that understand it as a transnational class project (Duménil and Lévpou; Harvey 2007). Authors following this tradition trace the links between the ascendance of neoliberalism to a worldwide hegemonic paradigm, the parallel reconfiguration of class relations beyond national states irlto supranational busirless networks following the crisis of advanced capitalism in the 197os, and the establishment of neoliberalism as state policy (see Carroll and Sapinski 2016; Cox 1987; Robinson and Harris 2000; Sklair 2001). Recent accounts putting emphasis on the history of neoliberal ideas trace the origins of the neoliberal political project to the postwar period-some even as early as the dissolution of the Habsburg empire after World War I (Jones 2012; Slobodian 2018; Mirowski and Plehwe 2009). Here, the issue of the resilience of neoliberalism is studied in two ways: first, in terms of the operation of globalized free markets in which processes of financial liberalization and deregulation since the 198os have enabled transnational financial capital to restrain domestic political actors from changing neoliberal trajectories (see Appel and Orenstein 2018; Campello 2015; Kaplan 2013; Roos 2019); second, through the "encasement"

THE PUZZLING 11.J!SILIBNCJ! OP NJ!OLÍBER.ALISM

7

(Slobodian 2018, 13) of the world economy in a world order of institutional governance and intemational law a.ffecting states' sovereign policy decisions (see Chwieroth2009; Gill 2002; Pop-Eleches 2009). These three definitions of neoliberalism and its resilience broadly correspond to three disciplinary fields in comparative and international political economy: discursive institutionalism, historical institutionalism, and criticai intemational political economy. ln spite of coming from different epistemological traditions, they are in fact three facets of the sarne phenomenon, and all are necessary to fully understand it (seeMadariaga 2020 ). At the sarne time, while neoliberalism's class roots and the history of its transnational diffusion are crucial to understanding its worldwide dominance, this dominance has relied on the experiences of a few countries that have become neoliberalism's standard bearers. Although international pressures have provided an important engine for neoliberalism and have constituted a "container oflast resort" against challenges to it, it is domestic actors and institutions that have played the key role in neoliberalism.'s durability in those countries (more on this on chapter 2). Moreover, it is impossible to understand the resilience of neoliberalism as a set of ide as and policy recommendations without understanding how those ideas are appropriated by domestic political actors in their concrete political struggles. ln other words, while acknowledging the importance of neoliberalism's transnational class dimension and its ideational architecture, l focus on how these are translated by and embedded in national institutions through the struggles of specific national business actors, political leaders, and state bureaucracies. Going beyond existing research, l analyze not only how neoliberals struggle to institutionalize their preferred policy solutions as state policy, but, more fundamentally, how they strive to alter the very roles of the democratic political game to increase their political clout and reduce that of their opponents.5 From this perspective, a_resilient neoliberal policy regime is one that is able to institutionalize neoliberalism's basic premises in the very functioning ofits democratic polity, making changes ever more clifficult over time. When this is not the case, neoliberalism remains prone to challenge. ln the extreme case, neoliberalism is not just contested over and over again, but it is replaced by an alternative policy regime that, with new supporters, can eventually reproduce itself. 5. Forpower resource theories inspiring this idea, see Korpi (1985), Rueschemeyer, Huber, and Stephens ( 1992).

8

CHAPTER 1

Neoliberalism in Crisis? the Global View Ever since the subprime crash in August 2007 and the fali ofLehman Brothers one year la ter, the future of neoliberalism has been at the forefront of scholarly debates. The depth of the Wall Street crisis (and its many repercussions extending to the European debt crisis and the Greek bailouts) created the illusion that this was the crisis of neoliberalism, compounding expectations of a revival ofKeynesianism, a "New" New Deal switching to more progressive policies, or the start of a slow but progressive disintegration of capitalism as we know it (Appel and Orenstein 2018; Duménil and Lévy 2011; Kotz 2015; Steger and Roy 2010, 131-36; Kuttner 2018; Mason 2017; Streecluo16; Wallerstein et al. 2013). These expectations were encouraged by past episodes of paradigmatic shift following major economic crises and the idea that these dynamics ofpendular movement through crises is innate to the development of capitalism (Blyth 2002; Gourevitch 1986; Hall 1993; Duménil and Lévy 2011; Grauwe 2017; Kotz 2015). Nevertheless, despite these early predictions, neoliberalism has survived. As Mirowski has ironically put it, "neoliberalism is alive and well: those on the receiving end need to knowwhy" (2013, 28). To understand the puzzling resilience of neoliberalism, 1 take two positions. First, instead of looking at big ruptures and crises, 1 clairn that we can only understand how neoliberalism survives if we analyze the way it overcomes constant challenges and altemative paths. This implies switchingfrom a punctuated equilibrium or critical juncture view of political development, to one focused on gradual changes and reproduction mechanisms (Pierson 2004; Streeck and Thelen 2005). Second, 1argue that the resilience of neoliberalism thus understood is better explained by studying the history of over three decades of neoliberal resilience at the capitalist periphery. Despite the universal character of neoliberalism and its policy recipes, the actual practice of neoliberalism in the core and the periphery of global capitalisrn has been quite different (Appel and Orenstein 2018; Boas and Gans-Morse 2009; Connell and Dados 2014 ). ln the advanced capitalist countries, neoliberalism has progressed gradually as a more or less successful challenge to postwar political and economic institutions; hence the frequent characterization of"actually existing neoliberalism" as an "always-imperfect realization" ofneoUberal theory ( Cahill :z.014; Connell and Dados 2014, 12.0). ln fact, at least until the 2ooos, it was still believed that neoliberalism represented just one of at least two successful varieties of advanced capitalist política! economy (Amable 2003; Campbell and Pedersen :z.001; Hall and Soskice 2001; lversen and Sos-

THE PUZZLING R.ESILIENCJ OI' NEOLIBERALISM

9

kk:e 2019). Students of advanced capitalism have thus concentrated on demonstrating the slow transformation of neoliberalism into the dominant policy and political practice it is today {Crouch 2ou; Blyth 2013; Streeck 2014). ln this sense, more than the resilience of neoliberalism per se, what they study is the gradual erosion ofthe postwar cornpromise (see Glyn 2007 ).6 At the periphery of global capitalism, particularly in Latin Arnerica and Eastern Europe, the implementation of neoliberalism was a different story:

fast and sweeping, amounting to a complete restructuring of state·society rela· tions with profound consequences for institution building and public policy. Moreover, the fact that neoliberal refoms were implemented alongside the reconstruction ofliberal democracies facilitated the connection between neoliberal economic policies and the political project behind them. 7 Despite the rich experience and research on radical neoliberalism outside the capitalist core, as Connell and Dados lament, "the most influential accounts of neoliberalism are grounded in the social experience of the global North" {20141 118 ).1his book brings Latin America and Eastern Europe back into the core of the debates about the future of neoliberal capitalism and democracy. Interestingly, recent events seem to be bringing neoliberal experiences in the advanced and nonadvanced worlds closer together. ln fact, research on the survival of neoliberalism ai the core of the capitalist economy and its impact on representative democracy has given place to scholarly debate over the ascendance ofright- and left-wingpopulism; the relationship between neoliberalism,_austerity politics, and the rise ofpopulist forces; and the parallel erosion of fundamental democratic values and institutions {Brown 2015; Eichengreen 2018; Dumas 2018; MacLean 2.017; Mair 2013; Levitskyand Ziblatt 2018; Kuttner 2018; Przeworski 2019 ). 'lhe Latin American and Eastem European experiences shed light on these global political-economic phenomena.

Neolíberalism in Latin America and Bastem Europe: The Empírica! Puzzk Latin Arnerica and Eastern Europe underwent rapid and thorough processes of economic and political liberalization in the final decades of the twentieth 6. Early accounts of this dynamic in individual countries can be found in Crouch and Streeck (1997 ). For a thorough analysis centered around industrial relations, see Baccaro and Howell (2017 ). For detailed and compelling studies of the gradual liberalization of Germany and France, see Streeclc (2009) and Amable (20171 respectively. 7. More on this below.

10

CHAPTER 1

century. The economic crises ofthe 198os heralded the collapse of decades-old economic development models that spearheaded these countries' quest for modernization and industrialization in a context of economic and political "underdevelopment" (Berend 1996; Edwards 1995; Przeworski 1991). ln this context1 neoliberalism was understood as a devdopment project able to put an end to these countries' manifold economic and political ills. Given the wholehearted commitment to radical market reforro, countries like Chile and Poland became poster children of the "new development orthodoxy" (Rodrik 19961 12-13) and were taken as benchmarks of good practice for other nonadvanced political economies in an era when neoliberalism became the only game in town (Àslund 1994; Edwards 1995; Sachs 1990 ). According to the eminent Hungarian anthropologist Karl Polanyi, explicit attempts at building a market societytend to generate societal "counter-movements" to shelter that society from the effects of free markets (Polanyi 2001). In Latin America and Bastem Europe, these counter-movements carne in waves, some accompanied by massive social protests, and many market-reformed countries shifted over the years towards less orthodox devdopment altematives (Bohle and Greskovits 2009; Frieden 1991a; Greskovits 1998; Orenstein 1001; Roberts 1008; E. Silva 2009). Steep and repeated economic crises, the disintegration of industrial and social tissues, growing unemployment, and rising inequality forced authorities to slow down the pace of reform or undertake outright policy reversals-altemative development projects that challenged neoliberalism's capacity to survive. However, a handful of countries maintained and even reinforced neoliberalism despite these challenges. Figure 1.1 depicts this process. It shows the Index ofEconomic Freedom1 a measure constructed from a series ofindicators assessing policy goals dear to neoliberalism (such as the free movement of capital and minimal govemment intervention in the decisions of private actors) for the countries under study1 as well as the average for their respective regions. 8 Most countries follow a 8. 'Ihis indicator is based on policy orientations and outcomes. Other indicators of market reform show the progress ofinstitutional reform, amongwhich, the Economic Freedom ofthe World Inda: by the Fraser Institute, the liberalization indexes. by Morley, Machado and Pettinato {1999) and Lora {2012) for Latin America, and the EBRD Transition Indicators for Eastem Europe. These indexes make it hard to assess Eastem Europe, where all countriel; were building capitalist institutions from scratch during the i99os and 2ooos, and therefore show continuous progressions rather than discontinuities over time. The index here presented has severa! shortcomings, induding a Jack of coverage of the 198os and early 299os. It should therefore be taken only as a representation of the research problem, and notas a proofofits existence, noras a case selection technique.

THE PUZZLING RESILIENCE OI' NEOLIBERALISl\l

11

90

80

.... ...

70

~

u

~ 60

~-:e"

Q)

-e

'•f-
7, 145-46, :1.21-23; and ex· change rates, SJ-54, 7:1.-73, 9:1., 93, 101-2, 103-4, m, us, us, 130, 131, 16912:1.1-23, :1.2J1, 231; and Estonia, U01 12J1 1:1.51 1641 and EOI (Bxport-Oriented Industr'ial· ization)1137n; ànd lisa! rules, 237, 238; and free trade, 29; and industrial policy, 53-ss, 57-58, 60, 89-91, 94-1 97, 114-15, 12.3, us, 127,131,146, 158,169, 206-7; and

PEEX (Programas Espccialll5 de B:cport· acl6n), 91; and Poland, 1111 114-15, 126-:1.71

130, 169; and prlvatization, 145, 16+ See also RCA lndex (Index ofRevealed Compara tive Advantages) extraordinary politlcs, 10.s, 1071 116 Faletto, Enzo, 43n Falkland Islands, 901 1841 2.IJ FDI (foreign dircctlnveslment), 58-60, 63n; and alternatlvc politlcal projects, 150; and.Atgentina, 156-57; and Chile, 931 1so; and EstoDia, uo, iu, 162-63, 165; and industrial policy, 58-60, 78; and MNCs (multinational corporat!ons), ?Si and neoliberal resilience, 136, 150116:1.-631 164, r6s; and power resowces, 1501 15657, 173; and privatization, 120, 136; anci productivity, 78; and R&D (research and dcvclopment), 59-60 Femández,Alberto, 104-5 Femández, Cristina, 104, 132, 133, i38, 2.081 21.sn, 231, 245, 162-63, 2.64 Fem~ndez León (business group), 147 FIC (National Fund for Innovatlon nnd Competitiveness), 97, :144. &e also Chile,

INDBX

and the rnlning royalty and tax; Chile, clusters policy of finance, and credit, 94-95, 144-45; and debt, 88, 145, iso; and deregulation, Ss86, 891 144, 150-'51; and ~ctatorsbips, 8589, 10.s, lJ7-41, 143-49, 153; and fiscal pol· lcy, 10'1; and íorelgn capital, i36; and inllation, 881 and labor unions, 101, 158; and political parties, 1:1.4-16, 118-311 1)2, 150, 151, 235, 150-53; and prlvatization; 101, 136, 13811:39, 142-4.s, 147, 150, 152, IS3S5i 157-581163, 164-65, 1661 169-72., 17374, 251-53; and shock therapy, 85-861 107, 113-141 119-20; and technocrats, 89, 144 fiscal policy, 141 23, 31, 48-49, 55; and accountnbility, 49-50, 246; and altemative politkal projects, 50, 103-.s, 113-14, 128, 133, 217-18, :i.39-48, 256; and Argentina, 91, 101, 103-4, 1550, 206, 2l'/-28, 237-38, 244-46, 246-48, :1.56; and balanced budget rules, 491 1161 237-40, 24:1.-43, :1.45; and Chlle, 89, 961 :1.21, :z.37-38, 2.41-44, 246-48; and commodities, :z.37; contractionary, 243; and "creative accounting," 241; and debt, 48-49, 237, 240, :1.41-42, :1.45; and debt roles, 237-38, :l.40-42. 245; and delegation of pollcyrnaking, JS. 246, 246-48, 254-55; and democracy, 48-49, 216-18, 2431 246, 248; and democratic eroslon, 49; and .Eastern Europe, 237-38; and economic discretion of go'VU'llments, 48-491 60; and Estonia, u6, u5, 237-38, 239-40, 246-48; and the Euro· pean Un!on, 105-6, 127-:z.8, 133' 237-381 :1.401 241-421248; and executive power, 206-?; a.t;d expenditurc, 47-49, 101, 2.3941, 141-42, 242-45, 248, :z.54;5; and expenditure roles, 47-49, 101, 237-45, :1.48; and cxports, 237, 238; and fiscal conservatism, 49, :1:39-40, :i..µ, :1.43; and fiscal constraints, 911 and fiscal deficits, 75. 89, 103, 227-28, :z.39, 241, :1.43, :z.44-45; and fiscal discipline, 60, 105-6, :1.15, 239, :1.43; and fiscal prudence, :1.43; and fiscal retrencb-

333 ment, 116, 1550, 207; and fiscal rules, i4, :z.3, 4?-4S>, 49-50, 91, 101, 103, u6, 237-38, :z.37n, 137-38, 238, :1.39-40, 141-42., :1.4:1.46, 246-48, 254-56; and liscalswpluscs, io4, 238, 239, :1.41, 243, 145, 254-55; formal, 237-381 and the "Great Moderation,• 611 and government lnterventionlsm, 48451; and Hagen, Jürgen von, +9i and the IMF (Internatlonal Monetary Fund), 31, 101, 224, 224n, 239, :z.45; md industrial poUcy, 47-481 140, :z.4:1., 254-,S6; and in· flat!on, 48; informal, :1.37-38, 14-3; and interm1tional pressures, 180, 108, 127-28, 1331 224, 239, 237-38, 140, 2.41-4-2, 145, :z.48; and Latln Amerlca, :z.37-JB; and Mundell-Flemming theorem, 31; and Poland, 108, 113-14, 12.7-:1.8, 133, :z.37-38, 24142, 146-48; and policymaking. 49-SO, 217-18, 236, 240, 24:1., 243-44, 246-48; and representation, 49, 246-4'; and revenue rules, 137, 138, 239-40, ,_.J, :1.45; and speculative attacks, 49; md sbbiliution funds, 237-381243, :z.45; and the trilemma of monetary policy in an open economy, 31; and veto pla.ycrs, 49-50 Remming, Marcus, 31 foreign exchange, 53-55, 57, 8J, u,s, :z._µ., 2.45 rourcade-Gourinclus, Marion, 15-16 Francc, 9061 171 fiee markels, 31 6, 27, 26-30, 31n, 40, 59, 85n, 92, 121, 1761 and capital account liberalization, 30-31, 40, 67, 88, 1440; anel democ.r:icy, 3, 32; and deregulation, 6, 40, 89; and economlc freedom, 1, 10, 1on, 11, :z.7:1.81 ].i, 320, 331 35. 36, 38; and elpori; performance, :191 and finanáal repression, 30-31; and free ~arket capitalism, 7.AS; and free trade, 28-19, 43-44, .ss, 93-941 103, 115, uB, u:z., 144119:1.; and free society, 32.J and Fr!edman, Milton, i, 29, 32.0; and government interventionlsm, s, :z.7, 27n, 28-301 51, 59; and Industrial policy, 5960; and marice! power, :z.7n; and the 10ilitary, 8sni and oligopol!ution, :r.70; :md

334 free markets (cont.) the theory cf regulatory capture, 19; and theoryoíthe "rent-seeldng society,• 2930, 41,; transltlon to, 43, 176 free trade agreements 94, 122.J bilater.d, 111, 133; FTAA (Free Trade Area of the Amerlcas), 103; Mercosur (Mercado Común del Sur), 91, 94, 95n, ioo, 1oon, 1031 298; NAFTA (North American Free Trade Agreement), 93, 941 94n9 Frei, Eduardo, ~3-94 Frleden,Jeffiy A., S31 59n Friedman, .Milton, 2, 17-3:1., 31n, 56-58 Garovaglio and Zorraquin (buslness group),154 Geneva Scbool, 6-71 2.6n, 351 3sn; andinternational law and govemance, 6-7, 16n, 35, 350; and neoliber.dism as polity, 111 14, 22, 1s, :i.7, 3:z.-36; and Slobodian, Qpinn, 6-7, :z.6n, 35, 35n Georgia, 123034 Gennany, $m61 156, 1910

Glll, Stephen, 4:1., 47013 Gilqwska, Zyta, u8n GK Enea SA, 171 GK Energa SA, 17:1. GK Grupy Lotos SA, i7:1. GK Orangc Polska, 171 GKPGNiG SA, 171 GK Tauron Polska Energia SA, 172 globalization, 61 14-151 19-201 11-:1.:1. gold standard, :1.6, 2:1.4 Goldwater, Bacry, 29 Gomulka, Stanisbw, usn González, Felipe, 146n, 148 Goodman,John B., :1.18n Goretti, Matteo, 184, 1&1n, 185n6, 20sn26 · Gramsci, Antonio, 62 GreatModeration, 61 Greece, 8 Greskovits, Béla, 4DJ. 16, 167 Grofman, Bernard, 186ruo, 19:i. Gronkiewia-Waltz, Hanna, 113-14, 2µ, 234

INDBX

Grupa Centrum (business group), ~9 Grupa Polnnc (business group),129 Gnymala-Dusse, Anna, 111-13 Gll%lllán,Jaime, 181, 199-200

Hagen, Jürgen von, 49 Haggard, Stephan, 61, 137n Hajer, M:iarten, 1m Hall, Peter A., 4D2, s, 1,51 56 Hanley, Seán, 16 Hayek, Fricdrich., :i., :i.7, 30, 31-3J, 34, 35, 41, 258 hegemony, i73, 261; and legitimatlng mechanisms ofneoliberalism, 14-15, cultural, 14-15, 252; of neoliberallsm, J-41 6, 71 g, 10, 36, 117, 152 Hibbs, Douglas A, 'S'f lücks, Rayrnond, 69 Hirschmnn, Albert O., 28 Howell, Chris, gn6 Huber, Evely.ne, 70 Human R!ghts Watch, uru Hungary, :i.21 1o6, 137, 1411 266 Hurtado Vicuila (business group)1 147 lda-Viru County (Estonia), 193-94 illiberalism, 16, 214, 266 llzeâki, Ethan, 68 IMF (lnternational Monetary Fund), and Argentina, 91-92, 99n, 101, 10J, 1331 i:i.9, 245, 163; and Chile, 89, 133; and democracy, 3sn; and Estonia, 22.4. 2:1.4n, 139; and exchange rateiJ, 68-69, 99n, 10101 214, 2:1.4n1 219, :i.35, 139; and fiscal policy, :u41 139, 245; and industrial policy, 101; · and standby agreements, 239; and Latln America, 83. 88, 133; and loans, 31, 881 245, 263; and Mundell-Flemming theorem, 31; and neoliberalism, 3sn, 89, 91-92; and Poland, 235; and stabilization programs, 161 88; and transnatlonal integration re· gimes,83 imports, 41, 53-54, 60, 79, 88-89; and ex· cliange rates, Sl-S4, 60, 73-74' 79. See

INDBX

a1so ISl (hnport Substituting lndustrihllzation) lndex oíEcopomic Frccdom, 10, 1on, u industrialization, 10, :z.8; and Argentina, 91, 158; and Chile, 85, 146, 148; and Eastern Europe, 10, 41; and EOI (ExportOriented Industrialiiatlon)1 911 137n1 and exchange rates, 60; and government lnterventionism, 28, 29-301 41,54-55, 58, 91; and industrial policy, 54-SS. .sS, 91 1 158; and !SI (~port Substituling lndustrializatlon), +1,.60, 851 137n, 158; and Latin Arnerica, 10, 4li and neoliberallsm, 28; and neostructwalism, 60; Soviet plms for, 107n22; and tbe Soviet Union, uo; state-led, 281 146, 148 indusb:ial policy, 6, 171 22, 28, 51-53, 53-61i and alternalive political projects, 561 61i and agriculture, 551 104, 106, 108-9, 110, 112, 117, no, 121, 121-23, 1251 126-:1.7, 131, 158, 161-6:1., 166, 169, 170, 206-8, :1.26, ::i.39; Artngufond (Estonlan Devclopment Fund), 12.3-24. 197, 140; and the Chicago School, :z.8-31; and constitutions, :1.3, 216-18; and credit, 55, 94-951 1041 108-91 1141 158, 244-45; and capital CX· penditure, 74; ànd current expenditure, 74; and debt, 112; and democracy, 216-18, 243, 246, ::i.48; and dictatorships, 85-921 discrctlonary, 28-29, 58-59, 6o-61; and employment, uo, u7; and EOI (ExportOriented Industrialization), IJ7Jl; and the European Union, 105-t 114, :1.40; and exports, 53-55, 57-58, 6o, 89-5u, 94, 97, 114-15, 12.J, 125, 12.?, 131, 146, 158, 169, 206-11 and FDI (foreign direct investment), 59-60, 78-79; and fiscal policy, 47-48, 240, 242, 254-56; and &ee mar· kets159-60; and the IMF (Intematlonal Monetary Fund), 101; and industrlalization1 54-55, 58, 91, 158; and industry upgrading, 170; and investment incentives, 55; and lntemational financial instltu· tions, 60; and intemational pressures1

335 180, 251, 94, 101, 105-6, 114, us, 121-24, 115-31, 13:i, 2.40; and labor un!ons, 77, 1021 104, 110, 112, 114, u.o, 158i 11ml m11nu· f'acturing, 55, 59; and mining, 971 109-10, u4, u6, 129, 131, 150-5:z, 203; and mo· nopolies, 59; and nontariff restr!ctions, 151, 55; and prlce d!stortions, 6, 59J and productMty, 54-ss; and Poland, 21, 13; and public expcndituce, 47-48J and public: cpinion, 201; and R&D (reseat:thand development) 159-60; and rent-sccking, 30; selective, 28-30; and subsidies, 55, 58; and tarüfs, 6, 29; and taxation, 60; and tu: exemptions1551 59-60; and theoryof regulatory capture, 29; and theory of"rent-seeklng society," 29-3oi and wagcs, ss; and the Washington Consensus, ss-56, 60 industry: advanced, 59; agriculture, 120; Argcntinean, 65, 87-88, 90-91,98-99, 101-4, 137, 140, 153-54, 157-58, 106; banking, 92, 96, 101-:z, 1.421 1511 2.31-Jl; capital goods, 91; chemical, 6.s, 66, 8687, 11.S, llO, 1291 131, i47, J,Sf, 163; Chilcan, 651 86-87, 9:z, 941 96, 971 1401 • 14on, 144-451 146-47, 151, 101, 1:z.3123233; energy, 79, 129, 1471 1681 171-72, 206; Estonian, 66, 1171 117ru.8, 120-;1, u31 141, 158, 163-64, 186n8, 193, 239; domcstic, 48188, 90, 106, 201; financial, no, 1sB; food, 66, 98, 1061 us, 120-211 u7, 129, 147, 154, 15711631171, 239; insurance, 96, 164; manufacturing, ss, 59, 63-64, 88, 90, 103-4, 137, 14on, 158, 169, 213; meta~, 65661 86, 94, 101, 146-47,154,157, 263, 172; and military-industrial coniplex, 87-88; mining (stt mining); natural-resource, 941 144-:451 2.23; Polish, 66, 1141 115-161 126-27, 129, 137, 141, 168-69, 171-72; tele· communicatlons, 123, 129, 147, 2711172; transportation, 65-