440 31 18MB
English Pages 747 Year 2017
Macroeconomics Principles for a Changing World
2
4 th
edition
Macroeconomics
Principles for a Changing World
Eric P. Chiang Florida Atlantic University
3
Vice President, Social Sciences: CHARLES LINSMEIER Publisher: SHANI FISHER Acquisitions Editor: TOM DIGIANO Editorial Assistant: COURTNEY LINDWALL Marketing Assistant: MORGAN RATNER Senior Development Editor: BRUCE KAPLAN Director, Content Management Enhancement: TRACEY KUEHN Managing Editor: LISA KINNE Media Editor: LINDSAY NEFF Media Producer: ANDREW VACCARO Photo Editor: CHRISTINE BUESE Photo Researcher: DONNA RANIERI Director of Design, Content Management: DIANA BLUME Senior Design Manager: VICKI TOMASELLI Cover Designer: PAULA JO SMITH Interior Text Designer: AMANDA KAVANAGH Senior Project Editor: JODI ISMAN Art Manager: MATTHEW MCADAMS Illustrations: ELI ENSOR Production Manager: STACEY B. ALEXANDER Composition: MPS LIMITED Printing and Binding: LSC COMMUNICATIONS Cover Photos: TSHOOTER/SHUTTERSTOCK (AIRPLANE WINDOW); ANTON BALAZH/SHUTTERSTOCK (EARTH IMAGE) Back Cover Photo: IZABELA HABUR/ISTOCKPHOTO Library of Congress Control Number: 2016931972 ISBN-13: 978-1-4641-8692-9 ISBN-10: 1-4641-8692-8 © 2017, 2014, 2012, 2008 by Worth Publishers All rights reserved. First printing Printed in the United States of America Worth Publishers One New York Plaza
4
Suite 4500 New York, NY 10004-1562 www.macmillanlearning.com
5
To John and Tina Chiang: my parents, who instilled in me a work ethic that allowed me to pursue endless opportunities
6
Tribute to Jerry Stone Jerry Stone long-believed that the best principles of economics textbooks are authored by people invested in their students’ classroom experience. The decisions made in the shaping of the first several editions of CoreEconomics were educated by Jerry’s thirty-plus years in the classroom. The foundation of this edition is a testament to Jerry’s accomplishment: a book envisioned, designed, and executed to be the principles of economics book that teaches better than any other textbook on the market. Jerry had a remarkable career as a longtime teacher at Metropolitan State University of Denver and as an author of two successful principles of economics textbooks. Those who knew Jerry miss his steadfast commitment to the teaching of economics, a legacy that lives on in each new edition of Economics: Principles for a Changing World. Jerry Stone passed away after a difficult battle with cancer in August of 2010.
7
about the author
Eric P. Chiang
received his bachelor’s degree in economics from the University of Nevada Las Vegas, and his master’s and doctorate in economics from the University of Florida. His first academic position was at New Mexico State University. Currently, Eric is an associate professor and graduate director of the Department of Economics at Florida Atlantic University. Eric also serves as the director of instructional technology for the College of Business. In 2009 Eric was the recipient of Florida Atlantic University’s highest teaching honor, the Distinguished Teacher of the Year Award. Among numerous other teaching awards, he also was named the Stewart Distinguished Professor at the College of Business. He has written approximately thirty articles in peer-reviewed journals on a range of subjects, including technology spillovers, intellectual property rights, telecommunications, and health care. His research has appeared in leading journals, including the Review of Economics and Statistics, Journal of Technology Transfer, and Southern Economic Journal. He is a frequent presenter at major economics conferences and at universities across the country and around the world. As an instructor who teaches both face-to-face and online courses, Eric uses a variety of technological tools, including clickers, Web-based polling, lecture capture, and homework management systems to complement his active-learning-style lectures. As an administrator in the College of Business, Eric’s role as director of instructional technology involves assisting instructors with effectively implementing classroom technologies. In this position, Eric also ensures that the quality of online courses meets accreditation standards, including those set by the Association to Advance Collegiate Schools of Business (AACSB). In addition to his dedication to teaching economic principles and his administrative duties, Eric devotes time to new research in economic education. His current research focuses on
8
student learning outcomes in economics education based on the different methods of instruction in use today. The fourth edition of Economics: Principles for a Changing World embodies Eric’s devotion to economics education and the benefits of adapting to the new, often creative ways in which students learn and instructors teach. In his spare time, Eric enjoys studying cultures and languages, and travels frequently. He has visited all fifty U.S. states, many of them to run half-marathons, and over eighty countries, and enjoys long jogs and walks when he travels in order to experience local life to the fullest.
9
Vision and Story of Economics Economics is a way of looking at the world and understanding how and why it’s changing.
E
very time I teach principles of economics, I keep in mind that many of my students are learning about economics for the first time, and how they perceive my course may influence their perceptions of economics for a long time. This was a guiding notion in the first edition of CoreEconomics and continues with this fourth edition, renamed Economics: Principles for a Changing World. Why the change in title?
The fourth edition still represents the “core” of economic principles. But it also provides students with a global perspective on how economic problems are addressed, an appreciation of data and how data are used, and the application of technology. I believe that such an approach is best suited to the changing world we live in. Instructors and students face two sets of problems with each principles of economics class. Instructors ask, “How many students can we reach today? Can we reach each one?” Students constantly ask, “How does this affect my life?” I have taught over 15,000 students since 2001—in small classrooms, large auditoriums, online classes, day classes, evening classes, and even overseas. The diversity of my students has provided abundant examples of learning by experience. Each setting provides a laboratory for using innovative teaching techniques and technologies to motivate students to appreciate the endless possibilities that thinking like an economist can provide. The challenge, of course, is reaching each and every student. This challenge is made especially difficult by the sheer amount of information now available to students and subsequently by the increasing number of ways in which students learn. Part of the work on this edition and the last one actually led me to consider active learning methodologies. Instructors often encourage or even require students to read their textbook prior to the related lecture. If students do, class time can be used more effectively to refine the knowledge. The problem is that students often don’t read the book ahead of class. When I started doing research on this, I eventually came to the conclusion that using a textbook in such a way may not be all that effective, and I instead was inspired to create FlipItEcon along with my co-author José Vázquez. The textbook and its technology obviously still play a critical role in learning, but they may be better suited to providing deeper understanding after the lecture. This edition was created with that active learning objective in mind. Each chapter contains a wealth of vivid examples, intuitive explanations, and visuals to help build a more comprehensive understanding of concepts. It’s no longer enough to write a good or even great textbook. The book is just one avenue
10
for delivering information when students are accustomed to consuming information from so many different sources. To reach students, it’s now essential to deliver information in a variety of formats beyond the textbook or even the lecture itself. I’ve thus worked with Worth Publishers to develop each of the elements of technology for Economics: Principles for a Changing World, so it is much more of an effective teaching tool for instructors. —Eric P. Chiang
11
Principles for a Changing World Developed by Eric Chiang’s experiences teaching thousands of students around the world. Today’s students are bombarded by information from many sources. To apply economic thinking to this constant flow of data, students must recognize differences in perspective. The most effective instructors are flexible, using different channels and methods to present information from different economic perspectives. Economics: Principles for a Changing World is designed to give you the tools to do so.
Technology as a Tool for Success Students are accustomed to using technology to learn, just as modern economists use technology for research. It stands to reason that the technology portion of this fourth edition should be just as integral as the textbook itself. The only system designed for prelecture and ideal for active learning. Eric Chiang is the only principles author to have also authored an online learning system. Groundbreaking homework system created as part of the fourth edition, with content from the author and used in his own classes. CourseTutor The most comprehensive study guide in economics, now in a digital format within LaunchPad and tied to Chiang’s signature author videos.
Data Literacy Data can be used to support any number of stories. By the Numbers features and their accompanying exercises focus on helping students to read and understand data, instilling a critical eye to the data presented in daily life.
Global Perspective Most principles texts simply seek to provide an international context for economic principles. The Around the World features help students recognize that people all over the world are faced with many of the same economic problems, yet seek to solve these challenges in different ways.
WHAT’S NEW IN THE FOURTH EDITION? 12
Three themes integrated in every chapter with By the Numbers infographics, Around the World features, and LaunchPad activity callouts. Expanded video program with an author video for every chapter, including new coverage of health care and the Affordable Care Act. New coverage of the central importance of economic growth in Chapter 7, “Economic Growth.”
13
Rethinking the Connection Between Author, Text, and Technology Ordinarily, textbooks are developed by first writing chapters, then making decisions about art and images, and finally assembling a test bank and ancillaries. Eric Chiang writes the text, develops the visual program, and assembles the resources for the homework system at the same time. These threads come together for a complete learning program, with every element integrated by the author himself.
Throughout his academic career, Eric Chiang has conducted a great deal of research on pedagogy in economic education. Much of this research has focused on increasing student retention and engagement, which inspired him to create along with co-author José Vázquez. Although can be used with any combination of textbook and resources, it’s an ideal solution for Economics, Fourth Edition, instructors simply looking to better prepare their students for class time and “flip” their level of engagement.
1. Animated prelecture tutorials provide a base-level understanding of core economic topics before
14
students ever “set foot” in a class. Straightforward animations provide information in an engaging format without distraction. Information is “chunked” into short, easily remembered segments. Embedded questions and a pacing system put learning in the students’ hands.
2. Bridge questions are designed to inform an instructor of students’ level of understanding before lecture as well as lead to discussion, review, use of iClickers, or another activity during lecture. They “bridge” prelecture time to lecture time. Students first answer a question designed to either be open-ended, address a typical misconception, or otherwise lead to further discussion in the lecture. Students then must explain the rationale behind their answer, allowing the instructor a deep level of insight into their understanding.
Once students have completed the Prelectures and Bridges, an instructor can assign Problems as either practice or post-class homework. Each unit has between 30–50 Problems, and all non-definitional problems include video feedback provided by the author himself.
features the most author-driven and text-specific content of any integrated homework system available. In this edition, you will find exciting 15
changes to , including a collection of new activities designed to augment in-chapter content and features to support student learning. for Economics: Principles for a Changing World, Fourth Edition, includes: Complete e-Book Pre-built Units Offer instructors and students readymade units for study with quizzes, e-Book pages, tutorials, and graded homework for every chapter. Units are flexible and easy to adapt or expand to suit individual preferences. NEW! Expanded Author Videos This hugely popular feature now provides concise and engaging explanations for nearly every chapter along with assessment, including new coverage of health care and the Affordable Care Act.
NEW! Digitized CourseTutor One of the most notable features of CoreEconomics from its first as part of the course edition, the CourseTutor study guide has now been brought into units. : Adaptive, formative quizzing, ’s game-like quizzing motivates each student to engage with the course, and reporting tools help teachers get a handle on what their class now features the first in a needs. Just as apps are continuously updated and improved, series of updates to continually improve the user experience. Customizable format allows instructors to tailor quizzes to the exact content they are teaching. Accessible format was redone in compliance with WCAG2.0 AA standards for users with disabilities. New design emphasizes useful study tools, like the personalized study plan, links to the e-Book, and hints to structure student reading.
16
NEW! Math and Graphing Review is a critically important new resource created by a team of instructors for students who would benefit from a review of basic math and graphing—skills needed to do well in an introductory economics course. It is organized as a series of activities, each with a pretest question, an animation with clear explanations, and five concluding questions to test comprehension.
17
NEW! Work It Out activities are skill-building tutorials that walk students through each step of solving an end-of-chapter problem using choice-specific feedback and video explanations for each step. The new activity is a useful extension of the end-of-chapter Solved Problem feature, which provide detailed text feedback while leading students through a stepped-out problem.
provides instructors with the following resources: FOR ASSESSMENT Test Bank contains more than 4,000 carefully constructed, thoroughly edited and revised, and comprehensively accuracy-checked questions. Each chapter’s test bank contains “anchor” questions written by the author himself. End-of-Chapter Problems have been converted to a multiple-choice format accompanied by answerspecific feedback.
18
Graded Homework Assignments Each unit concludes with a pre-built assignment, providing instructors with a curated set of multiple-choice and graphing questions that are easily assigned for graded assessment.
ADDITIONAL RESOURCES Gradebook offers clear feedback to students and instructors on individual assignments and on performance in the course as a whole. LMS Integration ensures that is easily integrated into a school’s learning management system and that an instructor’s gradebook and roster are always in sync. Instructor’s Teaching Manual is the ideal resource for many classroom teaching styles. The Teaching Manual focuses on expanding and enlivening classroom lectures by highlighting varied ways to bring real-world examples into the classroom. Lecture Slides are designed with visual learning in mind. This set of slides contains fully animated graphs, visual learning images, and additional examples and created links. Economics, Fourth Edition, is the only principles of economics textbook with slides created by the author.
Also available for instructors and students:
saplinglearning.com Online homework system that helps students get better grades with targeted instructional feedback tailored to each individual’s responses. It also helps instructors spend less time preparing for and managing a course by providing personalized classroom support from a doctorate- or master’s-level colleague fully trained in Sapling’s system.
19
econedactive.com EconED Active is a community focused on curating the best open source active learning content aligned to key topics in principles of economics. Find everything from classroom activities to experiments, to new ways of presenting topics. Rate and share ideas and connect with other instructors passionate about teaching.
20
community.macmillan.com Worth Economics partners with authors, instructors, and students to pioneer a complete learning experience. Our Economics Community is an outlet for you to interact with some of the thought leaders of economics education, follow their latest work, and share your own experiences in teaching and learning.
21
Thinking About Data Literacy Students who continue on from principles to intermediate macroeconomics will be asked to use data to solve economics problems. Before they can get to that point, they must learn to interpret and understand various formats of data presented to them. With the abundance of data in our daily lives and its growing importance in all manner of professions, developing this skill is just as important to students who will never take an economics course beyond principles as it is to future economists.
22
The By the Numbers feature in every chapter helps students visualize data from real life and offers an easy exercises in interpreting way to see how they link to concepts in the chapter. In addition to online data, two end-of-chapter problems test students on how well they understand the data presented.
23
24
Thinking About What Global Means One of the unique things about Eric Chiang is his philosophy on travel. Essentially, get in, get out, and try to gain as many impressions of world locales as you can. Years ago, he started his “Around the World in 80 Hours” trips where he would circumnavigate the globe, briefly stopping off in international spots, and film himself talking about the local economy. Why? People around the world are faced with many of the same economic problems and yet they solve them in surprisingly different ways.
25
Eric started these journeys on his own accord to help illustrate this concept to his students. His experiences have been developed into the new Around the World feature in every chapter. Students read a synopsis of an international issue faced around the world, view media to further their understanding (some featuring Eric himself), and answer a question on how that issue is resolved in different places throughout the world.
THOROUGH UPDATING 26
BY THE NUMBERS feature updated and now presented as an infographic WORK IT OUT problem in every chapter New END-OF-CHAPTER PROBLEMS in every chapter AROUND THE WORLD feature added to every chapter
CHAPTER 1 NEW ISSUE: Would a city change its name for a game show? NEW PRINCIPLE: Economic growth, low unemployment, and low inflation are three economic goals that do not always coincide. AROUND THE WORLD: Nunavut, abundance and scarcity
CHAPTER 2 AROUND THE WORLD: Ironbridge and the start of the Industrial Revolution NEW ISSUE: the ocean and land reclamation
CHAPTER 3 AROUND THE WORLD: Tokyo Disneyland and how people deal with long lines
CHAPTER 4 AROUND THE WORLD: Singapore’s attempt to control traffic by using peak-pricing tolls
CHAPTER 5 NEW CHAPTER OPENER: covers a broad range of issues, including the introduction of classical vs. Keynesian economics CONTENT REVISIONS: fewer subcategories in section on income approach to GDP; clearer breakdown of national income in Table 3; differences between nominal GDP, real GDP, and GDPPPP clarified AROUND THE WORLD: Costa Rica, happiness, and GDP
CHAPTER 6 CONTENT REVISION: rewritten section on underemployment and discouraged workers, with key data better linked to Department of Labor definitions AROUND THE WORLD: boom and bust in Dickinson, North Dakota
CHAPTER 7 NEW INTRODUCTION: China’s current growth problems
27
NEW ISSUE: the argument that dramatic growth in the United States in the 20th century is a thing of the past, and will not be so transformative in the future AROUND THE WORLD: growth champion Kazakhstan
CHAPTER 8 Thoroughly updated introduction
CONTENT REVISION: more prominent multiplier section AROUND THE WORLD: how the Beco do Batman area in Brazil turned graffiti into an engine for economic growth
CHAPTER 9 CONTENT REVISIONS: clarification of the effect of “business expectations”; how interest rates affect AD through consumption and investment AROUND THE WORLD: Myanmar and what it takes to open up a military regime to democracy
CHAPTER 10 CONTENT REVISIONS: shortened discussion of taxes and fewer equations; examination of the concepts of injections and withdrawals; clarification of national and public debt AROUND THE WORLD: fiscal policy as an engine of growth in Qatar
CHAPTER 11 CONTENT REVISIONS: downplay of traveler’s checks as part of M1; expanded discussion of government deficits on the market for loanable funds includes an explanation of how government borrowing actually reduces private saving AROUND THE WORLD: use of plastic money (literally) in Australia
CHAPTER 12 AROUND THE WORLD: the rise and fall of the Swiss Bank account
CHAPTER 13 CONTENT REVISIONS: updated sections on the Eurozone crisis and monetary theories AROUND THE WORLD: why a South American country would use the U.S. dollar as its own currency
CHAPTER 14 AROUND THE WORLD: post-unification Germany
CHAPTER 15 AROUND THE WORLD: how China’s New Year’s festival disrupts international trade
28
CHAPTER 16 AROUND THE WORLD: Hyder, Alaska, a town in the United States that uses Canadian currency and Canadian public services
29
acknowledgments No project of this scope is accomplished alone. Economics: Principles for a Changing World and its suite of learning resources came together as a result of the dedication of many individuals who devoted incredible amounts of time to the project. These include reviewers of manuscript chapters, workshop participants, accuracy reviewers, supplements contributors, project specialists, and the production and editorial staff at Worth Publishers. I want to thank those reviewers of the fourth edition who read through chapters in manuscript form and offered many important suggestions that have been incorporated into this project. They include: Steve Abid, Grand Rapids Community College Gian Aryani, Collin College Mohammad Bajwa, Northampton Community College Mihajlo Balic, Harrisburg Area Community College Yoram Bauman, Stand-Up Economist Dixie Button, Trident Technical College Jennifer Bryant, Lamar State College Joe Cahill, Lonestar College Tomball Michael Dale, Trident Technical College Lisa Gloege, Grand Rapids Community College Clark Goodlett, Trident Technical College Daniel Kuester, Kansas State University James Latham, Collin College Eric Levy, Florida Atlantic University Ting Levy, Florida Atlantic University Ishuan Li, Minnesota State University Mankato Grace O, Georgia State University Erick Perez, Broward College Chirinjev Peterson, Greenville Technical College Dennis Petruska, Youngstown State University
30
Olga Shemyakina, Georgia Institute of Technology Robert Simonson, Minnesota State University, Mankato One of my most enjoyable activities as an author and professor is to travel to campuses to present guest lectures to students or to facilitate workshops for instructors. The questions and feedback received during these visits contributed immensely to the development of this edition. I would like to thank those who have invited me to their campuses, including: Vicky Chiu-Irion, Honolulu Community College Debbie Evercloud, University of Colorado at Denver Paul Fisher, Henry Ford College Jolien Helsel, Youngstown State University Linda Hooks, Washington and Lee University Jennifer Imazeki, San Diego State University Venoo Kakar, San Francisco State University Gerard Klonarides, Broward College Jackie Lindo, Kapiolani Community College Daniel Murgo, Miami Dade College Max Nagiel, Daytona State College Tomi Ovaska, Youngstown State College Erick Perez, Broward College Larry Rowland, Hawaii Pacific University Martin Sabo, University of Colorado at Denver Ravi Samitamana, Daytona State College Sue Stockly, Eastern New Mexico University A. J. Sumell, Youngstown State University Andrew Tucker, Tallahassee Community College Enrique Valdes, Miami Dade College I would like to thank my current and former student assistants who helped with data collection and shared ideas for examples that would click with college students today. These students include Jonathan Lu, Alan Jagessar, Eileen Schneider, Yoko Uyehara, Kevin Brady, Craig Haberstumpf, Felicia Lu, and Thomas Thornton. I also thank all the students who have taken my principles courses. Their comments, body language, and facial expressions provided cues to whether my concept explanations and applications were clear and provided guidance on how to approach these topics in the book. I am thankful to have a friend and colleague in Vicky Chiu-Irion of Honolulu Community College, who has
31
contributed to the new edition in more ways than I can adequately describe. In addition to her eagle eye for detail, she provided many new examples used in this edition and class-tested new features in LaunchPad. Vicky’s support on this edition was indispensable. I am very grateful to Debbie Evercloud of University of Colorado at Denver and Varun Gupta of Wharton County Junior College for inspiring me to introduce the Around the World feature in this edition and for providing excellent reviews on drafts. I also thank Venoo Kakar of San Francisco State University for her valuable reviews. I also want to thank Thomas Dunn for his tireless examination of every set of page proofs and various LaunchPad resources. Despite dozens of eyes that have read through manuscript and proofs, Thomas still managed to catch errors that none of us want to see in the final product. A huge debt of gratitude is owed to Lindsay Neff and the supplements authors. Lindsay did a remarkable job to get the best people to author the supplements. They include Jane Himarios of the University of Texas at Arlington who managed the revision of the Test Bank, Albert J. Sumell of Youngstown State University and Dixie Button of Trident Technical College who revised and adapted the former CourseTutor into a new digital feature within LaunchPad, and Solina Lindahl of California Polytechnic University–San Luis Obispo for coordinating the pedagogical resources available to instructors. I would also like to thank Ting Levy, Tamika Steward, Enrique Valdes, Heather Luea, Brian Lynch, Katie Lotz, Mary Lesser, Winnie Lee, Kevin Beckwith, Beth Haynes, Karl Geisler, Greg Gilpin, Jan Wolcutt, Jackie Lindo, Scott Hegerty, Jesse Liebman, Kristen Zaborski, Varun Gupta, Sue Stockly, and Venoo Kakar for the development of materials for LaunchPad for this new edition. The fourth edition came together into a cohesive set of instructor and student resources because of their efforts. I owe a significant debt to the team of technology specialists who created many fascinating digital resources for Economics, Fourth Edition. I thank Tom Acox for his instrumental role in the development and management of the online resources, especially LaunchPad. There has been more than one occasion when a situation with my class required immediate attention, and Tom was always available, day and night, to resolve the problem. He truly exemplifies his title as director of customer experience. I am truly indebted to Jeremy Brown, who over the years has taught me the tools and tricks of digital technology that have become indispensable in today’s media-driven world. These tools include video editing, animation, and other visual effects, creating a professional Web site, and maximizing the effectiveness of social media. Whenever I have a technology-related question, I can count on Jeremy for an answer. His influence has given me the confidence to use cutting-edge technology to its maximum potential to the benefit of the Economics, Fourth Edition, suite of resources. The production team at Worth is truly the best in the industry. My heartfelt thanks go to the entire team, including Vicki Tomaselli, senior designer, for creating a fantastic set of interior and cover designs; Jodi Isman, senior project editor, for skillfully managing the copyediting and proofing of the book; Stacey Alexander, production manager; Matthew McAdams, art manager, for creating beautiful figures and graphs; Patti Brecht for her superb copyediting; photo editors Christine Buese and Donna Ranieri for their immense efforts at finding and obtaining rights to the hundreds of photos used in the book; Tracey Kuehn, director, content management enhancement; and Lisa Kinne, managing editor. Each of these individuals made sure each part of the production process went smoothly. Thank you very much for a job well done. I am very thankful to Charles Linsmeier, vice president, social sciences of Macmillan Learning, who signed me as an author in 2010 and has provided continuous support with each edition. I thank Shani Fisher, publisher, for her determination to broaden the appeal of the textbook to the wider market. I also thank Carlise Stembridge, editor, for her tireless efforts in ensuring that the textbook meets the needs of today’s instructors and students. She is always interested in hearing feedback from the book’s users in order to enhance its ability to improve the learning experience. And I thank Paul Shensa, who has provided valuable advice for many years; his steadfast commitment to the book’s success is truly evident. There is no one person I can thank more than Bruce Kaplan, senior development editor, who has guided me on the revision of Economics, Fourth Edition, from start to finish. Bruce had a long working relationship with Jerry Stone on his first two editions and was able to provide continuity into the third edition without Jerry’s presence. In fact, in my last conversation with Jerry Stone, he told me to “stick with Bruce; he’s the best and will take you far.” Jerry’s words ring true each time I work with Bruce, who is the best editor and mentor an author can have. My working relationship with Bruce has continued to be productive and efficient through the
32
fourth edition. As a night owl, I would send Bruce drafts of chapters in the wee hours of the morning, only to have him (as an early riser) read them almost immediately! You couldn’t ask for a better marketing team than that at Worth. I thoroughly enjoy working with Tom Digiano, marketing manager, who possesses remarkable talent and enthusiasm when developing innovative experiences to current and prospective users. These efforts resulted in many unique conference events, including the annual EconED teaching conference, regional focus group events, campus visits, webinars, and new social media campaigns such as econedactive.com and the Macmillan Community. In early 2016 Tom became an editor of this book, providing a seamless transition from marketing to editorial. I also enjoyed traveling with Tom in the fifth annual Around the World in 80 Hours economics documentary (viewable on YouTube). Finally, I thank Jerry Stone, a true friend and colleague who put his full trust in me when he offered me the opportunity to take over authorship of CoreEconomics in 2010 and carry the book forward to a new generation of students and instructors with new needs. I wish Jerry were still here to collaborate on the textbook he created so successfully in the first two editions. I will never cease my efforts to make this book a long-lasting legacy of Jerry’s brilliance and dedication to students and instructors.
—Eric P. Chiang
33
brief contents 1
Exploring Economics
2
Production, Economic Growth, and Trade
3
Supply and Demand
4
Markets and Government
5
Introduction to Macroeconomics
6
Measuring Inflation and Unemployment
7
Economic Growth
8
Aggregate Expenditures
9
Aggregate Demand and Supply
10
Fiscal Policy and Debt
11
Saving, Investment, and the Financial System
12
Money Creation and the Federal Reserve
13
Monetary Policy
14
Macroeconomic Policy: Challenges in a Global Economy
15
International Trade
16
Open Economy Macroeconomics
34
Sources for By the Numbers Glossary Index
35
contents BRIEF CONTENTS
1
Exploring Economics
BY THE NUMBERS Economics as a Career
What Is Economics About? Why Should One Study Economics? Microeconomics Versus Macroeconomics Economic Theories and Reality Model Building Ceteris Paribus: All Else Held Constant
Efficiency Versus Equity ISSUE Do Economists Ever Agree on Anything?
Positive Versus Normative Questions
Key Principles of Economics Principle 1: Economics Is Concerned With Making Choices With Limited Resources Principle 2: When Making Decisions, One Must Take Into Account Tradeoffs and Opportunity Costs Principle 3: Specialization Leads to Gains for All Involved Principle 4: People Respond to Incentives, Both Good and Bad ISSUE Would a City Change Its Name for a Game Show?
Principle 5: Rational Behavior Requires Thinking on the Margin Principle 6: Markets Are Generally Efficient; When They Aren’t, Government Can Sometimes Correct the Failure Principle 7: Economic Growth, Low Unemployment, and Low Inflation Are Economic Goals That Do Not Always Coincide Principle 8: Institutions and Human Creativity Help Explain the Wealth of Nations
36
AROUND THE WORLD Nunavut: Land of Abundance and Scarcity
Summing It All Up: Economics Is All Around Us ADAM SMITH (1723–1790)
Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
APPENDIX Working With Graphs and Formulas
Graphs and Data Time Series Scatter Plots Pie Charts Bar Charts Simple Graphs Can Pack In a Lot of Information A Few Simple Rules for Reading Graphs
Graphs and Models Linear Relationships Computing the Slope of a Linear Line
Nonlinear Relationships Computing the Slope of a Nonlinear Curve
Ceteris Paribus, Simple Equations, and Shifting Curves Ceteris Paribus: All Else Equal Simple Linear Equations Shifting Curves
Correlation Is Not Causation
2
Production, Economic Growth, and Trade
BY THE NUMBERS Growth, Productivity, and Trade Are Key to Our Prosperity
Basic Economic Questions and Production 37
Basic Economic Questions Economic Systems
Resources and Production Land Labor Capital Entrepreneurial Ability
Production and Efficiency AROUND THE WORLD Ironbridge: The Beginnings of the Industrial Revolution
Production Possibilities and Economic Growth Production Possibilities Opportunity Cost Increasing Opportunity Costs
Economic Growth Expanding Resources Technological Change Summarizing the Sources of Economic Growth
ISSUE Is the Ocean the Next Frontier? Land Reclamation and Underwater Cities
Specialization, Comparative Advantage, and Trade Absolute and Comparative Advantage The Gains from Trade Practical Constraints on Trade ISSUE Do We Really Specialize in That? Comparative Advantage in the United States and China DAVID RICARDO (1772–1823)
Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
3
Supply and Demand
BY THE NUMBERS The World of Markets
Markets 38
ISSUE Do Markets Exist for Everyone, Including Dogs and Cats?
The Price System
Demand Willingness-to-Pay: The Building Block of Market Demand The Law of Demand: The Relationship Between Quantity Demanded and Price The Demand Curve Determinants of Demand Tastes and Preferences Income Prices of Related Goods The Number of Buyers Expectations About Future Prices, Incomes, and Product Availability
Changes in Demand Versus Changes in Quantity Demanded
Supply The Law of Supply: The Relationship Between Quantity Supplied and Price The Supply Curve Market Supply Curves Determinants of Supply Production Technology Costs of Resources Prices of Related Commodities Expectations Number of Sellers Taxes and Subsidies
Changes in Supply Versus Changes in Quantity Supplied
Market Equilibrium Moving to a New Equilibrium: Changes in Supply and Demand Predicting the New Equilibrium When One Curve Shifts
ISSUE Two-Buck Chuck: Will People Drink $2-a-Bottle Wine? Predicting the New Equilibrium When Both Curves Shift
AROUND THE WORLD Tokyo Disneyland: Is THAT the Line for Space Mountain?! ALFRED MARSHALL (1842–1924)
Chapter Summary 39
KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
4
Markets and Government
BY THE NUMBERS Price Controls and Supports in the Economy Today
Consumer and Producer Surplus: A Tool for Measuring Economic Efficiency Using Consumer and Producer Surplus: The Gains from Trade The Consequences of Deviating from Market Equilibrium When Prices Exceed Equilibrium When Prices Fall Below Equilibrium
NOBEL PRIZE: PAUL A. SAMUELSON (1915–2009)
Market Failure Lack of Competition Information Is Not Shared by All Parties
AROUND THE WORLD Singapore: Resolving Traffic Jams and Reducing Pollution Using Price Controls The Existence of External Benefits or Costs The Existence of Public Goods
Market Efficiency Versus Equity
Price Ceilings and Price Floors Price Ceilings Price Floors ISSUE Are Price Gouging Laws Good for Consumers?
Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
5
Introduction to Macroeconomics 40
BY THE NUMBERS A Slow and Steady Macroeconomic Recovery
Business Cycles Defining Business Cycles Dating Business Cycles Alternative Measures of the Business Cycle National Activity Index Leading Economic Index Yield Curve
ISSUE The End of the Recession . . . It Does Not Feel Like It
National Income Accounting The Core of the NIPA The Circular Flow Diagram Spending and Income: Looking at GDP in Two Ways
NOBEL PRIZE: SIMON KUZNETS (1901–1985)
Gross Domestic Product The Expenditures (Spending) Approach to Calculating GDP Personal Consumption Expenditures Gross Private Domestic Investment Government Purchases Net Exports of Goods and Services Summing Aggregate Expenditures
The Income Approach to Calculating GDP Compensation of Employees Proprietors’ Income Corporate Profits Rental Income Net Interest Miscellaneous Adjustments Summing Up Income Measures
GDP and Our Standard of Living Different Ways of Comparing GDP Across Countries Population and GDP per Capita Environmental Quality AROUND THE WORLD Costa Rica: Pura Vida and Happiness Without a High Level of GDP
41
Nonmarket Activities and the Informal Economy
Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
6
Measuring Inflation and Unemployment
BY THE NUMBERS The Twin Evils of Inflation and Unemployment
Inflation What Causes Inflation? Measuring Inflation: Consumer Price Index, Producer Price Index, and GDP Deflator The Consumer Price Index The Producer Price Index The GDP Deflator
Adjusting for Inflation: Escalating and Deflating Series (Nominal Versus Real Values) Escalator Clauses Deflating Series: Nominal Versus Real Values The Effect of Overstating Inflation
The Consequences of Inflation Hyperinflation ISSUE The Consequences of Counterfeit Money on Inflation
Unemployment The Historical Record Defining and Measuring Unemployment Employed Unemployed Labor Force
Monthly Employment Surveys The Household Survey The Payroll Survey
Employment Trends Weekly Jobs Report Relationship Between Employment and the Unemployment Rate
Problems with Unemployment Statistics
42
Underemployment and Marginally Attached Workers
AROUND THE WORLD The Boom and Bust of Dickinson, North Dakota
Unemployment and the Economy Types of Unemployment Frictional Unemployment Structural Unemployment Cyclical Unemployment
Defining Full Employment The Natural Rate of Unemployment Changes in the Unemployment Rate Around the Natural Rate Jobless Recoveries Prolong Unemployment Above the Natural Rate
ISSUE Why Do Unemployment Rates Differ So Much Within the United States?
Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
7
Economic Growth
BY THE NUMBERS Why Should We Care About Economic Growth?
Why Is Economic Growth Important? How Is Economic Growth Measured? Small Differences in Growth Lead to Large Differences in Income Over Time Power of Compounding Growth Rates Rule of 70
ISSUE Can Economic Growth Bring a Billion People Out of Poverty?
Thinking About Short-Run and Long-Run Economic Growth Short-Run Versus Long-Run Growth Short-Run Growth Involves a Fixed Capacity Long-Run Growth Involves Expanding Capacity
Factors of Production Production Function
Applying the Production Function: Achieving Economic Growth 43
Achieving More Land or Natural Resources Growth of the Labor Force Increasing the Quality of the Labor Force Increasing the Capital-to-Labor Ratio THOMAS MALTHUS (1766–1834)
Improvements in Technology and Ideas Including Everything Else: Total Factor Productivity AROUND THE WORLD Kazakhstan: The Next Destination of Growth and Trade
The Role of Government in Promoting Economic Growth Government as a Contributor to Physical Capital, Human Capital, and Technology Physical Capital: Public Capital and Private Investment Human Capital: Public Education and Financial Aid Technology: Government R&D Centers and Federal Grants
Government as a Facilitator of Economic Growth Enforcement of Contracts Protection of Property Rights Stable Financial System
Government as a Promoter of Free and Competitive Markets Competitive Markets and Free Trade Economic Freedom
ISSUE Did Economic Growth Peak a Century Ago? Prospects for Future Growth
Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
8
Aggregate Expenditures
BY THE NUMBERS The Role of Spending in the Economy
Aggregate Expenditures Some Simplifying Assumptions Consumption and Saving Average Propensities to Consume and Save Marginal Propensities to Consume and Save
44
Other Determinants of Consumption and Saving
Investment Investment Demand Aggregate Investment Schedule
The Simple Aggregate Expenditures Model Macroeconomic Equilibrium in the Simple Model JOHN MAYNARD KEYNES (1883–1946)
The Multiplier The Multiplier Works in Both Directions Paradox of Thrift
ISSUE Do High Savings Rates Increase the Risk of a Long Recession? AROUND THE WORLD Brazil’s Beco Do Batman: How Graffiti Revived a Neighborhood
The Full Aggregate Expenditures Model Adding Government Spending and Taxes Tax Changes and Equilibrium The Balanced Budget Multiplier
Adding Net Exports Recessionary and Inflationary Gaps Recessionary Gap Inflationary Gap
ISSUE Was Keynes Right About the Great Depression?
Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
9
Aggregate Demand and Supply
BY THE NUMBERS The Sheer Size of Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply
Aggregate Demand Why Is the Aggregate Demand Curve Negatively Sloped? The Wealth Effect Export Price Effect
45
Interest Rate Effect
Determinants of Aggregate Demand Consumer Spending Investment Government Spending and Net Exports
AROUND THE WORLD Myanmar: Opening a Country to a Boom in Aggregate Demand
Aggregate Supply Long Run Determinants of Long-Run Aggregate Supply Short Run Determinants of Short-Run Aggregate Supply Input Prices Productivity Taxes and Regulation Market Power of Firms Inflationary Expectations
Macroeconomic Equilibrium The Spending Multiplier The Great Depression Demand-Pull Inflation Cost-Push Inflation ISSUE Why Didn’t Stimulus Measures Over the Past Decade Lead to Inflation?
Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
APPENDIX Deriving the Aggregate Demand Curve
10 Fiscal Policy and Debt
BY THE NUMBERS Your Government and Its Financial Operation
Fiscal Policy and Aggregate Demand Discretionary and Mandatory Spending
46
Discretionary Fiscal Policy Government Spending Taxes Transfers
Expansionary and Contractionary Fiscal Policy
Fiscal Policy and Aggregate Supply Infrastructure Spending Reducing Tax Rates Expanding Investment and Reducing Regulations AROUND THE WORLD Qatar: A Nation Built for the Future
Implementing Fiscal Policy Automatic Stabilizers Fiscal Policy Timing Lags The Government’s Bias Toward Borrowing and Away from Taxation
Financing the Federal Government Defining Deficits and the National Debt Balanced Budget Amendments ISSUE How Big Is the Economic Burden of Interest Rates on the National Debt?
Financing Debt and Deficits
Why Is the Public Debt So Important? Is the Size of the Public Debt a Problem? Does It Matter If Foreigners Hold a Significant Portion of the Public Debt? Does Government Debt Crowd Out Consumption and Investment? How Will the National Debt Affect Our Future? Are We Doomed?
Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
11 Saving, Investment, and the Financial System
BY THE NUMBERS The Financial System and Its Sheer Size and Scope
47
What Is Money? The Functions of Money Medium of Exchange Unit of Account Store of Value
Defining the Money Supply AROUND THE WORLD Using Plastic Money (Literally) in Australia Narrowly Defined Money: M1 A Broader Definition: M2
The Market for Loanable Funds Supply and Demand for Loanable Funds Shifts in the Supply of Loanable Funds Economic Outlook Incentives to Save Income or Asset Prices Government Deficits
Shifts in the Demand for Loanable Funds Investment Tax Incentives Technological Advances Regulations Product Demand Business Expectations
The Financial System The Bridge Between Savers and Borrowers The Roles of Financial Institutions Reducing Information Costs Reducing Transaction Costs Diversifying Assets to Reduce Risk
Types of Financial Assets Bond Prices and Interest Rates Stocks and Investment Returns
Financial Tools for a Better Future Short-Term Borrowing The Power (or Danger) of Compounding Interest Risk Assessment and Asset Allocation Saving for the Future: Employer-Based Programs
48
To Contribute or Not to Contribute? In What Assets Should One Invest?
Other Retirement Savings Tools: Social Security, Pensions, and IRAs Social Security Pension Plans
ISSUE Can a Stock Market Crash Increase Long-Term Savings? Individual Retirement Arrangements (IRAs)
Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
12 Money Creation and the Federal Reserve
BY THE NUMBERS Banks and the Federal Reserve
How Banks Create Money Creating Money as If Out of Thin Air Fractional Reserve Banking System The Money Creation Process
The Money Multiplier and Its Leakages Bank Reserves and the Money Multiplier Money Leakages Bank Leakages Leakages by Individuals and Businesses The Effect of Foreign Currency Holdings
What Is the Actual Money Multiplier in the Economy? AROUND THE WORLD The Rise and Fall of the Famous (and Infamous) Swiss Bank Account
The Federal Reserve System The Structure of the Federal Reserve The Board of Governors Federal Reserve Banks Federal Open Market Committee The Fed as Lender of Last Resort
The Federal Reserve at Work: Tools, Targets, and Policy Lags 49
Reserve Requirements Discount Rate Open Market Operations The Federal Funds Target
Monetary Policy Lags Information Lags Recognition Lags Decision Lags
ISSUE What Can the Fed Do When Interest Rates Reach 0%? Implementation Lags
Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
13 Monetary Policy
BY THE NUMBERS Monetary Policy in Action
What Is Monetary Policy? The Twin Goals of Monetary Policy Examples of Monetary Policy in Action Why Is the Interest Rate So Important to the Economy? When Is It Optimal to Loosen or Tighten Monetary Policy? Expansionary Monetary Policy Contractionary Monetary Policy
Monetary Theories The Short Run Versus the Long Run: What’s the Difference? The Long Run: The Classical Theory IRVING FISHER (1867–1947)
Short-Run Effects of Monetary Policy Money Illusion and Sticky Wages and Prices Keynesian Model Monetarist Model
NOBEL PRIZE: MILTON FRIEDMAN (1912–2006)
50
Summary of the Effectiveness of Monetary Policy Monetary Policy and Economic Shocks Demand Shocks Supply Shocks Implications for Short-Run Monetary Policy
Modern Monetary Policy Rules Versus Discretion The Federal Funds Target and the Taylor Rule A Recap of the Fed’s Policy Tools Transparency and the Federal Reserve ISSUE The Record of the Fed’s Performance
New Monetary Policy Challenges The Fed: Dealing with an Economic Crisis Not Seen in 80 Years The Eurozone Crisis and the Role of the European Central Bank ISSUE The Challenges of Monetary Policy with Regional Differences in Economic Performance AROUND THE WORLD Why Would a Country Give Up Its Monetary Policy?
Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
14 Macroeconomic Policy: Challenges in a Global Economy
BY THE NUMBERS The Long Road Back: The Great Recession and the Jobless Recovery
The Great Recession and Macroeconomic Policy From the Housing Bubble to the Financial Crisis Subprime Mortgages and Collateralized Debt Obligations Collapsing Financial Markets
The Government’s Policy Response The Financial Crisis and Its Effects
Effectiveness of Macroeconomic Policy: Phillips Curves and Rational 51
Expectations Unemployment and Inflation: Phillips Curves Productivity, Prices, and Wages The Importance of Inflationary Expectations Inflationary Expectations and the Phillips Curve The Long-Run Phillips Curve Accelerating Inflation Returning Inflation to Normal Levels
NOBEL PRIZE: ROBERT LUCAS Rational Expectations and Policy Formation Policy Implications of Rational Expectations A Critique of Rational Expectations
Macroeconomic Issues That Confront Our Future Are Recoveries Becoming “Jobless Recoveries”? Will Rising Debt and Future Debt Obligations Lead to Inflation? Rising Future Debt Obligations: Health Care and Social Security The Cost of Financing Debt The Effects of Debt on Inflation
ISSUE Inflating Our Way Out of Debt: Is This an Effective Approach?
Will Globalization Lead to Increased Obstacles to Economic Growth? AROUND THE WORLD Life on the Autobahn: Germany’s Role in European Growth and Stability
Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
15 International Trade
BY THE NUMBERS International Trade
The Gains from Trade Absolute and Comparative Advantage Gains from Trade Practical Constraints on Trade
ISSUE The Challenge of Measuring Imports and Exports in a Global Economy
52
The Terms of Trade Determining the Terms of Trade The Impact of Trade How Trade Is Restricted Effects of Tariffs and Quotas ISSUE Do Foreign Trade Zones Help or Hurt American Consumers and Workers?
Arguments Against Free Trade Traditional Economic Arguments Infant Industry Argument Antidumping Low Foreign Wages National Defense Argument
Recent Globalization Concerns Trade and Domestic Employment Trade and the Environment Trade and Its Effect on Working Conditions in Developing Nations
AROUND THE WORLD Can One Country’s Festival Disrupt World Trade?
Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
16 Open Economy Macroeconomics
BY THE NUMBERS The Foreign Exchange Market
The Balance of Payments The Current Account Imports and Exports Income Transfers
The Capital Account
Exchange Rates Defining Exchange Rates
53
Nominal Exchange Rates Real Exchange Rates Purchasing Power Parity
Exchange Rate Determination A Market for Foreign Exchange Flexible Exchange Rates Currency Appreciation and Depreciation Determinants of Exchange Rates
Exchange Rates and the Current Account Changes in Inflation Rates Changes in Domestic Disposable Income
Exchange Rates and the Capital Account Interest Rate Changes Expected Exchange Rate Changes
Exchange Rates and Aggregate Supply and Demand ISSUE Would a Stronger Chinese Yuan Be Good for Americans?
Monetary and Fiscal Policy in an Open Economy Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rate Systems Pegging Exchange Rates Under a Flexible Exchange Rate System Policies Under Fixed Exchange Rates Policies Under Flexible Exchange Rates AROUND THE WORLD Hyder, Alaska: An American Town That Uses the Canadian Dollar NOBEL PRIZE: ROBERT MUNDELL
Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
Sources for By the Numbers Glossary Index
54
Macroeconomics Principles for a Changing World
55
1
Exploring Economics
56
Understanding how economics explains everyday decisions made by individuals, 57
businesses, and governments
Learning Objectives 1.1
Explain how economic analysis can be used in decision making.
1.2
Differentiate between microeconomics and macroeconomics.
1.3
Describe how economists use models.
1.4
Describe the ceteris paribus assumption.
1.5
Discuss the difference between efficiency and equity.
1.6
Describe the key principles in economics.
1.7
Apply the key principles to situations faced in everyday life.
I
magine jumping over open pits of fire, being chased by crazed people with sticks, diving through muddy pools of water under barbed wire, and climbing over a series of rocky walls. This does not describe a war zone or a military boot camp. Instead, these are typical challenges found in the increasingly popular sport of obstacle course racing. Also known as
Warrior Dash, Tough Mudder, and Spartan Runs, obstacle course racing incorporates demanding physical and mental obstacles to challenge individuals over the standard 3- to 5-mile (or longer) length of the course. Does this sound thrilling? Or perhaps crazy? These are common thoughts that come to mind when people talk about the increasing popularity of new adventure sports. Would you imagine that whether or not to participate in such an activity is an economic question? Most people probably would not. But this example resembles an economic problem in many ways. Obstacle course racing involves a challenge, one with a benefit (a sense of accomplishment) and a cost (including monetary costs, physical demands on the body, and a risk of injury). It involves tradeoffs such as the countless hours spent practicing and training in order to be successful. And it involves societal beliefs about whether such activities should be regulated or restricted to persons of a minimum age and well-being. Benefits, costs, tradeoffs, and regulation: These are the foundations for making an economic decision. Nearly all decisions made by individuals, firms, and governments in pursuit of an objective or goal can be understood using these economic concepts. By the end of this course, you will come to understand that economics involves all types of decisions, from small everyday decisions on how to manage one’s time to world-changing decisions made by the president of the United States. Consumers make decisions about what clothes to buy and what foods to eat. Businesses must decide what products to make and how much of each product to stock on store shelves. Indeed, one cannot escape making decisions, and the outcomes of these decisions affect not only our own lives but also those of entire societies and countries.
58
You still might be asking yourself: Why should I study economics? First, you will spend roughly the next 40 years working in an economic environment: paying taxes, experiencing ups and downs in the overall economy, investing money, and voting on various economic issues. It will benefit you to know how the economy works. More important, economic analysis gives you a structure from which you can make decisions in a more rational manner. Economics teaches you how to make better and wiser decisions given your limited resources. This course may well change the way you look at the world. It can open your eyes to how you make everyday decisions, from what to buy to where you choose to live. Like our opening example, economic analysis involves decisions that are not just “economic” in the general sense of the term. Certainly, economic thinking may change your views on spending and saving, on how you feel about government debt, and on your opinion of environmental policies or globalization. But you also may develop a different perspective on how much time to study for each of your courses this term, or where you might go for spring break this year. Such is the wide scope of economic analysis.
59
This introductory chapter takes a broad look at economics. First, we study a key method of economic analysis:
60
model building. Economists use stylized facts and the technique of holding some variables constant to develop testable theories about how consumers, businesses, and governments make decisions. Then we turn to a short discussion of some key principles of economics to give you a sense of the guiding concepts you will encounter in this book. This chapter will give you a sense of what economics is, what concepts it uses, and what it finds to be important. Do not go into this chapter thinking you have to memorize these concepts. Rather, use this chapter to get a sense of the broad scope of economics. You will be given many opportunities to understand and use these concepts throughout this course. Return to this chapter at the end of the course and see if everything has now become crystal clear.
61
WHAT IS ECONOMICS ABOUT? Economics is a very broad subject. It often seems that economics has something important to say about almost everything. To boil it down to a simple definition, economics is about making choices. Economics studies how individuals, firms, and societies make decisions to maximize their well-being given limitations. In other words, economics attempts to address the problem of having too many wants but too few resources to achieve them all, an important concept called scarcity. Note that scarcity is not the same thing as something being scarce. Although all resources are scarce, certain goods are less scarce than others. For example, cars are not very scarce—there are car dealerships around the country chock-full of cars ready to be sold, but that doesn’t mean you can go out tonight and buy three. Scarcity refers to the fact that one must make choices given the resource limitations she or he faces. economics The study of how individuals, firms, and society make decisions to allocate limited resources to many competing wants. scarcity Our unlimited wants clash with limited resources, leading to scarcity. Everyone (rich and poor) faces scarcity because, at a minimum, our time on earth is limited. Economics focuses on the allocation of scarce resources to satisfy unlimited wants as fully as possible.
What kind of limitations are we referring to here? It could be money, but money is not the only resource that allows us to achieve the life we want. It’s also our time, our knowledge, our work ethic, and anything else that can be used to achieve our goals. It is this broad notion of economics being the study of how people make decisions to allocate scarce resources to competing wants that allows the subject to be applied to so many topics and applications.
Why Should One Study Economics?
The first answer that might come to mind as to why you are taking this course is “because I have to.” Although economics is a required course for many college students, economics should be thought of as something much, much more. For example, studying economics can prepare you for many types of careers in major industries and government. Studying economics also is a great launching pad for pursuing a graduate degree in law, business, or other fields. More practically speaking, economics helps you to think more clearly about the decisions you make every day and to understand better how the economy functions and why certain things happen the way they do. For example, economics has some important things to say about the environment. Most people care about the environment to some degree, and do their part by recycling, not littering, and turning off the lights when leaving a room. But not all people make decisions in the same way: Some might do much more to conserve resources, such as driving less or driving a more fuel-efficient car, joining a local organization to plant trees, or even writing to policymakers to support sustainability legislation. The extent to which people participate in environmental activities depends on the benefit they perceive when pursuing such actions compared to the costs, which can include monetary costs, time and effort, and forgone opportunities such as driving a larger, more comfortable car. Economics looks at all of these factors to determine how people make decisions that affect the environment, which affects us all. Economics is a way of thinking about an issue, not just a discipline that has money as its chief focus. Economists tend to have a rational take on nearly everything. Now all of this “analysis/speculation” may bring only limited insight in some cases, but it gives you some idea of how economists think. We look for rational responses to incentives. Incentives are the factors, both good and bad, that influence how people make decisions. For example, tough admissions requirements for graduate school provide an incentive for students to study harder in college, while lucrative commissions push car salespeople to sell even the ugliest or most unreliable car. Economics is all about how people respond to incentives. We begin most questions by considering how rational people would respond to the incentives that specific situations provide. Sometimes (maybe even often) this analysis leads us down an unexpected path. incentives The factors that motivate individuals and firms to make decisions in their best interest.
62
Microeconomics Versus Macroeconomics Economics is split into two broad categories: microeconomics and macroeconomics. Microeconomics deals with decision making by individuals, businesses, and industries. It is concerned with issues such as which orange juice to buy, which job to take, and where to go on vacation, as well as which items a business should produce and what price it should charge, and whether a market should be left on its own or be regulated. microeconomics The study of the decision making by individuals, businesses, and industries.
Microeconomics looks at how markets are structured. Some markets are very competitive, and where many firms offer similar products. Other markets have only one or two large firms, offering little choice. What decisions do businesses make under different market structures? Microeconomics also extends to such topics as labor laws, environmental policy, and health care policy. How can we use the tools of microeconomics to analyze the costs and benefits of differing policies? Macroeconomics, on the other hand, focuses on the broader issues we face as a nation. Most of us don’t care whether an individual buys Brooks or Sperry shoes. We do care whether prices of all goods and services rise. Inflation—a general increase in prices economy-wide—affects all of us. So does unemployment (virtually every person will at some point in their life be unemployed, even if it’s just for a short time when switching from one job to another) and economic growth. What decisions do governments make to deal with macroeconomic problems such as inflation and recessions? macroeconomics The study of the broader issues in the economy such as inflation, unemployment, and national output of goods and services.
Macroeconomics uses microeconomic tools to answer some questions, but its main focus is on the broad aggregate variables of the economy. Macroeconomics has its own terms and topics, such as business cycles, recession, and unemployment. Macroeconomics looks at policies that increase economic growth, the impact of government spending and taxation, the effect of monetary policy on the economy, and inflation. It also looks closely at theories of international trade and international finance. All of these topics have broad impacts on our economy and our standard of living. Still not clear? Here’s an easy way to remember the difference between microeconomics and macroeconomics. Only one letter separates the two terms, so just remember that the “i” in microeconomics refers to “individual” entities (such as a person or a firm), while the “a” in macroeconomics refers to “aggregate” entities (such as cities or a nation as a whole). Although we break economics into microeconomics and macroeconomics, there is considerable overlap in the analysis. Both involve the analysis of how individuals, firms, and governments make decisions that affect the lives of people. We use simple supply and demand analysis to understand both individual markets and the general economy as a whole. You will find yourself using concepts from microeconomics to understand fluctuations in the macroeconomy. Economics is a social science that uses many facts and figures to develop and express ideas. This inevitably involves numbers. For macroeconomics, this means getting used to talking and thinking in huge numbers: billions (nine zeros) and trillions (twelve zeros). Today, we are talking about a federal government budget of about $4 trillion. To wrap your mind around such a huge number, consider how long it would take to spend a trillion dollars if you spent a dollar every second, or $86,400 per day. To spend $1 trillion would require over 31,000 years. And the federal government now spends about 4 times this much in one year.
Economic Theories and Reality
If you flip through any economics text, you’ll likely see a multitude of graphs, charts, and equations. This book is no exception. The good news is that all of the graphs and charts become relatively easy to understand, since they all basically read the same way. The few equations in this book stem from elementary algebra. Once you get through one equation, the rest are similar. Graphs, charts, and equations are often the simplest and most efficient ways to express data and ideas. Equations
63
are used to express relationships between two variables. Complex and wordy discussions can often be reduced to a simple graph or figure. These are efficient techniques for expressing economic ideas.
Model Building
As you study economics this term, you will encounter stylized approaches to a number of issues. By stylized, we mean that economists boil down facts to their basic relevant elements and use assumptions to develop a stylized (simple) model to analyze the issue. There are always situations that lie outside these models, but they are exceptions. Economists generalize about economic behavior and reach broadly applicable results. We begin with relatively simple models, then gradually build to more difficult ones. For example, in the next chapter, we introduce one of the simplest models in economics, the production possibilities frontier which illustrates the limits of economic activity. This model has profound implications for the issue of economic growth. We can add in more dimensions and make the model more complex, but often this complexity does not provide any greater insight than the simple model.
Ceteris Paribus: All Else Held Constant
To aid in our model building, economists use the ceteris paribus assumption: “Holding all other things equal.” That means we will hold some important variables constant. For example, to determine how many songs you might be willing to download from iTunes in any given month, we would hold your monthly income constant. We then would change song prices to see the impact on the number purchased (again holding your monthly income constant). ceteris paribus Assumption used in economics (and other disciplines as well), that other relevant factors or variables are held constant.
Though model building can lead to surprising insights into how economic actors and economies behave, it is not the end of the story. Economic insights lead to economic theories, but these theories must then be tested. In some cases, such as the extent to which a housing bubble could lead to a financial crisis, economic predictions turned out to be false. Thus, model building is a process—models are created and then tested. If models fail to explain reality, new models are constructed.
Efficiency Versus Equity Efficiency deals with how well resources are used and allocated. No one likes waste. Much of economic analysis is directed toward ensuring that the most efficient outcomes result from public policy. Production efficiency occurs when goods are produced at the lowest possible cost, and allocative efficiency occurs when individuals who desire a product the most get those goods and services. As an example, it would not make sense for society to allocate a large amount of cranberry sauce to someone who wouldn’t eat it. Efficient policies are generally good policies. efficiency How well resources are used and allocated. Do people get the goods and services they want at the lowest possible resource cost? This is the chief focus of efficiency.
The other side of the coin is equity, or fairness. Is it fair that the CEOs of large companies make hundreds of times more money than rank-and-file workers? Is it fair that some have so much and others have so little? Should society take care of the homeless and disabled? There are many divergent views about fairness until we get to extreme cases. When just a few people earn nearly all of the income and control nearly all of a society’s wealth, most people agree that this is unfair. equity The fairness of various issues and policies.
Throughout this course, you will see instances where efficiency and equity collide. You may agree that a specific policy is efficient, but think it is unfair to some group of people. This will be especially evident when you consider tax policy and its impact on income distribution. Fairness, or equity, is a subjective concept, and each of us has different ideas about what is just and fair. When it comes to public policy issues, economics will help you see the tradeoffs between equity and efficiency, but you will ultimately have to make up your own mind about the wisdom of
64
the policy given these tradeoffs.
ISSUE Do Economists Ever Agree on Anything? Give me a one-handed economist! All my economists say, “on one hand . . . on the other.” —Harry S. Truman President Truman once exclaimed that the country needed more one-handed economists. What did he mean by that? He was saying that anytime an economist talks about a solution to an economic problem, the economist will often follow that statement by saying, “on the other hand. . . .” Economics is about making choices with scarce resources and the tradeoffs that result. Because individuals place different values on the benefits and costs within these tradeoffs, nearly every economic issue can be viewed from different perspectives, so much so that economists seemingly disagree with one another on everything. For example, suppose we debate whether gasoline taxes are too high. On the one hand, higher gasoline taxes will reduce oil consumption, reduce pollution, reduce traffic congestion, and generate money to promote public transportation such as buses, subways, and high-speed trains. On the other hand, higher gasoline taxes raise the cost of commuting to work and school, make travel more expensive, and result in higher prices for many consumer goods due to higher shipping costs. Different opinions about the relative weights of benefits and costs make economic policymaking challenging. Economic conditions are always changing. This is why economists rely so much on models and assumptions in order to prescribe a solution based on the conditions facing the economy.
But despite differences and frequent disagreements in economic policy, economists do agree on many things, such as the value of specialization, the efficiency of markets, and the role of incentives. These areas of consensus are grounded in the key economic principles described in the next section of this chapter.
65
Positive Versus Normative Questions Returning to the example in the chapter opener, we ask ourselves many questions whenever a decision needs to be made or an issue is debated. Some questions involve the understanding of basic facts, such as how risky a particular sport is, or how much enjoyment one receives from participating in the sport. Economists call these types of questions positive questions. Positive questions (which need not be positive or upbeat in the literal sense) are questions that can be answered one way or another as long as the information is available. This does not mean that people will always agree on an answer, because presentation of facts and information can differ. positive question A question that can be answered using available information or facts.
Another type of question that arises is how something ought to be, such as whether extreme sports should be banned or whether additional safety measures should be required. Economists call these types of questions normative questions. Normative questions involve societal beliefs on what should or should not be done; differing opinions on an issue can sometimes make normative questions difficult to resolve. normative question A question whose answer is based on societal beliefs on what should or should not take place.
Throughout this book, positive and normative questions will arise, which will play an important role in how individuals and firms make decisions, and how governments form policy proposals that may or may not become law. Indeed, economics encompasses many ideas and questions that affect everyone.
CHECKPOINT WHAT IS ECONOMICS ABOUT? Economics is about making decisions under scarcity, in which wants are unlimited but resources are limited. Economics is separated into two broad categories: microeconomics and macroeconomics. Microeconomics deals with individuals, firms, and industries and how they make decisions. Macroeconomics focuses on broader economic issues such as inflation, employment and unemployment, and economic growth. Economics uses a stylized approach, creating simple models that hold all other relevant factors constant (ceteris paribus). Economists and policymakers often face a tradeoff between efficiency and equity. Positive questions can be answered with facts and information, while normative questions ask how something should or ought to be.
QUESTION:
In each of the following situations, determine whether it is a microeconomic or macroeconomic issue. 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7.
Hewlett-Packard announces that it is lowering the price of its printers by 15%. The president proposes a tax cut. You decide to look for a new job. The economy is in a recession, and the job market is bad. The Federal Reserve announces that it is raising interest rates because it fears inflation. You get a nice raise. Average wages grew by 2% last year.
Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
66
67
KEY PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS Economics has a set of key principles that show up continually in economic analysis. Some are more restricted to specific issues, but most apply universally. These principles should give you a sense of what you will learn in this course. In the following, we summarize eight key principles that will be applied throughout the entire book. By the end of this course, these principles should be crystal clear and you will likely find yourself using these principles throughout your life, even if you never take another economics course.
Principle 1: Economics Is Concerned With Making Choices With Limited Resources
Economics deals with nearly every type of decision we face each day. But when a typical person is asked what economics is about, the most common answer is “money.” Why is economics commonly misconceived as dealing only with money? This may be due in part to how economics is portrayed in the news—dealing with financial issues, jobs and wages, and the cost of living, among other money matters. While money matters are indeed an important issue studied in economics, you now know that economics involves much, much more. Economics is about making decisions on allocating limited resources to maximize an individual or society’s wellbeing. Money is just one source of well-being, assuming that more money makes a person happier, all else equal. But other factors also improve a person’s well-being, such as receiving a day off from work with pay. Even if one does not have a lot of money or free time, satisfaction can come from other activities or events, such as participating in a fun activity with friends or family, or watching one’s favorite team win. In sum, many aspects of life contribute to the well-being of individuals and of society. Unfortunately, often these are limited by various resource constraints. Therefore, one must think of economics in a broad sense of determining how best to manage all of society’s resources (not just money) in order to maximize well-being. This involves tradeoffs and opportunity costs, which we consider next.
Principle 2: When Making Decisions, One Must Take Into Account Tradeoffs and Opportunity Costs Wouldn’t it be great if we all had the resources of Mark Zuckerberg (the founder of Facebook) and could buy just about any material possession one could possibly want? Most likely we won’t, so back to reality. We all have limited resources. Some of us are more limited than others, but each of us, even Mark Zuckerberg, faces limitations (and not because Mark chooses to wear a $30 shirt instead of a $3,000 Brioni suit). For example, we all face time limitations: There are only 24 hours in a day, and some of that must be spent sleeping. The fact that we have many wants but limited resources (scarcity) means that we must make tradeoffs in nearly everything we do. In other words, we have to decide between alternatives, which always exist whenever we make a decision.
68
How is this accomplished? What factors determine whether you buy a nicer car or use the extra money to pay down debt? Or whether you should spend the weekend at a local music festival or use the time to study for an exam? Economists use an important term to help weigh the benefits and costs of every decision we make, and that term is opportunity cost. In fact, economics is often categorized as the discipline that always weighs benefits against costs. opportunity cost The value of the next best alternative; what you give up to do something or purchase something.
At its very core, opportunity cost is determined by asking yourself, in any situation, “What could I be doing right now if I weren’t ____________ (fill in the activity)?” or “What could I have bought if I hadn’t bought this ____________ (fill in the last good or service you bought)?” In other words, opportunity cost measures the value of the next best alternative use of your time or money, or what you give up when you make an economic decision. And since there are always alternatives, one cannot avoid opportunity costs. A common mistake that people make is that they sometimes do not fully take their opportunity costs into account. Have you ever camped out overnight in order to get tickets for a concert? Was it even worth going to the concert? Opportunity cost includes the value of everything you give up in order to attend the concert, including the cost of the tickets and transportation, and the time spent buying tickets, traveling to and from the venue, and of course attending the concert. The sum of all opportunity costs can sometimes outweigh the benefits. Another example of miscalculating opportunity costs occurs when a student spends a copious amount of time to dispute a $15 parking ticket. Like the previous example, the opportunity cost (time and effort disputing the ticket that
69
can be used for some other activity) may exceed the $15 savings if successful and certainly if the attempt to dispute the ticket fails. In other cases, individuals do respond to opportunity costs. Why do many people choose a paper towel over a hand dryer in a public restroom when given the choice? It’s because the opportunity cost of using the hand dryer is higher than using a paper towel. Every activity involves opportunity costs. Sleeping, eating, studying, partying, running, hiking, and so on, all require that we spend resources that could be used on another activity. Opportunity cost varies from person to person. A company president rushing from meeting to meeting has a higher opportunity cost than a retired senior citizen, and therefore is more likely to choose the quickest option to accomplish day-to-day activities. Opportunity costs apply to us as individuals and to societies as a whole. For example, if a country chooses to spend more on environmental conservation, it must use resources that could be used to promote other objectives, such as education and health care.
Principle 3: Specialization Leads to Gains for All Involved Whenever we pursue an activity or a task, we use time that could be used for other activities or tasks. However, sometimes these other tasks are best left to others to perform. Life would be much more difficult if we all had to grow our own food. This highlights the idea that tradeoffs (especially with one’s time) can lead to better outcomes if one is able to specialize in activities in which she or he is more proficient. Suppose you and your roommate can each cook your own dinner and clean your own rooms. Alternatively, you might have your roommate clean both rooms (he’s better at it than you) in exchange for you preparing dinner for two (you’re a better cook). Using this arrangement, both tasks are completed in less time since each of you is specializing in the activity you’re better at, plus both of you will benefit from a cleaner apartment and a tastier dinner. Therefore, specialization in tasks in which one is more proficient can lead to gains for all parties as long as exchange is possible and those involved trade in a mutually beneficial manner. Each person is acting on the opportunity to improve his or her well-being, an example of how incentives affect people’s lives.
Principle 4: People Respond to Incentives, Both Good and Bad
Each time an individual or a firm makes a decision, that person or firm is acting on an incentive that drives the individual or firm to choose an action. These incentives often occur naturally. For example, we choose to eat every day because we face an incentive to survive, and we study and work hard because we face an incentive to be successful in our careers. However, incentives also can be formed by policies set by government to encourage individuals and firms to act in certain ways, and by businesses to encourage consumers to change their consumption habits. For example, tax policy rests on the idea that people respond to incentives. Do we want to encourage people to save for their retirement? Then let them deduct a certain amount that they can put into a tax-deferred retirement account. Do we want businesses to spend more to stimulate the economy? Then give them tax credits for new investment. Do we want people to go to college? Then give them tax advantages for setting up education savings accounts.
ISSUE Would a City Change Its Name for a Game Show? Driving along Interstate 25 in central New Mexico, one encounters a city with a very peculiar name,
70
one that required the state’s Department of Transportation to order extra-long road signs: Truth or Consequences. Originally named Hot Springs, the small city is popular for its natural hot springs and small quaint lodges that dot the landscape in this remote part of the desert. How did the city of Hot Springs end up changing its name? In 1950 a popular radio game show called Truth or Consequences, hosted by Ralph Edwards, offered a challenge. If any city was willing to rename itself Truth or Consequences, Mr. Edwards would host his show from that location. Hot Springs saw this as an opportunity to raise its city profile, and therefore acted on the incentive to be the first and only city to accept the challenge. It subsequently changed its official name to Truth or Consequences, New Mexico, a name that remains in use. Truth or Consequences has benefited from its name change long after it. The city continues to host an annual fiesta that welcomed Mr. Edwards in person every year for the 50 years that followed the name change. Today, Truth or Consequences remains a small city of 6,500 residents and is still popular for its natural springs. But on the horizon is another famous person, Richard Branson, the founder of Virgin Galactic, who plans to develop a commercial space flight industry in New Mexico. The location, Spaceport America, is just 30 miles from Truth or Consequences, another attraction that will add to the city’s unique character.
Tax policy is an obvious example in which people follow incentives. But this principle can be seen in action wherever you look. Want to encourage people to fly during the slow travel season? Offer price discounts or bonus frequent flyer miles for flying during that time. Want to increase business at restaurants? Give early-bird discounts to those willing to eat at 5:00 P.M., before peak dining time. Note that in saying that people follow incentives, economists do not claim that everyone follows each incentive every time. Though you may not want to eat dinner at 5:00 P.M., there might be other people who are willing to eat earlier in return for a price discount. If not properly constructed, incentives might lead to harmful outcomes. During the 2008 financial crisis, it became clear that the way incentives for traders and executives were set up by Wall Street investment banks was misguided. Traders and executives were paid bonuses based on short-term profits. This encouraged them to take extreme risks to generate quick profits and high bonuses with little regard for the long-term viability of the bank. The bank might have been gone the next day, but these people still had those huge bonuses. Responding to badly designed incentives is often described as greed, but they are not always the same. If you found a $20 bill on the sidewalk, would you pick it up? Of course, but would that make you a greedy person? The stranger who accidentally dropped the bill an hour ago might think so, but you are just responding to an incentive to pick up the money before the next lucky person does. Could incentives ever be designed to prevent people from picking up money they find? It may surprise you that one industry has: In many casinos, it is prohibited to keep chips or money you find on the floor. The natural tendency for society to respond to incentives leads individuals and firms to work hard and generate
71
ideas that increase productivity, a measure of a society’s capacity to produce that determines our standard of living. A worker who can do twice as much as another is likely to earn a higher salary, because productivity and pay tend to go together. The same is true for nations. Countries with the highest standards of living are also the most productive.
Principle 5: Rational Behavior Requires Thinking on the Margin Have you ever noticed that when you eat at an all-you-can-eat buffet, you always go away fuller than when you order and eat at a nonbuffet restaurant? Is this phenomenon unique to you, or is there something more fundamental? Remember, economists look at facts to find incentives to economic behavior. In this case, people are just rationally responding to the price of additional food. They are thinking on the margin. In a nonbuffet restaurant, dessert costs extra, and you make a decision as to whether the enjoyment you receive from the dessert (the marginal benefit) is worth the extra cost (the marginal cost). At the buffet, dessert is included, which means the marginal cost is zero. Even so, you still must ask yourself if dessert will give you satisfaction. If the dessert tastes terrible or adds unwanted calories to your diet, then you might pass on dessert even if it is free. But the fact that one is more likely to have dessert at a buffet than at a menu-based restaurant highlights the notion that people tend to think on the margin. The idea of thinking on the margin applies to a society as well. Like asking ourselves whether we want another serving of dessert, a society must ask itself whether it wants a little bit more or a little bit less of something, and policymakers and/or citizens vote on such policy proposals. An example of society thinking on the margin is whether taxes should be raised a little to pay for other projects, or whether a country should send up another space exploration craft to study other planets. Throughout this book, we will see examples of thinking on the margin. A business uses marginal analysis to determine how much of its products it is willing to supply to the market. Individuals use marginal analysis to determine how many hours to exercise or study. And governments use marginal analysis to determine how much pollution should be permitted.
Principle 6: Markets Are Generally Efficient; When They Aren’t, Government Can Sometimes Correct the Failure
Individuals and firms make decisions that maximize their well-being, and markets bring buyers and sellers together. Private markets and the incentives they provide are the best mechanisms known today for providing products and services. There is no government food board that makes sure that bread, cereal, coffee, and all the other food products you demand are on your plate during the day. The vast majority of products we consume are privately provided. Competition for the consumer dollar forces firms to provide products at the lowest possible price, or some other firm will undercut their high price. New products enter the market and old products die out. Such is the dynamic characteristic of markets. What drives and disciplines markets? Prices and profits are the keys. Profits drive entrepreneurs to provide new products (think of Apple) or existing products at lower prices (think of Walmart). When prices and profits get too high in any market, new firms jump in with lower prices to grab away customers. This competition, or sometimes even the threat of competition, keeps markets from exploiting consumers. Individuals and firms respond to prices in markets by altering the choices and quantities of goods they purchase and sell, respectively. These actions highlight the ability of markets to provide an efficient outcome for all. Markets can achieve this efficiency without a central planner telling what people should buy or what firms should sell. This phenomenon that markets promote efficiency through the incentives faced by individuals and firms (as if they were guided by an omnipotent force) is referred to as the invisible hand, a term coined by Adam Smith, considered the father of modern economics. As efficient as markets usually are, society does not desire a market for everything. For example, markets for hard drugs or child pornography are largely deemed undesirable. In other cases, a market does not provide enough of a good or service, such as public parks or public education. For these products and services, markets can fail to
72
provide an optimal outcome. But when markets do fail, they tend to do so in predictable ways. Where consumers have no choice but to buy from one firm (such as a local water company), the market will fail to provide the best solution, and government regulation is often used to protect consumers. Another example is pollution: Left unregulated, companies often will pollute the air and water. Governments then intervene to deal with this market failure. Finally, people rely on information to make rational decisions. When information is not readily available or is known only to one side of the market, markets again can fail to produce the socially desirable outcome. Markets can be crowded and chaotic, but they generally promote an efficient outcome by bringing buyers and sellers together.
We also can extend the idea of market efficiency to the greater economy. The market forces of supply and demand generally keep the economy in equilibrium. But occasionally, fluctuations in the macroeconomy will occur, and markets take time to readjust on their own. In some cases, the economy becomes stuck in a severe downturn. In these instances, government can smooth the fluctuations in the overall economy by using policies such as government spending or tax cuts. But remember, just because the government can successfully intervene does not mean it always successfully intervenes. The macroeconomy is not a simple machine. Successful policymaking is a tough task.
Principle 7: Economic Growth, Low Unemployment, and Low Inflation Are Economic Goals That Do Not Always Coincide The reliance on private markets and reasonable government intervention aims to maximize societal gains in terms of higher incomes and standards of living. The key to higher standards of living is economic growth, which can be
73
measured a number of ways, most commonly by estimating the change in a country’s real gross domestic income per capita. Yet, other measures of economic growth include average household income, quality of education, infrastructure development, improvement in technology and innovation, environmental sustainability, and poverty reduction. The goal of economic growth is fostered by policies set by government, including fiscal policy and monetary policy. But things are not always so simple, given the two persistent economic obstacles that naturally occur in the economy: unemployment and inflation. Unemployment and inflation often run opposite to one another; for example, when unemployment is high, inflation is generally low, and vice versa. When either unemployment or inflation is too high, economic growth can be inhibited. Government policy is therefore used to correct one problem at the potential expense of exacerbating the other. In 2015 the U.S. Federal Reserve faced an important decision: whether to raise interest rates, which had been kept very low for almost a decade, to address unemployment stemming from the financial crisis of 2007–2009. Although raising interest rates would help keep inflation from rising, doing so may cause unemployment to rise. Determining policy to boost economic growth is like walking a tightrope: One must stay balanced to prevent toppling over to one side.
ADAM SMITH (1723–1790)
W
hen Adam Smith was 4 years old, he was kidnapped and held for ransom. Had his captors not taken fright and returned the boy unharmed, the history of economics might well have turned out differently. Born in Kirkaldy, Scotland, in 1723, Smith graduated from the University of Glasgow at age 17 and was awarded a scholarship to Oxford. Smith considered his time at Oxford to be largely wasted. Returning to Scotland in 1751, Smith was named Professor of Moral Philosophy at the University of Glasgow. After 12 years at Glasgow, Smith began tutoring the son of a wealthy Scottish nobleman. This job provided him with the opportunity to spend several years touring the European continent with his young charge. In Paris, Smith met some of the leading French economists of the day, which helped stoke his own interest in political economy. While there, he wrote a friend, “I have begun to write a book in order to pass the time.” Returning to Kirkaldy in 1766, Smith spent the next decade finishing An Inquiry Into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Before publication in 1776, he read sections of the text to Benjamin Franklin. Smith’s genius was in taking the existing forms of economic analysis available at the time and putting them together in a systematic fashion to make sense of the national economy as a whole. Smith demonstrated how individuals left free to pursue their own economic interests end up acting in ways that enhance the welfare of all. This is Smith’s famous “invisible hand.” In Smith’s words: “By directing that industry in such a manner as its produce may be of the greatest value, he intends only his own gain, and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention.” How important was Adam Smith? He has been called the “father of political economy.” Many of the foundations of economic analysis we still use today are based on Adam Smith’s writings of several centuries ago. Information from Howard Marshall, The Great Economists: A History of Economic Thought (New York: Pitman Publishing), 1967; Paul Strathern, A Brief History of Economic Genius (New York: Texere), 2002; Ian Ross, The Life of Adam Smith (Oxford: Clarendon Press), 1995.
Principle 8: Institutions and Human Creativity Help 74
Explain the Wealth of Nations We have seen how individuals and firms make decisions to maximize their well-being, and how tradeoffs, specialization, incentives, and marginal analysis play an important role. We then saw how markets bring buyers and sellers together to promote better outcomes, and that governments sometimes step in when markets fail to produce the best outcome. But how does all of this affect the overall wealth of a nation? Two important factors influencing the wealth of nations are good institutions and human creativity. Institutions include a legal system to enforce contracts and laws and to protect the rights of citizens and the ideas they create, a legislative process to develop laws and policies that provide incentives to individuals and firms to work hard, a government free of corruption, and a strong monetary system.
Nunavut: Land of Abundance and Scarcity How does the condition of scarcity determine the economic tradeoffs observed in Canada’s newest and largest province?
W
hat products is Canada known for? Canada is a northern country known for its lakes and forests. And what are forests made of? Trees, of course. How important are trees? Just ask the 32,000 residents in the newest Canadian province of Nunavut. They know, because they have no trees! Larger in area than Alaska and California combined, Nunavut has many natural resources, but lacks the one resource most often associated with Canada: trees. With much of Nunavut’s land mass situated above the tree line, it must rely on goods supplied by other provinces and imported from other countries for its building materials and agricultural products. A visit to Nunavut highlights the prevalence of scarcity and the necessity of specialization and trade.
For example, nearly all of Nunavut’s food, household goods, and building materials must be flown in to its sparsely populated communities accessible only by air or snowmobile, resulting in extremely high prices for most goods. However, Nunavut has many gold mines and fisheries that allow it to specialize and export precious metals and its famous Arctic char fish, a close relative to the salmon. Residents of even the most remote places of the world can solve the challenge of scarcity and gain access to many goods and services by engaging in specialization and trade.
75
GO TO
TO PRACTICE THE ECONOMIC CONCEPTS IN THIS STORY
Equally as important as institutions is the ability of societies to create ideas. Ideas change civilizations. Ideas are the basis for creating new products and finding new ways to improve existing goods and services. Human creativity starts with a strong educational system, and builds with proper incentives that allow innovation and creativity to flourish into marketable outcomes to improve the lives of all.
Summing It All Up: Economics Is All Around Us The examples presented in these key principles should have convinced you that economic decisions are a part of our everyday lives. Anytime we make a decision involving a purchase, or decide what we plan to eat, study, or do with our day, we are making economic decisions. Just keep in mind that economics is broader than an exclusive concern with money, despite the great emphasis placed on money in our everyday economic discussions. Instead, economics is about making decisions when we can’t have everything we want, and how we interact with others to maximize our well-being given limitations. The existence of well-functioning markets allows individuals and firms to come together to achieve good outcomes, and government institutions and policies provide incentives that can lead to a better standard of living for all residents. The key principles discussed in this chapter will be repeated throughout this book, and you will learn more about these important principles as the term progresses. For now, realize that economics rests on the foundation of a limited number of important principles. Once you fully grasp these basic ideas, the study of economics will be both rewarding and exciting, because after this course you will discover and appreciate how much more you understand the world around you.
CHECKPOINT KEY PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS Economics is concerned with making choices with limited resources. When making decisions, one must take into account tradeoffs and opportunity costs. Specialization leads to gains for all involved. People respond to incentives, both good and bad. Rational behavior requires thinking on the margin. Markets are generally efficient; when they aren’t, government can sometimes correct the failure. Economic growth, low unemployment, and low inflation are economic goals that do not always coincide. Institutions and human creativity help explain the wealth of nations.
QUESTION: McDonald’s introduced a premium blend of coffee that sells for more than its standard
coffee. How does this represent thinking at the margin?
Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
76
chapter summary Section 1 What Is Economics About?
1.1
Economics is the study of how individuals, firms, and societies make decisions to improve their well-being given limitations.
Scarcity is the idea that people have unlimited wants but limited resources. Resources can be money, time, ability, work ethic, or anything that can be used to generate productive outcomes. Scarce versus scarcity: Large uncut diamonds are scarce—only a few are found in the world each year—and are sold for millions of dollars each. A car, on the other hand, is less scarce, as car dealerships around the country have lots full of them. But both large diamonds and cars are subject
77
to scarcity—many people want them, but can only buy what they can afford.
1.2
What Is the Difference Between Microeconomics and Macroeconomics? M“i”croeconomics deals with individual entities, such as individuals, firms, and industries. (Remember “i” = “individual”.) M“a”croeconomics deals with aggregate entities, such as cities or the nation. (Remember “a” = “aggregate” or “all”.)
1.3
Economic analysis uses a stylized approach: models boil issues and facts down to their basic relevant elements.
How governments deal with pollution is an important problem that can be addressed using economic analysis.
1.4
To build models means that we make use of the ceteris paribus assumption and hold some important variables constant. This useful device often provides surprising insights about economic behavior.
1.5
Economists and policymakers often confront the tradeoff between efficiency and equity. Efficiency reflects how well resources are used and allocated. Equity (or fairness) of an outcome is a subjective matter, where differences of opinion exist.
78
Section 2 Key Principles of Economics 1.6
1. Economics Is Concerned With Making Choices With Limited Resources
1.7
Economics involves making decisions to maximize one’s well-being, which can come from many sources, including money, time, happiness, or a fortuitous event.
“We should have done something different this weekend. . . .” 2. When Making Decisions, One Must Take Into Account Tradeoffs and Opportunity Costs Choice and scarcity force tradeoffs because we face unlimited wants but limited resources. We must make tradeoffs in nearly everything we do. Opportunity costs are resources (e.g., time and money) that could be used in another activity. Everything we do involves opportunity costs, the value of the next best alternative use of our resources. 3. Specialization Leads to Gains for All Involved Specializing in tasks in which one is comparatively better at doing than another allows individuals to
79
achieve productivity gains as long as the work is shared in a mutually beneficial manner. 4. People Respond to Incentives, Both Good and Bad Incentives encourage people to work hard and be more productive.
Rewarding the top salesperson in the company creates a valuable incentive to work hard.
Maximizing your food intake at a buffet is not thinking at the margin if you end up bloated from overeating. 5. Rational Behavior Requires Thinking on the Margin When making a decision involving benefits and costs, one should continue to consume or produce as long as the marginal (additional) benefit exceeds the marginal (additional) cost. 6. Markets Are Generally Efficient; When They Aren’t, Government Can Sometimes Correct the Failure Markets bring buyers and sellers together. Competition forces firms to provide products at the lowest possible price. New products are introduced to the market and old products disappear. This dynamism makes markets efficient. In some instances, though, markets might fail, such as in dealing with pollution, leading governments to intervene to correct the failure. 7. Economic Growth, Low Unemployment, and Low Inflation Are Economic Goals That Do Not Always Coincide Economic growth is an important factor in improving the standard of living in a country. A government uses various policies to promote economic growth by keeping unemployment and inflation low. However, addressing one goal (unemployment) often comes at the expense of the other (inflation).
80
8. Institutions and Human Creativity Help Explain the Wealth of Nations Institutions include the legal system, laws and policies, a government free of corruption, and a strong monetary system. Ideas and innovation lead to new products and improve on existing ones, raising the standard of living of all residents.
Market equilibrium often is achieved by letting market participants make decisions freely.
KEY CONCEPTS economics scarcity incentives microeconomics macroeconomics ceteris paribus efficiency equity positive questions normative questions opportunity cost
QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS Check Your Understanding 1. 2. 3. 4.
What is wrong with the statement “Economics is everything to do with money”? Does your going to college have anything to do with expanding choices or reducing scarcity? Explain. What is the difference between a positive question and a normative question? You normally stay at home on Wednesday nights and study. Next Wednesday night, your best friend is having his big 21st birthday party. What is the opportunity cost of going to the party? 5. What is the incentive to spend four years of one’s life and tens of thousands of dollars to earn a college degree? 6. Why do markets typically lead to an efficient outcome for buyers and sellers?
81
Apply the Concepts 7. In contrasting equity and efficiency, why do high-tech firms seem to treat their employees better (better wages, benefits, working environments, vacations, etc.) compared to how landscaping or fast-food franchises treat their employees? Is this fair? Is it efficient? 8. Stores depend on feedback from their customers as a way to improve their business practices and to market their products. To encourage customers to offer feedback, stores will sometimes offer an incentive, such as a discount on a future purchase or additional reward points in a frequent shopper program. Why do some customers, but not all, take advantage of the incentive to leave feedback? Does the actual shopping experience of the customer affect his or her willingness to do so? 9. The black rhinoceros is extremely endangered. Its horn is considered a powerful aphrodisiac in many Asian countries, and a single horn fetches many thousands of dollars on the black market, creating a great incentive for poachers. Unlike other stories of endangered species, this one might have a simple solution. Conservationists could capture as many rhinos as possible and remove their horns, reducing the incentive to poach. Do you think this will help reduce poaching? Why or why not? 10. Most amusement parks in the United States charge a fixed price for admission, which includes unlimited roller coaster rides for the day. Some people attempt to ride the roller coasters as often as possible in order to maximize the value of their admission. Why is riding a roller coaster at an amusement park over and over to “get your money’s worth” not considered thinking on the margin? 11. Because the U.S. government wants to reduce the nation’s reliance on fossil fuels, greater use of solar panels has been encouraged among households and businesses. However, the cost of installing solar panels can be prohibitively expensive for most people. Because people follow incentives, what can the government do to encourage more households and businesses to install solar panels? 12. Some colleges and universities charge tuition by the credit hour, while others charge tuition by the term, allowing students to take as many classes as they desire. How do these tuition structures affect the incentives students face when deciding how many classes to take? Provide an example of a beneficial effect and an example of a potentially harmful effect resulting from the incentives created with each system. How does marginal analysis affect the incentives with each system?
In the News 13. The New York Times reported on January 18, 2012, in an article titled “What the Top 1% of Earners Majored In,” that 8.2% of Americans who majored in economics for their undergraduate degree are in the top 1% of salary earners. Only those who majored in pre-med had a higher percentage in the top 1%. What might be some reasons why economics majors have done well in the job market? 14. According to the U.S. Department of Transportation, U.S. commercial airlines collected over $3.8 billion in baggage fees in 2015. Some airlines even charge passengers to bring carry-on bags onto the plane. How do baggage fees affect travelers’ behavior? What is a potential cost to the airline from this policy that might offset the benefit from the bag revenues?
Solving Problems 15. Suppose your favorite band is on tour and coming to your area. Tickets are $100, and you take a day off from work for which you could have earned $60. What is your opportunity cost of going to the concert?
WORK IT OUT 16. At your local family fun center, miniature golf is $12 per person for unlimited rounds in a day, while each go-kart session is $8. If you played 3 rounds of miniature golf and rode the go-karts 3 times, what was the marginal cost of the third round of miniature golf? What was the marginal cost of the
82
third go-kart session?
USING THE NUMBERS 17. According to By the Numbers, what is the average salary for a recent graduate who majored in economics? About how much does this average salary increase by one’s mid-career? 18. According to By the Numbers, about how many economics degrees were awarded to college graduates in 2014? How does this number compare to the number of nursing degrees? Communications degrees?
ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS Checkpoint: What Is Economics About? (1) microeconomics, (2) macroeconomics, (3) microeconomics, (4) macroeconomics, (5) macroeconomics, (6) microeconomics, (7) macroeconomics. Checkpoint: Key Principles of Economics McDonald’s is adding one more product (premium coffee) to its line. Thinking at the margin entails thinking about how you can improve an operation (or increase profits) by adding to your existing product line or reducing costs.
83
Appendix
Working With Graphs and Formulas Learning Objectives A1.1
Describe the four simple forms of data graphs.
A1.2
Make use of a straightforward approach to reading graphs.
A1.3
Read linear and nonlinear graphs and know how to compute their slopes.
A1.4
Use simple linear equations to describe a line and a shift of the line.
A1.5
Explain why correlation is not the same as causation.
You can’t watch the news on television or read a newspaper without seeing a graph of some sort. If you have flipped through this book, you have seen a large number of graphs, charts, and tables, and a few simple equations. This is the language of economics. Economists deal with data for all types of issues. Just looking at data in tables often doesn’t help you discern the trends or relationships in the data. Economists develop theories and models to explain economic behavior and levels of economic activity. These theories or models are simplified representations of real-world activity. Models are designed to distill the most important relationships between variables, and then these relationships are used to predict future behavior of individuals, firms, and industries, or to predict the future course of the overall economy. In this short section, we will explore the different types of graphs you are likely to see in this course (and in the media) and then turn to an examination of how graphs are used to develop and illustrate models. This second topic leads us into a discussion of modeling relationships between data and how to represent these relationships with simple graphs and equations.
84
Graphs and Data The main forms of data graphs are time series, scatter plots, pie charts, and bar charts. Time series, as the name suggests, plot data over time. Most of the figures you will encounter in publications are time series graphs.
Time Series
Time series graphs involve plotting time (minutes, hours, days, months, quarters, or years) on the horizontal axis and the value of some variable on the vertical axis. Figure APX-1 illustrates a time series plot for civilian employment of those 16 years and older. Notice that since the early 1990s, employment has grown by almost 25 million for this group. The vertical strips in the figure designate the last three recessions. Notice that in each case when the recession hit, employment fell, then rebounded after the recession ended.
Scatter Plots Scatter plots are graphs in which two variables (neither variable being time) are plotted against each other. Scatter plots often give us a hint if the two variables are related to each other in some consistent way. Figure APX-2 plots one variable, median household income, against another variable, percentage of Americans holding a college degree. Two things can be seen in this figure. First, these two variables appear to be related to each other in a positive way. A rising percentage of college graduates leads to a higher median household income. It is not surprising that college degrees and earnings are related, because increased education leads to a more productive workforce, which translates into more income. Second, given that the years for the data are listed next to the dots, we can see that the percentage of the population with college degrees has risen significantly over the last half-century. From this simple scatter plot, we can see a lot of information and ideas about how the two variables are related. FIGURE APX-1CIVILIAN EMPLOYMENT, 16 YEARS AND OLDER
85
This time series graph shows the number of civilians 16 years and older employed in the United States since 1990. Employment has grown steadily over this period, except in times of recession, indicated by the vertical strips. Note that employment fell during the recession, and then bounced back after each recession ended.
FIGURE APX-2THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN THE MEDIAN HOUSEHOLD INCOME AND THE PERCENTAGE OF AMERICANS HOLDING A COLLEGE DEGREE
86
This scatter diagram plots the relationship between median household income and the percentage of Americans holding a college degree. Median household income increased as a greater proportion of Americans earn college degrees. Note that the percentage of Americans earning college degrees has increased significantly in the last half-century.
Pie Charts Pie charts are simple graphs showing data that can be split into percentage parts that combined make up the whole. A simple pie chart for the relative importance of components in the consumer price index (CPI) is shown in Figure APX-3. It reveals how the typical urban household budget is allocated. By looking at each slice of the pie, we see a picture of how typical families spend their income. FIGURE APX-3RELATIVE IMPORTANCE OF CONSUMER PRICE INDEX (CPI) COMPONENTS (2015)
87
This pie chart shows the relative importance of the components of the consumer price index, showing how typical urban households spend their income.
Bar Charts Bar charts use bars to show the value of specific data points. Figure APX-4 is a bar chart showing the annual changes in real (adjusted for inflation) gross domestic product (GDP). Notice that over the last 50 years, the United States has had only 7 years when GDP declined.
Simple Graphs Can Pack In a Lot of Information
It is not unusual for graphs and figures to have several things going on at once. Look at Figure APX-5, illustrating the number of social media users as a percent of each age group. On the horizontal axis are the age groups in years. On the vertical axis is the percent of each age group that regularly used social media. Figure APX-5 shows the relationship between age and social media penetration for different periods. They include the most recent period shown (August 2015), a year previous (August 2014), and eight years ago (August 2007). FIGURE APX-4PERCENT CHANGE IN REAL (INFLATION ADJUSTED) GDP
88
This bar chart shows the annual percent change in real (adjusted for inflation) gross domestic product (GDP) over the last 50 years. Over this period, GDP declined only 7 times.
FIGURE APX-5SOCIAL MEDIA USAGE ACROSS AGE GROUPS
89
These curves show the percentage of Americans using a social media site by age. The curves slope downward because older Americans are less likely to use social media than younger Americans. However, over time, more Americans in all age groups are using social media, as evidenced by each point on the August 2014 curve being higher than the corresponding point on the August 2007 curve, and each point on the August 2015 curve being higher than the corresponding point on the August 2014 curve.
You should notice two things in this figure. First, the relationship between the variables slopes downward. This means that older Americans are less likely to use social media than younger Americans. Second, use of social media has increased across all ages over the three periods studied (from August 2007 to August 2014 to August 2015) as shown by the position of the curves. Each point on the August 2015 curve is above the corresponding point on the August 2014 curve, which is subsequently above each point on the August 2007 curve.
A Few Simple Rules for Reading Graphs
Looking at graphs of data is relatively easy if you follow a few simple rules. First, read the title of the figure to get a sense of what is being presented. Second, look at the label for the horizontal axis (x axis) to see how the data are being presented. Make sure you know how the data are being measured. Is it months or years, hours worked or hundreds of hours worked? Third, examine the label for the vertical axis (y axis). This is the value of the variable being plotted on that axis; make sure you know what it is. Fourth, look at the graph itself to see if it makes logical sense. Are the curves (bars, dots) going in the right direction? Look the graph over and see if you notice something interesting going on. This is really the fun part of looking closely at figures both in this text and in other books, magazines, and newspapers. Often, simple data graphs can reveal surprising relationships between variables. Keep this in mind as you examine graphs throughout this course. One more thing. Graphs in this book are always accompanied by explanatory captions. Examine the graph first, making your preliminary assessment of what is going on. Then carefully read the caption, making sure it accurately reflects what is shown in the graph. If the caption refers to movement between points, follow this movement in the graph. If you think there is a discrepancy between the caption and the graph, reexamine the graph to make sure you
90
have not missed anything.
91
Graphs and Models Let’s now take a brief look at how economists use graphs and models, also looking at how they are constructed. Economists use what are called “stylized graphs” to represent relationships between variables. These graphs are a form of modeling to help us simplify our analysis and focus on those relationships that matter. Figure APX-6 is one such model. FIGURE APX-6STUDYING AND YOUR GPA
This figure shows a hypothetical linear relationship between average study hours and GPA. Without studying, a D average results, and with 10 hours of studying, a C average is obtained, and so on.
92
Linear Relationships Figure APX-6 shows a linear relationship between average study hours and grade point average (GPA), indicating a higher GPA the more you study. By a linear relationship, we mean that the “curve” is a straight line. In this case, if you don’t study at all, we assume you are capable of making D’s and your GPA will equal 1.0, not enough to keep you in school for long. If you hit the books for an average of 10 hours a week, your GPA rises to 2.0, a C average. Studying for additional hours raises your GPA up to its maximum of 4.0. The important point here is that the curve is linear; any hour of studying yields the same increase in GPA. All hours of studying provide equal yields from beginning to end. This is what makes linear relationships unique.
Computing the Slope of a Linear Line
Looking at the line in Figure APX-6, we can see two things: The line is straight, so the slope is constant, and the slope is positive. As average hours of studying increase, GPA increases. Computing the slope of the line tells us how much GPA increases for every hour of additional studying. Computing the slope of a linear line is relatively easy and is shown in Figure APX-7. The simple rule for computing slope is: Slope is equal to rise over run (or rise ÷ run). Since the slope is constant along a linear line, we can select any two points and determine the slope for the entire curve. In Figure APX-7, we have selected points a and b, where GPA moves from 2.0 to 3.0 when studying increases from 10 to 20 hours per week. Your GPA increases by 1.0 for an additional 10 hours of study. This means that the slope is equal to 0.1 (1.0 ÷ 10 = 0.1). So for every additional hour of studying you add each week, your GPA will rise by 0.1. Thus, if you would like to improve your grade point average from 3.0 to 3.5, you would have to study five more hours per week. Computing slope for negative relations that are linear is done exactly the same way, except that when computing the changes from one point to another, one of the values will be negative, making the relationship negative. FIGURE APX-7COMPUTING SLOPE FOR A LINEAR LINE
93
Computing the slope is based on a simple rule: rise over run (rise divided by run). In the case of this straight line, the slope is equal to 0.1 because every 10 additional hours of studying yield a 1.0 increase in GPA.
94
Nonlinear Relationships It would be nice for model builders if all relationships were linear, but that is not the case. It is probably not really the case with the amount of studying and GPA either. Figure APX-8 depicts a more realistic nonlinear and positive relationship between studying and GPA. Again, we assume that one can get a D average (1.0) without studying and reach a maximum of straight A’s (4.0) with 30 hours of studying per week. Figure APX-8 suggests that the first few hours of study per week are more important to raising GPA than are the others. The first 10 hours of studying yield more than the last 10 hours. The first 10 hours of study raise one’s GPA from 1.0 to 3.3 (a gain of 2.3), while the 20th to the 30th hours raise GPA from 3.8 to 4.0 (a gain of only 0.2). This curve exhibits what economists call diminishing returns. Just as the first bite of pizza tastes better than the 100th, so the first 5 hours of studying bring a bigger jump in GPA than the 25th to 30th hours. FIGURE APX-8STUDYING AND YOUR GPA (NONLINEAR)
This nonlinear graph of study hours and GPA is probably more typical than the one shown in Figures APX-6 and APX-7. Like many other things, studying exhibits diminishing returns. The first hours of studying result in greater improvements to GPAs than further hours of studying.
FIGURE APX-9COMPUTING SLOPE FOR A NONLINEAR CURVE
95
Computing the slope of a nonlinear curve requires that you compute the slope of each point on the curve. This is done by computing the slope of a tangent to each point.
Computing the Slope of a Nonlinear Curve As you might suspect, computing the slope of a nonlinear curve is a little more complex than for a linear line. But it is not that much more difficult. In fact, we use essentially the same rise over run approach that is used for linear lines. Looking at the curve in Figure APX-8, it should be clear that the slope varies for each point on the curve. It starts out very steep, then begins to level out above 20 hours of studying. Figure APX-9 shows how to compute the slope at any point on the curve. Computing the slope at point a requires drawing a line tangent to that point, then computing the slope of that line. For point a, the slope of the line tangent to it is found by computing rise over run again. In this case, it is length dc ÷ bc or [(3.8 − 3.3) ÷ (10 − 7)] = 0.5 ÷ 3 = 0.167. Notice that this slope is significantly larger than the original linear relationship of 0.1. If we were to compute the slope near 30 hours of studying, it would approach zero (the slope of a horizontal line is zero).
96
Ceteris Paribus, Simple Equations, and Shifting Curves Hold on while we beat this GPA and studying example into the ground. Inevitably, when we simplify analysis to develop a graph or model, important factors or influences must be controlled. We do not ignore them, we hold them constant. These are known as ceteris paribus assumptions.
Ceteris Paribus: All Else Equal
By ceteris paribus, we mean other things being equal or all other relevant factors, elements, or influences are held constant. When economists define your demand for a product, they want to know how much or how many units you will buy at different prices. For example, to determine how many swimsuits you will buy at various prices (your demand for swimsuits), we hold your income and the price of shoes and shirts constant. If your income suddenly jumped, you would be willing to buy more swimsuits at all prices, but this is a whole new demand curve. Ceteris paribus assumptions are a way to simplify analysis; then the analysis can be extended to include those factors held constant, as we will see next. FIGURE APX-10STUDYING AND YOUR GPA: A SIMPLE EQUATION
The formula for a linear relationship is Y = a + bX, where Y is the y axis variable, X is the x axis variable, and a and b are constants. For the original relationship between study hours and GPA, this equation is GPA = 1.0 + 0.1H.
Simple Linear Equations Simple linear equations can be expressed as: Y = a + bX. This is read as, Y equals a plus b times X, where Y is the variable plotted on the y axis and a is a constant (unchanging), and b is a different constant that is multiplied by X, the value on the x axis. The formula for our studying and GPA example introduced in Figure APX-6 is shown in Figure
97
APX-10. The constant a is known as the vertical intercept because it is the value of GPA when study hours (X) is zero, and therefore it cuts (intercepts) the vertical axis at the value of 1.0 (D average). Now each time you study another hour on average, your GPA rises by 0.1, so the constant b (the slope of the line) is equal to 0.1. Letting H represent hours of studying, the final equation is GPA = 1.0 + 0.1H. You start with a D average without studying, and as your hours of studying increase, your GPA goes up by 0.1 times the hours of studying. If we plug 20 hours of studying into the equation, the answer is a GPA of 3.0 [1.0 + (0.1 × 20) = 1.0 + 2.0 = 3.0].
Shifting Curves Now let’s introduce a couple of factors that we have been holding constant (the ceteris paribus assumption). These two elements are tutoring and partying. So, our new equation now becomes GPA = 1.0 + 0.1H + Z, where Z is our variable indicating whether you have a tutor or whether you are excessively partying. When you have a tutor, Z = 1, and when you party too much, Z = −1. Tutoring adds to the productivity of your studying (hence Z = 1), while excessive late-night partying reduces the effectiveness of studying because you are always tired (hence Z = −1). Figure APX-11 shows the impact of adding these factors to the original relationship. With tutoring, your GPA-studying curve has moved upward and to the left. Now, because Z = 1, you begin with a C average (2.0), and with just 20 hours of studying (because of tutoring), you can reach a 4.0 GPA (point a). Alternatively, when you don’t have tutoring and you party every night, your GPA–studying relationship has worsened (shifted downward and to the right). Now you must study 40 hours (point c) to accomplish a 4.0 GPA. Note that you begin with failing grades. FIGURE APX-11THE IMPACT OF TUTORING AND PARTYING ON YOUR GPA
The effects of tutoring and partying on our simple model of studying and GPA is shown. Partying harms your academic efforts and shifts the relationship to the right, making it harder to maintain your previous average (you now have to study more hours). Tutoring, on the other hand, improves the relationship (shifts the curve to the left).
98
The important point here is that we can simplify relationships between different variables and use a simple graph or equation to represent a model of behavior. In doing so, we often have to hold some things constant. When we allow those factors to change, the original relationship is now changed and often results in a shift in the curves. You will see this technique applied over and over as you study economics this term.
99
Correlation Is Not Causation Just because two variables seem related or appear related on a scatter plot does not mean that one causes another. Economists 100 years ago correlated business cycles (the ups and downs of the entire economy) with sunspots. Because they appeared related, some suggested that sunspots caused business cycles. The only rational argument was that agriculture was the dominant industry and sunspots affected the weather; therefore, sunspots caused the economy to fluctuate. Other examples of erroneously assuming that correlation implies causality abound, some of which can be preposterous or humorous. For example, did Facebook cause the Greek debt crisis? Both the number of Facebook users and the total Greek debt skyrocketed between the years of 2005 and 2015. Just because two variables appear to be related does not mean that one causes the other to change. Understanding graphs and using simple equations are a key part of learning economics. Practice helps.
100
2
Production, Economic Growth, and Trade
101
Understanding how economies grow based on the goods and services they choose 102
to produce
Learning Objectives 2.1
Describe the three basic questions that must be answered by any economy.
2.2
Describe production and the factors that go into producing various goods and services.
2.3
Describe the opportunity cost an economy incurs to increase the production of one product.
2.4
Use a production possibilities frontier (PPF) to analyze the limits of production.
2.5
Describe economic growth and how it is stimulated by education and training, capital accumulation, and technological improvements.
2.6
Describe the concepts of absolute and comparative advantage.
2.7
Explain how specialization and trade can lead to gains for all countries involved.
C
an a speck of sand be the most significant driver of economic growth of the last generation? Just about every piece of electronic and computing equipment contains a microchip, a tiny piece of circuitry that allows devices to function and to store immense amounts of data and multimedia. Most chips are made of silicon, which is
nothing more than a basic element found in sand, and aside from oxygen is the most abundant element in the Earth’s crust.
Extracting silicon from sand, melting it, and creating silicon wafers on which transistors are produced to create a functioning microchip is a complex process. More impressive is how efficient the process has become. A single chip smaller than the size of a dime can hold billions of transistors, enough to store and display all of the music, videos, and photos you could ever want on a single device. Arguably, no invention has transformed the economy more in the past 30 years than the development and advancement of the silicon chip. Technological change has made production methods more efficient, allowing countries to produce more goods and services using fewer physical and natural resources. And as we emphasized in the previous chapter on the importance of scarcity, determining how to achieve more using less—fewer resources—is one of the important goals of economics. An industry that has experienced significant technological change is telecommunications. In 1950 long-distance phone calls were placed with the assistance of live operators, every minute on the line costing the average consumer the equivalent of several hours’ pay. Today, with Internet communications technology allowing one to call virtually anyone in the world for pennies or less, the globe is shrinking as communications brings us closer together and contributes to greater productivity. Another driver of economic growth is trade. Several centuries ago, individuals produced most of what they consumed. Today, most of us produce little of what we consume. Instead, we work at specialized jobs, then use our wages to purchase the goods we need.
103
Nearly every country engages in commercial trade with other countries to expand the opportunities for consumption and production by its people. As products are consumed, new products must be produced, allowing increased consumption in one country to spur economic growth in another. Given the ability of global trade to open economic doors and raise incomes, trade is vital for economic growth in all nations. This chapter gives you a framework for understanding economic growth. It provides a simple model for thinking about production, then applies this model to economies at large so you will know how to think about economic growth and its determinants. It then goes on to analyze international trade as a special case of economic growth. By the time you finish this chapter, you should understand the importance of economic growth and what drives it.
104
105
BASIC ECONOMIC QUESTIONS AND PRODUCTION Regardless of the country, its circumstances, or its precise economic structure, every economy must answer three basic questions.
Basic Economic Questions
The three basic economic questions that each society must answer are: What goods and services are to be produced? How are these goods and services to be produced? Who will receive these goods and services? The response an economy makes to the first question—What goods and services should it produce?—depends on the goods and services a society wants. In a communist state, the government decides what a society wants, but in a capitalist economy, consumers signal what products they want by way of their demands for specific commodities. In the next chapter, we investigate how consumer demand for individual products is determined and how markets meet these demands. For now, we assume that consumers, individually and as a society, are able to decide on the mix of goods and services they most want, and that producers supply these items at acceptable prices. Once we know what goods a society wants, the next question its economic system must answer is, How are these goods and services to be produced? In the end, this problem comes down to the simple question of how land, labor, and capital should be combined to produce the desired products. If a society demands a huge amount of corn, for example, we can expect the use of its resources will be different from a society that demands digital equipment. But even an economy devoted to corn production could be organized in different ways, perhaps relying on extensive use of human labor, or perhaps relying on automated equipment. Once an economy has determined what goods and services to produce and how to produce them, it is faced with the distribution question: Who will get the resulting products? Distribution refers to the way an economy allocates to consumers the goods and services it produces. How this is done depends on how the economy is organized.
Economic Systems
All economies have to answer the three basic economic questions. How that is done depends on who owns the factors of production (land, labor, capital, and entrepreneurship) and how decisions are made to coordinate production and distribution. In capitalist or market economies, private individuals and firms own most of the resources. The what, how, and who decisions are determined by individual desires for products and profit-making decisions by firms. Product prices are the principal mechanism for communicating information in the system. Based on prices, consumers decide whether to buy or not, and firms decide how to employ their resources and what production technology to use. This competition between many buyers and sellers leads to highly efficient production of goods and services. Producers are free to survive or perish based on their efficiency and the quality of their products. The government’s primary roles are protecting property rights, enforcing contracts between private parties, providing public goods such as national defense, and establishing and ensuring the appropriate operating environment for competitive markets. Today, the U.S. economy is not a pure laissez-faire (“leave it alone,” or minimal government role) market economy but more of a mixed economy with many regulations and an extended role for government. In contrast, planned economies (socialist and communist) are systems in which most of the productive resources are owned by the state and most economic decisions are made by central governments. Big sweeping decisions for the economy, often called “five-year plans,” are centrally made and focus productive resources on these priorities. Both the former Soviet Union and China (until quite recently) were highly centrally planned, and virtually all resources were government owned. Although Russia and China have moved toward market economies, a large
106
portion of each country’s resources is still owned by the state. Socialist countries (e.g., the Scandinavian nations of Europe) enjoy a high degree of freedom, but government plays a big role in providing services paid for by high taxes, and in regulating private businesses.
Resources and Production Having examined the three basic economic questions, let’s take a look at the production process. Production involves turning resources into products and services that people want. Let’s begin our discussion of this process by examining the scarce resources used to produce goods and services. production The process of converting resources (factors of production)—land, labor, capital, and entrepreneurial ability—into goods and services. resources Productive resources include land (land and natural resources), labor (mental and physical talents of people), capital (manufactured products used to produce other products), and entrepreneurial ability (the combining of the other factors to produce products and assume the risk of the business).
Land
For economists, the term land includes both land in the usual sense as well as all other natural resources that are used in production. Natural resources such as mineral deposits, oil and natural gas, and water are all included by economists in the definition of land. Economists refer to the payment to land as rent. land Includes natural resources such as mineral deposits, oil, natural gas, water, and land in the usual sense of the word. The payment for land used as a resource is rent.
Labor
Labor as a factor of production includes both the mental and physical talents of people. Few goods and services can be produced without labor resources. Improvement to labor capabilities from training, education, and apprenticeship programs—typically called “human capital”—all add to labor’s productivity and ultimately to a higher standard of living. Labor is paid wages. labor Includes the mental and physical talents of individuals who produce products and services. The payment to labor is wages.
Capital
Capital includes all manufactured products that are used to produce other goods and services. This includes equipment such as drill presses, blast furnaces for making steel, and other tools used in the production process. It also includes trucks and automobiles used by businesses, as well as office equipment such as copiers, computers, and telephones. Any manufactured product that is used to produce other products is included in the category of capital. Capital earns interest. capital Includes manufactured products such as tractors, welding equipment, and computers that are used to produce other goods and services. The payment for capital is interest.
Note that the term “capital” as used by economists refers to real (or physical) capital—actual manufactured products used in the production process—not money or financial capital. Money and financial capital are important in that they are used to purchase the real capital that is used to produce products.
Entrepreneurial Ability
Entrepreneurs combine land, labor, and capital to produce goods and services, and they assume the risks associated with running a business. Entrepreneurs combine and manage the inputs of production, and manage the day-to-day marketing, finance, and production decisions. Today, the risks of running a business are huge, as the many
107
bankruptcies and failures testify. Globalization has opened many opportunities as well as risks. For undertaking these activities and assuming the risks associated with business, entrepreneurs earn profits. entrepreneurs Entrepreneurs combine land, labor, and capital to produce goods and services. They absorb the risk of being in business, including the risk of bankruptcy and other liabilities associated with doing business. Entrepreneurs receive profits for their effort.
Production and Efficiency Production turns resources—land, labor, capital, and entrepreneurial ability—into products and services. The necessary production factors vary for different products. To produce corn, for instance, one needs arable land, seed, fertilizer, water, farm equipment, and the workers to operate that equipment. Farmers looking to produce corn would need to devote hundreds of acres of open land to this crop, plow the land, plant and nurture the corn, and finally harvest the crop. Producing digital equipment, in contrast, requires less land but more capital and more highly skilled labor. As we have seen, every country has to decide what to produce, how to produce it, and who receives the output. Countries desire to do the first two as efficiently as possible by choosing the production method that results in the greatest output using the least amount of resources. Figure 1 shows how factors of production enter into a production method to generate goods and services. Determining the production method is the role of a manager, who must decide how factors of production are best used. Economists refer to this actual choice as the production function, a concept that will be discussed in greater detail in a later chapter. For now, just understand that how resources are used is as important as the amount of resources available.
Ironbridge: The Beginnings of the Industrial Revolution How did the city of Ironbridge solve a logistical problem using factors of production, and how did it lead to enhanced production and economic growth?
W
hat is arguably the most important building material in modern societies? It’s steel, which is made primarily from iron ore. Prior to the Industrial Revolution, the use of iron was mostly limited to producing coins and other small trinkets. The Industrial Revolution began with the mass production of iron, and the town of Ironbridge, England, claims to be one of the birthplaces of the Industrial Revolution. Why Ironbridge?
108
Abraham Darby was an 18th-century British entrepreneur. He developed innovative ways to power machinery using water. In the mid-18th century, Darby built a large aqueduct to harness the natural flow of the river to power his iron furnace. In 1779, when iron began to be produced on a large scale, Darby began building an iron bridge, which was completed in 1781. How was this bridge revolutionary in design? Made of cast iron, the iron bridge was sturdier than any other bridge built before it. A single span allowed large boats to easily pass underneath its high arch. In fact, the original bridge remains open today, setting the standard for constructing bridges and buildings for centuries to come. The iron bridge represents a feat of engineering that led to the development of physical capital as a key factor of production. Today, it’s difficult to imagine production without the use of machines and other modern tools, and the creative ideas that employ these resources to produce goods efficiently. Physical capital and entrepreneurship are two key factors of production that greatly enhance the other factors of production, land and labor. Combining all of the factors of production has allowed economic growth to flourish over the past two centuries, and this can be traced back to a small Victorian town that bears the name of its most famous landmark.
GO TO
FIGURE 1
TO PRACTICE THE ECONOMIC CONCEPTS IN THIS STORY
FROM FACTORS OF PRODUCTION TO OUTPUT
Each of the four factors of production is employed in a production method in order to generate goods and services. The ability to use factors of production efficiently within a production method increases the amount of output given an amount of inputs used.
109
Productivity is a measure of efficiency determined by the amount of output produced given the amount of inputs used. But economists also use specific concepts to describe two different aspects of efficiency: production efficiency and allocative efficiency. Production efficiency occurs when the mix of goods is produced at the lowest possible resource or opportunity cost. Alternatively, production efficiency occurs when as much output as possible is produced with a given amount of resources. Firms use the best technology available and combine the other resources to create products at the lowest cost to society. production efficiency Goods and services are produced at their lowest resource (opportunity) cost.
Allocative efficiency occurs when the mix of goods and services produced is the most desired by society. In capitalist countries, this is determined by consumers and businesses and their interaction through markets. The next chapter explores this interaction in some detail. Needless to say, it would be inefficient (a waste of resources) to be producing cassette tapes in the age of digital music players. Allocative efficiency requires that the right mix of goods be produced at the lowest cost. allocative efficiency The mix of goods and services produced is just what the society desires.
Every economy faces constraints or limitations. Land, labor, capital, and entrepreneurship are all limited. No country has an infinite supply of available workers or the space and machinery that would be needed to put them all to work efficiently. No country can break free of these natural restraints. Such limits are known as production possibilities frontiers, and they are the focus of the next section.
CHECKPOINT BASIC ECONOMIC QUESTIONS AND PRODUCTION Every economy must decide what to produce, how to produce it, and who will get what is produced. Production is the process of converting factors of production (resources)—land, labor, capital, and entrepreneurial ability—into goods and services. To the economist, land includes both land and natural resources. Labor includes the mental and physical resources of humans. Capital includes all manufactured products used to produce other goods and services. Entrepreneurs combine resources to manufacture products, and they assume the risk of doing business. Production efficiency requires that products be produced at the lowest cost. Allocative efficiency occurs when the mix of goods and services produced is just what society wants.
QUESTION:
The one element that really seems to differentiate entrepreneurship from the other resources is the fact that entrepreneurs shoulder the risk of the failure of the enterprise. Is this important? Explain. Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
110
PRODUCTION POSSIBILITIES AND ECONOMIC GROWTH As we discovered in the previous section, all countries and all economies face constraints on their production capabilities. Production can be limited by the quantity of the various factors of production in the country and its current technology. Technology includes such considerations as the country’s infrastructure, its transportation and education systems, and the economic freedom it allows. Although perhaps going beyond the everyday meaning of the word “technology,” for simplicity, we will assume that all of these factors help determine the state of a country’s technology. To further simplify matters, production possibilities analysis assumes that the quantity of resources available and the technology of the economy remain constant, and that the economy produces only two products. Although a twoproduct world sounds far-fetched, this simplification allows us to analyze many important concepts regarding production and tradeoffs. Further, the conclusions drawn from this simple model will not differ fundamentally from a more complex model of the real world.
Production Possibilities
Assume that our simple economy produces backpacks and tablet computers. Figure 2 with its accompanying table shows the production possibilities frontier for this economy. The table shows seven possible production levels (a–g). These seven combinations, which range from 12,000 backpacks and zero tablets to zero backpacks and 6,000 tablets, are graphed in Figure 2. When we connect the seven production possibilities, we delineate the production possibilities frontier (PPF) for this economy (some economists refer to this curve as the production possibilities curve). All points on the PPF are considered attainable by our economy. Everything to the left of the PPF is also attainable, but is an inefficient use of resources—the economy can always do better. Everything to the right of the curve is considered unattainable. Therefore, the PPF maps out the economy’s limits; it is impossible for the economy to produce at levels beyond the PPF without an increase in resources or technology, or both. production possibilities frontier (PPF) Shows the combinations of two goods that are possible for a society to produce at full employment. Points on or inside the PPF are attainable, and those outside of the frontier are unattainable. FIGURE 2
PRODUCTION POSSIBILITIES FRONTIER
111
Using all of its resources, this stylized economy can produce many combinations of backpacks and tablets. Production levels on, or to the left of, the resulting PPF are attainable for this economy. Production levels to the right of the PPF are unattainable.
What the PPF in Figure 2 shows is that, given an efficient use of limited resources and taking technology into account, this economy can produce any of the seven combinations of tablets and backpacks listed, each of which represents a combination where the economy cannot produce another unit without giving up something. If society wants to produce 1,000 tablets, it will only be able to produce 10,000 backpacks, as shown by point b on the PPF. Should the society decide that mobile Internet access is important, it might decide to produce 4,000 tablets, which would force it to cut backpack production to 4,000, shown by point e. At each of these points, resources are fully employed in the economy, and therefore increasing production of one good requires giving up some production of the other. Also, the economy can produce any combination of the two products on or within the PPF, but not any combination beyond it. Contrast points c and e with production at point i. At point i, the economy is only producing 2,000 tablets and 4,000 backpacks. Clearly, some resources are not being used. When fully employed, the economy’s resources could produce more of both goods (point d). Because the PPF represents combinations of goods using resources fully, the economy could not produce 4,000 tablets and still produce 10,000 backpacks. This situation, shown by point h, lies to the right of the PPF and hence outside the realm of possibility. Anything to the right of the PPF is impossible for our economy to attain.
Opportunity Cost
Whenever a country reallocates resources to change production patterns, it does so at a price. This price is called opportunity cost. Recall from Chapter 1 that opportunity cost is what you give up when making an economic decision. Here, society is deciding how many backpacks and tablets to produce. If society decides to produce more tablets, it gives up the ability to produce more backpacks. Shown through the PPF, the opportunity cost of producing more of one good is determined by the amount of the other good that is given up. In moving from point b to point e in Figure 2, tablet production increases by 3,000 units, from 1,000 units to 4,000 units. However, the country must forgo producing 6,000 backpacks because production falls from 10,000 backpacks to 4,000 backpacks. Giving up 6,000 backpacks for 3,000 more tablets represents an opportunity cost of 6,000 backpacks for these 3,000 tablets, or two backpacks for each tablet. opportunity cost The cost paid for one product in terms of the output (or consumption) of another product
112
that must be forgone.
Opportunity cost thus represents the tradeoff required when an economy wants to increase its production of any single product. Governments must choose between infrastructure and national parks, or between military spending and social spending. Since there are limits to what taxpayers are willing to pay, spending choices are necessary. Think of opportunity costs as what you or the economy must give up to have more of a product or service.
Increasing Opportunity Costs
In most cases, land, labor, and capital cannot easily be shifted from producing one good or service to another. You cannot take a semitrailer and use it to plow a field, even though the semi and a top-of-the-line tractor cost about the same. The fact is that some resources are suited to specific sorts of production, just as some people seem to be better suited to performing one activity over another. Some people have a talent for music or art, and they would be miserable—and inefficient—working as accountants or computer programmers. Some people find they are more comfortable working outside, while others require the amenities of an environmentally controlled, ergonomically designed office. Thus, a more realistic production possibilities frontier is shown in Figure 3. This PPF is concave to (or bowed away from) the origin, because opportunity costs rise as more factors are used to produce increasing quantities of one product. Another way of saying this is that resources are subject to diminishing returns as more resources are devoted to the production of one product. Let’s consider why this is so. Let’s begin at a point at which the economy’s resources are strictly devoted to backpack production (point a). Now assume that society decides to produce 3,200 tablets. This will require a move from point a to point b. As we can see, 2,000 backpacks must be given up to obtain the added 3,200 tablets. This means the opportunity cost of 1 tablet is 0.625 backpacks (2,000 ÷ 3,200 = 0.625). This is a low opportunity cost, because those resources that are better suited to producing tablets will be the first ones shifted into this industry. But what happens when this society decides to produce an additional 2,000 tablets, or moves from point b to point c on the graph? As Figure 3 illustrates, each additional tablet costs 2 backpacks because producing 2,000 more tablets requires the society to sacrifice 4,000 backpacks. Thus, the opportunity cost of tablets has more than tripled due to diminishing returns on the tablet side, which arise because added resources are not as well suited to the production of tablets. FIGURE 3
PRODUCTION POSSIBILITIES FRONTIER (INCREASING OPPORTUNITY COSTS)
This figure shows a more realistic production possibilities frontier for an economy. This PPF is bowed out from the origin, since opportunity costs rise as more factors are used to produce increasing quantities of one
113
product or the other.
To describe what has happened in plain terms, when the economy was producing 12,000 backpacks, all its resources went into backpack production. Those members of the labor force who are engineers and electronic assemblers were probably not well suited to producing backpacks. As the economy reduces backpack production to start producing tablets, the opportunity cost of tablets was low, because the resources first shifted, including workers, were likely to be the ones most suited to tablet production and least suited to backpack manufacture. Eventually, however, as tablets became the dominant product, manufacturing more tablets required shifting workers skilled in backpack production to the tablet industry. Employing these less suitable resources drives up the opportunity costs of tablets. You may be wondering which point along the PPF is the best for society. Economists have no grounds for stating unequivocally which mixture of goods and services would be ideal. The perfect mixture of goods depends on the tastes and preferences of the members of society. In a capitalist economy, resource allocation is determined largely by individual choices and the workings of private markets. We consider these markets and their operations in the next chapter.
Economic Growth We have seen that PPFs map out the maximum that an economy can produce: Points to the right of the PPF are unattainable. But what if the PPF can be shifted to the right? This shift would give economies new maximum frontiers. In fact, we will see that economic growth can be viewed as a shift in the PPF outward. In this section, we use the production possibilities model to determine some of the major reasons for economic growth. Understanding these reasons for growth will enable us to suggest some broad economic policies that could lead to expanded growth. The production possibilities model holds resources and technology constant to derive the PPF. These assumptions suggest that economic growth has two basic determinants: expanding resources and improving technologies. The expansion of resources allows producers to increase production of all goods and services in an economy. Specific technological improvements, however, often affect only one industry directly. The development of a new color printing process, for instance, will directly affect only the printing industry. Nevertheless, ripples from technological improvements can spread out through an entire economy, just like ripples in a pond. Specifically, improvements in technology can lead to new products, improved goods and services, and increased productivity. Sometimes technological improvements in one industry allow other industries to increase their production with existing resources. This means producers can increase output without using added labor or other resources. Alternatively, they can get the same production levels as before by using fewer resources than before. This frees up resources in the economy for use in other industries. When the electric lightbulb was invented, it not only created a new industry (someone had to produce lightbulbs), but it also revolutionized other industries. Factories could stay open longer since they no longer had to rely on the sun for light. Workers could see better, thus improving the quality of their work. The result was that resources operated more efficiently throughout the entire economy. “Beaming” objects might not be restricted to Star Trek fantasy with the development of 3D printers capable of reproducing objects. Could this be the next big technological advancement in printing?
114
The modern-day equivalent of the lightbulb might be the smartphone. Widespread use of these mobile devices enables people all across the world to produce goods and services more efficiently. Insurance agents can file claims instantly from disaster sites, deals can be closed while one is stuck in traffic, and communications have been revolutionized. Thus, this new technology has ultimately expanded time, the most finite of our resources. A similar argument could be made for the Internet. It has profoundly changed how many products are bought, sold, and delivered, and has expanded communications and the flow of information. FIGURE 4
ECONOMIC GROWTH BY EXPANDING RESOURCES
115
An increase in population, the number of households, or the size of the labor force shifts the PPF outward. In this figure, a rising supply of labor expands the economy’s production possibilities from PPF0 to PPF1.
Expanding Resources
The PPF represents the possible output of an economy at a specific time. But economies are constantly changing, and so are PPFs. Capital and labor are the principal resources that can be changed through government action. Land and entrepreneurial talent are important factors of production, but neither is easy to change by government policies. The government can make owning a business easier or more profitable by reducing regulations, or by offering lowinterest loans or favorable tax treatment to small businesses. However, it is difficult to turn people into risk takers through government policy. Increasing Labor and Human Capital A clear increase in population, the number of households, or the size of the labor force shifts the PPF outward, as shown in Figure 4. With added labor, the production possibilities available to the economy expand from PPF0 to PPF1. Such a labor increase can be caused by higher birthrates, increased immigration, or an increased willingness of people to enter the labor force. This last type of increase has occurred over the past several decades as more women have entered the labor force on a permanent basis. America’s high level of immigration (both legal and illegal) fuels a strong rate of economic growth. Rather than simply increasing the number of people working, however, the labor factor can also be increased by improving workers’ skills. Economists refer to this as investment in human capital. Education, on-the-job training, and other professional training fit into this category. Improving human capital means people are more productive, resulting in higher wages, a higher standard of living, and an expanded PPF for society. Capital Accumulation Increasing the capital used throughout the economy, usually brought about by investment, similarly shifts the PPF outward, as shown in Figure 4. Additional capital makes each unit of labor more productive and thus results in higher possible production throughout the economy. Adding robotics and computer-controlled
116
machines to production lines, for example, means each unit of labor produces many more units of output. The production possibilities model and the economic growth associated with capital accumulation suggest a tradeoff. Figure 5 illustrates the tradeoff all nations face between current consumption and capital accumulation. Let’s first assume that a nation selects a product mix in which the bulk of goods produced are consumption goods —that is, goods that are immediately consumable and have short life spans, such as food and entertainment. This product mix is represented by point b in Figure 5. Consuming most of what it produces, a decade later the economy is at PPFb. Little growth has occurred, because the economy has done little to improve its productive capacity—the present generation has essentially decided to consume rather than to invest in the economy’s future. FIGURE 5
CONSUMPTION GOODS, CAPITAL GOODS, AND THE EXPANSION OF THE PRODUCTION POSSIBILITIES FRONTIER
If a nation selects a product mix in which the bulk of goods produced are consumption goods, it will initially produce at point b. The small investment made in capital goods has the effect of expanding the nation’s productive capacity only to PPFb over the following decade. If the country decides to produce at point a, however, devoting more resources to producing capital goods, its productive capacity will expand much more rapidly, pushing the PPF out to PPFa over the following decade.
Contrast this decision with one in which the country at first decides to produce at point a. In this case, more capital goods such as machinery and tools are produced, while fewer consumption goods are used to satisfy current needs. Selecting this product mix results in the much larger PPF a decade later (PPFa), because the economy steadily built up its productive capacity during those 10 years.
Technological Change 117
Figure 6 illustrates what happens when an economy experiences a technological change in one of its industries, in this case, the tablet industry. As the figure shows, the economy’s potential output of tablets expands greatly, although its maximum production of backpacks remains unchanged. The area between the two curves represents an improvement in the society’s standard of living. People can produce and consume more of both goods than before: more tablets because of the technological advancement, and more backpacks because some of the resources once devoted to tablet production can be shifted to backpack production, even as the economy is turning out more tablets than before. This example reflects the United States today, where the computer industry is exploding with new technologies. Companies such as Apple and Intel lead the way by relentlessly developing newer, faster, and more powerful products. Consequently, consumers have seen home computers go from clunky conversation pieces to powerful, fast, indispensable machines. Today’s computers are more powerful than the mainframe supercomputers of just a few decades ago. And the latest developments in smartphones allow them to do much more than what powerful computers did a decade ago. Besides new products, technology has dramatically reduced the cost of producing tablets and other high-tech items, allowing countries to produce and consume more of other products, expanding the entire PPF outward. However, the effect of technology on an economy also depends on how well its important trade centers are linked together. If a country has mostly dirt paths rather than paved highways, you can imagine how this deficiency would affect its economy: Distribution will be slow, and industries will be slow to react to changes in demand. In such a case, improving the roads might be the best way to stimulate economic growth. As you can see, there are many ways to stimulate economic growth. A society can expand its output by using more resources, perhaps by encouraging more people to enter the workforce or raising educational levels of workers. The government can encourage people to invest more, as opposed to devoting their earnings to immediate consumption. The public sector can spur technological advances by providing incentives to private firms to do research and development or underwrite research investments of its own. FIGURE 6
TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE AND EXPANSION OF THE PRODUCTION POSSIBILITIES FRONTIER
118
In this figure, an economy’s potential output of tablets has expanded greatly, while its maximum production of backpacks has remained unchanged. The area between the two curves represents an improvement in the society’s standard of living, since more of both goods can be produced and consumed than before. Some of the resources once used for tablet production can be diverted to backpack production, even as the number of tablets produced increases.
Summarizing the Sources of Economic Growth
Economic growth is driven by many factors, as we have seen. A study by the Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD)1 focused on what has been driving economic growth in twenty-one nations over the last several decades. The study first looked at contributions to economic growth from the macroeconomic perspective of added resources and technological improvements as we have been discussing in this chapter. It then looked at some benefits from good government policies that stimulate growth, and finally examined the industry and individual firm level for clues to the microeconomic sources of growth. The study showed that some of the policies that have led to growth and subsequently higher standards of living in these countries include: Increasing business investment (physical capital). Increasing average education levels (human capital). Increasing research and development. Reducing both the level and variability of inflation. Reducing the tax burden. Increasing the level of international trade.
119
ISSUE Is the Ocean the Next Frontier? Land Reclamation and Underwater Cities Can a city exist underneath the ocean surface? A team of engineers in Japan say that such cities can become a reality by 2030. They created a proposal for an underwater city that is powered by a process called ocean thermal energy conversion, in which power is generated from the differences in seawater temperatures at different depths. Can a self-sustained underwater city be a reality? If so, it could generate a vast amount of new territory around the world, since the majority of the Earth is covered by oceans that could become the next frontier. In fact, using the vast expanse of the ocean has already become a reality in some countries. Japan, Hong Kong, Singapore, and the United Arab Emirates have built islands off of their coastlines using a process called land reclamation, in which sand is moved from other parts of the ocean to create new land above the ocean’s surface. More recently, China made headlines by building islands far from its coastline, which brings into question the role of property rights. One of the concerns with underwater cities or land reclamation is who actually owns the right to live in the ocean. Because international waters begin 12 nautical miles beyond a country’s coastline, some have questioned whether creating underwater cities or new islands in the ocean is merely a way for a country to acquire new territory, and subsequently the resources deriving from that territory, such as fish, natural resources, or a strategic geographic location for military purposes.
One important point to take away from this discussion is that our simple stylized model of the economy using only two goods gives a good first framework upon which to judge proposed policies for the economy. While not overly complex, this simple analysis is still quite powerful.
CHECKPOINT PRODUCTION POSSIBILITIES AND ECONOMIC GROWTH A production possibilities frontier (PPF) depicts the different combinations of goods that a fully
120
employed economy can produce, given its available resources and current technology (both assumed fixed in the short run). Production levels inside and on the frontier are possible, but those outside the curve are unattainable. Because production on the frontier represents the maximum output attainable when all resources are fully employed, reallocating production from one product to another involves opportunity costs: The output of one product must be reduced to get the added output of the other. The more of one product that is desired, the higher its opportunity cost because of diminishing returns and the unsuitability of some resources for producing some products. The PPF model suggests that economic growth can arise from an expansion in resources or improvements in technology. Economic growth is an outward shift of the PPF.
QUESTION: Taiwan is a small mountainous island with 23 million inhabitants, little arable land, and few
natural resources, while Nigeria is a much larger country with 7 times the population, 40 times more arable land, and tremendous deposits of oil. Given Nigeria’s sizable resource advantage, why is Nigeria’s total annual production less than that of Taiwan’s? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
121
SPECIALIZATION, COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE, AND TRADE As we have seen, economics is all about voluntary production and exchange. People and nations do business with one another because all expect to gain from the transactions. Centuries ago, European merchants ventured to the Far East to ply the lucrative spice trade. These days, American consumers buy wines from Italy, cars from Japan, electronics from Korea, and millions of other products from countries around the world. Many people assume that trade between nations is a zero-sum game—a game in which, for one party to gain, another party must lose. This is how poker works. If one player walks away from the table a winner, someone else must have lost. But this is not how voluntary trade works. Voluntary trade is a positive-sum game: Both parties to a transaction score positive gains. After all, who would voluntarily enter into an exchange if he or she did not believe there was some gain from it? To understand how all parties to an exchange (whether individuals or nations) can gain from it, we need to consider the concept of comparative advantage developed by David Ricardo roughly 200 years ago, and how this concept differs from the concept of absolute advantage.
DAVID RICARDO (1772–1823)
D
avid Ricardo’s rigorous, dispassionate evaluation of economic principles influenced generations of theorists, including such vastly different thinkers as John Stuart Mill and Karl Marx. Ricardo was born in London as the third of 17 children. At age 14, he joined his father’s trading business on the London Stock Exchange. At 21, he started his own brokerage and within five years had amassed a small fortune. While vacationing in Bath, England, he chanced upon a copy of Adam Smith’s The Wealth of Nations, and decided to devote his energies to studying economics and writing. He once wrote to his lifelong friend Thomas Malthus (another prominent economist of the time) that he was “thankful for the miserable English climate because it kept him at his desk writing.” Ricardo and Malthus corresponded on a regular basis, and their exchanges led to the development of many economic concepts still used today. Later, as a member of the British Parliament, Ricardo was an out-spoken critic of the 1815 Corn Laws, which placed high tariffs on imported grain to protect British landowners. Ricardo was a strong advocate of free trade, and his writings reflected this view. His theory of “comparative advantage” suggested that countries would mutually benefit from trade by specializing in export goods they could produce at a lower opportunity cost than another country. His classic example was trade in cloth and wine between Britain and Portugal. Ricardo died in 1823 of an ear infection, leaving an enduring legacy of classical (pre-1930s) economic analysis. Information from E. Ray Canterbery, A Brief History of Economics (New Jersey: World Scientific), 2001; Howard Marshall, The Great Economists: A History of Economic Thought (New York: Pitman Publishing), 1967; Steven Pressman, Fifty Major Economists, 2nd ed. (New York: Routledge), 2006.
Absolute and Comparative Advantage Figure 7 shows hypothetical production possibilities frontiers for the United States and Mexico. To simplify the
122
analysis, we assume that opportunity costs are constant (PPFs are straight lines); however, the same analysis applies to PPFs with increasing opportunity costs. Both countries are assumed to produce only crude oil and silicon chips. Given the PPFs in Figure 7, the United States has an absolute advantage over Mexico in producing both products. An absolute advantage exists when one country can produce more of a good than another country. In this instance, the United States can produce 2 times more oil (40 million versus 20 million barrels) and 5 times as many silicon chips (40 million versus 8 million chips) as Mexico. absolute advantage One country can produce more of a good than another country.
At first glance, you might wonder why the United States would even consider trading with Mexico. The United States has so much more production capacity than Mexico, so why wouldn’t it just produce all of its own crude oil and silicon chips? The answer lies in comparative advantage. One country has a comparative advantage in producing a good if its opportunity cost to produce that good is lower than the other country’s. We can calculate each country’s opportunity cost for each good using the production possibility frontiers in Figure 7. comparative advantage One country has a lower opportunity cost of producing a good than another country.
If the United States uses all of its resources efficiently, it can produce a maximum of 40 million barrels of oil or 40 million silicon chips. It can also produce some of both goods, though clearly not 40 million of each, because in order to produce more of one good, it must reduce production of another (its opportunity cost). Because the PPF is linear, the tradeoff between oil and chips is constant. For the United States, it can substitute 1 million barrels of oil for 1 million silicon chips, which means it can produce 20 million barrels of oil and 20 million silicon chips. The opportunity cost for each good is summarized as follows: For every barrel of oil the United States produces, it must give up producing one silicon chip. For every silicon chip the United States produces, it must give up producing one barrel of oil. Now let’s look at Mexico. If it uses its resources efficiently, it can produce a maximum of 20 million barrels of oil or 8 million silicon chips. For Mexico, although the tradeoff between goods also is constant, the tradeoff is not one-for-one as in the United States. Because Mexico is better at producing oil than silicon chips, its opportunity cost for each good is as follows: For every barrel of oil Mexico produces, it must give up producing 0.4 silicon chips. For every silicon chip Mexico produces, it must give up producing 2.5 barrels of oil. FIGURE 7
PRODUCTION POSSIBILITIES FOR THE UNITED STATES AND MEXICO
123
One country has an absolute advantage if it can produce more of a good than another country. In this case, the United States has an absolute advantage over Mexico in producing both silicon chips and crude oil—it can produce more of both goods than Mexico can. Even so, Mexico has a comparative advantage over the United States in producing oil, since it can increase its output of oil at a lower opportunity cost than can the United States. This comparative advantage leads to gains for both countries from specialization and trade.
Note that the values of 0.4 and 2.5 are reciprocals of one another. In other words, 1/0.4 = 2.5, and 1/2.5 = 0.4. This relationship exists when calculating opportunity costs in a two-product economy. Now that we have determined the opportunity cost of each good in both countries, we can conclude that Mexico has a comparative advantage over the United States in producing oil. This is because Mexico gives up only 0.4 chips for every barrel of oil it produces, while the United States must give up 1 chip. Thus, Mexico’s opportunity cost of producing oil is less than that of the United States, giving Mexico a comparative advantage. Conversely, the United States has a comparative advantage over Mexico in producing silicon chips: Producing a silicon chip in the United States costs one barrel of oil, whereas the same chip in Mexico costs two-and-a-half barrels of oil. Table 1 summarizes the opportunity costs of each good and which country has the comparative advantage.
TABLE 1
COMPARING OPPORTUNITY COSTS FOR OIL AND CHIP PRODUCTION United States Opportunity Cost
Mexico Opportunity Cost
Comparative Advantage
Oil Production
1 chip
0.4 chips
Mexico
Chip Production
1 barrel of oil
2.5 barrels of oil
United States
Note that each country has a comparative advantage in one good, even though the United States has an absolute advantage in both goods. However, it is comparative advantage that generates gains from trade. These relative costs suggest that the United States should pour its resources into producing silicon chips, while Mexico specializes in crude oil. The two countries can then engage in trade to their mutual benefit. As long as opportunity costs differ between countries, specialization and trade can be mutually beneficial, allowing all countries to consume more. The same idea applies to individuals. Although we have focused on trade between countries, the concept of comparative advantage explains why individuals specialize in a few tasks and then trade with one another. For
124
example, if you are relatively better at understanding economics than your roommate who is on the golf team, you might offer to tutor him in economics in exchange for golf lessons. Comparative advantage explains all trade: between individuals as well as between countries.
The Gains From Trade To see how specialization and trade can benefit all trading partners, let’s return to our example in which the United States has the ability to produce more of both goods than Mexico. Assume that each country is at first (before trade) operating at point a in Figure 7. At this point, both countries are producing and consuming only their own output; the United States produces and consumes 20 million barrels of oil and 20 million silicon chips; Mexico, 10 million barrels of oil and 4 million chips. Table 2 summarizes these initial conditions. Now assume that Mexico focuses on oil, producing the maximum it can: 20 million barrels. We also assume both countries want to continue consuming 30 million barrels of oil between them. Therefore, the United States only needs to produce 10 million barrels of oil because Mexico is now producing 20 million barrels. For the United States, this frees up some resources that can be diverted to producing silicon chips. Because each barrel of oil in the United States costs one chip, reducing oil output by 10 million barrels means that 10 million more chips can be produced. Table 3 shows each country’s production after Mexico has begun specializing in oil production. Notice that the combined production of crude oil has remained constant, but the total output of silicon chips has risen by 6 million chips. Assuming that the two countries agree to share the added 6 million chips between them equally, Mexico will now ship 10 million barrels of oil to the United States in exchange for 7 million chips. From the 10 million additional chips the United States produces, Mexico will receive 4 million (its original production) plus 3 million for a total of 7 million, leaving 3 million additional chips for U.S. consumption. The resulting mix of products consumed in each country is shown in Table 4. Clearly, both countries are better off, having engaged in specialized production and trade.
TABLE 2
INITIAL CONSUMPTION-PRODUCTION PATTERN United States
Mexico
Total
Oil
20
10
30
Chips
20
4
24
TABLE 3
PRODUCTION AFTER MEXICO SPECIALIZES IN PRODUCING CRUDE OIL United States
Mexico
Total
Oil
10
20
30
Chips
30
0
30
TABLE 4
FINAL CONSUMPTION PATTERNS AFTER TRADE United States
Mexico
Total
Oil
20
10
30
Chips
23
7
30
125
The important point to remember here is that even when one country has an absolute advantage over another, both countries still benefit from trading with one another. In our example, the gains were small, but such gains can grow. As two economies become more equal in size, the benefits of their comparative advantages grow.
Practical Constraints on Trade Before leaving the subject of international trade and how it contributes to growth in both countries, we should take a moment to note some practical constraints on trade. First, every transaction involves costs, including transportation, communications, and the general costs of doing business. Even so, over the last several decades, transportation and communication costs have been declining all over the world, resulting in growing global trade. Second, the production possibilities curves for nations are not linear, but rather governed by increasing costs and diminishing returns. Therefore, it is difficult for countries to specialize in producing one product. Complete specialization would be risky, moreover, because the market for a product can always decline, perhaps because the product becomes technologically obsolete. Alternatively, changing weather patterns can wreak havoc on specialized agricultural products, adding further instability to incomes and exports in developing countries. Finally, although two countries may benefit from trading with one another, expanding this trade may well hurt some industries and individuals within each country. Notably, industries finding themselves at a comparative disadvantage may be forced to scale back production and lay off workers. In such instances, government may need to provide workers with retraining, relocation, and other help to ensure a smooth transition to the new production mix. When the United States signed the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) with Canada and Mexico, many people experienced what we have just been discussing. Some U.S. jobs went south to Mexico because of low production costs. By opening up more markets for U.S. products, however, NAFTA did stimulate economic growth, such that retrained workers ended up with new and better jobs.
ISSUE Do We Really Specialize in That? Comparative Advantage in the United States and China What do tofu, edamame, ink, soy sauce, livestock feed, and soy milk have in common? They are all important products commonly made from soybeans. Although direct human consumption of soybeans in the United States is often confined to health food products and food in Asian restaurants, soybeans are much more important to the U.S. economy than most people think. The United States has a comparative advantage in soybean production. It produces and sells more soybeans than any other country, with much of it being sold to China. How can a rich, technologically advanced country like the United States end up with a comparative advantage in an agricultural good like soybeans? Several factors play a role. First, the United States has an abundance of farmland ideal in climate and soil for soybean production. Second, modern fertilizers and seed technologies have made soybean production a much more innovative industry than in the past, allowing farms to increase soybean yields per acre of land. And third, a strong appetite for soy-based products, particularly in China, has made soybeans a very lucrative industry. China is the second largest trading partner to the United States after Canada, trading $610 billion worth of goods between the countries in 2014. Yet, the top five U.S. export goods (items sold) and import goods (items bought) with China, listed below, may be surprising. Top Five Exports to China (2014) 1. Soybeans ($15.3 billion) 2. Aircraft ($13.9 billion) 3. Automobiles ($13.2 billion) 4. Machinery ($12.5 billion)
Top Five Imports from China (2014) 1. Electrical goods ($129.8 billion) 2. Machinery ($108.1 billion) 3. Furniture ($28.0 billion) 4. Toys/sporting goods ($23.7 billion)
126
5. Electrical goods ($12.0 billion)
5. Footwear ($17.8 billion)
Although the United States sells a lot of machines and electrical goods to China (mostly specialized machinery and electronics used in factories and research labs), it buys significantly greater amounts of these products from China. In other words, the United States is a net buyer of machinery and electrical goods, industries that include many consumer technology goods we use, such as smartphones, computers, and digital equipment. Besides soybeans, wood pulp, copper, and wood are three other resource industries (not listed here but in the top 10) that constitute a large portion of U.S. sales to China. In sum, specialization and trade are not as simple as they used to be. Products such as computers and electronics that once were the purview of “rich” countries like the United States are now being manufactured in China and other countries, while improved technology in the agricultural and natural resource industries has given the United States a form of specialization that would have been unheard of 50 years ago.
CHECKPOINT SPECIALIZATION, COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE, AND TRADE An absolute advantage exists when one country can produce more of some good than another. A comparative advantage exists if one country has lower opportunity costs of producing a good than another country. Both countries gain from trade if each focuses on producing those goods with which it has a comparative advantage. Voluntary trade is a positive-sum game, because both countries benefit from it.
QUESTION: Why do Hollywood stars (and many other rich individuals)—unlike most people—have fulltime personal assistants who manage their personal affairs? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
127
chapter summary Section 1 Basic Economic Questions and Production 2.1
Every economy must decide: 1. What to produce. 2. How to produce it. 3. Who will get the goods produced.
Using scarce resources productively leads to: Production efficiency: Goods and services are produced at their lowest possible resource cost. Allocative efficiency: Goods are produced according to what society desires.
2.2
Factors of Production (Inputs)
128
Section 2 Production Possibilities and Economic Growth 2.3
The production possibilities frontier (PPF) shows the different combinations of goods that a fully employed economy can produce, given its available resources and current technology.
2.4
Production possibilities frontiers (PPFs) illustrate tradeoffs—if an economy operates at full employment (on the PPF), producing more of one good requires producing less of the other. A concave PPF shows how opportunity costs rise due to diminishing returns.
129
Some pizza makers were never meant to produce computers and some computer workers were never meant to produce pizza, which increases the opportunity cost of production as more of one good is produced.
The production possibilities model shows how economic growth can arise from an expansion in resources or from improvements in technology, or both.
2.5
Changes in the PPF: From PPFA to PPFB: An increase in productivity in the production of one good (e.g., an increase in the number of students studying computer engineering). From PPFA to PPFC: An increase in productive capacity of both goods (e.g., an increase in overall technology, or an increase in labor or capital resources).
130
Section 3 Specialization, Comparative Advantage, and Trade 2.6
An absolute advantage exists when one country can produce more of some good than another. A comparative advantage exists when one country can produce a good at a lower opportunity cost than another.
Gains from trade result when a country specializes in the production of goods in which it has a comparative advantage, and trades these goods with another country. Trade is a positive-sum game. Both countries can benefit even if one country has an absolute advantage in both goods. Calculating Opportunity Costs Using Production Numbers (units produced per day per worker) Australia New Zealand Boomerangs
20
8
Kiwi
12
16
Opportunity cost of 1 boomerang: Australia: 12 kiwi/20 boomerangs = 0.6 kiwi per boomerang. New Zealand: 16 kiwi/8 boomerangs = 2 kiwi per boomerang. Australia has a lower opportunity cost of producing boomerangs. Opportunity cost of 1 kiwi: Australia: 20 boomerangs/12 kiwi = 1.7 boomerangs per kiwi. New Zealand: 8 boomerangs/16 kiwi = 0.5 boomerangs per kiwi. New Zealand has a lower opportunity cost of producing kiwi.
131
2.7
Countries export goods for which they have a comparative advantage, and import goods for which they do not, leading to gains from trade to both countries.
KEY CONCEPTS production resources land labor capital entrepreneurs production efficiency allocative efficiency production possibilities frontier (PPF) opportunity cost absolute advantage comparative advantage
QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS Check Your Understanding 1. When can an economy increase the production of one good without reducing the output of another? 2. In which of the three basic questions facing any society does technology play the greatest role? 3. Explain the important difference between a straight-line PPF and the PPF that is concave to (bowed away from) the origin. 4. How would unemployment be shown on the PPF? 5. List three factors that can contribute to an economy’s growth. 6. How can a country that does not have an absolute advantage in producing goods still benefit from trade?
Apply the Concepts 7. China’s tremendous growth rate over the past two decades has allowed its economic output to nearly catch up to that of the United States. If China continued to grow much faster than the United States, would this eventually lead to the elimination of scarcity in China? 8. Describe how a country producing more capital goods than consumption goods ends up in the future with a
132
9. 10. 11. 12.
PPF that is larger than that of a country that produces more consumption goods and fewer capital goods. The United States has an absolute advantage in making many goods, such as short-sleeved cotton golf shirts. Why do Indonesia and Bangladesh make these shirts and export them to the United States? Why is it that the United States uses heavy street-cleaning machines driven by one person to clean the streets, while China and India use many people with brooms to do the same job? If specialization and trade as discussed in this chapter lead to a win-win situation in which both countries gain, why is there often opposition to trade agreements and globalization? The issue of climate change has risen to the forefront of economic discussion, especially among industrialized countries such as the United States and those in Europe. Critics, however, argue that greater environmental regulations restrict economic growth. Explain how relatively wealthy countries might react differently to this tradeoff compared to poor countries.
In the News 13. According to an April 4, 2015, New York Times report, California experienced the most severe drought in over a millennium from 2011 to 2015, when reservoirs and underground aquifers that farmers, households, and businesses depend on dried up. As a result, California’s governor ordered a major cut in water usage statewide that made it harder to live and work in the Golden State. If the drought forces some households and businesses to move out of California, what might happen to California’s ability to achieve economic growth? Illustrate your answer using a PPF. 14. At the 2015 White House Science Fair, a $240 million private-public initiative was announced for the purpose of boosting STEM (science, technology, engineering, and math) education, as the United States continues to fall behind other industrialized nations in student achievement in these fields. How would spending on STEM initiatives today, which leads to higher costs in the near term, pay off in future benefits to the economy?
Solving Problems
WORK IT OUT 15. Iceland and Denmark both produce skis and sleds. Iceland can produce 3 skis or 6 sleds using one day of labor, while Denmark can produce 4 skis or 12 sleds using one day of labor. Which country has an absolute advantage in producing skis? Sleds? Which country has a comparative advantage in producing skis? Sleds? Are gains from trade possible between Iceland and Denmark? If yes, which good should each country specialize in producing?
16. The table below shows the potential output combinations of oranges and jars of prickly pear jelly (from the flower of the prickly pear cactus) for Florida and Arizona. a. Compute the opportunity cost of oranges in Florida in terms of jars of prickly pear jelly. Do the same for prickly pear jelly in terms of oranges. b. Compute the opportunity cost of oranges in Arizona in terms of jars of prickly pear jelly. Do the same for prickly pear jelly in terms of oranges. c. Would it make sense for Florida to specialize in producing oranges and for Arizona to specialize in producing prickly pear jelly and then trade? Why or why not?
Florida Oranges
Arizona
Prickly Pear Jelly
Oranges
133
Prickly Pear Jelly
0
10
0
500
50
8
20
400
100
6
40
300
150
4
60
200
200
2
80
100
250
0
100
0
USING THE NUMBERS 17. According to By the Numbers, in which period (1965–1990 or 1990–2015) did corn and soybean production increase more in terms of yield per acre? 18. According to By the Numbers, during the period between 1997 and 2015, in how many years did the U.S. trade balance improve from the previous year and in how many years did the trade balance deteriorate? (Assume the trade balance deteriorated from 1996 [not shown in the figure] to 1997.)
ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS Checkpoint: Basic Economic Questions and Production Typically, entrepreneurs put not only their time and effort into a business but also their money, often pledging private assets as collateral for loans. Should the business fail, they stand to lose more than their jobs, rent from the land, or interest on capital loaned to the firm. Workers can get other jobs, landowners can rent to others, and capital can be used in other enterprises. The entrepreneur must suffer the loss of personal assets and move on. Checkpoint: Production Possibilities and Economic Growth Although Nigeria has significantly more natural resources and labor (two important factors of production) than Taiwan, these resources alone do not guarantee a higher ability to produce goods and services. Factors of production also include physical capital (machinery), human capital (education), and technology (research and development), all of which Taiwan has in great abundance. Thus, despite the lack of land, labor, and natural resources, Taiwan is able to use its resources efficiently and expand its production possibilities well beyond those of Nigeria. Checkpoint: Specialization, Comparative Advantage, and Trade For Hollywood stars and other rich people, the opportunity cost of their time is high. As a result, they hire people at lower cost to do the mundane chores that each of us is accustomed to doing because our time is relatively less valuable. 1
The Sources of Economic Growth in the OECD Countries (Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development), 2003.
134
3
Supply and Demand
135
Using the basic tools of supply and demand to determine how prices and quantities 136
are set in a market economy
Learning Objectives 3.1
Describe the characteristics and purposes of markets.
3.2
Describe the nature of demand, demand curves, and the law of demand.
3.3
Describe the determinants of demand and be able to forecast how a change in one or more of these determinants will change demand.
3.4
Explain the difference between a change in demand and a change in quantity demanded.
3.5
Describe the nature of supply, supply curves, and the law of supply.
3.6
Describe the determinants of supply and be able to forecast how a change in one or more of these determinants will change supply.
3.7
Determine market equilibrium price and output.
3.8
Determine and predict how price and output will change given changes to supply and demand in the market.
W
hat $100+ billion global industry sells a product that many people typically can obtain easily from another source free of charge? The bottled water industry! This industry began its meteoric rise in the early 1990s, and today, the ubiquitous bottle of water has changed the way we live. It also has created
new concerns regarding the environmental impact of the billions of plastic bottles used and discarded.
The bottled water industry took off as consumers changed their hydration habits, spurred by greater awareness of the health benefits of drinking water, including weight loss, illness prevention, and overall health maintenance. As water consumption increased, people started wanting something more than just ordinary water from the tap. They desired water that was purer, more consistent in taste, or infused with flavor or minerals. Plus, consumers wanted water that was easy to carry. Bottled water was the product consumers wanted, and the market was willing to provide it. Bottled water comes from many sources, both domestic and foreign, and consists of either spring water (from natural springs underneath the Earth’s surface) or purified water (ordinary tap water that undergoes a complex purification process). As the industry grew, new varieties of water were made available. Water from exotic faraway springs, vitamin-infused water, flavored water, and carbonated water were some of the choices consumers were given. The total amount of water produced for the bottled water industry continued to increase as long as there were customers willing to pay for it in the market. In the late 2000s, falling incomes from a deteriorating global economy, concerns about the harmful effects of discarded plastic bottles on the environment, increased use of home water purification devices, and even some laws
137
against the use of bottled water eventually halted the market’s growth. The economy has since improved, and the bottled water industry responded to the environmental concerns by using bottles made from recycled plastic or by using new technologies to reduce the plastic content in water bottles, again responding to the desires of consumers. As a result, sales increased again. Consumers have many choices of what water to buy and where to buy it. Even so, the bottled water market is one in which prices vary considerably depending on the location of purchase. A single bottle of water of the same brand might cost $0.69 at a grocery store, $0.99 at a convenience store, $1.25 from a vending machine, $1.49 at a local coffee shop, and $3.00 or more at a theme park, sports stadium, or movie theater. How can the same product be sold in different places at so many different prices? This chapter analyzes the various factors influencing how consumers value goods in different settings and circumstances. We also study how producers take costs and incentives into account in determining what products to produce, how much to produce, and what prices to charge. The interaction between consumers and producers within a market determines the prices we pay. In any given market, prices are determined by “what the market will bear.” Which factors determine what the market will bear, and what happens when events that occur in the marketplace cause prices to change? For answers to these questions, economists turn to supply and demand analysis. The basic model of supply and demand presented in this chapter will let you determine why product sales rise and fall, in what direction prices move, and how many goods will be offered for sale when certain events happen in the marketplace. Later chapters use this same model to explain complex phenomena such as how wages are set and how personal income is distributed.
138
This chapter introduces some of the basic economic concepts you need to know to understand how the forces of
139
supply and demand work. These concepts include markets, the law of demand, demand curves, the determinants of demand, the law of supply, supply curves, the determinants of supply, and market equilibrium.
140
MARKETS A market is an institution that enables buyers and sellers to interact and transact with one another. A lemonade stand is a market because it allows people to exchange money for a product, in this case, lemonade. Ticket scalping, which remains illegal or highly restricted in some states, similarly represents market activity, since it leads to the exchange of money for tickets, whether it takes place in person outside the stadium or online. markets Institutions that bring buyers and sellers together, so they can interact and transact with each other.
ISSUE Do Markets Exist for Everyone, Including Dogs and Cats? Over 78 million dogs and 86 million cats call the United States home, with many times more finding homes around the world. Over four in ten U.S. households include at least one pet, which is often treated as a beloved member of the family. The expenses associated with pet ownership often extend beyond the basic necessities of food and vet checkups.
Total spending on pet-related products in the United States has increased every year since 2001, surpassing $60 billion in 2015. Even during the depths of the economic downturn of 2007 to 2009, spending on pets continued to increase. The seeming immunity of the pet goods market to economic hardships raises an interesting question of to whom the market is geared: the pets or their sometimes fanatical owners? Manufacturers of pet goods have increased the types of “consumer” goods and services for pets. These include a greater selection of pet foods and toys, but increasingly sellers are being more creative in their offerings. For example, the number of pet spas, pet hotels, and even pet airlines, allowing pets to bathe in luxury as they or their owners travel, has boomed over the past decade. Pet consumerism has even gone high-tech. Since the introduction of tablets, programmers have introduced new tablet apps designed for cats, including games that are played feline versus human. Such apps highlight the ability of businesses to turn pets into consumers, whose desires (even if imagined by their owners) turn into actual purchases. The power of consumer decisions extending beyond the wants of humans demonstrates the broad reach of markets. Because humans share a deep connection with their furry loved ones, they will often incorporate their pets’ desires into real consumption choices. And based on the growth of
141
this market, it’s likely that dogs and cats will continue to be avid consumers.
The Internet, without a physical location, has dramatically expanded the notion of markets. Online market sites such as eBay permit firms and individuals to sell a large number of low-volume products, ranging from rare collectible items to an extra box of unused diapers, and still make money. This includes students who resell their textbooks on Amazon.com and Half.com. The Internet also has launched markets for virtual goods. For example, buying virtual tools, cash, and animals in online games has become an important part of social media sites. Even though all markets have the same basic component—the transaction—they can differ in a number of ways. Some markets are quite limited because of their geographical location, or because they offer only a few different products for sale. The New York Stock Exchange serves as a market for just a single type of financial instrument, stocks, but it facilitates exchanges worth billions of dollars daily. Compare this to the neighborhood flea market, which is much smaller and may operate only on weekends, but offers everything from food and crafts to T-shirts and electronics. Cement manufacturers are typically restricted to local markets due to high transportation costs, whereas Internet firms can easily do business with customers around the world.
The Price System When buyers and sellers exchange money for goods and services, accepting some offers and rejecting others, they are also doing something else: They are communicating their individual desires. Much of this communication is accomplished through the prices of items. If buyers value a particular item sufficiently, they will quickly pay its asking price. If they do not buy it, they are indicating they do not believe the item to be worth its asking price. Prices also give buyers an easy means of comparing goods that can substitute for each other. If the price of margarine falls to half the price of butter, this will suggest to many consumers that margarine is a better deal. Similarly, sellers can determine what goods to sell by comparing their prices. When prices rise for tennis rackets, this tells sporting goods store operators that the public wants more tennis rackets, leading the store operators to order more. Prices, therefore, contain a considerable amount of useful information for both consumers and sellers. For this reason, economists often call our market economy the price system. price system A name given to the market economy because prices provide considerable information to both buyers and sellers.
CHECKPOINT MARKETS Markets are institutions that enable buyers and sellers to interact and transact business. Markets differ in geographical location, products offered, and size. Prices contain a wealth of information for both buyers and sellers. Through their purchases, consumers signal their willingness to exchange money for particular products at particular prices. These signals help businesses decide what to produce, and how much of it to produce. The market economy is also called the price system.
QUESTION: What are the important differences between the markets for financial securities such as the
New York Stock Exchange and your local farmer’s market?
Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
142
DEMAND Whenever you purchase a product, you are voting with your money. You are selecting one product out of many and supporting one firm out of many, both of which signal to the business community what sorts of products satisfy your wants as a consumer. Economists typically focus on wants rather than needs because it is so difficult to determine what we truly need. Theoretically, you could survive on tofu and vitamin pills, living in a lean-to made of cardboard and buying all your clothes from thrift stores. Most people in our society, however, choose not to live in such austere fashion. Rather, they want something more, and in most cases they are willing and able to pay for more.
Willingness-to-Pay: The Building Block of Market Demand
Imagine sitting in your economics class around mealtime. In your rush to class, you did not have a chance to make a sandwich at home or to stop at the cafeteria on your way to class. You think about foods that sound appealing to you (just about anything at this point), and plan to go to the cafeteria immediately after class and buy a sandwich. Given your growling stomach, you think more about what you want on your sandwich and less about how much the sandwich will cost. In your mind, your willingness-to-pay (WTP) for that sandwich can be quite high, say, $10 or even more. willingness-to-pay An individual’s valuation of a good or service, equal to the most an individual is willing and able to pay. FIGURE 1
FROM INDIVIDUAL WILLINGNESS-TO-PAY TO MARKET DEMAND
143
In panel A, you would be willing to pay up to $10 for your first sandwich and $4 for the second. Jane, however, is only willing to pay up to $6 for her first sandwich and $2 for a second (panel B). Placing the WTP for sandwiches by you and Jane in order from the highest to lowest value, we generate a market with two consumers shown in panel C. As more and more individuals are added to the market, the demand for sandwiches becomes a smooth downward-sloping line, shown in panel D.
Economists refer to WTP as the maximum amount one would be willing to pay for a good or service, which represents the highest value that a consumer believes the good or service is worth. Of course, one always hopes that the actual price would be much lower. In your case, WTP is the cutoff between buying a sandwich and not buying a sandwich. WTP varies from person to person, from the circumstances each person is in to the number of sandwiches one chooses to buy. Suppose your classmate ate a full meal before she came to class. Her WTP for a sandwich would be much lower than yours because she isn’t hungry at that moment. Similarly, after you buy and consume your first sandwich, your WTP for a second sandwich would decrease because you would be less hungry. The desires consumers have for goods and services are expressed through their purchases in the market. Figure 1 illustrates how individuals’ WTP is used to derive market demand curves. Suppose you are willing to pay up to $10 for the first sandwich and $4 for the second sandwich (shown in panel A), while Jane, your less-hungry classmate, would pay up to $6 for her first sandwich and only $2 for her second sandwich (shown in panel B). If we take the WTP for your two sandwiches and the WTP of Jane’s two sandwiches and place all four values in order from highest to lowest, a two-person market for sandwiches is created as shown in panel C. Notice how the distance between steps becomes smaller in the two-person market. Now suppose we combine the WTPs for everybody in the class (or for an entire city or country) into a single market. What would that diagram look like? In large markets, the difference in WTP between each unit of a good becomes so small that it becomes a straight line, as shown in panel D. These illustrations show how ordinary demand curves, which we will discuss in detail in the remainder of this section, are developed from the perceptions of what individual consumers believe a good or service is worth to them (their WTP). Let’s now discuss an important characteristic of market demand.
The Law of Demand: The Relationship Between Quantity Demanded and Price Demand refers to the goods and services people are willing and able to buy during a certain period of time at various prices, holding all other relevant factors constant (the ceteris paribus condition). Typically, when the price of a good or service increases (say your favorite café raises its prices), the quantity demanded will decrease because fewer and fewer people will be willing and able to spend their money on such things. However, when prices of goods or services decrease (think of sales offered the day after Thanksgiving), the quantity demanded increases. demand The maximum amount of a product that buyers are willing and able to purchase over some time period at various prices, holding all other relevant factors constant (the ceteris paribus condition).
In a market economy, there is a negative relationship between price and quantity demanded. This relationship, in its most basic form, states that as price increases, the quantity demanded falls, and conversely, as price falls, the quantity demanded increases. This principle, when all other factors are held constant, is known as the law of demand. The law of demand states that the lower a product’s price, the more of that product consumers will purchase during a given time period. This straightforward, commonsense notion happens because, as a product’s price drops, consumers will substitute the now cheaper product for other, more expensive products. Conversely, if the product’s price rises, consumers will find other, less expensive products to substitute for it. law of demand Holding all other relevant factors constant, as price increases, quantity demanded falls, and as price decreases, quantity demanded rises.
144
To illustrate, when videocassette recorders first came on the market 35 years ago, they cost $3,000, and few homes had one. As VCRs became less and less expensive, however, more people bought them, and others found more uses for them. Two decades later, VCRs became obsolete as DVD players became the standard means of watching movies at home. Today, DVD players are becoming obsolete as digital movie streaming surpassed DVD sales. Similarly, digital music players have altered the structure of the music business, and digital cameras have essentially replaced cameras that use film. Time is an important component in the demand for many products. Consuming many products—watching a movie, eating a pizza, playing tennis—takes some time. Thus, the price of these goods includes not only their monetary cost but also the opportunity cost of the time needed to consume them. It follows that, all other things being equal, including the cost of a ticket, we would expect more consumers to attend a two-hour movie than a four-hour movie. The shorter movie simply requires less of a time investment. The day after Thanksgiving, dubbed “Black Friday,” is when stores offer steep discounts to jumpstart the holiday shopping season. This leads to massive quantities of goods sold, in an example of the law of demand.
The Demand Curve The law of demand states that as price decreases, quantity demanded increases. When we translate demand information into a graph, we create a demand curve. This demand curve, which slopes down and to the right, graphically illustrates the law of demand. A demand curve shows both the willingness-to-pay for any given quantity and what the quantity demanded will be at any given price. In Figure 1, we saw how individual demands (measured by willingness-to-pay) can be combined to represent market demand, which can consist of many consumers. For simplicity, from this point we will assume that all demand curves, including those for individuals, are linear (straight lines). demand curve A graphical illustration of the law of demand, which shows the relationship between the price of a good and the quantity demanded.
Consider the market for gaming apps, games that can be downloaded onto one’s smartphone or tablet. The mobile gaming industry is a $25 billion industry. Although each gaming app costs no more than a few dollars to download, sales of gaming apps have surpassed sales of PC and console games. Gaming apps such as Candy Crush Saga, Angry
145
Birds, and Words with Friends have each been downloaded hundreds of millions of times. Let’s examine the relationship between the price of gaming apps and the quantity demanded by individual consumers and the market. For simplicity, assume that all gaming apps are the same price. Suppose Abe and Betty are the only two consumers in the market for gaming apps. Figure 2 shows each of their annual demands using a demand schedule and a demand curve. A demand schedule is a table indicating the quantities consumers are willing to purchase at each price. Looking at the demand schedule, we can see that both Abe and Betty are willing to buy more gaming apps as the price decreases. When the price is $10, Abe is willing to buy 10 games, while Betty buys none. When the price falls to $8, Abe is willing to buy 15 games and Betty would buy 5. demand schedule A table that shows the quantity of a good a consumer purchases at each price.
We can take the values from the demand schedule in the table and graph them in a figure, with price shown on the vertical axis and quantity of gaming apps on the horizontal axis, following the convention in economics of always placing price on the vertical axis and quantity on the horizontal axis. By doing so, we can create a demand curve for both Abe and Betty. Both the table and the graph convey the same information. They also both portray the law of demand. As the price decreases, Abe and Betty demand more gaming apps. FIGURE 2
MARKET DEMAND: HORIZONTAL SUMMATION OF INDIVIDUAL DEMAND CURVES
Abe and Betty’s demand schedules (the table) and their individual demand curves (the graph) for gaming apps are shown. Abe will purchase 15 gaming apps when the price is $8, buy 25 apps when the price falls to $4, and buy more as prices continue to fall. Betty will purchase 5 gaming apps when the price is $8 and buy 15 when the price falls to $4. The individual demand curves for Abe and Betty are shown as Da and Db, respectively, and are horizontally summed to get market demand, DMkt. Horizontal summation involves adding together the quantities demanded by each individual at each possible price.
146
Although individual demand curves are interesting, market demand curves are far more important to economists, as they can be used to predict changes in product price and quantity. Further, one can observe what happens to a product’s price and quantity and infer what changes have occurred in the market. Market demand is the sum of individual demands. To calculate market demand, economists simply add the number of units of a product all consumers will purchase at each price. This process is known as horizontal summation. horizontal summation The process of adding the number of units of the product purchased or supplied at each price to determine market demand or supply.
Turning to the demand curves in Figure 2, the individual demand curves for Abe and Betty, Da and Db, are shown. For simplicity, let’s assume they represent the entire market, but recognize that this process would work for any larger number of people. Note that at a price of $10 a game, Betty will not buy any, although Abe is willing to buy 10 apps at $10 each. Above $10, therefore, the market demand is equal to Abe’s demand. At $10 and below, however, we add both Abe’s and Betty’s demands at each price to obtain market demand. Thus, at $8, individual demand is 15 for Abe and 5 for Betty; therefore, the market demand is equal to 20 (point c). When the price is $4 an app, Abe buys 25 and Betty buys 15, for a total of 40 apps (point e). The heavier curve, labeled DMkt, represents this market demand; it is a horizontal summation of the two individual demand curves. This all sounds simple in theory, but in the real world estimating market demand curves is tricky, given that many markets contain millions of consumers. Economic analysts and marketing professionals use sophisticated statistical techniques to estimate the market demand for particular goods and services in the industries they represent. The market demand curve shows the maximum amount of a product consumers are willing and able to purchase during a given time period at various prices, all other relevant factors being held constant. Economists use the term determinants of demand to refer to these other, nonprice factors that are held constant. This is another example of the use of ceteris paribus: holding all other relevant factors constant.
Determinants of Demand Up to this point, we have discussed only how price affects the quantity demanded. When prices fall, consumers purchase more of a product; thus quantity demanded rises. When prices rise, consumers purchase less of a product; thus, quantity demanded falls. But several other factors besides price also affect demand, including what people like, what their income is, and how much related products cost. More specifically, there are five key determinants of demand: (1) tastes and preferences; (2) income; (3) prices of related goods; (4) the number of buyers; and (5) expectations regarding future prices, income, and product availability. When one of these determinants changes, the entire demand curve changes. Let’s see why. determinants of demand Nonprice factors that affect demand, including tastes and preferences, income, prices of related goods, number of buyers, and expectations.
Tastes and Preferences
We all have preferences for certain products over others, easily perceiving subtle differences in styling and quality. Automobiles, fashions, phones, and music are just a few of the products that are subject to the whims of the consumer. Remember Crocs, those brightly colored rubber sandals with the little air holes that moms, kids, waitresses, and many others favored? They were an instant hit. Initially, demand was D0 in Figure 3. They then became such a fad that demand jumped to D1 and for a short while Crocs were hard to find. Eventually, Crocs were everywhere. Fads come and go, and now the demand for them settled back to something like D2, less than the original level. Notice an important distinction here: More Crocs weren’t sold because the price was lowered; the entire demand curve shifted rightward when they were hot and more Crocs could be sold at all prices. Now that the fad has subsided, fewer will be sold at all prices. It is important to keep in mind that when one of the determinants changes, such as tastes and preferences, the entire demand curve shifts.
147
Income
Income is another important factor influencing consumer demand. Generally speaking, as income rises, demand for most goods will likewise increase. Get a raise, and you are more likely to buy more clothes and acquire the latest technology gadgets. Your demand curve for these goods will shift to the right (such as from D0 to D1 in Figure 3). Products for which demand is positively linked to income—when income rises, demand for the product also rises— are called normal good normal good A good for which an increase in income results in rising demand.
There are also some products for which demand declines as income rises, and the demand curve shifts to the left. Economists call these products inferior goods. As income grows, for instance, the consumption of discount clothing and cheap motel stays will likely fall as individuals upgrade their wardrobes and stay in more comfortable hotels when traveling. Similarly, when you graduate from college and your income rises, your consumption of ramen noodles will fall as you begin to cook tastier dinners and eat out more frequently. inferior good A good for which an increase in income results in declining demand.
Prices of Related Goods
The prices of related commodities also affect consumer decisions. You may be an avid concertgoer, but with concert ticket prices often topping $100, further rises in the price of concert tickets may entice you to see more movies and fewer concerts. Movies, concerts, plays, and sporting events are good examples of substitute goods, because consumers can substitute one for another depending on their respective prices. When the price of concerts rises, your demand for movies increases, and vice versa. These are substitute goods. substitute goods Goods consumers will substitute for one another. When the price of one good rises, the demand for the other good increases, and vice versa. FIGURE 3
SHIFTS IN THE DEMAND CURVE
148
The demand for Crocs originally was D0. When they became a fad, demand shifted to D1 as consumers were willing and able to purchase more at all prices. Once the fad cooled off, demand fell (shifted leftward) to D2 as consumers wanted less at each price. When a determinant such as tastes and preferences changes, the entire demand curve shifts.
Movies and popcorn, on the other hand, are examples of complementary goods. These are goods that are generally consumed together, such that an increase or decrease in the consumption of one will similarly result in an increase or decrease in the consumption of the other—see fewer movies, and your consumption of popcorn will decline. Other complementary goods include cars and gasoline, hot dogs and hot dog buns, and ski lift tickets and ski rentals. Thus, when the price of lift tickets increases, the quantity of lift tickets demanded falls, which causes your demand for ski rentals to fall as well (shifts to the left), and vice versa. complementary goods Goods that are typically consumed together. When the price of a complementary good rises, the demand for the other good declines, and vice versa.
The Number of Buyers
Another factor influencing market demand for a product is the number of potential buyers in the market. Clearly, the more consumers there are who would be likely to buy a particular product, the higher its market demand will be (the demand curve will shift rightward). As our average life span steadily rises, the demands for medical services and retirement communities likewise increases. As more people than ever enter universities and graduate schools, demand for textbooks and backpacks increases.
Expectations About Future Prices, Incomes, and Product Availability
The final factor influencing demand involves consumer expectations. If consumers expect shortages of certain products or increases in their prices in the near future, they tend to rush out and buy these products immediately, thereby increasing the present demand for the products. The demand curve shifts to the right. During the Florida hurricane season, when a large storm forms and begins moving toward the coast, the demand for plywood, nails, bottled water, and batteries quickly rises. The expectation of a rise in income, meanwhile, can lead consumers to take advantage of credit in order to increase their present consumption. Department stores and furniture stores, for example, often run “no payments until next year” sales designed to attract consumers who want to “buy now, pay later.” These consumers expect to have more money later, when they can pay, so they go ahead and buy what they want now, thereby increasing the present demand for the promoted items. Again, the demand curve shifts to the right. The key point to remember from this section is that when one of the determinants of demand changes, the entire demand curve shifts rightward (an increase in demand) or leftward (a decline in demand). A quick look back at Figure 3 shows that when demand increases, consumers are willing to buy more at all prices, and when demand decreases, they will buy less at each and every price.
Changes in Demand Versus Changes in Quantity Demanded When the price of a product rises, consumers buy fewer units of that product. This is a movement along an existing demand curve. However, when one or more of the determinants changes, the entire demand curve is altered. Now at any given price, consumers are willing to purchase more or less depending on the nature of the change. This section focuses on this important distinction between changes in demand versus changes in quantity demanded. A change in demand occurs whenever one or more of the determinants of demand change and demand curves shift. When demand changes, the demand curve shifts either to the right or to the left. Let’s look at each shift in turn. change in demand Occurs when one or more of the determinants of demand changes, shown as a shift in
149
the entire demand curve.
Demand increases when the entire demand curve shifts to the right. At all prices, consumers are willing to purchase more of the product in question. Figure 4 shows an increase in demand for gaming apps; the demand curve shifts from D0 to D1. Notice that more gaming apps are purchased at all prices along D1 as compared to D0. Now look at a decrease in demand, when the entire demand curve shifts to the left. At all prices, consumers are willing to purchase less of the product in question. A drop in consumer income is normally associated with a decrease in demand (the demand curve shifts to the left, as from D0 to D2 in Figure 4). FIGURE 4
CHANGES IN DEMAND VERSUS CHANGES IN QUANTITY DEMANDED
A shift in the demand curve from D0 to D1 represents an increase in demand, and consumers will buy more of the product at each price. A shift from D0 to D2 reflects a decrease in demand. A movement along D0 from point a to point c indicates an increase in quantity demanded; this type of movement can only be caused by a change in the price of the product.
Whereas a change in demand can be brought about by many different factors, a change in quantity demanded can be caused by only one thing: a change in product price. This is shown in Figure 4 as a reduction in price from $8 to $4, resulting in sales (quantity demanded) increasing from 20 (point a) to 40 (point c) apps. This distinction between a change in demand and a change in quantity demanded is important. Reducing price to increase sales is different from spending a few million dollars on Super Bowl advertising to increase sales at all prices. change in quantity demanded Occurs when the price of the product changes, shown as a movement along an existing demand curve.
These concepts are so important that a quick summary is in order. As Figure 4 illustrates, given the initial demand D0, increasing sales from 20 to 40 apps can occur in either of two ways. First, changing a determinant (say, increasing advertising) could shift the demand curve to D1 so that 40 apps would be sold at $8 (point b).
150
Alternatively, 40 apps could be sold by reducing the price to $4 (point c). Selling more by increasing advertising causes an increase in demand, or a shift in the entire demand curve. Simply reducing the price, on the other hand, causes an increase in quantity demanded, or a movement along the existing demand curve, D0, from point a to point c.
CHECKPOINT DEMAND A person’s willingness-to-pay is the maximum amount she or he values a good to be worth at a particular moment in time and is the building block for demand. Demand refers to the quantity of products people are willing and able to purchase at various prices during some specific time period, all other relevant factors being held constant. The law of demand states that price and quantity demanded have an inverse (negative) relation. As price rises, consumers buy fewer units; as price falls, consumers buy more units. It is depicted as a downward-sloping demand curve. Demand curves shift when one or more of the determinants of demand change. The determinants of demand are consumer tastes and preferences, income, prices of substitutes and complements, the number of buyers in a market, and expectations about future prices, incomes, and product availability. A shift of a demand curve is a change in demand, and occurs when a determinant of demand changes. A change in quantity demanded occurs only when the price of a product changes, leading consumers to adjust their purchases along the existing demand curve.
QUESTION: Sales of electric plug-in cars, such as the Tesla, have risen in recent years. Despite their
relatively high price compared to gasoline-powered cars and the limited distance the cars can travel before requiring a recharge, other manufacturers are adding new models of plug-ins to their lines. What has led to the rising popularity of plug-in cars? Is this an increase in demand or an increase in quantity demanded? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
151
SUPPLY The analysis of a market economy rests on two foundations: supply and demand. So far, we’ve covered the demand side of the market. Let’s focus now on the decisions businesses make regarding production numbers and sales. These decisions cause variations in product supply.
The Law of Supply: The Relationship Between Quantity Supplied and Price
Supply is the maximum amount of a product that producers are willing and able to offer for sale at various prices, all other relevant factors being held constant. The quantity supplied will vary according to the price of the product. supply The maximum amount of a product that sellers are willing and able to provide for sale over some time period at various prices, holding all other relevant factors constant (the ceteris paribus condition).
What explains this relationship? As we saw in the previous chapter, businesses inevitably encounter rising opportunity costs as they attempt to produce more and more of a product. This is due in part to diminishing returns from available resources, and in part to the fact that when producers increase production, they must either have existing workers put in overtime (at a higher hourly pay rate) or hire additional workers away from other industries (again at premium pay). Producing more units, therefore, makes it more expensive to produce each individual unit. These increasing costs give rise to the positive relationship between product price and quantity supplied to the market. Unfortunately for producers, they can rarely charge whatever they would like for their products; they must charge whatever the market will permit. But producers can decide how much of their product to produce and offer for sale. The law of supply states that higher prices will lead producers to offer more of their products for sale during a given period. Conversely, if prices fall, producers will offer fewer products to the market. The explanation is simple: The higher the price, the greater the potential for higher profits and thus the greater the incentive for businesses to produce and sell more products. Also, given the rising opportunity costs associated with increasing production, producers need to charge these higher prices to increase the quantity supplied profitably. law of supply Holding all other relevant factors constant, as price increases, quantity supplied rises, and as price declines, quantity supplied falls.
Let’s return to our market for gaming apps. Why do programmers spend countless hours developing new gaming apps? Because they have an incentive to do so. Much like how consumers download more gaming apps when the price goes down, the opposite is true for suppliers. As the price rises, programmers are more willing to create new games, enhance existing games, and provide more server capacity (to ensure games operate smoothly) and technical support, all to increase the quantity of gaming apps supplied. Although gaming apps are not a physical good, the law of supply still applies. This is no different than an oil producer drilling for more oil when the price rises. In each case, producers respond to changes in price.
The Supply Curve Just as demand curves graphically display the law of demand, supply curves provide a graphical representation of the law of supply. The supply curve shows the maximum amounts of a product a producer will furnish at various prices during a given period of time. While the demand curve slopes down and to the right, the supply curve slopes up and to the right.1 This illustrates the positive relationship between price and quantity supplied: The higher the price, the greater the quantity supplied. supply curve A graphical illustration of the law of supply, which shows the relationship between the price of
152
a good and the quantity supplied. FIGURE 5
SUPPLY OF GAMING APPS
This supply curve graphs the supply schedule and shows the maximum quantity of gaming apps that producers will offer for sale over some defined period of time. The supply curve is positively sloped, reflecting the law of supply. In other words, as prices rise, quantity supplied increases; as prices fall, quantity supplied falls.
Market Supply Curves
As with demand, economists are more interested in market supply than in the supplies offered by individual firms. To compute market supply, use the same method used to calculate market demand, horizontally summing the supplies of individual producers. A hypothetical market supply curve for gaming apps is depicted in Figure 5. The quantity of gaming apps that producers will offer for sale increases as the price of gaming apps rises. The opposite would happen if the price of gaming apps falls.
Determinants of Supply Like demand, several nonprice factors help to determine the supply of a product. Specifically, there are six determinants of supply: (1) production technology, (2) costs of resources, (3) prices of related commodities, (4) expectations, (5) the number of sellers (producers) in the market, and (6) taxes and subsidies. determinants of supply Nonprice factors that affect supply, including production technology, costs of resources, prices of related commodities, expectations, number of sellers, and taxes and subsidies.
Production Technology 153
Technology determines how much output can be produced from given quantities of resources. If a factory’s equipment is old and can produce only 50 units of output per hour, then no matter how many other resources are employed, those 50 units are the most the factory can produce in an hour. If the factory is outfitted with newer, more advanced equipment capable of turning out 100 units per hour, the firm can supply more of its product at the same price as before, or even at a lower price. In Figure 6, this would be represented by a shift in the supply curve from S0 to S1. At every single price, more would be supplied. Technology further determines the nature of products that can be supplied to the market. A hundred years ago, the supply of computers on the market was zero because computers did not yet exist. More recent advances in microprocessing and miniaturization brought a wide array of products to the market that were not available just a few years ago, including mini-tablets, auto engines that go 100,000 miles between tune-ups, and constant-monitoring insulin pumps that automatically keep a diabetic patient’s glucose levels under control. FIGURE 6
SHIFTS IN THE SUPPLY CURVE
The supply of gaming apps originally is S0. If supply shifts to S1, producers are willing to sell more at all prices. If supply falls, supply shifts leftward to S2. Now firms are willing to sell less at each price. When a determinant of supply changes, the entire supply curve shifts.
Costs of Resources
Resource costs clearly affect production costs and supply. If resources such as raw materials or labor become more expensive, production costs will rise and supply will be reduced (the supply curve shifts to the left, from S0 to S2 in Figure 6). The reverse is true if resource costs drop (the supply curve shifts to the right, from S0 to S1). The growing power of microchips along with their falling cost has resulted in cheap and plentiful electronics and computers. Nanotechnology—manufacturing processes that fashion new products through the combination of individual atoms— may soon usher in a whole new generation of inexpensive products. However, when the cost of resources (such as oil and farm products) rise, the cost of products using those
154
resources in their manufacture will go up, leading to the supply being reduced (the supply curve shifts leftward). If labor costs rise because immigration is restricted, this drives up production costs of California vegetables (fewer farmworkers) and software in Silicon Valley (fewer software engineers from abroad) and leads to a shift in the supply curve to the left in Figure 6.
Prices of Related Commodities
Most firms have some flexibility in the portfolio of goods they produce. A vegetable farmer, for example, might be able to grow celery or radishes, or some combination of the two. Given this flexibility, a change in the price of one item may influence the quantity of other items brought to market. If the price of celery should rise, for instance, most farmers will start growing more celery. And since they all have a limited amount of land on which to grow vegetables, this reduces the quantity of radishes they can produce. Hence, in this case, the rise in the price of celery may well cause a reduction in the supply of radishes (the supply curve for radishes shifts leftward).
Expectations
The effects of future expectations on market supplies can be confusing, but it need not be. When sellers expect prices of a good to rise in the future, they are likely to restrict their supply in the current period in anticipation of receiving higher prices in some future period. Examples include homes and stocks—if you believe prices are going up, you’d be less likely to sell today, which decreases the supply of such goods (supply shifts to the left). Similarly, expectations of price reductions can increase supply as sellers try to sell off their inventories before prices drop (supply shifts to the right). Eventually, if prices do rise in the next period, producers would increase the quantity supplied of the good; however, this would be due to the law of supply, not due to a shift of the supply curve. In other words, rising prices result in a movement along the supply curve. Only when producers anticipate a change in a future price, causing a reaction now, does supply shift.
Number of Sellers
Everything else being held constant, if the number of sellers in a particular market increases, the market supply of their product increases. It is no great mystery why: Ten dim sum chefs can produce more dumplings in a given period than five dim sum chefs.
Taxes and Subsidies
For businesses, taxes and subsidies affect costs. An increase in taxes (property, excise, or other fees) will shift supply to the left and reduce it. Subsidies are the opposite of taxes. If the government subsidizes the production of a product, supply will shift to the right and rise. A proposed new tax on expensive health care insurance plans may reduce supply (the tax is equivalent to an increase in production costs), while today’s subsidies to ethanol producers expand ethanol production.
Changes in Supply Versus Changes in Quantity Supplied A change in supply results from a change in one or more of the determinants of supply; it causes the entire supply curve to shift. An increase in supply of a product, perhaps because advancing technology has made it cheaper to produce, means that more of the commodity will be offered for sale at every price. This causes the supply curve to shift to the right, as illustrated in Figure 7 by the shift from S0 to S1. A decrease in supply, conversely, shifts the supply curve to the left, since fewer units of the product are offered at every price. Such a decrease in supply is represented by the shift from S0 to S2. change in supply Occurs when one or more of the determinants of supply change, shown as a shift in the entire supply curve.
155
A change in supply involves a shift of the entire supply curve. In contrast, the supply curve does not move when there is a change in quantity supplied. Only a change in the price of a product can cause a change in the quantity supplied; hence, it involves a movement along an existing supply curve rather than a shift to an entirely different curve. In Figure 7, for example, an increase in price from $4 to $8 results in an increase in quantity supplied from 20 to 40 apps, represented by the movement from point a to point c along S0. change in quantity supplied Occurs when the price of the product changes, shown as a movement along an existing supply curve.
In summary, a change in supply is represented in Figure 7 by the shift from S0 to S1 or S2, which involves a shift in the entire supply curve. For example, an increase in supply from S0 to S1 results in an increase in supply from 20 gaming apps (point a) to 40 (point b) provided at a price of $4. More apps are provided at the same price. In contrast, a change in quantity supplied is shown in Figure 7 as a movement along an existing supply curve, S0, from point a to point c caused by an increase in the price of the product from $4 to $8. FIGURE 7
CHANGES IN SUPPLY VERSUS CHANGES IN QUANTITY SUPPLIED
A shift in the supply curve from S0 to S1 represents an increase in supply, because businesses are willing to offer more of the product to consumers at all prices. A shift from S0 to S2 reflects a decrease in supply. A movement along S0 from point a to point c represents an increase in quantity supplied; this type of movement can only be caused by a change in the price of the product.
As on the demand side, this distinction between changes in supply and changes in quantity supplied is crucial. It means that when a product’s price changes, only quantity supplied changes—the supply curve does not move. A summary of the determinants for both supply and demand is shown in Figure 8.
156
FIGURE 8
SUMMARY OF CHANGES IN DEMAND AND SUPPLY AND THEIR DETERMINANTS
Various factors cause a market demand curve to shift to the left (decrease in demand) or shift to the right (increase in demand) in panel A. Similarly, various factors cause a market supply curve to shift to the left (decrease in supply) or shift to the right (increase in supply) in panel B. The table summarizes the factors influencing demand and supply shifts.
CHECKPOINT SUPPLY 157
Supply is the quantity of a product producers are willing and able to put on the market at various prices, all other relevant factors being held constant. The law of supply reflects the positive relationship between price and quantity supplied: The higher the market price, the more goods supplied, and the lower the market price, the fewer goods supplied. As with demand, market supply is derived by horizontally summing the individual supplies of all of the firms in the market. A change in supply occurs when one or more of the determinants of supply change. The determinants of supply are production technology, the cost of resources, prices of related commodities, expectations about future prices, the number of sellers or producers in the market, and taxes and subsidies. A change in supply is a shift in the supply curve. A shift to the right reflects an increase in supply, while a shift to the left represents a decrease in supply. A change in quantity supplied is only caused by a change in the price of the product; it results in a movement along the existing supply curve.
QUESTION: At the end of the term, bookstores often increase the prices offered to students for their
used textbooks in order to stock their shelves for the following term. Would an increase in the buyback price affect the supply or the quantity supplied of used textbooks? Suppose an unusually difficult professor leads to many students having to retake the course the next term. How might this affect the supply for used textbooks? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
158
MARKET EQUILIBRIUM Supply and demand together determine the prices and quantities of goods bought and sold. Neither factor alone is sufficient to determine price and quantity. It is through their interaction that supply and demand do their work, just as two blades of a scissors are required to cut paper. A market will determine the price at which the quantity of a product demanded is equal to the quantity supplied. At this price, the market is said to be cleared or to be in equilibrium, meaning that the amount of the product that consumers are willing and able to purchase is matched exactly by the amount that producers are willing and able to sell. This is the equilibrium price and the equilibrium quantity. The equilibrium price is also called the marketclearing price. equilibrium Market forces are in balance when the quantities demanded by consumers just equal the quantities supplied by producers. equilibrium price The price at which the quantity demanded is just equal to quantity supplied. equilibrium quantity The output that results when quantity demanded is just equal to quantity supplied.
Figure 9 puts together Figures 2 and 5, showing the market supply and demand for gaming apps. It illustrates how supply and demand interact to determine equilibrium price and quantity. Clearly, the quantities demanded and supplied equal one another only where the supply and demand curves cross, at point e. From the table in Figure 9, you can see that quantity demanded and quantity supplied are the same at only one price. At $6 per app, sellers are willing to provide exactly the same quantity as consumers would like to purchase. Hence, at this price, the market clears, since buyers and sellers both want to transact the same number of units. The beauty of a market is that it automatically works to establish the equilibrium price and quantity, without any guidance from anyone. To see how this happens, let us assume that gaming apps are initially priced at $8, a price above their equilibrium price. As we can see by comparing points a and b, sellers are willing to supply more apps at this price than consumers are willing to buy. Economists characterize such a situation as one of excess supply, or surplus. In this case, at $8, sellers supply 40 apps to the market (point b), yet buyers want to purchase only 20 (point a). This leaves an excess of 20 apps overhanging the market; these unsold apps ultimately become surplus inventories. surplus Occurs when the price is above market equilibrium, and quantity supplied exceeds quantity demanded. FIGURE 9
EQUILIBRIUM PRICE AND QUANTITY OF GAMING APPS
159
Market equilibrium is achieved when quantity demanded and quantity supplied are equal at the market price. In this graph, that equilibrium occurs at point e, at an equilibrium price of $6 and an equilibrium output of 30. If the market price is above equilibrium ($8), a surplus of 20 computer apps will result (b − a), and market forces would drive the price back down to $6. When the market price is too low ($4), a shortage of 20 computer apps will result (d − c), and businesses will raise the offering prices until equilibrium is again restored.
Here is where the market kicks in to restore equilibrium. As inventories rise, most firms cut production. Some firms, moreover, start reducing their prices to increase sales. Other firms must then cut their own prices to remain competitive. This process continues, with firms cutting their prices and production, until most firms have managed to exhaust their surplus inventories. This happens when prices reach $6 and quantity supplied equals 30, because consumers are once again willing to buy up the entire quantity supplied at this price, and the market is restored to equilibrium. In general, therefore, when prices are set too high, surpluses result, which drive prices back down to their equilibrium levels. If, conversely, a price is initially set too low, say, at $4, a shortage results. In this case, buyers want to purchase 40 apps (point d), but sellers are only providing 20 (point c), creating a shortage of 20 apps. Because consumers are willing to pay more than $4 to obtain the few apps available on the market, they will start bidding up the price of gaming apps. Sensing an opportunity to make some money, firms will start raising their prices and increasing production once again until equilibrium is restored. Hence, in general, excess demand causes firms to raise prices and increase production. shortage Occurs when the price is below market equilibrium, and quantity demanded exceeds quantity supplied.
When there is a shortage in a market, economists speak of a tight market or a seller’s market. Under these conditions, producers have no difficulty selling off all their output. On the other hand, when a surplus of goods floods
160
the market, this gives rise to a buyer’s market, because buyers can buy all the goods they want at attractive prices. We have now seen how changing prices naturally works to clear up shortages and surpluses, thereby returning markets to equilibrium. Some markets, once disturbed, will return to equilibrium quickly. Examples include the stock, bond, and money markets, where trading is nearly instantaneous and extensive information abounds. Other markets react very slowly. Consider the labor market, for instance. When workers lose their jobs due to a plant closing, most will search for new jobs that pay at least as much as the salary at their previous jobs. Some will be successful, while others might struggle, having to settle for a lower-paying position after a long job search. Similarly, real estate markets can be slow to adjust because sellers will often refuse to accept a price below what they are asking, until the lack of sales over time convinces sellers to adjust the price downward. These automatic market adjustments can make some buyers and sellers feel uncomfortable: It seems as if prices and quantities are being set by forces beyond anyone’s control. In fact, this phenomenon is precisely what makes market economies function so efficiently. Without anyone needing to be in control, prices and quantities naturally gravitate toward equilibrium levels. Adam Smith was so impressed by the workings of the market that he suggested that it is almost as if an “invisible hand” guides the market to equilibrium. Given the self-correcting nature of the market, long-term shortages or surpluses are almost always the result of government intervention, as we will see in the next chapter. First, however, we turn to a discussion of how the market responds to changes in supply and demand, or to shifts of the supply and demand curves.
Moving to a New Equilibrium: Changes in Supply and Demand Once a market is in equilibrium and the forces of supply and demand balance one another out, the market will remain there unless an external factor changes. But when the supply curve or demand curve shifts (some determinant changes), equilibrium also shifts, resulting in a new equilibrium price and/or output. The ability to predict new equilibrium points is one of the most useful aspects of supply and demand analysis.
Predicting the New Equilibrium When One Curve Shifts
When only supply or only demand changes, the change in equilibrium price and equilibrium output can be predicted. We begin with changes in supply. Changes in Supply Figure 10 shows what happens when supply changes. Equilibrium initially is at point e, with equilibrium price and quantity at $9 and 30, respectively. But let us assume that a rise in wages or the bankruptcy of a key business in the market (the number of sellers falls) causes a decrease in supply. When supply declines (the supply curve shifts from S0 to S2), equilibrium price rises to $12, while equilibrium output falls to 20 (point a). If, on the other hand, supply increases (the supply curve shifts from S0 to S1), equilibrium price falls to $6, while equilibrium output rises to 40 (point b). This is what has happened in the electronics industry: Falling production costs have resulted in more electronic products being sold at lower prices.
ALFRED MARSHALL (1842–1924) ritish economist Alfred Marshall is considered the father of the modern theory of supply and demand—that price and output are determined by both supply and demand. He noted that the two go together like the blades of a scissors that cross at equilibrium. He assumed that changes in quantity demanded were only affected by changes in price, and that all other factors remained constant. Marshall also is credited with developing the ideas of the laws of demand and supply, and the concepts of consumer surplus and producer surplus—concepts we will study in the next chapter. With financial help from his uncle, Marshall attended St. John’s College, Cambridge, to study mathematics and physics. However after long walks through the poorest sections of several European
161
B
cities and seeing their horrible conditions, he decided to focus his attention on political economy. In 1890 he published Principles of Economics. In it he introduced many new ideas, though he would never boast about them as being novel. In hopes of appealing to the general public, Marshall buried his diagrams in footnotes. And, although he is credited with many economic theories, he would always clarify them with various exceptions and qualifications. He expected future economists to flesh out his ideas. Above all, Marshall loved teaching and his students. His lectures were known to never be orderly or systematic because he tried to get students to think with him and ultimately think for themselves. At one point near the turn of the 20th century, essentially all of the leading economists in England had been his students. More than anyone else, Marshall is given credit for establishing economics as a discipline of study. He died in 1924. Information from E. Ray Canterbery, A Brief History of Economics: Artful Approaches to the Dismal Science (Hackensack, NJ: World Scientific), 2001; Robert Skidelsky, John Maynard Keynes: Volume 2, The Economist as Saviour 1920–1937 (New York: Penguin Press), 1992; and John Maynard Keynes, Essays in Biography (New York: Norton), 1951.
When Universal Studios in Florida expanded its popular Wizarding World of Harry Potter attraction in 2014 with the opening of Diagon Alley and Hogwarts Express, demand for Universal Studios tickets increased. A one-day ticket (allowing entry to both parks) now exceeds $160. And that doesn’t include the wand (another $30 to $40) needed to operate many of the Harry Potter experiences!
162
FIGURE 10
EQUILIBRIUM PRICE, OUTPUT, AND SHIFTS IN SUPPLY
163
When supply alone shifts, the effects on both equilibrium price and output can be predicted. When supply increases (S0 to S1), equilibrium price will fall and output will rise. When supply declines (S0 to S2), the opposite happens: Equilibrium price will rise and output will fall.
We have seen how equilibrium price and quantity will change when supply changes. When supply increases, equilibrium price will fall and output will rise; when supply decreases, equilibrium price will rise and output will fall. Changes in Demand The effects of demand changes are shown in Figure 11. Again, equilibrium is initially at point e, with equilibrium price and quantity at $9 and 30, respectively. But let us assume that the economy then enters a recession and incomes sink, or perhaps the price of some complementary good soars; in either case, demand falls. As demand decreases (the demand curve shifts from D0 to D2), equilibrium price falls to $6, while equilibrium output falls to 20 (point a). FIGURE 11
EQUILIBRIUM PRICE, OUTPUT, AND SHIFTS IN DEMAND
164
When demand alone changes, the effects on both equilibrium price and output can again be determined. When demand grows (D0 to D1), both price and output rise. Conversely, when demand falls (D0 to D2), both price and output fall.
ISSUE Two-Buck Chuck: Will People Drink $2-a-Bottle Wine?
165
The great California wines of the 1990s put California vineyards on the map. Demand, prices, and exports grew rapidly. Overplanting of new grapevines was a result. When driving along Interstate 5 or Highway 101 north of Los Angeles, one can see vineyards extending for miles, and most were planted in the mid- to late 1990s. The 2001 recession reduced the demand for California wine, and a rising dollar made imported wine relatively cheaper. The result was a sharp drop in demand for California wine and a huge surplus of grapes. Bronco Wine Company president Fred Franzia made an exclusive deal with Trader Joe’s, an unusual supermarket that features innovative food and wine products. He bought the excess grapes at distressed prices, and in his company’s modern plant produced inexpensive wines—chardonnay, merlot, cabernet sauvignon, shiraz, and sauvignon blanc—under the Charles Shaw label. Consumers flocked to Trader Joe’s for wine costing $1.99 a bottle and literally hauled cases of wine out by the carload. In less than a decade, 400 million bottles of Two-Buck Chuck, as it is known, have been sold. This is not rotgut: The 2002 shiraz beat out 2,300 other wines to win a double gold medal at the 28th Annual International Eastern Wine Competition in 2004. Still, to many Napa Valley vintners, it is known as Two-Buck Upchuck. Two-Buck Chuck was such a hit that other supermarkets were forced to offer their own discount wines. This good, low-priced wine has had the effect of opening up markets. People who previously avoided wine because of the cost have begun drinking more. However, the influence of Two-Buck Chuck, which sold 60 million bottles in 2012, may be waning. Because of the rising costs of producing the wine in recent years, largely due to the severe California drought, Two-Buck Chuck is now sold between $2.99 and $3.99 per bottle. Although the price is still a bargain, the product that changed the wine industry may need a new nickname.
During the same recession just described, the demand for inferior goods (beans and bologna) will rise, as falling incomes force people to switch to less expensive substitutes. For these products, as demand increases (shifting the demand curve from D0 to D1), equilibrium price rises to $12, and equilibrium output grows to 40 (point b). Like changes in supply, we can predict how equilibrium price and quantity will change when demand changes. When demand increases, both equilibrium price and output will rise; when demand decreases, both equilibrium price and output will fall.
Predicting the New Equilibrium When Both Curves Shift 166
When both supply and demand change, things get tricky. We can predict what will happen with price in some cases and output in other cases, but not what will happen with both. Figure 12 portrays an increase in both demand and supply. Consider the market for corn. Suppose that an increase in corn-based ethanol production causes demand for corn to increase. Meanwhile, suppose that bioengineering results in a new corn hybrid that uses less fertilizer and generates 50% higher yields, causing supply to also increase. When demand increases from D0 to D1 and supply increases from S0 to S1, output grows to Q1 as shown in the left panel. FIGURE 12
INCREASE IN SUPPLY, INCREASE IN DEMAND, AND EQUILIBRIUM
When both demand and supply increase, output will clearly rise, but what happens to the new equilibrium price is uncertain. If demand grows relatively more than supply, price will rise, but if supply grows relatively more than demand, price will fall.
But what happens to the price of corn is not so clear. If demand and supply grow the same, output increases, but price remains at P0 (also captured in the middle panel to the right). If demand grows relatively more than supply, the new equilibrium price will be higher (top panel on the right). Conversely, if demand grows relatively less than supply, the new equilibrium price will be lower (bottom panel on the right). Figure 12 is just one of the four possibilities when both supply and demand change. The other three possibilities are shown in Table 1 along with the four possibilities when just one curve shifts. When only one curve shifts, the direction of change in equilibrium price and quantity is certain. But when both curves shift, the direction of change in either the equilibrium price or quantity will be indeterminate.
TABLE 1
THE EFFECT OF CHANGES IN DEMAND OR SUPPLY ON EQUILIBRIUM PRICES AND QUANTITIES Change in Demand
Change in Supply
Change in Equilibrium Price
Change in Equilibrium Quantity
No change
Increase
Decrease
Increase
167
One Curve Shifting
Both Curves Shifting
No change
Decrease
Increase
Decrease
Increase
No change
Increase
Increase
Decrease
No change
Decrease
Decrease
Increase
Increase
Indeterminate
Increase
Decrease
Decrease
Indeterminate
Decrease
Increase
Decrease
Increase
Indeterminate
Decrease
Increase
Decrease
Indeterminate
Tokyo Disneyland: Is THAT the Line for Space Mountain?! What are some factors that cause Tokyo Disneyland to be so crowded even during the middle of winter?
H
ow long are you willing to wait to experience your favorite ride at a theme park? 20 minutes? 60 minutes? How about 3 hours? On an ordinary day at Tokyo Disneyland, one of the most popular theme parks in the world, the line for its famous attractions such as Space Mountain, Splash Mountain, and Tower of Terror can reach 200 minutes. . . . That’s over a 3-hour wait to enjoy a 3-minute ride! What causes lines to form at theme parks? Theme park rides have lines because the quantity of rides demanded exceeds the quantity supplied. Why is that? Because most theme parks charge a fixed admission fee for unlimited rides, visitors typically demand more rides than the theme park is able to supply, even if a ride is operating at full capacity. The extent of the shortage, and consequently the length of wait time, are influenced largely by market factors.
A 200-minute wait for a ride at Tokyo Disneyland.
168
First, consider the role of preferences. Disneyland has a worldwide following, and for those living in Japan, visiting Tokyo Disneyland is certainly easier than visiting Disney parks in California or Florida. Second, consider the number of potential buyers. Tokyo Disneyland is located in a metropolitan area with over 30 million people. The sheer number of potential visitors will lead to higher demand. And third, consider the role of pricing. Given its popularity, Tokyo Disneyland could charge higher prices to reduce the quantity demanded. Yet, in 2016 a one-day adult admission to Tokyo Disneyland cost only $58, while its counterparts in California and Florida charged nearly $120. The combination of preferences, proximity to potential buyers, and relatively low prices cause demand for Tokyo Disneyland rides to far exceed the park’s reasonable capacity (at least by U.S. standards), creating massive lines. Yet for enthusiastic Disney fans, smiling faces abound. Despite the crowds, it’s still the “Happiest Place on Earth!”
GO TO
TO PRACTICE THE ECONOMIC CONCEPTS IN THIS STORY
CHECKPOINT MARKET EQUILIBRIUM Together, supply and demand determine market equilibrium, which occurs when the quantity supplied exactly equals quantity demanded. The equilibrium price is also called the market-clearing price. When quantity demanded exceeds quantity supplied, a shortage occurs and prices are bid up toward equilibrium. When quantity supplied exceeds quantity demanded, a surplus occurs and prices are pushed down toward equilibrium. When supply and demand change, equilibrium price and output change. When only one curve shifts, the resulting changes in equilibrium price and quantity can be predicted. When both curves shift, we can predict the change in equilibrium price in some cases or the change in equilibrium quantity in others, but never both. We have to determine the relative magnitudes of the shifts before we can predict both equilibrium price and quantity.
QUESTION: In China, where lines are a routine part of everyday life, a growing industry of professional
line waiters has developed. Exactly as it sounds, these people are paid an average of $3 an hour to wait in line for others, a wage that is higher than what a typical factory worker in China earns. Today, the professional line waiter has popped up in cities around the world, including New York, though at significantly higher prices than in China. Given that one can pay someone to wait, what might happen in the market for goods and services most prone to long waiting lines, such as prime concert tickets or the latest technology gadget? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
169
chapter summary Section 1 Markets 3.1
A market is an institution that enables buyers and sellers to interact and transact with one another.
Markets can be as simple as a lemonade stand, as large as an automobile lot, as valuable as the stock market, as virtual as an Internet shopping site, or as illegal as a ticket scalping operation. Buyers and sellers communicate their desires in a market through the prices at which goods and services are bought and sold. Hence, a market economy is called a price system.
170
Section 2 Demand 3.2
Demand refers to the goods and services people are willing and able to buy during a period of time. It is a horizontal summation of individual demand curves in a defined market.
The law of demand states that as prices increase, quantity demanded falls, and vice versa, resulting in a downward-sloping demand curve.
Roller coasters are a lot of fun, but riding the same one over and over gives less satisfaction with
171
each ride; therefore, willingness-to-pay falls with each ride.
3.3
Determinants of Demand: How Demand Curves Shift ↑Tastes and preferences: Demand shifts right. ↑Income: Demand for normal goods shifts right, while demand for inferior goods shifts left. ↑Price of substitutes: Demand shifts right. ↑Price of complements: Demand shifts left. ↑Number of buyers: Demand shifts right. ↑Price expectations: Demand shifts right.
When investors expect stock prices to increase, demand for stock increases.
3.4
A Common Confusion in Terminology A “change in demand” is a shift of the entire demand curve and is caused by a change in a nonprice demand factor.
A “change in quantity demanded” is a movement from one point to another on the same demand curve, and is caused only by a change in price of that good.
172
Section 3 Supply 3.5
Supply analysis works the same way as demand, but looking at the market from the firm’s point of view.
The law of supply states that as price increases, firms want to supply more, and vice versa. It leads to an upward-sloping supply curve.
3.6
Determinants of Supply: How Supply Curves Shift ↑Production technology: Supply shifts right. ↑Cost of resources: Supply shifts left. ↑Price of related commodities: Supply shifts left. ↑Price expectations: Supply shifts left. ↑Number of sellers: Supply shifts right. ↑Taxes: Supply shifts left. ↑Subsidies: Supply shifts right.
173
Section 4 Market Equilibrium 3.7
Market equilibrium occurs at the price at which the quantity supplied is equal to quantity demanded, and where the demand and supply curves intersect.
How does equilibrium change?
3.8
A shift in demand or supply will change equilibrium price and quantity.
Higher oil prices raise the cost of resins used to produce surfboards.
Which curve slopes up and which slopes down? Two tricks to aid in memory: S“up”ply contains the word “up” for upward-sloping.
174
Only the fingers on your right hand can make a “d” for demand. Hold that hand up in front of you!
Supply of surfboards shifts left, raising equilibrium price and lowering equilibrium quantity.
KEY CONCEPTS markets price system willingness-to-pay demand law of demand demand curve demand schedule horizontal summation determinants of demand normal good inferior good substitute goods complementary goods change in demand change in quantity demanded supply law of supply supply curve determinants of supply change in supply change in quantity supplied equilibrium equilibrium price equilibrium quantity surplus shortage
175
QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS Check Your Understanding 1. Product prices give consumers and businesses a lot of information besides just the price. What kinds of information? 2. Name and explain the determinants of demand. Why are they important? 3. Assume there is a positive relationship between aging and cholesterol levels. As the world population ages, will the demand for cholesterol drugs increase, decrease, or remain the same? Would this cause a change in demand or a change in quantity demanded? 4. Describe some of the reasons why supply changes. Improved technology typically results in lower prices for most products. Why do you think this is true? Describe the difference between a change in supply and a change in quantity supplied. 5. If a strong economic recovery boosts average incomes, what would happen to the equilibrium price and quantity for a normal good? How about for an inferior good? 6. Suppose the market for tomatoes is in equilibrium, and events occur that simultaneously shift both the demand and supply curves to the right. Is it possible to determine how the equilibrium price and/or quantity would change? Explain.
Apply the Concepts 7. Demand for tickets to sporting events such as the Super Bowl has increased. Has supply increased? What does the answer to this tell you about the price of these tickets compared to prices a few years ago? 8. Suppose the price of monthly data plans required to access the Internet anywhere using a tablet computer falls. How would this affect the market for tablet computers? 9. Using the accompanying figures, answer the following questions: a. On the Demand panel: Show an increase in demand and label it D1. Show a decrease in demand and label it D2. Show an increase in quantity demanded. Show a decrease in quantity demanded. What causes demand to change? What causes quantity demanded to change?
b. On the Supply panel: Show an increase in supply and label it S1. Show a decrease in supply and label it S2. Show an increase in quantity supplied. Show a decrease in quantity supplied. What causes supply to change? What causes quantity supplied to change?
176
10. Several medical studies have shown that drinking red wine in moderation is good for the heart. How would such a study affect the public’s demand for wine? Would it have an impact on the type of grapes planted in new vineyards? 11. Assume initially that the demand and supply for premium coffees (one-pound bags) are in equilibrium. Now assume Starbucks introduces the world to premium blends, and so demand rises substantially. Describe what will happen in this market as it moves to a new equilibrium. If a hard freeze eliminates Brazil’s premium coffee crop, what will happen to the price of premium coffee? 12. Over the past decade, cruise ship companies have dramatically increased the number of mega-ships (those that carry 3,000 passengers or more), increasing the supply of cruises. At the same time, the popularity of cruising has increased among consumers, increasing demand. Explain how these two effects can coincide with a decrease in the average price of cruise travel.
In the News 13. In 2015 Google’s Self-Driving Cars had driven over 1 million miles on public roads and were involved in only twelve minor accidents, all of which were caused by the non-self-driving car. In response to the early success of self-driving cars, nearly every major auto manufacturer in the world is developing its own version of a driverless car (CBS News, “Driverless Cars Prepare to Hit the Road,” October 4, 2015), potentially increasing the supply of such cars in the market. What factors might cause demand for driverless cars to take off and become the new standard? What factors might cause demand to falter, leading the industry to fail? 14. When the Segway was unveiled in 2001, many believed it would become the future of transportation, replacing bicycles and even cars. Yet this expensive, bulky device never quite took off other than those used in Segway tours offered in many cities and by security officers in malls and airports. A decade later, other companies began developing newer, lighter, and less expensive motorized transportation devices such as the IO Hawk. A February 23, 2015, online article by Oxy.com, “This Motorized Skateboard Might Kick Segway to the Curb,” suggests that Segways may become obsolete. Using a demand and supply diagram for Segways, show the effect of the introduction of the IO Hawk on the market for Segways. Based on the article, are Segways and IO Hawks substitutes or complements?
Solving Problems
WORK IT OUT
177
WORK IT OUT 15. A popular tradition when traveling to Hawaii is to receive a lei, a wreath of flowers to welcome guests. Although a lei can be made of flowers, leaves, nuts, or even candy and money, orchids remain the most popular flower used to create them. Suppose that supply and demand in the orchid lei market in Hawaii are as represented in the table below:
Price ($/unit)
Quantity Demanded (thousands)
Quantity Supplied (thousands)
5
24
8
10
20
12
15
16
16
20
12
20
25
8
24
a. Graph both the supply (S0) and demand (D0) curves. What is the current equilibrium price? Label that point a.
b. Assume that the Hawaiian lei industry increases its use of orchids from Thailand (where they are grown at a lower price), allowing orchid lei supply to increase by 8,000 units at every price. Illustrate the increase in the supply in your graph. Label the new supply curve (S1). What will the new equilibrium price in the market be? Label that point b. c. Now assume that luxury hotels in Hawaii begin cost-cutting measures by no longer presenting guests with a lei upon check-in, reducing orchid lei demand by 8,000 units at every price. Label the new demand curve (D1). What will the new equilibrium price be? Label this new equilibrium point c. d. Subsequently assume that severe monsoons and civil unrest in Thailand lead to a reduction in orchid production, reducing supply back to the original curve (S0). What will the new equilibrium price be? Label this new equilibrium point d.
16. The following figure shows the supply and demand for strawberries. Answer the questions that follow.
178
a. Indicate the equilibrium price and equilibrium quantity. b. Suppose sellers try to sell strawberries at $4. How much of a shortage or a surplus of strawberries would result? c. Now suppose that the demand for strawberries falls by 10 units at every price. Draw the new demand curve in the figure, and estimate what the new equilibrium price and equilibrium quantity would be. d. If sellers still try to sell strawberries at $4, would the shortage or the surplus increase or decrease?
USING THE NUMBERS 17. According to By the Numbers, about how many times larger is the bottled water market in the United States in the year 2014 compared to 1984? 18. According to By the Numbers, in which 6-month period between July 2012 and January 2015 did Uber experience the greatest increase in terms of number of drivers? Would you describe the growth of Uber drivers over this 2.5-year period as linear (constant growth) or exponential (rising growth)?
ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS Checkpoint: Markets The market for financial securities is a huge, well-organized, and regulated market compared to local farmer’s markets. Trillions of dollars change hands each week in the financial markets, and products are standardized. Checkpoint: Demand The ability to avoid high gasoline prices, a general rise in environmental consciousness, incentives such as preferred parking and reduced tolls offered by some states, an increase in the availability of charging stations (reducing opportunity cost), and improvements in quality have all led to an increase in demand for plug-in electric cars. These factors led to a change in demand, because factors other than the price of the car itself have led to an increase in demand for these cars. However, as the costs of production eventually fall, prices will decrease, which will result in an increase in quantity demanded.
179
Checkpoint: Supply A higher textbook buyback price would entice more students to sell their textbooks instead of keeping them. Because the price of the offer has increased, it results in an increase in the quantity supplied of used textbooks. If, however, many students are forced to retake a class, they would likely not sell their textbooks; hence, the supply of used textbooks would shift to the left. Checkpoint: Market Equilibrium Waiting in line for a new product or a good deal adds to the cost of acquiring a good. For those with higher opportunity costs of time, hiring a professional line waiter reduces this cost, making the product more affordable. Therefore, professional line waiters would cause an increase in demand for goods and services more prone to lines, causing even greater lines and shortages if prices do not adjust upward. 1
There are some exceptions to positively sloping supply curves. But for our purposes, we will ignore them for now.
180
4
Markets and Government
181
Analyzing the conditions that determine when markets are efficient and when 182
markets might fail
Learning Objectives 4.1
Define the concepts of consumer surplus and producer surplus, and explain how they are used to measure the benefits and costs of market transactions.
4.2
Use consumer surplus and producer surplus to describe the gains from trade.
4.3
Explain the causes of deadweight loss and how markets can mitigate them.
4.4
Understand why markets sometimes fail to provide an optimal outcome.
4.5
Describe what an effective price ceiling or price floor does to a market and how it creates shortages or surpluses.
4.6
Identify the winners and losers when price ceilings and price floors are implemented.
O
nce an exotic food from the Orient eaten by few outside Asia, sushi has become part of the U.S. diet in all parts of the country, available in sushi bars, cafés, buffets, and even grocery stores. The popularity of sushi stems largely from the known health benefits of eating fish, providing omega-3-rich, low-fat, and low-
calorie meals. But to have sushi, one must have access to fresh fish, not easy for those not living near a coastline. Or is it? To provide fresh sushi to inland consumers, fish must be caught, flash frozen (to kill bacteria), then flown to destinations in a short period of time in order to maintain the fish’s freshness. In some cases, fish is flown around the world to meet the demand. At the Tsukiji fish market in Tokyo, Japan, the largest fish market in the world, over 5 million pounds of fish are auctioned off each morning and then flown to wholesalers and restaurants around the globe. Why would fishermen, fish markets, wholesalers, and restaurants go through so much trouble just to provide fresh sushi to customers in faraway places whom they will never meet? Because the market provides incentives for each person to do so. Every person in the supply chain for sushi acts in his or her own best interest by supplying what the market wants (as determined by the prices received for their goods), and that leads to an efficiently functioning market. Adam Smith’s notion of the invisible hand works to ensure that, in a market society, consumers get what they want. Everywhere we look in the world there are markets, and not just the big markets for fish or other major industries. Countless smaller markets dot our local landscapes, and many new virtual markets are springing up on the Internet. All play a similar role in terms of providing what consumers want, using prices as a way to signal the values placed on goods and services. Hamachi, Unagi, Ikura, Maguro, Toro. . . . Fish from an ocean halfway around the world to a dinner plate in a
183
rural inland town highlights the ability of efficient markets to provide what consumers want.
184
The previous chapter considered how supply and demand work together to determine the quantities of various
185
products sold and the equilibrium prices consumers must pay for them in a market economy. The markets we have studied thus far have been stylized versions of competitive markets: They have featured many buyers and sellers, a uniform product, consumers and sellers who have complete information about the market, and few barriers to market entry or exit. In this chapter, we start with this stylized competitive market and introduce tools for measuring the efficiency of competitive markets. We then apply these tools to reveal the gains from trade. We briefly consider some of the complexities inherent to most markets. The typical market does not meet all the criteria of a truly competitive market. That does not mean that the supply and demand analysis you just absorbed will not be useful in analyzing economic events. Often, however, you will need to temper your analysis to fit the specific conditions of the markets you study. Finally, we will look at what happens when government intervenes in markets.
186
CONSUMER AND PRODUCER SURPLUS: A TOOL FOR MEASURING ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY Suppose you find a rare comic book on eBay that you believe is worth $100, and start putting in bids hoping to buy it. After a week, you get the comic book with the winning bid of $80. You are happy because not only will you get the comic book you’ve been looking for, but you have also paid a price lower than what you were willing to pay. However, you’re likely not the only one who is happy. The person who sold you that comic book found it in her granddad’s old trunk that she inherited, and had hoped to get at least $60 for it. In fact, she ended up receiving more money than the minimum amount she had hoped to receive. In this situation, the transaction took place, and both the buyer and seller are better off. When consumers go about their everyday shopping or when they seek out their next major purchase, their objective typically is to find the lowest price relative to the perceived value of the product. It is the reason why consumers compare prices, shop online, or bargain with sellers. In other words, the general goal of consumers is to find the product at a price no greater than their willingness-to-pay (perceived value); if the price is less, consumers benefit more. These “savings,” so to speak, are referred to as consumer surplus, and are a measure of the net benefits consumers receive in the market. consumer surplus The difference between what consumers (as individuals or the market) would be willing to pay and the market price. It is equal to the area above market price and below the demand curve.
Producers also have a corresponding objective. When an entrepreneur opens up a new business, her intention is to maximize its success by getting the highest price for a product relative to its cost for as large a quantity as possible. Sometimes this is achieved by selling fewer units at a higher markup (such as rare art), while other times it is achieved through the sale of mass quantities of products at relatively small markups (such as goods sold at Walmart). Regardless of the strategy used, the general goal of producers is to obtain a price at least equal to their willingness-tosell; if the price is higher, producers benefit more. These gains are called producer surplus, and are a measure of the net benefits producers receive in the market. producer surplus The difference between the market price and the price at which firms are willing to supply the product. It is equal to the area below market price and above the supply curve.
Now that you have an intuitive sense of what consumer surplus and producer surplus are, let’s look more carefully into how they are measured. We begin with a single case of a buyer and a seller at a car dealership. Suppose you are the buyer, and you find a car that interests you. Let’s assume that the most you would be willing to pay for that car is $20,000. In other words, you find the car to be worth $20,000, but paying that price would be the worstcase scenario other than not buying the car at all. You would rather get a better deal by negotiating with the sales manager. But now let’s look at the other side: Assume that the sales manager has a minimum price of $15,000 at which he is willing to sell the car. Selling the car at this price would be his worst-case scenario other than not selling the car. FIGURE 1
WILLINGNESS-TO-PAY AND WILLINGNESS-TO-SELL
187
In a transaction with a single buyer and a single seller, consumer surplus ($2,800) is the difference between the maximum amount the buyer was willing to pay ($20,000) and the actual price paid ($17,200). Producer surplus ($2,200) is the difference between the actual price received ($17,200) and the minimum amount the seller was willing to accept ($15,000).
We have now determined a potential “gain” of $5,000 that can be shared by the buyer and seller depending on the final negotiated price for this car. Figure 1 shows this gain as the difference between the buyer’s willingness-to-pay (WTP) and the seller’s willingness-to-sell (WTS). Assume that the final negotiated price of the car is $17,200. We can now use this information to calculate consumer surplus (WTP − P = $20,000 − $17,200 = $2,800) and producer surplus (P − WTS = $17,200 − $15,000 = $2,200). This example is unique in that the price of the car is negotiated between the buyer and seller. In most of our daily transactions, however, the prices of goods and services are not negotiated. When you go to the grocery store, all of the prices are fixed. You don’t negotiate over the price of milk, bread, or chicken. Nonetheless, the measurements of consumer surplus and producer surplus remain the same when prices are fixed. Suppose that instead of just one buyer and one seller, the market contains dozens or even thousands of buyers and sellers. What would change? Let’s look at the market for Frisbees used in the popular intramural sport of Ultimate. First, each of the many buyers would have a different WTP, which would be represented as a downward-sloping demand curve (by definition, demand is just a collection of WTPs of all consumers in a market). Second, each of the many sellers would have a different WTS, which would be represented as an upward-sloping supply curve. But the definition of consumer surplus (WTP − P) and producer surplus (P − WTS) remains the same, except that now we apply it to the entire market. Figure 2 illustrates how consumer and producer surplus is determined in a small market for Frisbees with specific consumers and firms and for the overall market. Panel A in Figure 2 represents a small market with 6 individual buyers and 6 individual sellers, with an equilibrium price of $6 (from equilibrium point e) at which 6 units of output are sold. In this market, Alanna has the highest willingness to pay, because she values a Frisbee to be worth $11. Because the market determines that $6 is the price everyone pays, Alanna clearly gets a bargain by purchasing the unit and receiving a consumer surplus equal to $5 ($11 − $6). Ben, however, values a Frisbee a little less at $10, but still receives a consumer surplus of $4 ($10 − $6). And so on for Christine, David, and Erika, who receive a consumer surplus of $3, $2, and $1, respectively. Only Francis, who values a Frisbee to be worth exactly the same amount as the market price, earns no consumer surplus.
188
Total consumer surplus for the 6 consumers in panel A is found by adding all of the individual consumer surpluses for each unit purchased. Thus, total consumer surplus in panel A is equal to $5 + $4 + $3 + $2 + $1 + $0 = $15. FIGURE 2
CONSUMER AND PRODUCER SURPLUS
Panel B shows a market consisting of many more of the specific consumers and firms shown in panel A. This market determines equilibrium price to be $6 (point e), and total sales for the market are 6,000 units. Consumer surplus is equal to the area under the demand curve but above the equilibrium price of $6. Producer surplus is the area under the equilibrium price but above the supply curve.
In a similar way, assume that each point on the supply curve represents a specific seller, each with a Frisbee to sell but each with a different willingness to sell. Equilibrium price is still $6; therefore, Zoe, who is willing to sell her Frisbee for just $2.67, receives a producer surplus of $3.33 ($6 − $2.67). Yvonne, Xerxes, Wanda, and Victor, who each have a higher willingness-to-sell, receive a correspondingly smaller producer surplus equal to $2.67, $2.00, $1.33, and $0.67, respectively. And Umberto, who had a willingness-to-sell of $6, receives no producer surplus for his sale. Total producer surplus in panel A is equal to $3.33 + $2.67 + $2.00 + $1.33 + $0.67 + $0 = $10. Panel B illustrates consumer and producer surplus for an entire market. For convenience, we have assumed that the market is 1,000 times larger than that shown in panel A, so the x axis is output in thousands. Whereas in panel A we had discrete buyers and sellers, we now have one big market; therefore, consumer surplus is equal to the area under the demand curve and above equilibrium price, or the area of the shaded triangle labeled “consumer surplus.” To put a number to the consumer surplus triangle (feh) in panel B, we can compute the area of the triangle using the formula 1/2(base × height). Thus, total market consumer surplus in panel B is [1/2 × (6,000) × ($12 − $6)] = $18,000. The shaded triangle labeled “producer surplus” (area hei) is found in the same way by computing the value of the triangle. Producer surplus is equal to [1/2 × (6,000) × ($6 − $2)] = $12,000. Although we simplify the calculation of consumer and producer surplus using the area of the triangle, remember that it is still the sum of many individual consumer and producer surpluses. It is merely because of the fact that markets have thousands of buyers and sellers that the steps in panel A of Figure 2 become very small, thus resulting in smooth demand and supply curves in panel B. We have now defined consumer surplus and producer surplus for individuals and for markets. But how do we know whether the market leads to an ideal outcome for consumers and producers? The next section goes on to reveal the efficiency of markets.
189
CHECKPOINT CONSUMER AND PRODUCER SURPLUS: A TOOL FOR MEASURING ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY Consumers and producers attempt to maximize their well-being by achieving the greatest gains in their market transactions. Consumer surplus occurs when consumers would have been willing to pay more for a good or service than the actual price paid. It represents a form of savings to consumers. Producer surplus occurs when businesses would have been willing to provide a good or service at prices lower than the market price. It represents a form of earnings to producers.
QUESTION: At the end of the semester, four college students list their economics textbooks for sale on
the bulletin board in the student union. The minimum price Alex is willing to accept is $20, Caroline wants at least $25, Kira wants at least $30, and Will wants at least $35. Now assume that four college students taking an economics class next semester are searching for a deal on the textbook. Cole wishes to pay no more than $50, Jacqueline no more than $55, Sienna no more than $60, and Tessa no more than $65. Suppose that the actual sales price for each of the four textbooks is $40. What is the total consumer surplus received by the four buyers and the total producer surplus received by the four sellers? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of the chapter.
190
USING CONSUMER AND PRODUCER SURPLUS: THE GAINS FROM TRADE Markets are efficient when they generate the largest possible amount of net benefits to all parties involved. When transactions between a buyer and a seller take place, each party is better off than before the transaction, leading to gains from trade. We had previously looked at gains from trade in an earlier chapter from the perspectives of individuals, firms, and countries specializing in activities and engaging in mutually beneficial transactions. This is no different than our present market examples, in which buyers and sellers mutually gain from transacting with one another. At the equilibrium price, shortages and surpluses are nonexistent, and all consumers wanting to buy a good at that price are able to find a seller willing to sell at that price. The market efficiency that results maximizes the sum of consumer surplus and producer surplus, referred to as total surplus. Total surplus is a measure of the total net benefits a society achieves when both consumers and producers are valued components of an economy. To see why markets are efficient at equilibrium, we need to analyze what happens to total surplus when markets deviate from equilibrium. total surplus The sum of consumer surplus and producer surplus, and a measure of the overall net benefit gained from a market transaction.
The Consequences of Deviating From Market Equilibrium
The market mechanism ensures that goods and services get to where they are most needed, because consumers desiring them bid up the price, while suppliers eager to make money supply them. Adam Smith termed this process the invisible hand to describe how resources are allocated efficiently through individual decisions made in markets. But not all markets end up in equilibrium, especially if buyers or sellers hold inadequate information about products, or if buyers or sellers hold unrealistic or inaccurate expectations about market prices and behavior. Let’s examine two scenarios in the market for treadmills in which prices deviate from the equilibrium price.
When Prices Exceed Equilibrium
Figure 3 illustrates a market for treadmills with an equilibrium price of $300. Suppose that due to unrealistic expectations of demand, prices for treadmills are set at $400, above the equilibrium price. We know from the previous chapter that a price above equilibrium leads to excess supply, because consumers only demand 10,000 units while producers desire to sell 30,000. Our tools of consumer surplus and producer surplus allow us to evaluate the effects on buyers and sellers in this market. FIGURE 3
CONSUMER AND PRODUCER SURPLUS WHEN PRICES EXCEED EQUILIBRIUM
191
Compared to the equilibrium price, a price of $400 would prevent some consumers from purchasing the product. A loss of consumer surplus equal to the blue area occurs. Further, consumers who still purchase the product pay $100 more than the equilibrium price, causing an additional loss of consumer surplus equal to the pink area. Producers, meanwhile, lose producer surplus equal to the yellow area resulting from the units that consumers no longer buy, but earn additional producer surplus equal to the pink area as a result of the higher price. Total lost surplus, called deadweight loss, is represented by the blue and yellow areas (no one gets this because some trades are not made now). The pink area is surplus transferred from consumers to producers because of the higher price.
When prices are above equilibrium, consumer surplus shrinks due to two effects. First, a price of $400 causes some consumers to not make a purchase, because these consumers were only willing to pay between $300 and $400. The area shown in blue represents the lost consumer surplus from these forgone purchases. Second, the consumers who still are willing and able to purchase a unit pay $100 more, which represents a loss in consumer surplus equal to the pink area. In sum, the pink and blue regions represent the total reduction in consumer surplus from the higher price. Producers, on the other hand, will likely benefit from the higher price but face two opposing effects. First, the fact that the higher price causes some consumers to not purchase a unit causes a loss in producer surplus equal to the yellow area. However, this is offset by the additional money earned from the consumers who buy the unit at the higher price, which is represented by the pink area. Therefore, the pink area represents a transfer of surplus from consumers to producers. The blue and yellow areas represent deadweight loss, the loss of consumer surplus and producer surplus caused by the inefficiency of a market not operating at equilibrium. Nobody gets the blue and yellow areas. Deadweight loss represents a loss in total surplus, because both buyers and sellers would have benefited from these transactions. deadweight loss The reduction in total surplus that results from the inefficiency of a market not in equilibrium.
192
When Prices Fall Below Equilibrium
When prices are below equilibrium, the opposite effects happen as a result of a shortage. Figure 4 shows the market for treadmills in which the price of $200 is below the equilibrium price. At that price, sellers provide 10,000 units for sale, while buyers demand 30,000 units, causing a shortage. At a price of $200, producers are clearly worse off. Some producers are unable to sell at that low price, causing a loss of producer surplus equal to the yellow area, while those who still sell the product earn $100 less per unit, resulting in a loss of producer surplus equal to the pink area. At first, you might believe consumers are better off with the lower price, and some in fact are. But these gains, shown by the pink area, are limited to consumers lucky enough to purchase the good. The rest of the consumers who are affected by the shortage are worse off, because consumer surplus equal to the blue area is lost because of trades never made. In sum, deadweight loss equal to the blue and yellow areas results. FIGURE 4
CONSUMER AND PRODUCER SURPLUS WHEN PRICES ARE BELOW EQUILIBRIUM
Compared to the equilibrium price, a price of $200 causes some producers to not sell the product. A loss of producer surplus equal to the yellow area occurs. Further, producers who still sell the product earn $100 less than before, causing an additional loss of producer surplus equal to the pink area. Consumers, meanwhile, lose consumer surplus equal to the blue area resulting from the shortage of units, but receive additional consumer surplus equal to the pink area as a result of the lower price for those lucky enough to find units for sale. Once again, deadweight loss is the blue and yellow areas, and the pink area is surplus transferred.
The two scenarios shown in Figures 3 and 4 demonstrate that whenever prices deviate from equilibrium, total surplus as measured by the sum of consumer surplus and producer surplus falls, resulting in a deadweight loss from mutually beneficial transactions between buyers and sellers not taking place. But why would markets not achieve
193
equilibrium? Sometimes a market will fail to achieve equilibrium because it is prevented from doing so on its own.
PAUL A. SAMUELSON (1915–2009)
NOBEL PRIZE I
n 1970 Paul Samuelson became the first American to win the Nobel Prize in Economics. One could say that Paul Samuelson literally wrote the book on economics. In 1948, when he was a young professor at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, the university asked him to write a text for the junior-year course in economics. Seventy years later, more than 4 million copies of his textbook Economics have been sold. Samuelson’s interests were wide ranging, and his contributions include everything from the highly technical and mathematical to a popular column for Newsweek magazine. He made breakthrough contributions to virtually all areas of economics. Born in Gary, Indiana, in 1915, Samuelson attended the University of Chicago. He received the university’s Social Science Medal and was awarded a graduate fellowship, which he used at Harvard, where he published eleven papers while in the graduate program. He wanted to remain at Harvard, but was only offered an instructor’s position. However, MIT soon made a better offer and, as he describes it, “On a fine October day in 1940 an enfant terrible emeritus packed up his pencil and moved three miles down the Charles River, where he lived happily ever after.” He often remarked that a pencil was all he needed to theorize. Seven years later, he published his Ph.D. dissertation Foundations of Economic Analysis, a major contribution to the area of mathematical economics. Harvard made several attempts to lure him back, but he spent his entire career at MIT and is often credited with developing a department as good as or better than Harvard’s. Samuelson was an informal adviser to President John F. Kennedy. A prolific writer, his Collected Works takes up five volumes and includes more than 350 articles. He was an active economist until his death in 2009 at the age of 94. As you read through this book, keep in mind that in virtually every chapter, Paul Samuelson created or added to the analysis in substantial ways. Information from David Warsh, Knowledge and the Wealth of Nations: A Story of Economic Discovery (New York: Norton), 2006; Paul Samuelson, “Economics in My Time,” in William Breit and Roger Spencer, Lives of the Laureates: Seven Nobel Economists (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press), 1986.
Market Failure
Markets are inherently efficient mechanisms for allocating resources because of the incentives that drive consumers and firms to act in their own best interests. But like all things, exceptions occur when circumstances prevent the market from achieving the socially desirable outcome. When freely functioning markets fail to provide an optimal amount of goods and services, a market failure occurs. market failure Occurs when a free market does not lead to a socially desirable outcome.
There are four major reasons why markets fail: a lack of competition, a mismatch of information, external benefits or costs, and the existence of public goods. Each causes total surplus to fall, and deadweight loss to appear.
Lack of Competition 194
When a market has many buyers and sellers, no one seller has the ability to raise its price above that of its competitors. But when a market lacks competition, a firm can raise its price in the market without worrying that other firms will undercut its price. For example, in most communities the local water provider is a firm that lacks competition. This can lead to inefficient production and higher prices unless the market failure is corrected using government regulation.
Information Is Not Shared by All Parties
An important condition for efficient markets is that buyers and sellers must possess adequate information about products. Sometimes, one party knows more about a product than the other, a situation known as asymmetric information. For example, a seller of a used car knows more about the true condition of the car than a potential buyer. Conversely, an art or antiques buyer may know more about the value of items than the seller at an estate sale. In these cases, a mismatch of information may lead to prices being set too high or too low. asymmetric information Occurs when one party to a transaction has significantly better information than another party.
Singapore: Resolving Traffic Jams and Reducing Pollution Using Price Controls How did Singapore use economic tools to intervene in the market to improve traffic flow and to correct a potential market failure?
H
ow much time is spent waiting in gridlock traffic in major cities? According to a study by the transportation analytics firm INRIX, in 2015, American drivers spent 8 billion hours stuck in traffic. Traffic creates an opportunity cost that leads to reduced productivity. Moreover, traffic jams reduce fuel efficiency and generate more air pollution. Is there an economic solution to these problems? Singapore may have the answer. Singapore uses an electronic road-pricing system that charges drivers a toll on dozens of its major roads and highways. Unlike traditional toll roads, Singapore’s road charges vary throughout the day. During times when roads are less subject to congestion, the fee is very minimal or even zero, while during times of the day when roads are likely to be congested, the fee is higher. As it becomes more expensive to drive during certain periods of the day, drivers are incentivized to drive less, to drive during off-peak times, or to find alternative means of transportation. The outcome is a road system that is less prone to congestion, reducing an inefficiency.
195
Singapore is not the only city that uses congestion charges. It costs approximately $15 to drive in Central London between the hours of 7 A.M. and 6 P.M. Even in the United States, the introduction of express lanes in Los Angeles, Atlanta, Miami, and other cities has allowed motorists to pay a toll to bypass traffic. Similar to Singapore, these tolls vary throughout the day, with prices rising as roads become more congested. Not only do congestion charges incentivize people to drive less; they also encourage companies to change the way they operate. Companies that do not need to operate during traditional business hours might encourage their employees to arrive at work later and return home later, avoiding times when congestion charges are at their peak. By reducing traffic congestion, less time is wasted, productivity rises, and pollution is reduced. Furthermore, the fees collected are a valuable source of government revenue. Many economists believe that market-based pricing mechanisms such as congestion charges can lead to increased efficiency and equity.
GO TO
TO PRACTICE THE ECONOMIC CONCEPTS IN THIS STORY
The Existence of External Benefits or Costs
When you drive your car on a crowded highway, you inflict external costs on other drivers by adding to congestion. When you receive a flu shot, you confer external benefits on the rest of us by reducing the chances of spreading an illness. Markets rarely produce the socially optimal output when external costs or benefits are present. When deciding whether to drive or obtain a flu shot, you tend not to think of the costs and benefits you impose on others. As a result, more people drive and fewer people receive flu shots than would be ideal to achieve the socially optimal outcome.
The Existence of Public Goods
Most goods we buy are private goods, such as meals and concert tickets; once we buy them, no one else can benefit from them. Public goods, however, are goods that one person can consume without diminishing what is left for others. Public television, for example, is a public good that illustrates nonrivalry (my watching of PBS does not mean there is less PBS for you to watch) and nonexclusivity (once a good is provided, others cannot be excluded from enjoying it). Because of these characteristics, public goods are difficult to provide in the private market.
Market Efficiency Versus Equity Reducing the effects of market failure is an important goal of government, which can enact policies to address markets in which private transactions do not lead to the optimal outcome. But the role of government extends beyond that of achieving social efficiency. It is also tasked with the goal of achieving equity in markets. For example, is it fair when teachers or firefighters who earn modest salaries are unable to afford market rents for apartments, or when a single parent working full time is unable to earn enough to avoid poverty? If a policy creates considerable unfairness, while spurring only a small gain in efficiency, some other policy might be better. One tool used by government to balance efficiency with equity is price controls, which we turn to next.
196
CHECKPOINT USING CONSUMER AND PRODUCER SURPLUS: THE GAINS FROM TRADE The sum of consumer surplus and producer surplus is total surplus, a measure of the overall net benefit for an economy. Markets are efficient when all buyers and all sellers willing to buy and sell at the market price are able to do so. When buyers and sellers engage in a market transaction, gains from trade are created from consumer surplus and producer surplus. Total surplus is maximized at a market equilibrium. Deadweight loss is created when markets deviate from equilibrium. Markets are typically efficient, although sometimes they can fail by not providing the socially optimal amount of goods and services. Market failure is caused by a lack of competition, mismatched information, external costs and external benefits, or the existence of public goods.
QUESTION: Waiting for an organ transplant is an ordeal for patients. Some wait years for a compatible donor organ to become available. Some economists have suggested that offering monetary compensation to organ donors would increase the supply of available organs. Would such a system lead to gains from trade? Why are such incentives difficult to implement? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
197
PRICE CEILINGS AND PRICE FLOORS To this point, we have assumed that competitive markets are allowed to operate freely, without any government intervention. Economists refer to freely functioning markets as laissez-faire, a French term meaning “let it be.” The justification for this type of economic policy is that when competitive markets are left to determine equilibrium price and output, they clear. This means that businesses provide consumers with the quantity of goods they want to purchase at the established prices; there are no shortages or surpluses. Consumer and producer surplus together, or total surplus, is maximized. laissez-faire A market that is allowed to function without any government intervention.
However, as we saw at the end of the previous section, sometimes freely functioning markets fail to achieve the optimal quantity of goods and services. An example of this is when many people consider the equilibrium price to be unfair. Because of these economic (efficiency) or political (equity) reasons, governments will sometimes intervene in the market by setting limits on the prices of various goods and services. Governments use price ceilings and price floors to keep prices below or above market equilibrium. What really happens when government sets prices below or above market equilibrium? The previous section hinted at the answer. Let’s look at price ceilings and floors more closely.
Price Ceilings
When the government sets a price ceiling, it is legally mandating the maximum price that can be charged for a product or service. This is a legal maximum; regardless of market forces, price cannot exceed this level. An historical example of a price ceiling is the establishment of rent-controlled apartments in New York City during World War II, some of which still exist today. However, more common examples of price ceilings include limits on what insurance companies can charge customers, price caps on telecommunications and electric services to customers in rural or remote locations, and limits on tuition hikes at public universities. price ceiling A maximum price established by government for a product or service. When the price ceiling is set below equilibrium, a shortage results.
Panel A in Figure 5 shows an effective price ceiling, or one in which the ceiling price is set below the equilibrium price. In this case, equilibrium price is Pe, but the government has set a price ceiling at Pc. Quantity supplied at the ceiling price is Q1, whereas consumers want Q2; therefore, the result is a shortage of Q2 − Q1 units of the product. As we saw in the previous section, setting a price below equilibrium alters consumer and producer surplus and results in a deadweight loss indicated by the shaded area. If the price ceiling is raised toward equilibrium, the shortage is reduced along with the deadweight loss. If the price ceiling is set above Pe (as shown in panel B), the market simply settles at Pe, and the price ceiling has no impact; it is nonbinding, and no deadweight loss occurs. A price ceiling can also become nonbinding if market factors cause supply to increase or demand to fall, pushing the equilibrium price below the ceiling. FIGURE 5
A PRICE CEILING BELOW EQUILIBRIUM CREATES SHORTAGES
198
When the government enacts a price ceiling below equilibrium (panel A), consumers will demand Q2 and businesses will supply only Q1, creating a shortage equal to Q2−Q1, and causing deadweight loss equal to the shaded area. If the price ceiling is set above equilibrium (panel B), the price ceiling has no effect, and the market price and quantity prevail with no deadweight loss created.
A common mistake when analyzing the effect of price ceilings is assuming that effective price ceilings appear above the market equilibrium, because the word “ceiling” refers to something above you. Instead, think of ceilings as something that keep you from moving higher. Suppose you build a makeshift skateboarding ramp in your apartment hallway, and tempt your friends to test it out. If the ceiling is too low, some of your friends might end up with a severe headache. In other words, an effective (binding) ceiling is one that is kept lower than normal. If the ceiling can be raised by 5 feet, then all of your friends would achieve their jumps without bumping their heads. In sum, price ceilings have their strongest effects when kept very low; as the ceiling is raised, the effect of the policy diminishes, and the ceiling becomes nonbinding once the equilibrium price is reached. Given the price ceiling, one might argue that although shortages might exist, at least prices will be kept lower and therefore more “fair.” The question is, fairer to whom? Suppose your university places a new price ceiling on the rents of all existing apartments located on campus, one that is below the rents of similar apartments off campus. This might sound like a great idea, but often what sounds like a great idea comes with costs. A price ceiling increases the quantity demanded for on-campus apartments, and without an increase in supply, a shortage results. Those lucky enough to obtain an on-campus apartment benefit from the lower rents. But what about those who couldn’t? Because some students who really could have benefited from lower rents (those with lower incomes or without cars) cannot find an on-campus apartment, while other students who could have easily afforded a higher-priced off-campus apartment managed to snatch one up, a misallocation of resources is created. Further, when on-campus apartments do open up, students eager to obtain one might spend a lot of time and resources trying. These resources (an opportunity cost) end up offsetting some or all of the savings from finding an on-campus apartment. misallocation of resources Occurs when a good or service is not consumed by the person who values it the most, and typically results when a price ceiling creates an artificial shortage in the market.
199
The ability to jump on one’s bed depends on the height of the ceiling. The lower the ceiling, the more it restricts this fun activity. Similarly, price ceilings below equilibrium (rather than above equilibrium) restrict the market and lead to shortages.
Besides the misallocation of resources and potential opportunity costs of long waits and search costs, price ceilings also lead to some unintended long-term consequences. For example, if a landlord owns some apartments on campus (where rents are controlled) and some apartments off campus (where rents are higher), on which apartments is she likely to spend more money for upgrades and/or maintenance? The quality of goods and services subjected to price ceilings tends to deteriorate over time, as the incentives shift toward products with higher prices. Further, when it comes time to invest in new apartments, where do you think they are likely to be built—on campus or off? The key point to remember here is that price ceilings are intended to keep the price of a product below its market or equilibrium level. When this happens, consumer surplus increases for those able to purchase the good, while producer surplus falls. The ultimate effect of a price ceiling, however, is that the quantity of the product demanded exceeds the quantity supplied, thereby producing a shortage of the product in the market. When shortages occur, deadweight losses are created because some mutually beneficial transactions do not take place, causing a reduction in total surplus.
Price Floors A price floor is a government-mandated minimum price that can be charged for a product or service. Regardless of market forces, product price cannot legally fall below this level. price floor A minimum price established by government for a product or service. When the price floor is set above equilibrium, a surplus results.
200
Figure 6 shows the economic impact of a price floor. In panel A, the price floor, Pf, is set above equilibrium, Pe, resulting in a surplus of Q2 − Q1 units. At price Pf, businesses want to supply more of the product (Q2) than consumers are willing to buy (Q1), thus generating a surplus. Depending on the government policy in place with the price floor, producers may end up having to store the excess supply if only Q1 is transacted in the market, or in some cases the government may buy the surplus goods. Either way, inefficiency is created in the market. However, if the price floor is set below equilibrium (as shown in panel B), the equilibrium price, Pe, will prevail in the market. Therefore, a price floor set below Pe has no impact on the market and no deadweight loss occurs. Likewise, a price floor can become nonbinding if market factors push the equilibrium price above the price floor. Throughout much of the past century, the U.S. government has used agricultural price supports (price floors) in order to smooth out the income of farmers, which often fluctuates due to wide annual variations in crop prices. This approach is not limited to the United States. Many developed countries, including members of the European Union and Japan, have long protected their agriculture industries by ensuring a minimum price level for many types of crops. FIGURE 6
A PRICE FLOOR ABOVE EQUILIBRIUM CREATES SURPLUSES
When the government sets a price floor above equilibrium (panel A), businesses try to sell Q2 at a price of Pf, but consumers are willing to purchase only Q1 at that price. This results in a surplus equal to Q2 − Q1, causing either producers to store the excess supply or the government to buy the surplus units.
ISSUE Are Price Gouging Laws Good for Consumers? During the summer hurricane season, residents along the Atlantic and Gulf Coasts brace for
201
hurricanes that can wreak havoc on the unprepared. The routine is well known: Buy plywood and shutters to protect windows; fill up gas tanks in cars and buy extra gas for generators; and stock up on batteries, bottled water, and nonperishable foods. Because of the huge spike in demand, numerous states have introduced price gouging laws, which prevent stores from raising prices above the average price of the past 30 days. Penalties for violating such laws are severe. Price gouging laws generally pass with huge majority votes from both major political parties. The logic seems clear—to prevent businesses from exploiting a bad situation to their benefit by raising prices. Passing such laws always appears to be a victory for the consumer. But is it really? Price gouging laws are price ceilings placed at the price last existing when times were normal. But during a natural disaster, the market is far from normal—demand is higher, and supplies are often restricted due to plant closures. The figure shows what happens when these two effects come together—the market price spikes upward. But price gouging laws require that prices remain at the original level, resulting in a shortage when demand increases to D1 and supply falls to S1.
The inside of a jumbo jet cargo plane can carry a tremendous amount of supplies to address supply shortages, as long as an incentive exists to use that plane for this purpose. What happens during a shortage? Huge lines form at home improvement stores, gas stations, and grocery stores. Time spent waiting in line is time that could be spent completing other tasks in preparation for the storm. What might be a better solution?
Instead of capping prices and causing a shortage, efforts can be made to provide incentives to businesses to generate more supply. If supply shifts enough to the right to compensate for the increase in demand, then prices need not increase, regardless of the price ceiling. But the question is, How do we incentivize supply? Subsidies to offset increased transportation costs might be an
202
example. Imagine how many supplies could be flown in on a single jumbo jet cargo plane from a non–hurricane-prone area. Quite a bit, but firms aren’t willing to spend that money. If the incentive is provided, supply will increase, reducing shortages and costs to everyone.
These price supports act very much as they are intended. By ensuring a minimum price for a crop, farmers have an incentive to grow more of these crops relative to crops that aren’t protected by price supports. Further, because the price supports typically are above market equilibrium prices, resulting in higher prices for consumers, demand for such crops is less than what it would be without the supports. Thus, with greater supply and smaller demand, price supports lead to surpluses of crops. What happens to these surpluses? Because the government guarantees the price levels of the crops, it must purchase the excess supply, which is typically stored for use in the event of future shortages. But agricultural surpluses eventually rot, which means government must find other ways to use the surplus before it goes bad. One common use of surplus foods is in public school lunches, leading to some criticism that the types of foods being provided (wheat, grains, and corn) are not the most nutritious foods for children to eat. Surplus foods resulting from government price floors are often given to public schools to be used in school lunches.
Another criticism of agricultural price supports comes from developing countries that depend on agricultural exports for their economic output. These countries claim that price supports hamper their economic development by preventing them from selling goods in which they have a comparative advantage. In other words, agricultural price supports restrict gains from trade. Despite their questionable economic justification, political pressures have ensured that agricultural price supports and related programs still command a sizable amount of the discretionary domestic federal budget. Price floors are also used to analyze minimum wage policy. To the extent that the minimum wage is set above the equilibrium wage, unemployment—a surplus of labor—may result if jobs go uncreated when employers are forced to pay the higher minimum wage. However, the minimum wage offers a potential positive effect of reducing income inequality by raising earnings among low-wage workers. This effect is stronger if increasing the minimum wage subsequently leads to higher wages for workers who are already earning slightly more than the minimum wage. In sum, price ceilings and price floors often are policies aimed at promoting equity or fairness in a society, such as preventing rapid price increases for consumers or ensuring fair wages for workers. Still, governments must be
203
careful when setting price ceilings and price floors to avoid meddling with markets.
CHECKPOINT PRICE CEILINGS AND PRICE FLOORS Governments use price floors and price ceilings to intervene in markets. A price ceiling is a maximum legal price that can be charged for a product. Price ceilings set below equilibrium result in shortages. A price floor is the minimum legal price that can be charged for a product. Price floors set above market equilibrium result in surpluses.
QUESTION: The day after Thanksgiving, also known as Black Friday, is a day on which retailers advertise very steep discounts on selected items such as televisions or laptops. Assuming the number of units available at the discounted price is limited, in what ways are the effects of this pricing strategy similar to a price ceiling set by the government? In what ways do they differ? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of the chapter.
204
chapter summary Section 1 Consumer and Producer Surplus: A Tool for Measuring Economic Efficiency
Consumer surplus is the difference between a person’s willingness-to-pay and the price paid. For a market, consumer surplus is the area between the demand curve and the market price. In the figure, consumer surplus equals $1,250. Producer surplus is the difference between the price a seller receives and its willingness-to-sell. For a market, producer surplus is the area between the market price and the supply curve. In the figure, producer surplus equals $1,000.
4.1
Economic efficiency is measured by the gains that consumers and producers achieve when engaging in an economic transaction.
205
Section 2 Using Consumer and Producer Surplus: The Gains From Trade Markets exhibit efficiency when every buyer and every seller eager to buy or sell goods are able to do so, resulting in gains from trade. Gains from trade are measured by the total surplus, or the sum of consumer and producer surplus in a market. Total surplus is maximized when a market is at equilibrium.
4.2
Suppose the price of a good rises above equilibrium to $75. The higher price causes two effects on consumer surplus and two effects on producer surplus: 1. Consumers who are priced out of the market lose consumer surplus equal to the blue area. 2. Consumers who continue to buy the good pay more, and lose consumer surplus equal to the pink area. 3. Producers who want to sell more at $75, but cannot, lose producer surplus equal to the yellow area. 4. Producers who do sell units earn $25 more per unit, equal to the pink area.
206
4.3
Deadweight loss occurs when prices deviate from equilibrium. In the preceding example, deadweight loss is shown by the blue and yellow areas. Markets can sometimes fail to produce the socially optimal output. Reasons for market failure include:
4.4
Lack of competition When a firm faces little to no competition, it has an incentive to raise prices. Existence of external benefits or costs Markets tend to provide too little of products that have external benefits, and too much of products with external costs.
Planting trees creates external benefits.
207
Talking loudly on your phone creates external costs. A mismatch of information Asymmetric information occurs when either a buyer or a seller knows more about a product than the other. Existence of public goods Public goods are nonrival and nonexclusive. This means: My consumption does not diminish your ability to consume. Once a good is provided for one person, others cannot be excluded from enjoying it.
Ecological conservation is a public good. Once people devote time and resources to saving the environment, everybody benefits from it, even if one does not contribute to the costs of maintaining it.
Section 3 Price Ceilings and Price Floors A price floor is a minimum price for a good. A binding price floor appears above
208
4.5
equilibrium and causes a surplus. A price ceiling is a maximum price for a good. A binding price ceiling appears below equilibrium and causes a shortage.
4.6
A literal mountain of surplus corn caused by agricultural price floors.
KEY CONCEPTS consumer surplus producer surplus total surplus deadweight loss market failure asymmetric information laissez-faire
209
price ceiling misallocation of resources price floor
QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS Check Your Understanding 1. Describe how consumer surplus and producer surplus are measured. 2. Using the following graph, show what happens to consumer surplus when a new technology reduces the cost of production.
3. Explain why deadweight loss can occur with a price below equilibrium even when some consumers benefit from it. 4. Provide three examples of activities that generate external benefits and three activities that generate external costs. 5. Why does an effective price ceiling appear below the equilibrium rather than above it? 6. If a price floor is reduced toward equilibrium but not below it, explain what happens to the total surplus and deadweight loss in this market.
Apply the Concepts 7. An increasing number of charities have turned to online auctions as a way to raise money by selling unique experiences donated by celebrities (such as a meet-and-greet with a celebrity before a concert or a walk-on role on a television show). Why would the use of auctions lead to a better outcome for the charity as opposed to just setting a fixed price? Explain using the concepts of consumer surplus and producer surplus. 8. Luigi’s is the only pizzeria in a small town in northern Alaska. It is constantly busy, but there is never a wait for a table. One of Luigi’s friends suggests that he would earn much more money if he raises his menu prices
210
9.
10. 11.
12.
by 25%, because no one is likely to open a new pizzeria in the near future. If Luigi follows his friend’s advice, what would happen to consumer and producer surplus, and efficiency, in this market? Over the past decade, many American candy companies, including Hershey Company, Brach’s Confections, and Ferrara Pan Candy, opened factories in Mexico and Canada to produce candy that is then shipped back to the United States for sale. Although lower wages in Mexico might explain part of this move, wages in Canada are comparable to U.S. wages. Explain how U.S. price supports (price floors) for the sugar industry may have encouraged these moves. Academic studies suggest that the amount people tip in restaurants is only slightly related to the quality of service, and that tips are poor measures of how happy people are with the service. Is this another example of market failure? What might account for this situation? In cities around the country, the government provides assistance to families with low incomes to rent apartments at prices capped by the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD), essentially setting a price ceiling on apartments. These designated apartments tend to rent quickly, and tenants are less likely to move once they find an apartment. Explain how rent controls affect market prices for non-rentcontrolled apartments. How are incentives by landlords affected in terms of maintaining rent-controlled and non-rent-controlled apartments? Would your answer change if the government provided a subsidy payment to landlords to offset the difference between the price ceiling and the market price? The U.S. Department of Labor reports that of the roughly 150 million people employed, just over half are paid by the hour, but fewer than 5% earn the minimum wage or less; 95% of wage earners earn more. And of those earning the minimum wage or less, 25% are teenagers living at home. If so few people are affected by the minimum wage, why does it often seem to be such a contentious political issue?
In the News 13. Over the past few years, several U.S. states have either legalized recreational marijuana or at least decriminalized its use (“Would Legalizing Marijuana Help the Economy?,” Debate.org). Proponents argue that legalizing the use of marijuana would help the economy by boosting economic activity and reducing costs. Do you agree? Why or why not? Use the concepts of supply and demand, and consumer and producer surplus to support your answer. 14. In 2015 Governor Cuomo of New York approved a measure to raise the minimum wage for all fast-food workers to $15 per hour by 2018 (“New York Oks $15 Minimum Wage for Fast-Food Workers,” USA Today, September 11, 2015). Proponents argue that this policy helps the working poor who hold full-time jobs yet are not able to pull their families out of poverty. Meanwhile, opponents argue that the policy would cause harm in the labor market. Provide an example of a situation that would support each side’s argument.
Solving Problems 15. Consider the market shown in the following graph.
211
a. Compute the consumer surplus. b. Compute the producer surplus. Now assume that government puts a price floor on this product at $20 a unit. c. Compute the new consumer surplus. d. Compute the new producer surplus. e. Would consumers or producers be more likely to have their advocates or lobbyists support price floors? Explain.
WORK IT OUT 16. Suppose the U.S. government places a price ceiling on the sale of gasoline at $2 per gallon in the accompanying figure. a. How much of a shortage or surplus of gasoline would result? b. Calculate the effects of this policy in terms of the changes in consumer surplus and producer surplus. c. How much deadweight loss is created? d. What would happen if the price ceiling is raised to $5 per gallon?
212
USING THE NUMBERS 17. According to By the Numbers, how much would you earn in one year if you worked 2,000 hours (50 weeks × 40 hours) at the federal minimum wage? How much more would you earn per year if you worked at the minimum wage rate in Washington state? 18. According to By the Numbers, which state has the highest average in-state tuition in the country, and which state has the lowest average in-state tuition? How do universities deal with shortages when in-state tuition prices are below the equilibrium price?
ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS Checkpoint: Consumer and Producer Surplus: A Tool for Measuring Economic Efficiency Cole’s consumer surplus is ($50 − $40) = $10, Jacqueline’s is ($55 − $40) = $15, Sienna’s is ($60 − $40) = $20, and Tessa’s is ($65 − $40) = $25. Total consumer surplus is $10 + $15 + $20 + $25 = $70. Alex’s producer surplus is ($40 − $20) = $20, Caroline’s is ($40 − $25) = $15, Kira’s is ($40 − $30) = $10, and Will’s is ($40 − $35) = $5. Total producer surplus is $20 + $15 + $10 + $5 = $50. Checkpoint: Using Consumer and Producer Surplus: The Gains From Trade Although many people voluntarily become organ donors because of the goodwill they feel knowing that their actions can potentially save a life, still many others choose not to become organ donors because they do not see any monetary benefit from doing so. Compensating individuals for becoming organ donors, thereby raising the “price” of organs, would be a way to increase the supply of organs, allowing the shortage to dissipate until equilibrium is reached. In doing so, organ donors and recipients both benefit, resulting in gains from trade. However, moral objections to selling body parts have led to many laws preventing organ donors from being compensated. As a result, shortages continue to be a problem. Checkpoint: Price Ceilings and Price Floors Black Friday specials are typically deeply discounted in order to attract customers into the store, which is why such specials are prominently shown on the first page of sales circulars. Like a price ceiling that is set below the equilibrium price, the quantity demanded for the discounted good increases, while stores limit the number of units
213
available for sale, creating a shortage. Some buyers will be fortunate to find units available to purchase, while subsequent shoppers will find that the product has sold out. Deadweight loss is generated because some customers who would have been willing to pay a little more are unable to purchase the good. However, unlike with a price ceiling, stores strategically choose to advertise goods with many alternatives, such as different brands of televisions and laptops, so that when the discounted product sells out, customers may consider buying a nondiscounted product. Therefore, the pricing strategy leads to a strategic shortage that is designed to attract customers into the store to buy goods in addition to those that are advertised.
214
5
Introduction to Macroeconomics
215
Understanding how the economy is measured and why recessions periodically occur 216
over time
Learning Objectives 5.1
Describe the four phases of the business cycle and how they are dated by the NBER.
5.2
Describe other methods used to measure the business cycle.
5.3
Describe the national income and product accounts (NIPA).
5.4
Describe the circular flow of income and discuss why GDP can be computed using either income or expenditure data.
5.5
List the four major expenditure components of GDP.
5.6
List the major income components of GDP.
5.7
Describe the shortcomings of GDP as a measure of our standard of living.
5.8
Describe how nonmarket activities and the informal economy create both positive and negative effects on society.
F
rom 2009 to 2016, the U.S. economy created over 10 million new jobs, the unemployment rate fell from nearly 10% to below 5%, inflation remained at historic lows, the housing market soared in many cities, and cheap energy prices led to lower costs of transportation and production. Under normal circumstances, these statistics
would suggest a booming economy with a high level of growth. However, these aren’t normal circumstances. These are the realities of a nation recovering from the most severe recession in over a generation. How severe of a recession did the United States experience such that despite the tremendous gains made since 2009, many Americans continue to believe that the economy is weak? The Great Recession of 2007–2009 resulted from a major financial crisis that led to many drastic problems requiring government action. These macroeconomic actions included huge stimulus programs consisting of tax reductions, increased government benefits, greater government spending, and the use of financial bailouts for struggling companies and banks. And it also included extraordinary actions by the Federal Reserve, the central bank of the United States, that kept key interest rates at or near 0% for nearly a decade. One of the consequences of these policies has been the buildup of the national debt, creating new challenges for the future. The ability for a country to maintain economic growth depends on the ability of companies to sell products not only domestically but also to foreign consumers as part of international trade. Countries in today’s global economy
217
are highly interconnected. Therefore, the recent economic slowdown in China and Brazil, along with the continuing financial struggles facing many European nations in managing their unified currency (the euro), makes it more difficult for the U.S. economy to expand. A significant challenge facing countries today is determining the best path to long-run prosperity. Over the course of the past century, two dominant schools of thought have frequently been debated: the classical view and the Keynesian view. Classical economists believe that rising debt is unsustainable, and that it creates an undue burden on future generations that can prevent them from achieving their economic goals. These economists believe in paring the size of government and relying more on markets to dictate economic actions. In contrast, Keynesian economists believe that an active government role is needed to ensure that economic activity is promoted in areas where markets cannot do it alone. Keynesians believe that using government tools to manage economic downturns will promote growth, and that debt incurred in the short run will eventually be reduced by an expanding economy. Classical economics was the dominant form of thinking a century ago when macroeconomic policy was largely based on microeconomic analysis. That all changed during the Great Depression of the 1930s, when John Maynard Keynes explained the causes of the Great Depression and set forth a framework on which to develop policies to avoid future severe macroeconomic downturns. This led to the development of macroeconomics as a discipline. Today, the use of Keynesian policy is common, as evidenced by government actions taken to minimize the effects of past recessions.
218
219
FIGURE 1
MARKETS AND INSTITUTIONS IN THE MACROECONOMY
Labor, capital, and product markets, along with financial and government institutions, come together to influence macroeconomic outcomes such as the unemployment rate.
Managing the economy is not an easy task. Changes in the macroeconomy occur every day, and many changes are beyond the control of government. Because the world has become more connected, recessions in one country have an effect on other countries. Competition for jobs intensifies with greater labor mobility through immigration and with more companies seeking to pay lower wages by moving production facilities overseas. Population growth means more jobs are needed for a country just to remain at its same employment level. And pressures to earn profits in a competitive global economy force businesses to find more efficient means of production, including the use of automation, leading to some job loss as workers are replaced by machines. These factors help to explain why economies fluctuate up and down over time, a phenomenon called the business cycle. The development of macroeconomics as a discipline came after the realization that business cycles occurred and the fact that they can vary significantly in duration and severity. Macroeconomics describes how individuals, businesses, financial institutions, and government institutions interact to achieve the goals of job growth, low inflation, and economic growth. It is not just the conditions of one industry or group of workers that influence macroeconomic outcomes, but rather the conditions of all. Figure 1 illustrates how different markets and institutions come together to influence macroeconomic outcomes such as the unemployment rate and economic growth. Most economists believe that the macroeconomy is too complex to function efficiently without policy interventions. Economists have developed many tools for managing the severity of business cycles. This chapter deals with how the macroeconomy is analyzed and measured. The first section considers how business cycles are defined. The second section looks at the system of national income accounts. These accounts give us our primary measures of income, consumer and government spending, business investment, and foreign transactions including exports and imports. The last section raises the question of how well the national income accounts measure our standard of living. We look at alternative measures of standard of living, nonmarket transactions, and the effect of environmental degradation and conservation. The foundation established in this chapter will apply to topics covered throughout the course.
220
BUSINESS CYCLES Macroeconomics is concerned with business cycles, those short-run fluctuations in the macroeconomy known also as booms and busts. Business cycles are a common feature of industrialized economies, and are important to study because they emphasize the idea that markets are intertwined with one another. What happens in one market is not usually independent from other markets, as we saw with the persistent unemployment during and after the recession of 2007–2009. business cycles Alternating increases and decreases in economic activity that are typically punctuated by periods of recession and recovery.
Defining Business Cycles
Business cycles are defined as alternating increases and decreases in economic activity. As economists Arthur Burns and Wesley Mitchell wrote, Business cycles are a type of fluctuation found in the aggregate economic activity of nations that organize their work mainly in business enterprises: a cycle consists of expansions occurring at about the same time in many economic activities, followed by similarly general recession, contractions and revivals which merge into the expansion phase of the next cycle.1
Figure 2 shows the four phases of the business cycle. These phases, around an upward trend, include the peak (sometimes called a boom), followed by a recession (often referred to as a downturn or contraction), leading to the trough or bottom of the cycle, finally followed by a recovery or an expansion to another peak. A peak in the business cycle usually means that the economy is operating at its capacity. Peaks are followed by downturns or recessions. This change can happen simply because the boom runs out of steam and business investment begins to decline, causing economic growth to slow or turn negative. Once a recession is under way, businesses react by curtailing hiring and perhaps even laying off workers, thus adding to the recession’s depth. Eventually, however, a trough is reached, and economic activity begins to pick up as businesses and consumers become more optimistic about the economy. Often, the federal government or the Federal Reserve Bank institutes fiscal or monetary policies to help reverse the recession. We will look at government actions in future chapters. Figure 2 suggests that business cycles are fairly regular, but in fact the various phases of the cycle can vary dramatically in duration and intensity. As Table 1 shows, the recessions of the last 65 years have lasted anywhere from 6 months to 18 months. Expansions or recoveries have varied even more, lasting from 1 year to as many as 10 years. Some recessions, moreover, have been truly intense, bringing about major declines in income, while others have been little more than potholes in the road, causing no declines in real income. A good metaphor for the wide variation in business cycles is a roller coaster. Some roller coasters rise higher than others, fall faster than others, or climb slower than others. Some roller coasters have one large dip followed by a series of smaller ups and downs, while others may have a large dip followed by another large dip. This is true with business cycles—some business cycles are higher, faster, or longer than others, but all have the same four phases described earlier. An important difference between a business cycle and a roller coaster, however, is that a roller coaster typically ends at the same level as it starts, while business cycles tend to have an upward long-run trend in most countries, indicating a growing economy over time. FIGURE 2
TYPICAL BUSINESS CYCLE
221
The four phases of the business cycle are the peak or boom, followed by a recession (often called a downturn or contraction), leading to the trough or bottom of the cycle, followed by a recovery or an expansion leading to another peak. Note that although this diagram suggests business cycles have regular movements, in reality the various phases of the cycle vary widely in duration and intensity.
TABLE 1
SELECTED DATA FOR U.S. BUSINESS CYCLES SINCE 1950 Expansion Length (months)
Percentage Change in Real GDP
Maximum Unemployment Rate (%)
Years
Peak
Trough
Recession Length (months)
1953–1954
July 1953
May 1954
10
39
−2.2
5.9
1957–1958
Aug. 1957
April 1958
8
24
−3.6
7.4
1960–1961
April 1960
Feb. 1961
10
106
−0.6
7.1
1969–1970
Dec. 1969
Nov. 1970
11
36
+0.2
6.1
1973–1975
Nov. 1973
March 1975
16
58
−1.8
9.0
222
1980
Jan. 1980
July 1980
6
12
−2.3
7.8
1981–1982
July 1981
Nov. 1982
16
92
−2.2
10.8
1990–1991
July 1990
March 1991
8
120
−1.0
6.9
2001
March 2001
Nov. 2001
8
73
+0.5
5.8
2007–2009
Dec. 2007
June 2009
18
—
−4.1
10.0
Business cycles resemble roller coasters—some are higher, faster, or longer than others, but all are similar in terms of the up-and-down nature of the ride.
Unemployment has shown a similar variability: The more severe the recession, the higher the unemployment rate goes. In the recessions of 1990–1991 and 2001, the economy as a whole showed remarkable resiliency, but the recoveries were termed jobless recoveries because the economic growth following the recessions did not coincide with strong levels of job growth. In fact, sometimes an economy’s recovery falls short and enters another recession before it fully recovers; this is referred to as a double-dip recession. The last double-dip recession occurred in the early 1980s. However, the slow recovery following the 2007–2009 recession caused many economists to worry that another double-dip recession would occur. Fortunately, it did not. double-dip recession A recession that begins after only a short period of economic recovery from the previous recession.
Dating Business Cycles Business cycles are officially dated by the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), a nonprofit research organization founded in 1920. The NBER assigns a committee of economists the task of dating “turning points”— times at which the economy switches from peak to downturn or from trough to recovery. The committee looks for
223
clusters of aggregate data pointing either up or down. Committee members date turning points when they reach a consensus that the economy has switched directions. The committee’s work has met with some criticism because the decisions rest on the consensus of six eminent economists, who often bring different methodologies to the table. The committee’s deliberations, moreover, are not public; the committee announces only its final decision. Finally, the NBER dates peaks and troughs only after the fact: Their decisions appear several months after the turning points have been reached.2 By waiting, the panel can use updated or revised data to avoid premature judgments. But some argue that the long lag renders the NBER’s decisions less useful to policymakers. Nonetheless, the work of the NBER in dating the turning points is important for investors and businesses alike, as they help form expectations of how the economy might perform based on the phase of the business cycle it has reached. Businesses are more likely to invest during a time of expansion, and they don’t want to be investing in greater production capacity at a time of recession when sales might fall.
Alternative Measures of the Business Cycle Because the NBER focuses on historical data to date phases of the business cycle after they occur, economists have developed tools to analyze trends in an effort to predict phases of the business cycle before they occur. The following are three examples of methods used to predict business cycle movements.
National Activity Index
The National Activity Index, developed by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, is a weighted average of 85 indicators of national economic activity. These indicators are drawn from a huge swath of economic activity including production, income, employment, unemployment, hours worked, personal consumption, housing, sales, orders, and inventories. Figure 3 shows the index since 1985. When the index has a zero value, the economy is growing at its historical trend rate of growth. Negative values mean that the economy is growing slower and positive rates imply it’s growing faster than its long-term trend. When the index moves below −0.70 following a period of expansion, this suggests a high likelihood that the economy has moved into a recession. The index has done a remarkable job in pinpointing the signs of recessions in a reasonably current time frame.
Leading Economic Index
The Leading Economic Index (or LEI) established by The Conference Board, an independent business and research association, is another index that economists look to when predicting movements in the business cycle. The LEI uses ten important leading indicators to produce a weighted index. Because each indicator is a predictor of how the economy should perform in the near future, any change in the LEI today is supposed to reflect how the economy will change tomorrow. FIGURE 3
THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO’S NATIONAL ACTIVITY INDEX
224
The National Activity Index is a weighted average of 85 indicators of economic activity in the economy. When the index moves below −0.70 (dashed line), the economy is probably moving into a recession. This index appears to track the official NBER peak turning points.
Indicators in the LEI Average weekly hours, manufacturing Average weekly initial claims for unemployment insurance Manufacturers’ new orders, consumer goods and materials Index of supplier deliveries—vendor performance Manufacturers’ new orders, nondefense capital goods Building permits, new private housing units Stock prices, 500 common stocks Money supply, M2 Interest rate spread, ten-year Treasury bonds less federal funds Index of consumer expectations The LEI predicts a recession whenever the index falls for three months in a row (compared to the same month the previous year). In fact, it has successfully predicted the last seven recessions since 1969, although critics point to the fact that it has also provided some false warnings of recessions (a funny adage shared among economists is that forecasters have predicted ten of the last seven recessions).
Yield Curve
Perhaps the simplest, and surprisingly accurate, predictor of changes in the business cycle is the yield curve. A yield curve shows the interest rates for bonds (shown on the vertical axis) with different maturity rates (shown on the horizontal axis). For example, it would show the difference in interest rates between a three-month Treasury bill and a thirty-year Treasury bond (a “bill” is a type of bond with a maturity of less than one year).
225
yield curve Shows the relationship between the interest rate earned on a bond (measured on the vertical axis) and the length of time until the bond’s maturity date (shown on the horizontal axis).
One approach economists have used to predict recessions, shown in Figure 4, is to take the interest rate of a longterm ten-year bond and subtract the interest rate on a short-term three-month bill. Whenever this value turns negative (in other words, interest rates on short-term bills exceed those on long-term bonds), a recession is likely to occur. Why? When investors believe an economic slowdown may occur, they buy long-term bonds to lock in interest rates, pushing interest rates on long-term bonds lower. This has been true for seven of the last eight recessions. However, some economists remain skeptical, pointing to several false warnings that the yield curve has given which did not result in actual recessions. FIGURE 4
TREASURY SPREAD
The 10-year bond rate minus 3-month bill rate (monthly average). Shaded bars indicate recessions. In all but one recession since 1960, the difference in rates turned negative prior to the recession. Data from New York Federal Reserve: https://www.newyorkfed.org/medialibrary/media/research/capital_markets/Prob_Rec.pdf.
ISSUE The End of the Recession . . . It Does Not Feel Like It According to the National Bureau of Economic Research, the last U.S. recession officially ended in June 2009. But ask most people (besides economists) at the time or even a year later whether they thought the recession was over and you would have likely been laughed at. Indeed, in June 2009, the economy was not in good shape: The unemployment rate was 9.5%, GDP was over 4% below its
226
peak, and the stock market was nearly 40% below its high two years prior. Why would such dismal economic conditions signal the end of the recession? Part of the explanation is how economists date the business cycle. The NBER looks at “turning points” when the economy goes from a peak to a downturn or from a trough to a recovery. A recession officially ends when the economy is at the trough, which occurs when the economy is at its worst (or near worst) condition. In fact, the NBER generally waits until evidence of two quarters of GDP growth is found before declaring the recession over. Therefore, some recovery may already have occurred when a recession ends. Looking at the lives of everyday people, the beginning of a recovery is sometimes a more difficult time to live through than the recession itself. This brings about the other part of the explanation—how economists define each phase of the business cycle. A recession describes a decrease in the growth of the economy from its peak, while a recovery describes an increase in the growth of the economy from its trough. Therefore, although a recession may have officially begun, life is still good (for the time being), and people subsequently believe that the economy is still strong. Contrast this with the start of a recovery, in which life is dismal (for the time being) and people subsequently believe the economy is still in recession. The following tables provide a comparison. To many people, life at the start of a recession was much better than life at the start of the recovery. In fact, the 2007–2009 recession had such a slow recovery period that even after two years from the official end of the recession, the unemployment rate stood at 9.1%, much higher than the 6.2% unemployment rate during the middle of the recession in 2008. It would take another four years (in 2015) until the unemployment rate returned to 5%.
For some communities, the recession did not seem to have ended in 2009. In sum, how economists date recessions and recoveries is based largely on the turning points of the business cycle, which may not always reflect what everyday people experience.
Start of Recession (December 2007)
Start of Recovery (June 2009)
Unemployment Rate = 5.0%
Unemployment Rate = 9.5%
GDP (2005 dollars) = $13.4 trillion
GDP (2005 dollars) = $12.8 trillion
Stock Market (Dow) = 13,500
Stock Market (Dow) = 8,800
Middle of Recession (September 2008)
Two Years of Recovery (June 2011)
Unemployment Rate = 6.2%
Unemployment Rate = 9.1%
GDP (2005 dollars) = $13.2 trillion
GDP (2005 dollars) = $13.4 trillion
Stock Market (Dow) = 11,200
Stock Market (Dow) = 12,000
227
Each of the three indices is one of many methods economists use to predict the movements of the business cycle. Although a perfect predictor of booms and busts is not possible, many people follow these indices because of the importance of the business cycle in the macroeconomy. The duration and intensity of business cycles are measured using data collected by the Bureau of Economic Analysis and U.S. Department of Labor. These data for aggregate income and output come from the national income and product accounts. We turn in a moment to see how these data are collected and analyzed and consider how well they measure our standard of living. Keep in mind that these data are the key ingredients economists use to determine the state of the macroeconomy.
CHECKPOINT BUSINESS CYCLES Business cycles are alternating increases and decreases in economic activity. The four phases of the business cycle include the peak, recession (or contraction), trough, and recovery (or expansion). Business cycles vary in intensity, duration, and speed. Business cycles are dated by the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER). Business cycles are usually dated some time after the trough and peak have been reached. Economists have developed different methods to predict movements in the business cycle, including the use of the National Activity Index, the Leading Economic Index, and the yield curve.
QUESTION: Do you think that the business cycle has a bigger impact on automobile and capital goods manufacturers or on grocery stores? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
228
NATIONAL INCOME ACCOUNTING The national income and product accounts (NIPA) let economists judge our nation’s economic performance, compare U.S. income and output to that of other nations, and track the economy’s condition over the course of the business cycle. Many economists would say that these accounts represent one of the greatest inventions of the 20th century.3 Before World War I, estimating the output of various sectors of the economy—and to some extent the output of the economy as a whole—was a task left to individual scholars. Government agencies tried to measure various sorts of economic activity, but little came of these efforts. When the Great Depression struck, the lack of reliable economic data made it difficult for the administration and Congress to design timely and appropriate policy responses. Much of the information that was available at the time was anecdotal: newspaper reports of plant shutdowns, stories of home and farm foreclosures, and observations of the rapid meltdown of the stock market. In 1933 Congress directed the Department of Commerce (DOC) to develop estimates of “total national income for the United States for each of the calendar years 1929, 1930, and 1931, including estimates of the portions of national income originating from [different sectors] and estimates of the distribution of the national income in the form of wages, rents, royalties, dividends, profits and other types of payments.” This directive was the beginning of the NIPA. In 1934 a small group of economists working under the leadership of Simon Kuznets and in collaboration with the NBER produced a report for the Senate. The report defined many standard economic aggregates still in use today, including gross national product, gross domestic product, consumer spending, and investment spending. Kuznets was later awarded a Nobel Prize for his lifetime of work in this area. Work continued on the NIPA through World War II, and by 1947 the basic components of the present day income and product accounts were in place. Over the years, the DOC has modified, improved, and updated the data it collects. These data are released on a quarterly basis, with preliminary data being put out in the middle of the month following a given quarter. By the end of a given quarter, the DOC will have collected about two-thirds of the survey data it needs, allowing it to estimate the remaining data to generate preliminary figures.
The Core of the NIPA
The major components of the NIPA can be found in either of two ways: by adding up the income in the economy or by adding up spending. A simple circular flow diagram of the economy shows why either approach can be used to determine the level of economic activity.
SIMON KUZNETS (1901–1985)
NOBEL PRIZE S
imon Kuznets was awarded the Nobel Prize in 1971 for devising systematic approaches to the compilation and analysis of national economic data. Kuznets is credited with developing gross national product as a measurement of economic output. Kuznets developed methods for calculating the size and changes in national income known as the national income and product accounts (NIPA). Caring little for abstract models, he sought to define concepts that could be observed empirically and measured statistically. Thanks to Kuznets, economists have had a large amount of data with which to test their economic theories.
229
The Circular Flow Diagram
Figure 5 is a simple circular flow diagram that shows how businesses and households interact through the product and resource markets. circular flow diagram Illustrates how households and firms interact through product and resource markets and shows that economic aggregates can be determined by examining either spending flows or income flows to households.
Let us first follow the arrows that point in a clockwise direction. Begin at the bottom of the diagram with households. Households supply labor (and other inputs or factors of production) to the resource market; that is, they become employees of businesses. Businesses use this labor (and other inputs) to produce goods and services that are supplied to the product markets. Such products in the end find their way back into households through consumer purchases. The arrows pointing clockwise show the flow of real items: hours worked, goods and services produced and purchased. The arrows pointing counterclockwise, in contrast, represent flows of money. Businesses pay for inputs (factors) of production: land, labor, capital, and entrepreneurship. Factors are paid rents, wages, interest, and profits. These payments become income for the economy’s households, which use these funds to purchase goods and services in the product market. This spending for goods and services becomes sales revenues for the business sector.
Spending and Income: Looking at GDP in Two Ways
The circular flow diagram illustrates why economic aggregates in our economy can be determined in either of two ways. The spending in the economy accrues on the right side of the diagram. In this simple diagram, all spending is assumed to be consumer spending for goods and services. We know, however, that businesses spend money on investment goods such as equipment, plants, factories, and specialized vehicles to increase their productivity. Also, government buys goods and services, as do foreigners. This spending shows up in the NIPA, although it is not included in our simple circular flow diagram. FIGURE 5
A SIMPLE CIRCULAR FLOW DIAGRAM
230
This circular flow diagram illustrates why the economic aggregates in our economy can be determined in either of two ways. Spending flows through the right side of the diagram, while the left side of the diagram shows incomes flowing to households. Note that one person’s spending is another person’s income.
Second, similar income is generated equal to the spending in the product market. This is shown on the left side of the diagram. Wages and salaries constitute the bulk of income in our economy (roughly two-thirds of it), with rents, interest, and profits comprising the rest. Everything that is spent on the right side represents income on the left side; all spending must equal input (factor) incomes.
231
The main idea of a circular flow diagram is that every dollar spent in an economy becomes a dollar of income to someone else. For example, suppose you spend $5 on a smoothie, and suppose this $5 goes to the following: $1 to rent and equipment = income to landlord and equipment makers $1 to fruits and juices = income to farmers $1 to wages for store workers and managers = income to labor $1 to taxes = income to government $1 to profit = income to investors Therefore, regardless of whether economic activity is measured by the $5 in spending by the consumer or the $5 in income generated to various parties, the resulting measurement is the same.
Gross Domestic Product
Gross domestic product (GDP) is a measure of the economy’s total output; it is the most widely reported value in the NIPA. Technically, the nation’s GDP is equal to the total market value of all final goods and services produced by resources in the United States in a given year. A few points about this definition need to be noted. gross domestic product (GDP) A measure of the economy’s total output; it is the most widely reported value in the national income and product accounts (NIPA) and is equal to the total market value of all final goods and services produced by resources in a given year.
First, GDP reflects the final value of goods and services produced. Therefore, measurements of GDP do not include the value of intermediate goods used to produce other products. This distinction helps prevent what economists call “double counting,” because a good’s final value includes the intermediate values going into its production. To illustrate, consider a box of toothpicks. The firm producing these toothpicks must first purchase a supply of cottonwood, let’s say for $0.22 a box. The firm then mills this wood into toothpicks, which it puts into a small box purchased from another company at $0.08 apiece. The completed box is sold to a grocery store wholesale for $0.65. After a markup, the grocery store sells the box of toothpicks for $0.89. The sale raises GDP by $0.89, not by $1.84 (0.22 + 0.08 + 0.65 + 0.89), because the values of the cottonwood, the box, and the grocery store’s services are already included in the final sales price of a box of toothpicks. Thus, by including only final prices in GDP, double
232
counting is avoided. A second point to note is that, as the term gross domestic product implies, GDP is a measure of the output produced by resources in the United States. It does not matter whether the producers are American citizens or foreign nationals as long as the production takes place within the country’s borders. GDP does not include goods or services produced abroad, even if the producers are American citizens or companies. In contrast to GDP is gross national product (GNP), the standard measure of output the Department of Commerce used until the early 1990s. GNP reflects the market value of all goods and services produced domestically and abroad using resources supplied by U.S. citizens, while excluding the value of goods and services produced in the United States by foreign-owned businesses. The difference between GDP and GNP is small. The main reason the DOC switched its measurements was to ensure that its data were more directly comparable to how other countries measure the size of their economic output. Also, in an increasingly globalized world, foreign-owned businesses contribute significantly to our economy in terms of jobs and domestic investment; GDP takes these contributions into account. Third, whenever possible, the NIPA uses market values, or the prices paid for products, to compute GDP. Therefore, even if a firm must sell its product at a loss, the product’s final sales price is what figures into GDP, not the firm’s production cost or the original retail price. Fourth, the NIPA accounts focus on market-produced goods and services. The major exceptions to this approach include substituting payroll costs for the value of government services and estimating (imputing) the rental value of owner-occupied housing. This focus on market values has been criticized on the grounds that child care services, for instance, when provided by a nanny, are figured into GDP, while the values for these same services when performed by parents are not.
The Expenditures (Spending) Approach to Calculating GDP Again, GDP can be measured using either spending or income. With the expenditures approach, all spending on final goods and services is added together. The four major categories of spending are personal consumption expenditures, gross private domestic investment (GPDI), government spending, and net exports (exports minus imports).
Personal Consumption Expenditures
Personal consumption expenditures are goods and services purchased by residents and businesses of the United States. Goods and services are divided into three main categories: durable goods, nondurable goods, and services. Durable goods are products that have an average useful life of at least three years. Automobiles, major appliances, books, and musical instruments are all examples of durable goods. Nondurable goods include all other tangible goods, such as canned soft drinks, frozen pizza, toothbrushes, and underwear (all of which should be thrown out before they are three years old). Services are commodities that cannot be stored and are consumed at the time and place of purchase, for example, legal, barber, and repair services. Table 2 gives a detailed account of U.S. personal consumption spending in 2016. Notice that personal consumption is almost 70% of GDP, by far the most important part of GDP, and services constitute the largest portion of personal consumption. personal consumption expenditures Goods and services purchased by residents of the United States, whether individuals or businesses; they include durable goods, nondurable goods, and services.
Gross Private Domestic Investment
The second major aggregate listed in Table 2 is gross private domestic investment (GPDI), which, at 16.7% of GDP, refers to fixed investments, or investments in such things as structures (residential and nonresidential), equipment, and software. It also includes changes in private inventories. gross private domestic investment (GPDI) Investments in such things as structures (residential and nonresidential), equipment, and software, and changes in private inventories.
233
TABLE 2 Category
THE EXPENDITURES APPROACH TO GDP (2016) Billions of $
% of GDP
12,429.0
68.5
Durable goods
1,347.6
7.4
Nondurable goods
2,663.3
14.7
Services
8,418.1
46.4
Gross Private Domestic Investment
3,019.2
16.7
Fixed nonresidential
2,311.6
12.8
631.8
3.5
75.8
0.4
3,206.5
17.7
Federal
1,235.6
6.8
State and local
1,970.9
10.9
–526.5
–2.9
Exports
2,214.7
12.2
Imports
2,741.2
15.1
18,128.20
100.0
Personal Consumption Expenditures
Fixed residential Change in inventories Government Purchases of Goods and Services
Net Exports
Gross Domestic Product
Data from U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, www.bea.gov.
Residential housing represents about one-fifth of GPDI, and nonresidential structures make up most of the rest because inventory changes are small. Nonresidential structures include such diverse structures as hotels and motels, manufacturing plants, mine shafts, oil wells, and fast-food restaurants. Improvements to existing business structures and new construction are counted as fixed investments. A “change in inventories” refers to a change in the physical volume of the inventory a private business owns, valued at the average prices over the period. If a business increases its inventories (whether intentionally or unintentionally due to weak sales volumes), this change is treated as an investment because the business is adding to the stock of products it has ready for sale. This type of investment is generally the least desirable, because excess inventory does not increase productivity and could fall in value if the goods become outdated or if the market price falls. Private investment is a key factor driving economic growth and an important determinant of swings in the business cycle. Figure 6 tracks GPDI as a percentage of GDP since 1980. Recessions are represented by the vertical shaded columns. Notice that during each recession, GPDI turns down, and when the recession ends, GPDI turns up.
234
Investment is, therefore, an important factor shaping the turning points of the business cycle, especially at the troughs, and an important determinant of how severe recessions will be.
Government Purchases
The government component of GDP measures the impact that government spending has on final demand in the economy. As Figure 7 illustrates, at 17.7% of GDP, government spending is a relatively large component of GDP. It includes the wages and salaries of government employees (federal, state, and local) and the purchase of products and services from private businesses and the rest of the world. Government spending also includes the purchase of new structures and equipment. government spending Includes the wages and salaries of government employees (federal, state, and local); the purchase of products and services from private businesses and the rest of the world; and government purchases of new structures and equipment.
Net Exports of Goods and Services
Net exports of goods and services are equal to exports minus imports for the current period. Exports include all the items we sell overseas, such as agricultural products, movies, pharmaceutical drugs, and military equipment. Our imports are all those items we bring into the country, including vegetables from Mexico, clothing from India, and cars from Japan. Most years our imports exceed our exports, and therefore net exports are a negative percentage of GDP. net exports Exports minus imports for the current period. Exports include all goods and services we sell abroad, while imports include all goods and services we buy from other countries. FIGURE 6
GROSS PRIVATE DOMESTIC INVESTMENT (GPDI) AS A PERCENT OF GDP
235
Private investment is a key factor driving economic growth and an important determinant of swings in the business cycle. This graph tracks GPDI as a percentage of GDP since 1980.
FIGURE 7
GOVERNMENT SPENDING AS A PERCENT OF GDP
Government spending as a percent of GDP fell in the 1990s, rose in the 2000s until peaking in 2009, and has since fallen every year.
Summing Aggregate Expenditures
The four categories just described are commonly abbreviated as C (consumption), I (investment), G (government spending), and X − M (net exports; exports minus imports). Together, these four variables constitute GDP. We summarize this by the following equation: GDP = C + I + G + (X − M) Using the information from Table 2, we can calculate GDP for 2016 (in billions of dollars) as 18,128.2 = 12,429.0 + 3,019.2 + 3,206.5 + (−526.5)
The Income Approach to Calculating GDP
As we have already seen, spending that contributes to GDP provides an income for one of the economy’s various inputs (factors) of production. And in theory, this is how this process works. In practice, however, the national income accounts need to be adjusted to fully account for GDP when we switch from the expenditures to the income approach. Let’s work our way through the income side of the NIPA, which Table 3 summarizes.
Compensation of Employees
Compensation to employees refers to payments for work done, including wages, salaries, and benefits. Benefits include the social insurance payments made by employers to various government programs, such as Social Security, Medicare, and workers’ compensation and unemployment insurance. Some other benefits that count as labor income
236
are employer-provided pensions, profit-sharing plans, group health insurance, and in-kind benefits such as day care services. Employee compensation is 54% of GDP.
TABLE 3
THE INCOME APPROACH TO GDP (2016)
Category
Billions of $
% of GDP
9,852.6
54.3
Wages and salaries
7,994.8
44.1
Supplements to wages and salaries
1,857.8
10.2
Proprietors’ Income
1,412.8
7.8
Corporate Profits
1,667.9
9.2
Rental Income
670.6
3.7
Net Interest
676.8
3.8
1,202.7
6.6
National Income
15,483.4
85.4
Adjustments to National Income
2,644.8
14.6
Consumption of fixed capital
2,856.7
15.8
Statistical discrepancy
−211.9
−1.2
18,128.2
100.0
Compensation of Employees
Miscellaneous Adjustments
Gross Domestic Product
Data from U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, www.bea.gov.
Proprietors’ Income
Proprietors’ income represents the current income of all sole proprietorships, partnerships, and tax-exempt cooperatives in the country. It includes the imputed (estimated) rental income of owner-occupied farmhouses. Proprietors’ income is adjusted by a capital consumption allowance to account for depreciating equipment (equipment that is used up while producing goods and services). Although there are a lot of proprietorships in the United States, their combined income is less than 8% of GDP.
Corporate Profits
Corporate profits are defined as the income that flows to corporations, adjusted for inventory valuation and capital consumption allowances. Most corporations are private enterprises, although this category also includes mutual financial institutions, Federal Reserve banks, and nonprofit institutions that mainly serve businesses. Despite the huge profit figures often reported in the news media, corporate profits are less than 10% of GDP.
237
Rental Income
Rental income, at 3.7% of GDP, is the income that flows to individuals engaged in renting real property (calculated as rent collected less depreciation, property taxes, maintenance and repairs, and mortgage interest). It does not include the income of real estate agents or brokers, but it does include the imputed rental value of homes occupied by their owners (again, less depreciation, taxes, repairs, and mortgage interest), along with royalties from patents, copyrights, and rights to natural resources.
Net Interest
Net interest is the interest paid by businesses less the interest they receive, from this country and abroad, and is 3.8% of GDP. Interest expense is the payment for the use of capital. Interest income includes payments from home mortgages, home improvement loans, and home equity loans.
Miscellaneous Adjustments
Both indirect business taxes (sales and excise taxes) and foreign income earned in the United States are part of GDP, but must be backed out of payments to factors of production in this country. Neither is paid to U.S. factors of production, and therefore appear in a separate category for measurement purposes.
Summing Up Income Measures
To this point, we have described different measures of income including wages, salaries, and benefits; profits (for sole proprietors, partnerships, and corporations); rental income; and interest. Summing each of these measures along with the miscellaneous adjustments equals the national income. But be careful—national income is not the same as GDP. National income is income generated from the use of a country’s resources, whether at home or abroad. national income All income, including wages, salaries and benefits, profits (for sole proprietors, partnerships, and corporations), rental income, and interest.
In order to complete the calculation of GDP using the income approach, two additional measures need to be included. First, an allowance for the depreciation (or consumption) of fixed capital is added. This is the amount of capital or infrastructure that a country needs to undertake in order to maintain its productivity. Second, a small statistical discrepancy is included because like all macroeconomic measurements, it is difficult to be exactly precise, especially in a country as large as the United States. Once these factors are included, GDP is the same whether it is derived from spending or income. We have now seen how the national income and product accounts determine the major macroeconomic aggregates. But what does the NIPA tell us about the economy? When GDP rises, are we better off as a nation? Do increases in GDP correlate with a rising standard of living? What impact does rising GDP have on the environment and the quality of life? We conclude this chapter with a brief look at some of these questions.
CHECKPOINT NATIONAL INCOME ACCOUNTING The circular flow diagram shows how households and firms interact through product and resource markets. GDP can be computed as spending or as income. GDP is equal to the total market value of all final goods and services produced by labor and property in an economy in a given year. Personal consumption expenditures are goods and services purchased by individual and business residents of the United States. Gross private domestic investment (GPDI) refers to fixed investments such as structures, equipment, and software.
238
GDP is equal to consumer expenditures, investment expenditures, government purchases, and exports minus imports. In equation form, GDP = C + I + G + (X − M). GDP can also be computed by adding all of the payments to factors of production. This includes compensation to employees, proprietors’ income, rental income, corporate profits, and net interest, along with some statistical adjustments.
QUESTIONS: Each individual has a sense of how the macroeconomy is doing based on his or her own
experience. How might individual experiences lead one astray in thinking about what is happening in the overall economy? How might it help? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
239
GDP AND OUR STANDARD OF LIVING GDP data provide us with one way of comparing the productivity of different nations. But it doesn’t necessarily give us an accurate picture of the standard of living in each country. For example, China, India, and Brazil each have a GDP that places them among the top ten largest economies in the world. But clearly one would not describe the average citizen in these countries as wealthy. This section describes some of the factors that make it challenging to use GDP measures to compare the standard of living of average citizens across countries.
Different Ways of Comparing GDP Across Countries
The previous section described the two ways of measuring GDP using total expenditures and total income in an economy. But once the value of GDP is determined, does that mean it can be used to compare the size of the overall economy between two countries? To some extent, yes, in that countries with larger GDP do produce more output based on the final value of goods and services in that country and in a particular year. Herein lies an important caveat regarding GDP measures: Nominal GDP statistics do not do a good job of factoring changes in the prices of goods and services over time, nor taking into account differences in the cost of living between countries. To address the first issue of changing prices, the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis reports GDP statistics in both nominal terms as well as in real terms. Real GDP statistics adjust each year’s data to prices in a single base year (such as 2005). Therefore, real GDP does a better job of measuring actual growth in output, rather than counting the rise in prices of goods and services over time. The next chapter on inflation discusses nominal and real values in greater detail. real GDP The total value of final goods and services produced in a country in a year measured using prices in a base year.
To address the second issue of differences in the cost of living between countries, organizations that report GDP statistics across countries, such as the World Bank’s World Development Indicators, also report GDP statistics based on purchasing-power-parity–adjusted measures, or GDP-PPP. For example, a haircut in India may cost $3, while that same haircut in Switzerland may cost $30. Since the service is the same, is it accurate to count a haircut ten times more in Switzerland than in India in terms of GDP? By using a GDP-PPP measure, countries in which prices of goods and services (especially nontraded items such as haircuts and restaurant meals) are lower than a representative base country will have their GDP numbers increased, while countries in which prices are higher than the base country will have their GDP statistics lowered. The effect of using GDP-PPP can be substantial. Although the United States remains the world’s largest economy in terms of nominal GDP, it falls to second place behind China when GDP-PPP is used. The reason is because the cost of living in China (on average) is still lower than the cost of living in the United States. But despite this remarkable achievement by China in terms of GDP-PPP, the average Chinese citizen is much less well off than the average American. This is because aggregate GDP measures do not take into account population.
Population and GDP per Capita How can GDP measures better reflect a country’s population? The most common approach is to divide GDP by a country’s population, resulting in a statistic known as GDP per capita. GDP per capita is a useful measure of the relative standard of living of citizens in different countries. However, by simply dividing GDP by population, GDP per capita does not take into account the differences in wealth between the rich and poor within a country, and therefore might not fully reflect the standard of living of the typical citizen. For example, U.S. GDP per capita is about $55,000, but certainly the typical American family of four does not earn $220,000 a year. Yet, GDP per capita data are fairly easy to measure, and thus are a useful measure of relative wealth between countries. GDP per capita A country’s GDP divided by its population. GDP per capita provides a useful measure of a
240
country’s relative standard of living.
An alternative measure of the standard of living is median household income. Being the median household means that half of all households make less and the other half make more. Using this statistic reduces the effect of outliers (i.e., the very destitute or the superrich) skewing the averages. The U.S. median household income in 2016 was about $57,000, an amount that is closer to what middle-income households make.
Environmental Quality People around the globe have become increasingly concerned with the impact economic activity has on the natural world. These days, it is difficult to watch a nightly newscast without seeing a report about some ecological disaster or looming environmental problem. U.S. consumers, businesses, and the government spend hundreds of billions of dollars annually to protect the environment at home and abroad. Surprisingly, however, our national income and production statistics do little to account for the environmental benefits or harmful impacts of economic activity.
Costa Rica: Pura Vida and Happiness Without a High Level of GDP What does GDP fail to measure in terms of how well Costa Ricans live?
W
hen one thinks of countries in which citizens live well, rich countries often come to mind, such as Luxembourg, Denmark, and Switzerland. These countries have a high GDP per capita, allowing many of their people to live comfortable, and consequently happy, lives. This contrasts with countries with low GDP per capita, such as Sudan, Bangladesh, or Chad, where many people lack basic necessities and where much suffering takes place. But does a country need to be materially rich in order to be happy? One country in Central America whose name literally translates to “rich coast” doesn’t think so. Costa Rica’s GDP per capita is about $10,000 a year, or one-sixth that of the United States. However, according to the World Happiness Report by the Sustainable Development Solutions Network, in 2015 Costa Rica ranked 12th in terms of happiness, higher than the United States. What factors allow Costa Ricans to live happy lives despite having modest incomes? First, life expectancy in Costa Rica is slightly higher than in the United States. Good, affordable health care and guaranteed government pension payments make retiring in Costa Rica pleasant. Second, Costa Rica’s emphasis on ecotourism has helped preserve its environment and biodiversity. And third, without an army per its constitution, Costa Rica is able to devote funds otherwise spent on military uses to provide better education to its citizens.
241
It’s no wonder why many companies including those in the United States choose to operate production facilities in Costa Rica. With a literacy rate near 100% and a healthy, long-living populace, Costa Rica offers a productive and inexpensive labor force, with manufacturing and service wages averaging $2 to $3 per hour. Still, low wages means that many families in Costa Rica struggle with daily finances and lack the ability to afford luxuries that richer countries take for granted. But Costa Ricans, in addition to their uplifting country name, also have an uplifting national slogan, “Pura Vida,” a phrase used in ordinary everyday conversations to express optimism about life. As long as people are happy, they live productive lives, which bodes well for the future of the country.
GO TO
TO PRACTICE THE ECONOMIC CONCEPTS IN THIS STORY
In 1992 the Bureau of Economic Analysis decided to develop an experimental set of economic accounts known as the Integrated Environmental and Economic Satellite Accounts. Preliminary versions of these green GDP accounts were published in 1994, and later Congress directed the DOC to set up an outside panel of experts to study this issue in greater depth. The DOC asked the National Academy of Sciences to look at green economic accounting, which it did, appointing a select panel. Santiago, Chile, is one of the richest cities in Latin America, but also one of the most polluted. Should the negative effects of pollution be reflected in Chile’s GDP?
242
The DOC panel concluded that “extending the U.S. NIPA to include assets and production activities associated with natural resources and the environment is an important goal.”4 In terms of natural resources, these include the flow of services that are produced by environmental capital such as forests, national parks, and ocean fisheries. But from a consumer’s perspective, a cleaner environment also provides value. The ability to hike in parks, to suntan on clean beaches, and to swim in lakes and rivers all depend on a level of environmental quality that does not show up in our national accounts.
Nonmarket Activities and the Informal Economy In addition to addressing such concerns as environmental impacts and the value of nonmarket natural resources, the DOC panel’s recommendations highlight some of the broader shortcomings of the NIPA. For example, the national accounts ignore nonmarket transactions, investments in human capital, and the use of people’s time. Nonmarket transactions are an important part of our everyday lives. If a maid cleans your apartment, GDP rises, but if you did the same job yourself, GDP is unaffected. The same is true for babysitting, lawn care, and car maintenance. There is one exception—NIPA already imputes (estimates) the rental value, less expenses, of owneroccupied homes and adds this to GDP. Many people believe that the NIPA should be an index of the well-being found within our economy. In that case, it would ideally need to take into account the implications of economic activity the DOC panel noted and more, perhaps including data on life expectancy; business spending on research and development; the stock of human capital, including education and health; greenhouse gas emissions; income distribution; poverty rates; and unemployment rates. The informal economy (the underground or black market) is a large unmeasured component of our economy. The informal economy can be as simple as the money earned from a garage sale or from items sold on eBay that are not reported to the IRS. It also includes transactions dealing with illegal goods and services, such as drugs, prostitution, or unlicensed gambling. Finally, the informal economy includes the income earned by undocumented residents— those working on farms, factories, or restaurants for cash, or workers hired for housekeeping or babysitting services who are easily paid under the table. The size of the informal economy in the United States is estimated at around 10% of GDP. This is relatively small compared to many developing countries that can have an informal economy valued at as much as 50% of their GDP. informal economy Includes all transactions that are conducted but are not licensed and/or generate income that is not reported to the government (for tax collection).
243
The effects of the informal economy can be positive and negative. On the upside, people working in the informal economy are generating and spending income, contributing to national economic activity. Countries with large informal markets have total output that is significantly larger than what is officially reported in their GDP statistics. On the downside, those working in the informal economy do not pay much if any taxes, placing a greater tax burden on the rest of society. Also, the informal economy is less regulated, which increases the probability of corruption and crime. Despite these shortcomings in the NIPA measurements, it is important to keep the NIPA’s original purpose in mind. As the DOC panel noted, The modern national income and product accounts are among the great inventions of the twentieth century. Among other things, they are used to judge economic performance over time, to compare the economies of different nations, to measure a nation’s saving and investment, and to track the business cycle. Much as satellites in space can show the weather across an entire continent, the national accounts can give an overall picture of the state of the economy.5 The informal market ranges from casual tutoring students do in their spare time for cash to the multimillion dollar online poker industry.
The NIPA has served us well. Still, making adjustments to account for various environmental and other nonmarket considerations might provide us with an even better picture of the health of our economy. But we must keep in mind that an aggregate measure of the economy cannot be all things to all people. As we add complexity to an already complex undertaking, the NIPA may lose some effectiveness as a measure of economic activity, as pointed out earlier in the discussion of environmental quality. This is a difficult balancing act facing policymakers. The NIPA allow us to track business cycles, compare the domestic economy with that of other nations, and take a crude measure of our standard of living. In the next chapter, we will see how two other important policy variables, unemployment and inflation, are measured. The next several chapters will focus on developing explanations of short-term movements in the business cycle and long-term economic growth (the trend line in Figure 2). If we can understand why upturns and downturns occur, we may be able to devise policies that reduce the severity of business cycle swings while promoting economic growth. These investigations and policy objectives form the essence of modern macroeconomic analysis.
CHECKPOINT 244
GDP AND OUR STANDARD OF LIVING Nominal GDP uses current year prices, while real GDP measures output using prices from a base year. GDP-PPP takes into account the cost of living in a country. GDP per capita divides GDP by population, providing a useful measure of a country’s relative standard of living. GDP does not include most of the benefits and costs from environmental and natural resources. GDP does not include nonmarket activities or the informal economy. Despite the shortcomings of the GDP measure, GDP provides a simple and consistent way of measuring the overall economic activity in an economy.
QUESTIONS: Each summer, many of the campsites at America’s favorite national parks sell out months
in advance due to their limited supply, low prices, and prime locations and views. This has led entrepreneurial individuals to reserve these campsites well in advance and then sell the reservations for a high premium on sites such as Craigslist. Does the money earned by these campsite scalpers appear in GDP? Why or why not? Suppose the government attempts to minimize campsite scalping by doubling the price of campsites. Would this affect GDP? Explain. Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
245
chapter summary Section 1 Business Cycles 5.1
Business cycles are the alternating increases and decreases in economic activity typical of market economies. Business cycles can vary in duration and intensity, just like a roller coaster. These fluctuations take place around a long-run growth trend.
Business cycles are officially dated by the National Bureau of Economic Research, which assigns a committee of economists to determine “turning points” when the economy switches from peak to recession or from trough to recovery. They do this using past data, which means announcements take place after the turning points occur.
246
Four Phases of the Business Cycle Peak: The economy is operating at its capacity. Recession: Occurs when the economy runs out of steam and business investment falls. Trough: The economy reaches the depth of the recession. Recovery: Economic activity picks up and the economy grows.
5.2
Alternative Measures of Business Cycles National Activity Index Leading Economic Index Yield curve
Section 2 National Income Accounting 5.3
The national income and product accounts (NIPA) allow economists to judge our nation’s economic performance, compare income and output to that of other nations, and track the economy’s condition over the course of the business cycle. Gross domestic product (GDP) is the total market value of all final goods and services produced in a year within a country’s borders, regardless of a firm’s nationality. Gross national product (GNP) measures goods produced by a country’s firms, regardless of where they are produced.
247
Caterpillar Tractor U.S. firm; made in USA Part of U.S. GDP and GNP
Toyota Camry Japanese firm; made in USA Part of U.S. GDP, not GNP
Brooks Running Shoes U.S. firm; made in China Part of U.S. GNP, not GDP
5.4
The circular flow diagram shows how businesses and households interact through the resource and product markets. It shows spending as well as income. The major components of the NIPA can be constructed in either of two ways: by summing the spending of the economy or by summing income. Likewise, GDP can be measured by adding together either spending or income.
248
5.5 Calculating GDP Using Expenditures (% U.S. GDP) Personal Consumption Expenditures (C) Gross Private Domestic Investment (I) Government Purchases (G) Net Exports (X − M)
68% 17% 18% −3%
5.6 Calculating GDP Using Income (% U.S. GDP) Compensation of Employees Proprietors’ Income Corporate Profits Rental Income Net Interest Other/Adjustments
54% 8% 9% 4% 4% 21%
Section 3 GDP and Our Standard of Living 5.7
GDP per capita is measured as GDP divided by the population. It provides a rough measure of a country’s standard of living relative to other countries. However, it does not reflect differences in wealth within a country. Different Measures of GDP
249
Nominal GDP: GDP measured in current year prices Real GDP: GDP measured using prices from a base year GDP-PPP: GDP adjusted for cost of living relative to a base country Countries are placing greater emphasis on protecting the environment. The economic benefits from a clean environment, however, are mostly unmeasured in GDP statistics. This is changing as new measures are introduced to take environmental quality and degradation into account.
Liechtenstein: small GDP but many rich citizens.
India: large GDP but many poor citizens.
5.8
The informal economy includes all market transactions that are not officially reported and hence are not included in GDP measures; it creates both positive and negative effects: Positive: Transactions in an informal economy create jobs and contribute to overall economic activity. Negative: Taxes are rarely paid on income in the informal economy, putting a greater tax burden on others. Also, the informal economy is less regulated, which can lead to unsafe products or risky job conditions.
KEY CONCEPTS 250
business cycles double-dip recession yield curve circular flow diagram gross domestic product (GDP) personal consumption expenditures gross private domestic investment (GPDI) government spending net exports national income real GDP GDP per capita informal economy
QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS Check Your Understanding 1. 2. 3. 4.
How are business cycles defined? Describe the four phases of business cycles. What is a key problem with the way the NBER dates recessions and recoveries? Describe the circular flow diagram. Why must all income equal spending in the economy? Why does GDP accounting include only the final value of goods and services produced? What would be the problem if intermediate products were included? 5. Describe why GDP can be computed using either expenditures or income. 6. What does GDP per capita measure? Why is it not a precise measure of a typical person’s standard of living in a country?
Apply the Concepts 7. Explain how it is possible for an economy in the recovery phase of the business cycle to have a lower GDP and a higher unemployment rate than when it was in the recession phase of the business cycle. 8. As a percentage of GDP, government spending tends to increase during recessions and decrease during times of economic expansion. Explain why government spending tends to change depending on the phase of the business cycle, and how that affects spending as a percentage of GDP. 9. Critics argue that the NIPA are outdated and fail to account for “intangibles” in our new knowledge economy. For example, many firms create copyrighted materials (movies, books, etc.) that when completed are much more valuable than just the value of the marketplace inputs that went into their production. What might be some of the problems associated with trying to include these intangibles in the NIPA? 10. Gross domestic product and its related statistics are published quarterly and are often revised in the following quarter. Do you think quarterly publication and revision in the next quarter would present problems for policymakers trying to control the business cycle? Why or why not? 11. Gross private domestic investment (GPDI) includes new residential construction as investment. Why is new housing included? Isn’t this just another consumer purchase of housing services? How would the sale of an existing house be treated in the GDP accounts? 12. Suppose that a new method of calculating GDP allows for reductions in GDP as a result of the severity of environmental degradation in a country. If this method is used, which of the following countries might experience the greatest adjustment to their GDP calculation: India, Germany, or Iceland?
In the News
251
13. For much of the last 20 years, China’s GDP has grown around 10% per year, but in recent years has fallen to around 6% per year, which is still much higher than the average U.S. growth rate in recent years of about 2% per year. Why would a slowdown in China’s GDP growth be a significant concern to the U.S. macroeconomy? If prices of goods and services fall in China due to slower growth, does this help or hurt U.S. GDP? 14. According to the CIA’s World Factbook, in 2015 the tiny country of Equatorial Guinea had the highest GDP per capita in Africa (over $20,000 per year), even higher than more developed countries such as Morocco, Egypt, or South Africa. But despite the significant overall income from the sale of its natural resources, Equatorial Guinea has extreme poverty, with half of the population lacking clean drinking water, and one of the highest infant mortality rates in the world. How can a country that looks so good on paper (in terms of GDP per capita) be one of the least desirable places to live on the planet for the average citizen?
Solving Problems 15. The table lists gross domestic product (GDP), consumption (C), gross private domestic investment (I), government spending (G), and net exports (X − M). Compute each as a percent of GDP for the six years presented. Year
GDP
C
I
G
X−M
1965
719.1
443.8
118.2
151.5
5.6
1975
1,638.3
1,034.4
230.2
357.7
16.0
1985
4,220.3
2,720.3
736.2
879.0
115.2
1995
7,397.7
4,975.8
1,144.0 1,369.2
−91.4
2005
12,455.8
8,742.4
2,057.4 2,372.8
−716.7
2015
18,128.2 12,429.0
3,019.2 3,206.5
−526.5
C (%)
I (%)
G (%)
X − M (%)
a. Which category (or categories) has increased as a percent of GDP from 1965 to 2015? Which category (or categories) has decreased? And which category (or categories) has not changed much from 1965 to 2015? b. Which category has been the most volatile in terms of changes in the percent of GDP? c. Ignoring net exports, which component has grown the fastest as a percent of GDP since 1965?
WORK IT OUT 16. Use the following list of GDP components and data (given in millions of $U.S.) to answer the following questions.
Corporate profits Gross private domestic investment Consumption of nondurable goods Exports Proprietors’ income Miscellaneous adjustments Consumption of services 252
1,300 ______ 2,800 ______ 3,100 ______ 1,400 ______ 1,000 ______ 700 ______ 4,300 ______
Net interest Compensation of employees Imports Rental income Government spending Consumption of durable goods Consumption of fixed capital
500 ______ 8,000 ______ 1,900 ______ 400 ______ 2,100 ______ 1,300 ______ 1,400 ______
a. Indicate whether each component is part of the expenditures approach to calculating GDP (put an “E” next to the component) or the income approach to calculating GDP (put an “I” next to the component). b. Compute the GDP using both expenditures and income approaches. What factor explains the difference between these measures? c. Calculate the value of national income. Which category (categories) is (are) not included in national income, but are included in the calculation of GDP using the income approach?
USING THE NUMBERS 17. According to By the Numbers, in what year since 2005 was the difference between the unemployment rate and the real GDP growth rate the largest? What phase of the business cycle would this year best represent? 18. According to By the Numbers, has the personal savings rate trended upward or downward during the last five economic recessions? Why does this trend occur?
ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS Checkpoint: Business Cycles Big-ticket (high-priced, high-margin) items such as automobiles are affected by a recession more than grocery stores, where the margins are smaller and prices are lower. When the economy turns downward, investment falls; therefore, the capital goods industry is one of the first to feel the pinch. Checkpoint: National Income Accounting In general, it is probably a bad idea to interpret how the aggregate economy is doing by using your personal situation. Just because you are having trouble finding a job does not mean that everyone else is. Downsizing by Bank of America and Citigroup in recent years meant that bank workers had problems, even though the rest of the economy may have been growing steadily. There might be times when your situation (such as a layoff in an important industry) may be a leading indicator of what is coming for the economy as a whole. In general, anecdotal evidence is not particularly helpful in forecasting where the aggregate economy is going. When times are uncertain, anecdotal evidence may mislead. Even in recessions, some firms do well; therefore, anecdotal evidence is suspect. This is why the NIPA was created. Checkpoint: GDP and Our Standard of Living The money earned by the scalpers is not counted in GDP because scalpers are not likely to report this income on their tax returns, and thus this is considered part of the informal economy. The revenues earned by Craigslist, a legitimate enterprise, for the transaction would count toward GDP. If the government doubles the price of campsites and they continue to sell out, then GDP would increase because money paid to the National Parks is part of consumption spending in GDP.
253
1Arthur
Burns and Wesley Mitchell, Measuring Business Cycles (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research), 1946, p. 3. 2Marcelle
Chauvet and Jeremy Piger, “Identifying Business Cycle Turning Points in Real Time,” Review (St. Louis: The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis), March/April 2003, pp. 47–61. 3William
Nordhaus and Edward Kokkelenberg (eds.), Nature’s Numbers: Expanding the National Economic Accounts to Include the Environment (Washington, D.C. National Academy Press), 1999, p. 12. 4Nordhaus
and Kokkelenberg, Nature’s Numbers, pp. 2–3.
5Nordhaus
and Kokkelenberg, Nature’s Numbers, p. 12.
254
6
Measuring Inflation and Unemployment
255
Understanding the effects of rising prices and unemployment on the ability of people 256
to save and prepare for the future
Learning Objectives 6.1
Define inflation and explain how it is measured.
6.2
Use the consumer price index to estimate the effects of inflation on prices.
6.3
Describe the main causes of inflation.
6.4
Describe the economic consequences of the different forms of inflation.
6.5
Explain how “labor force,” “employment,” and “unemployment” are defined.
6.6
Compare alternative measures of unemployment that include marginally attached workers and underemployed workers.
6.7
Describe the different forms of unemployment and which ones can be influenced by government policies.
6.8
Explain what full employment means and how the natural rate of unemployment is measured.
F
ifty years ago, a single dollar bought a lot. A gallon of gasoline cost less than 30 cents, a movie theater ticket cost about 75 cents, and a meal at a relatively new restaurant chain called McDonald’s cost about 50 cents.
Today, none of these items can be purchased for a dollar. The general rise in prices in the economy is referred to as inflation. Inflation has fluctuated each year, ranging from less than 5% in the 1960s, to nearly 15% in 1980, to less than 2% in recent years. Inflation reduces the ability of consumers to purchase goods and services. Your dollar just does not go as far. Inflation is a macroeconomic issue because it reduces the purchasing power of both income and savings over time. Another macroeconomic concern facing the economy is unemployment, which measures the number of workers without a job but who are actively seeking one. Like the inflation rate, the unemployment rate fluctuates from year to year, falling below 5% during the Internet boom of the late 1990s and the housing bubble in the early 2000s, and reaching 10% during the early 1980s and late 2000s. Unemployment is a concern because not only does it force unemployed people to cut back on consumption and to use up their savings, it influences the employed to cut back on their consumption as well. Unemployment puts considerable strain on the government when it results in lower tax revenues but higher spending on assistance programs for the unemployed. Because inflation and unemployment can have such bad macroeconomic effects, they have been called the “twin evils” of the modern macroeconomy. Each alone is bad. Together, they amplify each other, making things worse. In the 1960s, macroeconomists thought they had these twin evils beaten. Historical data led them to believe that inflation and unemployment were linked in an inverse fashion; when unemployment went up, inflation would go down, and vice versa. Macroeconomists thought policymakers faced a menu of choices. Pick an unemployment rate from column A and get a corresponding inflation rate from column B. Better yet, the rates at issue were thought to be
257
relatively low: An inflation rate of 3% to 4% was thought to be needed to keep unemployment under 4%. For those unemployed in the 2007–2009 recession when unemployment reached 10%, an unemployment rate less than 4% would seem like a dream. Is a 3% to 4% inflation rate so bad? Unfortunately, the data amassed in the 1960s gave a false reading, as the high unemployment and high inflation rates of the 1970s proved. According to the 1960s macroeconomic model, the macroeconomy was just not supposed to witness the twin evils together. McDonald’s menu in 1955.
Jump ahead to 2016. After a long recovery since 2009 that saw persistent unemployment for several years, the silver lining was that inflation was low throughout the recovery, again confirming the trend that unemployment and inflation tend to run opposite of each other. But as the official unemployment rate fell below 5% in 2016, inflation did not rise, largely due to a steep drop in energy prices. Because both unemployment and inflation were low, the twin evils appeared seemingly defeated . . . but were they? Economists have pointed out that the extraordinary measures taken during and after the last recession resulted in growing debt and a large infusion of money into the economy, policies that could eventually lead to higher inflation. And if the slowdown in the global economy increases unemployment in the near future, we might have to confront the twin evils together again.
258
259
By now, you might be wondering: What is the big deal about inflation? You have a visceral sense that unemployment is bad. Inflation is less tangible. Thus, this chapter will start with inflation, what it is, how it is measured, and why it is bad. Then we will turn to unemployment. How does the government define the unemployment rate? An Uber driver with a Ph.D. is employed, but is he or she really underemployed? Is someone who has given up looking for a job considered unemployed? You may be surprised at the answers. The chapter then will categorize the types of unemployment, revealing which type can be moderated by government policies and which cannot. Finally, we will return to a key concern from the last chapter: the slow economic recovery that reduced the overall number of people seeking jobs.
260
INFLATION Suppose that 20 years ago, your parents put aside $18,200 each for your and your twin sister’s college education, which was the average cost of four years of tuition at a public university at that time. Your money was placed into a savings account that earned 1.5% interest per year on average, and your sister’s money was placed into a Treasury Inflation-Protected Security (TIPS) bond, which pays a fixed interest rate but whose value also changes with the inflation rate. Now you and your sister withdraw the money to pay for college. Big problem: The cost of tuition has more than doubled in the 20 years since your parents put the money into your accounts. Do you both still have enough to pay your tuition bill? Your sister perhaps does, but not you. Your account has $24,513 in it, and your sister’s account has $38,372. Looks like your sister got the better deal. Prices are constantly changing for the goods and services we buy. Prices for items such as concert tickets, airline tickets, and fast-food meals have risen steadily over time, making every dollar earned worth a little less in terms of how much it can buy. However, prices for some goods, such as smartphones, laptops, and other technology goods, have fallen. Overall, the prices of a typical “basket” of goods and services we buy rise each year—by 38% over the last 15 years, and 651% over the last 50 years. This gradual rise in prices each year is known as inflation. Over time, the effects of inflation can be substantial if one does not take action to protect against rising prices. For example, paying $4 for a gallon of milk today is much harder than paying $2.50 a gallon was back in 2002. But it would be even harder if your wages or savings have not increased over that period. inflation A general rise in prices throughout the economy. It is a measure of changes in the cost of living.
How do individuals protect themselves against rising prices? First, workers demand higher wages to compensate for higher prices. But in a weak economy, wage increases are not always possible, especially when many people are out of work and willing to work for lower wages. Second, individuals with money saved can invest that money in assets that earn interest or can increase in value over time. Holding cash, for example, does not earn interest and therefore does not protect one against inflation. Many forms of assets pay interest, including savings accounts, certificates of deposit (CDs), bonds, and money market accounts. But they do not pay equal amounts—safer assets, such as savings accounts, pay less than the average rise in prices, while riskier assets might pay more than the average rise in prices. One asset that pays a rate roughly equal to the rise in prices are TIPS bonds, which pay a small fixed interest rate in addition to an adjustment based on how prices change in an economy. Therefore, when prices do not rise much, a TIPS bond would pay little, but when prices rise a lot, a TIPS bond will pay a lot. Table 1 shows how $18,200 placed into different assets would have grown over 20 years. The TIPS bond better ensures that when you take money out after 20 years, you will be more able to pay for college at the higher prices.
TABLE 1
A COMPARISON OF TWO INVESTMENTS 1997
2017
Average price of 4 years of tuition at a public college or university
$18,200
$38,800
Value of $18,200 held in cash
$18,200
$18,200
Value of $18,200 held in a savings account
$18,200
$24,513
Value of $18,200 in a TIPS bond
$18,200
$38,372
261
What Causes Inflation? Inflation is a measure of changes in the cost of living. In an economy like ours, prices are constantly changing. Some go up as others go down, and some prices rise and fall seasonally. Inflation is caused by many different factors, but the primary reasons can be attributed to demand factors, supply shocks, and government policy. First, prices for goods and services are influenced by demand factors such as consumer confidence, income, or wealth. Think of a busy mall or restaurant. When there are plenty of customers, businesses are not pressured to offer discounts to attract buyers. This keeps prices higher than when consumer demand is depressed. For this reason, economic growth tends to coincide with inflation as a result of the demand for goods and services that higher incomes produce. Second, prices are affected by supply shocks, caused by fluctuations in the price of inputs such as oil, natural resources, and farm crops. Over the last decade, the average price of a gallon of gasoline skyrocketed from less than $2 to nearly $4 a gallon due to increased demand for energy worldwide (especially in emerging countries such as China and India). But more recently, as a result of a glut in oil production and decreased global demand, gasoline prices fell back to below $2 a gallon. Farm products have seen similar fluctuations in prices as droughts and other natural disasters disrupt the supply of crops. When input prices rise, this not only raises the cost of living for individuals, but also raises the cost for businesses to produce and transport goods once produced. These higher costs of doing business typically are passed on to consumers in the form of higher prices. When input prices fall, we generally expect the opposite effect on prices to occur. Lastly, inflation can result from specific government actions. Government has a great power that no one individual has—the power to print money. No doubt you have heard that the federal government runs a budget deficit as it spends more than it receives in tax revenues. How does the government obtain the money to overspend? It borrows by issuing Treasury bonds. When the bonds come due and the government does not have the money to buy them back, it can, in essence, run the printing presses and print up new dollars. As more new money is printed, a surplus of dollars is generated in relation to the supply of goods and services. When too much money chases a fixed quantity of goods and services, prices are bid up, which leads to inflation. Governments, like everyone else, have to obey the laws of supply and demand by limiting the growth of the money supply to prevent rampant inflation from occurring. The town of Sycamore, Illinois, installed parking meters with prices reminiscent of the 1950s, when the price of parking was 1 cent per 12 minutes or 5 cents per hour. Parking citations were $1.00. The parking meters, stuck in a time long before inflation set in, became a tourist draw for the town.
262
Now that we have described the main causes of inflation, let’s discuss how inflation is measured.
Measuring Inflation: Consumer Price Index, Producer Price Index, and GDP Deflator
Each month, the U.S. Department of Labor, through its Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS), reports several important statistics that provide us with our principal measure of inflation. It does so by reporting changes in the average level of prices over the previous month in terms of the price level. The price level is the absolute level of a price index, whether this is the consumer price index (CPI; retail prices), the producer price index (PPI; wholesale prices), or the GDP deflator (average price of all items in GDP). The percentage increase in prices over a 12-month period is referred to as the rate of inflation. price level The absolute level of a price index, whether the consumer price index (CPI; retail prices), the producer price index (PPI; wholesale prices), or the GDP deflator (average price of all items in GDP).
Because inflation rates fluctuate up and down, the term disinflation is used to describe a reduction in the rate of inflation. Note that an economy going through disinflation still experiences rising prices, just at a slower pace. This was the case from the mid-1980s throughout the 1990s. However, if overall prices in an economy actually fall, this is referred to as deflation. Cases of deflation are rare, but did occur in the early 1930s, and briefly in 2015 as a result of a steep drop in energy prices. disinflation A reduction in the rate of inflation. An economy experiencing disinflation still faces inflation, but at a declining rate. deflation A decline in overall prices throughout the economy. This is the opposite of inflation.
Measuring consumer spending and inflation is one of the oldest data-collection functions of the BLS. The first nationwide survey was conducted in 1888–1891, which at the time emphasized the worker’s role as a producer rather than as a consumer. During World War I, surveys of consumer spending were conducted to compute one of the first cost-of-living indices. During the Great Depression, extensive consumer surveys were used to study the welfare of selected groups, notably farmers, rural families, and urban families. The BLS began regular reports of the modern CPI in the late 1930s. Today, the CPI is the measure of inflation most Americans are familiar with, although the producer price index and the GDP deflator also are widely followed.
The Consumer Price Index
The consumer price index (CPI) is an index of the average prices paid by urban consumers (CPI-U) and urban wage earners (CPI-W) for a market basket of consumer goods and services. The CPI-U covers roughly 88% of the population. consumer price index (CPI) An index of the average prices paid by urban consumers for a typical market basket of consumer goods and services.
The CPI is often referred to as a “cost-of-living” index, but the current CPI differs from a true cost-of-living measure. A cost-of-living index compares the cost of maintaining the same standard of living in the current and base periods. A cost-of-goods index, in contrast, merely measures the cost of a fixed bundle of goods and services from one period to the next. Why does CPI use a fixed bundle of goods and services? First, this avoids having to measure how consumers react to price changes; for example, if the price of beef rises, people might buy more chicken. Second, because it is difficult to follow every decision made by consumers, the government measures how prices change for a fixed basket of goods that an average consumer would buy. The CPI is calculated by dividing the market basket’s cost in the current period by its cost in the base period. The
263
current CPI is a cost-of-goods index because it measures changes in the price of a fixed basket of goods. The reference or base period used today for the CPI is 1982–1984, but any base year would work just as well. How the Bureau of Labor Statistics Measures Changes in Consumer Prices Measuring consumer prices requires the work of many people. Data collectors record about 83,000 prices in 87 urban areas each month from selected department stores, supermarkets, service stations, doctors’ offices, rental offices, and more. Yet, the BLS does not have enough resources to price all goods and services in all retail outlets; therefore, it uses three sample groups to approximate the spending behavior of all urban consumers. These include a Consumer Expenditure Survey tracking the spending habits of over 30,000 families nationwide used to construct the market basket of goods and services, a Point-of-Purchase Survey that identifies where households purchase goods and services, and census data to select the urban areas where prices are collected. Goods and services are divided into more than 200 categories, with each category specifying over 200 items for monthly price collection. Data from the three surveys are combined, weighted, and used to compute the cost in the current period required to purchase the fixed market basket of goods. This cost is then compared to the base period to calculate the CPI using the following formula: CPI = (Cost in Current Period ÷ Cost in Base Period) × 100 For example, assume that the market basket of goods cost $5,000 in 2011 and that the same basket of goods now costs $5,750. The CPI for today, using 2011 for the base year, is 115.0 = ($5,750 ÷ $5,000) × 100 Therefore, the cost of goods has risen by 15% over this time period because the index in the base year (2011 in this case) is always 100. Again, the choice of base year does not matter as long as the CPI for each year is calculated relative to the cost in the selected base year. In fact, one can use CPI data as reported by the BLS to calculate price changes between any two years, neither of which is the base year, using the following formula: % Change in Price = [(CPI in Current Year/CPI in Original Year) × 100] − 100 For example, if the CPI in 2016 was 238.6 and the CPI in 2011 was 224.9, the average change in prices over this five-year period was 6.1% = [(238.6/224.9) × 100] − 100 We now take a quick look at some of the problems inherent in the current approach to measuring the CPI. Problems in Measuring Consumer Prices The CPI is a conditional cost-of-goods index in that it measures only private goods and services; public goods (such as national defense spending) are excluded. Other background environmental factors, meanwhile, are held constant. The current CPI, for instance, does not take into account such issues as the state of the environment, homeland security, life expectancy, crime rates, climate change, or other conditions affecting the quality of life. For these reasons alone, the CPI will probably never be a true cost-of-living index. But even if we ignore the environmental factors and public services, the CPI still tends to overstate inflation for three key reasons: product substitution, quality improvements, and the introduction of new products. The CPI uses a fixed market basket determined by consumer expenditure surveys that often are three to five years old. The CPI assumes that consumers continue to purchase the same basket of goods from one year to the next. We know, however, that when the price of one good rises, consumers substitute other goods that have fallen in price, or at least did not rise as much. Also, in any given year, about 30% of the products in the market basket will disappear from store shelves. Data collectors can directly substitute other products for roughly two-thirds of these dropped products, which means that about 10% of the original market basket must be replaced by products that have been improved or modified in some important way. These quality improvements affect standards of living although they are not fully accounted for in CPI measurements.
264
Another problem for CPI is the introduction of new products. Not too long ago, digital streaming of books, music, and movies did not exist. Neither did iPads and other devices allowing these media to be played. Because technology is constantly changing along with the prices of technology goods, the BLS often waits until a product matures and is used by a significant number of consumers before including it in the market basket. By not measuring the benefits of new products that consumers enjoy, the actual rate of inflation will be overstated. One final difficulty to note has to do with measuring the changing costs of health care. The CPI looks only at consumers’ out-of-pocket spending on health care, and not the overall health care spending (including payments made by Medicare, Medicaid, and employer-provided insurance), which is 3 times larger. If price changes differ between out-of-pocket spending and total spending, the CPI will not reflect the true rise in costs. One solution to these problems was the introduction of an indicator by the BLS called C-CPI-U, or chained CPI for urban consumers. The C-CPI-U uses the same data as the CPI-U, but applies a different formula to account for product substitutions made by consumers. Although the C-CPI-U does a better job of approximating a cost-of-living index, it takes longer to estimate because data must be collected over several years. The BLS reports the C-CPI-U, which has a base period of 1999, alongside CPI-U and CPI-W. The difference in magnitudes between CPI-U and C-CPI-U varies from year to year; however, the trend has been for C-CPI-U to be lower than CPI-U by roughly 0.3% to 0.4% each year.
The Producer Price Index
The producer price index (PPI) is an index of the average prices received by domestic producers for their output. Before 1978 this index was known as the wholesale price index (WPI). The PPI is compiled by doing extensive sampling of nearly every industry in the mining and manufacturing sectors of our economy. producer price index (PPI) An index of the average prices received by domestic producers for their output.
The PPI contains the following: Price indexes for roughly 500 mining and manufacturing industries, including over 10,000 indexes for specific products and product categories Over 3,700 commodity price indexes organized by type of product and end use About 800 indexes for specific outputs of industries in the service sector, and other sectors that do not produce physical products Several major aggregate measures of price changes, organized by stage of processing, both commodity-based and industry-based The PPI measures the net revenue accruing to a representative firm for specific products. Because the PPI measures net revenues received by the firm, excise taxes are excluded, but changes in sales promotion programs such as rebate offers or zero-interest loans are included. Because the products measured are the same from month to month, the PPI is plagued by the same problems discussed above for the CPI. These problems include quality changes, deleted products, and some manufacturers exiting the industry.
The GDP Deflator
The GDP deflator shown in Figure 1 is our broadest measure of inflation. It is an index of the average prices for all goods and services in the economy, including consumer goods, investment goods, government goods and services, and exports. The prices of imports are excluded. Note that deflation occurred in the Great Depression. The spike in inflation occurred just after the end of World War II, when price controls were lifted. Since the mid-1980s, the economy has witnessed disinflation—inflation was present but generally at a decreasing rate. GDP deflator An index of the average prices for all goods and services in the economy, including consumer goods, investment goods, government goods and services, and exports. It is the broadest measure of inflation in the national income and product accounts (NIPA).
Adjusting for Inflation: Escalating and Deflating Series 265
(Nominal Versus Real Values) Price indexes are used for two primary purposes: escalation and deflation. An escalator agreement modifies future payments, usually increasing them, to take the effects of inflation into account. Deflating a series of data with an index involves adjusting some current value (often called the nominal value) for the impact of inflation, thereby creating what economists call a real value. Using the GDP deflator, for instance, to deflate annual GDP involves adjusting nominal GDP to account for inflation, thereby yielding real GDP, or GDP adjusted for inflation. FIGURE 1
INFLATION FROM 1930 TO 2016—GDP DEFLATOR
The broadest measure of inflation, the GDP deflator, is used to graph inflation from 1930 to the present. Deflation occurred during the Great Depression. The spike in inflation occurred after World War II ended, when price controls were lifted. Since then, inflation has existed in a 1%–14% range. Since the mid-1980s, the U.S. economy has generally faced disinflation (inflation, but generally at a decreasing rate).
Escalator Clauses
Many contracts, including commercial rental agreements, labor union contracts, and Social Security payments are subject to escalator clauses. An escalator clause is designed to adjust payments or wages for changes in the price level. Social Security payments, for example, are adjusted upward (and referred to as a cost-of-living adjustment, or COLA) almost every year to account for the rate of inflation. Escalator clauses become important in times of rising or significant inflation. These clauses protect the real value of wages as well as payments such as Social Security. In fact, voting blocs and organizations such as AARP have been formed to protect those who depend on escalator clauses to maintain their standards of living. However, over the past decade, low inflation rates have correspondingly resulted in tiny increases in benefits. In fact, in 2009, 2010, 2015, and 2016, inflation was so low (around 0%) that no increase in Social Security benefits occurred. This caused some concern among many seniors because the lack of inflation in 2015 and 2016 was due to a large drop in energy prices, despite higher prices for food and health care, items on which seniors are more likely to spend their money. In general, though, escalator clauses are important because they do protect people from spikes in the overall price level.
Deflating Series: Nominal Versus Real Values
GDP grew by 22% from 2008 to 2016, but should we be celebrating? Not really, because inflation has eroded the
266
purchasing power of that increase. The question is, by how much did GDP really increase? First, remember that every index is grounded on a base year, and that the value for this base year is always 100. The base year used for the GDP deflator, for instance, is 2008. The formula for converting a nominal value, or current dollar value, to real value, or constant dollar value, is Real = Nominal × (Base Year Index ÷ Current Year Index) To illustrate, nominal GDP in 2016 was $18,128.2 billion. The GDP deflator, having been 100 in 2008, was 112.3 in 2016. Real GDP for 2016 (in 2008 dollars) was therefore $16,142.6 billion = $18,128.2 billion × (100.0 ÷ 112.3). Note that because the economy has faced some inflation—12.3% from 2008 to 2016—the nominal value of GDP has been reduced by this amount to arrive at the real value. In other words, of the 22% growth in nominal GDP, 12.3% was due to rising prices. If we subtract 12.3% from 22%, real growth of GDP from 2008 to 2016 was less than 10%, or a little over 1%, per year. The slow economic recovery following the recession of 2007–2009 played a large role in the very slow growth of real GDP over this time period.
The Effect of Overstating Inflation
Many federal benefits, including Social Security payments, food stamps, and veterans’ benefits, are indexed to the CPI, which means that if inflation (as measured by the CPI) goes up by 3%, these benefits are increased by 3%. If the CPI overstates inflation, federal expenditures on benefits are higher. Although individuals initially benefit from the higher payments, overstating inflation in the long run makes real earnings appear smaller than what they actually are. This leads to a different set of issues for policymakers and our economy. Because CPI had been estimated to overstate inflation, in 1999 the Department of Labor revised its measurement tools used for estimating inflation. As a result, today’s CPI is a more accurate measure of inflation.
The Consequences of Inflation
Why do so many policymakers, businesspeople, and consumers dread inflation? Your attitude toward inflation will depend in large part on whether you live on a fixed income, whether you are a creditor or debtor, and whether you have properly anticipated inflation. Many elderly people live on fixed incomes; often, only their Social Security payments are indexed to inflation. People on fixed incomes are harmed by inflation because the purchasing power of their income declines. If people live long enough on fixed incomes, inflation can reduce them from living comfortably to living in poverty. Creditors, meanwhile, are harmed by inflation because both the principal on loans and interest payments are usually fixed. Inflation reduces the real value of the payments they receive, while the value of the principal declines in real terms. This means that debtors benefit from inflation; the real value of their payments declines as their wages rise with inflation. Many homeowners in the 1970s and 1980s saw the value of their real estate rise from inflation. At the same time, their wages rose, again partly due to inflation, but their mortgage payment remained fixed. The result was that a smaller part of the typical household’s income was needed to pay the mortgage. Inflation thus redistributes income from creditors to debtors. This result takes place only if the inflation is unanticipated. If lenders foresee inflation, they will adjust the interest rates they offer to offset the inflation expected over the period of the loan. Suppose, for instance, that the interest rate during zero inflation periods is roughly 3%. Now suppose that a lender expects inflation to run 5% a year over the next three years, the life of a proposed loan. The lender will demand an 8% interest rate to adjust for the expected losses caused by inflation. Only when lenders fail to anticipate inflation does it harm them, to the benefit of debtors. But the effects of unexpected inflation do not stop there. When inflation is unexpected, the incentives individuals and firms face change. For example, suppose that inflation causes prices of everyday purchases along with wages to increase by 5%. If this inflationary effect was anticipated, then consumption decisions should not change, because real prices stay the same when prices and wages rise by the same amount. But if the price rise was unexpected, it
267
might cause consumers to reduce their consumption, leading to lower spending in the economy. For firms, if an increase in money due to unexpected inflation causes demand for their products to rise at their original prices, firms might react by increasing production (and their costs) rather than adjusting their prices when actual demand has not changed. Therefore, unexpected inflation leads to faulty signals, which can reduce consumer and producer welfare. Lastly, when inflation becomes rampant, individuals and firms expend resources to protect themselves from the harmful effects of rapidly rising prices, an effect that is especially prevalent in cases of hyperinflation.
Hyperinflation Hhyperinflation is an extremely high rate of inflation. Today, most economists refer to an inflation rate above 100% a year as hyperinflation. But in most episodes of hyperinflation, the inflation rates dwarf 100% a year. In 2008 in Zimbabwe, prices were more than doubling every day, for an annual inflation rate of 231,000,000%. hyperinflation An extremely high rate of inflation; above 100% per year.
Hyperinflation is not new. It has been around since paper money and debt were invented. During the American Revolutionary War, the Continental Congress issued money until the phrase “not worth a continental” became part of the language. Germany experienced the first modern hyperinflation after World War I. Hungary experienced the highest rate of inflation on record during World War II. By the end of the war, it took over 800 octillion (8 followed by 29 zeros) Hungarian pengos to equal 1 prewar pengo. Millions, billions, and quadrillions are the types of numbers people have to deal with when using hyperinflated currencies.
ISSUE The Consequences of Counterfeit Money on Inflation Each day, hundreds of billions of U.S. dollars exchange hands in everyday transactions. A small fraction of these dollars are counterfeit, circulating throughout the economy as if they were genuine. When counterfeit money is created, who ends up paying for it? Suppose you receive some money, and later realize one of the bills is fake (the ink runs, the paper is too thin, or the watermark is missing). What can you do? Many people assume they could go to a bank and exchange the fake bill for a real one. But most banks won’t accept a fake bill because then the bank would lose the money. Some people pass the fake to the next unsuspecting person, but this is a punishable offense. The law states that a counterfeit bill must be reported to the nearest U.S. Secret Service field office. By doing so, you still lose the money, as there is no compensation for turning in counterfeit money. Thus, the responsibility lies with individuals and businesses to check the authenticity of the money received, and to refuse money that appears to be counterfeit. That is not always as easy as it sounds. A low-quality counterfeit might be detected by the naked eye, by touch, or by the use of devices such as a counterfeit detector pen. But sophisticated counterfeiters produce high-quality counterfeits that are hard to detect. For example, one counterfeiting method is to remove the ink from a lower-
268
denomination bill and then reprint a higher denomination on the paper. The paper is real, making counterfeit detector pens ineffective, and the bill contains a watermark (however, the wrong one) and a security strip. These counterfeits are nearly indistinguishable from authentic bills, and can circulate for years without being noticed. Restaurants and other businesses often receive counterfeits because cashiers are rushed. Consumers sometimes pass them to businesses thinking it won’t hurt them. Because banks generally do not accept counterfeits, businesses with counterfeits incur a loss that acts as a tax on the business, which leads to higher prices. Therefore, even if individuals do not end up with the counterfeit in their possession, they pay for them in the form of higher prices. What happens when a high-quality counterfeit circulates for years in the economy? In terms of its economic impact, counterfeit money acts as real money if people accept it as real money. Ultimately, the government loses. Why? The government (the U.S. Treasury to be specific) is the only institution with the authority to print money. When another entity prints counterfeits, the amount of money in circulation rises, but the government never had the opportunity to use it first. When more money chases a limited amount of goods and services in an economy, inflation arises. Because counterfeits produce the same effect as an increase in the money supply, inflation will occur. In sum, counterfeits hurt everyone, which is why governments invest in new technology to produce money with many security features.
Counterfeit detector pens are commonly used to monitor currency that comes into businesses. When counterfeit money doesn’t get detected, businesses lose the money, which acts as a tax, which leads to higher prices.
Hyperinflation is usually caused by an excess of government spending over tax revenues (extremely high deficits) coupled with the printing of money to finance these deficits. Post–World War I Germany faced billions of dollars in war reparations that crippled the country. The German government found it difficult to collect enough taxes to pay the reparations, and instead it simply printed more money, causing the value of the currency to fall as prices rose. Over time, financial assets in banks and pension accounts became worthless and were essentially taxed away through hyperinflation. Stopping hyperinflation requires restoring confidence in the government’s ability to bring its budget under control. It usually requires a change in government and a new currency, and most important a commitment to reduce the growth of the money supply. Hyperinflation is an extreme case, yet it shows how inflation can have detrimental effects on an economy. This is why it is important to keep track of inflation, as it is an important measure of the health of an economy.
CHECKPOINT 269
INFLATION Inflation is a measure of the change in the cost of living. Inflation is a general rise in prices throughout the economy. Disinflation is a reduction in the rate of inflation, and deflation is a decline in overall prices in the economy. The CPI is a price index used to measure inflation for urban consumers and is based on a survey of a fixed market basket of goods and services each month. The PPI is a price index used to measure price changes for the output of domestic producers. The GDP deflator is the broadest measure of inflation and covers all goods and services in GDP. Escalator clauses adjust payments (wages, rents, and other payments such as Social Security) to account for inflation. Real (adjusted for inflation) values are found by multiplying the nominal (current dollar) values by the ratio of the base year index to the current year index. Hyperinflation is an extremely high rate of inflation.
QUESTIONS: Suppose you took out $20,000 in student loans at a fixed interest rate of 5%. Assume that after you graduate, inflation rises significantly as you are paying back your loans. Does this rise in inflation benefit you in paying back your student loans? Who is hurt more from unexpected higher inflation—a borrower or a lender? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
270
UNEMPLOYMENT Unemployment is a phenomenon that affects nearly all workers at some point in their lives. When people become unemployed, the loss of wages often creates hardships on workers and their families. Moreover, the loss of income reduces consumer spending, which can lead to a ripple effect as businesses cut back production, leading to more workers losing their jobs.
The Historical Record
The Census Bureau began collecting data on wages and earnings in the early 19th century, but it took the Great Depression to focus national attention on the need for consistent data on unemployment rather than specific instances of things such as factory closings. By the 1940s, the Department of Labor began collecting employment data using monthly surveys to get a more detailed picture of the labor force. As the Bureau of Labor Statistics has noted, To know about unemployment—the extent and nature of the problem—requires information. How many people are unemployed? How did they become unemployed? How long have they been unemployed? Are their numbers growing or declining? Are they men or women? Are they young or old? Are they white or black or of Hispanic origin? Are they skilled or unskilled? Are they the sole support of their families, or do other family members have jobs? Are they more concentrated in one area of the country than another?1 A 1946 Census Bureau poster encouraging compliance with the initial unemployment survey.
271
Once the BLS has collected and processed the current employment statistics, policymakers use this information to craft economic policies. Before we discuss how these statistics are defined, collected, used, and made accurate, let’s briefly look at the historical record of unemployment and its composition. Figure 2 shows unemployment rates for the last century. Unemployment has varied from a high of 25% of the labor force in the middle of the Great Depression to a low of just over 1% during World War II. Unemployment during the past 50 years has tended to hover around the 5% to 6% range, although it reached 10% during the 1981– 1982 and 2007–2009 recessions. FIGURE 2
A CENTURY OF UNEMPLOYMENT (1916–2016)
Over the last century, unemployment has varied from a high of 25% of the labor force in the middle of the Great Depression to a low of just over 1% during World War II. Unemployment during the past 50 years has tended to hover around the 5%–6% range.
Table 2 shows a breakdown of unemployment among various groups by gender, race, and education for 1985, 1995, 2005, and 2015. For blacks, unemployment has tended to be more than double the rate of white unemployment, and the unemployment rate for Hispanics has usually exceeded that for whites by roughly 50%. Unemployment for college graduates is consistently low. Roughly half of all unemployment is normally from job losses, but this rose to
272
two-thirds during the 2007–2009 downturn. The next largest group involves people who have not worked in some time and are looking to reenter the labor force. Finally, those people who quit their jobs or are new entrants into the labor force constitute a small percentage of the unemployed. Now that we have some idea of the composition of the unemployed, let us consider just how these numbers are compiled. First, we need to examine how people get categorized as employed or unemployed.
Defining and Measuring Unemployment The three major monthly numbers the BLS reports are the size of the labor force, number of people employed, and number unemployed. The unemployment rate is the number of people unemployed divided by the labor force.
Employed
People are counted as employed if they have done any work at all for pay or profit during the survey week. Regular full-time work, part-time work, and temporary work are all included. People who have a job, but are on vacation, ill, having child care problems, on family leave, on strike, prevented from working because of bad weather, or engaged in some family or personal obligation are treated as employed. These people are considered to be employed because they have jobs to return to once their temporary situations have been resolved.
TABLE 2 Industry
UNEMPLOYMENT RATES BY GENDER, RACE, EDUCATION, OCCUPATION, AND REASON FOR UNEMPLOYMENT, 1985–2015 1985
1995
2005
2015
Total unemployment
7.2
5.6
5.1
5.3
Gender Men
7.0
5.6
5.1
5.4
7.4
5.6
5.1
5.2
6.2
4.9
4.4
4.6
Black
15.1
10.4
10.0
9.6
Hispanic
10.5
9.3
6.0
6.6
Education Less than high school diploma
8.5
9.0
7.6
8.0
High school graduate
5.2
4.8
4.7
5.4
Less than bachelor’s degree
4.4
4.0
3.9
4.5
College graduate and higher
2.2
2.4
2.3
2.6
3.0
2.2
2.3
2.5
5.2
4.3
4.6
4.7
Women Race or Ethnicity White
Occupation Managerial and professional Office and
273
administrative support Production occupations
8.8
8.7
6.7
5.7
Reason Why Unemployed Job loser
3.6
2.6
2.5
2.6
Job leaver
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.5
Reentrant
2.0
1.9
1.6
1.6
New entrant
0.9
0.4
0.4
0.6
Data from U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics (Historical Data Series, CPS Database).
One other group, called unpaid family workers, is considered to be employed. These are people who work 15 or more hours a week in a family enterprise; they usually show up in agriculture and retail. Unpaid family workers who work fewer than 15 hours a week are not counted as employed.
Unemployed
People are counted as unemployed if they do not have a job, but are available for work and have been actively seeking work for the previous four weeks. Actively looking for work includes efforts such as responding to online job ads, sending off résumés, scheduling job interviews, visiting school placement centers, and contacting private or public employment agencies. Note the emphasis on being active in the job search. A passive job search that merely involves browsing online employment openings or talking to friends about jobs is not enough to characterize someone as unemployed. One exception involves workers who have been laid off but are expecting to be recalled; they do not need to seek other work to count as being unemployed. Aside from the only other exception—namely, people suffering a temporary illness—individuals must be engaged in a job search to be counted as unemployed.
Labor Force
The labor force is the total number of those employed and unemployed. The unemployment rate is the number of unemployed divided by the labor force, expressed as a percent. labor force The total number of those employed and unemployed. The unemployment rate is the number of unemployed divided by the labor force, expressed as a percent.
The measurement of the labor force has important implications for the unemployment rate. To be counted in the labor force, one must either be employed or not employed, but actively seeking work. As a result, a number of groups are not included in the labor force, including full-time students who do not hold jobs, retirees, children under the age of 16, and persons who are institutionalized. If a person within these categories is not working, he or she is not counted in unemployment statistics because he or she is not in the labor force. A discussion of how changes in the labor force affect the unemployment rate appears later in this section.
Monthly Employment Surveys The Census Bureau and the Department of Labor conduct different surveys to measure employment. The Census Bureau surveys households and the U.S. Department of Labor focuses on the payrolls of businesses and government agencies to produce their monthly reports.
274
The Household Survey
Every month the Census Bureau, as part of the Current Population Survey (CPS), contacts roughly 60,000 households to determine the economic activity of people. The sample is drawn from over 700 geographical areas intended to represent the entire country, including urban and rural areas. The survey includes self-employed workers, unpaid family workers, agricultural workers, private household workers, and workers absent without pay. The Census Bureau does not directly ask interviewees if they are employed. Rather, it asks a series of questions designed to elicit information that permits the Bureau to determine by its own standards whether people are employed or unemployed and whether they are in the labor force.
The Payroll Survey
Officially called the Current Employment Statistics (CES) Survey, the payroll or establishment survey focuses on approximately 146,000 companies and government agencies that are asked how many employees they currently have. If jobs are cut, this survey will immediately show a decrease in the number of employees. According to the Bureau of Labor Statistics, “Both the payroll and household surveys are needed for a complete picture of the labor market. The payroll survey provides a highly reliable gauge of monthly changes in nonfarm payroll employment. The household survey provides a broader picture of employment including agriculture and the self-employed.”2 The household survey provides a detailed demographic picture of the labor market and captures entrepreneurial activity missed by the payroll survey. In contrast, the payroll survey provides detailed information by industry and region of the country. Because the payroll survey has a larger sample, it is generally viewed as the most accurate gauge of employment and unemployment changes, but both surveys closely track each other.
Employment Trends The surveys described in the previous section are important measures of employment and unemployment for the country as a whole as well as for individual states and cities included in the surveys. However, investors and economists are interested in trends in employment and how they affect the overall health of the economy. Although major companies are highlighted in the news for their decisions on hiring and laying off workers, the majority of jobs in the country are generated by small and mid-sized companies. These employment decisions fluctuate often, and therefore investors are interested in statistics that might capture these short-term trends.
275
Weekly Jobs Report
One report that has gained increasing attention is the Unemployment Insurance Weekly Claims Report, more commonly referred to as the Weekly Jobs Report, released by the U.S. Department of Labor each Thursday. The Weekly Jobs Report contains an estimate of the number of persons filing for unemployment benefits for the first time, and is used as a way to estimate trends in layoffs and in hiring. Economists are interested in seeing how the weekly data change from week to week. These data provide a more immediate estimate of unemployment than waiting for the monthly survey report.
Relationship Between Employment and the Unemployment Rate
People often generalize the negative relationship between employment and the unemployment rate. Although these terms are negatively related, the relationship is not perfect. For example, it is possible for employment to grow and the unemployment rate to increase at the same time. Recall that the unemployment rate measures the number of people unemployed and seeking work divided by the labor force. The important point to highlight here is that the labor force is constantly changing. The labor force changes for many reasons. For example, the labor force in the United States grows by around 1.5 million persons each year just from population growth (from natural births as well as from immigration). Therefore, even without considering any other factor influencing the labor force, the United States needs to generate numerous new jobs just to keep the unemployment rate steady. Further, people enter and leave the labor force for many reasons —college, retirement, family reasons, or just frustration with the job market. As a result of these factors, the unemployment rate is not perfectly correlated with employment numbers, as we will analyze in greater detail next.
Problems With Unemployment Statistics Analyzing issues as complex and personal as employment, unemployment, and job seeking can be expected to generate its share of criticism. When the Department of Labor announces its results each month, commentators often note that these numbers understate unemployment, because they do not include chronically unemployed workers who have grown so frustrated and discouraged that they have dropped out of the labor force. Media pundits agonize over the plight of discouraged workers or the underemployed while discussing the impact of the latest numbers on the stock market. How unemployment is measured depends on the intended use of the resulting measurements. Various uses for unemployment statistics include (1) gauging the state of the economy, (2) determining the divergence of supply and demand in labor markets, and (3) assessing the distribution of unemployment and the extent to which people are suffering from being out of work. In the United States, most unemployment statistics have been developed to gauge
276
the state of the economy. The Bureau of Labor Statistics does, however, publish data about underemployment, discouraged workers, and other marginally attached workers.
Underemployment and Marginally Attached Workers
It is not uncommon for people to take jobs that do not fully use their skills. In the early 1990s, many engineers and skilled workers who were employed in the defense industry saw their careers fall apart with the collapse of the Soviet Union. The “peace dividend” most people enjoyed generated excess supplies in defense-related labor markets. In the early 2000s, the collapse of many Internet start-ups and telecommunications firms eliminated the jobs of many highly skilled workers. The 2007–2009 recession caused by the collapse of the housing market and the subsequent financial crisis put large numbers of construction, real estate, and Wall Street workers out of work. As a result of these shake-ups, many people were unable to find jobs that enabled them to duplicate their past standards of living. These underemployed workers were forced to take jobs that did not fully—or in some cases, even remotely—use their education, background, or skills. Many underemployed workers took temporary or part-time jobs to earn income to supplement their unemployment benefits (each state has different limits on how much income can be earned while receiving unemployment benefits) or gave up their unemployment benefits altogether if the temporary or part-time work paid well. For example, in recent years, many people who lost their jobs became Uber drivers or Airbnb hosts, because these are flexible jobs that allow one to earn income while searching for permanent work. underemployed workers Workers who are forced to take jobs that do not fully utilize their education, background, or skills. Underemployed workers often hold part-time jobs.
Another common situation that occurs during economic downturns is that people give up looking for work altogether. The Department of Labor categorizes those who were available for work and actively looked for it during the last 12 months, but not in the last 4 weeks, as marginally attached workers. Marginally attached workers are not counted in the official unemployment statistics, because they are not considered part of the labor force. marginally attached workers Workers who were available for work and actively looked for it during the last 12 months, but not in the last 4 weeks.
The reasons that people stop looking for work vary, but the most common reason is a person’s belief that there simply aren’t any good jobs available, and he or she consequently gives up looking for work until the labor market improves. This portion of marginally attached workers is called discouraged workers. The deeper the recession, the more discouraged workers there will be. Other reasons for being marginally attached include giving up the search for work due to family responsibilities or transportation problems. discouraged workers Discouraged workers are the portion of marginally attached workers who have given up actively looking for work and, as a result, are not counted as unemployed.
Today, the Census Bureau asks other questions of respondents to determine whether they fit into the categories of a discouraged worker, other marginally attached worker, or underemployed worker. These data are then reported by the Bureau of Labor Statistics to provide a more comprehensive analysis of the employment situation. Figure 3 shows a breakdown of unemployed, discouraged, other marginally attached, and underemployed (measured by those working part-time who would prefer full-time employment) workers over the past 15 years, using the measurements defined by the Department of Labor as U-3 (the official unemployment rate), U-4, U-5, and U-6, respectively. Discouraged workers and other marginally attached workers each increase unemployment rates by a small amount, but those working part-time (underemployment) increase the overall unemployment rate the most. Adding together all these categories (U-6) nearly doubles the unemployment rate. Other countries have different definitions of actively seeking work, classifying individuals engaged in passive job searches as unemployed. Notably, Canada and Europe have more relaxed search standards than the United States.
277
The Boom and Bust of Dickinson, North Dakota How did the expansion of the oil industry affect prices and employment in Dickinson, and how quickly did it unravel?
F
rom 2010 to 2013, when much of the United States was recovering from a severe recession, one town experienced a boom. High school graduates without specialized skills were earning six-figure salaries, and even fast-food workers were making double the minimum wage and receiving hiring bonuses. At the same time, prices in this small city were rising rapidly, especially for housing which couldn’t keep up with the pace of new workers arriving in search of jobs and higher wages. How did this small remote city in western North Dakota experience such a rapid rise and subsequent bust?
Dickinson is not an easy city to spot on a map, nor one that is easy to get to, being over 500 miles from the nearest major airport hub. But because of its proximity to the Bakken Formation, one of the largest oil and natural gas deposits in North America, Dickinson became a destination for workers across the country seeking lucrative job opportunities that were readily available, created by the high price of oil which kept the industry very profitable. Although jobs were seemingly endless and unemployment practically nonexistent, the boom led to shortages of goods and services, especially housing, which couldn’t keep up with demand due to the city’s remote location. As a result, prices rose significantly in Dickinson and in other towns in the region. Anecdotal evidence of high inflation abounded as Dickinson residents paid rents that would be more expected in Los Angeles than in North Dakota, and where in a trip to a grocery store one might encounter prices that resemble those of a convenience store. But alas, the boom of Dickinson would not last. As oil prices plummeted by over 60% from 2014 to 2016, oil drilling in North Dakota was no longer profitable for many companies. As a result, most drilling rigs were abandoned, resulting in rising unemployment that forced many newly arrived residents to pack up again and leave. The silver lining for residents of Dickinson is that prices fell, making living in the remote western region of North Dakota affordable once again.
GO TO
FIGURE 3
TO PRACTICE THE ECONOMIC CONCEPTS IN THIS STORY
UNEMPLOYMENT CATEGORIES (2000–2015)
278
The Department of Labor categorizes unemployment into those unemployed and still actively seeking work, those who are discouraged (not looked for work in the last 4 weeks), those who are marginally attached for other reasons (have looked for work in the past 12 months, but not in the last 4 weeks due to, for example, family issues or transportation problems), and those working part-time but who would prefer full-time work. The categories U-3 (the official unemployment rate), U-4, U-5, and U-6 correspond to the sum of these respective categories.
CHECKPOINT UNEMPLOYMENT People are counted as employed if they are at least 16 years old, not institutionalized, and have worked for pay or profit during the survey week. People are unemployed if they do not have a job, but are available for work and have been actively seeking work for the previous four weeks. The labor force is the sum of the employed and unemployed. The unemployment rate is the number of unemployed divided by the labor force. The official unemployment rate statistics do not account for underemployed, discouraged, and other marginally attached workers.
QUESTIONS: Does it seem reasonable to require that to be counted as unemployed, a person must be actively seeking work? Why not just count those who do not have a job but indicate they would like to work? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
279
UNEMPLOYMENT AND THE ECONOMY Inevitably, our economy will contain some unemployment. People who are reentering the workforce or entering it for the first time will often find that landing a new job can take some time. Then they may find, moreover, that taking the first available job is not always in their best interest—that it might be better to take the time to search for another position better matching their skills and personality. Getting information and searching more extensively can extend the period people remain unemployed. Unemployment can occur because wages are artificially set above the market clearing or equilibrium wage. Both minimum wage laws and union bargaining can have this effect, helping those workers who are employed to earn more, but shutting some potential workers out of jobs. Employers often keep wages above market equilibrium to reduce turnover (and training costs), boost morale, and increase employee productivity. These efficiency wages give employees an incentive to work hard and remain with their present employers, because at other jobs they could earn only market wages. These higher wages, however, can also prevent employers from hiring additional workers, thus contributing to unemployment. Changes in the business cycle will also generate unemployment. When the economy falls into a recession, sales decline, and employers are forced to lay off workers; therefore, unemployment grows. Separating different types of unemployment into distinct categories will help us apply unemployment figures to our analysis of the economy.
Types of Unemployment
There are three types of unemployment: frictional, structural, and cyclical. Each type has different policy ramifications.
Frictional Unemployment
Do you recall how many different part-time jobs you held during high school? How about summer jobs while in college? If you have worked several types of jobs, you’re not alone, as many reasons exist why one may leave a job. You may get bored; the business may close or reduce the staff it needs; you might move to a new city; or you could have been fired. If you’re enrolled in school while working part-time jobs, generally you are not considered unemployed while between jobs, because being in school generally means you’re not counted in the labor force. But the reasons for changing jobs are still relevant once you graduate and work full-time. As you pursue your career, chances are that you’ll work for more than one company during your lifetime. Frictional unemployment describes the short-term duration of unemployment caused by workers switching jobs, often voluntarily, for a variety of reasons. Some workers quit their jobs to search for better positions. In some cases, these people may already have other jobs, but it may still take several days or weeks before they can report to their new employers. In these cases, people moving from one job to the next are said to be frictionally unemployed. frictional unemployment Unemployment resulting from workers who voluntarily quit their jobs to search for better positions, or are moving to new jobs but may still take several days or weeks before they can report to their new employers.
Frictional unemployment is natural for any economy and, indeed, necessary and beneficial. People need time to search for new jobs, and employers need time to interview and evaluate potential new employees. The Internet has helped to facilitate job searches by expanding access to information; still, frictional unemployment will always exist.
Structural Unemployment
Another naturally occurring phenomenon in an economy is structural unemployment. Whereas frictional unemployment is assumed to be of rather short duration, structural unemployment is usually associated with extended periods of unemployment.
280
structural unemployment Unemployment caused by changes in the structure of consumer demands or technology. It means that demand for some products declines and the skills of this industry’s workers often become obsolete as well. This results in an extended bout of unemployment while new skills are developed.
Structural unemployment is caused by changes in the structure of consumer demands or technology. Many industries and products inevitably decline and become obsolete, and when they do, the skills honed by workers in these industries often become obsolete as well. Declining demand for cigarettes, for instance, has changed the labor market for tobacco workers. Farm work, textile finishing, and many aspects of manufacturing have all changed drastically in the last several decades. Farms have become more productive, and many sewing and manufacturing jobs have moved overseas because of lower wages there. People who are structurally unemployed are often unemployed for long periods and then some become discouraged workers. Music stores selling CDs are a dying breed as consumers buy most of their music online, causing structural unemployment in CD manufacturing and in the music retail industry.
To find new work, those who are structurally unemployed must often go through extended periods of retraining. But ultimately, the new skills learned make workers more productive in a changing labor market, which make production more efficient. Displaced workers with more education are more likely to retrain easily and adjust to a new occupation. For that reason, governments often provide assistance to workers seeking new skills or more education. One benefit of a growing economy is that retraining is more easily obtained when labor markets are tight.
Cyclical Unemployment
Cyclical unemployment is the result of changes in the business cycle. If, for example, business investment or consumer spending declines, we would expect the rate of economic growth to slow, in which case the economy would probably enter a recession, as we will examine in later chapters. Cyclical unemployment is the difference between the current unemployment rate and what it would be at full employment, defined below. cyclical unemployment Unemployment that results from changes in the business cycle, and where public policymakers can have their greatest impact by keeping the economy on a steady, low-inflationary, solid growth path.
Frictional and structural unemployment are difficult problems, and macroeconomic policies provide only limited relief. Cyclical unemployment, most economists agree, is where public policymakers can have their greatest impact.
281
By keeping the economy on a steady, low-inflationary, solid growth path, policymakers can minimize the costs of cyclical unemployment. Admittedly, this is easier said than done given the various shocks (such as a sharp decline in consumer spending) that can affect the economy.
Defining Full Employment Economists often describe the health of the economy by comparing its performance to full employment. We know full employment cannot be zero unemployment, because frictional and structural unemployment will always be present. Full employment today is generally taken to be equivalent to the natural rate of unemployment.
The Natural Rate of Unemployment
The natural rate of unemployment has come to represent several ideas to economists. First, it is often defined as that level of unemployment at which price and wage decisions are consistent—a level at which the actual inflation rate is equal to people’s inflationary expectations. The natural rate of unemployment is also considered to be the unemployment level at which unemployment is only frictional and structural, or alternatively, when cyclical unemployment is zero. natural rate of unemployment The level of unemployment at which price and wage decisions are consistent; a level at which the actual inflation rate is equal to people’s inflationary expectations and where cyclical unemployment is zero.
Economists often refer to the natural rate of unemployment as the nonaccelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU), defined as the unemployment rate most consistent with a low rate of inflation. It is the unemployment level at which inflationary pressures in the economy are at their minimum. We will discuss these issues in greater detail throughout the remainder of the book. For now, it is enough to remember that the NAIRU is the unemployment rate consistent with low inflation and low unemployment. Full employment, or the natural rate of unemployment, is determined by such institutional factors as the presence or absence of employment agencies and their effectiveness. Many job seekers today, for example, search online postings on sites such as Indeed or LinkedIn, reducing the time it takes to match available employees with prospective employers. Other factors might include the demographic makeup of the labor force and the incentives associated with various unemployment benefit programs and income tax rates.
Changes in the Unemployment Rate Around the Natural Rate
In the previous chapter, we studied how the business cycle leads to both periods of high economic growth and periods of recessions, fluctuating around a long-term trend. The unemployment rate follows a similar pattern, rising during recessions and falling during economic booms, but fluctuating around the natural rate of unemployment. In the United States, the natural rate of unemployment is very steady and has fallen slowly over the past 30 years from about 6% to between 5 and 5.5% largely due to improvements in labor market efficiencies (such as the use of the Internet in job searches and the increase in part-time and temporary work) that has reduced the unemployment rate associated with low inflation. Of particular importance is the length of time it takes the unemployment rate to return to the natural rate when recessions push unemployment higher. To analyze this point, Figure 4 shows the unemployment rate over the past 50 years, along with the natural rate. Periods of recession are shaded, most indicating cyclical unemployment as the unemployment rate line rises above the natural rate. It is interesting to note that the time it takes the unemployment rate to return to the natural rate varies. In most economic recoveries prior to 1990, the unemployment rate returned to the natural rate fairly quickly. The 1990–1991 and 2001 recessions did not produce much cyclical unemployment; however, the unemployment rate initially rose during the recovery, leading to a “jobless recovery.” But the longest jobless recovery occurred after the 2007–2009 recession, in which the unemployment rate stayed well above the natural rate for several years. FIGURE 4
UNEMPLOYMENT RATE VERSUS THE NATURAL RATE OF UNEMPLOYMENT
282
The average unemployment rate and the natural rate of unemployment are shown from 1966 to 2016. Periods of recession are shaded. The rising unemployment line and flatter downward slopes following the last three recessions indicate a longer recovery period for jobs caused by a jobless recovery.
Jobless Recoveries Prolong Unemployment Above the Natural Rate
The previous chapter discussed some of the reasons why unemployment can stay high for so long after a recession is deemed over. It highlighted the four key markets—labor, financial, capital, and output—that influence one another and affect job growth. But the fact that economic growth does not always coincide with job growth deserves an explanation. In the labor market, recessions tend to send people looking for other options—going back to college, seeking early retirement, or just taking time off until the economy improves. Some who are out of work during these periods take temporary or part-time jobs to support their loved ones until better work can be found. Although all of these people’s jobs were affected, the government does not consider them as unemployed, because they had either found temporary work or had left the labor force to pursue other options. Thus, the official unemployment rate reported during recessions tends to underestimate the actual number of people seeking work, a problem discussed in the previous section.
ISSUE Why Do Unemployment Rates Differ So Much Within the United States? In December 2015, the U.S. unemployment rate was 5.0%. However, in New Mexico it was 6.7%. Meanwhile, in North Dakota, it was only 2.7%. Looking at metropolitan area unemployment rates reveals even starker differences. The unemployment rate in El Centro, California, was 19.6%, while in Ames, Iowa, it was 2.2%. Why do such large differences in unemployment exist between states and between cities?
283
In Europe, where citizens of the European Union are free to live and work in any other country within the union, differences in unemployment rates between member countries remain largely due to cultural reasons. People are hesitant to move to a country where people speak a different language or have a different culture. But in the United States, language and cultural differences between states are considerably less than between European countries—English is the primary language and Americans all basically watch the same types of movies and television shows. Aside from the common language and culture, differences do arise in other areas, which helps to explain the differences in unemployment rate. First, differences in taxes and regulations exist between states. Some states have lower taxes than others, and some states have environmental and work rules that are more business friendly than others.
The college town of Ames, Iowa, home of Iowa State University, had virtually no unemployment in 2015. Second, many industries tend to form a cluster in order to take advantage of economies of scale and scope. For example, industrial agglomeration in the computer industry centers in greater San Jose (“Silicon Valley”). Detroit has long been the automobile capital of the country, while Gary, Indiana, was once a major steel-producing town (in addition to being the birthplace of Michael Jackson). Economic trends tend to favor some industries over others. Biotechnology, eCommerce, and health care industries have experienced much growth over the past decade, leading to employment growth in cities home to these industries. However, declines in manufacturing and the recent collapse of the oil industry have increased unemployment in cities heavily dependent on those industries for employment.
The farming community of El Centro, California, near the southern border with Mexico, had the highest unemployment rate in the nation in 2015. Finally, and perhaps most obvious, people prefer certain geographic areas to others. Significant population growth has occurred in the South and Mountain West, where warm weather and scenic beauty await, respectively. Many immigrants from Mexico prefer living in states bordering Mexico for
284
cultural reasons. And throughout much of the past century, people have moved from rural areas to urban areas. How much would you sacrifice to live in a preferred area? People ask themselves this question often.
During an economic recovery, as jobs are being created, not only do the unemployed seek these jobs, but also many of those who had left the labor force return to compete for these same jobs. When many would-be workers choose to leave the workforce during a prolonged economic downturn, competition for jobs can be more severe during an economic recovery when these workers return to the labor force. The last few recessions saw many people temporarily leave the workforce to pursue nonwork options such as schooling, stay-at-home parenting, or volunteer work. These choices may explain why unemployment is slow to fall during economic recoveries, and one of the major reasons why jobless recoveries might remain a feature in future recessions. Inflation, employment, unemployment, and gross domestic product (GDP) are the key macroeconomic indicators of our economic health. Our rising standards of living are closely tied to GDP growth. In the next chapter, we will investigate what causes our economy and living standards to grow over the long term.
CHECKPOINT UNEMPLOYMENT AND THE ECONOMY Frictional unemployment is inevitable and natural for any economy as people change jobs and businesses open and close. Structural unemployment is typically caused by changes in consumer demands or technology. It is typically of long duration and often requires that the unemployed become retrained for new jobs. Cyclical unemployment is the result of changes in the business cycle. When a recession hits, unemployment rises, then falls when an expansion ensues. Macroeconomic policies have the most effect on cyclical unemployment. Full employment is typically defined as that level at which cyclical unemployment is zero or that level associated with a low nonaccelerating inflation rate.
QUESTION: The financial industry experienced a rapid expansion in the middle of the last decade as a
result of the housing bubble, which created jobs for millions of workers in banks, mortgage companies, financial advising companies, and insurance companies. When the bubble burst, many of these workers became unemployed as the financial industry retrenched. For many, their skills were so specialized that they were unable to find new jobs at their old salaries. Were these people frictionally, structurally, or cyclically unemployed? Explain. Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
285
chapter summary Section 1 Inflation Inflation is a general rise in prices throughout the economy. Prices for individual goods can fluctuate up or down, but the price level captures the overall trend in the movement of prices.
6.1
How Inflation Is Measured Consumer price index (CPI): An index of the average change in prices of a market basket of consumer goods and services. Producer price index (PPI): An index of the average change in prices received by producers for their output. GDP deflator: The broadest index used to measure inflation; it includes the prices of all goods and services in the economy.
6.2
Calculating Inflation Using the CPI CPI = (Cost in current period) ÷ (Cost in base period) × 100 Example: Suppose a market basket consists of pizza and soda Base year prices:
Pizza = $6 and Soda = $2
Current year prices:
Pizza = $8 and Soda = $3
CPI = ($8 + $3) ÷ ($6 + $2) × 100 = 137.5 (average prices rose 37.5% since the base year)
286
6.3
The Main Causes of Inflation Strong consumer demand: Consumers spend more money, demand increases, and prices rise. Supply shocks on key inputs: When prices for goods with inelastic demand (such as food or oil) rise, the higher prices are passed on to other industries and to consumers. Government printing money: The government prints money to finance its borrowing, more money is chasing a relatively fixed amount of goods and services, and therefore prices rise.
A severe drought in the summer of 2012 pushed corn prices higher, leading to higher prices for many goods.
6.4
Disinflation Versus Deflation Disinflation occurs when the rate of inflation falls, but is still positive. Deflation occurs when the rate of inflation turns negative. Hyperinflation is an extremely high rate of inflation. It typically is caused by excess government spending over tax revenues (high deficits) and the printing of money to finance deficits.
287
A price list of photocopying services in Zimbabwe in 2008 during hyperinflation.
Section 2 Unemployment The labor force is the total number of people employed or unemployed. Employed persons are individuals age 16 and over who work for pay, whether full-time, part-time, or even temporary. Unemployed persons are those without jobs but actively seeking work.
6.5
6.6
Who Are NOT Considered in the Labor Force? Discouraged workers are the portion of marginally attached workers who have given up looking for work because they believe there are not enough good jobs. Marginally attached workers are those who have looked for work in the past 12 months but not in the last 4 weeks. Students who do not work are not counted in the labor force. Retired persons and children under 16 are not counted in the labor force. Institutionalized persons including persons in prison also are not counted in the labor force.
288
If you work part-time at the local coffee shop after graduation while looking for a good job, you are not unemployed. Instead, you are underemployed, which still is considered employed.
Section 3 Unemployment and the Economy 6.7
Types of Unemployment Frictional unemployment: Includes workers who voluntarily quit their jobs in search of better positions, or recent graduates seeking their first full-time job. Structural unemployment: Longer-term unemployment that is caused by changes in consumer demands or technology, and requires workers to be retrained for a career in another industry. Cyclical unemployment: Unemployment that results from the business cycle—when a recession hits, firms lay off workers until the economy recovers.
35mm film is hardly ever used anymore, and has led to structural unemployment as workers in the 35mm film industry find new employment.
6.8
The natural rate of unemployment or nonaccelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU) is the rate of unemployment that exists when prices and wages
289
are equal to people’s expectations. At the natural rate of unemployment, the economy is at “full employment.” Natural rate of unemployment = Frictional + Structural Unemployment The natural rate of unemployment is very stable in the United States, at around 5% to 6%.
KEY CONCEPTS inflation price level disinflation deflation consumer price index (CPI) producer price index (PPI) GDP deflator hyperinflation labor force underemployed workers marginally attached workers discouraged workers frictional unemployment structural unemployment cyclical unemployment natural rate of unemployment
QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS Check Your Understanding 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6.
Describe the three common indices used to measure inflation and the focus of each one. Who loses from unanticipated inflation? Who benefits? Describe the possible losses to our society and the economy when people are unemployed. What is required for a person to be considered unemployed? How is the unemployment rate computed? Why do teenagers and young people have high unemployment rates? Describe the three types of unemployment. What types of government programs would be most effective in combating each type of unemployment?
Apply the Concepts 7. You have several student loans that have interest rates that change every year. After graduation, you can consolidate these loans into a fixed-rate single loan. You can consolidate now or one year from now. How do your expectations of the inflation rate during the next year affect your decision regarding when to consolidate? 8. Suppose you work hard at a job after graduation and after your first year, your effort is rewarded with a 3% raise when the average wage increase in your company is 2%. Then, the government releases its inflation
290
9. 10.
11. 12.
report which states inflation is running at 5%. Given this information, did your standard of living improve? Why or why not? Since 1987, the U.S. population has grown 32%, while employment has increased by 39%. Further, the number of people unemployed has risen by 3%. Are all of these indicators a sign of a strong or weak labor market over the past two decades? Assume you just lost your job and have decided to take a month-long break to travel to Europe before looking for a new position. Just as you return home from your trip, you are interviewed by the Department of Labor about your employment status. How would you be classified (employed, unemployed, or not in the labor force)? Explain why. The Bureau of Labor Statistics categorizes unemployed people into several groups, including job leavers, job losers, and discouraged workers. During a mild recession, which group would tend to increase the most? During a deep recession? During a boom? In the beginning of a recovery after a recession, employment begins to rise and the news media report these data on job growth. Would such a report have an impact on the labor force? Would it affect the unemployment rate?
In The News 13. A debate that regularly occurs in Congress concerns raising the debt ceiling, allowing the U.S. government to continue paying its obligations. A few years ago, one politician proposed that instead of raising the debt ceiling, the U.S. Treasury should just mint a trillion dollar coin and use it to “pay off” the federal deficit. If such a coin were to be minted, what would be its potential effects on inflation? Is this a risk-free way of paying off a fiscal deficit? Why or why not? 14. Federal unemployment benefits were extended in 2013, allowing unemployed workers to receive up to 73 weeks of benefits depending on the unemployment rate in each state. This is an extension of a program that at its peak during the last recession offered up to a maximum of 99 weeks of unemployment benefits. How does extending the federal unemployment benefit program influence the unemployment rate?
Solving Problems
WORK IT OUT 15. Suppose the country of Snowland uses the following market basket of goods to determine its consumer price index, with Year 1 being the base year with a CPI of 100. Nominal GDP is also provided.
Market basket items
Year 1
Year 2
Year 3
Year 4
Loaf of bread
$2.50
$2.80
$3.00
$3.10
Movie ticket
$8.00
$8.80
$9.20
$9.50
Gallon of gasoline
$3.50
$4.20
$4.00
$3.60
Scented candle
$12.00
$13.20
$14.00
$14.30
Nominal GDP
$5 billion
$5.6 billion
$6.1 billion
a. Calculate the CPI in Snowland for each year, using Year 1 as the base year with CPI = 100. b. Calculate the rate of inflation (based on CPI) in Year 2, Year 3, and Year 4.
291
$6.5 billion
c. Using the CPI, calculate the real GDP in each of the four years. d. Between Year 1 and Year 4, what proportion of the total increase in nominal GDP was due to inflation?
16. The town of Villageton has 500 residents, of which 300 are employed, 30 are not working but actively seeking work, 80 are children in school, 40 are retirees, 30 are full-time college students, and 20 are institutionalized. a. Calculate the unemployment rate in Villageton. b. Suppose that 10 of the 30 college students graduate and enter the labor force actively seeking work, but only 5 find a job. How does this change the unemployment rate in Villageton?
USING THE NUMBERS 17. Using By the Numbers, describe the change in the average price of public college tuition and private college tuition relative to the overall change in prices based on CPI. Has a college education become more or less affordable in real terms? 18. By approximately what percentage did average housing prices increase from 2001 to the peak in 2006? By what percentage did average housing prices fall from the peak in 2006 to the bottom point in 2012?
ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS Checkpoint: Inflation Inflation makes the value of a dollar fall in purchasing power. Therefore, if you borrow money when inflation is low and pay back the loan when inflation is higher, the money you are paying back is worth less than what you received. You benefit by being able to pay back your loans with money that is valued at less than before. Thus, unexpected inflation hurts lenders because the money they are being paid back is worth less in purchasing power than they had planned. Alternatively, had the inflation rate unexpectedly fallen, lenders would gain, as the money being paid back would be worth more in purchasing power than was expected. Checkpoint: Unemployment The reason for the requirement that a person actively seek work is to differentiate empirically those who profess to want a job (at possibly a higher wage than they can earn in the market) from those who are actively trying to obtain work. Checkpoint: Unemployment and the Economy Many workers became structurally unemployed because the skills they had acquired for the financial industry (and in many cases, specific to the housing industry) were not as useful in other industries. Therefore, as the financial industry became smaller after the housing bubble burst, many workers needed to find work in other industries, which required learning a new skills set. 1From
the BLS Web site.
2U.S.
Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Employment from the BLS Household and Payroll Surveys: Summary of Recent Trends, 2016, http://www.bls.gov.
292
7
Economic Growth
293
Understanding the importance of economic growth and the factors that drive it 294
Learning Objectives 7.1
Describe how economic growth is measured using real GDP and real GDP per capita.
7.2
Use the Rule of 70 to approximate the number of years it takes for an economy’s output to double in size.
7.3
Explain the power of compounding in making small differences much larger over time.
7.4
Explain the difference between short-run and long-run growth.
7.5
List the four factors of production and how each plays a role in the production function.
7.6
Discuss the factors that increase productivity and economic growth.
7.7
Explain total factor productivity and what it measures.
7.8
Explain how the government promotes economic growth through the provision of physical capital and the enhancement of human capital and technology.
7.9
Discuss how strong institutions and economic freedom facilitates economic growth.
O
n a typical downtown street in Beijing in the 1980s, one would see thousands of bicycles and pedestrians among a trickling of cars owned by the privileged few. The skyline consisted of just a few large buildings.
How times have changed. Today, the bicycles in Beijing have largely been replaced with cars driven by millions of Chinese (now the world’s largest consumers of cars) whose incomes have increased enough to afford one, the skyline is dominated by modern skyscrapers, and the pedestrians have largely moved underground, traveling on one of the world’s most extensive and modern subway systems. China’s transformation from a poor, agricultural nation to an emerging world power with a growing middle and upper class has been remarkable. China’s annual growth rate has averaged 9% over the past 20 years, compared to the average U.S. annual growth rate of 2% over the same period. Although a 7% difference might not seem significant, over 20 years the cumulative growth effect is staggering: China’s real GDP grew 521% from 1995 to 2015, while in the United States, real GDP grew 62%. Economic growth plays a very powerful role in how people live and how standards of living change over time. Even small differences in growth rates turn into large differences in the long run. One generation ago, the United States, Europe, and the East Asian economies of Japan, Singapore, South Korea, Taiwan, and Hong Kong were the leaders of economic growth. These countries had consistent, strong growth, while the rest of the world lagged behind. Today, a much different picture emerges. Some developing countries are experiencing the highest rates of growth, while those in the developed world have seen slower growth rates, especially in the aftermath of the devastating financial crisis and recession of 2007–2009. During the 2000s, much of the world’s global economic growth was concentrated in the BRIC countries: Brazil, Russia, India, and China. These countries transformed from developing economies to more advanced economies, and
295
by doing so achieved a remarkable feat: In 2015 all four countries were among the ten largest economies in the world, measured by GDP. Chang’an Avenue, Beijing (1981)
Chang’an Avenue, Beijing (2011)
296
297
But rapid growth in any country cannot be maintained forever. Although India continued to maintain a high growth rate of over 7% in 2016, China’s economy has slowed in recent years, from an average annual growth rate of nearly 10% just a few years ago to less than 7% in 2016. Even worse, Russia’s and Brazil’s economy both entered into recessions in 2015—Russia largely due to the significant drop in oil prices that affected the entire economy, and Brazil due to the fall in prices of other commodities such as coffee, sugar, and metals. Meanwhile, growth in the United States continues at a slow pace, averaging around 2% per year. Where, then, are today’s beacons of growth? They are concentrated in developing countries in Africa and Central/South Asia, including Ethiopia, Turkmenistan, Myanmar, and Ivory Coast, all of which are growing faster than China and India. This bodes well for bringing many more people out of poverty, just as the BRIC countries have done over the past decade. This chapter focuses on long-term economic growth and describes the conditions needed to sustain economic growth and improve standards of living. In the long run, all variables in the economy can adjust to changing conditions. The models in this chapter provide a framework for evaluating policies meant to encourage economic growth in the long run.
298
WHY IS ECONOMIC GROWTH IMPORTANT? Economic growth is tied closely to how well people live. We already saw how a high growth rate in China changed the lives of much of its population—more people now can buy cars, computers, and other goods that previously were either unavailable or unaffordable. Economic growth improves the lives of people of all income levels, from the richest to the poorest citizens. economic growth Usually measured by the annual percentage change in real GDP, reflecting an improvement in the standard of living.
The benefits of economic growth extend beyond the goods people can buy. For example, economic growth leads to lower poverty rates and longer life expectancies as people can afford better medical care, more nutritious diets, and more leisure to reduce stress. The data speak for themselves. In 1980 the average life expectancies (females and males combined) in China and India were 67 and 54 years, respectively. In 2016 they were 75 and 68 years, respectively. Children born in China and India today can expect to live about a decade longer, on average, than their parents. Still, according to estimates by the World Bank, over a billion people in the world live on less than $1.25 per day, and over 2 billion people live on less than $2 per day. However, the number of people living on these amounts has fallen from their peaks as many countries, such as the BRIC nations which make up over 40% of the world’s population, saw economic growth rates improve over the past two decades. This section analyzes how economic growth is measured and how the power of compounding, in which growth builds upon prior growth, can turn small rates of growth into substantial increases in outcome and income over time, leading to better lives for all. compounding The ability of growth to build on previous growth. It allows variables such as income and GDP (as well as debt) to increase significantly over time.
How Is Economic Growth Measured?
Small differences in growth can lead to dramatic differences in income due to the effect of compounding. To show this, we first have to measure economic growth, using the concepts of gross domestic product (GDP) and GDP per capita introduced in an earlier chapter. As we saw, GDP is a measure of the total value of final goods and services produced in a country in one year, or simply a country’s total annual output. GDP per capita is a country’s GDP divided by its population, and provides a rough measure of a typical person’s standard of living. Also, recall that real GDP and real GDP per capita use constant dollars to remove the effects of inflation, allowing for more accurate comparisons in output from year to year. real GDP The total value of final goods and services produced in a country in a year measured using prices in a base year. real GDP per capita Real GDP divided by population. Provides a rough estimate of a country’s standard of living.
When a country’s real GDP per capita increases, the average output per person is increasing (rather than just prices), and this generally translates into a higher standard of living for most of its residents. Therefore, this is a good indicator of how an economy grows over time.
TABLE 1
1st quarter
COMPARING REAL GDP GROWTH DATA IN 2015 Annualized GDP Growth Rate
Year-Over-Year Growth Rate
+ 0.6%
+ 2.9%
299
2nd quarter
+ 3.9%
+ 2.7%
3rd quarter
+ 2.1%
+ 2.1%
4th quarter
+ 0.7%
+ 1.8%
Data from BEA Interactive Tables: GDP and the National Income and Product Accounts.
In the United States, real GDP is measured by the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA). The BEA produces quarterly reports on the changes in U.S. GDP from the previous quarter, and is reported as an annualized rate (quarterly change multiplied by 4). For example, in January 2016, the BEA reported that the U.S. economy grew 0.7% in the fourth quarter of 2015. This means that real GDP in the United States increased 0.175% from the third quarter of 2015 to the fourth quarter of 2015, which equals a rise of 0.7% when annualized. In addition, the BEA provides GDP growth data year-over-year. For example, the BEA reported that the U.S. economy grew 1.8% from the fourth quarter of 2014 to the fourth quarter of 2015. Why does the BEA report yearover-year growth? Year-over-year growth allows investors and policymakers to compare how the economy has grown over an entire 12-month period, without the seasonal ups and downs most economies experience. Table 1 shows the quarterly real GDP growth rates in 2015 using the annualized and year-over-year methods. The Annualized column shows the seasonal fluctuations that influenced economic growth each quarter, while the Year-Over-Year column shows the growth rate for the preceding 12 months. Both measures are useful depending on whether one is analyzing trends in economic performance for a particular season or for the entire year.
Small Differences in Growth Lead to Large Differences in Income Over Time When we think of a stark contrast in living standards, we need look no further than the U.S.–Mexican border. For example, driving along Interstate 10 in El Paso, Texas (which is less than 200 yards from the border at its closest point), one can see tremendous differences in the quality of housing in Mexico versus that in the United States. Yet, how did such a difference in standard of living occur? Did the U.S. economy grow that much faster? The surprising answer is that the U.S. growth rate over the past 100 years averaged just 1% higher than Mexico’s growth rate. Perhaps more surprising is that Mexico’s real GDP per capita is above average in the world. Even Mexico appears “rich” to countries such as Nicaragua and Honduras, whose real GDP per capita is only about one-fourth that of Mexico. If growth rates did not differ much between the United States and Mexico, or between Mexico and Nicaragua over the past century, why are the economies of these countries so different? The answer is the power of compounding growth. The border between the United States and Mexico offers a glimpse at the sharp contrast between two nations with different growth paths.
300
Power of Compounding Growth Rates
Suppose you deposit $1,000 in a high-interest money market account that averages 10% in interest per year. If you simply let the interest accrue without adding any additional money to the account, that $1,000 would turn into $28,102 in 35 years. How is that possible? Money earns interest, in this case 10%. But interest also earns interest. In fact, jump ahead 34 years, when your $1,000 is worth $25,548. In year 35, earning 10% on $25,548 equals over $2,500 in interest, bringing your total to $28,102. In that year, you earned over 2.5 times more in interest than the $1,000 you originally put in. That is the power of compounding growth. Suppose instead that your money grew at 5% per year. What do you think the return will be? One-half of the 10% amount of $28,102? No . . . saving $1,000 at 5% would result in a total value of $5,516 in 35 years, significantly less than half of the $28,102 had the interest rate been 10%. This example shows that small differences in interest result in big changes over time. Suppose that your money grew at 9%, just 1% less than 10%. Your $1,000 would be worth $20,414 in 35 years, a drop of almost $8,000 over this period. These numerical examples highlight the importance of small differences in growth between the United States and Mexico over time. By growing just 1% faster over a 100-year period, two countries can end up having real GDP per capita several times apart (about 4 times in the case of the United States and Mexico and about 4 times between Mexico and Nicaragua). Over the past 100 years, the United States grew 2% a year on average, Mexico grew 1.2% a year on average, and Nicaragua grew 0.3% a year on average. Doubling the interest rate on a $1,000 deposit generates over 5 times more earnings over 35 years.
301
Rule of 70
Calculating compounding growth over a long period requires the use of a formula and calculator. Luckily, there is an easy way to approximate the number of years it takes for an amount to double in value by using the Rule of 70. The Rule of 70 states that the number of years required for a value (such as a nation’s GDP) to double in size is equal to 70 divided by the growth rate: Number of Years to Double Value = 70/Growth Rate Rule of 70 Provides an estimate of the number of years for a value to double, and is calculated as 70 divided by the annual growth rate.
For example, if the growth rate is 10%, it would take about 70/10 = 7 years for an initial value of $1,000 to double to $2,000, another 7 years (or 14 years total) to double again to $4,000, another 7 years (or 21 years total) to double again to $8,000, and so on. The Rule of 70 is fairly accurate for small growth rates. For larger growth rates, especially above 10%, the Rule of 70 becomes slightly less accurate over time. Table 2 provides a comparison between actual values and estimated values using the Rule of 70 for 5% and 10% growth rates. The smaller growth rate keeps the Rule of 70 estimated values closer to the actual values than the larger growth rate. Although the Rule of 70 does not provide an exact estimate of compounded values over time, its ease of use makes it a valuable tool in understanding the power of compounding growth rates over time. In all examples so far, we have shown how compounding growth can lead to much improved lives over time. However, it is also important to note that the reverse can be true. The compounding effect also makes debts significantly larger over time.
TABLE 2
ACCURACY OF THE RULE OF 70 5% Growth Rate
Initial:
10% Growth Rate
Actual
Using Rule of 70
Actual
Using Rule of 70
$1,000
$1,000
$1,000
$1,000
302
14 years:
$1,979
$2,000
$3,797
$4,000
28 years:
$3,920
$4,000
$14,421
$16,000
ISSUE Can Economic Growth Bring a Billion People Out of Poverty? Poverty is a global concern. Although definitions of poverty vary from country to country, the World Bank defines extreme poverty as a person living on less than $1.90 per day (in real, inflation-adjusted dollars). According to World Bank estimates, in 1990 over 2 billion people in the world lived in extreme poverty. Twenty-five years later, that number had been cut in half. This drop in extreme poverty is even more remarkable considering that the world’s population grew from 5.3 billion to 7.1 billion over this period. How did over a billion people find themselves no longer in extreme poverty? Much of the drop can be attributed to economic growth in developing countries such as China and India, and more recently, countries in Africa. In China alone, 25 years of solid growth pulled more than 600 million people above the extreme poverty threshold. Although average wages remain low compared to those in the United States or Europe, a typical factory worker making $500 per month can live a modest life in China, where the cost of living is significantly lower, and clearly a better life than in 1990 when average monthly wages were only $20 per month. India is another country that has seen significant reductions in extreme poverty. Although poverty rates remain much higher in India than in China, India’s growth rate of over 7% led to tens of millions exiting poverty each year. And since 2005, many countries in Africa have begun seeing their poverty rates fall, as greater investment in natural resource industries has led to strong economic growth on the mineral-and oil-rich continent. Clearly, economic growth is a powerful factor, even during times of economic downturn. Even during the 2007–2009 global economic downturn, when poverty based on higher thresholds in the United States and in Europe increased, extreme poverty as defined by the $1.90 per day threshold continued to fall. The World Bank announced in 2013 a goal of ending extreme poverty by 2030. Economic growth is arguably the most important contributor to reducing extreme poverty worldwide. Yet, not all problems with poverty have been resolved. First, while extreme poverty has fallen precipitously, poverty as defined by higher income thresholds has dropped less than 20% since 1990. In other words, while much progress has been made to eliminate extreme poverty, nearly a third of the world’s population remains very poor.
303
Strong economic growth in India over the past 25 years has brought hundreds of millions of people out of poverty, allowing a much more comfortable life for the next generation. Hence, economic growth remains one of the most important, if not the most important, macroeconomic objective pursued by policymakers in order to continue the progress of reducing poverty worldwide. Information from “World Bank Forecasts Global Poverty to Fall Below 10% for First Time; Major Hurdles Remain in Goal to End Poverty by 2030,” the World Bank, October 4, 2015.
Do you keep a balance on a credit card? If so, you’re not alone. The average American household carries about $16,000 in credit card balances each month. Most credit cards charge interest rates on unpaid balances between 12% and 18%, some even more. Suppose an individual has $15,000 in debt at a 17.5% interest rate. If no payments are made on this debt (let’s assume a minimum monthly payment is not required), the Rule of 70 says that the debt will double about every 4 years (70/17.5). If no payments are made on this debt, that $16,000 will turn into $32,000 in 4 years, $64,000 in 8 years, $128,000 in 12 years, and $256,000 in 16 years. Paying off credit card balances can lead to significant savings over time. In sum, the power of compounding means that policies aimed at increasing the annual rate of economic growth can have powerful long-run effects, resulting in some countries becoming rich while others that do not achieve such growth remain poor. The benefits of economic growth are highlighted through the remarkable rise in income over time that leads to a higher standard of living for all citizens. But what exactly spurs economic growth? That is a question we answer in the next section.
CHECKPOINT WHY IS ECONOMIC GROWTH IMPORTANT? Economic growth is measured by the increase in real GDP and real GDP per capita. In the United States, it is measured by the BEA on a quarterly basis as an annualized percentage change as well as a year-over-year change. Small differences in growth rates translate into large differences in output and income over time.
304
Just a 1% difference in growth over time can make one country appear rich and another country appear poor. The Rule of 70 provides an easy way to approximate the number of years required for a value to double.
QUESTIONS: In 2016 the average Chinese manufacturing worker earned about $6,000 a year, while
the average U.S. manufacturing worker earned $48,000 a year. Suppose that the U.S. growth rate is 3% per year (income doubles about every 24 years using the Rule of 70), while China’s growth rate is 7% per year (income doubles about every 10 years using the Rule of 70). If these growth rates do not change, in what year would the typical Chinese worker earn $48,000 a year? In what year would the typical Chinese worker catch up to the American worker if U.S. wages continue to increase by 3% per year? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
305
THINKING ABOUT SHORT-RUN AND LONG-RUN ECONOMIC GROWTH Up to this point, we have discussed why economic growth is good and how it is measured. Next, we need to discuss the differences between short-run and long-run growth and the factors that determine economic growth.
Short-Run Versus Long-Run Growth
The first step to understanding how growth occurs is to understand the difference between short-run and long-run growth.
Short-Run Growth Involves a Fixed Capacity
Short-run growth occurs when an economy makes use of existing but underutilized resources. For example, abandoned shopping centers or malls could easily be reopened with new stores. Idle construction equipment and unemployed workers could quickly be put into use on a new project. In these cases, the resources to produce goods and services are available but are not being used. Short-run growth is common when countries are recovering from an economic downturn, or when obstacles preventing resources from being fully used (such as restrictions on land use or high mandatory benefits for workers) are loosened. But to sustain growth beyond the small fluctuations common in the business cycle, efforts to expand an economy’s ability to produce are necessary. This leads to long-run growth.
Long-Run Growth Involves Expanding Capacity
Long-run growth occurs when an economy finds new resources or improved ways to use existing resources. In other words, the capacity to produce goods and services increases, leading to long-run growth. For example, suppose natural gas deposits that are estimated to be abundant in the United States are explored, leading to an expansion in production of natural gas–powered vehicles (NGVs). This may lead to an expansion of production capacity in the United States through the reduction of its dependence on foreign oil and through the development of more environmentally friendly cars. In a previous chapter, we introduced production possibilities frontiers (PPF) to illustrate the maximum productive capacity of an economy if all resources are fully utilized. We now use PPF diagrams to show the difference between short-run and long-run economic growth. FIGURE 1
SHORT-RUN VERSUS LONG-RUN GROWTH ILLUSTRATED ON PPF DIAGRAMS
306
Short-run economic growth occurs when underutilized resources are placed into production. In a PPF diagram, this is shown as a movement from a point inside the PPF to a point closer to or on the PPF (such as from a to b). Long-run economic growth occurs when new resources are found or existing resources are used more efficiently, thus expanding an economy’s capacity to produce. In this case, PPFA expands outward to PPFB, allowing for more production possibilities.
In Figure 1, the left panel shows an economy initially producing at point a inside of its PPF, indicating underutilized resources such as idle equipment or excess labor. By putting these resources to work, an economy can work toward production capacity on the PPF line at point b, representing short-run growth. Long-run growth, illustrated in the right panel, requires an economy to find new resources such as new natural resources or improved human capital in its workforce, or new ideas to make better use of existing resources. Such improvements in production capacity will shift PPFA outward to PPFB, allowing for more production possibilities.
Factors of Production Achieving long-run growth requires an economy to acquire new resources or to find better ways to use the resources it has to generate goods and services people desire either domestically or abroad through trade. These resources are categorized into the four factors of production, which are the building blocks for production and economic growth. Let’s review these factors of production. The United States has been called the “Saudi Arabia of Natural Gas” due to its abundance of natural gas deposits.
307
1. Land and natural resources (denoted as N) include land and any raw resources that come from land, such as mineral deposits, oil, natural gas, and water. 2. Labor (denoted as L) includes both the mental and physical talents of people. Human capital (denoted as H) includes the improvements to labor capabilities from training, education, and apprenticeship programs. 3. Physical capital (denoted as K) includes all manufactured products that are used to produce other goods and services. This includes machinery used in factories, cash registers in stores and restaurants, and
308
communications networks used to track shipments. 4. Entrepreneurial ability and ideas, or technology (A) describe the ability to take resources and use them in creative ways to produce goods and services. For example, technology improves the productivity of all factors, and therefore is considered a highly valuable input in production. In other words, land, labor, and physical capital are not useful unless the idea of how to turn these resources into goods and services people want exists. When factors of production are used to produce goods and services useful for consumption, a measurement tool is needed to calculate the extent to which inputs (resources) are turned into outputs (goods and services). The relationship between the amount of inputs used in production and the amount of output produced is called a production function.
Production Function A production function shows the output that is produced using different combinations of inputs combined with existing technology. Although many types of production functions exist, most are variations of the classical form: Output = f(L, K), which means that output is determined by some function of available labor and capital. production function Measures the output that is produced using various combinations of inputs and a fixed level of technology.
Every country, industry, and even firm can have a different production function that measures how much output it can produce given the physical inputs and technology available. No two countries will produce exactly the same type or amount of products given the resources they have. Thus, a production function is a very important tool used to determine whether a country is using its limited resources efficiently and to what extent it can experience long-run growth. Suppose f(L, K) = L + K for simplicity. This means that if an economy has 10 units of labor and 10 units of capital, total output would equal 10 + 10 = 20. Although most production functions are not this simple, the idea is that more inputs can produce more output by some function. Because inputs are not limited to just labor and capital, a more realistic production function would look like the following: Output = A × f(L, K, H, N) where total output equals technology (A) times a function of available labor (L), physical capital (K), human capital (H), and land and natural resources (N). This equation helps to explain how an entire economy grows. For example, having a more educated labor force or having more capital will contribute to higher productive capacity of the economy (shifting the PPF outward). But what we are truly interested in is how growth affects the lives of people living in those countries. For example, India’s GDP has grown at a very fast pace, but so has its population. The important question is how economic growth affects the standard of living of the average person, or output per person. One way to achieve a close (but not exact) measure of output per person is to revise the previous production function to one that measures output per worker. To do so, assume that the production function exhibits constant returns to scale (a reasonable assumption). This means that any proportional change in the number of inputs results in the same proportional change in output. For example, if we divide all inputs by L, we would be able to calculate the output per worker as follows: Output per worker = A × f(L/L, K/L, H/L, N/L) This equation shows that output per worker equals technology times a function of physical capital per worker, human capital per worker, and land and natural resources per worker. Because we are concerned with output per worker, having more people will not automatically lead to a better standard of living (hence, L/L = 1). However, having more capital per person or more human capital (education) will increase the productivity of labor as each worker produces more output. Therefore, increases in capital will lead to improved standards of living. To this point, we have discussed the importance of economic growth and defined the building blocks for
309
economic growth using the factors of production that enter into the production function. The next section will use the production function to discuss ways in which an economy achieves growth by way of increasing productivity.
CHECKPOINT THINKING ABOUT SHORT-RUN AND LONG-RUN ECONOMIC GROWTH Short-run growth occurs from using resources that have been sitting idle or underutilized, and is represented in a PPF diagram as a movement from a point within the PPF toward the PPF. Long-run growth occurs when the productive capacity of an economy is expanded through more resources or better uses of existing resources (i.e., technological advancements), and is shown in a PPF diagram as an outward shift of the PPF. The primary factors of production are land and natural resources, labor (and human capital), physical capital, and technology (entrepreneurial ability and ideas). A production function measures the amount of output that can be produced using different combinations of inputs. Production functions vary by firms, industries, and countries. Output per person adjusts the production function for changes in population growth in a country.
QUESTION: The Ivory Coast (Côte d’Ivoire) in West Africa is a country with abundant natural resources, a long coastline, and a stable currency that is tied to the euro and managed by the French Treasury. Despite these benefits, it remains an extremely poor country with an unstable government. What does this finding suggest about the Ivory Coast’s overall factors of production and its production function compared to a country, say, Iceland, with fewer physical resources but a significantly higher standard of living? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
310
APPLYING THE PRODUCTION FUNCTION: ACHIEVING ECONOMIC GROWTH The production function allows us to measure how inputs are converted into outputs. The extent to which inputs are converted into outputs is referred to as productivity. For example, when worker productivity grows, each worker is producing more output for each hour devoted to production. productivity How effectively inputs are converted into outputs. Labor productivity is the ratio of the output of goods and services to the labor hours devoted to the production of that output. Productivity and living standards are closely related.
Productivity is a key driver of wages and incomes. The primary reason that the American standard of living is so high is that American workers produce more per hour than do workers in most other countries. Many people in the developing world eke out a living using tools that would remind us of an earlier century. This lower productivity is reflected in their lower standard of living. The factors of production discussed in the previous section play an important role in increasing economic growth. As the quantity of each factor rises, output rises according to the production function for each industry. In addition, technology plays an important role in enhancing the productive output of all other resources. A country’s output is measured by the value of the goods and services it produces, which can increase based on their quantity or quality. In other words, highly productive countries are able to produce many goods that are high in value. One reason why Japan remains one of the world’s richest countries is that its labor force is highly productive. Using abundant capital, human capital, and technology, Japan’s labor force produces many high-priced products such as cars, robots, and advanced electronics. Let’s look at each factor of production in turn to examine what increases productivity and economic growth.
Achieving More Land or Natural Resources
Natural resources are the building blocks of production; however, they are not a significant driver of economic growth. Countries that are abundant in land and natural resources have an advantage that can translate into economic growth only if such resources are used effectively. Countries that discovered new natural resources have experienced higher rates of growth. For example, new oil deposits have been discovered in Angola and Cameroon over the past decade. These discoveries led to significant investment by oil companies from China, India, and the United States in these countries, which contributed to a higher growth rate.
Growth of the Labor Force Many countries have experienced significant population growth, leading to an increase in the labor supply. In the United States, population growth has been spurred by a relatively open immigration policy compared to other countries. In addition to population growth, labor force participation increased over the last few decades, as more women entered the workforce and as government policies were implemented to make work more attractive. An increase in the labor force generally leads to greater output, but not necessarily more output per person. In order for economic growth to improve the standard of living of its citizens, countries must expand not only the quantity of its labor force, but also the quality of labor to ensure that economic growth exceeds population growth.
Increasing the Quality of the Labor Force
One source of productivity growth comes from improvements to the labor force from investment in human capital. Human capital is a term economists use to describe skills, knowledge, and the quality of workers. On-the-job training
311
and general education can improve the quality of labor. In many ways, increasing capital and a highly skilled labor force go together. Well-trained workers are needed to run the highly productive, often highly complex, machines. Unskilled workers are given the least important jobs and earn the lowest wages. investment in human capital Improvements to the labor force from investments in skills, knowledge, and the overall quality of workers and their productivity.
By investing in human capital, nations can ultimately raise their growth rates by improving worker productivity. Government programs that raise the literacy rate, such as universal public education, also raise the rate of economic growth.
Increasing the Capital-to-Labor Ratio When a farmer in the small Himalayan country of Bhutan plows his field with a crude plow hitched to a couple of yaks, the amount of land he can plant and harvest is minuscule. American farmers, in contrast, use equipment that allows them to plow, plant, fertilize, water, and harvest thousands of acres; they have a high capital-to-labor ratio. This raises U.S. farm productivity many orders of magnitude above that of Bhutanese farmers. The ultimate result of this productivity is that American farmers earn a far higher income than their counterparts in the developing world. capital-to-labor ratio The capital employed per worker. A higher ratio means higher labor productivity and, as a result, higher wages.
Developing countries have large labor forces, but little capital. Developed nations like the United States, on the other hand, have limited labor supplies, and each worker works with a large array of capital equipment. As a rule, the more capital employed by workers, the greater their productivity and the higher their earnings. Although a powerful contributor to productivity, capital is subject to diminishing returns to capital. For example, suppose that the farmer in Bhutan buys a tractor to replace his yaks. The increase in productivity would be dramatic. Now suppose that the farmer invests in an irrigation system. Surely, the irrigation system will further increase productivity, but likely not as much as the tractor did. In other words, a farmer is likely to purchase the most essential equipment first. Each subsequent piece of equipment will increase production but by a smaller amount than the previous one. For this reason, countries with abundant capital will not gain as much per additional piece of capital than countries with little capital with which to start. This is one reason why developing countries may initially grow faster than developed countries, a phenomenon called the catch-up effect. diminishing returns to capital Each additional unit of capital provides a smaller increase in output than the previous unit of capital.
The catch-up effect describes the notion that developing countries are able to achieve greater productivity for each unit of capital invested because they have the advantage of using technologies that have already been developed by other countries. This has allowed many developing countries to achieve a higher rate of growth compared to developed countries. catch-up effect Countries with smaller starting levels of capital experience larger benefits from increased capital, allowing these countries to grow faster than countries with abundant capital.
An example of the catch-up effect is China’s expanding high-speed rail network. High-speed rail networks were largely invented and perfected by the Japanese, Germans, and French. However, large development costs required substantial government subsidies. China, on the other hand, had the advantage of building its rail network using existing technologies. As a result, China was able to expand its rail network at a lower price per mile, allowing it to catch up and to develop an even more advanced rail network than its predecessors. But because all factors face diminishing returns, the catch-up effect tends to slow over time unless new technologies are developed to keep the growth rate high.
312
Using expensive tractors and other capital equipment, U.S. farmers are more productive than Bhutanese farmers who rely on wooden plows pulled by yaks.
THOMAS MALTHUS (1766–1834)
T
homas Malthus was raised in Surrey, England, the son of a wealthy eccentric country gentleman. Home-schooled by his father and a tutor, he had learned enough to be accepted to Cambridge University. After attending Cambridge, he spent several years as a clergyman before accepting a teaching post in political economy at the college of the East India Company, making him the first academic economist in history. In 1793 the pamphleteer William Godwin published Political Justice, describing a utopian future with no war, poverty, crime, injustice, or disease. Malthus argued against the book’s conclusions during a lengthy discussion with his father, who agreed with the book, but nevertheless suggested that Malthus set down his ideas in print. The result was “An Essay on the Principle of Population As It Affects the Future Improvement of Society.” Malthus argued that the origins of poverty were rooted in an unavoidable contradiction: Population, when allowed to grow without limits, increases geometrically, while the food supply could only increase arithmetically. He argued that English Poor Laws spread pauperism because any improvement in conditions of the poor would simply lead to population increases and to rising food prices and scarcities. He even went so far as to suggest that “a proclamation should be read out at marriage ceremonies warning couples that they would have to bear the financial burden and consequences of their passion.” His dire predictions about world starvation led Thomas Carlyle a few decades later to describe the economics profession as the “Dismal Science.” Although the predictions of inadequate food supply did not fully materialize due to the invention of agricultural technologies and fertilizer, the “Dismal Science” remains today as an alternative name for economics. Information from Paul Strathern, A Brief History of Economic Genius (New York: Texere), 2002; Howard Marshall, The Great Economists: A History of Economic Thought (New York: Pitman Publishing), 1967; Donald Winch, “Malthus,” in Three Great Economists (Oxford: Oxford University Press), 1997, pp. 105–218.
Improvements in Technology and Ideas
Technological improvements can come from various sources and play the major role in improving productivity, raising the standard of living, and increasing economic growth. These include enterprising individuals who discover
313
innovative products and production methods, from Henry Ford’s auto assembly line to Steve Jobs’s role in developing the Apple home computer, iPod, iPhone, and iPad that have changed the way we live, work, and socialize. Technology has also improved as a result of advancements in telecommunications, the Internet, and biotechnology. Technological progress is the primary explanation for the extraordinary economic growth the United States has enjoyed over the last century. In the production function, technology enhances the productive capacity of all other resources. Technologies that kept our economy expanding have also helped many other countries to grow. In the developing world, growth most often comes from foreign companies building factories that employ locals at low wages. These companies often pay more than workers could have hoped to earn on their own. These higher earnings become the resources invested to ensure better education and earnings for their children. Today, new technologies are helping many developing nations accelerate their growth. Wireless service has improved communications, inexpensive vaccinations and health education programs have reduced mortality rates, and the global movement of capital and production facilities has created new job opportunities.
Including Everything Else: Total Factor Productivity We have shown that productivity can be measured by how well a country uses its resources to produce goods and services. However, a country’s productivity is not entirely dependent on the amount of inputs it has. True, a country with more inputs such as physical and human capital will likely produce more output. However, external factors influence the ability of inputs to be used effectively. The measure of output that is not explained by the number of inputs used in production is called total factor productivity. total factor productivity The portion of output produced that is not explained by the number of inputs used in production.
Total factor productivity captures the factors that influence the overall effectiveness of inputs. For example, suppose a major hurricane sweeps through a region, knocking out power and communications for a week. Factories would likely be less productive despite having all of their workers and equipment available. Some equipment might not be able to run without electricity, and the morale of workers after a hurricane might make them less motivated to work. Such effects on output would not be captured by the number of inputs available.
Kazakhstan: The Next Destination of Growth and Trade What policies did the government of Kazakhstan implement to promote economic growth over the past decade?
W
hen one thinks of cities experiencing significant economic growth and trade, cities such as Hong Kong, Dubai, and Shanghai often come to mind. But in terms of rapidly growing cities, one city in Central Asia has been overlooked by many: Astana, the capital of Kazakhstan. How did this large country relatively unknown to Americans become a beacon of growth? Kazakhstan is a melting pot of ethnic cultures, from Russians to Kazakhs who look more like East Asians. Once lampooned by British comedian Sasha Cohen in the movie Borat as an impoverished backward nation, Kazakhstan is quite the opposite today. Upon arrival in the capital of Astana, one encounters hundreds of construction cranes as new skyscrapers dot the changing city landscape. Kazakhstan is also home to the Russian Federal Space Agency, where Soyuz flights regularly take off and land in the desert steppe at Baikonur Cosmodrome, which today remains the oldest and largest space
314
launch facility in the world.
The emphasis on growth in Kazakhstan can be attributed to several key factors. One surely is abundant natural resources, such as oil. More important are an emphasis on higher education, encouragement of international trade, and significant investment in infrastructure and technology, all backed by government policies. These government efforts attracted significant foreign investment from countries around the world, including the United States. These efforts have resulted in strong economic growth in Kazakhstan, which today has the highest average income in Central Asia. A stroll through the modern streets of Astana and Almaty (the former capital and home to most historical sights) points to the powerful role that economic growth has on improving the lives of a country’s citizens.
GO TO
TO PRACTICE THE ECONOMIC CONCEPTS IN THIS STORY
Another factor affecting total factor productivity is the value of new innovations, which increases the efficiency of inputs used in production. For example, social media were originally designed to allow individuals to communicate better with one another through sites such as Facebook and Twitter. However, an external effect occurred when firms began to use these sites to market their products, which led to a dramatic change in how people learn about various products and improved the efficiency of production and consumption. Total factor productivity also is influenced by the institutions in place within a country. For example, a country can have a very educated labor force but policies in place that prevent its human capital from being used efficiently. The country could be engaged in frequent military conflicts, preventing its resources from being used to improve the lives of its citizens. Or, a country may have a weak legal system or property rights, or a lack of economic freedom that prevents its markets from producing what people want. These institutional factors are largely influenced by the government. In the next section, we discuss government’s role in fostering economic growth.
CHECKPOINT APPLYING THE PRODUCTION FUNCTION: ACHIEVING ECONOMIC GROWTH Productivity is the key driver for economic growth, and rises when labor is able to produce greater quantities and higher values of output. Increased productivity of labor can come from increases in land and natural resources, the quality of the labor force, the capital-to-labor ratio, and technology. Physical capital is subjected to diminishing returns, which allows countries with less starting capital to experience a catch-up effect as they acquire more capital.
315
Total factor productivity measures the portion of output that is not explained by the amount of inputs placed in use. It captures the external effects that influence the productivity of all inputs.
QUESTION: Several years ago, Warren Buffett, one of the world’s richest individuals, pledged that “more than 99% of my wealth will go to philanthropy during my lifetime or at death” and noted that he would give this approximately $30 billion in installments to the Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation. The foundation focuses on grants to developing nations, helping the poorest of the poor. What suggestions would you give the foundation to help these developing nations grow? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
316
THE ROLE OF GOVERNMENT IN PROMOTING ECONOMIC GROWTH Government plays an important role in how well a country utilizes its resources in production. The policies and incentives put into place affect a country’s total factor productivity. Now we discuss some of the key ways in which government plays a role in influencing productivity.
Government as a Contributor to Physical Capital, Human Capital, and Technology
The government is the single largest consumer of goods and services in the United States. Each year, the U.S. government spends over $350 billion on purchases including highways, bridges, transportation systems, public education, military equipment, and more. By investing heavily in capital goods, the government promotes a higher level of labor productivity in the country.
Physical Capital: Public Capital and Private Investment
One of the reasons why some nations are rich and others are poor lies in the different levels of infrastructure development. The focus on infrastructure means that there is something important that lies behind our aggregate production: We do not just increase capital, increase labor, improve technology, and turn a crank to obtain economic growth. Infrastructure is defined as a country’s public capital. It includes dams, roads, and bridges; transportation networks, such as air and rail lines; power-generating plants and power transmission lines; telecommunications networks; and public education facilities. These items are tangible public goods that can easily be measured. All are crucial for economic growth. infrastructure The public capital of a nation, including transportation networks, power-generating plants and transmission facilities, public education institutions, and other intangible resources such as protection of property rights and a stable monetary environment.
The government also encourages private investment in physical capital through tax incentives and other subsidies to firms willing to invest in capital projects. Industries that receive the largest tax incentives include aerospace, defense, energy, and telecommunications.
Human Capital: Public Education and Financial Aid
The government plays an important role in ensuring that every person has access to a minimum level of education. In the United States, state laws mandate that children stay in school until a minimum age, typically 16. Public schools and universities are highly subsidized by local and state governments to provide affordable access to educational opportunities. The Los Alamos National Laboratory in New Mexico is one of the largest government research centers in the country. During World War II, it was a secret lab that housed the “Manhattan Project,” which ultimately produced the world’s first atomic bomb.
317
Besides providing funding directly to schools and universities, the government offers various forms of financial assistance directly to students to use toward educational expenses. These include Pell Grants and the G.I. Bill, federal subsidized loans, and various types of tax incentives that allow qualified students (or their parents) to deduct a portion of their tuition and fees from their taxable income or from their taxes directly. The government also allows teachers to deduct certain expenses from their taxes, and provides tax-exempt status for organizations whose mission is to provide scholarships, such as the prestigious National Merit Scholarship Program. These grants, loans, and tax incentives contribute to the government’s role in promoting human capital.
Technology: Government R&D Centers and Federal Grants
Some of the largest research centers in the country are government funded. These include Los Alamos National Laboratory and Sandia National Laboratories (part of the Department of Energy), the National Institutes of Health, the National Aeronautics and Space Administration (NASA), and the National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA), just to name a few. These government research centers employ thousands of scientists, researchers, and doctors for the purpose of advancing knowledge and inventing products that enhance the lives of all citizens and promote economic growth. In addition to running research centers, the government provides funds directly to public and private research centers as well as to individual researchers. Among the largest grantors of funds is the National Science Foundation (NSF), founded in 1950. In 2016, the NSF provided over $7 billion in grants to around 11,000 projects, and has maintained its mission of promoting research essential for the nation’s economic health and global competitiveness.
Government as a Facilitator of Economic Growth A second major role of government in promoting economic growth is to ensure that an effective legal system is in place to enforce contracts and to protect property rights, and that the financial system is kept stable. These are the less tangible yet equally important components of a country’s infrastructure.
Enforcement of Contracts
The legal enforcement of contract rights is an important component of an infrastructure that promotes economic growth and well-being. Without contract enforcement, people are less likely to be willing to enter into contracts, for example, to produce and deliver goods for payment at some future date. Therefore, contract enforcement promotes economic growth by ensuring that production and purchasing commitments made by producers and consumers are
318
honored.
Protection of Property Rights
A stable legal system that protects property rights is essential for economic growth. Many developing countries do not systematically record the ownership of real property: land and buildings. Although ownership is often informally recognized, without express legal title, the capital locked up in these informal arrangements cannot be used to secure loans for entrepreneurial purposes. As a result, valuable capital sits idle; it cannot be leveraged for other productive purposes. In addition, a legal system that recognizes and protects ideas (or intellectual property) is critical to encouraging innovation. Common legal protections for ideas include patents (for inventions), copyrights (for written works, music, and film), and trademarks (for names and symbols). Every country has its innovators; the question is whether these people are offered enough of an incentive to devote their efforts to develop the innovations that drive economic growth. The extent to which countries establish intellectual property rights varies, and even when such protections exist, enforcement of the protections varies.
Stable Financial System
Another important component of a nation’s infrastructure is a stable and secure financial system. Such a financial system keeps the purchasing power of the currency stable, facilitates transactions, and permits credit institutions to arise. The recent global financial turmoil is an example of the problems caused by financial instability. Further, bank runs, like those that caused major economic disruption in Uruguay and Argentina in 2001–2002, are less likely when a nation’s financial environment is stable. Unanticipated inflations or deflations are both detrimental to economic growth. Consumers and businesses rely on the monetary prices they pay for goods and services for information about the state of the market. If these price signals are constantly being distorted by inflation or deflation, the quality of business and consumer decisions suffers. Unanticipated price changes further lead to a redistribution of income between creditors and debtors. Financial instability is harmful to improving standards of living and generating economic growth.
Government as a Promoter of Free and Competitive Markets A third role of government in promoting economic growth is maintaining competitive and efficient markets and the freedom for firms and individuals to pursue their interests.
Competitive Markets and Free Trade
One of the challenges of government is choosing the right mix of policies to keep markets competitive and fair. Regulations are put into place to protect various interests, whether consumer welfare, worker rights and safety, or the environment. But government also must ensure that such regulations do not stand in the way of markets operating efficiently. Competitive markets refer to the ability of firms to open and close businesses without unnecessary restrictions or other burdens. Also important is free trade, which refers to the ability to buy and sell products with other countries without significant barriers such as tariffs or quotas. Allowing the market to function freely within the confines of sensible regulatory laws generally creates more potential for economic growth.
Economic Freedom
One of the measures used to gauge the ability of individuals and businesses to make investment and production decisions freely is the Index of Economic Freedom. Unlike physical infrastructure such as roads and dams, which are easy to measure, attempting to measure the intangibles of doing business often requires subjective judgments. One reasonably objective measure is the 2016 Index of Economic Freedom.1 This index incorporates information about freedoms in ten categories: business, trade,
319
fiscal policy, government size, monetary policy, investment, finance, property rights, corruption, and labor. Clearly, assigning some of these items a numeric value requires a bit of subjective judgment. Even so, this index is one reasonable approach to measuring the overall infrastructure of a country. Figure 2 portrays the relationship between economic freedom and per capita GDP measured by purchasing power parity (what income will buy in each country). Those nations with the most economic freedom have the highest per capita GDP and also the highest growth rates (not shown). In this chapter, we have seen that economic growth in the long run comes from improvements in labor productivity, increases in capital, or improvements in technology. Investments in human capital and greater economic freedom also lead to higher growth rates and higher standards of living.
ISSUE Did Economic Growth Peak a Century Ago? Prospects for Future Growth When one thinks of life just 15 years ago, imagine what has changed. GPS technology was nearly nonexistent, digital music was in its infancy and downloaded using very slow Internet connections, and smartphones and tablets didn’t exist, at least in the way we know these products today. Certainly, life has changed from how we lived at the start of the new millennium. But was this a true transformation of our standard of living? According to one economist, the technological advances of the past few decades do not compare with the effect that inventions over a century ago had. In fact, he argues that U.S. economic growth peaked nearly a century ago. Are prospects for future growth in trouble? Robert Gordon is a distinguished macroeconomist and economic historian who is skeptical about the technological “revolution” that has resulted from the development of the Internet and social media. In his book The Rise and Fall of American Growth, he argues that the true transformation of American standards of living occurred between 1870 and 1940. He argues that the tremendous period of growth a century ago may be a one-time event, and that future growth may never match it. How did Gordon come to this conclusion? He points to the five “great inventions,” which were (1) electric lights, (2) flush toilets, (3) chemicals and pharmaceuticals, (4) cars, and (5) the telephone. Each of these inventions occurred prior to 1940. Therefore, Gordon argues that life became modernized by the 1940s, and every invention since, while making life more comfortable, has not had the same effect. He makes the point that if a person today walked into a 1940s apartment, it would be functional, with indoor plumbing, lights, a refrigerator, and a telephone. But if a person from 1940 walked into an 1870s apartment, the same could not be said.
Living in the 1940s was “modern” compared to the late 1800s in the sense that people today would find it mostly functional. Have changes in standards of living since the 1940s been as dramatic?
320
Is Gordon’s pessimistic view on future growth accurate? Only time will tell whether recent and future inventions will measure up to those of a century ago. What would be the contenders of the new “great inventions”? The obvious choices would include personal computers, Internet, social media, biotechnology, and artificial intelligence. But have these inventions been so transformative to our lives that living without them would be as burdensome as living without lights or the modern toilet? It’s a powerful thought to ponder as one considers the factors that will lead to future growth and the factors that will challenge it. Prospects for future growth depend largely on the willingness of businesses to innovate and create new products, on the willingness of consumers to demand these new products, and on the willingness of government (and the people who elect policymakers) to foster an environment that promotes long-term economic growth. In each case, large investments and capital spending are needed, especially in research and development, infrastructure, and other ambitious projects that may not reap returns until the next generation. Generating another strong and sustained period of growth will not be easy. First, many countries including the United States today face debt problems as populations rise and as people live longer. As a result, investing in long-term projects such as the space program or high-speed rail often gets put aside. Second, the world is affected by conflict, war, and supply shocks, making long-term investments more difficult and risky. Finally, income inequality across the world has risen, and recent economic growth has benefited the wealthy more than the poor. These obstacles make prospects for future growth more challenging. Yet, just as few predicted the five great inventions of the past century, perhaps a new set of great inventions will occur that might eliminate poverty and diseases, and lead to another period of remarkable economic growth.
In the long run, all of these factors generate growth and higher standards of living. Yet, what are we to do if the economy collapses in the short run? The Great Depression of the 1930s was to prove that for a reasonably long period (a decade), the economy could be mired in a slowdown with high unemployment rates and negative growth. A deep economy-wide downturn inflicts high costs on both today’s citizens and future generations. In the next chapter, we turn to the first of our discussions on managing the economy in the short run. FIGURE 2
ECONOMIC FREEDOM AND PER CAPITA GDP
321
The relationship between economic freedom and per capita GDP is shown here. Those nations with the most economic freedom also have the highest per capita GDP.
CHECKPOINT THE ROLE OF GOVERNMENT IN PROMOTING ECONOMIC GROWTH Government has an important role in promoting economic growth by providing physical and human capital, ensuring a stable legal system and financial markets, and promoting free and competitive markets. Infrastructure is a country’s public capital, including dams, roads, transportation networks, powergenerating plants, and public schools. Governments provide capital and technology by purchasing public capital and providing incentives for private investment, supporting education through subsidies and financial aid, and supporting research with grants. Other less tangible infrastructure elements include protection of property rights, enforcement of contracts, and a stable financial system. The Index of Economic Freedom measures a country’s infrastructure, which supports economic growth.
QUESTIONS: Imagine a country with a “failed government” that can no longer enforce the law. Contracts are not upheld and lawlessness is the order of the day. How well could an economy operate and grow in this environment? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
322
323
chapter summary Section 1 Why Is Economic Growth Important? 7.1
Economic growth is the most important factor influencing a country’s standard of living. Economic growth is measured by a nation’s ability to increase real GDP and real GDP per capita. Using real values instead of nominal values allows a country to compare growth from year to year without having to take into account the effects of inflation. Countries with high economic growth have seen rising incomes and better lives for their citizens.
Small differences in growth rates can result in large differences over time due to the power of compounding.
7.2
The Rule of 70 is a simple tool used to estimate the number of years it takes for a value to double given a constant growth rate. Number of Years = 70/Growth Rate Examples: Number of years to double at growth rate of 1%: 70/1 = 70 years 2%: 70/2 = 35 years 5%: 70/5 = 14 years 10%: 70/10 = 7 years 20%: 70/20 = 3.5 years
7.3
Using the Rule of 70 to estimate 5% versus 10% growth: Year
Value at 5%
Year
2017
$1,000
2017
$1,000
2024
$2,000
324
Value at 10%
2031 2045
$2,000 $4,000
2031
$4,000
2038
$8,000
2045
$16,000
In 28 years, the initial $1,000 is worth $16,000 at 10% growth versus $4,000 at 5% growth.
Section 2 Thinking About Short-Run and LongRun Economic Growth 7.4
Short-Run Versus Long-Run Growth Short-run growth occurs when an economy makes use of existing or underutilized resources, and is shown as a movement from inside a PPF toward the PPF (such as from point a to point b). Long-run growth requires an expansion of production capacity through an increase in resources and/or technology, and is shown by a shift of the PPF (such as from PPFA to PPFB).
7.5
Factors of Production Land (N): Includes land and natural resources Labor (L): Within labor is human capital (H), labor improved by education or training Capital (K): Manufactured goods used in the production process Entrepreneurial ability (A): Includes ideas and the technology that is developed
325
A production function is the method by which firms turn factors of production into goods and services.
Section 3 Applying the Production Function: Achieving Economic Growth 7.6
Productivity is the ability to turn a fixed amount of inputs (factors of production) into more outputs (goods and services). Ways to Increase Productivity Increasing access to natural resources Improving quality of labor (human capital) Increasing the capital-to-labor ratio Promoting innovation and technology
Rising productivity leads to growing incomes and a better standard of living.
7.7
Total factor productivity is a measurement of productivity taking into account all other factors beyond the quantity and quality of inputs that could influence production. Examples include natural disasters, climate, or cultural norms that influence the effectiveness of productive inputs.
326
Section 4 The Role of Government in Promoting Economic Growth 7.8
Government involvement in promoting economic growth occurs by way of investing in physical capital, human capital, and technology. Physical capital: The building and maintenance of the country’s public capital (infrastructure), which includes roads, bridges, airports, power plants, and telecommunications networks Human capital: Providing subsidized public college education, financial aid grants, and loans Technology: Funding research via grants and the establishment of major government research labs
West Point, the United States Military Academy, is an example of government promoting physical capital (the campus and buildings), human capital (education), and technology (research by its faculty).
7.9
Government as a Guarantor of Economic Growth Enforcement of contracts: A strong legal system Protection of property rights: Ensuring that monetary rewards are provided to innovators Stable financial system: A functioning and stable monetary system ensures investment is undertaken when the opportunity arises Promoting free and competitive markets: International trade allows for specialization and gains from trade, and competitive markets ensure firms do not exploit market power, their ability to set prices for goods and services in a market
327
The Index of Economic Freedom ranks 178 nations in terms of overall environment for promoting economic growth. In 2016 Hong Kong ranked first, and the United States came in 11th.
KEY CONCEPTS economic growth compounding real GDP real GDP per capita Rule of 70 production function productivity investment in human capital capital-to-labor ratio diminishing returns to capital catch-up effect total factor productivity infrastructure
QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS Check Your Understanding 1. Although having abundant natural resources can be an advantage for a country, are they necessary to ensure economic growth and a prosperous economy? 2. Why does a small difference in the economic growth rate lead to big differences over time? 3. What are some ways in which countries can improve labor productivity? 4. In what ways do governments help to build technology and ideas? 5. Why is investment in human capital good for both individuals and fostering economic growth for the economy as a whole? 6. Why is a stable financial system important to economic growth?
Apply the Concepts
328
7. The standard of living we enjoy today is largely due to the investments of earlier generations of Americans. Do you agree? Why or why not? 8. What role might foreign investment play in helping developing nations improve their growth rate and increase income levels? 9. Higher levels of savings and investment lead to greater rates of economic growth. What can government do to encourage more savings and investment? 10. Per capita income (or output) is the general measure used to compare the standards of living between countries. If a country’s population growth is higher than its economic growth, what happens to per capita income? What are some of the limitations to using per capita income as a measure to compare the well-being of different countries? 11. Energy independence has been a goal for many decades. But only in the past decade has the increased focus on renewable energy sources, such as solar, wind, and water, taken on greater significance. How does achieving energy independence contribute to labor productivity and economic growth? 12. One of the potential negative consequences of both economic and population growth is that we will eventually exhaust Earth’s natural resources, leading to our demise. What kind of activities might prevent this from happening?
In the News 13. The European Union faced many challenges in recent years, especially disparities in economic growth among member countries, to the point that citizens of the United Kingdom voted on whether they wished to remain in the EU or not. In 2015 average real GDP growth in the EU was 1.5%, while the top three fastest-growing members, the United Kingdom, Ireland, and Poland, achieved average growth of 3.3%. Is the effect of a 3.3% growth rate so different from that of 1.5%? 14. Finland consistently ranks very high in global rankings of educational achievement in science and math. This was a result of a transformation in Finland’s public education system to one that focuses on small class sizes and highly trained teachers for primary and secondary education, which is considered a highly prestigious profession. At the college level, many countries fully subsidize college tuition, and in Saudi Arabia, the King Abdullah Scholarship Program offers to send its citizens to study at many of the world’s prestigious universities for free. Explain how government investment in education could pay for itself in the long run.
Solving Problems
WORK IT OUT 15. In 2016 U.S. GDP was approximately $18 trillion, while India’s GDP was approximately $2.25 trillion. However, India is growing faster than the United States. a. If the U.S. economy grows at 3% per year, in what year will U.S. GDP double to $36 trillion? (Hint: Use the Rule of 70 to approximate the number of years needed for GDP to double.) b. If India’s economy grows at 7% per year, in what year will its GDP double to $4.5 trillion? In what year would India’s economy increase 16-fold to $36 trillion? c. If each country’s growth rate continues at the same rate, in what year would each country’s GDP reach $72 trillion?
16. Suppose a new colony is created on the moon with the following production function: Output = A × (L + K + H + N). If L, K, H, and N each equal 5, and technology (A) equals 3, how much output would this new colony produce?
329
USING THE NUMBERS 17. According to By the Numbers, approximately how many years did it take for real GDP per capita in the United States to double from $5,000 to $10,000? How about from $25,000 to $50,000? During which period was economic growth stronger in terms of annual growth? 18. According to By the Numbers, what is the range of life expectancies for the countries whose GDP per capita was less than $10,000 in 2015? Compare these life expectancies with those with GDP per capita greater than $35,000. Is there a strong correlation between GDP per capita and life expectancy?
ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS Checkpoint: Why Is Economic Growth Important? If incomes in China double every 10 years, Chinese workers would earn $12,000 in 2026, $24,000 in 2036, and $48,000 in 2046, equaling what American workers earned in 2016. If growth continues at the same rate, Chinese workers would earn $96,000 in 2056 and $192,000 in 2066. American workers would earn $96,000 in 2040, and $192,000 in 2064. Therefore, Chinese workers would earn the same as American workers in about 50 years. Checkpoint: Thinking About Short-Run and Long-Run Economic Growth Every factor of production contributes to economic growth. Although the Ivory Coast is abundant in natural resources and labor compared to Iceland, it lacks the human capital, physical capital, and technology that are important components in the production function. In addition, the lack of stability in the country from recent civil and military strife has left many of its resources underutilized for productive purposes, further inhibiting the Ivory Coast from achieving higher long-run growth. Checkpoint: Applying the Production Function: Achieving Economic Growth An organization such as the Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation can help people improve their health through vaccinations, clean water, and sanitation, thereby enabling them to improve their productivity and earning power. Then, focus can be put on schools and improving education. All of this focus on human capital broadly can be accomplished with grants to communities or parents (by subsidizing them to send their kids to school) in developing nations. Checkpoint: The Role of Government in Promoting Economic Growth Not very well. Large-scale businesses that we are accustomed to could not exist. What’s left is small individual businesses that serve small local populations. Growth is stymied, and everyone ekes out a small living. Countries such as Somalia are in this no-win situation. 1Heritage
Foundation, 2016 Index of Economic Freedom (Washington, D.C.), 2016.
330
8
Aggregate Expenditures
331
Understanding the power of spending and how it can multiply income many times 332
over
Learning Objectives 8.1
Name the components of aggregate spending.
8.2
Analyze the relationship between consumption and income using a basic aggregate expenditures graph.
8.3
Analyze consumption and saving using marginal propensity to consume (MPC) and marginal propensity to save (MPS).
8.4
Describe the determinants of consumption, saving, and investment.
8.5
Determine macroeconomic equilibrium in the simple aggregate expenditures model of the private domestic economy.
8.6
Explain the multiplier process, how it is computed, and why it operates in both directions.
8.7
Describe macroeconomic equilibrium in the full aggregate expenditures model when government and the foreign sectors are added.
8.8
Explain why, at equilibrium, injections equal withdrawals in the economy.
8.9
Describe the differences between recessionary and inflationary gaps.
M
adawaska, Maine, near the northern end of U.S. 1 that extends all the way south to Key West, Florida, is like many other idyllic small towns in the United States— picturesque, friendly, and highly dependent on one industry to provide jobs for its residents. For Madawaska, it is the local paper mill, which provides jobs to 620 of
its 4,100 residents. The salaries earned by its workers help to keep the rest of the town employed, including workers in restaurants and cafés, pharmacies, banks, and gas stations that serve the paper mill workers and their families.
During the depth of the 2007–2009 recession, when Madawaska’s paper mill was on the brink of closure, not only did its workers face potential unemployment, but so did the rest of the community, which depends on people with jobs at the paper mill to support their businesses. Towns such as Madawaska highlight the interdependency of the economy in which the loss of one job results in a reduction in spending that affects other jobs. In 2010 the workers at the paper mill took the unusual step of accepting an 8.5% wage cut in order to keep the company (and town) from closing down. And the plan worked—the plant survived and was sold to an investment firm in 2013 that promised to keep the paper mill running in Madawaska, where it remains in operation today. The economic crisis that Madawaska faced during the last recession was one that many cities, big and small,
333
experienced. As unemployment rose, people had less money to spend on clothing, electronics, travel, and cars, which caused a chain reaction downward in consumption, leading to further unemployment and slow or negative economic growth. This chain reaction is what John Maynard Keynes alluded to when he published The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money in 1936, which discussed the importance of aggregate spending and the government’s role in stabilizing the macroeconomy. Today, the U.S. economy (along with the majority of its cities) has recovered from the last recession. As employment opportunities grew during the recovery, more money was earned and subsequently spent, which generated more economic activity and jobs. The chain reaction in recent years has worked in a positive direction. Sometimes, however, consumers and businesses alone cannot pull an economy out of recession, and government policies are needed to speed up growth. But how should government act and to what extent should it act? These are the more contentious questions that are debated today. Stimulus packages, tax cuts, farm subsidies, laws and regulations, and even financial aid for college students are all part of a huge arsenal of tools available to government policymakers. The goal of government stimulus programs is to put money into the hands (through jobs, tax cuts, and cash benefits) of those most likely to spend it in their communities, thus carrying a positive ripple effect through to other businesses that depend on consumer spending. But Keynesian policies have not been without their critics as the size of government grew. Spending by government (federal, state, and local) has increased from 10% of GDP in the 1930s to over 30% today as the size and scope of government programs expand. Although many people benefit from these programs, some believe government has overreached and they would prefer something smaller and simpler.
334
335
This sort of thinking is not new. In fact, over a century ago, government policies were rarely used to intervene in the workings of the economy, even when the economy entered a downturn. Classical economists, as they are called, viewed the role of the government as providing the necessary framework upon which the market could operate— maintaining competition, providing central banking services, providing for national defense, administering the legal system, and so forth. But government was not expected to play a role in promoting full employment, stabilizing prices, or stimulating economic growth—the economy was supposed to do this on its own. The belief at the time was that economic downturns were self-correcting, meaning that if the economy were left alone, the forces of supply and demand would naturally bring the economy back into equilibrium. The classical perspective was challenged during the Great Depression by Keynes, who turned away from the classical framework with its three separate and distinct competitive markets operating through prices, wages, and interest rates. He focused instead on the economy as a whole and on aggregate spending. In this chapter, we develop the aggregate expenditures model, which is commonly referred to as the Keynesian model. It can be used to analyze short-run macroeconomic fluctuations and how policymakers counteract the effects caused by the business cycle. Keynes’s focus was on aggregate spending, and how consumption spending is a key component to explaining how the economy reaches short-term equilibrium employment, output, and income. Using this model, we will see why an economy can get stuck in an undesirable place, and why policies are useful in smoothing out the business cycle.
336
AGGREGATE EXPENDITURES Recall that when we discussed measuring gross domestic product (GDP), we concluded that it could be computed by adding up either all spending or all income in the economy. We saw that the expenditures side consists of consumer spending, business investment spending, government spending, and net foreign spending (exports minus imports). Thus, aggregate expenditures are equal to GDP = AE = C + I + G + (X − M) aggregate expenditures Consist of consumer spending, business investment spending, government spending, and net foreign spending (exports minus imports): GDP = C + I + G + (X − M).
Some Simplifying Assumptions In this chapter, we first will focus on a simple model of the private economy that includes only consumers and businesses. Later in the chapter, we will incorporate government spending, taxes, and the foreign sector into our analysis. Second, we will assume that all saving is personal saving as opposed to national saving, which includes business saving and government saving. Third, because Keynes was modeling a depression economy, we follow him in assuming that there is considerable slack in the economy, much like the economy during and in the years following the 2007–2009 recession. Unemployment is high and other resources are sitting idle, which means that if demand were to rise, businesses could quickly increase output without any upward pressure on costs. We will assume therefore that the aggregate price level (the CPI, PPI, or GDP deflator) is fixed. Taking into account these assumptions, which make the analysis easier but do not affect the key points, let us begin by looking at consumption and saving.
Consumption and Saving Personal consumption expenditures (C) represent about 68% of GDP, and for this reason consumption is a major ingredient in our model. Figure 1 shows personal consumption expenditures for the years since 1980. Notice how closely consumption parallels disposable income. consumption Spending by individuals and households on both durable goods (e.g., autos, appliances, and electronic equipment) and nondurable goods (e.g., food, clothing, and entertainment). FIGURE 1
CONSUMPTION AND DISPOSABLE INCOME
337
This graph shows personal consumption spending (C) for the years since 1980. The 45° line represents an economy that spends its entire income each year, resulting in no saving. Annual saving (S) is equal to the vertical difference between the 45° line and annual consumption (S = Yd − C). The inset shows more clearly that consumption fell in 2009 when the economy was at the trough of the business cycle, but has since recovered.
The 45° line inserted in the figure represents all points where consumption is equal to disposable income (Yd). If an economy spends its entire annual income, saving nothing, the 45° line would represent consumption. Consequently, annual saving (S) is equal to the vertical difference between the 45° reference line and annual consumption (S = Yd − C). After all, what can you do with income except spend it or save it? saving The difference between income and consumption; the amount of disposable income not spent.
Notice that consumption spending increased every year since 1980 except in 2009, when disposable income rose but consumption dropped. This was an important contributor to the depth of the 2007–2009 recession. In fact, the last time annual consumption spending dropped occurred in 1933, during the depth of the Great Depression. Keynes began his theoretical examination of consumption by noting the following: The fundamental psychological law, upon which we are entitled to depend with great confidence both a priori from our knowledge of human nature and from the detailed facts of experience, is that men are disposed, as a rule and on
338
the average, to increase their consumption as their income increases, but not by as much as the change in their income.1
Consumption spending grows, in other words, as income grows, but not as fast. Therefore, as income grows, saving will grow as a percentage of income. Notice that this approach to analyzing saving differs from the classical approach. Classical economists assumed that the interest rate is the principal determinant of saving and, by extension, one of the principal determinants of consumption. Keynes, in contrast, emphasized income as the main determinant of consumption and saving. Table 1 portrays a hypothetical consumption function of the sort Keynes envisioned. As income grows from $4,000 to $4,200, consumption increases by $150 ($4,150 − $4,000) and saving grows from $0 to $50. Thus, the change in income of $200 is divided between consumption ($150) and saving ($50). Note that at income levels below $4,000, saving is negative; people are spending more than their current income either by using credit or drawing on existing savings to support consumption.
TABLE 1
HYPOTHETICAL CONSUMPTION AND SAVING AND PROPENSITIES TO CONSUME AND SAVE
(1) Income or Output Y (in $)
(2) Consumption C (in $)
(3) Saving S (in $)
(4) APC C÷Y
(5) APS S÷Y
(6) MPC ΔC ÷ ΔY
(7) MPS ΔS ÷ ΔY
3,000
3,250
−250
1.08
−0.08
0.75
0.25
3,200
3,400
−200
1.06
−0.06
0.75
0.25
3,400
3,550
−150
1.04
−0.04
0.75
0.25
3,600
3,700
−100
1.03
−0.03
0.75
0.25
3,800
3,850
−50
1.01
−0.01
0.75
0.25
4,000
4,000
0
1.00
0.00
0.75
0.25
4,200
4,150
50
0.99
0.01
0.75
0.25
4,400
4,300
100
0.98
0.02
0.75
0.25
4,600
4,450
150
0.97
0.03
0.75
0.25
4,800
4,600
200
0.96
0.04
0.75
0.25
5,000
4,750
250
0.95
0.05
0.75
0.25
5,200
4,900
300
0.94
0.06
0.75
0.25
5,400
5,050
350
0.94
0.06
0.75
0.25
5,600
5,200
400
0.93
0.07
0.75
0.25
Average Propensities to Consume and Save
The percentage of income that is consumed is known as the average propensity to consume (APC); it is listed in column (4) of Table 1. It is calculated by dividing consumption spending by income (C ÷ Y). For example, when income is $5,000 and consumption is $4,750, APC is 0.95, meaning that 95% of the income is spent. average propensity to consume The percentage of income that is consumed (C ÷ Y).
339
The average propensity to save (APS) is equal to saving divided by income (S ÷ Y); it is the percentage of income saved. Again, if income is $5,000 and saving is $250, APS is 0.05, or 5% is saved. The APS is shown in column (5) of Table 1. average propensity to save The percentage of income that is saved (S ÷ Y).
Notice that if you add columns (4) and (5) in Table 1, the answer is always 1. That is because Y = C + S; therefore, all income is either spent or saved. Similar logic dictates that the two percentages spent and saved must total 100%, or that APC + APS = 1.
Marginal Propensities to Consume and Save
Average propensities to consume and save represent the proportion of income that is consumed or saved. Marginal propensities measure what part of additional income will be either consumed or saved. This distinction is important because changing policies by government policymakers mean that income changes and consumers’ reactions to their changing incomes are what we will see later drive changes in the economy. The marginal propensity to consume (MPC) is equal to the change in consumption associated with a given change in income. Denoting change by the delta symbol (Δ), MPC = ΔC ÷ ΔY. Thus, for example, when income grows from $5,000 to $5,200 (a $200 change), and consumption rises from $4,750 to $4,900 (a $150 change), MPC is equal to 0.75 ($150 ÷ $200). marginal propensity to consume The change in consumption associated with a given change in income (ΔC ÷ ΔY).
Notice that this result is consistent with Keynes’s fundamental psychological law quoted earlier, holding that people “are disposed, as a rule and on the average, to increase their consumption as their income increases, but not by as much as the change in their income.” In Table 1, the MPC for all changes in income is 0.75, as shown in column (6). The marginal propensity to save (MPS) is equal to the change in saving associated with a given change in income; MPS = ΔS ÷ ΔY. Therefore, when income grows from $5,000 to $5,200, and saving grows from $250 to $300, MPS is equal to 0.25 ($50 ÷ $200). Column (7) lists MPS. marginal propensity to save The change in saving associated with a given change in income (ΔS ÷ ΔY).
Note once again that the sum of the MPC and the MPS will always equal 1, because the only thing that can be done with a change in income is to spend or save it. A small word of warning, however: Though APC + APS = 1 and MPC + MPS = 1, most of the time APC + MPS ≠ 1 and APS + MPC ≠ 1. Try adding a few different columns from Table 1 and you will see that this is true. Suppose you receive some birthday money from your aunt. What portion of this money would you spend and what portion would you save? These portions are your marginal propensity to consume and marginal propensity to save, respectively.
340
Figure 2 graphs the consumption and saving schedules from Table 1. The graph in panel A extends the consumption schedule back to zero income, where consumption is equal to $1,000 and saving is equal to −$1,000. (Remember that Y = C + S; therefore, if Y = 0 and C = $1,000, then S must equal −$1,000. With no income, people in this economy would continue to spend, either borrowing money or drawing down their accumulated savings to survive.) The 45° line in panel A is a reference line where Y = C + S. At the point at which the consumption schedule crosses the reference line (point a, Y = $4,000), saving is zero because consumption and income are equal. The saving schedule in panel B plots the difference between the 45° reference line (Y = C + S) and the consumption schedule in panel A. For example, if income is $4,000, saving is zero (point f in panel B), and when income equals $5,000, saving equals $250 [line (b − c) in panel A, point g in panel B]. Saving is positively sloped, again reflecting Keynes’s fundamental law; the more people earn, the greater percentage of income they will save (the average propensity to save rises as income rises). Make a mental note that the saving schedule shows how much people desire to save at various income levels. How much people will actually save depends on equilibrium income, or how much income the economy is generating. We are getting a bit ahead of the story here, but planting this seed will help you when we get to the section where we determine equilibrium income in the economy. FIGURE 2
CONSUMPTION AND SAVING
341
The consumption and saving schedules from Table 1 are graphed here. Panel A extends the consumption schedule back to zero income, where consumption is equal to $1,000 and saving is equal to −$1,000. At the point where the consumption schedule crosses the reference line (point a, Y = $4,000), saving is zero. The saving schedule in panel B simply plots the difference between the 45° reference line and the consumption schedule in panel A. Thus, when income = $5,000, saving = $250 [line (b − c) in panel A, point g in panel B].
Note finally that the consumption and saving schedules in our example are straight-line functions. This need not be the case, but it simplifies some of the relationships to graph them like this at this point. When the consumption and saving schedules are linear, the MPC is the slope of the consumption function, and the MPS is the slope of the saving schedule. In this case, MPC = 0.75 and MPS = 0.25, which tells us that every time income changes by $1,000, consumption will change by $750 and saving will change by $250.
342
Other Determinants of Consumption and Saving
Income is the principal determinant of consumption and saving, but other factors can shift the saving and consumption schedules. These factors include the wealth of a family, their expectations about the future of prices and income, family debt, and taxation. Wealth The more wealth a family has, the higher its consumption at all levels of income. Wealth affects the consumption schedule by shifting it up or down, depending on whether wealth rises or falls. When the stock market was soaring in the late 1990s, policymakers worried about the wealth effect, that as many households saw their wealth dramatically expand, rising consumption might cause the economy’s inflation rate to rise. As it turned out, the stock market collapsed in 2000, and again in 2008, and the economy moved into recession. Then, economists began worrying about the negative impact of this wealth effect as trillions of dollars of wealth evaporated from the stock market before it eventually recovered. Expectations Expectations about future prices and incomes help determine how much a person will spend today. If you anticipate that prices will rise next week, you will be more likely to purchase more products today. What are sales, after all, but temporary reductions in price designed to entice customers into the store today? Similarly, if you anticipate that your income will soon rise—perhaps you are about to graduate from medical school—you will be more inclined to incur debt today to purchase something you want, as was the case with LeBron James, who drove an expensive Hummer while in high school, knowing that when he was drafted into the NBA, he would be making a fortune. Lotto winners who receive their winnings over a 20-year span often spend much of the money early on, running up debts. Few winners spend their winnings evenly over the 20 years. Household Debt Most households carry some debt, typically in the form of credit card balances, auto loans, student loans, or a home mortgage. The more debt a household has, the less able it is to spend in the current period as it makes payments toward the debt. Although the household might want to spend more money on goods now, its debt level restricts its ability to get more credit. Taxes Taxes reduce disposable income, and therefore taxes result in reduced consumption and saving. When taxes are increased, spendable income falls; therefore, consumption is reduced by the MPC times the reduction in disposable income, and saving falls by the reduction in disposable income times the MPS. Tax reductions have the opposite effect, as we will see later in this chapter.
Investment
When the town of West Point, Georgia, received the news that South Korean automaker Kia Motors was building a $1 billion car manufacturing facility in its town, its residents couldn’t have been happier. Not only was Kia creating thousands of jobs, the spending by its workers would create even more jobs throughout the region. Because Kia’s manufacturing facility was new to the U.S. economy (and not simply a move from another town), it is counted as gross private domestic investment (the “I” in the GDP equation), an important component of the aggregate expenditures model. Investment can come from foreign and domestic sources, for example, when American companies expand their operations by investing in new capital such as building a new factory. investment Spending by businesses that adds to the productive capacity of the economy. Investment depends on factors such as its rate of return, the level of technology, and business expectations about the economy.
Unlike consumer spending, which at 68% is the largest component of GDP and until recently held fairly steady from year to year, gross private domestic investment is volatile. Sure, large investment deals like Kia’s new plant in West Point, Georgia, are a huge boost to the economy, but such investments tend to be sporadic. The annual percentage changes in consumption and investment spending from 1980 to 2015 are shown in Figure 3. Many residents in West Point, Georgia, were excited when South Korean auto manufacturer Kia Motors built a large factory in their town in 2008, saving the town’s economy after decades of factory closings and job losses.
343
Notice that although consumption plodded along with annual increases between 0% and 10%, investment spending has undergone annual fluctuations ranging from −22% to +27%. Investment constitutes about 16% of GDP; therefore, its volatility often accounts for our recessions and booms. The economic boom of the 1990s, for instance, was fueled by investments in information technology infrastructure, including massive investments in telecommunications. In the 1990s, people believed that Internet traffic would grow by 1,000% a year, doubling every three months or so. This belief led many companies to lay millions of miles of fiber optic cable. When the massive investments made in computer hardware and software over that same decade are taken into account, it is no wonder that the economy grew at a breakneck pace. But this increase came to a halt in the early 2000s, when businesses—especially the telecoms—discovered that they had built up a massive excess capacity, and thus bandwidth prices plummeted. The resulting plunge in investment between 2000 and 2001 can be seen in Figure 3. Investment recovered by 2003, then collapsed from 2007 to 2009 as the housing and financial crises took their toll.
Investment Demand
Investment levels depend mainly on the rate of return on capital. Investments earning a high rate of return are the investments undertaken first (assuming comparable risk), with those projects offering lower returns finding their way into the investment stream later. Interest rate levels also are important in determining how much investment occurs, because much of business investment is financed through debt. As interest rates fall, investment rises, and vice versa. FIGURE 3
CHANGES IN CONSUMPTION AND GROSS PRIVATE DOMESTIC INVESTMENT
344
The annual percentage changes in consumption and gross private domestic investment (GPDI) are shown here. Consumption is relatively stable, but investment spending is highly volatile, with annual fluctuations ranging from −22% to +27%. The shaded bars represent recessions.
Each month, the Institute of Supply Management provides a forecast of investment demand by asking businesses whether their inventories are higher, the same, or lower than the previous month. Investors cheer falling inventories, because it is a sign that businesses will boost factory production and investment in new facilities. Although inventories rose slightly from November 2015 to February 2016, the overall index remains low, signaling continued economic growth.
Although the rate of return on investments is the main determinant of investment spending, other factors influence investment demand, including expectations, technological change, capital goods on hand, and operating costs.
345
Expectations Projecting the rate of return on investment is not an easy task. Returns are forecasted over the life of a new piece of equipment or factory, yet many changes in the economic environment can alter the actual return on these investments. As business expectations improve, investment demand will increase as businesses are willing to invest more at any given interest rate. Technological Change Technological innovations periodically spur investment. The introduction of electrification, automobiles, and phone service at the beginning of the 20th century and, most recently, mobile technology and the new products they have spawned, are examples. Producing brand-new products requires massive investments in plants, equipment, and research and development. These investments often take a long time before their full potential is realized. Operating Costs When the costs of operating and maintaining machinery and equipment rise, the rate of return on capital equipment declines and new investment will be postponed. Capital Goods on Hand The more capital goods a firm has on hand, including inventories of the products it sells, the less the firm will want to make new investments. Until existing capacity can be fully used, investing in more equipment and facilities will do little to help profits.
Aggregate Investment Schedule
To simplify our analysis, we will assume that rates of return and interest rates fully determine investment in the short run. But once that level of investment has been determined, it remains independent of income, or autonomous, as economists say. Therefore, unlike consumption, which increases as income rises, we will assume that investment does not vary based on income, but instead on the rates of return that determine how potentially profitable investment will be. Figure 4 shows the resulting aggregate investment schedule that plots investment spending with respect to income. FIGURE 4
THE INVESTMENT SCHEDULE
The aggregate investment schedule, relating investment spending to income, is shown here. Because aggregate investment is I0 at all income levels, the curve is a horizontal straight line. This assumption simplifies the aggregate expenditures model.
Because we have assumed that aggregate investment is I0 at all income levels, the curve is a horizontal straight
346
line. Investment is unaffected by different levels of income. This is a simplifying assumption that we will change in later chapters when we look at its implications. Our emphasis in this section has been on two important components of aggregate spending: consumption and investment. Consumption is about 68% and investment is about 16% of aggregate spending. Consumption is relatively stable, but investment is volatile and especially sensitive to expectations about conditions in the economy. We have seen that, on average, some income is spent (APC) and some is saved (APS). But, it is that portion of additional income that is spent (MPC) and saved (MPS) that is most important for where the economy settles or where it reaches equilibrium, as we will see in the next section.
CHECKPOINT AGGREGATE EXPENDITURES Aggregate expenditures are equal to C + I + G + (X − M), with consumption being about 68% of aggregate spending. Keynes argued that saving and consumption spending are related to income. As income grows, consumption will grow but not as fast. The marginal propensities to consume (MPC) and save (MPS) are equal to ΔC ÷ ΔY and ΔS ÷ ΔY, respectively. They represent the change in consumption and saving associated with a change in income. Other factors affecting consumption and saving include wealth, expectations about future income and prices, the level of household debt, and taxes. Investment levels depend primarily on the rate of return on capital. Other determinants of investment demand include business expectations, technology change, operating costs, and the amount of capital goods on hand. Consumption is relatively stable. In contrast, investment is volatile.
QUESTION: Why is investment spending generally much more volatile than consumption spending? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
347
THE SIMPLE AGGREGATE EXPENDITURES MODEL Now that we have stripped the government and foreign sectors from our analysis at this point, aggregate expenditures (AE) will consist of the sum of consumer and business investment spending (AE = C + I). Figure 5 shows a simple aggregate expenditures model based on consumption and investment. Aggregate expenditures based on the data in Table 1 are shown in panel A of Figure 5; panel B shows the corresponding saving and investment schedules. Let us take a moment to remind ourselves what these graphs represent. The 45° line in panel A represents the situation when income exactly equals spending, or Y = AE. In other words, no savings occur at any level of income. All other lines represent situations in which income does not exactly equal spending at all levels of income. Point a in both panels is that level of income ($4,000) at which saving is zero and all income is spent. Saving is therefore positive for income levels above $4,000 and negative at incomes below. The vertical distance ef in panel A represents investment (I0) of $100; it is equal to I0 in panel B. Note that the vertical axis of panel B has a different scale from that of panel A. FIGURE 5
EQUILIBRIUM IN THE AGGREGATE EXPENDITURES MODEL
348
Ignoring government spending and net exports, aggregate expenditures (AE) consist of consumer spending and business investment (AE = C + I). Panel A shows AE and its relationship with income (Y); when spending equals income, the economy is on the Y = AE line. Panel B shows the corresponding saving and investment schedules. Point a in both panels shows where income equals consumption and saving is zero. Therefore, saving is positive for income levels above $4,000 and negative at incomes below $4,000. The vertical distance ef in panel A represents investment ($100); it is equal to I0 in panel B. Equilibrium income and output are $4,400 (point e), because this is the level at which businesses are producing just what other businesses and consumers want to buy.
Macroeconomic Equilibrium in the Simple Model 349
The important question to ask is where this economy will come to rest. Or, in the language of economists, at what income will this economy reach Keynesian macroeconomic equilibrium? By equilibrium, economists mean that income at which there are no net pressures pushing the economy to move to a higher or lower level of output. Keynesian macroeconomic equilibrium The state of an economy at which all injections equal all withdrawals. There are no pressures pushing the economy to a higher or lower level of output.
To find this equilibrium point, let’s begin with the economy at an income level of $4,000. Are there pressures driving the economy to grow or decline? Looking at point a in panel A of Figure 5, we see that the economy is producing $4,000 worth of goods and services and $4,000 in income. At this income level, however, consumers and businesses want to spend $4,100 ($4,000 in consumption and $100 in investment). Because aggregate expenditures (AE) exceed current income and output, there are more goods being demanded ($4,100) than are being supplied at $4,000. As a result, businesses will find it in their best interests to produce more, raising employment and income and moving the economy toward income and output level $4,400 (point e). Once the economy has moved to $4,400, what consumers and businesses want to buy is exactly equal to the income and output being produced. Businesses are producing $4,400, aggregate expenditures are equal to $4,400, and there are no pressures on the economy to move away from point e. Income of $4,400, or point e, is an equilibrium point for the economy. Panel B shows this same equilibrium, again as point e. Is it a coincidence that saving and investment are equal at this point where income and output are at equilibrium? The answer is no. In this simple private sector model, saving and investment will always be equal when the economy is in equilibrium. Remember that aggregate expenditures are equal to consumption plus business investment (AE = C + I). Recall also that at equilibrium, aggregate expenditures, income, and output are all equal; what is demanded is supplied (AE = Y). Finally, keep in mind that income can either be spent or saved (Y = C + S). By substitution, we know that, at equilibrium, AE = Y = C + I We also know that Y=C+S Substituting C + I for Y yields C+I=C+S Canceling the C’s, we find that, at equilibrium, I=S
JOHN MAYNARD KEYNES (1883–1946) n 1935 John Maynard Keynes boasted in a letter to playwright George Bernard Shaw of a book he was writing that would revolutionize “the way the world thinks about economic problems.” This was a brash prediction to make, even to a friend, but it was not an idle boast. His General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money did change the way the world looked at economics. Keynes belongs to a small class of economic earth-shakers that includes Karl Marx and Adam Smith. His one-man war on classical theory launched a new field of study known as macroeconomics. His ideas would have a profound influence on theorists and government policies for decades to come. Keynes was once asked if there was any era comparable to the Great Depression. He replied, “It was called the Dark Ages and it lasted 400 years.” His prescription to President Franklin D. Roosevelt was to
350
I
increase government spending to stimulate the economy. Sundeep Reddy reports that “during a 1934 dinner . . . after one economist carefully removed a towel from a stack to dry his hands, Mr. Keynes swept the whole pile of towels on the floor and crumpled them up, explaining that his way of using towels did more to stimulate employment among restaurant workers” (The Wall Street Journal, January 8, 2009, p. A10). During the world economic depression in the early 1930s, Keynes became alarmed when unemployment in England continued to rise after the first few years of the crisis. Keynes argued that aggregate expenditures, the sum of consumption, investment, government spending, and net exports, determined the levels of economic output and employment. When aggregate expenditures were high, the economy would foster business expansion, higher incomes, and high levels of employment. With low aggregate spending, businesses would be unable to sell their inventories and would cut back on investment and production. The ideas formulated by Keynes dramatically changed the way government policy is used throughout the world. Today, as many countries face a slow economic recovery, governments have taken a more proactive role in their economies in hopes of avoiding another downturn of the magnitude seen in the 1930s.
Thus, the location of point e in panel B is not just coincidental; at equilibrium, actual saving and investment are always equal. Note that at point a, saving is zero, yet investment spending is $100 at I0. This difference means businesses desire to invest more than people desire to save. With desired investment exceeding desired saving, this cannot be an equilibrium point, because saving and investment must be equal in order for the economy to be at equilibrium. Indeed, income will rise until these two values are equal at point e. What is important to take from this discussion? First, when intended (or desired) saving and investment differ, the economy will have to grow or shrink to achieve equilibrium. When desired saving exceeds desired investment—at income levels above $4,400 in panel B—income will decline. When intended saving is below intended investment— at income levels below $4,400—income will rise. Notice that we are using the words “intended” and “desired” interchangeably. Second, at equilibrium all injections of spending (investment in this case) into the economy must equal all withdrawals (saving in this simple model). Spending injections increase aggregate income, while spending withdrawals reduce it. This fact will become important as we add government and the foreign sector to the model. injections Increments of spending, including investment, government spending, and exports. withdrawals Activities that remove spending from the economy, including saving, taxes, and imports.
Returning to Figure 5, given an initial investment of $100 (I0), equilibrium is at an output of $4,400 (point e). Remember that at equilibrium, what people withdraw from the economy (saving) is equal to what others are willing to inject into the spending system (investment). In this case, both values equal $100. Point e is an equilibrium point because there are no pressures in the system to increase or decrease output; the spending desires of consumers and businesses are satisfied. FIGURE 6
SAVING AND INVESTMENT
351
When investment is $100, equilibrium employment occurs at an output of $4,400 (point e). When investment rises to $200 (I1), equilibrium output climbs to $4,800 (point b). Thus, $100 of added investment spending causes income to grow by $400. This is the multiplier at work.
The Multiplier Injections and withdrawals in an economy produce an effect that is greater than the initial value of the injection or withdrawal. The following example illustrates why. Assume that full employment occurs at output $4,800. How much would investment have to increase to move the economy out to full employment? As Figure 6 shows, investment must rise to $200 (I1), an increase of $100. With this new investment, equilibrium output moves from point e to point b, and income rises from $4,400 to $4,800. What is remarkable here is that a mere $100 of added spending (investment in this case) caused income to grow by $400. This phenomenon is known as the multiplier effect. Recognizing it was one of Keynes’s major insights. How does it work? multiplier Spending changes alter equilibrium income by the spending change times the multiplier. One person’s spending becomes another’s income, and that second person spends some (the MPC), which becomes income for another person, and so on, until income has changed by 1/(1 − MPC) = 1/MPS. The multiplier operates in both directions.
In this example, we have assumed the marginal propensity to consume is 0.75. Therefore, for each added dollar received by consumers, $0.75 is spent and $0.25 is saved. Thus, when businesses invest an additional $100, the firms providing the machinery will spend $75 of this new income on more raw materials, while saving the remaining $25. The firms supplying the new raw materials have $75 of new income. These firms will spend $56.25 of this (0.75 × $75.00), while saving $18.75 ($56.25 + $18.75 = $75.00). This effect continues on until the added spending has been exhausted. As a result, income will increase by $100 + $75 + $56.25 . . . . In the end, income rises by $400. Figure 7 outlines this multiplier process. The general formula for the spending multiplier (k) is k = 1/(1 − MPC)
352
Alternatively, because MPC + MPS = 1, the MPS = 1 − MPC; therefore, k = 1/MPS FIGURE 7
THE MULTIPLIER PROCESS
An initial $100 of spending generates more spending because of the multiplier process shown in this figure. With an MPC = 0.75 in the second round, $75 is spent and $25 is saved. In the third round, $56.25 of the previous $75 is spent and $18.75 is saved, and so on. Total spending is $400, and total saving is $100 when all rounds are completed.
Thus, in our simple model, the multiplier is 1/(1 − 0.75) = 1/0.25 = 4 As a result of the multiplier effect, new spending will raise equilibrium by 4 times the amount of new spending. Note that any change in spending (consumption, investment—and as we will see in the next section—government spending or changes in net exports) will also have this effect. Spending is spending. Note also—and this is important —the multiplier works in both directions.
The Multiplier Works in Both Directions
If spending increases raise equilibrium income by the increase times the multiplier, a spending decrease will reduce income in corresponding fashion. In our simple economy, for instance, a $100 decline in investment or consumer spending will reduce income by $400. This is one reason why recession watchers are always concerned about consumer confidence. During a recession, income declines, or at least the rate of income growth falls. If consumers decide to increase their saving to guard against the possibility of job loss, they may inadvertently make the recession worse. As they pull more of their money out of the spending stream, withdrawals increase, and income is reduced by a multiplied amount as other agents in the economy feel the effects of this reduced spending. The result can be a more severe or longer-lasting recession.
353
This was the case when consumer spending peaked in the summer of 2008. After that, auto sales plummeted and housing prices and sales fell. As the recession that started in December 2007 progressed and jobs were lost, consumers reduced their spending. As their confidence in the economy deteriorated, households began to save more, consumer spending declined further, and the economy sank into a deeper recession. Figure 8 shows how consumer spending (downward arrow) fell and saving rose (upward arrow) after September 2008. Leading up to the recession, saving was less than 1% of personal income, but by mid-2009 it had grown to 7%. Before the recession, aggregate household debt had soared, and part of what we are seeing in Figure 8 may reflect households spending less in order to pay off debt and return to more sustainable levels of debt. FIGURE 8
CONSUMPTION AND SAVING, 2007–2009
Consumption declined as the recession developed, and consumer worries about job losses and the decline in housing prices resulted in households saving more. The shaded area on the right represents the recession.
Paradox of Thrift
The implication of Keynesian analysis for actual aggregate household saving and household intentions regarding saving is called the paradox of thrift. As we saw in Figure 8, if households intend (or desire) to save more, they will reduce consumption, thereby reducing income and output, resulting in job losses and further reductions in income, consumption, business investment, and so on. The end result is an aggregate equilibrium with lower output, income, investment, and in the final analysis, lower actual aggregate saving.
354
paradox of thrift When investment is positively related to income and households intend to save more, they reduce consumption. Consequently, income and output decrease, reducing investment such that savings actually end up decreasing.
Notice that we have modified our assumption about investment—it now varies with economic conditions and is positively related to income. When the economy improves and income (or output) rises, investment expands as well, and vice versa when the economy sours. This is shown in our simple aggregate expenditures framework in Figure 9. FIGURE 9
PARADOX OF THRIFT
When consumers intend to save more and consume less (the saving schedule shifts from S0 to S1), and if investment is a rising function of income, the end result is that at equilibrium, households actually end up saving less (point a).
ISSUE Do High Savings Rates Increase the Risk of a Long Recession? Everyone has a frugal friend or relative who saves every penny possible, or a shopaholic friend who can’t seem to save any money at all. These differences in savings rates often are influenced by economic and demographic factors. People with higher incomes tend to save a larger portion of their incomes than those with lower incomes. Older people tend to save more than younger people. And those living in rural areas tend to save more than those in urban areas. Yet, although these factors explain savings rates within a country, they do not fully explain the savings rate across countries. In other words, cultural differences play an important role as well. The following bar graph shows the average household saving rate in a sample of twelve countries in 2016. China and India rank at the top of this list, despite having a lower income per capita than any other country on the list. The United States, which has the highest income per capita among the countries shown, has a savings rate toward the bottom. And some countries have seen dramatic changes in their savings rate, such as Japan, which had one of the highest savings rates 30 years ago, but today has the lowest savings rate among the countries shown.
355
The savings rate plays an important role in an economy. A high savings rate, such as that in China, India, and France, gives a country’s banking system a vote of confidence; people trust putting their money into financial institutions and expect the money will be available when desired. Also, savings provide opportunities for others to borrow, providing inexpensive access to loans for investment. However, a high savings rate can also make a country vulnerable in times of recession. The adverse effects of a high savings rate are seen in China today, which has seen its growth rate fall in recent years. The natural reaction by Chinese citizens is to save even more, which may further slow economic growth and eventually lead to a recession. In the 1990s, Japan faced a decade-long recession due to the government’s inability to boost consumption and investment using incentives, largely because its citizens and businesses were too worried to consume and invest, and instead chose to save.
The ability of governments to minimize the effects of economic downturns depends on the marginal propensity to consume, which determines the multiplier. The higher the multiplier, the greater the effect government efforts to increase spending will have. Because China and India have very high savings rates, government incentives to boost consumption and investment may not be very effective, which doesn’t bode well should either country enter into a recession.
356
Initially, the economy is in equilibrium at point e with saving equal to S0. If households desire to save more because they feel insecure about their jobs, the savings curve will shift upward and to the left to S1. Now at all levels of income households intend to save more. This sets up the chain reaction described previously, leading to a new equilibrium at point a, where equilibrium income has fallen to Y1 and actual saving has declined to S1. The paradox is that if everyone tries to save more (even for good reasons), in the end they may end up saving less.
Brazil’s Beco Do Batman: How Graffiti Revived a Neighborhood How did the Beco Do Batman neighborhood in São Paolo turn graffiti into an economic growth engine?
I
n cities around the world, graffiti artists exhibit their talents on the sides of buildings, trains, and bridges, turning otherwise pristine areas into unsightly views. Graffiti is also a common tool used by gangs, which increases the perception of neighborhoods with graffiti as unsafe, leading to a reduction in their desirability as a place to live or visit. As a result, neighborhoods and cities have an incentive to clean up graffiti. But because cleanup costs can be expensive and graffiti artists often return, winning the war against graffiti becomes difficult. In one neighborhood in São Paulo, Brazil, instead of pumping more money into a never-ending battle on graffiti, residents decided on a markedly different strategy. What did the residents of Beco Do Batman (“Batman Alley” in Portuguese) choose to do?
Instead of cleaning up the graffiti, residents encouraged graffiti artists to come to the area. Since the 1980s, artists from around Brazil and other countries journeyed to Beco Do Batman to paint giant murals in its alleyways. Because the lack of unpainted walls means that new artists must paint over a previous artist’s work, a constantly changing art gallery is created for visitors to enjoy. How did this strategy of welcoming graffiti affect the neighborhood? First, overall crime declined. Because graffiti in Beco Do Batman was no longer a sign of gang power, criminal graffiti artists went elsewhere. This attracted wealthier residents and investors to build homes in the area, raising the property values of all homeowners and businesses. Second, as Beco Do Batman became a unique tourist attraction, money was spent by tourists who
357
visited the shops and restaurants in the area. The economic activity spurred by visitors created jobs and higher wages for its residents, who then had more money to spend. The cycle of increased economic activity generated a multiplier effect that allowed Beco Do Batman and its surrounding neighborhoods to thrive, pulling many of its residents out of poverty. The graffiti art of Beco Do Batman is a unique example of how aggregate expenditures and the multiplier effect can lead to higher economic growth.
GO TO
TO PRACTICE THE ECONOMIC CONCEPTS IN THIS STORY
CHECKPOINT THE SIMPLE AGGREGATE EXPENDITURES MODEL Ignoring both the government and the foreign sector in a simple aggregate expenditures model, macroeconomic equilibrium occurs when aggregate expenditures are just equal to what is being produced. At equilibrium, aggregate saving equals aggregate investment. The multiplier process amplifies new spending because some of the new spending is saved and some becomes additional spending. And some of that spending is saved and some is spent, and so on. The multiplier is equal to 1/(1 − MPC) = 1/MPS. The multiplier works in both directions. Changes in spending are amplified, changing income by more than the initial change in spending. The paradox of thrift results when households intend to save more, but at equilibrium they end up saving less.
QUESTION: Business journalists, pundits, economists, and policymakers all pay attention to the results
of the Conference Board’s monthly survey of 5,000 households, called the Consumer Confidence Index. When the index is rising, this is good news for the economy, and when it is falling, concerns are often heard that it portends a recession. Why is this survey important as a tool in forecasting where the economy is headed in the near future? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
358
THE FULL AGGREGATE EXPENDITURES MODEL With the simple aggregate expenditures model of the domestic private sector (individual consumption and private business investment), we concluded that at equilibrium, saving would equal investment, and that changes in spending lead to a larger change in income. This multiplier effect was an important insight by Keynes. To build the full aggregate expenditures model, we now turn our attention to adding government spending and taxes and the impact of the foreign sector.
Adding Government Spending and Taxes
Although government spending and tax policy can get complex, for our purposes it involves simple changes in government spending (G) or taxes (T). As we have seen in the previous section, any change in aggregate spending causes income and output to rise or fall by the spending change times the multiplier. Figure 10 illustrates a change in government spending. Initially, investment is $100; therefore, equilibrium income is $4,400 (point e), just as in Figure 6 earlier. Rather than investment rising by $100, let’s assume that the government decides to spend another $100. As Figure 10 shows, the new equilibrium is $4,800 (point b). This result is similar to the one in Figure 6, confirming that spending is spending; the economy does not care where it comes from. A quick summary is now in order. Equilibrium income is reached when injections (here, I + G = $200) equal withdrawals (in this case, S = $200). It did not matter whether these injections came from investment alone or from investment and government spending together. The key is spending. Changes in spending modify income by an amount equal to the change in spending times the multiplier. How, then, do changes in taxes affect the economy? The answers are not as simple in that case.
Tax Changes and Equilibrium
When taxes are increased, money is withdrawn from the economy’s spending stream. When taxes are reduced, money is injected into the economy’s spending stream because consumers and businesses have more to spend. Thus, taxes form a wedge between income and that part of income that can be spent, or disposable income. Disposable income (Yd) is equal to income minus taxes (Yd = Y − T). For simplicity, we will assume that all taxes are paid in a lump sum, thereby removing a certain fixed sum of money from the economy. This assumption does away with the need to worry now about the incentive effects of higher or lower tax rates. FIGURE 10
SAVING, INVESTMENT, AND GOVERNMENT SPENDING
359
A change in government spending (G) causes income and output to rise or fall by the spending change times the multiplier.
TABLE 2
KEYNESIAN EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS WITH TAXES
Income or Output (Y), in $
Taxes (T), in $
Disposable Income (Yd), in $
Consumption (C)
Saving (S)
Investment (I)
Government Spending (G)
4,000
100
3,900
3,925
−25
100
100
4,100
100
4,000
4,000
0
100
100
4,200
100
4,100
4,075
25
100
100
4,300
100
4,200
4,150
50
100
100
4,400
100
4,300
4,225
75
100
100
4,500
100
4,400
4,300
100
100
100
4,600
100
4,500
4,375
125
100
100
4,700
100
4,600
4,450
150
100
100
4,800
100
4,700
4,525
175
100
100
4,900
100
4,800
4,600
200
100
100
5,000
100
4,900
4,675
225
100
100
360
Returning to the model of the economy we have been developing, consumer spending now relates to disposable income (Y − T), rather than just income. Table 2 reflects this change, using disposable income to determine consumption. With government spending and taxes (fiscal policy) in the model, spending injections into the economy include government spending plus business investment (G + I). Withdrawals from the system include saving and taxes (S + T). Again, equilibrium requires that injections equal withdrawals, or in this case, G+I=S+T In our example, Table 2 shows that G + I = S + T at income level $4,500 (the shaded row in the table). If no tax had been imposed, equilibrium would have been at the point at which S = G + I, and thus at an income of $4,800 (point b in Figure 10, not shown in Table 2). Therefore, imposing the tax reduces equilibrium income by $300. Because taxes represent a withdrawal of spending from the economy, we would expect equilibrium income to fall when a tax is imposed. Yet, why does equilibrium income fall by only $300, and not by the tax multiplied by the multiplier, which would be $400? The answer is that consumers pay for this tax, in part, by reducing their saving. Specifically, with the MPC at 0.75, the $100 tax payment is split between consumption, reduced by $75, and saving, reduced by $25. When this $75 decrease in consumption is multiplied by the multiplier, this yields a decline in income of $300 ($75 × 4). The reduction in saving of $25 dampens the impact of the tax on equilibrium income because those funds were previously withdrawn from the spending stream. Changing the withdrawal category from saving to taxes does not affect income: Both are withdrawals. Equilibrium is shown at point g in Figure 11. At point g, I + G = S + T, with equilibrium income equal to $4,500 and taxes and saving equal to $100 each. The result is that a tax increase (or decrease, for that matter) will have less of a direct impact on income, employment, and output than will an equivalent change in government spending. For this reason, economists typically describe the “tax” multiplier (calculated as MPC/(1 − MPC)) as being smaller than the “spending” multiplier (1/(1 − MPC)).
The Balanced Budget Multiplier
By now you have probably noticed a curious thing. Our original equilibrium income was $4,400, with investment and saving equal at $100. When the government was introduced with a balanced budget (G = T = $100), income rose by $100 to $4,500, while equilibrium saving and investment remained constant at $100. FIGURE 11
SAVING, INVESTMENT, GOVERNMENT SPENDING, AND TAXES
361
Tax increases or decreases have less of a direct impact on income, employment, and output than an equivalent change in government spending. Some of a tax increase will come from saving and some of a tax decrease will go into saving, thereby reducing the effect of these tax changes.
This has led to what economists call the balanced budget multiplier. Equal changes in government spending and taxation (a balanced budget) lead to an equal change in income. Equivalently, the balanced budget multiplier is equal to 1. If spending and taxes are increased by the same amount, income grows by this amount, hence a balanced budget multiplier equal to 1. Note that the balanced budget multiplier is 1 no matter what the values of MPC and MPS. balanced budget multiplier Equal changes in government spending and taxation (a balanced budget) lead to an equal change in income (the balanced budget multiplier is equal to 1).
Adding Net Exports Thus far we have essentially assumed a closed economy by avoiding adding foreign transactions: exports and imports. We now add the foreign sector to complete the aggregate expenditures model. The impact of the foreign sector in the aggregate expenditures model is through net exports: exports minus imports (X − M). Exports are injections of spending into the domestic economy, and imports are withdrawals. When Africans purchase grain from American farmers, they are injecting new spending on grain into our economy. Conversely, when we purchase French wine, we are withdrawing spending (as saving does) and injecting these funds into the French economy. Figure 12 adds net exports to Figure 10 with investment and government spending. By adding $100 of net exports to the previous equilibrium at point b, equilibrium moves to $5,200 (point c). Again, we see the multiplier at work as the $100 in net exports leads to a $400 increase in income. With the foreign sector included, all injections into the economy must equal all withdrawals; therefore at equilibrium, I+G+X=S+T+M Thus, if we import more and all other spending remains the same, equilibrium income will fall. This is one reason
362
why many economists focus on the trade deficit or net exports (X − M) figures each month. The aggregate expenditures model illustrates the importance of spending in an economy. Investment, government spending, and exports all increase income, whereas saving, taxes, and imports reduce it. Further, the fact that consumers spend and save some of the changes in income (MPC and MPS) gives rise to a spending multiplier that magnifies the impact of changes in spending on the economy. FIGURE 12
SAVING, INVESTMENT, GOVERNMENT SPENDING, AND NET EXPORTS
Adding investment (I), government spending (G), and net exports (X − M) causes income and output to rise or fall by the spending change times the multiplier. In this figure, we have added net exports (X − M) of $100 to the investment and government spending in Figure 10 to get I + G + (X − M). Thus, an increase in investment spending, government spending, and net exports has the same effect on income and output.
Recessionary and Inflationary Gaps
Keynesian analysis illustrated what was needed to get the economy out of the Great Depression: an increase in aggregate spending. Without an increase in spending, an economy can be stuck at a point below full employment for an extended period of time. Therefore, Keynes argued that if consumers, businesses, and foreigners were unwilling to spend (their economic expectations were clearly dismal), government should. This was also the basic rationale for the extraordinary spending measures implemented by Congress and signed by President Obama during the 2007–2009 recession. This leads to the question of just how much additional spending is needed to return the economy to full employment.
Recessionary Gap
The recessionary gap is the increase in aggregate spending needed to bring a depressed economy back to full
363
employment. Note that it is not the difference between real GDP at full employment and current real GDP, which is called the GDP gap. If full employment income is $4,400 and our current equilibrium income is $4,000, the recessionary gap is the added spending ($100) that when boosted by the multiplier (4 in this case) will close a GDP gap ($400). recessionary gap The increase in aggregate spending needed (when expanded by the multiplier) to bring a depressed economy back to full employment.
Inflationary Gap
If aggregate spending generates income above full employment levels, the economy will eventually heat up, creating inflationary pressures. Essentially, the economy is trying to produce more output and income than it can sustain for very long. Thus, the excess aggregate spending exceeding that necessary to result in full employment is the inflationary gap. Using our previous example, if full employment is an income of $4,400 and our current equilibrium is $4,800, a reduction in spending is needed to close the $400 GDP gap and to prevent inflation from building. In this case, a reduction in aggregate expenditures of $100 with a multiplier of 4 would bring the economy back to full employment at $4,400. In sum, changes in aggregate expenditures expanded by the multiplier can help bring an economy facing either recessionary or inflationary pressures back into equilibrium sooner. inflationary gap The spending reduction necessary (when expanded by the multiplier) to bring an overheated economy back to full employment.
This Keynesian approach to analyzing aggregate spending revolutionized the way economists looked at the economy and led to the development of modern macroeconomics. In the next chapter, we extend our analysis to the aggregate demand and supply model, a modern extension of this aggregate expenditures model to account for varying price levels and the supply side of the macroeconomy.
ISSUE Was Keynes Right About the Great Depression? There is little disagreement that the Great Depression was one of the most important events in the United States in modern history. Good aggregate data were not yet available, but President Roosevelt and congressional leaders knew something was very wrong. Within a couple of years, 10,000 banks collapsed, farms and businesses were lost, the stock market lost 85% of its value from the beginning of the decade, and soup kitchens fed a growing horde as unemployment soared to nearly 25%, up from 3.2% in 1929. Worse, the Great Depression persisted: It did not look to be temporary; there was no end in sight.
364
The aggregate expenditures model we have just studied provides some insight into the Great Depression. The figure plots hypothetical saving and investment curves over the actual data for 1929 and 1933. Both government and the foreign sector were tiny at this time; therefore, the simple aggregate expenditures model effectively illustrates why the Great Depression did not show signs of much improvement; by 1939 the unemployment rate was still over 17%. Saving and investment were over $16 billion in 1929, or roughly a healthy 15% of GDP (point a). By 1933 investment collapsed to just over $1 billion (a 91% decline), and the economy was in equilibrium at an income of roughly half of that in 1929 (point b). Government spending remained at roughly the same levels while net exports, a small fraction of aggregate expenditures, fell by more than half of their previous levels.
Keynes had it right: Unless something happened to increase investment or exports (not likely given that the rest of the world was suffering economically as well), the economy would remain mired in the Great Depression (point b). He suggested that government spending was needed. Ten years later (1943), the United States was in the middle of World War II, and aggregate expenditures swelled as government spending rose by a factor of 10. The Great Depression was history.
365
CHECKPOINT THE FULL AGGREGATE EXPENDITURES MODEL Government spending affects the economy in the same way as other spending. Tax increases withdraw money from the spending stream but do not affect the economy as much as spending reductions, because these tax increases are partly offset by decreases in saving. Tax decreases inject money into the economy but do not affect the economy as much as spending increases, because tax reductions are partly offset by increases in saving. Equal changes in government spending and taxes (a balanced budget) result in an equal change in income (a balanced budget multiplier of 1). A recessionary gap is the new spending required that, when expanded by the multiplier, moves the economy to full employment. An inflationary gap is the spending reduction necessary (again when expanded by the multiplier) to bring the economy back to full employment.
QUESTIONS: If the government is considering reducing taxes to stimulate the economy, does it matter if the MPS is 0.25 or 0.33? What if the government reduces government spending by an equal amount to fund the tax cut? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
366
chapter summary Section 1 Aggregate Expenditures 8.1
Gross domestic product (GDP) is measured by spending or income. Using the spending approach, GDP is equal to aggregate expenditures (AE). Therefore, GDP = AE = C + I + G + (X – M)
8.2
The 45° line shows where total spending (AE) equals income. No borrowing or saving exists. The consumption line (C) starts above the origin on the vertical axis (even with no income, one still consumes by borrowing). As income increases, consumption rises, but not as fast as income (the slope of C depends on the MPC). When C crosses AE, spending equals income (on the 45° line). When C is below the AE line, saving is positive.
367
Investment spending fluctuates much more than consumption year to year. Disposable income, YD, is income after all taxes have been paid. Disposable income can either be spent (C) or saved (S). Thus, YD = C + S. The portion that is consumed or saved is an important concept in the aggregate expenditures model:
8.3
Marginal propensity to consume (MPC) = ΔC ÷ ΔYD Marginal propensity to save (MPS) = ΔS ÷ ΔYD MPC + MPS = 1 (all money is either spent or saved)
Even with little to no income, college students still consume goods and services, often by borrowing against future income.
8.4
Determinants of Consumption and Saving The aggregate expenditures model states that income is the main determinant of
368
consumption and saving. But other factors also can shift the consumption schedule, such as: Wealth Expectations Household debt Taxes Determinants of Investment Demand Investment demand is assumed to be independent of income, but certain factors can shift investment demand, such as: Expectations Technological change Operating costs Capital goods on hand
Section 2 The Simple Aggregate Expenditures Model Ignoring government spending and net exports, aggregate expenditures (AE) are the sum of consumer and business investment: AE = C + I. Because AE also equals C + S at equilibrium, this means that saving equals investment.
8.5
With no investment, Income = $12 million. With $1 million in investment, income rises to $15 million, an increase of $3 million. The multiplier in this example is 3.
8.6
The multiplier effect occurs when a dollar of spending generates many more dollars of spending in the economy.
369
The multiplier is equal to 1/(1 − MPC) or 1/MPS
Section 3 The Full Aggregate Expenditures Model 8.7
Government spending affects the economy just like any other spending, and so does spending by foreign consumers (exports). In the full aggregate expenditures model, all forms of spending are analyzed, including C, I, G, and (X − M). If the multiplier for an economy is 5, a $1 million increase in investment increases income by $5 million. The same effect occurs with a $1 million increase in government spending or $1 million increase in net exports. Essentially, spending is spending, no matter where it comes from.
8.8
A general way to analyze policies that increase or decrease aggregate output is to categorize activities as either an injection or a withdrawal: Injections increase spending in an economy, and include investment (I), government spending (G), and exports (X). Withdrawals decrease spending in an economy, and include savings (S), taxes (T), and imports (M). In equilibrium, all injections must equal all withdrawals:
370
I+G+X=S+T+M
Purchasing an American-made car injects spending into the economy, and the economic benefits are enhanced by the multiplier.
8.9
Whenever the economy moves away from its full employment equilibrium, one of two gaps is created: Recessionary gap: The increase in aggregate spending (that is then multiplied) to bring a depressed economy to full employment. Inflationary gap: The reduction in aggregate spending (again expanded by the multiplier) needed to reduce income to full employment levels.
Purchasing a foreign-made car, however, results in a withdrawal because money leaves the country, and this effect is compounded by the multiplier.
KEY CONCEPTS aggregate expenditures consumption saving average propensity to consume average propensity to save marginal propensity to consume marginal propensity to save investment Keynesian macroeconomic equilibrium injections withdrawals
371
multiplier paradox of thrift balanced budget multiplier recessionary gap inflationary gap
QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS Check Your Understanding 1. Describe the important difference between the average propensity to consume (APC) and the marginal propensity to consume (MPC). 2. List the factors that influence an individual’s marginal propensity to consume. 3. Explain why we wouldn’t expect investment to grow sufficiently to pull the economy out of a depression. 4. Define the multiplier effect. Describe why a multiplier exists. 5. Explain why a $100 reduction in taxes does not have the same impact on output and employment as a $100 increase in government spending. 6. How do injections and withdrawals into an economy affect its income and output?
Apply the Concepts 7. Assume a simple Keynesian depression economy with a multiplier of 4 and an initial equilibrium income of $3,000. Saving and investment equal $400, and assume full employment income is $4,000. a. What is the MPC equal to? The MPS? b. How much would government spending have to rise to move the economy to full employment? c. Assume that the government plans to finance any spending by raising taxes to cover the increase in spending (it intends to run a balanced budget). How much will government spending and taxes have to rise to move the economy to full employment? d. From the initial equilibrium, if investment grows by $100, what will be the new equilibrium level of income and savings?
8. Other than reductions in interest rates that increase the level of investment by businesses, what factors would result in higher investment? 9. The simple aggregate expenditures model argues that one form of spending is just as good as any other; increases in all types of spending lead to equal increases in income. Is there any reason to suspect that private investment might be better for the economy than government spending? 10. Assume that the economy is in equilibrium at $5,700, and full employment is $4,800. If the MPC is 0.67, how big is the inflationary gap? 11. How does the economy today differ from that of the Great Depression, the economy Keynes used as the basis for the macroeconomic model discussed in this chapter? 12. In modern politics, the word “Keynesian” often is synonymous with “big government” spending. Does this characterization accurately reflect the role of government in spurring economic activity? How would a tax cut be characterized today versus in Keynes’s time?
In the News 13. In recent years banks have encouraged their customers to save by giving incentives to join programs that automatically transfer money from checking accounts to savings accounts. For example, a bank might offer to round debit transactions to the nearest dollar, transferring the change to one’s savings account, and then boost this amount with a match up to a certain amount. Although these programs were intended to encourage customers to save, some economists are not very enthusiastic about these programs. What reasons, both practical and theoretical, might cause some to be concerned?
372
14. The Affordable Care Act (a.k.a. Obamacare) is one of the largest government programs to be implemented in recent years, and involves the use of government subsidies to increase the percentage of Americans with health insurance. Explain how the increase in government spending may lead to a multiplier effect. How might this multiplier be affected if taxes are raised to finance the increased government spending?
Solving Problems 15. Using this aggregate expenditures table, answer the questions that follow.
a. b. c. d. e.
Income (Y), in $
Consumption (C), in $
Saving (S), in $
2,200
2,320
−120
2,300
2,380
−80
2,400
2,440
−40
2,500
2,500
0
2,600
2,560
40
2,700
2,620
80
2,800
2,680
120
2,900
2,740
160
3,000
2,800
200
Compute the APC when income equals $2,300 and the APS when income equals $2,800. Compute the MPC and MPS. What does the multiplier equal? If investment spending is equal to $120, what will be equilibrium income? Using the following graph, show saving, investment, and equilibrium income.
373
WORK IT OUT 16. Use the figure to answer the following questions. a. What are the MPC, the MPS, and the multiplier? b. If the economy is currently in equilibrium at point a, and full employment income is $4,000, how much in additional expenditures is needed to move this economy to full employment? What is this level of spending called? c. Assume that the economy is currently in equilibrium at point a and full employment income is $4,000. How much of a tax decrease would be required to move the economy to full employment?
374
USING THE NUMBERS 17. According to By the Numbers, in the year 2015, by how much did total food and grocery consumption exceed total gasoline and energy consumption? Based on your knowledge of how food and gas prices have changed since 2015, how would this difference in spending change? 18. According to By the Numbers, the U.S. government spends less per person than any other developed country on the list. Does this mean that the overall size of the U.S. government is smaller than that of the other developed countries? Why or why not?
ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS Checkpoint: Aggregate Expenditures Consumer spending, while 5 times larger in absolute size than investment spending, involves many small expenditures by households that do not vary much from month to month, such as rent (or mortgage payment), food, and utilities. Consumers change habits, but slowly. Business investment expenditures are typically on big-ticket items such as new factories and equipment, but such investments occur only when businesses have favorable expectations about the economy. When expectations sour, investment by all firms in an industry typically falls. Checkpoint: The Simple Aggregate Expenditures Model When consumer confidence is declining, this may suggest that consumers are going to spend less and save more. Because consumer spending is about 68% of aggregate spending, a small decline represents a significant reduction in aggregate spending and may well mean that a recession is on the horizon. Relatively small changes in consumer spending coupled with the multiplier can mean relatively large changes in income, and therefore forecasters and policymakers should keep a close eye on consumer confidence. Checkpoint: The Full Aggregate Expenditures Model Yes, it does matter. If the tax reduction is going to be $100, for example, and the MPS is 0.25, the multiplier is 4, and the income increase will be $75 × 4 = $300. Keep in mind that in this case, one-fourth of the tax reduction will go into saving and will not be amplified by the multiplier. However, with a MPS of 0.33, the multiplier will be 3, and one-third will not be multiplied (will go into saving); therefore, the increase in income will be $66.6 × 3 = $200. If government spending is reduced by an amount equal to the tax cut, income in the economy will fall by exactly the value of the reduction in government spending. The balanced budget multiplier is equal to 1, regardless of the value of MPS. 1John
Maynard Keynes, The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich), 1936, p. 96.
375
9
Aggregate Demand and Supply
376
Understanding how the interaction of total spending and production explains the 377
booms and busts of an economy
Learning Objectives 9.1
Explain what an aggregate demand curve is and what it represents.
9.2
Describe why the aggregate demand curve has a negative slope due to the wealth, export, and interest rate effects.
9.3
List the determinants of aggregate demand.
9.4
Analyze the aggregate supply curve and differentiate between the short run and long run.
9.5
Describe the determinants of an aggregate supply curve.
9.6
Use AD/AS analysis to illustrate long-run and short-run macroeconomic equilibrium.
9.7
Define the multiplier and describe why it is important.
9.8
Describe demand-pull and cost-push inflation.
A
mong cities that have changed dramatically over the past two decades is Dubai, a large city in the Middle East that thrived on oil production. But unlike many other oilrich cities, at the start of the new millennium, Dubai undertook a strategy of transforming its economy to one less dependent on oil, as it foresaw (correctly) a
future when oil is no longer an endless source of money. What did Dubai do?
Investors and the government in Dubai invested heavily in infrastructure, building massive skyscrapers that became home to multinational corporations, luxury homes and condos (including thousands on artificial islands in the Persian Gulf) to attract wealthy foreigners seeking a vacation home, and some of the most lavish shopping malls and attractions to make Dubai a world travel destination. By diversifying its economy, Dubai ensured that its capacity to produce goods and services that consumers desired extended beyond energy resources. The takeaway from Dubai’s strategy is that the state of an economy cannot be assessed solely based on the performance of a single market, region, or time period. Likewise, government policies are often designed to meet the needs of an entire nation. It would be dangerous to look at just one region or one industry and come to conclusions or make policy recommendations for the nation as a whole. British economist John Maynard Keynes recognized the need to develop tools to analyze the macroeconomy as a whole. He focused on aggregate expenditures by consumers, businesses, and governments as the key drivers for the economy that determined employment and output. But the model he developed during the Great Depression did not fully consider the effect that changes in the economy would have on prices. Why? Keynes focused on the problem at hand, when resources were underutilized. For this reason, an expansion of consumption or production did not create much upward pressure on prices. For example, in times of high unemployment, more labor can be hired without raising wages because firms with job openings often are inundated with applicants.
378
Therefore, the initial Keynesian model was a fixed price model, one that essentially ignored the supply side because increasing production would occur without a rise in prices. The lessons from Keynes, with their focus on spending, formed the foundation of the demand side of the modern macroeconomic model. In this chapter, we add the supply side and move from a fixed price model to a flexible price model, where prices and wages adjust to macroeconomic conditions. We call this model the aggregate demand–aggregate supply (AD/AS) model. This model looks a lot like the supply and demand model for a market, but it has several important differences: It measures real output of the aggregate (overall) economy, it uses the average price level for an economy, and it focuses on short-run fluctuations around a long-run equilibrium output. The response of prices and wages does not always change in a consistent manner. As we will see, sometimes prices and wages can be sticky in the short run, a condition that allows an economy to respond positively to economic stimulus policies. But in the long run, prices and wages tend to be very responsive to changing macroeconomic conditions.
379
380
This flexible price model expands the analysis that began with Keynes to many more modern problems facing economies. The AD/AS model builds on skills you already have: defining demand and supply curves, assessing changes in economic facts, and determining a new equilibrium. These techniques provide policymakers with a way of looking at the overall economy when many factors and differences in economic performance prevail across regions and industries. This chapter begins with an analysis of aggregate demand and its determinants. We then turn to aggregate supply, studying the differences between a long-run aggregate supply curve and a short-run aggregate supply curve, and the determinants of each. Finally, we put the aggregate demand and aggregate supply curves together to analyze macroeconomic equilibrium. The AD/AS model gives you the tools to analyze tradeoffs between economic output and inflation. It will allow you to understand the causes of recessions and inflation, and how government policy is sometimes used to correct these problems.
381
AGGREGATE DEMAND The aggregate demand (AD) curve (or schedule) shows the output of goods and services (real GDP) demanded at different price levels. The aggregate demand curve in Figure 1 looks like the product demand curves we studied earlier. They both slope downward, showing how output rises as prices fall, and vice versa. However, it’s important to remember that the reasons the product and aggregate demand curves slope downward are different. aggregate demand The output of goods and services (real GDP) demanded at different price levels.
Why Is the Aggregate Demand Curve Negatively Sloped?
Product demand curves slope downward due to income and substitution effects. An income effect occurs when the price of a given product falls, resulting in money being freed up, allowing consumers to afford more of all goods. A substitution effect occurs when the price of a product falls, causing consumers to purchase more of the product because they substitute it for other higher-priced goods. Income and substitution effects work the other way when the price of a given product rises. Although these explanations work for a product demand curve, they do not explain why an aggregate demand curve slopes downward, because aggregate demand does not measure the demand for just one product, but rather it measures the demand for all products. For the latter, we need to look at other factors influencing the aggregate economy. FIGURE 1
THE AGGREGATE DEMAND CURVE
382
The aggregate demand curve shows the amount of real goods and services (Output = Real GDP) that will be purchased at various price levels.
The Wealth Effect
One reason that real output declines when the aggregate price level rises is the resulting reduction in household wealth, called the wealth effect. Households usually hold some of their wealth in financial assets such as savings accounts, bonds, and cash. A rising aggregate price level means that the purchasing power of this monetary wealth is declining. If, for example, you have $5,000 in a savings account and prices rise throughout the economy, that $5,000 will now purchase less than before. This reduction in household purchasing power means that some purchases are put on hold, thereby reducing output demanded. This is represented by a movement from point a to point b in Figure 1. wealth effect Households usually hold some of their wealth in financial assets such as savings accounts, bonds, and cash, and a rising aggregate price level means that the purchasing power of this monetary wealth declines, reducing output demanded.
Export Price Effect
When the U.S. aggregate price level rises, American goods become more expensive in the global marketplace. Higher prices mean that our goods are less competitive with the goods made in other countries. The result is that foreigners purchase fewer American products, and our exports decline. A decrease in exports means that the demand for domestically produced goods and services (the quantity purchased by foreign consumers, a component of real GDP) also declines. Therefore, higher prices result in lower real output.
Interest Rate Effect
Interest rates are the prices paid for the use of money. If we assume for a moment that the quantity of money is fixed, then as aggregate prices rise, people will need more money to carry out their economic transactions. As people demand more money, the cost of borrowing money—interest rates—will go up. Rising interest rates mean reduced business investment, which results in a drop in quantity demanded for real GDP, shown in Figure 1 as a movement from point a to b and falling real output. In summary, the aggregate demand curve is negatively sloped because of three factors. When the aggregate price level rises, this lowers household purchasing power because of the wealth effect. A rising aggregate price level also lowers the amount of exports because our goods are now more expensive. Furthermore, a rising aggregate price level increases the demand for money and therefore drives up interest rates. Rising interest rates reduce business investment and reduce the quantity demanded of real GDP. In each case, as aggregate prices rise from P0 to P1, quantity demanded of real GDP falls from Q0 to Q1.
Determinants of Aggregate Demand We have seen that the aggregate demand curve is negatively sloped. Everything else held constant, a change in the aggregate price level will change the quantity of real GDP demanded along the aggregate demand curve. The determinants of aggregate demand are those factors that shift the entire aggregate demand curve when they change. They are the “everything else held constant.” These include the components of GDP: consumption, investment, government spending, and net exports. If one of these components of aggregate spending changes, the aggregate demand curve will shift, as shown in Figure 2. At first, aggregate demand is AD0; therefore, a shift to AD1 represents an increase in aggregate demand; more real output is demanded at the same price level, P0. If, for example, businesses decide to invest more in new technology, more real output is now demanded at the current price level, P0, and at all other price levels. For similar reasons, a decrease in aggregate demand to AD2 means that less real output is being demanded. If consumers fear the onset of a recession and decide to reduce spending to increase their savings, then less output will be demanded at all
383
price levels. Let’s look at these determinants of aggregate demand more closely. What might cause the various components of aggregate expenditures to change, shifting the AD curve?
Consumer Spending
Consumer spending is the largest component of aggregate demand, representing about 68% of total spending in the economy. The level of spending as a percentage of overall output is relatively stable over time. Still, consumer spending is affected by several major factors: wealth, consumer confidence, household debt, interest rates, and taxes. Because consumer spending represents such a large part of the economy, even small changes in these factors can have a significant impact on the economy. And in times when consumption changes a lot, the effect on the economy can be dramatic. FIGURE 2
SHIFTS IN THE AGGREGATE DEMAND CURVE
The determinants of aggregate demand include the components of GDP and aggregate spending: consumption, investment, government spending, and net exports. A change in one will shift the aggregate demand curve, as shown here. At first, aggregate demand is AD0; therefore, a shift to AD1 represents an increase in aggregate demand; more real output is demanded at all price levels. A decline in aggregate demand to AD2 means that less real output is being demanded at all price levels.
For example, when home prices skyrocketed in the mid-2000s, homeowners became wealthier, which led to more consumer spending throughout the economy. But when housing prices along with the stock market declined in 2008 and 2009, coupled with reduced consumer confidence, an unusually large drop in consumer spending resulted, which became an important factor in the depth of the recession. Note that changes in wealth have two similar but distinct impacts on aggregate demand. First, as described
384
earlier, when aggregate prices rise, the purchasing power of financial assets falls, reducing the amount of goods and services that can now be purchased with this money. This is a movement along an existing aggregate demand curve to a higher price level (point a to b in Figure 2). Second, described here, is a decrease in wealth (e.g., caused by a stock market crash) that reduces consumption at all price levels. In this case, the entire aggregate demand curve shifts from AD0 to AD2 in Figure 2. This is the impact of changing wealth on consumer spending that is usually the focus of attention by the media and policymakers. Consumer expectations and confidence about the economy play a significant role in determining the level of consumer spending. High confidence in the economy eases job security fears and stimulates consumer spending, shifting the aggregate demand curve to the right. High family debt ratios restrict access to future credit, reducing spending on high-ticket items often bought on credit. Higher interest rates increase the cost of borrowing (whether on loans or credit card balances), making purchases more difficult. And finally, higher taxes reduce disposable income which reduces consumer spending, shifting the aggregate demand curve to the left.
Investment
Investment (spending, mostly by businesses for structures, equipment, and software) is determined mainly by interest rates and the expected rate of return on capital projects. When interest rates rise, investment will fall and the aggregate demand curve will shift to the left, and vice versa. When business expectations become more favorable—perhaps some new technology is introduced, or excess capacity is reduced—investment will increase, and the aggregate demand curve will increase, or shift to the right. But if businesses see clouds on the horizon, such as new regulations, higher taxes, restrictions on the use of technology, or excess capacity, investment will drop, and the aggregate demand curve will shift to the left. Because investment decisions tend to be larger in magnitude than everyday consumption purchases, investment varies much more from year to year. Therefore, although investment represents a smaller percentage of aggregate demand, its relative instability can result in a significant effect on the aggregate economy.
Government Spending and Net Exports
Government spending and net exports have essentially the same effect on the aggregate economy as consumer and investment spending. When government spending or net exports rise, aggregate demand increases, and vice versa. A favorable exchange rate for the euro makes shopping trips to New York City for Europeans less expensive, providing a boost to U.S. aggregate demand.
385
When the national income of a foreign country rises, some of this money is used to buy more American goods and services. The increase in demand for U.S. goods and services in other countries results in more exports, which increases U.S. aggregate demand. A change in foreign exchange rates will also affect aggregate demand. An appreciation, or rise, in the value of the euro, for instance, will result in Europeans buying more American goods because a euro will buy more. Again, this change increases U.S. exports and U.S. aggregate demand. These effects on aggregate demand are offset by increases in imports of foreign goods, because goods are being demanded from outside of the United States. A quick summary is now in order. The aggregate demand curve shows the quantities of real GDP demanded at different price levels. (The derivation of the AD curve using the Keynesian fixed price model is shown in the Appendix to this chapter.) The aggregate demand curve slopes downward because of the wealth effect (the value of monetary assets falls when the price level rises), because exports fall as domestic prices rise, and because rising prices raise interest rates, which reduce investment. On the other hand, changes in one of the determinants of aggregate demand shift the aggregate demand curve. Table 1 summarizes the determinants of aggregate demand. Again, the determinants of aggregate demand are those “other factors held constant”: consumption, investment, government spending, and net exports. If one of those determinants changes, the entire aggregate demand curve will shift. Keep in mind that changes in the determinants are most important for policymaking. When a policy is enacted (say, lower tax rates), policymakers expect to stimulate consumer and investment spending, increasing aggregate demand, output, and employment.
TABLE 1
THE DETERMINANTS OF AGGREGATE DEMAND (THE AGGREGATE DEMAND CURVE SHIFTS WHEN THESE CHANGE)
Determinant
AD Increases
AD Decreases
Consumer Spending Wealth
Wealth increases
Wealth decreases
Consumer expectations
Expectations improve
Expectations worsen
Household debt
Debt falls
Debt rises
386
Interest rates
Lower
Higher
Taxes
Taxes are cut
Taxes increase
Lower
Higher
Expected rate of Higher return on investment
Lower
Business expectations
More positive
More negative
Taxes
Taxes are cut
Taxes increase
Increase
Decrease
Income in other countries
Rising
Falling
Exchange rate changes
Depreciating dollar
Appreciating dollar
Investment Interest rates
Government Spending Net Exports
Myanmar: Opening a Country to a Boom in Aggregate Demand How did Myanmar’s transition from an authoritarian regime to a democracy lead to an increase in aggregate demand?
F
or many nations in Asia and Africa that had been colonized by Europeans in the 19th and 20th centuries, a cultural clash existed between the rich histories of the native inhabitants and the modern influences that were brought by the colonizers. When many of these countries (including major countries such as India and Vietnam) achieved independence in the mid-20th century, the new governments struggled to find a balance between minimizing their colonizer’s cultural influences and maintaining the economic developments that were achieved. Often, this led to war and a path toward declining economic growth. For one South Asian nation whose experience under long military rule resulted in one of the most impoverished nations in the world, the transition to a democratic nation in 2012 was a significant economic event.
387
What happened in Myanmar since 2012 that has resulted in a significant increase in aggregate demand? Myanmar (formerly Burma) achieved its independence from the British in 1948, but the transition process was not smooth, as various political organizations (each supported by a segment of the military) competed for power. This culminated in 1962 with a strict authoritarian regime led by a series of political parties that ruled by force. It would take another 50 years before Myanmar held its first democratic elections. Since 2012 foreign investment has entered the country of 53 million, welcomed by a labor force eager to work, even at low wages, for a chance at a better life. The improved employment picture led to increased consumption, and subsequently the opening of new markets and service industries. Then, a very significant change occurred: The re-introduction of the foreign tourist, largely banned during military rule, who came by the thousands to experience Myanmar’s rich 13,000-year history filled with temples and other historical treasures. These tourists brought hard currency (such as dollars, euros, and yen) into a nation seeking to connect with the world that it had long ago abandoned. Each of these events, which led to an increase in consumption, investment, government spending, and net exports, resulted in a dramatic increase in aggregate demand, and subsequently an annual growth rate that ranks among the highest in the world. Today, Myanmar’s future is as bright as its rich historical past centuries ago.
GO TO
TO PRACTICE THE ECONOMIC CONCEPTS IN THIS STORY
As important as aggregate demand is in determining an economy’s output, aggregate demand tells only one part of the story. The other part, aggregate supply, describes the impetus for businesses to create and produce goods and services, which we turn to next.
CHECKPOINT AGGREGATE DEMAND The aggregate demand curve shows the relationship between real GDP and the price level. The aggregate demand curve has a negative slope because of the impact of the price level on financial wealth, exports, and interest rates. The determinants of aggregate demand are consumer spending, investment spending, government expenditures, and net exports. Changes in any of these determinants will shift the aggregate demand curve.
QUESTION: Housing and stock market prices have risen substantially in recent years. Explain how this affects aggregate demand in an economy. Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
388
389
AGGREGATE SUPPLY The aggregate supply curve shows the real GDP that firms will produce at varying price levels. Even though the definition seems similar to that for aggregate demand, note that we have now moved from the spending side of the economy to the production side. We will consider two different possibilities for aggregate supply: the short run and the long run. In the short run, aggregate supply is positively sloped and prices rise when GDP grows. In contrast, long-run aggregate supply reflects the long-run state of the economy and is represented by a vertical curve. Growth occurs in the economy by shifting this vertical aggregate supply curve to the right. Let’s begin by looking at the economy from the long-run perspective. aggregate supply The real GDP that firms will produce at varying price levels. The aggregate supply curve is positively sloped in the short run but vertical in the long run.
Long Run
The vertical long-run aggregate supply (LRAS) curve incorporates the assumptions of classical (pre-1930s) economic analysis. Classical analysis assumes that all variables are adjustable in the long run, where product prices, wages, and interest rates are flexible. As a result, the economy will gravitate to the position of full employment shown as Q0 in Figure 3. long-run aggregate supply (LRAS) curve The long-run aggregate supply curve is vertical at full employment because the economy has reached its capacity to produce.
Full employment is often referred to as the natural rate of output or the natural rate of unemployment by economists. This long-run output is an equilibrium level at which inflationary pressures are minimal. Once the economy has reached this level, further increases in output are extremely difficult to achieve; there is no one else to operate more machines, and no more machines to operate. As we will see later, attempts to expand beyond this output level only lead to higher prices and rising inflation. In general terms, the vertical LRAS curve represents the full employment capacity of the economy and depends on the amount of resources available for production and the available technology. Full employment is determined by the capital available, the size and quality of the labor force, and the technology employed; in effect, the productive capacity of the economy. Remember from earlier chapters that these are also the big three factors driving economic growth (shifting the LRAS0 curve to the right to LRAS1) once a suitable infrastructure has been put in place. FIGURE 3
LONG-RUN AGGREGATE SUPPLY
390
The long-run aggregate supply (LRAS) curve is vertical, reflecting the assumptions of classical economic analysis. In the long run, all variables in the economy can adjust, and the economy will settle at full employment at output Q0. Changes in the amount of resources available, the quality of the labor force, and technology can shift the LRAS curve to the right to LRAS1, at a new full employment output at Q1.
Determinants of Long-Run Aggregate Supply Attempts to improve technology such as automation and digitalization are clear examples of an increase in productive capacity. But so is the enhancement of labor quality. As a greater percentage of people pursue college and postgraduate degrees, productivity increases and leads to economic growth. Finally, increased trade and globalization have allowed resources to flow more freely, permitting the United States to gain access to better or cheaper inputs and more specialized labor. Each of the shifts in the LRAS curve takes time. It’s not easy to improve the human capital of an entire nation or to develop new production technologies. Therefore, although the LRAS is of concern to the long-term welfare of the country, policymakers are often more concerned about short-run outcomes. We now turn to the short-run aggregate supply (SRAS) curve.
Short Run
Figure 4 shows the short-run aggregate supply (SRAS) curve, which is positively sloped because some input costs are slow to change in the short run. When prices rise, firms do not immediately see an increase in wages or rents because these are often fixed for a specified term; in other words, input prices are sticky. Thus, profits will rise with the rising prices and firms will supply more output as their profits increase. short-run aggregate supply (SRAS) curve The short-run aggregate supply curve is positively sloped because many input costs are slow to change (sticky) in the short run.
391
This situation, however, cannot last for long. As an entire industry or the economy as a whole increases its production, firms must start hiring more labor or paying overtime. As each firm seeks more employees, wages are driven up, increasing costs and forcing higher prices. For the economy as a whole, a rise in real GDP results in higher employment and reduced unemployment. Lower unemployment rates mean a tightening of labor markets. This often leads to fierce collective bargaining by labor, followed by increases in wages, costs, and prices. The result is that a short-run increase in GDP is usually accompanied by a rise in the price level.
Determinants of Short-Run Aggregate Supply We have seen that, because the aggregate supply curve is positively sloped in the short run, a change in aggregate output, other things held constant, will result in a change in the aggregate price level. The determinants of short-run aggregate supply—those other things held constant—include changes in input prices, productivity, taxes, regulation, the market power of firms, or business and inflationary expectations. When any of these determinants change, the entire SRAS curve shifts, as Figure 5 illustrates. FIGURE 4
SHORT-RUN AGGREGATE SUPPLY
The short-run aggregate supply (SRAS) curve is positively sloped because many input costs are slow to change in the short run (they are sticky).
Input Prices
Changes in the cost of land, labor, or capital will change the output that firms are willing to provide to the market. When world crude oil prices rise, it is never long before prices rise at the gasoline pump. Rising input prices are quickly passed along to consumers, and the opposite is true as well. New discoveries of raw materials result in falling input prices, causing the prices for products incorporating these inputs to drop. This means that more of these
392
products can be produced at a price of P0 in Figure 5 as short-run aggregate supply shifts to SRAS1 (point a), or now output Q0 can be produced at a lower price on SRAS1 (point b). The dramatic rise in copper prices from 2006 to 2012 increased the cost of producing copper products, and contributed to a decrease in aggregate supply.
Productivity
Changes in productivity are another major determinant of short-run aggregate supply. Rising productivity will shift the short-run aggregate supply curve to the right—from SRAS0 to SRAS1 in Figure 5—and vice versa. This is why changes in technology that increase productivity are so important to the economy. Technological advances, moreover, often lead to new products that expand short-run aggregate supply. The willingness of firms to invest in new capital equipment (aided by an improved business outlook) will enhance the productive capacity of an economy, which can also increase long-run aggregate supply. An example of a technological advance is the improvement in traffic-enhanced GPS navigational devices, which allows one to select the quickest route to a destination taking into account traffic and roadblocks (such as those caused by construction projects and car crashes) in real time. Such technological enhancements let commercial vehicles reduce their time on the road, reducing transportation costs to the company. These cost reductions lead to an increase in short-run aggregate supply. If these technologies expand the overall productive capacity of the economy, they can also increase long-run aggregate supply. FIGURE 5
SHIFTS IN SHORT-RUN AGGREGATE SUPPLY
393
The determinants of short-run aggregate supply include changes in input prices, productivity, taxes, regulation, the market power of firms, and inflationary expectations. If one of these determinants changes, the entire short-run aggregate supply curve shifts. Increasing productivity, for instance, will shift the short-run aggregate supply curve to the right, from SRAS0 to SRAS1. Conversely, raising taxes or adding inefficient regulations can shift the short-run aggregate supply curve to the left, from SRAS0 to SRAS2.
Taxes and Regulation
Rising taxes or increased regulation can shift the short-run aggregate supply curve to the left, from SRAS0 to SRAS2 in Figure 5. Excessively burdensome regulation, though it may provide some benefits, raises costs so much that the new costs exceed the benefits. This results in a decrease in short-run aggregate supply. Often, no one knows how much regulation has increased costs until some sort of deregulation is instituted. Alternatively, tax reductions such as investment tax credits reduce the costs of production, resulting in an increase in short-run aggregate supply. Similarly, improving the process of satisfying regulations, such as reducing required paperwork, also can increase short-run aggregate supply even when the regulations themselves do not change.
Market Power of Firms
Monopoly firms charge more than competitive firms. Therefore, a change in the market power of firms can increase prices for specific products, thereby reducing short-run aggregate supply. When the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) formed in 1973, it raised oil prices by over 200% within three years by reducing the global supply of oil. Because at that time there were very few substitutes for oil, higher oil prices shifted the SRAS curve to the left. Today, with many non-OPEC nations (such as Russia, Norway, and Canada) producing large quantities of oil, OPEC’s power to raise prices has fallen.
394
Inflationary Expectations
A change in inflationary expectations by businesses, workers, or consumers can shift the short-run aggregate supply curve. If, for example, workers believe that inflation is going to increase, they will bargain for higher wages to offset the expected losses to real wages. The intensified bargaining and resulting higher wages will reduce aggregate supply. To summarize, the short-run aggregate supply curve slopes upward because many input costs are slow to change (i.e., are sticky) in the short run. This SRAS curve can shift because of changes in input prices, productivity, taxes, regulation, the market power of firms, or inflationary expectations. Table 2 summarizes the determinants of short-run aggregate supply.
TABLE 2
DETERMINANTS OF SHORT-RUN AGGREGATE SUPPLY (THE SHORTRUN AGGREGATE SUPPLY CURVE SHIFTS WHEN THESE CHANGE)
Determinant Changes in Input Prices
SRAS Increases
SRAS Decreases
Prices decline
Prices rise
Technology
Improvements
Reductions
Changes in human capital
Improvements
Reductions
Tax rates
Lower
Higher
Subsidies
Higher
Lower
Change in burdensome regulations
Reductions
Additions
Change in Market Power
Reductions
Increases
Changes in Inflationary Expectations
Lower
Higher
Changes in Productivity
Changes in Taxes and Regulations
CHECKPOINT AGGREGATE SUPPLY The aggregate supply curve shows the real GDP that firms will produce at varying price levels. The vertical long-run aggregate supply (LRAS) curve represents the long-run full-employment capacity of the economy. Increasing resources or improved technology shift the LRAS curve, which represents economic growth. The short-run aggregate supply (SRAS) curve is upward-sloping, reflecting rigidities in the
395
economy because input and output prices are slow to change (sticky). The determinants of short-run aggregate supply include changes in input prices, productivity, taxes, regulations, the market power of firms, and inflationary expectations.
QUESTION: Because interest rates had been kept extremely low for almost a decade, many investors worried that access to cheap loans will drive prices higher as more people borrow money for purchases. How might this change in inflationary expectations affect the SRAS curve? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
396
MACROECONOMIC EQUILIBRIUM Let us now put together our aggregate demand and aggregate supply model. A short-run macroeconomic equilibrium occurs at the intersection of the short-run aggregate supply and aggregate demand curves; see point e in Figure 6. In this case, point e also represents long-run macroeconomic equilibrium because the economy is operating at full employment, producing output Qf. macroeconomic equilibrium Occurs at the intersection of the short-run aggregate supply and aggregate demand curves. At this output level, there are no net pressures for the economy to expand or contract.
Output level Qf represents full employment. The SRAS curve assumes price level expectations equal to Pe, and thus Qf is the natural rate of unemployment or output. Remember that the natural rate of unemployment is that unemployment level at which inflation is low and consistent with inflationary expectations in the economy. FIGURE 6
MACROECONOMIC EQUILIBRIUM
Point e represents a short-run macroeconomic equilibrium, the point at which the short-run aggregate supply curve and aggregate demand curve intersect. In this case, point e also represents a long-run macroeconomic equilibrium, because the economy is operating at full employment, producing output Qf.
The Spending Multiplier 397
The spending multiplier is an important concept introduced into macroeconomics by John Maynard Keynes in 1936. The central idea is that new spending creates more spending, income, and output than just an amount equal to the new spending itself. multiplier Spending changes alter equilibrium income by the spending change times the multiplier. One person’s spending becomes another’s income, and that second person spends some (the MPC), which becomes income for another person, and so on, until income has changed by 1/(1 − MPC) = 1/MPS. The multiplier operates in both directions.
Let’s assume, for example, that consumers tend to spend three-quarters and save one-quarter of any new income they receive. Now, assume that good weather encourages a family to spend the day at the annual county fair, spending $100 on food and rides. In other words, $100 of new spending is introduced into the economy. That $100 spent on food and rides adds $100 in income to the operator of the fair, because all spending equals income to someone else (whether that be the owner or the workers she hires). Of this additional income, suppose that $25 is saved and $75 is spent by the fair operator to fix a plumbing leak in her home. That $75 in spending becomes $75 in income to the plumber. Now that the plumber has $75 more income, suppose he saves $18.75 (25% of $75) and uses the rest ($56.25) to change the oil in his car, generating $56.25 in income to the mechanic, and so on, round-byround. Adding up all of the new spending (equal to the sum of $100 + $75 + $56.25 + . . . ) from the initial $100 results in total spending increasing by $400. This represents an increase in output or GDP of $400. Adding up total new saving ($25 + 18.75 + . . . ) equals $100, which means that the initial $100 in new spending has increased savings by the same amount through the multiplier process. The proportion of additional income that consumers spend and save is known as the marginal propensity to consume and the marginal propensity to save (MPC and MPS). In our example, MPC = 0.75 and MPS = 0.25. The multiplier is equal to 4, given that $400 of new income was created with the introduction of $100 of new spending. The formula for the spending multiplier is equal to 1/(1 − MPC) = 1/MPS, and in this case, is 1/(1 − 0.75) = 1/0.25 = 4. This formula works as long as the aggregate price level is stable. marginal propensity to consume The change in consumption associated with a given change in income. marginal propensity to save The change in saving associated with a given change in income.
When the economy has many unemployed resources and excess capacity, the price level will remain constant and output will increase by the full magnitude of the multiplier. However, when the economy moves up the SRAS curve in the short run, its response to the same increase in aggregate spending is not as great. In Figure 7, aggregate demand increases the same amount as before. The new equilibrium is at point a with output of Qf. But, output grows less because price increases or inflation eat up some of each spending round, resulting in less real output. The multiplier is therefore less than the pure spending multiplier of 4 just discussed. Note that once aggregate demand is increased beyond AD1, price increases soak up the entire increase in aggregate demand (along the LRAS curve) because real output does not change. FIGURE 7
THE MULTIPLIER AND AGGREGATE DEMAND AND SUPPLY
398
The spending multiplier magnifies new spending into greater levels of income and output because of roundby-round spending. Your spending becomes my income, and I spend some of that income, creating further income and consumption, and so on.
Let’s take a moment to summarize where we are before we begin to use this model to understand some important macroeconomic events. Short-run macroeconomic equilibrium occurs at the intersection of AD and SRAS. It can also happen that this equilibrium represents long-run equilibrium, but not necessarily; equilibrium can occur at less than full employment. As we will see shortly, the Great Depression is one example of this. Increases in spending are multiplied and lead to greater changes in output than the original change in spending. For policymakers, this means that the difference between equilibrium real GDP and full-employment GDP (the GDP gap) can be closed with a smaller change in spending. This leads us to the point where we can use the AD/AS model to analyze past macroeconomic events. By looking at these events through the AD/AS lens, we begin to see the options open to policymakers. Let’s now look at what happened during the Great Depression, then examine both demand-pull and cost-push inflation. Each type of inflation presents unique challenges for policymakers.
The Great Depression Figure 6 conveniently showed the economy in long-run equilibrium and short-run equilibrium at the same point. The Great Depression demonstrated, however, that an economy can reach short-run equilibrium at output levels substantially below full employment. The 1930s Depression was a graphic example of just such a situation. Real GDP dropped by nearly 40% between 1929 and 1933. Unemployment peaked at 25% in 1932 and never fell below 15% throughout the 1930s. Figure 8 shows the actual data for the Great Depression with superimposed aggregate demand and SRAS curves for 1929 and 1933. Investment is the most volatile of the GDP components, and it fell nearly 80% from 1929 to 1933.
399
This drop in investment reduced spending, and therefore income and consumption, resulting in a deep depression. The increase in aggregate demand necessary to restore the economy back to 1929 levels was huge, and it was no wonder that a 6% increase in government spending had virtually no impact on the Depression. It wasn’t until spending ramped up for World War II that the country moved beyond the Depression. FIGURE 8
AGGREGATE DEMAND, SHORT-RUN AGGREGATE SUPPLY, AND THE DECLINE IN INVESTMENT DURING THE DEPRESSION
Aggregate demand and short-run aggregate supply are superimposed on the real GDP and price level data for the Great Depression. Investment dropped nearly 80% and consumption declined nearly 20%. Together, these reductions in spending created a depression that was so deep that it took the massive spending for World War II to bring the economy back to full employment.
FIGURE 9
DEMAND-PULL INFLATION
400
Demand-pull inflation occurs when aggregate demand expands and equilibrium output (point a) exceeds full employment output (Qf). Because the LRAS curve has not shifted, the economy will in the end move into long-run equilibrium at point c. With the new aggregate demand at AD1, prices have unexpectedly risen; therefore, short-run aggregate supply shifts to SRAS2 as workers, for example, adjust their wage demands upward, leaving prices permanently higher at P2.
Demand-Pull Inflation Demand-pull inflation occurs when aggregate demand expands so much that equilibrium output exceeds full employment output. Turning to Figure 9, assume that the economy is initially in long-run equilibrium at point e. If businesses become overly exuberant and expand investments in some area (such as telecommunications in the late 1990s), this expansion will push aggregate demand out to AD1. The economy moves to a short-run equilibrium beyond full employment (point a), and the price level rises to P1. demand-pull inflation Results when aggregate demand expands so much that equilibrium output exceeds full employment output and the price level rises.
On a temporary basis, the economy can expand beyond full employment as workers incur overtime, temporary workers are added, and more shifts are employed. Yet, these activities increase costs and prices. And because LRAS has not shifted, the economy will ultimately move to point c (if AD stays at AD1), shifting short-run aggregate supply to SRAS2 and leaving prices permanently higher (at P2). In the long run, the economy will gravitate to points such as e and c. Policymakers could return the economy back to the original point e by instituting policies that reduce AD back to AD0. These might include reduced government spending, higher taxes, or other policies that discourage
401
investment, consumer spending, or exports. Demand-pull inflation can continue for quite a while, especially if the economy begins on the SRAS curve well below full employment. Inflation often starts out slow and builds up steam. Decade-long demand-pull inflation scenarios for the United States in the 1960s and for Japan in the last half of the 1980s and first half of the 1990s are shown in Figure 10. For the United States, the slow escalation of the Vietnam conflict fueled a rising economy along the hypothetical short-run aggregate supply curve placed over the data in panel A. Early in the decade, the price level rose slowly as the economy expanded. But notice how the short-run aggregate supply curve began to turn nearly vertical and inflation rates rose as the economy approached full employment in 1969. Real output growth virtually halted between 1969 and 1970, but inflation was 5.3%. The economy had reached its potential. The Japanese economy during the 1985–1995 period is a different example of demand-pull inflation. Panel B of Figure 10 shows a steadily growing economy with rising prices, throughout the 1980s and early 1990s. Japan ran huge trade surpluses and the yen appreciated (becoming more valuable). A rising yen would eventually reduce exports (Japanese products would become too expensive). To keep this from happening, the Japanese government kept interest rates artificially low, reducing the pressure on the yen and encouraging investment. But these policies fueled a huge real estate and stock bubble that began collapsing in the beginning of the 1990s and led to a decadelong recession that has been called “the lost decade.” FIGURE 10
DEMAND-PULL INFLATION, UNITED STATES (1960S) AND JAPAN (1985–1995)
This figure shows two examples of demand-pull inflation for the United States and Japan. Hypothetical aggregate demand and short-run aggregate supply curves are superimposed over the data for the two time periods. The Vietnam conflict expanded aggregate demand in the 1960s, and the U.S. economy experienced inflation over the entire decade and faced rising inflation rates as the economy approached full employment in 1969. Japan experienced demand-pull inflation as it enjoyed a huge trade surplus, which expanded the economy. Japanese policymakers kept interest rates artificially low, fueling a real estate and stock bubble that collapsed in the 1990s, resulting in a decade-long recession.
Demand-pull inflation can often take a while to become a problem. But once the inflation spiral gains momentum, it can pose a serious problem for policymakers.
Cost-Push Inflation
Cost-push inflation occurs when a supply shock hits the economy, shifting the short-run aggregate supply curve
402
leftward, as from SRAS0 to SRAS2 in Figure 11. The 1973 oil shock is a classic example. Because oil is a basic input in so many goods and services we purchase, skyrocketing oil prices affected all parts of the economy. After a bout of cost-push inflation, rising resource costs push the economy from point e to point b in Figure 11. Note that at point b, real output has fallen (the economy is in a recession) and the price level has risen. Policymakers can increase demand to AD1 and move the economy back to full employment at point c. For example, they might increase government spending, reduce taxes, or introduce policies that encourage consumption, investment, or net exports. But notice that this means an even higher price level. Alternatively, policymakers could reduce inflationary pressures by reducing aggregate demand, but this leads to an even deeper recession as output and employment fall further. cost-push inflation Results when a supply shock hits the economy, reducing short-run aggregate supply, and thus reducing output and increasing the price level. FIGURE 11
COST-PUSH INFLATION
Cost-push inflation is represented by an initial decline in short-run aggregate supply from SRAS0 to SRAS2. Rising resource costs or inflationary expectations will reduce short-run aggregate supply, resulting in a shortrun movement from point e to point b. If policymakers wish to return the economy to full employment, they can increase aggregate demand to AD1, but must accept higher prices as the economy moves to point c. Alternatively, they could reduce aggregate demand, but that would lead to lower output and higher unemployment.
ISSUE 403
Why Didn’t Stimulus Measures Over the Past Decade Lead to Inflation? The 2007–2009 recession and the high unemployment that persisted for years after led policymakers to implement many policies to jumpstart the economy. These included government spending (stimulus) programs, tax rebates in 2009, a reduction in payroll taxes in 2011 and 2012, extension of unemployment benefits, loan modification programs, and more. Each of these policies was designed to encourage spending by consumers and thereby increase aggregate demand. By doing so, the AD/AS model presented in this chapter predicts that rightward shifts of the AD curve would lead to a higher aggregate price level, or inflation. Yet, inflation rates in the United States have remained low. How is that possible? First, the AD curve might not have moved at all. Much of the government spending to increase aggregate demand was offsetting corresponding decreases in aggregate demand due to high unemployment, low consumer and business confidence, and low foreign demand for American goods. Thus, the role of such policies may have prevented a worsening of the economy by keeping aggregate demand in the same place as before. Using this explanation, the price level would not be affected at all. Second, the recession created a large amount of underutilized resources. Keynes argued that during times of poor economic performance, many resources (such as labor and capital) remain underutilized. In such cases, an increase in aggregate demand, which subsequently increases demand for labor and capital, would merely be using resources that had been sitting idle. There would be little pressure on wages and prices to rise.
Inflation remained low despite an increase in government spending on infrastructure and tax cuts to encourage more spending by consumers. These reasons and others help to explain why the government was able to engage in various policies to increase the speed of economic recovery without the immediate threat of inflation. But as the economy recovers and idle resources are used up, any further government spending would likely lead to a higher aggregate price level, which means higher inflation can be lurking around the corner.
Figure 12 shows the striking leftward shift in equilibrium points for 1973–1975. Output stood still, while prices rose as the economy adjusted to the new energy prices. Superimposed over the annual data are two hypothetical short-run aggregate supply curves. Notice that it took the economy roughly three years to absorb the oil shock. Only after the economy had adjusted to the new prices did it continue on a path roughly equivalent to the pre-1973 SRAS curve.
404
Before the Great Depression, economic analysis focused on the behavior of individuals, households, and businesses. Little attention was paid to the macroeconomic stabilization potential of government policies. The federal government had its responsibilities under the Constitution in many areas—such as national defense, the enforcement of contracts, and tax collection—but managing the economy was not among them. The Great Depression of the 1930s and John Maynard Keynes’s The General Theory drastically changed how economists viewed the role of the federal government. During the Depression, when unemployment reached 25% and bank failures wiped out personal savings, federal intervention in the economy became imperative. After the 1930s, the federal government’s role grew to encompass (1) expanded spending and taxation and the resulting exercise of fiscal policy, (2) extensive new regulation of business, and (3) expanded regulation of the banking sector, along with greater exercise of monetary policy. FIGURE 12
COST-PUSH INFLATION IN THE 1970S
The rise in equilibrium prices following the 1973 oil shocks was striking. From 1973 to 1975, prices rose, yet output stood still as the economy adjusted to the new energy prices. Superimposed over the actual annual data are two hypothetical short-run aggregate supply curves. Notice that it took the economy roughly three years to absorb the oil shock.
The next chapter focuses on how government spending and taxation combine to expand or contract the macroeconomy. When the economy enters a recession, fiscal policy can be used to moderate the impact and prevent another depression. Later chapters will explore the monetary system and the use of monetary policy to stabilize the economy and the price level. The AD/AS model will serve as a tool to analyze both fiscal and monetary policies. As you read these chapters, keep in mind that the long-run goals of fiscal and monetary policy are economic growth, low unemployment, and modest inflationary pressures.
CHECKPOINT 405
MACROECONOMIC EQUILIBRIUM Macroeconomic equilibrium occurs where short-run aggregate supply and aggregate demand cross. The spending multiplier exists because new spending generates new round-by-round spending (based on the marginal propensities to consume and save) that creates additional income. The formula for the spending multiplier is 1/(1 − MPC) = 1/MPS. The effect of the multiplier on aggregate output is larger when the economy is in a deep recession or a depression. Policymakers can increase output by enacting policies that expand government spending, consumption, investment, or net exports, or reduce taxes. Demand-pull inflation occurs when aggregate demand expands beyond that necessary for full employment. Cost-push inflation occurs when short-run aggregate supply shifts to the left, causing the price level to rise along with rising unemployment.
QUESTIONS: In recent years, the price of agricultural goods, such as vegetables, fruit, and milk, rose
significantly due to severe droughts in several farming regions in the United States. Describe the impact of this price increase on short-run aggregate supply. How might it affect employment, unemployment, and the price level? Would the impact depend on whether consumers and businesses thought the price increase was permanent?
Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
406
chapter summary Section 1 Aggregate Demand 9.1
The aggregate demand curve shows the quantity of goods and services (real GDP) demanded at different price levels.
9.2
The aggregate demand curve is downward-sloping for three main reasons: Wealth effect: When price levels rise, the purchasing power of money saved falls. Export price effect: Rising price levels cause domestic goods to be more expensive in the global marketplace, resulting in fewer purchases by foreign consumers. Interest rate effect: When price levels rise, people need more money to carry out transactions. The added demand for money drives up interest rates, causing investment spending to fall. The determinants of aggregate demand include the components of aggregate spending:
9.3 1. 2. 3. 4.
Consumption spending Investment spending Government spending Net exports
Changing any one of these aggregates will shift the aggregate demand curve.
407
The housing market recovery has resulted in a boost to aggregate demand.
Section 2 Aggregate Supply 9.4
The aggregate supply curve shows the real GDP firms will produce at varying price levels. In the short run, aggregate supply is upward-sloping (SRAS). In the long run, aggregate supply is vertical (LRAS).
In the short run, prices and wages are sticky (think of menu prices staying the same for a period of time). Therefore, firms respond by increasing output when prices rise. In the long run, prices and wages adjust; therefore, output is not affected by the price level.
408
9.5
Factors that shift the SRAS curve: Input prices Productivity Taxes and regulation Market power of firms Inflationary expectations
Electronic toll collection booths save time and reduce transportation costs to firms, leading to an increase in short-run aggregate supply and potentially long-run aggregate supply.
Factors that shift the LRAS curve: Increase in technology Greater human capital Trade Innovation and R&D
409
Section 3 Macroeconomic Equilibrium 9.6
A long-run macroeconomic equilibrium occurs at the intersection of the LRAS and AD curves, at full employment. A short-run macroeconomic equilibrium occurs at the intersection of the SRAS and AD curves. Short-run equilibrium can occur below full employment (recession) or above full employment (inflationary pressure).
9.7
The spending multiplier exists because new spending generates income that results in more spending and income, based on the marginal propensities to consume and save.
9.8
Demand-pull inflation occurs when aggregate demand expands so much that equilibrium output exceeds full employment output. Temporarily, the economy can expand beyond full employment as workers incur overtime and more workers are added. But as wages rise, the economy will move to a new long-run equilibrium, where prices are permanently higher.
410
Multiplier Example: MPC = 0.80 and MPS = 0.20 Round 1: $100 in new spending = $100 in new income. Round 2: $80 is spent and $20 is saved ($80 in new income). Round 3: $64 is spent and $16 is saved. Round 4: $51.20 is spent and $12.80 is saved. Round 5: $40.96 is spent and $10.24 is saved. Round 6: $32.76 is spent and $8.20 is saved. ... Round n: $0.01 is spent and $0.00 is saved. Total Effect of $100 in Spending = $500 in Spending and $100 in Savings Multiplier = 1/(1 − MPC) = 1/(1 − 0.80) = 5 Cost-push inflation occurs when a supply shock hits the economy, shifting the SRAS curve to the left. Cost-push inflation makes using policies to expand aggregate demand to restore full employment difficult because of the additional inflationary pressures added to the economy.
411
KEY CONCEPTS aggregate demand wealth effect aggregate supply long-run aggregate supply (LRAS) curve short-run aggregate supply (SRAS) curve macroeconomic equilibrium multiplier marginal propensity to consume marginal propensity to save demand-pull inflation cost-push inflation
QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS Check Your Understanding 1. Describe the impact of rising interest rates on consumer spending. 2. When the economy is operating at full employment, why is an increase in aggregate demand not helpful to the economy? 3. When the economy is hit with a supply shock, such as rising prices for energy, food, or raw materials, why is this doubly disruptive and harmful to the economy? 4. Explain why the aggregate supply curve is positively sloped during the short run and vertical in the long run. 5. Explain how imports and exports affect aggregate demand. 6. List some examples of factors that will shift the long-run aggregate supply curve.
Apply the Concepts 7. There is little doubt that computers and the Internet have changed the economy. Information technology (IT) can boost efficiency in nearly everything: Markets are more efficient, IT is global, and IT improves the design, manufacture, and supply chain of products we produce. Use the aggregate demand and supply framework discussed in this chapter to show the impact of IT on the economy. 8. Unemployment can be caused by a reduction in aggregate demand or short-run aggregate supply. Both changes are represented by a leftward shift in the curves. Does it matter whether the shift occurs in aggregate demand or short-run aggregate supply? Use the AD/AS framework to show why or why not. 9. Why is cost-push inflation a more difficult problem for policymakers than demand-pull inflation? 10. Why is consumer confidence so important in determining the equilibrium level of output and employment? 11. As the Japanese yen appreciated in value during the 1980s and 1990s, more Japanese auto companies built manufacturing plants in other parts of Asia and in the United States. What impact did this have on net exports for the United States? Why did Japanese automakers build plants in the United States? Were the reasons similar to the reasons that American firms build plants (or establish offshore production) in China and other parts of Asia? 12. Some advocates have suggested that the United States should move to a universal health care plan paid for at the federal level, like Medicare, which would be funded out of general tax revenues. Such a plan, it is argued, would guarantee quality health care to all. Ignoring all the controversy surrounding such a plan, would the introduction of universal health care paid for from tax revenues have an impact on short-run aggregate supply? On long-run aggregate supply? Why or why not?
412
In the News 13. In 2016 a worldwide health scare resulted from the rapid spread of the mosquito-borne Zika virus, which was alleged to cause birth defects in infected pregnant women. Brazil was the epicenter of the epidemic, which also hosted the Summer Olympic Games that same year. Explain how a health epidemic experienced in Brazil affected its aggregate demand and/or aggregate supply. 14. In late 2015 congressional House Speaker Paul Ryan helped pass a major budget bill signed by President Obama that eliminated many of the “sequester” provisions, or automatic spending cuts, that were implemented in 2013 after significant political gridlock. Many economists applauded the elimination of the spending cuts because they believed the cuts increased the risk of another recession when the economy was still in recovery. Using the AD/AS model and what you know about the spending multiplier, explain why economists would come to this conclusion.
Solving Problems 15. In the figure, the economy is initially in equilibrium at full employment at point e. Assume that consumption falls by 100, leading to a shift in aggregate demand from AD0 to AD1.
a. What is the new short-run macroeconomic equilibrium price and output? b. How large is the simple Keynesian multiplier if there were no changes to the aggregate price level? c. How large is the spending multiplier if the aggregate price level adjusts to the new equilibrium?
WORK IT OUT 16. Use the table and grid below to answer the following questions:
Aggregate Price Level
Output (short-run aggregate supply)
413
Output (aggregate demand)
150
1,000
200
125
800
400
100
600
600
75
400
800
50
200
1,000
a. In the grid, graph the aggregate demand and short-run aggregate supply curves (label them AD0 and SRAS0). What are equilibrium output and the aggregate price level? b. Assume aggregate demand grows by 200 at each price level. Graph the new aggregate demand curve and label it AD1. What are the new equilibrium output and aggregate price level? c. If full employment output is 600, is the economy experiencing recessionary or inflationary pressures? d. By how much does the SRAS curve need to shift in order for the economy to return to full employment output at 600? What would the new equilibrium aggregate price level be?
USING THE NUMBERS 17. According to By the Numbers, if the average price of a barrel of oil is $50, and total aggregate demand in 2015 was $18 trillion in the United States and $11 trillion in China, what percentage of aggregate demand did oil consumption represent in each country? 18. According to By the Numbers, by what percentage did M&E revenues increase from 2012 to 2015? How does M&E growth compare to the percentage growth in overall aggregate output over this time period (which was approximately 2-3% per year)?
414
ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS Checkpoint: Aggregate Demand An increase in home prices and stock values would increase the wealth of those who owned these assets. An increase in wealth provides greater financial security, even if income does not change. All else equal, consumption would rise, which would increase aggregate demand. Checkpoint: Aggregate Supply Low interest rates make it easier for individuals and firms to borrow for consumption and investment, which may lead to higher inflation, especially when the economy fully recovers and production resources are no longer sitting idle. As investors anticipate a rise in inflation, they will adjust production in anticipation of higher input (wage and raw materials) prices, which means SRAS will decrease. Checkpoint: Macroeconomic Equilibrium Agriculture goods are an important input in our economy. Higher crop prices increase the cost of producing food products as well as operating restaurants and cruise ships, which will reduce short-run aggregate supply. Over time, these cost increases will show up as a higher price level, reduced employment, and higher unemployment. If the economy continues to grow, these impacts will be masked, but will still reduce the level of growth. If the change is seen as permanent, consumers and businesses will begin making long-run adjustments to higher prices. For example, consumers might change their diets to include less expensive foods or plant their own crops in gardens, while businesses might consider alternative ingredients when planning menu items. If the price increases are just viewed as temporary, both groups might not adjust much at all.
415
Appendix
Deriving the Aggregate Demand Curve The aggregate demand curve shows the quantities of goods and services (real GDP) demanded at different price levels, and can be derived using the aggregate expenditures model. To illustrate, panel A of Figure APX-1 shows aggregate expenditures (AE) curves at two different price levels. Remember that AE curves are drawn assuming fixed prices. First, consider equilibrium point a on aggregate expenditures curve AE(P0). This point shows an equilibrium income of Y0, which is equivalent to a real output of Q0. Point a in panel B therefore represents a real output of Q0 and a price level of P0. However, if the aggregate price level rises to P1, aggregate expenditures will decline to AE(P1) because at these higher prices, the same level of expenditures will not buy as much real output as before. The result is a new equilibrium at point b in both panels. Connecting points a and b in panel B, we have constructed aggregate demand curve AD, which represents the relationship between the price level and aggregate output. FIGURE APX-1DERIVING THE AGGREGATE DEMAND CURVE
416
The aggregate demand curve, which shows the quantities of goods and services demanded at different price levels for the entire economy, can be derived using the aggregate spending model. Panel A shows aggregate expenditures curves at two different price levels. Point a on aggregate expenditures curve AE(P0) represents equilibrium income Y0, equivalent to a real output of Q0. Point a in panel B shows real output of Q0 that is associated with equilibrium point a and its price level P0. If the aggregate price level rises to P1, aggregate spending will decline to AE(P1) in panel A. The result is a new equilibrium at point b in both panels. Connecting points a and b in panel B results in aggregate demand curve AD.
417
10
Fiscal Policy and Debt
418
Understanding the role of taxes and spending in addressing fluctuations in the 419
macroeconomy
Learning Objectives 10.1
Describe the tools that governments use to influence aggregate demand.
10.2
Describe expansionary and contractionary fiscal policy.
10.3
Determine the influence that the multiplier effect has on government spending and aggregate output.
10.4
Describe the fiscal policies that governments use to influence aggregate supply.
10.5
Describe the impact of automatic stabilizers, lag effects, and the propensity toward deficits from fiscal policymaking.
10.6
Identify the different lags that occur when implementing fiscal policy.
10.7
Define deficits and surpluses, and explain the difference between national debt and public debt.
10.8
Describe the potential consequences of maintaining high public debt.
W
hen you apply for a loan to buy a car, you undoubtedly will go through a credit check and receive a credit rating, which is a number that estimates the probability of you paying back the loan. The government is also given a credit rating for the loans it takes out. This rating, like yours, estimates the probability
of the government paying back its loans.
On August 5, 2011, Standard and Poor’s (S&P), a credit rating agency, did something it had never done in its history: lower the debt rating of the United States government from a perfect AAA rating to a slightly less than perfect AA+ rating. Although an AA+ rating is still excellent, this change was significant, because it suggested for the first time that the United States government is not immune from all and any hardships in paying its debts. Why did the United States government lose its perfect debt rating? One reason was its extensive use of fiscal policy in the aftermath of the 2007–2009 recession. Fiscal policy is the use of government revenue collection (mainly taxation) and spending to influence the economy. When the government taxes something, individuals and businesses have less money to spend. Therefore, taxes put the brakes on various economic activities. However, in terms of spending, think of what it means to local employment if the government decides to improve the roads and bridges in a city. By their very nature, taxation and spending affect the economy. In extraordinary times, governments use fiscal policy to influence the macroeconomy with the express purpose of smoothing fluctuations in the business cycle. During the 2007–2009 recession, nearly $800 billion in additional government spending was added in an attempt to pull the economy out of its doldrums. If people would not spend, government would spend in their place. Spending was used to spur the economy when citizens were too scared to spend themselves. In inflationary times, government uses fiscal policy to pull money out of people’s hands in an
420
attempt to cool down spending and inflation. Fiscal policy influences aggregate demand and aggregate supply in many ways. However, fiscal policy that is used to stimulate the economy is often accompanied by persistent budget deficits and debt. Why and to what end? This chapter will examine these issues and focus on the problem of financing deficits by accruing debt. Most Americans are accustomed to dealing with debt. Individuals might have a home mortgage, car loan, student loan, or credit card balances, while businesses often take out loans for capital purchases and other expenses to run their operations. Most debt is managed by making periodic payments toward the balance and interest. However, when debt becomes too high to be controlled, individuals and companies face financial distress and are sometimes forced to declare bankruptcy. As we will see, it is no surprise that governments also deal with debt. In recent years, deficits and the national debt have dominated economic headlines. The national debt grows when the government spends more than the tax revenues it collects. In 2015, the U.S. government collected about $3.25 trillion in taxes, but spent about $3.69 trillion. The difference of $440 billion represented the federal deficit that was added to the national debt.
421
Unlike individuals and small companies, a government has a much larger arsenal of tools to prevent it from going
422
bankrupt, including the power to tax and the ever-powerful ability to “print” money. But even those tools can sometimes be rendered useless, causing a government to rack up sizeable debt and increasing the burden of managing the debt. Further, when a government does default on its debt, havoc in markets throughout the world may result. In this chapter, we analyze the tools government uses to implement fiscal policy and study their effects on aggregate demand and aggregate supply, which affects income and output. We then analyze whether the amount of the federal debt is a problem, and if so, what the government can do about it. This chapter will give you a good sense of the scope of fiscal policy and the tradeoffs between relying on public debt and balancing taxes and spending.
423
FISCAL POLICY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND When an economy faces underutilization of resources because it is stuck in equilibrium well below full employment, we saw that increases in aggregate demand can move the economy toward full employment without generating excessive inflation pressures. However, in normal times, influencing aggregate demand brings with it a tradeoff: Output is increased at the expense of raising the price level. In contrast, consider decreasing aggregate demand. When the economy is in an inflationary equilibrium above full employment, contracting aggregate demand dampens inflation but leads to another tradeoff: unemployment. Before we examine the theory behind how government actually goes about influencing aggregate demand by using fiscal policy, let’s take a brief look at what categories of spending fiscal policy typically alters.
Discretionary and Mandatory Spending
The federal budget can be split into two distinct types of spending: discretionary and mandatory. Discretionary spending is the part of the budget that works its way through the appropriations process of Congress each year. Discretionary spending includes such programs as national defense (primarily the military), transportation, science, environment, income security (some welfare programs and a large portion of Medicaid), education, and veterans benefits and services. As Figure 1 shows, discretionary spending has steadily declined as a percent of the budget since the 1960s, when it was over 60% of the budget, to about one-third of the budget today. discretionary spending The part of the budget that works its way through the appropriations process of Congress each year and includes national defense, transportation, science, environment, and income security.
Mandatory spending is authorized by permanent laws and does not go through the same appropriations process as discretionary spending. To change one of the entitlements of mandatory spending, Congress must change the law. Mandatory spending includes such programs as Social Security, Medicare, part of Medicaid, interest on the national debt, and some means-tested income-security programs, including SNAP (Supplementary Nutrition Assistance Program, formerly known as the Food Stamp Program) and TANF (Temporary Assistance to Needy Families). This part of the budget has been growing, as Figure 1 illustrates, and now accounts for over 60% of the budget. mandatory spending Spending authorized by permanent laws that does not go through the same appropriations process as discretionary spending. Mandatory spending includes Social Security, Medicare, and interest on the national debt.
Even though discretionary spending is only 32% of the budget, this is still roughly $1.2 trillion, and the capacity to alter this spending is a powerful force in the economy. Therefore, we are mainly concerned with discretionary spending when we consider fiscal policy.
Discretionary Fiscal Policy The exercise of discretionary fiscal policy is done with the express goal of influencing aggregate demand. It involves adjusting government spending and tax policies to move the economy toward full employment, encouraging economic growth, or controlling inflation. discretionary fiscal policy Policies that involve adjusting government spending and tax policies with the express short-run goal of moving the economy toward full employment, expanding economic growth, or controlling inflation.
Some examples of the use of discretionary fiscal policy include tax cuts enacted during the Kennedy, Reagan, and George W. Bush administrations. These tax cuts were designed to expand the economy under the belief that people
424
would spend their tax savings, both in the near term and the long run—they were meant to influence both aggregate demand and aggregate supply. Tax increases were enacted under the George H. W. Bush and Clinton administrations in the interest of reducing the government deficit and interest rates. The Roosevelt administration used increased government spending, although small amounts by today’s standards, to mitigate the impact of the Great Depression. FIGURE 1
DISCRETIONARY AND MANDATORY FEDERAL SPENDING
Mandatory spending includes entitlements authorized by law such as Social Security, Medicare, and the Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program, along with interest on the national debt. Mandatory programs do not go through the normal congressional appropriations process and have been growing. Discretionary programs are authorized each year by the appropriations process of Congress and include national defense, transportation, environment, and education. Discretionary spending has been steadily declining as a percent of the budget.
425
Government Spending
Although discretionary fiscal policy can get complex, the impact of changes in government spending is relatively simple. As we know, a change in government spending or other components of GDP will cause income and output to rise or fall by the spending change times the multiplier. This is illustrated in Figure 2 with the economy initially in equilibrium at point e, with real output at Q0. If government spending increases, shifting aggregate demand from AD0 to AD1, aggregate output will increase from Q0 to Qf. Because the short-run aggregate supply curve is upward-sloping, some of the increase in output is absorbed by rising prices, reducing the pure spending multiplier discussed in earlier chapters. Once the economy reaches full employment (point a), further spending is not multiplied as the economy moves along the LRAS curve, and only higher prices result. Finally, keep in mind that the multiplier works in both directions.
Taxes
Changes in government spending modify income by an amount equal to the change in spending times the multiplier. How, then, do changes in taxes affect the economy? The answer is not quite as simple. Let’s begin with a reminder of what constitutes spending equilibrium. FIGURE 2
THE MULTIPLIER AND GOVERNMENT SPENDING
The economy is initially in equilibrium at point e. As new government spending works its way through the economy round-by-round, both income and output are multiplied, but price increases absorb some of the increase in AD. Once the economy reaches full employment (point a), price increases absorb all of the increase in AD.
426
When the economy is in equilibrium, GDP = C + I + G + (X − M) At equilibrium, all spending injections into the economy equal all withdrawals of spending. To review, injections are activities that increase spending in an economy, such as investment (I), government spending (G), and exports (X). Withdrawals, on the other hand, are activities that remove spending from the economy, such as saving (S), taxes (T), and imports (M). Therefore, in equilibrium: I+G+X=S+T+M With this equation in hand, let’s focus on taxes. When taxes are increased, money is withdrawn from the economy’s spending stream. When taxes are reduced, consumers and businesses have more to spend. Disposable income is equal to income minus taxes (Y − T). Because taxes represent a withdrawal of spending from the economy, we would expect equilibrium income to fall when a tax is imposed. Consumers pay a tax increase, in part, by reducing their saving. If we initially increase taxes by $100, let’s assume that consumers draw on their savings for $25 of the increase in taxes. Because this $25 in savings was already withdrawn from the economy, only the $75 in reduced spending gets multiplied, reducing the change in income. The reduction in saving of $25 dampens the effect of the tax on equilibrium income because those funds were previously withdrawn from the spending stream. Changing the withdrawal category from saving to taxes does not affect income. A tax decrease has a similar but opposite impact because only the MPC part is spent and multiplied, and the rest is saved and thus withdrawn from the spending stream. The result is that a tax increase (or decrease, for that matter) has less of a direct impact on income, employment, and output than an equivalent change in government spending. Another way of saying this is that the government tax multiplier is less than the government spending multiplier. Therefore, added government spending leads to a larger increase in GDP when compared to the same reduction in taxes.
Transfers
Transfer payments are money payments paid directly to individuals. These include payments for such items as Social Security, unemployment compensation, and welfare. In large measure, they represent our social safety net. We will ignore them as part of the discretionary fiscal policy, because most are paid as a matter of law, but we will see later in the chapter that they are very important as a way of stabilizing the economy. FIGURE 3
EXPANSIONARY FISCAL POLICY BELOW FULL EMPLOYMENT
427
When the economy is below full employment, expansionary policies move it to full employment. Here, the economy begins at equilibrium at point e, below full employment. Expansionary fiscal policy increases aggregate demand from AD0 to AD1, raising equilibrium output to Qf and the price level to P1 (point f).
Expansionary and Contractionary Fiscal Policy Expansionary fiscal policy involves increasing government spending (such as on highways and education), increasing transfer payments (such as unemployment benefits), and/or decreasing taxes—all to increase aggregate demand. These policies put more money into the hands of consumers and businesses. In theory, these additional funds should lead to higher spending. The precise effect expansionary fiscal policies have, however, depends on whether the economy is at or below full employment. expansionary fiscal policy Policies that increase aggregate demand to expand output in an economy. These include increasing government spending, increasing transfer payments, and/or decreasing taxes.
When the economy is below full employment, an expansionary policy will move the economy to full employment, as Figure 3 shows. The economy begins at equilibrium at point e, below full employment. Expansionary fiscal policy increases aggregate demand from AD0 to AD1, and equilibrium output rises to Qf (point f) as the price level rises to P1. In this case, one good outcome results—output rises to Qf—though it is accompanied by one less desirable result, the price level rising to P1. Figure 4 shows what happens when the economy is at full employment. An expansionary policy raises prices without producing any long-run improvement in real GDP. In this figure, the initial equilibrium is already at full employment (point e); therefore, increasing aggregate demand moves the economy to a new output level above full employment (point a), thereby raising prices to P1. This higher output is only temporary, however, as workers and
428
suppliers adjust their expectations to the higher price level, thus shifting short-run aggregate supply upward to SRAS2. Short-run aggregate supply declines because workers and other resource suppliers realize that the prices they are paying for products have risen; hence, they demand higher wages or prices for their services. Prices are then pushed up until workers adjust their inflationary expectations and the economy settles into equilibrium at point b. At this point, the economy is again at full employment, but at a higher price level (P2) than before. When an economy moves to a point beyond full employment, as just described, economists say an inflationary spiral has set in. The explanation for this phenomenon was suggested earlier. Still, we can already see that one way to reduce such inflationary pressures is to use contractionary fiscal policy. These policies include reducing government spending, reducing transfer payments, and/or raising taxes (increasing withdrawals from the economy). Figure 5 shows the result of contractionary policy. The economy is initially overheating at point e, with output above full employment. Contractionary policy reduces aggregate demand to AD1, bringing the economy back to full employment at price level P1 and output Qf. contractionary fiscal policy Policies that decrease aggregate demand to contract output in an economy. These include reducing government spending, reducing transfer payments, and/or raising taxes. FIGURE 4
EXPANSIONARY FISCAL POLICY AT FULL EMPLOYMENT
When an economy is already at full employment, expansionary policies lead to no long-run improvement in real GDP. Beginning at full employment (point e), increasing aggregate demand moves the economy to output level Q1 above full employment (point a). This higher output is only temporary, however, as workers and suppliers adjust their expectations to the higher price level (P1), thus shifting short-run aggregate supply left toward SRAS2. But this just pushes prices up further, until finally workers adjust their inflationary expectations, and the economy settles into a new long-run equilibrium at point b, where the economy is again at full employment, but at a higher price level (P2).
429
Exercising demand-side policy requires tradeoffs between increasing output at the expense of raising the price levels, or else lowering price levels by accepting a lower output. When a recession occurs, the public is often happy to trade higher prices for greater employment and output. One would think the opposite would be true when an inflationary spiral loomed on the horizon. Politicians, however, are loath to support contractionary policies that control inflation by reducing aggregate demand, because higher unemployment can cost politicians their jobs. As a result, the demand-side fiscal policy tools—government spending, transfer payments, and taxes—may remain unused. In these instances, politicians often look to the Federal Reserve to use its tools and influence to keep inflation in check. We will examine the Federal Reserve in later chapters. FIGURE 5
CONTRACTIONARY FISCAL POLICY TO REDUCE INFLATION
In this figure, the economy is overheating at point e, with output above full employment. Contractionary policies reduce aggregate demand to AD1, bringing the economy back to full employment at price level P1. These policies prevent an inflationary spiral, but the fall in aggregate output leads to an increase in unemployment.
CHECKPOINT FISCAL POLICY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND Demand-side fiscal policy involves using government spending, transfer payments, and taxes to influence aggregate demand and equilibrium income, output, and the price level in the economy. In the short run, government spending raises income and output by the amount of spending times the multiplier. Tax reductions have a smaller impact on the economy than government spending
430
because some of the reduction in taxes is added to saving and is therefore withdrawn from the economy. Expansionary fiscal policy involves increasing government spending, increasing transfer payments, and/or decreasing taxes. Contractionary fiscal policy involves decreasing government spending, decreasing transfer payments, and/or increasing taxes. When an economy is at full employment, expansionary fiscal policy may lead to greater output in the short term, but will ultimately just lead to higher prices in the longer term. Politicians tend to favor expansionary fiscal policy because it can bring with it increases in employment although with increasing inflation. Politicians tend to shun contractionary fiscal policy because it brings unemployment.
QUESTION: During the 2007–2009 recession, the government passed a $787 billion stimulus package, which was roughly $2,500 in government spending for every person. The time required for the government to spend that sum on infrastructure projects (funding approvals, environmental clearances, and so on) meant that the spending stretched over several years. Why didn’t Congress just send a $2,500 check to each woman, man, and child in America to speed up the impact on the economy? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
431
FISCAL POLICY AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY Fiscal policies that influence aggregate supply are different from policies that influence aggregate demand, as they do not always require tradeoffs between price levels and output. That is the good news. The bad news is that supply-side fiscal policies require more time to work than do demand-side fiscal policies. The focus of fiscal policy and aggregate supply is on long-run economic growth. supply-side fiscal policies Policies that focus on shifting the long-run aggregate supply curve to the right, expanding the economy without increasing inflationary pressures. Unlike policies to increase aggregate demand, supply-side policies take longer to impact the economy.
Figure 6 shows the impact that fiscal policy can have on the economy over the long run. The goal of these fiscal policies is to shift the long-run aggregate supply curve to the right, here from LRAS0 to LRAS1. This shift moves the economy’s full employment equilibrium from point a to point b, thereby expanding full-employment output while keeping inflation in check. In Figure 6, the price level falls as output expands. In practice, this would be unusual because when the economy grows, aggregate demand typically expands and keeps prices from falling. Figure 6 may well reflect what happens in general as the world economy embraces trade and globalization. Improvements in technology and communications increase productivity to the point that global long-run aggregate supply shifts outward. These changes, along with freer trade, help increase economic growth and keep inflation low. FIGURE 6
FISCAL POLICY AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY
The ultimate goal of fiscal policy directed at aggregate supply is to shift the long-run aggregate supply curve from LRAS0 to LRAS1. This moves the economy’s full employment equilibrium from point a to point b,
432
expanding output from Q0 to Q1 while keeping inflation in check. With these fiscal policies, inflationary pressures are reduced as output expands, but these policies take a longer time to have an impact.
Just what fiscal policies will allow the economy to expand without generating price pressures? First, there are government policies that encourage investment in human capital (education) and policies that encourage the development and transfer of new technologies. Second, there are the fiscal policies that focus on reducing tax rates. Third, there are policies that promote investment in new capital equipment, encourage investment in research and development, and trim burdensome business regulations. These policies are intended to expand the supply curves of all businesses and industries.
Infrastructure Spending Governments can do a great deal to create the right environment to encourage economic growth. We already have seen the benefits of building and maintaining a nation’s infrastructure, including roads, bridges, dams, and communications networks, or setting up a fair and efficient legal system and stable financial system. Further, the higher the levels of human capital and the more easily technology is transferred to other firms and industries (the public good aspect of technology), the more robust economic growth. Therefore, long-run growth is enhanced through investments in higher education and research.
Reducing Tax Rates
Reducing tax rates has an impact on both aggregate demand and aggregate supply. Lower tax rates increase aggregate demand because households now have more money to spend. At the same time, lower tax rates mean that take-home wages rise and this may encourage more work effort. Also, entrepreneurial profits are taxed at lower rates, encouraging more people to take risks and start businesses. At different times, policymakers have lowered taxes to stimulate consumption: John F. Kennedy reduced tax rates in the early 1960s and George W. Bush in 2001 and 2008 provided tax rebates to taxpayers as part of economic stimulus packages. President Obama’s 2009 stimulus program included tax credits along with increases in government spending. At other times, administrations have reduced marginal tax rates, the rate paid on the next dollar earned, with the express purpose of stimulating incentives to work and for businesses to take risks. President Kennedy reduced the top marginal rate from 70% to 50%, and President Reagan reduced the top marginal rate from 50% to 28%. FIGURE 7
THE LAFFER CURVE
433
The Laffer curve shows the relationship between average tax rates and total tax revenues. As the tax rate rises from 0%, tax revenues increase. At point c, tax revenues are maximized. If tax rates continue to rise, tax revenues will decrease because higher tax rates discourage people from working and firms from producing. A government collects the same tax revenues at points a or b. The tax rates that correspond to points b and c are often debated by economists.
Clearly, high marginal income tax rates can have adverse effects on the economy. Still, there is considerable controversy regarding the benefits of the supply-side approach to macroeconomic fiscal policy. The supply-side movement that resulted in the marginal tax rate reductions in the 1980s by the Reagan administration was partially driven by reference to a simple tax revenue curve drawn by economist Arthur Laffer showing how reducing tax rates could increase tax revenues. The Laffer curve in Figure 7 shows that if tax rates are 0% or 100%, tax revenues will be zero (the latter because there would be no incentive to earn income). In between these two extreme tax rates, tax revenues will be positive. Laffer argued that high tax rates (such as the one that generates revenues at point a on the Laffer curve) create disincentives to work and invest. He claimed that a lower tax rate would generate the same amount of revenue, seen as point b on the curve. Economists debate about what the tax rate corresponding to point b would be. Further, it raises a bigger debate about the tax rate at which the disincentive to work begins to reduce tax revenues. In other words, what tax rate corresponds to point c on the Laffer curve? Laffer curve A curve that shows a hypothetical relationship between income tax rates and tax revenues. As tax rates rise from zero, revenues rise, reach a maximum, then decline until revenues reach zero again at a 100% tax rate.
Expanding Investment and Reducing Regulations We have already seen how closely standards of living are tied to productivity. Investment increases the capital with which labor works, thereby increasing productivity. Rising productivity drives increased economic growth and raises the average standard of living, shifting the long-run aggregate supply curve to the right. Investment can be encouraged by such policies as investment tax credits (direct reductions in taxes for new
434
investment) and more rapid depreciation schedules for plant and equipment. When a firm can expense (depreciate) its capital equipment over a shorter period of time, it cuts its taxes now rather than later, and therefore earns a higher return on the capital now. Similarly, government grants for basic research help firms increase their budgets for research and development, which results in new products and technologies brought to market. Chromosome genetics research has led to significant advances in medical cures, and is an example of how fiscal policy can expand aggregate supply.
Nowhere is this impact more evident than in the health care field. The National Institutes of Health, part of the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, invests over $30 billion in health care research each year, mostly in grants to medical schools, universities, and research institutions. These investments have enabled new medicines to be developed at a much faster rate than previously. And beyond the obvious benefits this has for the people who require such medicines, investments of this sort pay dividends for the entire economy. As health care improves, workers’ absentee rates are lower and productivity rises. Another way of increasing long-run aggregate supply involves repealing unnecessarily onerous regulations that hamper business and add to costs. Clearly, some regulation of business activities is needed, as the financial industry meltdown in 2008 has shown. Still, these regulations should be subjected to rigorous cost-benefit analyses. Otherwise, excessive regulations end up adding to the costs of the products we buy, without yielding significant benefits. Examples of excessively regulated industries have included trucking and the airlines. When these industries were deregulated in the 1980s, prices fell and both industries expanded rapidly. Today, some economists argue that the Federal Drug Administration’s drug approval process is too long and costly; bringing a new drug to market can cost over $1 billion. Fiscal policies to increase aggregate supply are promoted mainly through the government’s encouragement of human capital development and technology improvements, its power to tax, its ability to promote investment in infrastructure and research, and the degree and efficiency of regulation. Cutting marginal tax rates, offering investment tax credits, and offering grants for research are the favored policies. The political fervor of the 1980s supply-side movement has largely dissipated as marginal income tax rates have declined. But fiscal policies to encourage growth in long-run aggregate supply are still an important part of the government’s long-term fiscal policy arsenal.
Qatar: A Nation Built for the Future 435
How did Qatar, a tiny nation in the Middle East that has never participated in a World Cup soccer match, win its bid to host the biggest sporting event in the world?
I
n November 2022 around 4 billion people from 200 countries will be focused on the world’s most popular sports tournament, the FIFA World Cup. That year’s tournament will be held in one of the smallest nations on Earth, both in size and in population. This country is still relatively unknown to most people, and its national soccer team has never qualified for the World Cup in its history. How then, did Qatar become the host of the 2022 World Cup? Qatar is located on a peninsula off of the Persian Gulf in the Middle East, with an area smaller than the size of Connecticut and fewer than 2 million residents. But what it lacks in size and population is offset by its abundance of resources, particularly oil and natural gas. According to statistics from the World Bank, in 2015 Qatar was the richest nation on Earth in terms of GDP per capita. Its government is flush with cash from its resource exports, which has allowed it to use expansionary fiscal policy with ease.
Over the past two decades, Qatar’s government invested heavily to build infrastructure, increase human capital, and attract foreign investment. These policies not only increased Qatar’s aggregate demand, but also its capacity to produce through its long-run aggregate supply. While many countries struggle with debt, Qatar’s commitment to infrastructure spending made it an excellent candidate to host the World Cup. In its bid to host the World Cup in 2022, Qatar promised to build at least eight new stadiums, including five high-tech climate-controlled stadiums that are able to keep players and spectators cool even when outside temperatures exceed 100°F. In addition, the government-owned airline, Qatar Airways, will expand its operations to include direct flights to nearly all major cities around the world. Qatar’s use of expansionary fiscal policy has helped diversify its economy. This strategy is especially important given the volatility of oil prices, which will encourage oil-rich countries such as Qatar to depend on other factors such as capital and innovation to maintain economic growth.
GO TO
TO PRACTICE THE ECONOMIC CONCEPTS IN THIS STORY
CHECKPOINT FISCAL POLICY AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY The goal of fiscal policies that influence aggregate supply is to shift the long-run aggregate supply curve to the right.
436
Expanding long-run aggregate supply can occur through higher investments in human capital and a focus on technological infrastructure with “public good” benefits. The Laffer curve suggests that reducing tax rates could lead to higher revenues if tax rates are high enough. Other fiscal policies to increase long-run aggregate supply include providing incentives for business investment and reducing burdensome regulation. The major limitation of fiscal policies to influence long-run aggregate supply is that they take a longer time to have an impact compared to polices aimed at influencing aggregate demand.
QUESTIONS: Some economists have suggested that an improved tax structure would entail a reduction
in income taxes for individuals, corporations (corporate income tax), and investors (capital gains taxes), which is offset by an increase in consumption taxes (such as sales and excise taxes). Which part(s) of this type of proposal would be consistent with supply-side economics? Why? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
437
IMPLEMENTING FISCAL POLICY Implementing fiscal policy is often easier said than done. It is frequently a complex and time-consuming process. Three disparate entities—the Senate, House, and the president—must collectively agree on specific spending and tax policies. Ideally, these decisions are made in the open with the public fully informed. The complexities of the budgeting process and its openness (not a bad thing in itself) give rise to several inherent difficulties. We will briefly consider some problems having to do with the timing of fiscal decisions and the political pressures inherent in the process, after first looking at the automatic stabilization mechanisms contained in the federal budgeting process.
Automatic Stabilizers
There is a certain degree of stability built into the U.S. macroeconomic system. Tax revenues and transfer payments are the two principal automatic stabilizers; without any overt action by Congress or other policymakers, these two components of the federal budget expand or contract in ways that help counter movements of the business cycle. automatic stabilizers Tax revenues and transfer payments automatically expand or contract in ways that reduce the intensity of business fluctuations without any overt action by Congress or other policymakers.
When the economy is growing at a solid rate, tax receipts rise because individuals and firms are increasing their taxable incomes. At the same time, transfer payments decline, because fewer people require welfare or unemployment assistance. Rising tax revenues and declining transfer payments have contractionary effects, and act as a brake to slow the growth of GDP, helping to keep the economy from overheating, or keeping it from generating inflationary pressures. When the economic boom ends, and the economy goes into a downturn, the opposite happens: Tax revenues decline and transfer payments rise. These added funds being pumped into the economy help cushion the impact of the downturn, not just for the recipients of transfer payments, but for the economy as a whole. The income tax is also a powerful stabilizer because of its progressivity. When incomes fall, tax revenues fall faster because people do not just pay taxes on smaller incomes, but they pay taxes at lower rates as their incomes fall. Disposable income, in other words, falls more slowly than aggregate income. But when the economy is booming, tax revenues rise faster than income, thereby withdrawing spending from the economy. This helps to slow the growth in income, thus reducing the threat of an inflationary spiral. The key point to remember here is that automatic stabilizers reduce the intensity of business fluctuations. Automatic stabilizers do not eliminate fluctuations in the business cycle, but they render business cycles smoother and less chaotic. Automatic stabilizers act on their own, whereas discretionary fiscal policy requires overt action by policymakers, and this fact alone creates difficulties.
Fiscal Policy Timing Lags Using discretionary fiscal policy to smooth the short-term business cycle is a challenge because of several lags associated with its implementation. First, most of the macroeconomic data that policymakers need to enact the proper fiscal policies are not available until at least one quarter (three months) after the fact. Even then, key figures often get revised for the next quarter or two. The information lag therefore creates a one- to six-month period before informed policymaking can even begin. information lag The time policymakers must wait for economic data to be collected, processed, and reported. Most macroeconomic data are not available until at least one quarter (three months) after the fact.
Even if the most recent data suggest that the economy is trending into a recession, it may take several quarters to confirm this fact. Short-term (month-to-month or quarter-to-quarter) variations in key indicators are common and sometimes represent nothing more than randomness in the data. This recognition lag is one reason why recessions and recoveries are often well under way before policymakers fully acknowledge a need for action.
438
recognition lag The time it takes for policymakers to confirm that the economy is in a recession or a recovery. Short-term variations in key economic indicators are typical and sometimes represent nothing more than randomness in the data.
Third, once policymakers recognize that the economy has trended in a certain direction, fiscal policy requires a long and often contentious legislative process, referred to as a decision lag. Not all legislators have the same goals for the economy; therefore, any new government spending must first survive an arduous trip through the political sausage machine. Once some new policy has become law, it often requires months of planning, budgeting, and implementation to set up a new program. This process, the implementation lag, rarely consumes less than 18 to 24 months. decision lag The time it takes Congress and the administration to decide on a policy once a problem is recognized. implementation lag The time required to turn fiscal policy into law and eventually have an impact on the economy.
The problem these lags pose is clear: By the time the fiscal stimulus meant to jumpstart a sputtering economy kicks in, the economy may already be on the mend. And if so, the exercise of fiscal policy can compound the effects of the business cycle by overstimulating a patient that is already recovering. Some of these lags can be reduced by expediting spending already approved for existing programs rather than implementing new programs. This was the approach Congress and the administration wanted to take with the 2009 stimulus package. Congress allocated part of the increased spending to “shovel-ready” projects to reduce the time for this spending to have an impact on the economy. Also, the lags associated with tax changes are much shorter, given that new rates can go into withholding tables and take effect within weeks of enactment. Therefore, policymakers often include tax changes because of their shorter implementation lags.
The Government’s Bias Toward Borrowing and Away From Taxation Because of the uncertainties surrounding the economy, politicians often take their own interests into account when considering fiscal policy, if not for economic reasons then very likely for political ones. In times of recessions or slow economic recovery, those on the left tend to favor more government spending and transfer payments, while those on the right tend to favor reductions in taxes. Both policies are expansionary and lead to greater deficits, especially as tax receipts fall due to lower incomes and fewer jobs. Political gridlock can delay fiscal policy legislation for months or years.
439
But in order to balance the budget over the long run, such policies generally need to be reversed in good times so that government spending is reduced and taxes raised, along with the generation of more tax receipts from higher incomes and more jobs. But politicians often are reluctant to do so. Even in good economic times, tax hikes are politically dangerous, and so are major cuts to government spending programs and transfer programs. The result is that fiscal policy is financed by deficits. Deficits persist in our system of government. Public choice theory involves the economic analysis of public and political decision making. James Buchanan, considered the father of public choice theory, essentially fused the disciplines of economics and political science. Buchanan contrasted Adam Smith’s description of social benefits that arise from private individuals acting in their own self-interest with the harm that frequently results from politicians doing the same thing. Competition among individuals and firms for jobs, customers, and profits creates wealth, and thus it benefits the entire society. Selfinterested politicians, however, often instigate government interventions that are harmful to the larger economy. public choice theory The economic analysis of public and political decision making, looking at issues such as voting, the impact of election incentives on politicians, the influence of special interest groups, and rentseeking behaviors.
Public choice economists such as Buchanan argue that deficit spending reduces the perceived cost of current government operations. The result is that taxpayers permit some programs to exist that they would oppose if required to pay the full cost today. But this situation, public choice economists charge, amounts to shifting the cost of government to the next generation, and has led to the steady expansion of the federal government. Public choice analysis helps us to understand why deficits seem inevitable. Simply, we do not pay the full costs of today’s programs. In the past 50 years, the federal government has run a deficit in 45 of these years, despite significant growth of the economy over this time. The next section focuses on the role of deficits and public debt on the economy.
CHECKPOINT IMPLEMENTING FISCAL POLICY Automatic stabilizers reduce the intensity of business fluctuations. When the economy is booming, tax revenues rise and unemployment compensation and welfare payments fall, dampening the boom. When the economy enters a recession, tax revenues fall and transfer payments rise,
440
cushioning the decline. This happens automatically. Fiscal policymakers face information lags (the time it takes to collect, process, and provide data on the economy), recognition lags (the time required to recognize trends in the data), decision lags (the time it takes for Congress and the administration to decide on a policy), and implementation lags (the time required by Congress to pass a law and see it put in place). These lags can often result in government policy being mistimed. For example, expansionary policy taking effect when the economy is well into a recovery or failing to take effect when a recession is under way can make stabilization worse. Public choice economists argue that deficit spending reduces the perceived cost of current government operations, and therefore politicians are generally more willing to enact expansionary policies that lead to deficits and a higher public debt.
QUESTION: Suppose that the president wishes to enact fiscal policies that would generate the most
immediate effect on the economy, and thus improve his or her chances of re-election. What type of policies would he or she tend to favor and why? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
441
FINANCING THE FEDERAL GOVERNMENT In the late 1990s, an economic boom fueled by the expansion of the Internet and “dot com” industries resulted in tremendous economic growth and low unemployment. In 1998 an increase in tax revenues collected as a result of higher incomes and on profits earned from a rising stock market led to tax revenues exceeding government spending for the first time in nearly 30 years. This trend lasted four years until 2002, when the government again spent more than it collected in taxes, and has since never reversed course. This section begins by defining deficits and surpluses, national debt, and public debt before studying their impact on the economy.
Defining Deficits and the National Debt
A deficit is the amount by which annual government expenditures exceed tax revenues. A surplus is the amount by which annual tax revenues exceed government expenditures. In 2000 the budget surplus was $236.2 billion. By 2002 tax cuts, a recession, and new commitments for national defense and homeland security had turned the budget surpluses of 1998–2001 into deficits—a deficit of $157.8 billion for fiscal year 2002. The effects of the deep recession in 2007–2009, and the extent of fiscal policies used, changed the magnitude of the deficit picture again. Government intervention and support for the financial and automobile industries and a nearly $800 billion stimulus package to soften the recession resulted in a 2009 deficit of over $1.4 trillion. However, the economic recovery since 2009 significantly reduced the deficit to $440 billion in 2015. deficit The amount by which annual government expenditures exceed tax revenues. surplus The amount by which annual tax revenues exceed government expenditures.
The gross federal debt, or more commonly known as the national debt, is the total accumulation of past deficits less surpluses. The national debt is measured as the total amount of debt issued by the U.S. Treasury (including Treasury bills, notes, and bonds, and Savings bonds). The national debt in 2016 was over $19 trillion. However, a portion of this debt is held by other agencies of government, such as the Social Security Administration, the Treasury Department, and the Federal Reserve, in what is referred to as an intergovernmental transfer. What exactly does this mean? national debt The total debt issued by the U.S. Treasury, which represents the total accumulation of past deficits less surpluses. A portion of this debt is held by other government agencies, and the rest is held by the public. It is also referred to as the gross federal debt.
Suppose you have a savings account with funds to be used to pay your college tuition, but due to an unexpected expensive $2,000 car repair, you temporarily borrowed from your college savings account by withdrawing $800 and borrowed the remaining $1,200 using a credit card. Although you fully intend to pay back the full $2,000 in debt (including your college savings), only $1,200 is owed to someone other than yourself. Similarly, part of the total debt that the government has incurred is owed to itself, and the rest is owed to the public. The public debt, also known as the net debt or federal debt held by the public, is the portion of the national debt that is held by individuals, companies, and pension funds, along with foreign entities and foreign governments. Public debt represents a real claim on government assets, and is the debt that is more scrutinized when analyzing the health of the macroeconomy. public debt The portion of the national debt that is held by the public, including individuals, companies, pension funds, along with foreign entities and foreign governments. This debt is also referred to as net debt or federal debt held by the public.
In sum, the national debt and public debt are distinct measures of the extent to which government spending has exceeded tax revenues over the course of time. Figure 8 shows the public debt as a percentage of gross domestic product (GDP) since 1940. During World War II, public debt exceeded GDP. It then trended downward until the
442
early 1980s, when public debt began to climb again. Public debt as a percentage of GDP fell from the mid-1990s until 2000, first because of growing budget surpluses in the late 1990s, then because of falling interest rates (what the government has to pay on the debt), but it has risen since then. Public debt today exceeds 70% of GDP. Public debt is held as U.S. Treasury securities, including Treasury bills, notes, bonds, and U.S. Savings Bonds. Treasury bills, or T-bills, as they are known, are short-term instruments with a maturity period of a year or less that pay a specific sum at maturity. T-bills do not pay interest. Rather, they are initially sold at a discount, and their yields are then determined by the time to maturity and the discount. T-bills are the most actively traded securities in the U.S. economy, and they are highly liquid, providing the closest thing there is to risk-free returns. Treasury notes are financial instruments issued for periods ranging from 1 to 10 years, whereas Treasury bonds have maturity periods exceeding 10 years. Both of these instruments have stated interest rates and are traded sometimes at discounts and sometimes at premiums. Today, interest rates on the public debt are between 1% and 4%. This relatively low rate has not always been the case. In the early 1980s, interest rates varied from 11% to nearly 15%. Inflation was high and investors required high interest rates as compensation. When rates are high, government interest costs on the debt soar. FIGURE 8
PUBLIC DEBT AS A PERCENT OF GDP
The public debt as a percentage of GDP has varied considerably since 1940. During World War II, public
443
debt exceeded GDP. It then trended downward until the early 1980s, when public debt began to climb again. In 2016 public debt held by the public (as opposed to government institutions) exceeded 70% of GDP.
Balanced Budget Amendments Although federal budget deficits have been the norm for the past 50 years, the 2007–2009 recession led to record deficits, leading many politicians to propose federal balanced budget amendments requiring the federal government to balance its budget every year. Balanced budget amendments are not new. They exist, with varying exceptions, for most state governments. At the federal level, however, such rules have not existed since the 1930s. Most balanced budget amendments require an annually balanced budget, which means government would have to equate its revenues and expenditures every year. Most economists, however, believe such rules are counterproductive. For example, during times of recession, tax revenues tend to fall due to lower incomes and higher unemployment. To offset these lost revenues, an annually balanced budget would require deep spending cuts or tax hikes (in other words, contractionary fiscal policy) during a time when expansionary fiscal policies are needed. Many economists believe that balanced budget rules of the early 1930s turned what probably would have been a modest recession into the global Depression. annually balanced budget Expenditures and taxes would have to be equal each year.
An alternative to balancing the budget annually would be to require a cyclically balanced budget, in which the budget is balanced over the course of the business cycle. The basic idea is to restrict spending or raise taxes when the economy is booming, allowing for a budget surplus. These surpluses would then be used to offset deficits accrued during recessions, when increased spending or lower taxes are appropriate. To some extent, balancing the budget over the business cycle happens automatically as long as fiscal policy is held constant due to the automatic stabilizers discussed earlier. However, the business cycle takes time to define (due to lags), making it difficult to enforce such a rule in practice. cyclically balanced budget Balancing the budget over the course of the business cycle by restricting spending or raising taxes when the economy is booming and using these surpluses to offset the deficits that occur during recessions.
ISSUE How Big Is the Economic Burden of Interest Rates on the National Debt? The federal government paid $223 billion in interest payments on the national debt in 2016. This is money that could have been used for other public programs. In fact, interest payments on the debt were greater than the amount the government paid for education, transportation infrastructure, lowincome housing, and Homeland Security combined. Although interest payments on the debt are large, they represent a small portion of the federal budget and an even smaller portion of GDP. Interest on the debt as a percentage of GDP, as shown in the figure, was steady from 1950 to 1980, hovering around 1.5%. This percentage more than doubled during the 1980s because of high inflation and interest rates, and rising deficits. In the 1990s, interest rates dropped and deficits fell, allowing interest payments as a percentage of GDP to fall toward the level it was in the 1950s. The rising debt associated with the 2007–2009 recession increased the percentage again, but not by much due to record low interest rates. Today, interest rates remain low, allowing interest payments to remain a small percentage of GDP. The fact that rising debt has not led to dramatic borrowing costs highlights the important role that interest rates have on the economy. Many individuals, firms, and foreign governments hold long-term (up to 30-year) Treasury bonds. During the economic crisis in the early 1980s, interest rates on 30-
444
year Treasury bonds reached 15%, guaranteeing a bondholder a 15% annual return for 30 years. Today, those 15% bonds from the 1980s have matured, and new 30-year bonds are paying less than 4%, resulting in tremendous savings to the government in financing the national debt. For example, an average interest rate of 2% saves the U.S. federal government $500 billion per year compared to a 5% interest rate, and saves over $1 trillion per year compared to an 8% interest rate. Why have long-term interest rates remained low despite the high debt and a debt downgrade in U.S. bonds? One reason is that volatility in stock markets makes U.S. debt still one of the safest investments in the world. Second, foreign governments perceive the U.S. dollar as a valuable hard currency, and thus buy our bonds as a way to build up their national reserves. For these reasons and more, the U.S. government has little trouble selling bonds at low interest rates. Despite the current favorable conditions under which the U.S. government finances its debt, it must still focus on keeping debt in check for a number of reasons. For example, interest payments on external (foreign) holdings of U.S. debt are a leakage from our economy. Also, as interest rates rise in the future, low interest rate bonds issued today will mature and be replaced by higher interest rate bonds.
Finally, some economists believe that balancing the budget should not be the primary concern of policymakers; instead, they view the government’s primary macroeconomic responsibility to foster economic growth and stable prices, while keeping the economy as close as possible to full employment. This is the functional finance approach to the budget, where governments provide public goods and services that citizens want (such as national defense and education) and focus on policies that keep the economy growing, because rapidly growing economies do not have significant public debt or deficit issues. functional finance An approach that focuses on fostering economic growth and stable prices, while keeping the economy as close as possible to full employment.
In sum, balancing the budget annually or over the business cycle may be either counterproductive or difficult to do. It is not a solution to the public choice problem previously discussed of politicians’ incentives to spend and not raise taxes. Budget deficits begin to look like a normal occurrence in our political system.
Financing Debt and Deficits Seeing as how deficits may be persistent, how does the government deal with its debt, and what does this imply for the economy? Government deals with debt in two ways. It can either borrow or sell assets.
445
Given its power to print money and collect taxes, the federal government cannot go bankrupt per se. But it does face what economists call a government budget constraint: G − T = ΔM + ΔB + ΔA where G = government spending T = tax revenues; thus, (G − T) is the federal budget deficit ΔM = the change in the money supply (selling bonds to the Federal Reserve) ΔB = the change in bonds held by public entities, domestic and foreign ΔA = the sales of government assets government budget constraint The government budget is limited by the fact that G − T = ΔM + ΔB + ΔA.
The left side of the equation, G − T, represents government spending minus tax revenues. A positive (G − T) value is a budget deficit, and a negative (G − T) value represents a budget surplus. The right side of the equation shows how government finances its deficit. It can sell bonds to the Federal Reserve, sell bonds to the public, or sell assets. Let’s look at each of these options. ΔM > 0: First, the government can sell bonds to government agencies, especially the Federal Reserve, which we will study in depth in a later chapter. When the Federal Reserve buys bonds, it uses money that is created out of thin air by its power to “print” money. When the Federal Reserve pumps new money into the money supply to finance the government’s debt, it is called monetizing the debt. ΔB > 0: If the Federal Reserve does not purchase the bonds, they may be sold to the public, including corporations, banks, mutual funds, individuals, and foreign entities. This also has the effect of financing the government’s deficit. ΔA > 0: Asset sales represent only a small fraction of government finance in the United States. These sales include auctions of telecommunications spectra and offshore oil leases. Developing nations have used asset sales, or privatization, in recent years to bolster sagging government revenues and to encourage efficiency and development in the case where a government-owned industry is sold. Thus, when the government runs a deficit, it must borrow funds from somewhere, assuming it does not sell assets. If the government borrows from the public, the quantity of publicly held bonds will rise; if it borrows from the Federal Reserve, the quantity of money in circulation will rise. The main idea from this section is that deficits must be financed in some form, whether by the government borrowing or selling assets. As we’ll see in the next section, rising levels of deficits and the corresponding interest rates raise some important issues about the ability of a country to manage its debt burden.
CHECKPOINT FINANCING THE FEDERAL GOVERNMENT A deficit is the amount that government spending exceeds tax revenue in a particular year. The public (national) debt is the total accumulation of past deficits less surpluses. Approaches to financing the federal government include annually balancing the budget, balancing the budget over the business cycle, and ignoring the budget deficit and focusing on promoting full employment and stable prices. The federal government’s debt must be financed by selling bonds to the Federal Reserve (“printing money” or “monetizing the debt”), by selling bonds to the public, or by selling government assets. This is known as the government budget constraint.
QUESTION: One reason why state governments have been more willing to pass balanced budget amendments than the federal government is the difference between mandatory and discretionary spending.
446
What are some expenses of the federal government that are less predictable or harder to cut that make balanced budget amendments more difficult to pursue? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
447
WHY IS THE PUBLIC DEBT SO IMPORTANT? We have seen that politicians have a bias toward using expansionary fiscal policy and not contractionary fiscal policy, and also have a bias toward using debt rather than taxes to finance the ensuing deficits. This explains the persistence of federal debt. We have seen that balancing the federal budget by passing an amendment is not an ideal solution. This leads to the following questions: How big a problem is persistent deficits? Should we be worrying about this now? Figure 9 shows the debt of mostly developed nations in 2015. Japan, Greece, and Italy had a large debt relative to their GDP, but Greece and Italy have reduced their deficit in recent years, allowing the increase in debt to slow. India has a relatively low debt ratio but has seen higher deficits recently. China, Russia, and Chile have very low debt ratios, but deficits in all three countries have risen in recent years as economic growth slowed. When an economy moves toward the upper left portion of the figure, problems begin to rise. In Japan, an aging population (fact: Japan has more people over the age of 100 than any other country in the world!) along with a shrinking working-age population has severely strained government budgets. FIGURE 9
PUBLIC DEBT AND DEFICITS AS A PERCENT OF GDP
This figure shows the relationship between public debt and deficits for several nations. Countries with high deficits tend to have high debt-to-GDP ratios. An aging population in Japan contributes to its high national debt. However, the willingness of Japan’s private sector to hold government bonds allows Japan’s government to finance its debt at low interest rates. Still, deficit and debt remain a major problem, so much so that Japan has stopped its tradition of bestowing a commemorative silver sake dish when a citizen celebrates his or her 100th birthday.
Politicians frequently warn that the federal government is going bankrupt, or that we are burdening future generations with our own enormous public debt. After all, U.S. public debt of nearly $14 trillion means that every baby born in the United States begins life saddled with over $42,000 in public debt. Before you start panicking, let’s examine the burden of the public debt.
Is the Size of the Public Debt a Problem? Public debt in the United States represents a little over 70% of GDP. Is this amount of debt a cause for immediate
448
concern? It really depends on the costs of financing the debt. What is the burden of the interest rate payments on the debt? Think about it another way. Suppose that you earn $50,000 a year and have $35,000 in student loan debt, equal to 70% of your annual income. Is this a problem? It would be if the interest rate on the student loans were 20% a year, because interest payments of $7,000 per year would take up a significant chunk (14%) of your gross salary. But if the interest rate is 3%, the debt burden from the interest ($1,050 per year) would not be as substantial, representing only about 2% of your gross salary. For the U.S. national debt, current interest rates are relatively low due in large part to aggressive action by the Federal Reserve. Interest costs on the national debt were $223 billion in 2015, representing about 6% of the federal budget. That is not an overwhelming amount. Wouldn’t it be wise to pay the debt down or pay it off? Not necessarily. Many people today “own” some small part of the public debt in their pension plans, but many others do not. If taxes were raised across the board to pay down the debt, those who did not own any public debt would be in a worse position than those who did. Servicing the debt requires taxing the general public to pay interest to bondholders. Most people who own part of the national debt (or who indirectly own parts of entities that hold the debt) tend to be richer than those who do not. This means that money is taken from those across the income or wealth distribution and given to those near the top. Still, the fact that taxes are mildly progressive mitigates some, and perhaps even all, of this reverse redistribution problem. Thus, the public debt is not out of control, at least based on the economy’s ability to pay the interest costs. However, rising interest rates will raise the burden of this debt. Even so, at its current size, the public debt is manageable as long as it does not experience another spike in the near term. Another consideration is whether the debt is mostly held externally (i.e., financed by foreign governments, banks, and investors), as is the case of many developing countries. These countries have discovered that relying on foreign sources of financing has its limits.
Does It Matter If Foreigners Hold a Significant Portion of the Public Debt? The great advantage of citizens being creditors as well as debtors with relation to the public debt is obvious. Men readily perceive that they can not be much oppressed by a debt which they owe to themselves. —ABRAHAM LINCOLN (1864)
Consider first, as Abraham Lincoln noted in 1864, that much of the national debt held by the public is owned by American banks, corporations, mutual funds, pension plans, and individuals. As a people, we essentially own this debt—this is internally held debt. Hence, the taxes collected from a wide swath of the American public to pay the interest on the debt are paid back out to yet another group of Americans. As Table 1 shows, however, foreigners own nearly half of the public debt held by the public. This is externally held debt. internally held debt Public debt owned by domestic banks, corporations, mutual funds, pension plans, and individuals. externally held debt Public debt held by foreigners, including foreign industries, banks, and governments.
TABLE 1
DISTRIBUTION OF NATIONAL DEBT, AS OF MARCH 2016 (TRILLIONS) Amount
Percent
Held by the Federal Reserve and government agencies
$5.316
27.7%
Held by the public
13.872
72.3
449
Held by foreigners
6.435
33.5
Held domestically
7.437
38.8
19.188
100.00
Total national debt
Data from the U.S. Department of the Treasury.
Of the interest paid on the $19.2 trillion national debt, about 28% goes to federal agencies holding this debt—the Social Security Administration, the Federal Reserve, and other federal agencies, 39% goes to the American private sector, and 34% goes to foreigners. The interest paid on externally held debt represents a real claim on our goods and services, and thus can be a real burden on our economy. Debt held by the public has grown, and the portion of the debt held by foreigners has expanded. Until the mid-1990s, foreigners held roughly 20% of publicly held debt. Traditionally much of the U.S. debt is held internally, but this is changing. In just a decade, foreign holdings have doubled to nearly 50% of debt held by the public, and about 40% of this is held by China and Japan. Why such a rapid expansion of foreign holdings since the 1990s? One reason is that these countries are buying our debt to keep their currencies from rising relative to the dollar. When their currencies rise, their exports to America are more costly; as a result, sales fall, hurting their economies. It is better to accumulate U.S. debt than see their export sectors suffer. However, the increased reliance on external financing of our debt raises some concerns. For example, the significant amount of our debt held by China makes our economy more vulnerable to policy changes by the Chinese government and/or businesses that hold our debt. On the positive side, however, creditors such as China are likely to maintain strong economic and political ties with the United States; besides, China eventually will want its money back.
Does Government Debt Crowd Out Consumption and Investment? As we saw in the budget constraint section earlier, when the government runs a deficit, it must sell bonds to either the public or the Federal Reserve. If it sells bonds to the Federal Reserve (prints money) when the economy is near full employment, the money supply will grow and inflation will result. Alternatively, when the federal government spends more than tax revenues permit, it can sell bonds to the public. But doing so drives up interest rates as the demand for loanable funds (this time by the government rather than the public sector) increases. As interest rates rise, consumer spending on durable goods such as cars and appliances, often bought on credit, falls. It also reduces private business investment. Therefore, while deficit spending is usually expansionary, the consequence is that future generations will be bequeathed a smaller and potentially less productive economy, resulting in a lower standard of living. This is the crowding-out effect of deficit spending. However, in a severe recession when consumers and businesses are not eager to buy or invest, the crowding-out effect is less pronounced, making fiscal policy more powerful. crowding-out effect When deficit spending requires the government to borrow, interest rates are driven up, reducing consumer spending and business investment.
The crowding-out effect also can be mitigated if the funds from deficit spending are used for public investment. Improvements in the nation’s transportation infrastructure, education establishment, and research facilities, for instance, are all aimed at improving the economy’s future productive capacity. If the investments expand the nation’s productive capacity enough, growth will be such that the debt-to-GDP ratio may fall. But if all or most of the deficit is spent on current consumption, growth in GDP may be weak and the debt-to-GDP ratio will most likely rise.
How Will the National Debt Affect Our Future? Are We 450
Doomed? If the federal debt is not an enormous burden now, what about in the future? Here there is a large cause for concern. Economists have argued that economic growth depends on the fiscal sustainability of the federal budget. For a fiscal policy to be fiscally sustainable, the present value (current dollar value) of all projected future revenues must be equal to the present value of projected future spending. If the budget is not fiscally sustainable, an intergenerational tax burden may be created, with future generations paying for the spending of the current generation. fiscal sustainability A measure of the present value of all projected future revenues compared to the present value of projected future spending.
Clearly, some tax burden shifting is sensible. When current fiscal policy truly invests in the economy, future generations benefit, and therefore, some of the present costs may justifiably be shifted to them. Investments in infrastructure, education, research, national defense, and homeland security are good examples. However, the federal government has immense obligations that extend over long periods that are unrelated to economic investment. Its two largest programs, Social Security and Medicare, account for over 35% of all federal spending. People who are just beginning to enter retirement can expect to live for two or three more decades. Add to this the fact that medical costs are growing at rates significantly higher than economic growth as new and more sophisticated treatments are developed and demanded. The intergenerational impact results from the fact that Social Security and Medicare are pay-as-you-go programs. The current working generation, in other words, funds the older generation’s benefits; there are no pooled funds waiting to be tapped as needed. Thus, these two programs represent huge unfunded liabilities to younger (and yet to be born) generations. With the current national debt held by the public at nearly $14 trillion, and total future liabilities (the money that has been promised, such as for Social Security and Medicare, but have not been paid) estimated to be several times the current public debt, the implications for future budgeting are significant. In other words, without some significant change in economic or demographic growth, taxes will have to be increased dramatically at some point, or else the benefits for Social Security and Medicare will have to be drastically cut. If these estimates of fiscal imbalance are on track, fiscal policy is headed for a train wreck as the baby boomers keep retiring. The public choice analysis discussed earlier suggests that politicians will try to keep this issue off the agenda for as long as possible, one side fighting tax increases while the other resists benefit reductions. Clearly, given the magnitudes discussed here, this problem will be difficult to solve. We started this chapter by talking about the government’s ability to address fluctuations in the business cycle by using fiscal policy to affect aggregate demand and aggregate supply. But given the government’s penchant for expansionary policy, persistent budget deficits tend to result. Unlike for individuals, the federal government has the ability to incur debt for some time because of its ability to print money and borrow from the public. And while the federal government is currently able to safely manage its debt, this picture may change down the road as Social Security and Medicare liabilities continue to grow. The implication is that we are better off dealing with this future problem now rather than later.
CHECKPOINT WHY IS THE PUBLIC DEBT SO IMPORTANT? Interest payments on the debt exceed 6% of the federal budget. These funds could have been spent on other programs. About half of the public debt held by the public is held by domestic individuals and institutions, and half is held by foreigners. The domestic half is internally held and represents transfers among individuals, but that part held by foreigners is a real claim on our resources. When the government pays for the deficit by selling bonds, interest rates rise, crowding out some consumption and private investment and reducing economic growth. To the extent that these funds are used for public investment and not current consumption, this effect is mitigated.
451
The rising costs of Social Security and Medicare represent the biggest threat to the long-run federal budget. Either the costs of such programs eventually need to be reduced, or additional taxes will be required to cover these rising expenses.
QUESTIONS: Suppose China and Japan, the two largest external creditors of U.S. public debt, choose to diversify their asset holdings by selling some of their U.S. Treasury bonds. How will this affect the U.S. government’s ability to finance its debt? What might happen to consumption and investment in the United States? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
452
chapter summary Section 1 Fiscal Policy and Aggregate Demand 10.1
Fiscal policy describes the use of government taxation and spending to influence the economy. Specifically, it involves three main tools: taxation, government spending on goods and services, and transfer payments.
10.2
Contractionary fiscal policy includes reducing government spending or transfer payments, or raising taxes. The effect is a shift of the AD curve to the left, decreasing prices and aggregate output.
Expansionary fiscal policy includes increases in government spending or transfer payments, or reducing taxes. The effect is a shift of the AD curve to the right, increasing prices and aggregate output.
10.3
The multiplier effect allows each dollar of government spending to expand aggregate output by a multiple of the amount spent. Changes in government spending have a larger multiplier than changes in taxes.
453
Unemployment benefits generally produce a high multiplier effect because recipients are likely to spend all of the money quickly. Using expansionary fiscal policy to shift AD during a recession can reduce the time required to achieve full employment. The tradeoff of such policies is potential inflation, although the effect is small when used in a deep recession.
Section 2 Fiscal Policy and Aggregate Supply The goal of supply-side fiscal policy is to shift the LRAS curve to the right. Such policies do not require a tradeoff between output and prices; however, these policies require more time to work.
Maintaining highways such as the treacherous Trans-Alaskan Highway can increase aggregate supply if better roads increase productivity.
454
10.4
Common Supply-Side Policies Increase Infrastructure Spending: Improving roads and communications networks, stabilizing legal and financial systems, and improving human capital and technologies (R&D). Decrease Tax Rates: Increases aggregate supply by providing firms incentives to expand or for individuals to work more. Eliminate Burdensome Regulations: Leads to greater efficiency if the costs of regulation outweigh the benefits.
Section 3 Implementing Fiscal Policy 10.5
The economy contains automatic stabilizers: When the economy is strong:
When the economy is weak:
455
10.6
Using fiscal policy involves timing lags: Information lag: Time required to acquire macroeconomic data Recognition lag: Time required to recognize trends in the data Decision lag: Legislative process to enact policies Implementation lag: Time required after laws are passed to set up programs
Passing new fiscal policy can take a lot of time, especially in a divided Congress.
Section 4 Financing the Federal Government 10.7
The federal deficit is the annual amount by which government spending exceeds tax revenues. A surplus occurs when tax revenues exceed government spending. The national debt is the accumulation of all past deficits less surpluses. The public debt is the portion of the national debt that is held by the public.
How Does the Government Finance Its Deficit (G – T)? The Federal Reserve prints money to buy bonds: ΔM Treasury bonds held domestically and externally: ΔB
456
Sales of government assets: ΔA
U.S. Savings Bonds are one form of financing government debt.
Section 5 Why Is the Public Debt So Important? 10.8
In 2015 the U.S. government paid $223 billion in interest payments on the public debt. Although this is a manageable expense, higher interest rates and rising future liabilities can make debt a more significant problem in the future.
Social Security and Medicare liabilities rise each year as Americans live longer and health care costs rise. These two components pose a big concern for future debt. About half of U.S. public debt is held externally, by foreign governments and investors. Of this amount, about 40%, or about $2.4 trillion, is held by China and Japan. Borrowing money to finance the debt raises interest rates, making it more expensive for individuals and businesses to borrow money. This is the crowding-out effect.
KEY CONCEPTS discretionary spending mandatory spending discretionary fiscal policy expansionary fiscal policy
457
contractionary fiscal policy supply-side fiscal policies Laffer curve automatic stabilizers information lag recognition lag decision lag implementation lag public choice theory deficit surplus national debt public debt annually balanced budget cyclically balanced budget functional finance government budget constraint internally held debt externally held debt crowding-out effect fiscal sustainability
QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS Check Your Understanding 1. Explain why government spending theoretically gives a bigger boost to the economy than tax cuts. 2. Explain why increasing government purchases of goods and services is expansionary fiscal policy. Would increasing taxes or reducing transfer payments be contractionary or expansionary? Why? 3. Changes in tax rates affect both aggregate demand and aggregate supply. Explain why this is true. 4. What is one benefit to businesses when the government budget is in surplus? 5. How might interest paid on the national debt lead to greater income inequality? 6. Is the absolute size of the national debt or the national debt as a percent of GDP the best measure of its importance to our economy? Explain.
Apply the Concepts 7. One argument often heard against using fiscal policy to tame the business cycle is that the lags associated with getting a fiscal policy implemented are so long that when the program is finally passed and implemented, the business cycle has moved on to the next phase and the new program may not be necessary and may even be potentially destabilizing at that point. Does this argument seem reasonable? What counterarguments can you make in support of using fiscal policy? 8. As mandatory federal spending becomes increasingly a larger share of the budget, should we worry that the economic stabilization aspects of fiscal policy are becoming so limited as to be ineffective? 9. Our current personal income tax system is progressive: Income tax rates rise with rising incomes and are lower for low-income individuals. Some policymakers have favored a “flat tax” as a replacement for our modestly progressive income tax system. Most exemptions and deductions would be eliminated, and a single low tax rate would be applied to personal income. Would such a change in the tax laws alter the automatic stabilization characteristics of the personal income tax? 10. In 1962 in a speech before the Economic Club of New York, President Kennedy argued that “it is a paradoxical
458
truth that taxes are too high today and tax revenues are too low—and the soundest way to raise revenues in the long run is to cut rates now.” Is President Kennedy’s argument consistent with supply-side economics? Why or why not? 11. A balanced budget amendment to the Constitution requiring Congress to balance the budget every year is introduced in Congress every so often. What sort of problems would the passage of such an amendment introduce for policymakers and the economy? What would be the benefit of the passage of such an amendment? 12. If the economy (gross domestic product) is growing faster than the growth of the national debt held by the public (both domestic and foreign), how does that affect the ability of the government to manage the national debt? What arguments can you make to rebut the common assertion that the national debt is bankrupting the country?
In the News 13. In recent years, a growing number of states have legalized marijuana for recreational purposes. Sales of marijuana are subject to various state sales and excise taxes that add between 25% and 44% to the price. Previously, sales of marijuana in these states took place in the informal or underground economy, where taxes are avoided and crime runs high. What are some fiscal policy justifications for legalizing marijuana? 14. In the aftermath of the 2007–2009 recession, the U.S. national debt rose to record levels as the federal government used expansionary fiscal policy to speed up the economic recovery. This led some politicians to propose a significant reduction in the size of government in order to balance the budget. Would such a policy be expansionary or contractionary in nature? What factors would determine whether or not such a policy would harm economic growth?
Solving Problems 15. Suppose a small economy has two income tax rates: 15% for all income up to $50,000 and 30% for any income earned above $50,000. Suppose that prior to the recession, the economy had five workers earning the following salaries: Amy Betty Charlie Dimitry Evelyn
$20,000 $40,000 $60,000 $80,000 $100,000
a. Calculate the total tax revenues paid by the five workers. What percent of total income does this represent? b. Now assume that a recession causes each of the five salaries to fall by 25%. Given the lower salaries, what would be the total tax revenues paid by the five workers? What percent of total income does this represent? c. Explain how this progressive tax structure acts as an automatic stabilizer.
WORK IT OUT 16. Suppose an economy has a GDP of $40 billion and a national debt of $20 billion, and the average interest rate on this debt is currently 3%. a. Calculate the annual interest payments on the debt. What percentage of this economy’s GDP is spent on interest payments on its debt? b. Suppose that next year one of two events occurs: (1) GDP and interest rates stay the same, but the economy adds $4 billion to its national debt; (2) GDP and the national debt stay the same, but interest rates increase to 4%. Which of the two events would result in a larger portion of the economy’s GDP going toward interest payments on the national debt?
459
USING THE NUMBERS 17. According to By the Numbers, approximately what percent of total external debt is held by China? What does this suggest about the importance of U.S. relations with China? 18. According to By the Numbers, in which year between 1990 and 2016 did the United States have the biggest budget surplus and what was that value? In which year did it have the biggest budget deficit and what was that value?
ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS Checkpoint: Fiscal Policy and Aggregate Demand Although the money would have hit the economy sooner, a significant portion of the proceeds would have been saved or used to pay existing bills, potentially limiting the stimulative impact of added spending. The other benefit of the infrastructure package is that by being spread out over several years, it won’t just be a big jolt to the economy that ends as fast as it began. Thus, the impact on employment and business planning was smoother. Checkpoint: Fiscal Policy and Aggregate Supply Supply-side economics focuses on providing incentives for individuals to work and for businesses to invest, and therefore advocate lower tax rates. The reduction in the individual, corporate, and capital gains taxes would each be consistent with supply-side economics. However, if a portion of these tax savings is offset through higher consumption taxes, this would not be consistent with supply-side economics because such a tax would discourage consumption and negatively affect business and investment outlook. Checkpoint: Implementing Fiscal Policy The president would favor policies that could be implemented quickly, such as “shovel ready” infrastructure projects that have already been approved, the expansion of unemployment benefits that can take effect immediately, or tax cuts that can be applied in the current tax year. The president would not favor policies that require a new law to be passed, as such policies may take years before being implemented. Checkpoint: Financing the Federal Government The federal government must satisfy its mandatory spending requirements, including Social Security, unless it passes a law to reform such spending. Also, the federal government must pay for national defense, including wars, which are unpredictable. Also unpredictable are expenses related to natural disasters, which require action by various federal agencies. Because of the combination of various mandatory spending programs and unpredictable discretionary spending requirements, the federal government would find it difficult in practice to enforce a balanced budget amendment. Checkpoint: Why Is the Public Debt So Important? If China and Japan reduce their holdings of U.S. debt, interest rates would need to rise in order to attract other investors to purchase these bonds. Rising interest rates would adversely affect consumption and investment in the United States, potentially slowing economic growth.
460
11
Saving, Investment, and the Financial System
461
Understanding the importance of financial institutions and their role in connecting 462
savers with borrowers
Learning Objectives 11.1
Describe the functions of money.
11.2
Define the money supply according to M1 and M2.
11.3
Use the loanable funds model to show how savers and borrowers are brought together.
11.4
Describe how economic factors can lead to a change in the market for loanable funds.
11.5
Explain how financial intermediaries make it easier and less risky for people to save and borrow.
11.6
Describe the relationship between the price of bonds and interest rates.
11.7
Explain how the compounding effect makes debt and savings much larger over time.
11.8
Describe the tradeoff between risk and return, and how that influences the return on investment for bonds and stocks.
11.9
Understand how retirement savings programs function and the benefits they provide.
O
n August 13, 2004, the city of Athens, Greece, celebrated as the Summer Olympic Games returned to its historic homeland, the place where Olympic athletes nearly 3,000 years ago competed on the same land as athletes in the current games were about to compete.
Indeed, it was a proud moment for Greeks, and for their government, which had borrowed billions of dollars to build new stadiums, a modern transportation network, and a new airport, and to give the city a significant facelift to showcase its growing economic prosperity to a worldwide audience. Where did the government get this money? It borrowed money from banks and from the public by issuing bonds, and there was plenty of money to be borrowed. The Olympics were the ultimate showpiece of a nation on the rise. No one could have predicted on that proud day that in less than a decade, that same city would be engulfed in financial turmoil, with large government debt, protests and riots, and a country in complete despair. What happened in Greece that led to such a dramatic reversal in fortune? In short, it was a breakdown of financial institutions caused by a global recession along with uncontrolled government debt that caused long-term interest rates to skyrocket from 4% in 2009 to 27% in 2012. With interest rates so high, the ability to borrow, whether by the government, by businesses, or by consumers, became prohibitive, leading to a drastic decline in consumption and investment and subsequently a rise in unemployment. Clearly, Greece headed into a vicious cycle that threatened not only the country but the stability of the euro, the currency it shares with much of Europe. Although Greece was not the only country to have undergone a financial crisis, it was one of the most difficult cases because of the challenges that affected the banks, bond market, and stock market—which form what we refer to
463
as a country’s financial system. The financial system plays an important role in the health of the macroeconomy, and when the system breaks down, as it did in Greece, the economy often goes down with it.
Up to now, we have looked at how the federal government tries to manage the macroeconomy through fiscal policy, by using government taxation and spending. We now want to look at the government’s other policy approach —monetary policy. To analyze how government uses monetary policy to influence the macroeconomy, we must first lay the foundation by examining the financial system and the role of money, which is the subject of this chapter. Building on this foundation, in the following chapters we will see how financial institutions create money and how the government enacts policies that encourage the financial system to do things that mitigate fluctuations in the macroeconomy.
464
We begin by looking at money: what it is and what it does. We then examine why people save and why firms
465
borrow. We next show how the market for loanable funds brings together these two groups, and how the financial system makes this process easier and better for all. The chapter concludes with an overview of financial tools that illustrates the importance of financial literacy in our everyday lives.
466
WHAT IS MONEY? Anything can serve as money, from the cowrie shells of the Maldives to the huge stone disks used on the Pacific islands of Yap. And now, it seems, in this electronic age nothing can serve as money too. NIALL FERGUSON, THE ASCENT OF MONEY
Money is anything that is accepted in exchange for goods and services or for the payment of debt. For example, we are familiar with currency and coins. Over the ages, however, a wide variety of commodities have served as money— giant circular stones on the island of Yap, wampum (trinkets) among early Native Americans, and cigarettes in prisoner-of-war camps during World War II. money Anything that is accepted in exchange for goods and services or for the payment of debt.
Commodity money consists of objects and materials (such as gold, silver, and trinkets) that have value in and of itself. However, commodities must meet certain criteria to be effectively used as money. First, its value must be easy to determine. Therefore, it must be easily standardized. Second, it must be divisible so that people can make change. Third, money must be durable and portable. It must be easy to carry (so much for the giant circular stones, which today are used only for ceremonial purposes in Yap.) Fourth, a commodity must be accepted by many people as money if it is to act as money. As Niall Ferguson makes clear in the quote above, today we have “virtual” money, in the sense that digital money is moved from our employer to the bank and then to the retailer for our goods and services in nothing but a series of electronic transactions. This is really the ultimate in fiat money: money without any intrinsic value but accepted as money because the government has made it legal tender. fiat money Money without intrinsic value but nonetheless accepted as money because the government has decreed it to be money.
Money is so important that nearly every society has invented some form of money for its use. We begin our examination of money by looking at its functions.
The Functions of Money
Money has three primary functions in our economic system: as a medium of exchange, as a measure of value (unit of account), and as a store of value. These uses make money unique among commodities.
Medium of Exchange
Let us start with a primitive economy. There is no money. To survive, you have to produce everything yourself: food, clothing, housing. It is a fact that few of us can do all of these tasks equally well. Each one of us is better off specializing, providing those goods and services we are more efficient at supplying. Say I specialize in dairy products and you specialize in blacksmithing. We can engage in barter, which is the direct exchange of goods and services. I can give you gallons of milk if you make me a pot for cooking. A double coincidence of wants occurs if, in a barter economy, I find someone who not only has something I want, but who also wants something I have. What happens if you, the blacksmith, are willing to make the cooking pot for me but want clothing in return? Then I have to search out someone who is willing to give me clothing in exchange for milk; I will then give you the clothing in exchange for the cooking pot. You can see that this system quickly becomes complicated. This is why barter is restricted to primitive economies. barter The direct exchange of goods and services for other goods and services.
Consider what happens when money is introduced. Everyone can spend their time producing goods and services, rather than running around trying to match up exchanges. Everyone can sell their products for money, and then can use this money to buy cooking pots, clothing, or whatever else they want. Thus, money’s first and most important
467
function is as a medium of exchange. Without money, economies remain primitive. medium of exchange A function of money in which goods and services are sold for money, then the money is used to purchase other goods and services.
Unit of Account
Imagine the difficulties consumers would have in a barter economy in which every item is valued in terms of the other products offered—12 eggs are worth 1 shirt, 1 shirt equals 3 gallons of gas, and so forth. A 10-product economy of this sort, assigning every product a value for every other product, would require 45 different prices. A 100-good economy would require 4,950 prices.1 This is another reason why only the most primitive economies use barter. Once again, money is able to solve a problem inherent to the barter economy. It reduces the number of prices consumers need to know to the number of products on the market; a 100-good economy will have 100 prices. Thus, money is a unit of account, or a measure of value. Dollar prices give us a yardstick for measuring and comparing the values of a wide variety of goods and services. unit of account Money provides a yardstick for measuring and comparing the values of a wide variety of goods and services. It eliminates the problem of double coincidence of wants associated with barter.
Admittedly, ascribing a dollar value to some things, such as human life, love, and clean air, can be difficult. Still, courts, businesses, and government agencies manage to do so every day. For example, if someone dies and the court determines this death was due to negligence, the court tries to determine the value of the life to the person’s survivors —not a pleasant task, but one that has to be undertaken. Without a monetary standard, such valuations would be not just difficult, but impossible.
Store of Value
Using cherry tomatoes as a medium of exchange and unit of account might be handy, except that they have the bad habit of rotting. Money lasts, enabling people to save the money they earn today and use it to buy the goods and services they want tomorrow. Thus, money is a store of value. It is true that money is not unique in preserving its value. Many other commodities, including stocks, bonds, real estate, art, and jewelry, are used to store wealth for future purchases. Indeed, some of these assets may rise in value, and therefore might be preferred to money as a store of value. Why, then, use money as a store of wealth at all? store of value The function that enables people to save the money they earn today and use it to buy the goods and services they want tomorrow.
The answer is that every other type of asset must be converted into money if it is to be spent or used to pay debts. Converting other assets into cash involves transaction costs, and for some assets, these costs are significant. An asset’s liquidity is determined by how fast, easily, and reliably it can be converted into cash. liquidity How quickly, easily, and reliably an asset can be converted into cash.
Money is the most liquid asset because, as the medium of exchange, it requires no conversion. Stocks and bonds are also liquid, but they do require some time and often a commission fee to convert into cash. Prices in stock and bond markets fluctuate, causing the real value of these assets to be uncertain. Real estate requires considerable time to liquidate, with transaction costs that often approach 10% of a property’s value. Money differs from many other commodities in that its value does not deteriorate in the absence of inflation. When price levels do rise, however, the value of money falls: If prices double, the value of money is cut in half. In times of inflation, most people are unwilling to hold much of their wealth in money. If hyperinflation hits, money will quickly become worthless as the economy reverts to barter. Money, then, is crucial for a well-functioning modern economy. All of its three primary functions are important: medium of exchange, unit of account, and store of value.
468
The United States has introduced $1 coins many times throughout its history, and in recent decades has included the Susan B. Anthony dollar, Sacagawea dollar, and the presidential dollar. Yet, the use of dollar coins as a medium of exchange never caught on, with the majority of dollar coins ending up in coin collections rather than in cash registers.
Defining the Money Supply
How much money is there in the U.S. economy? One of the tasks assigned to the Federal Reserve System (the Fed), the central bank of the United States, is that of measuring our money supply. The Fed has developed several different measures of monetary aggregates, which it continually updates to reflect the innovative new financial instruments our financial system is constantly developing. The monetary aggregates the Fed uses most frequently are M1, the narrowest measure of money, and M2, a broader measure. An even broader measure called M3 was published until 2006 when the Fed decided the additional benefit of this measure was not worth the costs of collecting the data.
Using Plastic Money (Literally) in Australia How did a commemorative 1988 Australian $10 banknote made of plastic turn into a trend adopted by over 40 countries?
T
ake out a few U.S. banknotes of different denominations and notice their characteristics—they are all the same size and are made from the same cotton-and-linen-material used for over a century. Compared to banknotes in many other countries, old U.S. banknotes appear bland and worn out, and are sometimes counterfeited using advanced scanners to make realistic copies. To minimize counterfeiting, new U.S. banknotes contain more security features such as a watermark and color-shifting ink. And since 2008, new banknotes (other than the $1 bill) contain colors different from the old green and black. Still, other countries have transformed their banknotes in more dramatic ways. One such transformation was introduced in Australia in 1988—money made literally of plastic. How did the introduction of plastic (polymer-based) banknotes transform the way many countries produce their banknotes?
469
When Australia celebrated the 200th anniversary in 1988 of the first arrival of Europeans, the Australian Treasury introduced a commemorative $10 banknote made of plastic. The plastic banknote was colorful, was difficult to rip or tear, stayed crisp even after many uses, and most importantly, was nearly impossible to counterfeit. Because of the popularity of the new design and the subsequent reduction in counterfeiting, Australia changed all of its banknote denominations to polymer-based materials, becoming the first country to do so but certainly not the last. Today, over forty countries (including Mexico) use polymer banknotes for at least their most used denomination, while at least ten countries (including Canada) have adopted polymer banknotes for all denominations. Although polymer banknotes cost about twice as much to make as cotton-paper banknotes, they last over twice as long and dramatically reduce counterfeiting. Moreover, the rising cost of cotton in recent years has reduced the difference in cost of producing polymer banknotes. Are Americans too wed to the paper greenback to accept polymer banknotes? Americans have mostly rejected other ideas, including attempts to eliminate the penny and to replace the $1 bill with a $1 coin. Such aversion to currency changes is ironic, considering that fewer than 25% of U.S. consumer transactions are conducted in cash and over half of Americans do not regularly carry cash at all. In fact, cash may disappear altogether in the future, which might ultimately make this debate obsolete.
GO TO
TO PRACTICE THE ECONOMIC CONCEPTS IN THIS STORY
More specifically, the Fed defines M1 and M2 as follows: M1 equals:2 ▪ Currency (banknotes and coins) + Demand deposits + Other checkable deposits M2 equals: ▪ M1 + Savings deposits + Money market deposit accounts + Small-denomination (less than $100,000) time deposits + Shares in retail money market mutual funds M1 The narrowest definition of money that measures highly liquid instruments including currency (banknotes and coins), demand deposits (checks), and other accounts that have check-writing or debit capabilities. M2 A broader definition of money that includes “near monies” that are not as liquid as cash, including deposits in savings accounts, money market accounts, and money market mutual fund accounts.
Narrowly Defined Money: M1 470
Because money is used mainly as a medium of exchange, when defined most narrowly, it includes currency (banknotes and coins), demand deposits (checking accounts), and other accounts that have check-writing capabilities. Currency represents slightly less than half of M1, with banknotes constituting more than 90% of currency; coins form only a small part of M1. Checking accounts represent the other half of the money supply, narrowly defined. In 2016, M1 was about $3.2 trillion. It is the most liquid part of the money supply. Checking accounts can be opened at commercial banks and at a variety of other financial institutions, including credit unions, mutual savings banks, and savings and loan associations. Also, many stock brokerage firms offer checking services on brokerage accounts.
A Broader Definition: M2
A broader definition of money, M2, includes the “near monies”: money that cannot be drawn on instantaneously but that is nonetheless accessible. This includes deposits in savings accounts, money market deposit accounts, and money market mutual fund accounts. Many of these accounts have check-writing features similar to demand deposits. Certificates of deposit (CDs) and other small-denomination time deposits can usually be cashed in at any time, although they often carry penalties for early liquidation. Thus, M2 includes the highly liquid assets in M1 and a variety of accounts that are less liquid, but still easy and inexpensive to access. This broader definition of money increased the money supply in 2016 to about $12.6 trillion. When economists speak of “the money supply,” they are usually referring to M1, the narrowest definition. Even so, the other measures are sometimes used. The index of leading economic indicators, for instance, uses M2, adjusted for inflation, to gauge the state of the economy. Economists sometimes disagree on which is the better measure of the money supply; although M1 and M2 tend to have similar trends, they have deviated significantly in certain periods. For the remainder of this book, the money supply will be considered to be M1 unless otherwise specified. The monetary components that make up the money supply serve many purposes. But at its essence, it channels funds from savers to borrowers, an important function of the financial system that barter societies are unable to do. In the next section, we look at a simple model of loanable funds to show how savers and borrowers come together to make moneylending possible and contribute to economic growth.
CHECKPOINT WHAT IS MONEY? Money is anything accepted in exchange for goods and services and for the payment of debts. The functions of money include: a medium of exchange, a unit of account, and a store of value. Liquidity refers to how fast, easily, and reliably an asset can be converted into cash. M1 is currency plus demand deposits plus other checkable deposits. M2 is equal to M1 plus savings deposits plus other savings-like deposits.
QUESTION: The U.S. penny, with Abraham Lincoln’s image on the front, has been in circulation since
1909. Back then, pennies were inexpensive to produce and could be used to purchase real items. Today, a U.S. penny actually costs the government more than 1 cent to produce, and it is virtually unusable in any coin-operated machine and impractical to use in stores. How has the role of the penny changed over the past century in terms of its monetary functions (medium of exchange, unit of account, and store of value)? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
471
THE MARKET FOR LOANABLE FUNDS The market for loanable funds is a model that describes the financial market for saving and investment. Initially, we will assume that savers deal directly with investors. This simplifies our analysis. We then will bring in financial intermediaries (banks, mutual funds, and other financial institutions) to describe the benefits of a well-functioning financial system.
Supply and Demand for Loanable Funds
Why do people save? Why do they borrow? The first thought might be that people save because they can save. Unlike barter economies, money makes saving possible. People supply funds to the loanable funds market because they do not spend all of their income; they save. There are many reasons why individuals save. People save “for a rainy day”: They put away some of their income when times are good to take care of them when times turn bad. Saving behavior is also a cultural phenomenon: Many countries, such as China, India, and France, have savings rates far higher than those in the United States. The reward for not spending today is the interest received on savings, enabling people to spend more in the future. Therefore, in the market for loanable funds shown in Figure 1, the quantity of loanable funds is measured on the horizontal axis, and the price of the funds (interest rate) is measured on the vertical axis. In this market, the supply curve represents savers, while the demand curve represents borrowers. The supply of funds to the loanable funds market, shown as S0, is positively related to the interest rate. Because interest rates are the price (reward) that savers receive, higher interest rates result in more saving (funds) supplied to the market. This results in an upward-sloping supply curve much like other supply curves we studied earlier, and is just another example of people reacting to incentives. The demand for loanable funds comes from people who want to purchase goods and services, such as taking out a loan to go to college, taking out a mortgage on a house, or who, as entrepreneurs, want to start or expand a business. Firms are borrowers, too. Firms may want to invest in new plants, additional equipment, expanded warehouse facilities, or engage in additional research and development on new products. The specific investment depends on the industry. For firms in the oil industry, it might be for an offshore oil platform or refinery. For a start-up network firm that has a growing number of subscribers but limited financial capital, the loanable funds might be used for another server farm. Building a new server farm requires a substantial amount of cash, often obtained by borrowing in the loanable funds market.
472
The demand for loanable funds, shown as D0 in Figure 1, slopes downward because when the interest rate is high, fewer projects will have a rate of return high enough to justify the investment. A project will be undertaken only if its expected return (its benefit) is higher than the cost of funding the project. When oil prices fall, for example, an oil platform will not generate enough revenues to justify paying a high interest rate. As interest rates fall, more projects become profitable and the amount of funds demanded rises. FIGURE 1
THE MARKET FOR LOANABLE FUNDS
This market represents supply and demand for loanable funds. Savers spend less than they earn and supply the excess funds to the market. Borrowers (primarily businesses) have potential profit-making investment opportunities, and this leads to their demand for funds. Equilibrium is at point e.
Keep in mind that when we refer to interest rates, we are referring to real interest rates (adjusted for inflation) that reflect the real cost of borrowing and the real return to savers. The loanable funds market reaches equilibrium in Figure 1 at a 3% real interest rate and $300 billion in funds traded in the market. If for some reason the real interest rate exceeded 3%, savers would provide more funds to the market than investors want and interest rates would fall until the market reached point e. In a similar way, if interest rates were somehow below 3%, investors would want more funds than savers would be willing to provide. In this case, the market would push up interest rates to 3% at point e. Not surprisingly, this market is similar to the competitive markets for other goods and services. When compared to most markets, financial markets are typically more competitive and often reach equilibrium more quickly if something changes in the market. Let’s now use this model to analyze various impacts (private and public) on the market for loanable funds. Just as in other markets, the market for loanable funds is subject to factors that shift the supply or demand for loanable funds. When this occurs, interest rates and the level of saving and investment also change.
Shifts in the Supply of Loanable Funds
A shift in the supply curve of loanable funds occurs when a factor increases or decreases the country’s willingness to
473
save (either by private individuals or the public government) at any given interest rate. Changes in economic outlook, incentives to save, income or asset prices, and government deficits can influence savings patterns.
Economic Outlook
Suppose households decide to save a larger proportion of their income because they fear job loss in a recession. If households decide to save more, the amount of funds provided to the market at all interest rates will increase, shifting the supply of loanable funds from S0 to S1 in Figure 2. Equilibrium will move from point e to point a, real interest rates will fall, and both saving and investment will rise from $300 billion to $400 billion. Similarly, if a recession ends and people go on a buying spree, savings will fall. In Figure 2, this would be a shift in the supply curve from S1 to S0.
Incentives to Save
Governments and companies offer various incentives to individuals to save, such as retirement contribution plans and other tax incentives. Adjusting such incentives will change the level of savings accordingly. FIGURE 2
CHANGES IN SUPPLY, DEMAND, AND INTEREST RATES
If savers decide to save more, the supply of funds will grow to S1. At the new equilibrium, point a, interest rates fall and the amount of loanable funds rises. If instead there is an increase in the rate of return on investment (due to investment tax credits or increased demand for the firm’s product), demand for funds will increase to D1. At the new equilibrium, point b, interest rates and loanable funds rise.
Income or Asset Prices
As incomes rise, people generally save a larger proportion of their income, all else equal. Asset prices, however, tend to work the other way. As home prices and stock values increase, people feel wealthier (without necessarily having more income) and will spend more and save less. The opposite effects occur when incomes fall or asset prices fall.
474
Government Deficits
The supply of loanable funds includes both private and public saving. When a government runs a budget surplus, additional loanable funds are provided to the market, increasing the supply of loanable funds. However, governments often incur budget deficits, which means the government becomes a borrower instead of a saver. Governments borrow money by issuing bonds, which are then purchased by individuals and investors using their savings. Therefore, when governments borrow, they do so by reducing the amount that the private sector saves, which decreases the supply of loanable funds. Subsequently, interest rates rise, which crowds out consumption and investment, an effect discussed in the previous chapter.
Shifts in the Demand for Loanable Funds We have seen how changes in savings can shift the supply of loanable funds. Now let’s turn our attention to the demand side. Anything that changes the rate of return on potential investment will cause the demand for loanable funds to change. Let’s keep saving on the initial supply curve, S0, in Figure 2.
Investment Tax Incentives
Investment tax credits effectively reduce tax payments for firms building new factories or buying new equipment. These laws give firms incentives to invest by increasing their after-tax rate of return, and often are created in bad economic times with the expectation of a quick jolt to investment demand. An increase in investment demand would shift the demand for loanable funds from D0 to D1 in Figure 2 and results in both higher real interest rates (3.75%) and higher investment ($400 billion). An increase in business taxes would have the opposite effect on demand.
Technological Advances
New technologies that increase productivity or create new products give businesses an incentive to increase production, which often results in plant expansion or the need to build an additional facility, increasing the demand for loanable funds.
Regulations
Government regulations tend to influence the level of business investment. When regulations reduce corruption and instill confidence in firms and entrepreneurs, demand for investment will rise. But when regulations impose higher costs or make plant expansion difficult, the demand for investment will fall because the return on investment is reduced.
Product Demand
When demand for a firm’s product or service increases, the return on investment rises. This increases the demand for loanable funds. The opposite is true when product demand falls.
Business Expectations
When business sentiment about the economy rises, firms will tend to increase their investment demand, which increases the demand for loanable funds. When business sentiment falls, investment demand decreases and so does demand for loanable funds. In summary, the market for loanable funds works just like any other market where one can use the familiar tools of supply and demand analysis. The only slight difference is that the price is represented by the real interest rate on loanable funds. We have seen that when households decide to increase saving, real interest rates fall and investment rises. When the demand by firms for investment funds rises, real interest rates rise along with expanded investment. Together, saving and investment move toward equilibrium in the market for loanable funds.
475
CHECKPOINT THE MARKET FOR LOANABLE FUNDS Households supply loanable funds to the market because they spend less than their income and because they are rewarded with interest for saving. Firms demand funds to invest in profitable opportunities. The supply curve of funds is positively sloped; higher real interest rates bring more funds into the market. The demand for loanable funds is negatively sloped, reflecting the fact that at higher real interest rates, fewer investment projects are profitable. Any policy that provides additional incentives for households to save will increase the supply of loanable funds, resulting in lower interest rates and greater investment. Anything that increases the potential profitability (rate of return) of business investments will increase the demand for loanable funds, resulting in higher interest rates and investment.
QUESTIONS: A major downturn in an economy can bring about many consequences, including a
reduction in business confidence in which firms become reluctant to invest, and an increased fear of job loss among workers. How do these two events affect the supply of savings and the demand for borrowing? What happens to the supply and demand curves found in Figure 2? Once the economy recovers, what is supposed to happen to these curves? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
476
THE FINANCIAL SYSTEM The previous section discussed how savers and borrowers interact in a market such that those who demand money for various reasons are able to turn to those who have extra money to save. The interest rate is what keeps this market in equilibrium between savers and borrowers. But how does one actually go about saving or borrowing money? Suppose you have an extra $1,000 that you want to save for the future, and a buddy from your old high school asks you to invest in a new skateboard shop he plans to open on campus. Do you lend your money to him? That should depend on a number of factors. First, will your friend be paying you interest or a share of his profits? Second, how risky would such an investment be? Is your friend borrowing from you because he can’t qualify for a small business loan elsewhere? Third, when will you expect to get your money back? Next year, or just whenever the business makes enough profit to pay you back? Or perhaps never if the shop goes bust. These are important questions to evaluate before making financial decisions about your money. Often, the time it takes to evaluate proposals such as lending money to your buddy and to everyone else you know looking to borrow money can be significant and costly. For this reason, many individuals instead choose to save by putting money into banks, bonds, and stocks, which together represent the financial system. Should you invest your money here?
The Bridge Between Savers and Borrowers
The financial system is a complex set of institutions that, in the broadest sense, allocates scarce resources (financial capital) from savers, those who are spending less than they earn, to borrowers, those who want to use these resources to invest in potentially profitable projects. Both savers and borrowers can include households, firms, and governments, but our focus is on households as savers and firms as borrowers. As we have seen, savers expect to earn interest on their savings and borrowers expect to pay interest on what they borrow. Households may save for a down payment on a house or a new car, and firms borrow to invest in new plants, equipment, or research and development. financial system A complex set of institutions, including banks, bond markets, and stock markets, that allocate scarce resources (financial capital) from savers to borrowers.
477
Financial institutions or financial intermediaries are the bridge between savers and borrowers. They include, among others, commercial banks, savings and loan associations, credit unions, insurance companies, securities firms (brokerages), and pension funds. The complexity of a country’s financial institutions often is a sign of economic efficiency and growth, as these financial firms take savings from savers and loan them to borrowers. financial intermediaries Financial firms (banks, mutual funds, insurance companies, etc.) that acquire funds from savers and then lend these funds to borrowers (consumers, firms, and governments).
The Roles of Financial Institutions Financial institutions fulfill three important roles that facilitate the flow of funds to the economy. They (1) reduce information costs, (2) reduce transaction costs, and (3) spread risk by diversifying assets.
Reducing Information Costs
Information costs are the expenses associated with gathering information on individual borrowers and evaluating their creditworthiness. Savers (in this case, lenders) would have a difficult time without financial institutions. For example, when deciding whether to lend your buddy money to open his skateboard shop, you might know plenty about your friend’s personality and habits, but have few ways to determine if his shop was safe to lend to or was unsound, or even just a fraud. Financial institutions reduce information costs by screening, evaluating, and monitoring firms to see that they are creditworthy and use the borrowed funds loaned in a prudent manner.
Reducing Transaction Costs
Transaction costs are those associated with finding, selecting, and negotiating contracts between individual savers and borrowers. Suppose your buddy needs much more than $1,000, and asks all of his friends to lend him money. Trying to set up contracts individually between many lenders and a borrower can be time-consuming and costly, especially if every lender wants to make sure the business is a sound investment. Financial institutions reduce transaction costs by providing standardized financial products, including savings accounts, stocks, bonds, annuities, mortgages, futures, and options. In your case, you and your friends might put your money into a savings account, while your buddy applies for a loan at that bank.
Diversifying Assets to Reduce Risk
Firms need funds for long-term investments, but savers want access to their money at a moment’s notice and would want their funds invested in a number of diversified projects to reduce risk. In other words, you might not want to put your entire savings into one risky loan. Financial institutions accept funds from savers and pool this money into a portfolio of diversified financial instruments (stocks, bonds, etc.), reducing overall risk and at the same time permitting savers access to their funds when needed. In addition, they can also offer securities with different risk profiles to savers, from relatively safe CDs and savings accounts to more risky domestic and foreign stocks. In so doing, these institutions allow a greater flow of funds between savers and borrowers, greatly increasing the efficiency of investment in the economy. The role of financial institutions in channeling funds from savers to investors is essential, because the people who save are often not the same people with profitable investment opportunities. Without financial institutions, investment would be a pale version of what we see today, and the economy would be a fraction of its size.
Types of Financial Assets
Savers have many options when it comes to where to put their money. The primary difference among the many types of financial assets available is the return on investment (ROI) one can achieve. A return on investment can be determined by the interest rate earned on savings accounts or CDs, or the capital gains, dividends, and other interest earned from investing in stocks or bonds. The ROI of an asset largely depends on the risk of the asset, with lower risk assets generally earning a lower ROI and higher risk assets earning a higher ROI.
478
return on investment The earnings, such as interest or capital gains, that a saver receives for making funds available to others. It is calculated as earnings divided by the amount invested.
The simplest way to save is to deposit money into a checking or savings account at your local bank. This is also the lowest risk approach to saving, because all savings up to $250,000 per account are insured by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) as long as the bank is a member. In its 85-year history, no saver’s deposit insured with the FDIC has ever been lost, even when a bank has gone bankrupt. The advantages of placing savings in banks are clear—savers have easy access to their money (high liquidity) in addition to virtually no risk. The disadvantage is that savings and checking accounts pay very low interest, and in some cases no interest at all. Thus, in order to increase earnings on savings, savers must either (1) choose financial assets with lower liquidity, or (2) choose assets that carry a higher level of risk. One way to achieve this is to invest in bonds and stocks, to which we now turn our attention. Savers can invest their funds directly in businesses by purchasing a bond or shares of stock from a firm using one of many brokerage firms easily accessible by ordinary individuals. Savers can also invest indirectly by providing funds to a financial institution (such as a bank or mutual fund) that channels those funds to borrowers. A share of stock represents partial ownership of a corporation, and its value is determined by the earning capacity of the firm. A bond, on the other hand, represents debt of the corporation. Bonds are typically sold in $1,000 denominations and pay a fixed amount of interest. If you own a bond, you are a creditor of the firm.
Bond Prices and Interest Rates We examined real interest rates when we described the loanable funds market, and we described several direct and indirect financial instruments such as stocks, savings accounts, and bonds. But most of the loanable funds are in the form of corporate or government bonds. In 2016, the total value of loans made by U.S. commercial banks was almost $9 trillion, the total value of the U.S. bond market was about $41 trillion, and the total value of stocks traded in U.S. stock exchanges was about $25 trillion. Because of the sheer size of the U.S. bond market, economists frequently look at financial markets from the viewpoint of the supply and demand for bonds. They often consider policy implications by their impact on the price of bonds and the quantity traded. It can be a little confusing because bond prices and interest rates are inversely related—when interest rates go up, bond prices go down, and vice versa. Let’s take a quick look at the characteristics of bonds to help you see why interest rates and bond prices move in opposite directions. Understanding this will give you a better understanding of how monetary policy actually works. To see why bond prices and interest rates are inversely related, we need to analyze bond contracts more closely. A bond is a contract between a seller (the company or government issuing the bond) and a buyer that determines the following: Coupon rate of the bond Maturity date of the bond Face value of the bond The seller agrees to pay the buyer a fixed rate of interest (the coupon rate) on the face value of the bond (usually $1,000 for a corporate bond, but often much larger values for government bonds) until a future fixed date (the maturity date of the bond). For example, if XYZ Company issues a bond with a face value of $1,000 at a coupon rate of 5%, it agrees to pay the bondholder $50 per year until the maturity date of the bond. Note that this $50 payment per year is fixed for the life of the bond. Once a bond is issued, it is subject to the forces of the marketplace. As economic circumstances change, people may be willing to pay more or less for a bond that originally sold for $1,000. The yield on a bond is the percentage return earned over the life of the bond. Yields change when bond prices change. Assume, for instance, that when a $1,000 bond is issued, general interest rates are 5% so that the bond yields an annual interest payment of $50. For simplicity, let’s assume that the bond is a perpetuity bond—that is, the bond has no maturity date. The issuer of the bond has agreed to pay $50 a year forever for the use of this money. Assume that market interest rates rise to 8%. Just how much would the typical investor now be willing to pay for
479
this bond that returns $50 a year? We can approach this intuitively. If we can buy a $1,000 bond now that pays $80 per year, why would we pay $1,000 for a similar bond that pays only $50? Would we pay more or less for the bond that pays $50? If we can get a bond that pays $80 for $1,000, we would pay less for a bond paying $50. There is a simple formula we can use for perpetuity bonds:
Yield =
Interest Payment Price of Bond
Or rearranging terms:
Price of Bond =
Interest Payment Yield
The new price of the bond will be $625 ($50 ÷ 0.08 = $625). Clearly, as market interest rates went up, the price of this bond fell. Conversely, if market interest rates were to fall, say, from 5% to 3%, the price of the bond would rise to $1,666.67 ($50 ÷ 0.03 = $1,666.67). Keep this relationship between interest rates and bond prices in mind when we focus on the tools of monetary policy in the next couple of chapters, for this approach to bond pricing is important to understanding how the government manages the money supply through the purchase and sale of bonds.
Stocks and Investment Returns
An alternative to placing savings into banks or bonds is to purchase shares of stock (also known as equity) in a company. When one buys a share of stock, this share represents one fraction (of the total shares issued) of ownership in the company, and subsequently one vote at shareholder meetings and one share of any dividends (periodic payments to shareholders). The buying and selling of stock shares occur in stock exchanges (such as the New York Stock Exchange or NASDAQ). The price of a share of stock is determined by supply and demand just as in any other market, and for every buyer of a share of stock there must be a seller. Compared to bonds, stocks tend to be riskier investments, because shares, representing partial ownership as opposed to a creditor of a company, become worthless when a company goes bankrupt. Bonds are generally considered safer investments because bondholders are the first to be repaid when businesses face financial trouble. However, stockholders get to share in the company’s profits through dividend payments and the increase in share values, which can be substantial when a company succeeds. Both bonds and stocks are less liquid than savings and checking accounts, as both require the asset to be sold and a small commission paid in order to convert the asset into cash. Which pays more over the long run, bonds or stocks? Given their higher risk, stocks tend to reward investors with a higher average return on investment over the long run, which follows the general rule of the tradeoff between risk and return. Riskier assets typically offer a greater return; otherwise, investors would not choose to take such risks. With the exception of a few periods during which the stock market dropped considerably (such as the crash in technology stocks from 2000 to 2001 and the stock market crash from late 2007 to early 2009 when many companies went bankrupt or nearly bankrupt), stocks generally trend upward, providing an average return on investment higher than what can be earned through less risky bonds and the least risky savings accounts and CDs, which are FDIC insured. tradeoff between risk and return The pattern of higher risk assets offering higher average annual returns on investment than lower risk assets.
The complexity of the financial system offers savers and borrowers many opportunities to conduct economic transactions quickly and efficiently. But because the financial system also can be subject to corruption, financial institutions are heavily regulated to ensure the soundness and safety of the financial system and to increase the transparency and information to investors. The agencies regulating financial markets include the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), the Federal Reserve System, the FDIC, and another half-dozen or so federal agencies, along with all the state agencies regulating firms in this market. Although heavily regulated, financial markets are complex environments that are occasionally subjected to
480
meltdowns that can lead the economy into a recession and result in huge losses for the affected firms. When meltdowns occur, the bridge that financial intermediaries bring between savers and lenders can collapse.
CHECKPOINT THE FINANCIAL SYSTEM Financial institutions are financial intermediaries that build a bridge between savers and borrowers. Financial institutions reduce information costs, transaction costs, and risk, making financial markets more efficient. Efficient financial markets foster growth because they maximize the amount of funds channeled from savers to borrowers. Financial assets include savings and checking accounts, certificates of deposit (CDs), bonds, stocks, and mutual funds. Bond prices and interest rates are inversely related.
QUESTION: In 2008 voters in California approved the construction of a high-speed rail system connecting Anaheim (near Los Angeles) and San Francisco by 2030, at a cost of over $65 billion. A portion of this cost will be financed by institutions such as Goldman Sachs, an investment banking and securities firm, while a larger portion will be financed by the issuance of bonds to investors and local governments, with the rest financed by private investors who will own shares in the rail system. Explain how financial intermediation is necessary in order to make this project a reality. Why couldn’t the state government just pay for it by using tax revenues it collects this year? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
481
FINANCIAL TOOLS FOR A BETTER FUTURE Now that we have discussed the role of money, the market for loanable funds, and financial intermediaries, we should step back and ask ourselves how we can apply what we have learned to our everyday finances and our future. As a caveat, it is always best to seek financial advice from a trusted professional who has your best interests in mind. This section is meant to introduce you to the basic financial concepts encountered when borrowing and saving money.
Short-Term Borrowing
As a college student, your income is low to nonexistent as you invest (very wisely) in human capital by pursuing a college degree that will increase your earning potential during your working years. That means that in the near term, you will likely accumulate debt in the form of student loans, credit card balances, and car loans. Eventually, a home mortgage might also necessitate more borrowing. Interest rates on personal debt vary considerably, with small differences leading to substantial payments over the long run, as we will see shortly. Student loans funded by the government typically offer low interest rates in addition to allowing you to defer payments until after you graduate. These loans often provide the lowest cost of borrowing to get you through until your income rises. The most common short-term loan, however, comes in the form of credit card debt. Credit card companies typically charge a higher interest rate, although on occasion may provide teaser rates—offers of low or even zero interest for a limited time on purchases and/or balance transfers. They are called teasers because credit card companies hope that you actually don’t pay off your balance at the end of the offer period. Interest rates after the offer period increase considerably, and often are higher than other borrowing rates. In addition, many credit cards charge balance transfer fees of 3% to 5% of the transferred amount, which means the 0% offer that you enjoy for a limited time is not truly 0%. teaser rates Promotional low interest rates offered by lenders for a short period of time to attract new customers and to encourage spending.
Because of the high costs of holding credit card debt, it is generally advisable to: 1. Keep credit card balances to a minimum. 2. Find lower cost borrowing opportunities (such as student loans or bank loans) to keep higher interest credit card balances lower. 3. Avoid applying for too many credit cards, because fees can rack up and credit scores can be negatively affected by excessive credit applications. 4. Never miss a minimum payment, for any amount, even for a month. Every missed payment remains on credit reports for years, potentially raising costs for future car loans and home mortgages, and even making insurance and certain jobs harder to find. Plastic surgery for your debt.
482
The Power (or Danger) of Compounding Interest Interest rates are an important factor in deciding how to go about borrowing, or saving, money. For the most part, we see interest rates as being quite low, typically less than 10%. The exceptions typically are for credit card debt or highrisk lending when the borrower has a greater likelihood of defaulting on the loan. But even for low interest rates, the effect on long-run payments can be substantial due to the compounding effect. Compounding occurs when interest is calculated and added on a periodic (often daily) basis to money borrowed or saved in addition to the interest already charged or earned. Let’s use annual terms for simplicity. Suppose you borrow $1,000 at a 10% interest rate. Table 1 shows how compounding interest can add up quickly. After a year, you incur 10% × $1,000 = $100 in interest charges. Suppose you do not make any payments on the debt. The next year, you incur 10% × $1,100 (the original debt + interest already charged) = $110 in interest. compounding effect The effect of interest added to existing debt or savings leading to substantial growth in debt or savings over the long run.
This may not seem like much. But suppose you do not make any payments on the debt for 30 years. Your original $1,000 debt will become $17,449! In fact, in year 30 alone, nearly $1,600 in interest would be added to the debt, more than the original borrowed amount. That is the danger of compounding interest on borrowed debt, and an important reason to seek low interest rates and make adequate payments. The good news, however, is that while compounding works against those with debt, it helps those who save, leading to higher future wealth.
TABLE 1
COMPOUNDING INTEREST AND DEBT
Year
Starting Value
10% Interest
Ending Value
1
$1,000.00
$100.00
$1,100.00
2
1,100.00
110.00
1,210.00
3
1,210.00
121.00
1,331.00
4
1,331.00
133.10
1,464.10
5
1,464.10
146.41
1,610.51
...
...
...
...
483
28
13,109.99
1,311.00
14,420.99
29
14,420.99
1,442.10
15,863.09
30
15,863.09
1,586.31
17,449.40
Risk Assessment and Asset Allocation
As you work and accumulate savings, an important question is how to go about putting unspent money into assets that will grow over the years until you eventually need it. The simplest and most liquid means of saving might be to keep money in cash stashed in a safe place or just letting money sit in a checking or savings account at your local bank. Although these methods give you the quickest access to your money, they are unlikely to provide much gain in value. Most checking accounts and even savings accounts pay no interest (and if they do, it’s often less than 1%). With inflation, when you eventually want to use the money, the purchasing power of that money has decreased. How does one go about choosing an asset that pays higher returns? An important consideration when choosing the type of investment is assessing your tolerance for risk. Would you be frantic if you see your savings fluctuate up and down each day? Would you instead prefer to see steady growth of your savings? Or would you be willing to accept some volatility, the fact that some investments may fall in value, in exchange for a chance of higher growth over the long term? Risk tolerance should reflect the type of investment instruments purchased. A less risky portfolio would contain a large portion of savings in assets such as CDs and high-rated bonds, and “blue chip” stocks. A more risky portfolio would contain a greater portion of savings in growth stocks and high-return bonds. As described in the previous section, a tradeoff between risk and return exists, where riskier assets typically offer a greater average return. This choice between risk and return not only affects one’s personal investments, but also affects how one goes about saving for the future and for retirement, which we discuss next.
Saving for the Future: Employer-Based Programs Upon graduating from college, among the exciting challenges facing the new graduate is seeking a good job and earning a salary that, hopefully, allows for a more comfortable life. But besides earning more money, decisions must be made about how to save for the future. Suppose you find your dream job and begin work. Besides the Social Security (FICA) tax that is taken out of each paycheck to fund retirement benefits, you are asked whether you want to contribute to your employer’s retirement program. Do you contribute, and if so, how much? 3%? 6%? More? And once you contribute to an account, in what type of assets do you invest that money? Safe or risky assets, or some combination? The tradeoff between risk and return becomes a very important factor in these decisions. Let’s begin by looking at employer-based savings programs, the most common being the 401(k) (offered by most privately held and publicly traded companies), though similar programs exist for government employees and taxexempt organizations [such as 403(b)], and for teachers (such as TIAA-CREF).
To Contribute or Not to Contribute?
Most retirement savings programs allow (or in some cases, require) employees to contribute a certain percentage of their wage earnings into a retirement account. Many companies will then offer a full or partial match of the contribution up to 3% to 4% of one’s salary. If your employer offers to match savings contributions, this is essentially “free money” that gets added to your savings, dramatically increasing your return as long as you satisfy the vesting period, the minimum years of employment required for the employer-paid portion to become permanent in the account, even if you leave the company.
484
vesting period The minimum number of years a worker must be employed before the company’s contribution to a retirement account becomes permanent.
Suppose you contribute $1,000 into the savings program, and your employer matches it with another $1,000. You will have instantly earned a 100% return on your investment as long as the vesting period has been satisfied. Try finding another financial asset that offers this high a return! Another benefit of 401(k) (or similar) programs is that contributions are tax-deferred, meaning that an employee does not pay income tax on the contributed amount until the money is eventually withdrawn. Why does this matter? Suppose you earn $75,000 in taxable income. This means you are in the 25% tax bracket for most income earned. Suppose you increase your 401(k) contribution by $1,000. How much does your take-home pay fall? Because you normally would pay 25% in income tax on the $1,000, your take-home pay would fall by only $1,000(1 − 0.25) = $750. Essentially, you give up $750 now to add an additional $1,000 into your retirement account. That is $250 (33%) in extra savings right from the start, on top of the investment earnings on that additional amount over your life until the money is eventually withdrawn. A downside of most retirement plans is the restriction on when you can use the savings. The minimum age for withdrawing money from most 401(k) accounts is 59.5 years. Withdrawing money before this age incurs (with few exceptions) a 10% early withdrawal penalty.
In What Assets Should One Invest?
Suppose you have decided to contribute to your employer’s retirement plan and to take advantage of the employer match and tax benefits. Now you are given online access to your account, where you see many options on where to invest your money. As with all investments, risk assessment is an important consideration when it comes to managing retirement accounts. Most accounts allow you to choose a portfolio of investments ranging from safe assets (such as Treasury bills) to risky assets (such as high-growth stocks). Many financial advisors suggest that you choose a higher risk portfolio in your younger years, then gradually reduce your risk as you approach retirement. Why? Let’s use the 2007–2009 stock market crash as an example. Between October 2007 and March 2009, major stock market indexes fell by nearly 50%. Retirement accounts that were invested fully in stocks fell drastically in value. This had devastating effects on older workers who had not transitioned to safer assets as they approached retirement. However, for younger workers, stock market drops tend to have minimal effects in the long run. In fact, temporary dips in the stock market can even improve outcomes over time, as the Issue in this section describes.
Other Retirement Savings Tools: Social Security, Pensions, and IRAs Besides employer-sponsored retirement contribution funds, other programs exist that allow individuals to save for their future. These include Social Security, employer-based pension programs, and individual retirement arrangement (IRA, also known as individual retirement account) programs.
Social Security
Social Security is another form of retirement savings that nearly every American participates in from the time they start working as a teenager. The payroll tax (FICA) is 12.4% (of which 6.2% is paid by employees and 6.2% is paid by employers) of wage earnings up to a maximum of $118,500 in 2016. Unlike 401(k) contributions, the money you contribute to FICA is not yours, but rather is used to pay the benefits of those currently collecting Social Security benefits. Benefits are determined by a formula based on one’s lifetime contributions. The minimum age to begin collecting Social Security is 62, though if you wait until age 67, monthly benefits will be greater, and potentially will pay more overall if you live longer. Of course, if you have a family history of shorter lifespans, it might be a good idea to start collecting sooner. Some have argued that Social Security is unfair to the poor, who generally have lower life expectancies than the rich. If the minimum age for collecting Social Security rises due to a shortfall of funds, those with lower life
485
expectancies might not collect anything (except for a portion that can be bequeathed to a spouse or heir).
Pension Plans
Pensions are an alternative to 401(k)-type accounts. Pensions are monthly payments made by your employer from the day you retire until you die, based on the number of years you worked at the company. For example, a person who worked at a company 30 years might receive a pension of $3,000 per month upon retirement for the rest of his or her life, while someone who worked only 10 years might receive $1,000 per month. pensions A retirement program into which an employer pays a monthly amount to retired employees until they die.
ISSUE Can a Stock Market Crash Increase Long-Term Savings? From October 2007 to March 2009, major U.S. stock market indices (Dow, NASDAQ, and S&P 500) fell by more than 50% from their peaks. Investment savings accounts that took decades to accumulate saw their values drop in half in less than 17 months. The same was true for many retirement accounts, such as 401(k) and IRA accounts, which often are heavily invested in stocks. Indeed, this was a bleak period to follow one’s retirement savings, not to mention the equally devastating loss in housing values during this period. Would the drop in stock values create long-term consequences for retirement? The answer may be surprising. Although money invested up to October 2007 suffered a severe decline in value, most workers who continued to contribute to their retirement plans (and with matching employer additions to the new funds), saw their retirement portfolio values bounce back within a few years. How did this happen? As new money entered retirement plans during the stock market decline, these funds were invested in assets at their new lower prices. When stock values recovered, old funds regained their values, while new funds saw healthy gains in value. The following example illustrates two scenarios using hypothetical numbers. This hypothetical scenario shows that a drop in the stock market may not cause a major problem for retirement savings over the long run as long as one continues to work and contribute toward retirement. And the younger the worker, the less of an impact short-term stock market corrections will have, because a smaller balance would be affected by the market drop, while new funds invested at lower prices can earn substantial gains (assuming no withdrawals or loans are made from the account). Unfortunately, some people dumped stocks after they fell, and became conservative with new money. The moral of the story: Don’t panic. Slow and steady wins the race.
486
Because pension benefits are difficult for companies to predict as people live longer, employers are increasingly switching to fixed-contribution plans such as a 401(k), where employer contributions are made up-front. But a few notable jobs retain comfortable pensions: The president of the United States receives a pension of over $200,000 every year after leaving office. Finally, in addition to personal savings, investments, 401(k) and pensions plans, many individuals choose to save using individual retirement arrangements (IRAs).
487
Individual Retirement Arrangements (IRAs)
Similar to 401(k) programs, traditional IRA programs allow one to save pretax (tax-deferred) dollars up to a certain limit, which, as discussed earlier, gives an immediate boost to savings compared to posttax dollars. Traditional IRA accounts allow one to invest in a broad range of stocks, bonds, and other assets. The minimum age to withdraw funds without penalty is 59.5 years, and taxes are paid on money withdrawn. (Note that most retirees are in lower tax brackets compared to their tax bracket during their working years.) An alternative to a traditional IRA is a Roth IRA, which allows posttax dollars to be contributed up to a certain limit each year. Why would one contribute posttax dollars as opposed to pretax dollars? First, with a Roth IRA, money that you contribute (but not the earnings on contributions except in certain circumstances) can be withdrawn anytime without penalty. Second, Roth IRAs do not incur any taxes upon withdrawal after age 59.5, including the interest and capital gains the account accumulates over its life. Thus, while one pays taxes upfront on initial contributions, no taxes are paid on earnings, which can be very substantial with compounding. Saving for the future is an important financial decision. Fortunately, many programs such as 401(k), Social Security, and IRAs make the process easier.
CHECKPOINT FINANCIAL TOOLS FOR A BETTER FUTURE Credit cards typically are an expensive way to finance borrowing, even with teaser rates. Debt and savings rise rapidly over the long run due to the compounding effect. A tradeoff exists between risk and return: The greater the risk, the higher the average return on investment. Company-sponsored retirement accounts such as a 401(k) allow employees to contribute pretax dollars and receive matching company contributions. Social Security is a program into which current contributors (workers) pay for benefits of the recipients (retirees) by way of a payroll tax on wages. Individual retirement arrangements (IRA) are similar to 401(k) programs except that they are not company sponsored and they provide greater investment choices.
QUESTIONS: Suppose Nicole is very risk averse with her money, while Jose likes to invest in riskier assets in hopes of a higher return. What type of assets would be best suited for each person? Supposing the tradeoff between risk and return holds true over the next 30 years, how would Nicole’s savings compare to Jose’s given the compounding effect (assuming each saves the same amount)? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
488
chapter summary Section 1 What Is Money? Money is anything that is accepted in exchange for goods and services or for the payments of debts.
11.1
Three Primary Functions of Money 1. Medium of exchange: Eliminates the double coincidence of wants common to barter. 2. Unit of account: Reduces the number of prices needed to just one per good. 3. Store of value: Allows people to save now and spend later.
11.2
Two Primary Money Supply Measures M1 = currency (banknotes and coins) and demand deposits (checking accounts). M2 = M1 + “near monies” (savings accounts, money market deposit accounts, smalldenomination time deposits, and money market mutual fund accounts).
An asset’s liquidity is determined by how fast, easily, and reliably it can be converted into cash.
489
Section 2 The Market for Loanable Funds 11.3
The market for loanable funds describes the financial market for saving and investment. Savers provide more funds to the loanable funds market as interest rates increase. Firms demand more funds for investment opportunities as interest rates fall.
490
11.4
Factors affecting the willingness to save or borrow lead to a change in the market for loanable funds. For example, growing business confidence increases firms’ willingness to invest, thus shifting the demand for loanable funds to the right, causing interest rates to rise.
Section 3 The Financial System
491
Banks, savings and loans associations, credit unions, insurance companies, securities firms (brokerages), and pension funds are all types of financial intermediaries that take savings from savers and loan the funds to borrowers.
11.5
Financial intermediaries accept funds from savers and efficiently channel these to borrowers, reducing transaction and information costs, as well as lowering risk. A bond is a contract between a seller (government or company) and a buyer. As a general rule, as market interest rates rise, the value of bonds (paying fixed dollars of interest) fall, and vice versa.
11.6
How to Calculate the Price of a Perpetuity Bond Price of Bond = Annual Interest Payment ÷ Yield (%) Example: If a bond pays $100 per year, and the yield is 6%, the price of the bond is $100 ÷ 0.06 = $1,667.
Section 4 Financial Tools for a Better Future 11.7
The compounding effect is powerful because it causes debt (if no payments are made) and savings to increase dramatically over time.
11.8
Tradeoff Between Risk and Return: The greater the risk involved, the higher the average annual return on investment.
492
U.S. Savings Bonds and Treasury securities are among the safest assets in the world. Because of their low risk, the interest rates paid also are very low.
11.9
Programs for Retirement Savings Employer-sponsored programs Fixed contribution plans, such as 401(k), 403(b), and TIAA-CREF, allow workers to contribute pretax dollars and employers to partially match contributions. Pensions are monthly payments made by employers to their retired employees based on length of employment with the company.
Government-sponsored programs Social Security: Current workers pay benefits of retirees through the payroll tax on wages.
Other retirement programs Traditional IRAs use pretax dollars to fund investments; taxes are paid upon withdrawal after age 59.5. Roth IRAs use after-tax dollars to fund investments. Contributed funds (but not earnings on those contributions) can be withdrawn anytime without penalty, and no taxes are paid on withdrawals (including earnings on investment) after one reaches the age of 59.5.
KEY CONCEPTS money fiat money barter medium of exchange unit of account store of value liquidity M1 M2 financial system
493
financial intermediaries return on investment tradeoff between risk and return teaser rates compounding eff ect vesting period pensions
QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS Check Your Understanding 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6.
Describe the three functions of money. What is a barter economy? Describe why such an approach is a difficult way for a modern economy to exist. Explain the important difference between M1 and M2. What gives our money its value if there is no gold or silver backing the currency? What happens to savings if the real interest rate goes up? What happens to the demand for borrowing? Explain why bond prices and interest rates are inversely related.
Apply the Concepts 7. List the following assets from most liquid to least liquid: a house (real estate); cash; a one-carat diamond; a savings account; 100 shares of Google stock; a Harley-Davidson motorcycle; a checking account; your old leather jacket. 8. At many game centers (such as Chuck E. Cheese’s), it is common for kids to play carnival-type games to win prize tickets, which are then redeemed for a variety of prizes based on the number of tickets earned. In what ways do these prize tickets illustrate the three functions of money? 9. How do recessions affect the market for loanable funds? What happens to the supply of savings? What happens to the demand for borrowing? What is the effect on real interest rates? 10. Most individuals with average wealth choose to save their money using a financial intermediary such as a bank or a mutual fund. However, individuals with greater wealth are more likely to invest in individual stocks or directly in new or existing businesses. Explain why persons of different wealth are likely to show differences in how they save, and how financial intermediaries play a role. 11. Why would it be better to put $1,000 each year into a retirement account than to wait ten years and put in $10,000 all at once? Would it make much of a difference in the long run? 12. Why have pensions become a less common form of retirement benefit offered by companies?
In the News 13. A proposal in the government budget set forth in 2016 placed a limit on the total amount of savings that can be accumulated in tax-preferred retirement accounts to $3.4 million. The White House has argued that wealthy individuals have accumulated “tax-preferred retirement savings sufficient to finance an annual income of over $200,000 per year in retirement,” and that the tax deductions from these excess savings cost the government billions each year. How do these sorts of proposals affect the market for loanable funds? 14. The U.S. stock market doubled in value between 2010 and 2016. However, a slowdown in economic growth in many countries, increased volatility in stock markets, and an anticipated rise in U.S. interest rates have led some analysts to believe bonds may outperform stocks. If more investors switch from buying stock to bonds, how might this lead to a self-fulfilling prophecy? Does this argument reflect the theory of the tradeoff between risk and return?
494
Solving Problems 15. Suppose a small country has the following monies in circulation: Cash/currency: $1 million Demand deposits: $2 million Other checkable deposits: $2 million Small-denomination time deposits: $4 million Savings deposits: $5 million Money market deposit accounts: $5 million Calculate the value of M1 and M2 for this country.
WORK IT OUT 16. The yield for a perpetuity bond is determined by the simple formula Yield =
Interest Payment Priceof Bond
a. Calculate the yield on a $1,000 perpetuity bond that pays $40 a year forever to the bondholder. b. Suppose that actions taken by the Fed cause interest rates in the economy to fall by 2%. How will this affect the price of the bond that still pays $40 a year in interest? c. Now suppose that one purchases a new $1,000 perpetuity bond at the lower interest rate. What will the annual interest payment be equal to? d. If interest rates were to rise back to the original level determined in part (a), how will that affect the price of the new bond purchased in part (c)?
USING THE NUMBERS 17. According to By the Numbers, which bank had the largest amount of assets in 2015, and what was this value? How much in assets did a bank need to reach the top ten largest banks in the world in 2015? 18. According to By the Numbers, how much in U.S. dollars is currently in circulation in the world? How much in U.S. dollars is held in reserves in the world? Describe how these numbers compare to the euro and the Japanese yen.
ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS Checkpoint: What Is Money? Because the purchasing power of the penny has fallen significantly since its first introduction, its monetary role also has diminished. It still serves as a medium of exchange, though the ease of its use has become so difficult that pennies oft en are left in coin jars, tip jars, and charity bins, as opposed to being kept for everyday use. Its function as a unit of account remains, since most prices are still quoted to the nearest penny. And its function as a store of value remains, though a substantial jar of pennies would be needed before taking the time to bring it to a coin exchange machine or the bank. Checkpoint: The Market for Loanable Funds A fall in business confidence would reduce the demand for loanable funds, shift ing the demand curve to the left in Figure 2. Meanwhile, increased insecurity about jobs will encourage people to save more, shift ing the supply of savings to the right. Th ese shift s create a huge surplus of funds at the original interest rate, and therefore interest
495
rates would fall until a new equilibrium is reached. As the economy recovers, businesses resume their investments and consumers begin spending again, and the demand curve will shift back to the right and the supply curve would shift to the left. Interest rates would trend upward. Checkpoint: The Financial System The high-speed rail system is a multiyear, costly project that is too large to be paid for using taxes from any one year. Even if the state government pays for it using taxes over many years, it still must borrow the money first before paying it back using taxes collected in the future. Th erefore, financial intermediation by banks is required. But the rail project will use more than just banks. It also relies heavily on the bond market, relying on investors willing to lend money for a relatively long period of time before being paid back with interest. Lastly, it relies on the equity markets, by selling partial ownership of the new rail system to investors willing to put up billions in hopes of a profitable return in the future once the rail line goes into service. Checkpoint: Financial Tools for a Better Future Because Nicole is more risk averse with her money, she would choose a low-risk portfolio containing safer bonds and stocks, while Jose, being more risk preferring, would invest in growth stocks and high-yield bonds. If the tradeoff between risk and return holds, Jose’s savings would grow at a higher average annual rate than Nicole’s. With compounding, Jose’s savings over the long run will likely be substantially larger than Nicole’s. One exception might be if a stock market crash occurs at the end, in which Jose’s savings would fall if he didn’t reduce the riskiness of his portfolio in the later years. Even so, with the power of compounding, Jose’s portfolio would likely be much higher than Nicole’s even if a stock market crash did occur. 1
The formula for determining the number of prices needed when N goods are in an economy is [N(N − 1)]/2. Thus, for 10 goods, the result is [10(10 − 1)]/2 = 90/2 = 45. 2
Traveler’s checks are also officially counted as part of M1. However, the improved efficiency of international debit card and credit card transactions has made traveler’s checks mostly obsolete. In 2016 traveler’s checks represented less than one-tenth of 1% of M1.
496
12
Money Creation and the Federal Reserve
497
Understanding how banks play a powerful role in the economy by accepting deposits 498
and lending money
Learning Objectives 12.1
Explain how banks create money by accepting deposits and making loans.
12.2
Define fractional reserve banking and explain why banks can lend much more than they keep in reserves.
12.3
Explain how the money multiplier works and how it makes monetary policy decisions very powerful.
12.4
Define a money leakage and explain how it affects the money multiplier.
12.5
Describe the history and structure of the Federal Reserve System.
12.6
List the important banking functions conducted by the Federal Reserve regional banks and their branches.
12.7
Describe the Federal Reserve’s principal monetary tools.
12.8
Analyze the federal funds rate and how it affects all other interest rates.
12.9
Explain why the Federal Reserve’s policies take time to affect the economy.
I
n small towns and villages throughout Central and South Asia, Africa, and Latin America, entrepreneurship is flourishing. These are not your typical high-tech start-ups or research and development centers, but rather primitive small shops selling basic goods and services. Many got their start using a microloan—a small loan (as little as $50) offered by organizations
aiming to promote business enterprise among individuals who would not qualify for traditional bank loans.
These small loans and the new businesses they help create (largely by women in the poorest parts of the world) have been credited with bringing more people out of poverty in recent years than direct foreign aid has. How can a tiny loan of $50 have such a positive effect on the economy? Quite easily, in fact. In Bangladesh, Fatima takes her $50 loan and buys cotton to make a dozen sharis. She sells the sharis at the local outdoor market for a total of $120, of which she uses $50 to pay back her microloan and $70 to buy more cotton to make even more sharis. Only this time, she is debt-free, allowing her to use all her proceeds to expand her business and provide income for her family. Meanwhile, the $50 she paid back will be loaned to another entrepreneur, allowing another small business to get its start. When a small loan is used to create a new business, jobs are created, which allows people to spend money at other businesses (also likely started from a microloan). The collective power of new businesses, jobs, and increased spending leads to healthy economic growth in the village, and it all started from a single microloan. Now, multiply
499
this one case by the thousands of microloans being made available throughout the developing world, and the effect on reducing poverty is staggering. This example represents a microcosm of the global economy and the money creation process in which financial intermediaries play an important role. During the recent 2007–2009 recession and ensuing economic recovery, a very different scenario was happening in the United States. The downturn caused a steep decline in consumer and business confidence. Individuals and firms were not in a spending mood as jobs were lost and wages cut, on top of falling home and stock prices. A microloan bank in Burkina Faso.
Afghan women attend a village meeting to make payments on their microloans.
500
501
When consumers are not eager to spend, businesses suffer. Business owners develop a much bleaker view of the economy and reduce investment. Businesses may even cut jobs, jobs that are important for economic recovery. But this wasn’t the entire story. Financial institutions during this time also lacked a willingness to lend to individuals and businesses that actually wanted to spend and invest. Why weren’t the banks eager to lend? And why did the lack of lending slow the economic recovery? The answer is surprisingly similar to the situation of the villager seeking a small loan. When the financial industry was jolted by massive losses in the aftermath of the housing and construction collapse, many banks failed while others barely survived or required government bailouts. The scare faced by banks led to a severe tightening in lending practices (which, ironically, is the type of prudent lending that might have prevented the financial crisis to begin with). The unwillingness of banks to lend money prolonged the period of time necessary for economic recovery. In times when individuals and businesses are unwilling to spend and banks unwilling to lend, people begin to look elsewhere for help. For the small village, it was the emergence of the microloan organizations. For the U.S. economy, people turned to the government to take action. The Federal Reserve (or Fed), the central bank of the United States, has extensive power in controlling the supply of money and interest rates, key elements in its arsenal of tools to jumpstart the economy when markets fail to do so on their own. After the 2007–2009 recession, the Fed took dramatic steps to make borrowing less expensive for consumers and homeowners, and to provide banks with more capital and the confidence to lend to qualified borrowers. This chapter takes a detailed look at the process by which banks go about creating money, as if out of thin air, by accepting deposits by savers and channeling these funds to borrowers. We then study in more detail the role of the Federal Reserve, the guarantor of our money and our financial system. We will look at the history of the Fed, what it does with our money, and why it is called “the lender of last resort.” Lastly, we analyze the policies and tools the Fed can use to influence the money supply and interest rates.
502
HOW BANKS CREATE MONEY When most people think of money being created, the typical images conjured up are of large machines at government institutions printing sheets of crisp new banknotes or a large mint hammering out shiny new coins. Although this is indeed money creation in the literal sense, in reality currency represents less than half of the money supply, as we saw in the previous chapter. Most money that we use every day does not involve cash and coins, but rather a sophisticated system of electronic debits and credits to our bank accounts. For example, unless one works primarily for cash tips or runs a small business where most purchases are paid for in cash, most of us will receive either a physical paycheck or a direct deposit of our wages into our bank accounts. Similarly, when we make purchases, most of us might use a debit or a credit card. Given that most transactions today do not involve cash, the idea of creating money takes on an additional meaning, one in which banks play a very important role in its process.
Creating Money as if Out of Thin Air
Suppose that you run a small tutoring service helping students at your school succeed in (or at least pass) their economics courses. Some of your clients pay you with a personal check at the end of their session, while others give you cash. Let’s assume that this month, you received a total of $500 in checks, which you deposit into your checking account, and $500 in cash, which you keep in your safe at home. Your goal is to save as much of your tutoring earnings as possible in order to buy a new car. Aside from the potential forgone interest earnings and the temptation to spend the cash, does it really matter whether you put the cash in the bank or not? To you, it doesn’t. If you need the money, you could just as easily go to an ATM to withdraw the cash as it is to take the cash out of your safe. But for the economy, there is in fact an important difference. The $500 you hold in cash is available to you—and only you—to use. However, the $500 in checks you had deposited in your bank account is money that others can use until you eventually need it. How is it that other people can use your money and yet this money is still available for you to take out when you need it? Banks hold deposits from many customers at one time, and only a small portion is withdrawn on any given day, which the banks service using the reserves they keep on hand. The rest is lent out to borrowers who pay interest to the bank, part of which is then used to pay interest on the deposits the bank holds. The deposits and lending that occur in a bank start the money creation process. To illustrate the power of the money creation process, suppose you decide to take your $500 in cash and deposit it into your checking account. Let’s analyze how the bank uses this money using a simplified balance sheet comparing a bank’s assets (money the bank claims) and liabilities (money the bank owes) called a T-account. Liabilities are shown on the right side of the T-account. When you deposit money into the bank, it becomes a liability for the bank —the bank owes you this money. To balance out this liability, however, the bank now has an asset consisting of the cash from your deposit. Assets are shown on the left side of the T-account. The following T-account shows an increase in the bank’s assets by $500 (the cash that you deposit that the bank now holds). On the right side, the bank’s liabilities increase by $500 because it must give back the $500 when you ask for it. T-ACCOUNT AFTER INITIAL CASH DEPOSIT Assets +$500 (cash)
Liabilities +$500 (increase in your checking account balance)
It is important to note that based on this initial transaction, no new money has been created in the economy. Why? Cash and demand deposits (checking accounts) are both components of the money supply measured as M1. By taking
503
cash and converting it into a checkable deposit, there is now $500 less cash in circulation, but $500 more in checkable deposits, for a net change in M1 of 0. But the process is just beginning. Now that the bank has additional reserves, it can lend some of this money to someone else. Suppose another customer at the same bank, Jenna, is running low on cash and needs to take out a small loan of $300 to cover bills that are coming up at the end of the month. How would the bank handle this? The bank would create a $300 loan for Jenna (which becomes an asset to the bank), and add $300 to Jenna’s checking account for her to use when needed. The following shows the new T-account for the bank. T-ACCOUNT AFTER LOAN TO JENNA Assets
Liabilities
+$500 (cash)
+$500 (increase in your checking account)
+$300 (loan to Jenna)
+$300 (increase in Jenna’s checking account)
After the loan to Jenna is made, the total amount of checkable deposits has now increased by $800 based on the initial $500 cash deposit. In other words, the bank has created $300 in money, as if out of thin air, simply by making a loan to Jenna. And the process doesn’t stop there. When Jenna writes a check to the vet for her cat’s annual checkup, her vet deposits the check into her bank, which allows that bank to start another round of lending and money creation. The obvious question would now be—Couldn’t banks just keep making infinite amounts of loans? The answer is that the bank needs to have enough funds in place should you, Jenna, or the vet decide to make a withdrawal to pay bills or make purchases. Thus, a bank’s ability to make loans is limited to a certain percentage of its total customer deposits. In other words, a bank must keep some reserves (such as cash) on hand to cover day-to-day withdrawals. The level of reserves a bank holds as a percentage of total deposits is called its reserve ratio. Further, the government requires that banks maintain a minimum level of reserves called the reserve requirement. reserve ratio The percentage of a bank’s total deposits that are held in reserves, either as cash in the vault or as deposits at the regional Federal Reserve Bank. reserve requirement The required ratio of funds that commercial banks and other depository institutions must hold in reserve against deposits.
In our example, the reserve ratio is calculated by reserves/total deposits, which in this case is $500/($500 + $300) = 62.5%. Because most reserve requirements are much lower than this percentage, this bank is considered highly liquid, and may continue to make more loans using your initial cash deposit until the reserve ratio drops down toward its reserve requirement. Up until now, we have assumed that all loans and deposits occurred at the same bank, but this need not be true. In fact, most money transactions in our economy take place between banks. But the way in which we analyzed loans and deposits and how that leads to money being created does not change. Our example above describes the process of a fractional reserve banking system.
Fractional Reserve Banking System Banks loan money for consumer purchases and business investments. Assume that you deposit $1,000 into your checking account and the bank then loans this $1,000 to a local business to purchase some machinery. If you were to go to the bank the next day and ask to withdraw your funds, how would the bank pay you? The bank could not pay you if you were its only customer. Banks, however, have many customers, and the chance that all these customers would want to withdraw their money on the same day is small. Such “runs on the bank” are rare, normally occurring only when banks or a country’s currency are in trouble. In the United States, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) protects bank deposits (up to $250,000 per
504
account) from bank failure. When a bank gets into financial trouble, the FDIC typically arranges for another (healthy) bank to take over the failing bank, resulting in virtually no interruption of services to the bank’s customers. The bank takeover usually occurs late on a Friday and the bank reopens on Monday morning under a new name. Because most accounts are insured, it is business as usual on Monday. It was the possibility of bank runs that led to the fractional reserve banking system. When someone deposits money into a bank account, the bank is required to hold part of this deposit in its vault as cash, or else in an account with the regional Federal Reserve Bank. We will learn more about the Federal Reserve System later in this chapter, but for the moment, let us continue to concentrate on how fractional reserve banking permits banks to create money. fractional reserve banking system Describes a banking system in which a portion of bank deposits are held as vault cash or in an account with the regional Federal Reserve Bank, while the rest of the deposits are loaned out to generate the money creation process.
The Money Creation Process
Banks create money by lending some or all of their excess reserves, or reserves above the reserve requirement. When money is loaned out, it eventually is deposited back into the original bank or some other bank. The bank will again hold some of these new deposits as reserves, loaning out the rest. The whole process continues until the entire initial deposit is held as reserves somewhere in the banking system. excess reserves Reserves held by banks above the legally required amount.
Assume that the Federal Reserve sets the reserve requirement at 20%. This means that banks must hold 20% of each deposit as reserves, whether in their vaults or in accounts with the regional Federal Reserve Bank. Now assume that you take $1,000 out of your personal safe at home and take it to Bank A. Bank A puts 20% of your $1,000 into its vault as reserves and loans out the rest. Its T-account balance sheet now reads: BANK A Assets Reserves +$200
Liabilities Deposits +$1,000
Loans +$800
As the balance sheet indicates, your $1,000 deposit is now a liability for Bank A. But the bank also has new assets, split between reserves and loans. In each of the transactions that follow, we assume banks become fully loaned-up, loaning out all they can and keeping in reserves only the amount required by law. Assume that Bank A loans out the $800 it has in excess funds to a local gas station, and assume that this money is deposited into Bank B. Bank B’s balance sheet now reads: BANK B Assets Reserves +$160
Liabilities Deposits +$800
Loans +$640
Bank B, in other words, has new deposits totaling $800. Of this, the bank must put $160 into reserves; the remaining $640 it loans out to a local winery. The winery deposits these funds into its bank, Bank C. This bank’s balance sheet shows: BANK C
505
Assets Reserves +$128
Liabilities Deposits +$640
Loans +$512
Summing up the balance sheets of the three banks shows that total reserves have grown to $488 ($200 + $160 + $128), loans have reached $1,952 ($800 + $640 + $512), and total deposits are $2,440 ($1,000 + $800 + $640). Your original $1,000 new deposit has caused the money supply to grow. BANK A, B, C Assets Reserves +$488
Liabilities Deposits +$2,440
Loans +$1,952
This process continues until the entire $1,000 of the original deposit has been placed in reserves, thus raising total reserves by $1,000. By this point, all the banks together will have loaned out a total of $4,000. A summary balance sheet for all banks reads: ALL BANKS Assets Reserves +$1,000
Liabilities Deposits +$5,000
Loans +$4,000
Notice what has happened. Keeping in mind that demand deposits form part of the money supply, your original deposit of $1,000—cash that was injected into the banking system—has turned into $5,000 in deposits, a $4,000 increase in the money supply. Bank reserves, in other words, have gone up by your initial deposit, but beyond this, an added $4,000 has been created. And this was made possible because banks were allowed to loan part of your deposit to consumers and businesses. The ability of banks to take an initial deposit of cash and turn it into loans and deposits many times over (5 times the initial deposit in our example) demonstrates the power of the banking system to create money. Moreover, the initial deposit of cash need not come from an individual; in fact, much of the money creation that occurs in the economy begins with deposits made by the government, as we will see later in this chapter.
CHECKPOINT HOW BANKS CREATE MONEY Money is created when banks make loans to customers, because these funds are eventually deposited into other banks as checkable deposits. The fractional reserve system permits banks to create money through their ability to accept deposits and make loans. The reserve ratio is the fraction of total customer deposits held in reserves. The reserve requirement is the minimum reserve ratio banks must follow. A T-account is a simplified bank balance sheet showing assets (money banks lay claim to) and
506
liabilities (money banks owe).
QUESTIONS: Suppose that you go to your bank and withdraw $1,000 from your checking account to
spend on your Spring Break vacation to the Caribbean. If the bank has plenty of cash to pay you without falling below its reserve requirement or changing the amount of loans it has, would the money supply M1 change? Would the money supply change if the bank had planned to loan out its excess reserves?
Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
507
THE MONEY MULTIPLIER AND ITS LEAKAGES We have just seen how banks create new money when they make loans using the deposits of their customers. As money gets deposited and loaned out from banks over and over, an initial amount of money can generate new deposits and loans many times over. Just how much money can an initial deposit actually create? We can use the money multiplier to find out.
Bank Reserves and the Money Multiplier
In theory, money creation can be infinite if banks loaned out 100% of all money deposited, and all loaned money found its way back into another bank following their business transactions. But this is highly unlikely due to several factors, the most important being reserves held by the bank. Because all banks are required to hold a certain percentage of their deposits as reserves in their vault or at their regional Fed bank, the maximum amount of money that can be created is limited by the reserve requirement. Given a bank’s reserve requirement, the potential or maximum amount the money supply can increase (or decrease) when a dollar of new deposits enters (exits) the system is called the money multiplier. The money multiplier is defined as:
Money Multiplier =
1 Reserve Requirement
money multiplier A formula that measures the potential or maximum amount the money supply can increase (or decrease) when a dollar of new deposits enters (exits) the system and is defined as 1 divided by the reserve requirement.
Thus, if the reserve requirement is 20%, as in our example in the previous section, the money multiplier is 1/0.20 = 5. Therefore, an initial deposit of $1,000 will create an additional $4,000 in money for a total of $5,000, a five-fold increase. The money multiplier is important to economic policy because money can be initially deposited into the banking system in two ways. The first approach, described earlier, is a cash deposit made by a bank customer. The second approach occurs when the government injects new money into the banking system through the power it has to print money. When the government “prints money,” it does not mean it is printing banknotes and spending it at the mall. Instead, the government typically adds reserves electronically to banks in exchange for bonds and other assets. This money did not exist before the Fed created it by just a stroke of a computer key. When these funds are added to bank reserves, that in itself increases the money supply (unlike a customer’s cash that is already counted in the money supply). Further, the effect is compounded by the money multiplier. The government therefore possesses tremendous power in influencing the money supply through its ability to print money and via the money multiplier. But the ability of the government to expand the money supply is subjected to various factors preventing the full money multiplier from taking place. In other words, the money multiplier formula gives us the potential money multiplier. The actual money multiplier will be smaller because of leakages from the banking system. How much smaller?
Money Leakages The potential money multiplier and the actual money multiplier are rarely the same because of money leakages. A leakage is money that leaves the money creation process of deposits and loans due to an action taken by a bank, an individual, a business, or a foreign entity. leakages A reduction in the amount of money that is used for lending that reduces the money multiplier. It is caused by banks choosing to hold excess reserves and from individuals, businesses, and foreigners
508
choosing to hold more cash.
Bank Leakages
Banks are in the business of making loans. If they don’t, they likely will not stay in business for long, especially if all they do is accept deposits and pay interest on those deposits. For any bank, profits come from the interest charged on loans made to borrowers. For this reason, it is generally presumed that banks will be loaned-up, or maximize the amount of loans they can make given the reserve requirement. However, many banks choose not to be loaned-up. Instead, banks hold excess reserves, or reserves above the legally required amount. Why would a bank choose not to loan out the maximum amount of money allowed? The lessons from the last financial crisis point to the answer. The recession caused many loan defaults and foreclosures as workers were laid off or faced wage cuts. Whenever a borrower defaults on a loan, the amount of that loan is removed (written off) from the bank’s assets; however, the bank still owes the people whose deposits made those funds available. Banks absorb these losses through the profits they earn from charging interest to those who pay back their loans. If a large number of borrowers default on their loans, the bank risks a solvency crisis, when its liabilities exceed its assets. This means that the bank owes more than what is owed to it, increasing the likelihood of bankruptcy. solvency crisis A situation when a bank’s liabilities exceed its assets.
Returning to our earlier example, suppose that Jenna used her $300 loan to pay off her bills (transferring money from her account to her creditor’s account) but then defaults on her loan. The bank’s balance sheet would now read: Assets
Liabilities
+$500 (cash)
+$500 (increase in your checking account)
+$300 (loan to Jenna)
+$300 (increase in Jenna’s creditor’s account)
−$300 (Jenna’s default)
−$300 (bank equity)
The difference between assets and liabilities is a bank’s equity, or value that is shared by the bank’s shareholders. Although equity is not a liability, it appears in the liabilities column because ultimately any gains are distributed to shareholders like a liability. When liabilities exceed assets, as in the case above, the bank has negative equity (shown as -$300 on the right-hand side of the T-account). When this occurs, the bank is insolvent; in other words, it’s broke. To reduce the risk of a solvency problem leading to bankruptcy, banks often hold excess reserves during tough economic times to ensure that they have the ability to absorb a higher rate of defaults. Further, banks also choose to be more cautious about to whom they lend money, as they did following the last financial crisis, which led to a smaller money multiplier. When banks choose not to loan all of their excess reserves, the actual money multiplier is reduced because the reduction in loans recirculates less money back through the banking system. As we saw in the chapter opener, the willingness of banks to lend generates a powerful effect on the economy. We now know that this is due to the money multiplier. However, the lack of lending creates the opposite effect, which makes bank leakages an extremely important obstacle to economic growth.
Leakages by Individuals and Businesses
Earlier in the chapter, we saw how holding cash reduces the ability of banks to create money. Why would people choose to hold more cash? Got jars of coins? Coins represent a cash leakage. Businesses such as Coinstar convert coins into banknotes or gift cards that are more likely to be spent, helping to bring money back into the banking system.
509
One factor might be the interest rate the bank pays on deposits. If interest rates paid on savings and checking accounts at the bank are near 0, as they has been for much of the past decade, one might choose to hold more savings in cash out of convenience, or make fewer trips to the bank by making larger withdrawals from an ATM. Another factor might be a general rise in fear about the financial system. Despite the existence of the FDIC, when banks are in trouble, people begin to believe that their money is less safe in banks and start to hold more cash. When individuals choose to keep money in cash rather than deposit it in a bank, a leakage in the money supply occurs because that money is not available to be loaned to someone else. The cycle of lending and saving that would be generated from that money comes to a halt, and the actual money multiplier is reduced. Individuals are not the only ones to hold cash. Most businesses conduct a portion of their transactions using cash. Therefore, at any one time, a business will be holding a certain fraction of its money in cash rather than in a bank. The percentage of cash holdings varies by business, but regardless represents a leakage in the money supply. As businesses hold more cash, as do individuals, this diminishes their deposits, thus reducing the actual money multiplier.
The Effect of Foreign Currency Holdings
Most Americans are accustomed to using debit and credit cards for daily transactions, reducing the need to hold cash. Yet, surprisingly, the U.S. government continues to print billions of new U.S. dollars each year. If Americans generally are holding smaller amounts of cash, who then is holding all of these dollars? The answer is foreign consumers, businesses, and governments. Because of the relative stability of the U.S. dollar, many countries hold U.S. dollars in reserves in order to provide support to their own currencies. Some countries, such as El Salvador and Ecuador, have abandoned their own currency altogether, choosing to use the U.S. dollar as their only legal form of currency. The prominent role that the U.S. dollar plays as the world’s most popular reserve currency causes the majority of U.S. dollars (about two-thirds, in fact) to be held outside of the United States. Because of the sheer volume of U.S. currency being held as cash throughout the world, this has the effect of reducing the actual money multiplier relative to its potential. But keep in mind that this is not necessarily a bad thing. A popular currency allows the U.S. government to print more without worrying about a significant decrease in its value relative to other currencies.
510
What Is the Actual Money Multiplier in the Economy? Given the leakages described earlier, economists have studied and estimated the actual value of the money multiplier that ultimately influences economic growth. What they have found is that leakages in the U.S. economy tend to be large, due to significant cash holdings by foreigners and banks’ unwillingness to lend when the perceived risks of default are high. To study the effect of leakages on the actual money multiplier, it is useful to modify our original money multiplier formula (1/Reserve Requirement) by adding the bank and cash leakages to the formula to create a leakageadjusted money multiplier.
The Rise and Fall of the Famous (and Infamous) Swiss Bank Account How did Switzerland become the preferred destination of the world’s offshore funds and how is that changing today?
F
or centuries, people around the world, including the rich and famous as well as the powerful and infamous, looked to Switzerland to deposit their wealth. Swiss banks today remain the world’s largest holder of offshore funds (holding about one-third of the world’s total), which are deposits of money by people outside of their country of citizenship. But times are changing, as banks in other countries, especially in Hong Kong and Singapore, experience vastly higher growth rates in offshore deposits. What made Swiss banks so popular with foreigners, and how is that changing today?
The popularity of Swiss banking derives largely from its secrecy laws, which date back several centuries. The ability of people to store money (regardless of where that money came from) without scrutiny or risk of disclosure made Swiss banks a magnet for the world’s wealthy. These secrecy laws were further cemented with the Swiss Banking Act of 1934 that made it a criminal offense for banks to disclose names of account holders. It also led to the development of numbered bank accounts in which people accessed their accounts using code words instead of their names. Moreover, Switzerland is a centrally located, neutral nation that hasn’t been invaded in centuries, adding confidence to those seeking a safe place to store money. But times have changed. Worldwide efforts to crack down on tax evaders using Swiss bank accounts to hide profits and criminal organizations hiding stolen money led to changes in how Swiss banks do business. Although Swiss banks still have strict secrecy laws, most no longer accept hidden profits or illgotten gains on behalf of individuals or corporations. Moreover, Swiss banks with branches in other countries are subjected to those countries’ banking laws. This has made life more difficult for the world’s
511
criminals and tax evaders. Today, banks remain a prominent fixture in Swiss cities such as Geneva and Zurich, and an important source of economic activity for the country as a whole. But how Swiss banks operate today resembles how most banks in the world operate: by accepting deposits and making loans, and creating money in the process.
GO TO
TO PRACTICE THE ECONOMIC CONCEPTS IN THIS STORY
A leakage-adjusted money multiplier takes into account the required reserve requirement along with excess reserves held by banks and cash held by individuals, businesses, and foreigners. Higher values of these components translate to greater leakages and therefore a lower actual money multiplier. For example, suppose that the reserve requirement is 20%, but the existence of leakages doubles the percentage held in reserves and cash to 40%. These money leakages cause the money multiplier to drop from 5 (1/0.20) to 2.5 (1/0.40), a significant reduction in money creation in the economy. Empirical data have shown that money leakages tend to increase during economic recessions, when banks are more reluctant to lend and people are more likely to hold cash. We will see in the next chapter that the resulting decrease in the money multiplier adds to the challenges of using monetary policy to pull the economy out of a recession. During the 2007–2009 recession, the money multiplier fell precipitously from 1.7 to less than 1. A money multiplier of less than 1 means that fewer loans were being made than the new money introduced into the economy. This is very important because actions by the government to increase the money supply result in less bang for the buck when the money multiplier is smaller. Such an effect renders monetary policy much more challenging. The fact that banks can create money by making loans represents a great deal of power. This power is mitigated by leakages and their effect on the actual money multiplier. Governments can encourage this money creation process by injecting banks with new money. But how do governments go about doing this? Once we understand how the government, meaning the Fed, creates money, we can then go on in the next chapter to discuss the short- and longrun results of this monetary policy. The institution charged with overseeing the money supply and creating money out of thin air is the Federal Reserve System. Let us turn to a brief survey of the Federal Reserve System. Here, we consider how it is organized, what purposes it serves, and what functions it has. The next chapter takes a closer look at the Fed in action.
CHECKPOINT THE MONEY MULTIPLIER AND ITS LEAKAGES The potential money multiplier is equal to 1 divided by the reserve requirement. This is the maximum value for the multiplier. Money leakages are caused by banks choosing to hold excess reserves and by individuals, businesses, and foreigners holding a portion of their funds in cash rather than depositing it in a bank. Leakages reduce the money multiplier. The leakage-adjusted money multiplier takes leakages into account and provides a more realistic estimate of the money multiplier in the economy.
QUESTIONS: In the following table, calculate the potential money multiplier for each of the following
reserve requirements if banks fully loan out all of their excess reserves. If banks were not required to hold any reserves, how big could the money multiplier potentially be? Is this a realistic money multiplier? Why or why not?
Reserve Requirement
Potential Money Multiplier
512
50% 33.3% 25% 20% 10% Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
513
THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM The Federal Reserve System is the central bank of the United States. It controls an immense power to create money in the economy. Federal Reserve System The central bank of the United States.
Early in U.S. history, banks were private and chartered by the states. In the 1800s and early 1900s, bank panics were common. After an unusually severe banking crisis in 1907, Congress established the National Monetary Commission. This commission proposed one central bank with sweeping powers. But a powerful national bank became a political issue in the elections of 1912, and the commission’s proposals gave way to a compromise that is today’s Federal Reserve System. The Federal Reserve Act of 1913 was a compromise between competing proposals for a huge central bank and for no central bank at all. The act declared that the Fed is “to provide for the establishment of Federal Reserve Banks, to furnish an elastic currency, to afford means of rediscounting commercial paper, to establish a more effective supervision of banking in the United States, and for other purposes.” Since 1913, other acts have further clarified and supplemented the original act, expanding the Fed’s mission. These acts include the Employment Act of 1946, the International Banking Act of 1978, the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978, the Depository Institutions Deregulation and Monetary Control Act of 1980, and the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act of 1991. The original Federal Reserve Act, the Employment Act of 1946, and the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978 all mandate national economic objectives. These acts require the Fed to promote economic growth accompanied by full employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates. As we will see in the next chapter, meeting all of these objectives at once has often proved difficult. The Federal Reserve is considered to be an independent central bank, in that its actions are not subject to executive branch control. The entire Federal Reserve System is, however, subject to oversight from Congress. The Constitution gives Congress the power to coin money and set its value, and the Federal Reserve Act delegated this power to the Fed, subject to congressional oversight. Though several presidents have disagreed with Fed policy over the years, the Fed has always managed to maintain its independence from the executive branch. Experience in this country and abroad suggests that independent central banks are better at fighting inflation than are politically controlled banks. The main reason is that an independent central bank is less likely to be influenced by short-term political pressures to engage in excessive expansionary monetary policy to hasten a recovery.
The Structure of the Federal Reserve
The Federal Reserve Act of 1913 passed by Congress led to the establishment of regional banks governed by a central authority. The intent was to provide the Fed with a broad perspective on the economy, with the regional Federal Reserve Banks contributing economic analysis from all parts of the nation, while still investing a central authority with the power to carry out a national monetary policy. The Fed is composed of a central governing agency, the Board of Governors, located in Washington, D.C., and twelve regional Federal Reserve Banks in major cities around the nation. Figure 1 shows the twelve Fed districts and their bank locations.
The Board of Governors
The Fed’s Board of Governors consists of seven members who are appointed by the president and confirmed by the Senate. Board members serve terms of 14 years, after which they cannot be reappointed. Appointments to the Board are staggered such that one term expires on January 31 of every even-numbered year. The Chair and the Vice Chair of the Board must already be Board members; they are appointed to their leadership positions by the president, subject to Senate confirmation, for terms of four years. The Chair and Vice Chair can be reappointed (without term limits) as long as they remain members of the Board of Governors. The Board of Governors’ staff of nearly 2,000
514
helps the Fed carry out its responsibilities for monetary policy, and banking and consumer credit regulation. FIGURE 1
REGIONAL FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICTS
The twelve regional Federal Reserve districts and their bank locations.
Federal Reserve Banks
Twelve Federal Reserve Banks and their branches perform a variety of functions, including providing a nationwide payments system, distributing coins and currency, regulating and supervising member banks, and serving as the banker for the U.S. Treasury. Table 1 lists all regional banks and their main locations. Each regional bank has a number and letter associated with it. If you look at your money, you will see that all U.S. currency bears the designation of the regional bank where it was first issued, as shown in Table 1. Each regional bank also provides the Federal Reserve System and the Board of Governors with information on economic conditions in its home region. Eight times a year this information is compiled into a report—called the Beige Book—that details the economic conditions around the country. These reports are provided to the Board of Governors first, and later released to the public. The Board and the Federal Open Market Committee use the information the Beige Book contains to determine the course of the nation’s monetary policy.
TABLE 1
FEDERAL RESERVE REGIONAL BANKS
515
Federal Open Market Committee
The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) oversees open market operations, the main tool of monetary policy. Open market operations involve the buying and selling of government securities. How these open market operations influence reserves available to banks and other thrift institutions will become clear shortly. Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) A twelve-member committee that is composed of members of the Board of Governors of the Fed and selected presidents of the regional Federal Reserve Banks. It oversees open market operations (the buying and selling of government securities), the main tool of monetary policy.
The FOMC is composed of the seven members of the Board of Governors and five of the twelve regional Federal Reserve Bank presidents. The president of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York is a permanent member because actual open market operations take place at the New York Fed. The other four members are appointed for rotating one-year terms. All regional presidents participate in FOMC deliberations, but only those serving on the committee vote. Traditionally, the Chair of the Board of Governors has also served as the Chair of the FOMC.
The Fed as Lender of Last Resort
The essence of banking, as we have seen, is that banks take in short-term deposits (liabilities) and make long-term, often illiquid, loans (assets). This puts banks in the unique position of facing extraordinary withdrawals when people panic and all want their money at the same time. Banks typically do not have sufficient reserves to stem a full-fledged financial panic. They cannot turn these long-term loans into cash. During a panic, banks would be forced to dump the securities or loans onto the market at a deep discount (or “take a haircut” in modern parlance), potentially forcing them into insolvency. Lending to banks during financial panics—being a lender of last resort—is a principal reason for the existence of central banks. The value of the Fed’s ability to provide loans during a financial crisis stood out during the financial panic in late
516
2008. The Fed extended credit where none was available. As markets collapse during financial panics, banks become reluctant to lend out money to businesses and to other banks that need cash in an emergency. This is when the Fed steps in. In just a few months, the Fed extended more than $2 trillion in loans to banks and other financial institutions, and by doing so changed the allocation of assets in its balance sheet in ways not seen since it was created in 1913. Specifically, instead of holding primarily government Treasury securities, the Fed began buying up large sums of risky mortgage-backed securities from banks struggling to sell them as investor confidence fell. By the end of 2008, the Fed held more bank assets than Treasury securities. Had the Fed and its lender of last resort capability not been available, the 2007–2009 recession would have been much deeper and could possibly have resulted in another depression. The ability of the Fed to make loans and inject the banking system with new money allows the fractional banking process to work and prevents the economy from facing a much worse financial crisis.
CHECKPOINT THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM The Federal Reserve System is the central bank of the United States. The Federal Reserve is structured around twelve regional banks and a central governing agency, the Board of Governors. The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) oversees open market operations (the buying and selling of government securities) for the Federal Reserve. The Federal Reserve serves as the lender of last resort, stepping in to loan money to banks that are facing cash emergency shortages or other financial difficulties.
QUESTION: If a large portion of a bank’s customers want their money back at the same time and other
banks won’t lend to it, what can the Federal Reserve do to prevent a run on the bank? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
517
THE FEDERAL RESERVE AT WORK: TOOLS, TARGETS, AND POLICY LAGS With an ability to alter the money supply, both directly and indirectly through the money multiplier, the Federal Reserve has remarkable powers to conduct monetary policy, its primary role. And because it acts independently of political parties, the Fed is able to set monetary policy with remarkable efficiency, especially compared to fiscal policy, which involves the ever common wrangling between political parties in Congress and the president. For this reason, monetary policy is often looked at as a way to provide quicker remedies to economic conditions facing the country. But how is monetary policy actually carried out? Quite remarkably, the Federal Reserve uses just three primary tools for conducting monetary policy: Reserve requirements—The required ratio of funds that commercial banks and other depository institutions must hold in reserve against deposits. The discount rate—The interest rate the Federal Reserve charges commercial banks and other depository institutions to borrow reserves from a regional Federal Reserve Bank. Open market operations—The buying and selling on the open market of U.S. government securities, such as Treasury bills and bonds, to adjust reserves in the banking system.
Reserve Requirements The Federal Reserve Act specifies that the Fed must establish reserve requirements for all banks and other depository institutions. As we have seen, this law gives rise to a fractional reserve system that enables banks to create new money, expanding demand deposits through loans. The potential expansion depends on the money multiplier, which in turn depends on the reserve requirement. By altering the reserve ratio, the Fed can alter reserves in the system and alter the supply of money in the economy. Banks hold two types of reserves: required reserves and excess reserves above what they are required to hold. Roughly 15,000 depository institutions, ranging from banks to thrift institutions, are bound by the Fed’s reserve requirements. Reserves are kept as vault cash or in accounts with the regional Federal Reserve Bank. These accounts not only help satisfy reserve requirements, but are also used to clear many financial transactions. Banks are assessed a penalty if their accounts with the Fed are overdrawn at the end of the day. Given the unpredictability of the volume of transactions that may clear a bank’s account on a given day, most banks choose to maintain excess reserves. At the end of the day, banks and other depository institutions can loan one another reserves or trade reserves in the federal funds market. One bank’s surplus of reserves can become loans to another institution, earning interest (the federal funds rate). A change in the federal funds rate reflects changes in the market demand and supply of excess reserves. federal funds rate The interest rate financial institutions charge each other for overnight loans used as reserves.
In 2008 the Fed changed its long-standing law of not paying interest on reserves. The new law allowed banks to earn interest on the reserves it deposits at the Fed. This law changed the incentives faced by banks by reducing the opportunity cost of choosing not to lend. In other words, in tough economic times, banks may choose to forgo making loans (especially risky ones) in favor of earning interest on their excess reserves deposited at the Fed. As we saw in the previous section, when banks hold more excess reserves, the money multiplier falls. By raising or lowering the reserve requirement, the Fed can add reserves to the system or squeeze reserves from it, thereby altering the supply of money. Yet, changing the reserve requirement is almost like doing surgery with a bread knife; the impact is so massive and imprecise that the Fed rarely uses this tool.
518
Discount Rate The discount rate is the rate regional Federal Reserve Banks charge depository institutions for short-term loans to shore up their reserves. The discount window also serves as a backup source of liquidity for individual depository institutions. discount rate The interest rate the Federal Reserve charges commercial banks and other depository institutions to borrow reserves from a regional Federal Reserve Bank.
The Fed extends discount rate credit to banks and other depository institutions typically for overnight balancing of reserves. The rate charged is roughly 0.5 percentage point higher than the FOMC’s target federal funds rate. However, most banks avoid using the discount window out of fear that it might arouse suspicion by both their customers and by the Fed that they are facing financial trouble. Still, the Fed prefers that banks use the discount window when needed than to make imprudent decisions that could increase the risk of bankruptcy. Although setting the discount rate and reserve requirement are both important tools used by the Fed, neither gives the Fed as much power to implement monetary policy as open market operations. Open market operations allow the Fed to alter the supply of money and system reserves by buying and selling government securities.
Open Market Operations
When one private financial institution buys a government security from another, funds are redistributed in the economy; the transaction does not change the amount of reserves in the economy. When the Fed buys a government security, however, it pays some private financial institution for this bond; therefore, it adds to aggregate reserves by putting new money into the financial system. Open market operations are powerful because of the dollar-for-dollar change in reserves that comes from buying or selling government securities. When the FOMC buys a $100,000 bond, $100,000 of new reserves is instantly put into the banking system. These new reserves have the potential to expand the money supply as banks make loans. open market operations The buying and selling of U.S. government securities, such as Treasury bills and bonds, to adjust reserves in the banking system.
Open market operations are the most important of the Fed’s tools. When the Fed decides on a policy objective, the volume of bonds being traded in open market operations to achieve that objective can be staggering. With the bond market valued in the trillions, it requires billions of dollars in bond transactions in order for the FOMC to push the federal funds rate toward its target.
The Federal Funds Target
The target federal funds rate is the Fed’s primary approach to monetary policy. As we will see in the next chapter, targeting the federal funds rate through open market operations gives the Fed an ability to influence the price level and output in the economy, a very powerful effect. The FOMC meetings result in a decision on the target federal funds rate, which is announced at the end of the meeting. Keep in mind that the federal funds rate is not something that the Fed directly controls. Banks lend overnight reserves to each other in this market, and the forces of supply and demand set the interest rate. The Fed uses open market operations to adjust reserves and thus change nominal interest rates with the goal of nudging the federal funds rate toward the Fed’s target. When the Fed buys bonds, its demand raises the price of bonds, lowering nominal interest rates in the market. The opposite occurs when the Fed sells bonds and adds to the market supply of bonds for sale, lowering prices and raising the nominal interest rate. The Fed has actually been fairly good at keeping the federal funds rate near the target, as Figure 2 illustrates. In summary, typically the Fed sets a target for the federal funds rate and then uses open market operations to manipulate reserves to alter the money supply. Changing the money supply alters market interest rates to bring the federal funds rate in line with the Fed’s target. Open market purchases increase reserves, reducing the need for banks to borrow, lowering the federal funds rate, and vice versa for open market sales. The key thing to note here is that the Fed does not directly control the money supply. It proceeds indirectly, though it has been very successful in meeting
519
its goals. FIGURE 2
THE FEDERAL FUNDS RATE AND TARGET FEDERAL FUNDS RATE
In the last 25 years, the Fed has been very successful at hitting its federal funds target rate.
Monetary Policy Lags
Although the Fed has a remarkable ability to use tools that have important impacts on interest rates, bank reserves, and the money supply, they can still take time to have an effect on the economy. Like fiscal policy, monetary policy is subject to four major lags: information, recognition, decision, and implementation. The combination of these lags can make monetary policy difficult for the Fed. Not only does the Fed face a moving bull’s-eye in terms of its economic targets, but often it can be difficult for the Fed to know when its own policies will take effect and what their effect will be.
Information Lags
We discussed information lags when we discussed fiscal policy lags. Economic data are available only after a lag of one to three months. Therefore, when an economic event takes place, changes may ripple throughout the economy for up to three months before monetary authorities begin to see changes in their data. Many economic measures published by the government, moreover, are subject to future revision. It is not uncommon for these revisions to be so significant as to render the original number meaningless. Thus, it might take the Fed several quarters to identify a changing trend in prices or output clearly.
520
Recognition Lags
Simply seeing a decline in a variable in one month or quarter does not necessarily mean that a change in policy is warranted. Data revisions upward and downward are common. In the normal course of events, for instance, unemployment rates can fluctuate by small amounts, as can GDP. A quarter-percent decline in the rate of growth of GDP does not necessarily signal the beginning of a recession, although it could. Nor does a quarter-percent increase in GDP mean that the economy has reached the bottom of a recession; double-dip recessions are always a possibility. Because of this recognition lag, policymakers are often unable to recognize problems when they first develop.
Decision Lags
The Federal Reserve Board meets roughly on a monthly basis to determine broad economic policy. Therefore, once a problem is recognized, decisions are forthcoming. Decision lags for monetary policy are shorter than for fiscal policy. Once the Fed makes a decision to, say, avert a recession, the FOMC can begin to implement that decision almost immediately. As Figure 2 illustrates, once the Fed decides on a federal funds target, nominal interest rates track that target in a hurry. In contrast, fiscal policy decisions typically require administrative proposals and then congressional action.
ISSUE What Can the Fed Do When Interest Rates Reach 0%? At the height of the 2007–2009 recession, the Federal Reserve used aggressive expansionary policy to prevent a much more severe recession or even a depression. The Fed did so by reducing the federal funds rate target, the interest rate that influences almost all other interest rates in the economy. By December 2008 the Federal Reserve had lowered the federal funds rate target to essentially 0%. Yet, the economy was still struggling and needed additional help to prevent a deeper recession. But with interest rates already at 0%, what else could the Fed do? The Fed developed new ways to expand the money supply without using its regular open market operations. First, it purchased poorly performing assets from banks, such as mortgage-backed securities, in an effort to remove these bad assets from bank balance sheets. Second, the Fed reduced the difference between the federal funds target rate and the discount rate and used term auction facilities to encourage borrowing by banks that typically would not borrow from the Fed out of fear it would signal that the bank was in trouble. In an effort to reduce this stigma, the Fed essentially auctioned money for banks to borrow, taking interest rate bids from banks. This tool allowed many banks to borrow money at rates lower than the discount rate, improving bank liquidity, and making it easier for banks to lend to individuals and businesses. Then came the tool often considered to be the last resort to stimulating the economy, quantitative easing, or QE. With quantitative easing, the Fed purchased huge amounts of bank debt, mortgagebacked securities, and long-term Treasury notes, all with money it created electronically. Between 2008 and 2014, the Fed more than tripled the monetary base (currency in circulation plus bank reserves). It is difficult to quantify the success of the Fed’s efforts. Critics of the Fed’s actions point to the fact that economic growth remained sluggish after the recession ended. But supporters of the Fed argue that had the Fed not taken these actions, the economy might have entered a depression.
521
In situations such as these, economists often wonder about the counterfactual, or what would have happened if the Fed hadn’t engaged in these policies. The reality is that we may never know, because once a decision is made, it is not possible to determine what would have happened using another approach. But regardless of whether or not the Fed played a pivotal role in the economic recovery, there is no question that the Fed’s power in controlling the money supply remains a very powerful tool that influences our lives in many ways.
Implementation Lags
Once the FOMC has decided on a policy, there is another lag associated with the reaction of banks and financial markets. Monetary policy affects bank reserves, interest rates, and decisions by businesses and households. As interest rates change, investment and buying decisions are altered, but often not with any great haste. Investment decisions hinge on more than just interest rate levels. Rules, regulations, permits, tax incentives, and future expectations (what Keynes called “animal spirits”) all enter the decision-making process. Economists estimate that the average lag for monetary policy is between a year and 18 months, with a range varying from a little over one quarter to slightly over two years. Using monetary policy to fine-tune the economy requires more than skill—some luck helps. This chapter began with a discussion of how banks create money by lending excess reserves from their customer deposits or from the sale of bonds to the Federal Reserve. The power of the fractional banking system to generate money many times over allows the Fed to wield this power in several ways, mainly by targeting the federal funds rate using open market operations. The next chapter looks more deeply into how the Fed uses its monetary tools to balance its goals of keeping income growing and prices stable.
CHECKPOINT THE FEDERAL RESERVE AT WORK: TOOLS, TARGETS, AND POLICY LAGS The Fed’s tools include altering reserve requirements, changing the discount rate, and open market operations (the buying and selling of government securities). The Fed uses open market operations to keep the federal funds rate at target levels. The Fed’s policies, as with fiscal policy, are subject to information, recognition, decision, and implementation lags. Unlike fiscal policy, the Fed’s decision lags tend to be shorter because Fed policies are not subjected to lengthy legislative processes.
QUESTIONS: Of the three tools used by the Fed, open market operations are the most common. Why is
the Fed more hesitant about adjusting the reserve requirement and the discount rate? What can go wrong?
522
Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
523
chapter summary Section 1 How Banks Create Money 12.1
Money is created when banks make loans that eventually get deposited back into the system, generating checkable deposits. Part of these deposits are held as new reserves while the rest is again loaned out, creating even more money as it gets deposited back into the system.
12.2
In a fractional reserve banking system, banks accept deposits and hold only a certain portion in reserves, loaning out the rest. T-Accounts and Reserve Ratios
A T-account is a simple balance sheet showing a bank’s assets (money the bank claims) on the left side and liabilities (money the bank owes) on the right side. Assets
Liabilities
Cash reserves
Deposits by customers
Loans made A bank can continue to make loans as long as its reserve ratio, calculated as its reserves as a percentage of its total customer deposits, is greater than the reserve requirement.
524
Reserve Ratio = Reserves/Customer Deposits
Section 2 The Money Multiplier and Its Leakages 12.3
The money multiplier is the maximum amount the money supply can increase (or decrease) when a dollar of new deposits enters (or exits) the system. Money Multiplier = 1/Reserve Requirement
Examples: If the reserve requirement is 25%, the money multiplier = 1/0.25 = 4. If the reserve requirement is 15%, the money multiplier = 1/0.15 = 6.67.
A leakage-adjusted money multiplier takes into account the excess reserves and cash holdings that reduce the loans made and therefore reduces the actual money multiplier.
12.4
The actual money multiplier found in the economy is often lower than the potential money multiplier due to leakages caused by: 1. Banks choosing to hold excess reserves by not lending out the maximum amount allowed. 2. Individuals and businesses holding money in cash rather than in a bank. 3. Foreign consumers, businesses, and governments holding cash in reserves or as a medium of exchange.
Stashing cash under the mattress creates a leakage in the money supply because this money cannot be loaned out to another borrower.
525
Section 3 The Federal Reserve System
The Federal Reserve System is the central bank of the United States. It was established by the Federal Reserve Act of 1913 and is required by law to promote economic growth accompanied by full employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates.
12.5
The Federal Reserve Is the Guarantor of the Financial System Its actions are not subject to executive branch oversight, although the entire Federal Reserve System is subject to oversight by Congress. The Fed is composed of a seven-member Board of Governors and twelve regional Federal Reserve Banks. The regional banks and their branches conduct the following services:
12.6 1. 2. 3. 4.
Provide a nationwide payments system. Distribute coins and currency. Regulate and supervise member banks. Serve as the banker for the U.S. Treasury.
526
Section 4 The Federal Reserve at Work: Tools, Targets, and Policy Lags 12.7
The Fed uses three major tools to conduct monetary policy: 1. Reserve requirements: Establishing the minimum level of reserves banks must hold. 2. Discount rate: Setting the interest rate at which banks can borrow from the Fed. 3. Open market operations: Buying and selling government securities to target the federal funds rate.
12.8
The Fed targets the federal funds rate, an interest rate that influences nearly all other interest rates. The federal funds rate was near 0% from 2008 to 2015.
527
12.9
Monetary policy is subject to lags: Information lag: The time it takes for economic data to become available. Recognition lag: The time before a trend in the data is certain enough to warrant a change in policy. Decision lag: The time it takes for the Federal Reserve Board to meet and make policy decisions. Implementation lag: The time it takes for banks and financial markets to react to the policy change.
Compared to fiscal policy lags, monetary policy lags, especially decision lags, are often shorter because decisions do not require the cooperation of Congress and the president.
KEY CONCEPTS reserve ratio reserve requirement fractional reserve banking system excess reserves money multiplier leakages solvency crisis Federal Reserve System Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) federal funds rate discount rate open market operations
QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS 528
Check Your Understanding 1. 2. 3. 4.
Describe the role required reserves play in determining how much money the banking system creates. Why are checking accounts (demand deposits) considered a liability to the bank? Why do leakages reduce the money multiplier from its potential? What is the most common tool used by the Federal Reserve to conduct monetary policy and how does it affect interest rates? 5. For what type of borrowing do the federal funds rate and the discount rate apply? Which rate is used in more transactions in the United States? 6. Why are monetary policy lags generally shorter than fiscal policy lags?
Apply the Concepts 7. The U.S. government produces billions of dollars in banknotes and coins for use in everyday transactions. Explain why currency alone does not represent money creation. 8. During an economic boom, banks tend to increase their willingness to lend. How does this trend influence the actual money multiplier? 9. The Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) insures individual bank accounts up to $250,000 per account. Does the existence of this insurance eliminate the need for reserve requirements? Does it essentially prevent “runs” on banks? 10. Many central banks in the world are independent in the sense that they are partially isolated from short-run political considerations and pressures. How is this independence attained? How important is this independence to policymaking at the Federal Reserve? 11. Alan Greenspan, a former Fed Chair, noted that “the Federal Reserve has to be independent in its actions and as an institution, because if Federal Reserve independence is in any way compromised, it undercuts our capability of protecting the value of the currency in society.” What is so important about protecting the value of the currency? How does Fed independence help? 12. The reserve requirement sets the required percentage of vault cash plus deposits with the regional Federal Reserve Banks that banks must keep for their deposits. Many banks have widespread branches and ATMs. Would the existence of branches and ATMs affect the level of excess reserves (above those required) that banks hold? Why or why not? What would be the effect on the actual money multiplier?
In the News 13. Eric Keetch offered an interesting anecdote in the Financial Times (August 12, 2009): In a sleepy European holiday resort town in a depressed economy and therefore no visitors, there is great excitement when a wealthy Russian guest appears in the local hotel reception, announces that he intends to stay for an extended period and places a €100 note on the counter as surety while he demands to be shown the available rooms. While he is being shown the room, the hotelier takes the €100 note round to his butcher, who is pressing for payment. The butcher in turn pays his wholesaler who, in turn, pays his farmer supplier. The farmer takes the note round to his favorite “good time girl” to whom he owes €100 for services rendered. She, in turn, rushes round to the hotel to settle her bill for rooms provided on credit. In the meantime, the Russian returns to the lobby, announces that no rooms are satisfactory, takes back his €100 note and leaves, never to be seen again. No new money has been introduced into the local economy, but everyone’s debts have been settled. What’s going on here? In the end, no new money was introduced into the town, but all debts were paid. Is the money multiplier infinite? How do you explain what has happened? Did local GDP increase as a result of all debts being paid?
14. Following the March 16, 2016, FOMC meeting, Fed Chair Janet Yellen announced that the federal funds rate would remain steady (around 0.5%) through the end of the year, essentially delaying the goal of raising interest rates to the long-run target of 2% to 3% for another two years. How might this announcement affect the lives of ordinary individuals, and what impact might this have on the economy?
529
Solving Problems
WORK IT OUT 15. Assume that First Purity Bank begins with the balance sheet below and is fully loaned-up. Answer the questions that follow.
First Purity Bank Assets Reserves +$700,000
Liabilities Deposits +$2,000,000
Loans +$1,300,000 a. What is the reserve requirement equal to? b. If the bank receives a new deposit of $1 million and the bank wants to remain fully loaned-up, how much of this new deposit will the bank loan out? c. What is the potential money multiplier equal to in this case? d. When the new deposit to First Purity Bank works itself through the entire banking system (assume all banks keep fully loaned-up), by how much will total deposits, total loans, and total reserves increase?
16. Suppose that the leakage-adjusted money multiplier can be calculated using a modification of our money multiplier formula: 1/(Reserve Requirement + Excess Reserves + Cash Holdings) where each component in the denominator is expressed as a percentage. Suppose that the reserve requirement is 25%, but banks, on average, hold an additional 10% of their deposits as excess reserves. Further, assume that individuals and businesses choose to hold 15% of their borrowed funds in cash. Compare the potential money multiplier with the leakage-adjusted money multiplier. Does the existence of leakages make a significant impact on the ability to conduct monetary policy? Explain why or why not.
USING THE NUMBERS 17. According to By the Numbers, during which decade did the greatest number of U.S. banks fail? During which decade did the second most number of U.S. banks fail? 18. According to By the Numbers, about how much in U.S. Treasuries did the Federal Reserve have on its balance sheet in 2005 and 2015? (Hint: Use the percentages given in each pie to calculate the values.) If the amount of U.S. Treasuries held by the Fed increased over the ten years, why did the percentage drop by so much?
ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS Checkpoint: How Banks Create Money The basic transaction reduces your checking account by $1,000 and adds $1,000 in cash for your trip. Therefore, M1 would stay the same because cash and checkable deposits are both part of M1. However, by withdrawing $1,000 from the bank, this is $1,000 that could be loaned out by the bank and lead to money creation. Therefore, by making the withdrawal, the money supply would drop if the bank had planned to loan out its excess reserves.
530
Checkpoint: The Money Multiplier and Its Leakages The potential money multipliers are 2, 3, 4, 5, and 10. If banks were not required to hold any reserves, the money multiplier could theoretically be infinite if every bank loans out 100% of its deposits. This is not likely, however, due to the many leakages that occur in the banking system. Banks would still hold some reserves, just as banks currently hold excess reserves over the required limit. No bank would want to be at the mercy of a small bank run that would lead to its ruin; therefore, it would keep some currency reserves on hand. Also, individuals, businesses, and foreign entities may choose to hold a portion of their assets in cash, preventing this money from working its way through the money creation process. Checkpoint: The Federal Reserve System The Federal Reserve has the power to loan the struggling bank the money to satisfy the withdrawals. However, such withdrawals are often a sign of deeper underlying troubles at the bank. The question then becomes whether to let the bank fail and be taken over by a solvent bank, or to help it survive by purchasing bad debts and recapitalizing the bank. Checkpoint: The Federal Reserve at Work: Tools, Targets, and Policy Lags Open market operations are very effective because they influence virtually all interest rates. Reducing the reserve requirement can certainly boost lending; however, reducing it too much can put banks at risk should defaults rise. Adjusting the discount rate is generally less effective, because bank customers and investors often view borrowing from the discount window as a warning sign of the bank’s deteriorating financial health. As a result, the Fed typically keeps the discount rate at a fixed level slightly above the federal funds rate.
531
13
Monetary Policy
532
Understanding how central banks alter the money supply to minimize fluctuations in 533
the macroeconomy
Learning Objectives 13.1
Explain the importance of interest rates on the economy and how it affects our daily lives.
13.2
Explain the goals of monetary policy and how the Fed uses policies to expand or contract the economy.
13.3
Contrast classical monetary theory with Keynesian and monetarist theories.
13.4
Describe the equation of exchange and its implications for monetary policy in the long run.
13.5
Determine the effectiveness of monetary policy when demand or supply shocks occur.
13.6
Describe the debate on whether the Fed should have discretion or be governed by simple monetary rules.
13.7
Describe the federal funds target, the Taylor rule, and how they are used in modern monetary policymaking.
13.8
Explain why extraordinary powers were used in response to the financial crisis of 2008.
13.9
Discuss the monetary policy challenges faced by the European Central Bank following the financial crises affecting individual Eurozone members.
Information received since the Federal Open Market Committee met in January suggests that economic activity has been expanding at a moderate pace. . . . A range of recent indicators, including strong job gains, points to additional strengthening of the labor market. . . . However, global economic and financial developments continue to pose risks. . . . Against this backdrop, the Committee decided to maintain the target range for the federal funds rate at 1/4 to 1/2 percent. The stance of monetary policy remains accommodative, thereby supporting further improvement in labor market conditions and a return to 2 percent inflation.
A
—EXCERPT FROM THE FOMC STATEMENT OF MARCH 16, 2016
t 2:00 P.M. EST on an ordinary weekday afternoon, the Federal Reserve (Fed) concludes its meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee, and just 15 minutes later, at 2:15 P.M. a meeting statement is released. To the twelve voting members of this committee, which meets about every six weeks, it’s just another day on the job.
But this is not your ordinary everyday job. On Wall Street, millions of investors, physically present at a stock exchange or virtually present via their online brokerage accounts, anxiously await this Fed statement. Corporate executives, just coming back from lunch, immediately search their news app for the latest statement release. Government policymakers in Ecuador, El Salvador, Panama, and Timor-Leste tune in to the news to hear the Fed
534
statement because it affects their countries’ interest rates and their currency, which in fact is the U.S. dollar. And markets in the rest of the world await the Fed statement to determine how their own economies will be affected. Indeed, in a matter of minutes after the release of the Fed statement, the twelve members of the Federal Open Market Committee will have affected the lives of hundreds of millions of people. How do such ordinary people carry such tremendous power? The Federal Open Market Committee is the body within the Federal Reserve that controls U.S. monetary policy. Their economic policy decisions affect not only the U.S. economy but also the entire world economy. An investor awaiting the Fed statement.
Although not every Fed meeting statement produces a dramatic flurry of reactions, the ability of the Fed to exert powerful policy action in times of economic fluctuation makes its meeting statement the most dissected piece of economic news in the world. Even the most slightly nuanced wording of the statement can generate mass market activity as people attempt to predict how the Fed will act not only today but also in the months and years ahead. This chapter studies the remarkable influence the Fed has to alter the macroeconomy using the tools that form the basis of monetary policy. The Federal Reserve Act mandates that the Fed implement monetary policies that will promote economic growth accompanied by high employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates. In the previous chapter, we saw how the Federal Reserve System is organized and described the three monetary policy tools the Fed uses, which are setting reserve requirements, setting the discount rate, and conducting open market operations. In this chapter, we look at what monetary policy aims to achieve and how the Fed undertakes monetary policy to deal with economic fluctuations.
535
536
The first part of this chapter describes how monetary policy is used during economic downturns and during economic booms. We then consider the question: How do changes in the money supply affect the economy? We will see that money has no effect on the economy’s real growth in the long run but can have sizable effects in the short run. We examine the impact of monetary policy on controlling demand and supply shocks and how the Fed actually tries to manage the economy, a process that is considered both art and science. The chapter concludes by looking at monetary policy challenges faced by the Fed and the European Central Bank, both of which have recently dealt with financial crises not seen in generations.
537
WHAT IS MONETARY POLICY? Throughout the study of macroeconomic principles, we have emphasized the effect of the business cycle in creating natural ups and downs in the economy, which often lead to inflation or unemployment. The rest of our study has dealt largely with ways to manage these fluctuations and to limit the harm from deviating too far from the long-run growth path of the economy. One way of managing economic fluctuations is the use of fiscal policy, which we studied earlier. Fiscal policy uses the tools of taxation, government transfer payments, and government spending. The other way of managing economic fluctuations is the use of monetary policy, which deals with how the money supply is controlled to target interest rates in an economy.
The Twin Goals of Monetary Policy
The authority to control a nation’s monetary policy is typically held by a country’s central bank. In the United States, the central bank is the Federal Reserve, an independent organization unaffiliated with any political party. The seven members of its Board of Governors are appointed by the president for a 14-year term rather than being elected. As discussed in the previous chapter, the Fed uses its primary tools of conducting open market operations, setting reserve requirements, and setting the discount rate to manage the money supply in the economy. By doing so, it has tremendous influence on interest rates, including those on savings accounts, money market accounts, government bonds, mortgage payments, student loans, car loans, and credit card balances. The Fed uses these tools to promote its twin goals of economic growth with low unemployment, and stable prices with moderate long-term interest rates. When the economy enters a boom or a recession that threatens the stability of these factors, the Fed can step in to enact an appropriate policy to counteract the effect.
Examples of Monetary Policy in Action The business cycle of the economy produces frequent ups and downs, and the Fed is kept busy anticipating and reacting to prevent major economic crises from occurring. Let’s take a brief look at a few recent periods when the Fed stepped in to promote economic and price stability.
1998–1999: The peak of the Internet growth, when new “dot.com” companies sprouted up daily, led to tremendous economic growth. But along with growth came inflationary pressures, and the Fed responded by raising interest rates.
2001–2003: With the dramatic collapse in the price of technology stocks along with the short recession in 2001, the Fed lowered interest rates to stimulate employment.
2004–2006: The housing bubble led to strong growth throughout the economy and inflationary pressures crept up (especially in industries related to housing), leading the Fed to raise interest rates again.
2007–2009: When the housing bubble collapsed, unemployment rose significantly and the Fed dramatically reduced interest rates to record lows.
2010–2015: A slow economic recovery with lackluster employment growth encouraged the Fed to hold interest
rates at record lows until late 2015 when the Fed began raising interest rates again.
A lower interest rate allows one to afford a better car (or at least fancier rims) with the same monthly payment.
538
Why Is the Interest Rate So Important to the Economy? Examine the economic decisions you make every day, and you might discover how interest rates play a powerful role. Interest rates affect the manner in which we borrow and consume, and the way in which we save and invest. Suppose you are looking to buy a new car, and have budgeted $2,000 for a down payment and $400 a month toward the monthly payment on a five-year loan. How much of a car can you afford with this budget? It depends a great deal on the interest rate. Suppose the current interest rate on a car loan is 8.99%. Using the money you have, you would be able to afford a car costing up to $21,275. But now suppose that the interest rate on a car loan is 2.99%. At the lower interest rate, you would be able to afford a car costing up to $24,265, or almost $3,000 in extra spending without changing your monthly payment. This extra $3,000 in potential spending resulting from the lower interest rate adds to the amount of consumption in the economy. Recall that aggregate demand is the sum of consumption, investment, government spending, and net exports. Just as lower interest rates make cars more affordable, they also make homes more affordable, along with equipment purchases by businesses. Therefore, a reduction in interest rates promotes greater consumption and investment, which leads to an increase in aggregate demand, shifting the aggregate demand curve to the right.
When Is It Optimal to Loosen or Tighten Monetary Policy?
By influencing interest rates, the Fed influences aggregate demand. Specifically, the Fed loosens monetary policy in times of recessionary concerns and tightens monetary policy in times of inflationary concerns. Loosening monetary policy: Reducing interest rates → increases consumption and investment → increases aggregate demand.
539
Tightening monetary policy: Raising interest rates → decreases consumption and investment → decreases aggregate demand. Let’s explore “loosening” and “tightening” a bit more.
Expansionary Monetary Policy
During times of economic downturn, the Fed will engage in expansionary monetary policy by conducting open market operations. By buying government bonds from banks using money it creates, the Fed puts more money into the economy, thus expanding the money supply and reducing interest rates. Lower interest rates tend to reduce the proportion of income people save and increase the amount they consume or invest, all else equal. The increase in consumption and/or investment results in an increase in aggregate demand (AD). expansionary monetary policy Fed actions designed to increase the money supply and lower interest rates to stimulate the economy (expand income and employment).
As interest rates are lowered, consumers and businesses find the cost of borrowing decreasing as well. For a business, this reduces the financing cost for an expansion of a factory or the building of a new restaurant or store. To a consumer, a lower interest rate on a home or car purchase can significantly reduce monthly payments, freeing up some money for other purchases. As borrowing increases to finance consumption or investment, AD again increases. FIGURE 1
EXPANSIONARY MONETARY POLICY
Expansionary monetary policies reduce interest rates, which lead to greater aggregate demand, shifting the aggregate demand curve to the right.
Further, a reduction in interest rates, in particular on Treasury securities, means that the government is spending less on financing the national debt. By spending less on financing the debt, the government is then able to spend more on other purchases, which contributes to an increase in AD. Finally, as the interest rate falls, American bonds become less attractive to foreign investors, and this often leads to a decline in the value of the U.S. dollar in foreign exchange markets. A falling dollar makes American products cheaper relative to foreign products, which stimulates exports and reduces imports, increasing AD. In sum, expansionary monetary policy is used when the economy faces a recessionary gap, in which output is below the level needed to reach full employment. By engaging in expansionary policy, the aggregate demand curve shifts to the right as shown in Figure 1, expanding output at every price level.
540
Contractionary Monetary Policy
The opposite of expansionary monetary policy is contractionary monetary policy, which occurs when the Fed sells bonds, taking money out of the economy to reduce the money supply and raise interest rates. The Fed uses contractionary monetary policy when inflationary pressures build up. When do inflationary periods typically occur? contractionary monetary policy Fed actions designed to decrease the money supply and raise interest rates to shrink income and employment, usually to fight inflation.
Inflationary pressures typically occur following a period of strong economic growth, such as during the housing bubble between 2004 and 2006. As eager consumers and investors bid up prices for homes, demand increased for related items such as furniture, appliances, and even plane tickets for those who bought second homes far away. As demand for goods and services rises, prices tend to rise as well. If prices rise too much, this would have consequences on the economy as the purchasing power of savings erodes. To stem the growth of inflation, the Fed would reduce the money supply, thereby increasing the interest rate to slow the growth of demand. In this case, rising interest rates would lead to a fall in consumption and investment. The government would spend more financing the national debt, reducing what it can spend on other goods and services. Moreover, a rise in the value of the dollar from increased demand for higher interest bonds makes American goods more expensive, reducing net exports. Each of these effects causes the aggregate demand curve to shift to the left as shown in Figure 2, reducing output at every price level and putting downward pressure on prices. Up until now, we have assumed that monetary policy affects the interest rate, which subsequently influences aggregate demand. But how does a simple change in the money supply influence the amount of goods and services in the real economy? The next section explores this question by analyzing how prices and output change in the short run and long run. FIGURE 2
CONTRACTIONARY MONETARY POLICY
Contractionary monetary policies raise interest rates, which lead to lower aggregate demand, shifting the aggregate demand curve to the left.
CHECKPOINT WHAT IS MONETARY POLICY? 541
Monetary policy involves the control of the money supply to target interest rates in order to stabilize fluctuations in the business cycle. The Federal Reserve implements monetary policy. Its goals are to promote economic growth by maintaining full employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates. Interest rates are crucial because they directly influence the components of aggregate demand, including consumption and investment. Expansionary monetary policy is used during times of recession, and involves expanding the money supply to reduce interest rates. Contractionary monetary policy is used during times of rising inflation, and involves reducing the money supply to raise interest rates.
QUESTION: Suppose the government passes legislation limiting the maximum interest rate that can be charged on student loans, reducing the monthly payment on your loans. How is this legislation similar to an expansionary monetary policy? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
542
MONETARY THEORIES In discussing the theories that justify the use of monetary policy, it is best to differentiate the long run from the short run. We will see that money has no effect on the real economy (such as employment and output) in the long run but can have an effect in the short run.
The Short Run Versus the Long Run: What’s the Difference?
One of the important concepts covered earlier in the book is the comparison between the short-run aggregate supply curve (SRAS) and the vertical long-run aggregate supply curve (LRAS). Recall that the LRAS curve is vertical because economic output is always fixed in the long run at the full employment output when wages and prices are flexible. Only factors that increase the productivity of inputs can shift the LRAS curve. The SRAS curve, however, is upward-sloping because higher prices can cause temporary increases in output. This is due to sticky wages and prices. We now build on the AD/AS model by explaining how changes in the money supply, which directly affect the aggregate demand curve, might change prices and output in the economy. Let’s begin by looking at the long run, which is the analysis most commonly associated with the classical theory.
The Long Run: The Classical Theory Classical economists focused on long-run adjustments in economic activity. In the long run, wages, prices, and interest rates are flexible, allowing the labor, product, and capital markets to adjust to keep the economy at full employment. A product of the classical theory is the quantity theory of money, which is defined by the equation of exchange: M×V=P×Q equation of exchange The heart of classical monetary theory uses the equation M × V = P × Q, where M is the supply of money, V is the velocity of money (the average number of times per year a dollar is spent on goods and services, or the number of times it turns over in a year), P is the price level, and Q is the economy’s real output level.
where M is the supply of money, V is the velocity of money (the average number of times per year a dollar is spent on goods and services), P is the price level, and Q is the economy’s real output level. Note that the right side of the equation—the aggregate price level times the level of real output—is equal to nominal GDP. In the long run, when the economy is at full employment, the implications for monetary policy are straightforward. Because velocity (V) is assumed to be fixed by existing monetary institutions (e.g., the amount of cash you use on a monthly basis is generally consistent), and real aggregate output (Q) is assumed to be fixed at full employment, any change in the money supply (M) will translate directly to a change in prices (P), or in other words, inflation.
IRVING FISHER (1867–1947) rving Fisher was one of the ablest mathematical economists of the early 20th century. He was a staunch advocate of monetary reform, and his theories influenced economists as different as John Maynard Keynes
543
I
and Milton Friedman. Born in upstate New York in 1867, Fisher studied mathematics, science, and philosophy at Yale University. In 1905 Fisher was in a phone booth in Grand Central Terminal in New York City when someone stole his briefcase, which contained his manuscript of The Nature of Capital and Income, one of the first economics books about the stock market. He rewrote the book over the next year, making copies of each chapter as it was finished and always closing the doors to phone booths after that. Monetarists owe a great debt to Fisher’s next great book, The Purchasing Power of Money, in which he offered an “equation of exchange”: MV = PT (where T is the number of transactions taking place, or output). Classical economists have used variations of the formula to suggest that inflation is caused by increases in the money supply. Fisher was prim and straight-laced, disciplined, and did not drink alcohol or coffee or tea, smoke, eat chocolate, or use pepper. His lack of humor and sometimes controversial economic beliefs (such as 100% bank reserves) led some to regard him as quite odd. But among his many skills and interests, Fisher was a successful inventor and businessman. In 1925 he patented the “visible card index” system, an early version of the Rolodex, and earned a fortune. Unfortunately, within a few years he would lose everything in the stock market crash of 1929, an event that he famously failed to predict. His insistence of an imminent recovery during the early Depression years caused irreparable damage to a well-earned reputation as one of America’s greatest economists. Information from Robert Allen, Irving Fisher: A Biography (Cambridge, MA: Blackwell), 1993.
Suppose you sell your grandma’s old LP records on eBay. Last month you listed five records for sale and sold them at an average winning bid of $20 each. Now suppose that this month a 10% increase in the money supply causes more people to want to buy records. If you again list only five records for sale, what will likely happen? There is more money to spend on the same amount of goods. Buyers might bid up the price to, say, $22. In the end, prices rise in the exact proportion to the rise in the money supply. This is the essence of the classical theory—that increases in the money supply translate into an immediate and proportional rise in the aggregate price level with no change in real output (Q). As a result, monetary policy is ineffective. Panel A of Figure 3 illustrates how the quantity theory works within an aggregate demand and supply model. The economy is initially in long-run equilibrium at point e with full employment output of $15 trillion and an initial money supply of $2.0 trillion. Increasing the money supply to $2.2 trillion (a 10% increase) shifts aggregate demand upward to AD($2.2T), resulting in a new equilibrium at point b where the aggregate price level increases to 110 (a 10% increase), yet real output remains constant at $15 trillion. This positive relationship between changes in the supply of money and inflation is evident in the plot shown in panel B, which shows the strong correlation between average growth in the money supply and inflation for 30 countries from 1975 to 2015. This suggests that any central bank that wants to avoid high inflation must avoid rapid growth of its money supply. FIGURE 3
THE IMPACT OF A CHANGE IN THE MONEY SUPPLY IN THE LONG RUN: THEORY AND EVIDENCE
544
The quantity theory of money is shown using aggregate demand and aggregate supply. The economy is initially in equilibrium at point e. The long-run aggregate supply curve is vertical at the full employment output of $15 trillion, while the aggregate demand curve reflects a money supply of $2.0 trillion. Increasing the money supply to $2.2 trillion (a 10% increase) shifts aggregate demand upward to AD($2.2T), resulting in a new equilibrium at point b, where the aggregate price level rises by 10%, yet real output remains constant. The price level rise is equal to the percentage increase in the money supply. Money supply growth and inflation for thirty countries from 1975 to 2015 support this theory.
The quantity theory of money provides a good explanation of the long-run impact of monetary growth in the larger economy. But do people really catch on so quickly to money growth? Typically not. The realization that wages and prices can be “sticky” led economists to develop theories of how prices and output can change in the short run, leading to a SRAS curve that differs from a LRAS curve. The most notable theories include the Keynesian and monetarist models.
Short-Run Effects of Monetary Policy If the short-run effects of money supply were the same as in the long run, that would be the end of the story. In contrast to the long run, changes in the money supply can have an effect on the real economy in the short run, not just on the price level. To explain this, let’s start by returning to our earlier example to show how money supply growth can affect economic output.
Money Illusion and Sticky Wages and Prices
Suppose you continue to sell your grandma’s records on eBay, listing five for sale each month. And every month, you notice that the average winning bids keep rising, first to $22, then to $25, then to $30, or even higher. This increase in the sales price makes you happy because you feel richer each month compared to the previous month. You think you are benefiting from the growing popularity of your grandma’s good taste in music. How would you use your additional income? Most people would spend it by going out to eat more or buying more clothes. This extra spending (by you and everyone who feels richer) results in a temporary increase in economic output. But then you notice that the items you typically buy each month start increasing in price, so much so that despite earning more money, you end up buying about the same amount of goods as you did before. In other words, after prices caught up, you’re no better off than when you made only $20 per record. What you have discovered is that grandma’s records are not growing in popularity. Rather, growth in the money supply is causing an increase in
545
all prices. You misperceived that you were wealthier when you really were not. The example above illustrates the misperceptions in wealth that occur when the money supply grows, and is known as money illusion. But money illusion is not the only distinguishing factor between the short run and the long run. Another short-run effect is that wages and prices tend to react slowly to changes in the economy. Most workers’ wages do not change with every paycheck; similarly, the prices of many goods and services we buy do not change every day. This delayed reaction in wages and prices to economic conditions makes them sticky. This is not the first time we have studied the effects of sticky wages and sticky prices—we studied them previously when explaining why the SRAS curve slopes upward. But now we look at how an upward-sloping SRAS curve can make monetary policy effective in the short run by looking at two opposing views on the effectiveness of monetary policy in the short run. money illusion A misperception of wealth caused by a focus on increases in nominal income but not increases in prices.
Keynesian Model
Developed by John Maynard Keynes during the Great Depression of the 1930s, Keynesian analysis has had a profound effect on policymakers and economists that continues today. According to Keynesian theory, an increase in the money supply leads more people to buy interest-earning assets (bonds), causing the price of bonds to rise and the interest rate to fall. Lower interest rates should normally lead to an increase in investment that increases aggregate demand, which increases income, output, and employment. However, Keynesians believed that this outcome occurs only when the economy is healthy. During times of recession, people become fearful and don’t buy as much, leading to massive excess capacity for businesses. Reducing interest rates might not lead to greater investment, because firms are unable to sell what they were currently producing. With a decline in business expectations, firms would be reluctant to invest more. Further, when interest rates fall to very low levels, Keynes argued that people simply hoard money because it’s not worth holding bonds that pay so little interest. Keynes referred to this phenomenon as the liquidity trap. In a liquidity trap, an increase in the money supply does not result in a decrease in interest rates; thus, there is no change in investment, and consequently no change in income or output. Monetary policy is totally ineffective. This was one reason Keynes argued that fiscal policy, especially government spending, was needed to get the economy out of the Depression. liquidity trap When interest rates are so low, people hold on to money rather than invest in bonds due to their expectations of a declining economy or an unforeseen event such as war.
Monetarist Model
Milton Friedman challenged the Keynesian view by arguing that government spending inherent to fiscal policy must be financed either by increased taxation and/or increased borrowing. His monetarist theory states that higher taxation means consumers and firms have less money to consume and invest, while increased borrowing leads to higher interest rates, which also reduces consumption and investment. Thus, monetarists believe that the crowding out effect makes fiscal policy ineffective.
MILTON FRIEDMAN (1912–2006)
NOBEL PRIZE ilton Friedman may be the best-known economist of the latter half of the 20th century. During the 1980s, his advocacy of free market economics and “monetarist” theories had a dramatic impact on policymakers, notably President Ronald Reagan and British Prime Minister Margaret Thatcher. His book A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960, co-authored with Anna Schwartz, is considered a modern classic
546
M
of economics. Born in 1912 in Brooklyn, New York, to poor immigrant parents, Friedman was awarded a scholarship to Rutgers University but paid for his additional expenses by waiting on tables and clerking in a store. He eventually went on to graduate school at the University of Chicago to study economics, and then to Columbia University. In 1946 he accepted a professorship at the University of Chicago where he delved into the role of money in business cycles. In 1950 Friedman worked in Paris for the Marshall Plan, studying a precursor to the Common Market. He came to believe in the importance of flexible exchange rates between members of the European community. Friedman’s views were explicitly counter to the Keynesian belief in a range of activist government policies to stabilize the economy. Friedman emphasized the importance of monetary policy in determining the level of economic activity, and advocated a consistent policy of steady growth in the money supply to encourage stability and economic growth. Friedman was awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics in 1976 for his work on monetary theories and also for his concept of “permanent income,” the idea that people based their savings habits on the typical amount they earn instead of on increases or decreases they may view as temporary.
Friedman pioneered the notion that consumption is not only based on income, but also on wealth, an idea he referred to as the permanent income hypothesis. With Friedman’s approach, when the money supply increases, interest rates fall, and individuals rebalance their asset portfolios by exchanging money for other assets, including real estate and consumer durables such as cars and recreational equipment. Therefore, falling interest rates will lead to higher investment and/or consumption. This leads to an increase in aggregate demand and ultimately an increase in income, output, and/or the price level. Therefore, monetarists believe that monetary policy can be effective in the short run. But, like classical economists, monetarists believe that an increase in money will ultimately increase prices in the long run. As Milton Friedman famously remarked: “Inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon.” Figure 4 illustrates the monetarist approach that a change in output will occur only in the short run. The economy is initially in long-run equilibrium at point e, with output at $15 trillion and a price level of 100. A 10% increase in the money supply from $2.0 trillion to $2.2 trillion shifts the aggregate demand curve from AD0 to AD1, initially raising output to $16 trillion and the aggregate price level to 105 (point b). Over time, as prices adjust, the SRAS curve will shift left to SRAS1 and the economy will move back to its full employment output ($15 trillion), raising prices in the long run by 10% to 110 (point c).
Summary of the Effectiveness of Monetary Policy Let’s summarize the theories of the effectiveness of monetary policy. Long Run: Changes in the money supply show up directly as increases in the price level because both velocity and output are considered fixed in the equation of exchange (M × V = P × Q). Because classical economists focused on the long run, they saw no use for monetary policy. Short Run: Keynes believed that when the economy is well below full employment, monetary policy is ineffective because investment is more influenced by business expectations about the economy than interest rates. Further, Keynes suggested that once interest rates get very low, monetary policy might confront a “liquidity trap,” where money is just hoarded. Thus, Keynesians favor fiscal policy to move the economy toward full employment. FIGURE 4
MONETARIST THEORY ON MONEY SUPPLY
547
Monetarists argue that a change in output will last only for the short run; in the long run, the economy will move back to full employment. The economy begins in equilibrium at point e. An increase in the money supply of 10% shifts the aggregate demand curve from AD0 to AD1, resulting in higher short-run output, $16 trillion, and a higher price level at point b. Over time, the economy will move back to full employment output ($15 trillion), increasing the price level in the long run to 110 (a 10% increase) at point c. The long-run aggregate supply curve is vertical at the full employment output of $15 trillion.
TABLE 1
SUMMARY OF MONETARY THEORIES Short Run
Classical Theory Keynesian Theory Monetarist Theory
Long Run
Monetary policy is ineffective. The economy always self-adjusts.
Economy self-adjusts due to flexible prices. Changes in the money supply lead only to price changes.
Fiscal policy is effective, while monetary policy is ineffective in times of deep recession.
Economy adjusts to long-run equilibrium; increased money supply leads to higher prices.
Fiscal policy is ineffective because government spending crowds out consumption and investment, while monetary policy is effective.
Economy adjusts to long-run equilibrium; increased money supply leads to higher prices.
Monetarists, on the other hand, do see a role for monetary policy. In the short run, changes in the money supply reduce interest rates, which in turn stimulate both investment and consumption. Consumer spending is related to wealth (not just income), and changes in interest rates lead to changes in consumer spending for durable goods.
548
A summary of the three theories is provided in Table 1.
Monetary Policy and Economic Shocks Our discussion thus far suggests that the Fed’s approach to monetary policy should be based on both short- and longrun considerations. Low inflation represents a reasonable long-run goal, while greater income and output are more appropriate for the shorter term. Economists generally agree that, in the long run, the Fed should focus on price stability because low rates of inflation have been shown to create the best environment for long-run economic growth. We have seen from the equation of exchange that, in the long run, aggregate supply is vertical and fixed at full employment output. Thus, changes in the supply of money lead to changes in the price level. But in the short run, demand and supply shocks to the economy may require differing approaches to monetary policy. The direction of monetary policy and its extent depend on whether it focuses on the price level or income and output, and whether the shock to the economy comes from the demand or the supply side.
Demand Shocks
Demand shocks to the economy can come from reductions in consumer demand, investment, government spending, or exports, or from an increase in imports. For example, the economy faced a demand shock in 2008 when households, fearing unemployment after the housing bubble burst, increased saving and reduced spending. Let’s consider an economy that is initially in full employment equilibrium at point e in panel A of Figure 5. A demand shock then reduces aggregate demand to AD1. At the new equilibrium (point a), the price level and output both fall. An expansionary monetary policy will increase the money supply, lower interest rates, and thereby shift aggregate demand back to AD0, restoring employment and output to full employment levels. In this case, targeting either a stable price level (100) or the original income and output level ($15 trillion) will bring the economy back to the same point of equilibrium, point e, where both targets are reached. FIGURE 5
DEMAND SHOCKS, SUPPLY SHOCKS, AND MONETARY POLICY
Monetary policy can be effective in counteracting a demand shock. In panel A, the economy begins in full employment equilibrium at point e and then a demand shock reduces aggregate demand to AD1, resulting in a new equilibrium (point a). Expansionary monetary policy will shift aggregate demand back to AD0, restoring
549
full employment output ($15 trillion) and prices (100). Monetary policy is less effective in counteracting a supply shock. In panel B, a negative supply shock shifts SRAS0 to SRAS1. The new equilibrium (point a) is at a higher price level, 105, and lower output, $14 trillion, a doubly negative result. The Fed could use expansionary monetary policy to shift AD0 to AD1; this would restore the economy to full employment output (point b), but at an even higher price level (110). Alternatively, the Fed could focus on price level stability, using contractionary monetary policy to shift aggregate demand to AD2, but this would further deepen the recession as output falls to $13 trillion (point c).
A positive demand shock produces a corresponding, though opposite, result. The positive demand shock will jolt output and the price level upward. Contractionary monetary policy will reduce both of them, restoring the economy to its original equilibrium. For demand shocks, therefore, no conflict arises between the twin goals of monetary policy. Not only is the objective of full employment compatible with the objective of stable prices, but by the Fed targeting either one of these objectives, the other objective also will be achieved.
Supply Shocks
Supply shocks can hit the economy for many reasons, including changes in resource costs such as a drought causing a rise in food prices, changes in inflationary expectations, or changes in technology. Looking at panel B of Figure 5, let us again consider an economy initially in full employment equilibrium at point e. Assume that a negative shock to the economy, say, a spike in crop prices, shifts short-run aggregate supply from SRAS0 to SRAS1. The new equilibrium (point a) occurs at a higher price level (105) and a lower output of $14 trillion. This doubly negative result means that a supply shock is very difficult to counter. The Fed could use expansionary monetary policy to shift AD0 to AD1; this would restore the economy to full employment output of $15 trillion (point b), but at an even higher price level (110). Alternatively, the Fed could focus on price level stability, using contractionary monetary policy to shift aggregate demand to AD2, but this would further deepen the recession by pushing output down to $13 trillion (point c). For a negative supply shock, not only has price level stability worsened, but so has output and income. Contrast this with the situation earlier, when a demand shock worsened the economy for one of its targets, but improved it for the other. Supply shocks are difficult to counteract because of their doubly negative results.
Implications for Short-Run Monetary Policy
There is general agreement among economists that monetary policy should focus on price stability in the long run, while focusing on output or income in the short run. When a demand shock strikes, following this short-run policy course has the same effect as using price stability as the goal. When a supply shock occurs, however, targeting nominal income or output is preferable, because it permits the Fed to spread the shock’s impact between income and output losses and price level increases. By increasing aggregate demand, the economy will suffer some added increase in the price level, but output will rise, reducing the severity of any recession. The Fed will probably not try to push the economy back to full employment (from point a to point b in panel B of Figure 5) immediately, because this action would result in much higher inflation. Moving the economy back to full employment is typically spread over several periods.
CHECKPOINT MONETARY THEORIES The classical equation of exchange is M × V = P × Q. In the long run, velocity (V) and output (Q) are assumed to be fixed. Therefore, changes in the money supply translate directly into changes in the price level: ΔM = ΔP. In the short run, Keynesian monetary analysis suggests that changes in the money supply change
550
interest rates, leading to changes in investment and aggregate demand when the economy is healthy. However, in a deep recession, changes in the money supply have no effect on the real economy. Monetarists suggest that in the long run, the economy functions in the way that classical economists described, but they see monetary policy affecting interest rates in the short run, which in turn affects investment and/or consumption. In the long run, the Fed targets price stability. Low rates of inflation are most conducive to long-run economic health. Monetary policy can offset demand shocks because the objective of full employment is compatible with the objective of stable prices. Supply shocks present a more challenging problem for monetary policy. A negative supply shock reduces output but increases the price level. Expansionary monetary policy to increase output further increases the price level, and contractionary policy to reduce the price level worsens the recession.
QUESTION: A common debate on dealing with rising national debt involves those who prefer a smaller
government (reduced taxation with a dramatic reduction in government spending) versus those who prefer increased government spending funded by higher taxes. Which general theories described in this section best resemble the two sides of the debate? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
551
MODERN MONETARY POLICY When the Fed engages in expansionary monetary policy, it is buying bonds using money it creates by adding to the existing bank reserves deposited at the Fed. Other terms used to describe this process include easy money, quantitative easing, and accommodative monetary policy. It is designed to increase excess reserves and the money supply, and ultimately reduce interest rates to stimulate the economy and expand income and employment. The opposite of an expansionary policy is contractionary monetary policy, also referred to as tight money or restrictive monetary policy. Tight money policies are designed to shrink income and employment, usually in the interest of fighting inflation. The Fed brings about tight monetary policy by selling bonds, thereby pulling reserves from the financial system. easy money, quantitative easing, or accommodative monetary policy Fed actions designed to increase excess reserves and the money supply to stimulate the economy (increase income and employment). See also expansionary monetary policy. tight money or restrictive monetary policy Fed actions designed to decrease excess reserves and the money supply to shrink income and employment, usually to fight inflation. See also contractionary monetary policy.
The Federal Reserve Act gives the Board of Governors significant discretion over conducting monetary policy. It sets goals, but leaves it up to the discretion of the Board of Governors how best to reach these objectives. As we have seen, the Fed attempts to frame monetary policy to keep inflation low over the long run, but also to maintain enough flexibility to respond in the short run to demand and supply shocks.
Rules Versus Discretion
The complexities of monetary policy, especially in dealing with a supply shock, have led some economists, most notably Milton Friedman, to call for a monetary rule to guide monetary policymakers. Other economists argue that modern economies are too complex to be managed by a few simple rules. Constantly changing institutions, economic behaviors, and technologies means that some discretion, and perhaps even complete discretion, are essential for policymakers. Also, if policymakers could use a simple and efficient rule on which to base successful monetary policy, they would have enough incentive to adopt it voluntarily, because it would guarantee success and their job would be much easier. monetary rule Keeps the growth of money stocks such as M1 or M2 on a steady path, following the equation of exchange (or quantity theory), to set a long-run path for the economy that keeps inflation in check.
Milton Friedman argued that variations in monetary growth were a major source of instability in the economy. To counter this problem, which is compounded by the long and variable lags in discretionary monetary policy, Friedman advocated the adoption of monetary growth rules. Specifically, he proposed increasing the money supply by a set percentage every year, at a level consistent with long-term price stability and economic growth. Friedman and other monetarists, like the classical economists before them, believed the economy to be inherently stable. If a demand shock is small or temporary, a monetary growth rule will probably function well enough. But if the shock is large or persistent, as was the case during the 2007–2009 recession, a discretionary monetary policy aimed at bringing the economy back to full employment more quickly would probably be preferred. In some cases, a monetary rule keeps policymakers from making things worse by preventing them from taking imprudent actions. Yet, the monetary rule also prevents policymakers from aiding the economy when a policy change is needed, as was the case in the 1970s when the Fed’s practice of setting a fixed rate for money supply growth wasn’t considered successful. The alternative to setting money growth rules that modern monetary authorities around the world have tried is the simple rule of inflation targeting, which sets targets on the inflation rate, usually around 2% per year. If inflation (or
552
the forecasted rate of inflation) exceeds the target, contractionary policy is employed; if inflation falls below the target, expansionary policy is used. Inflation targeting has the virtue of explicitly iterating that the long-run goal of monetary policy is price stability. inflation targeting The central bank sets a target on the inflation rate (usually around 2% per year) and adjusts monetary policy to keep inflation near that target.
But while inflation targeting may work well to combat negative demand shocks, the same is not true when a negative supply shock occurs. Inflation targeting means that contractionary monetary policy should be used to reduce the inflation spiral. But contractionary policy would deepen the recession, and in reality, few monetary authorities would stick to an inflation-targeting approach in this situation. They would be more likely to stimulate the economy slightly, hoping to move it back to full employment with only a small increase in inflation. The result is that inflation targeting would be less effective in dealing with a negative supply shock.
The Federal Funds Target and the Taylor Rule If not monetary targeting or inflation targeting, what other rule can the Fed use? We know that the Fed alters the federal funds rate as its primary monetary policy instrument. Under what circumstances will the Fed change its federal funds target? The Fed is concerned with two major factors: preventing inflation and preventing and moderating recessions. Professor John Taylor of Stanford University studied the Fed and how it makes decisions and he empirically found that the Fed tended to follow a general rule that has become known as the Taylor rule for federal funds targeting: Taylor rule A rule for the federal funds target that suggests the target is equal to 2% + Current Inflation Rate + 1/2(Inflation Gap) + 1/2(Output Gap).
Federal Funds Target Rate = 2 + Current Inflation Rate + 1/2(Inflation Gap) + 1/2(Output Gap) The Fed’s inflation target is typically 2%, the inflation gap is the current inflation rate minus the Fed’s inflation target, and the output gap is current GDP minus potential GDP1. If the Fed tries to target inflation around 2%, the current inflation rate is 4%, and output is 3% below potential GDP, then the target federal funds rate according to the Taylor rule is
FFT arg et = 2 + 4 + 1/2(4 − 2) + 1/2(−3) = 2 + 4 + 1/2(2) + 1/2(−3) = 2 + 4 + 1 − 1.5 = 5.5% Notice that the high rate of inflation (4%) drives the federal funds target rate upward, while the fact that the economy is below its potential reduces the rate. If the economy were operating at its potential, the federal funds target would be 7%, because the Fed would not be worried about a recession and would be focused on controlling inflation. Figure 6 shows how closely the Taylor rule tracks the actual federal funds rate. Some economists have blamed the large spread between the two rates during the period between 2003 and 2007 for the housing boom that precipitated the financial crisis in 2008. They argue that the extremely low interest rates fueled the housing boom. More important, what the Taylor rule tells us is that when the Fed meets to change the federal funds target rate, the two most important factors are whether inflation is different from the Fed’s target (typically 2%) and whether output varies from potential GDP. If output is below its potential, a recession threatens and the Fed will lower its target, and vice versa when output exceeds potential and inflation threatens to exceed the Fed’s target. FIGURE 6
ACTUAL FEDERAL FUNDS RATE AND THE TAYLOR RULE
553
The Taylor rule tracks the actual federal funds rate quite closely. Some economists have argued that the low federal funds rate during the period from 2003 to 2007 was the cause of the housing boom that precipitated the financial crisis in 2008 and the ensuing recession.
A Recap of the Fed’s Policy Tools Now is a good time to summarize the monetary policy actions that the Fed can take to achieve its twin goals of price stability and full employment. When output exceeds potential output (Q > Qf), firms are operating above their capacities and costs will rise, adding an inflationary threat that the Fed wants to avoid. Therefore, the Fed would increase the real interest rate to cool the economy. When output is below potential (Q < Qf), the Fed’s goal is to drive the economy back to its potential and avoid a recession along with the losses associated with an economy below full employment. The Fed does this by lowering the real interest rate. This reflects the Fed’s desire to fight recession when output is below full employment and fight inflation when output exceeds its potential. Today, monetary authorities set a target interest rate and then use open market operations to adjust reserves and keep the federal funds rate near this level. The Fed’s interest target is the level that will keep the economy near potential GDP and/or keep inflationary pressures in check. When GDP is below its potential and a recession threatens the economy, the Fed uses expansionary policy to lower interest rates, expanding investment, consumption, and exports. When output is above potential GDP and inflation threatens, the Fed uses a higher interest rate target to slow the economy and reduce inflationary pressure. Raising interest rates is never a politically popular act, but the Fed will be forced to balance future economic growth against rising inflationary expectations. As former Fed Chair William McChesney Martin said, “The job of a good central banker is to take away the punchbowl just as the party gets going.”
554
Transparency and the Federal Reserve How does the Fed convey information about its actions, and why is this important? For many years, decisions were made in secrecy, and often they were executed in secrecy. The public did not know that monetary policy was being changed. Because monetary policy affects the economy, the Fed’s secrecy stimulated much speculation in financial markets about current and future Fed actions. Uncertainty often led to various counterproductive actions by people guessing incorrectly. These activities were highly inefficient. When Alan Greenspan became head of the Fed in 1987, this policy of secrecy started to change. By 1994 the Fed released a policy statement each time it changed interest rates, and by 1998 it included a “tilt” statement forecasting what would probably happen in the next month or two. By 2000 the FOMC released a statement after each of its eight meetings per year even if policy remained the same. As the chapter opener describes, the FOMC statement is now one of the most anticipated pieces of economic news. This new openness has come about because the Fed recognized that monetary policy is mitigated when financial actors take counterproductive actions when they are uncertain about what the Fed will do. In the words of William Poole, former president of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Explaining a policy action—elucidating the considerations that led the FOMC to decide to adjust the intended funds rate, or to leave it unchanged—is worthwhile. Over time, the accumulation of such explanations helps the market, and perhaps the FOMC itself, to understand what the policy regularities are. It is also important to understand that many—perhaps most—policy actions have precedent value. . . . One of the advantages of public disclosure of the reasons for policy actions is that the required explanation forces the FOMC to think through what it is doing and why.2
ISSUE The Record of the Fed’s Performance Determining how to measure the impact of Federal Reserve policy on our huge, complex economy is not easy. The figure shows how three variables—unemployment, inflation, and interest rates (effective federal funds rate)—have fared during the tenure of the five* Fed Chairs over the last four decades. Before 1980, when Arthur Burns headed the Fed, inflation was rising. An oil supply shock in 1973 was met with accommodative monetary policy and aggregate demand expanded. The economy was hit with a second oil price shock in the late 1970s. By the early 1980s, inflation rose to double digits, peaking at over 14% in 1980. Paul Volcker, the head of the Fed at that time, tightened monetary policy to induce a recession (1981–1982) to reduce inflation. By the end of his term, inflation had been reduced to little more than 4%, a remarkable feat.
555
During the 1990s, the Alan Greenspan Fed alternated between encouraging output growth (mid1990s) and fighting inflation (early and late 1990s). The Fed under Greenspan did a good job of keeping the economy near full employment. Interest rates trended down and inflation was moderate during the 1990s and early 2000s. But a housing bubble, partly the result of the extremely low interest rates from 2003 to 2007, followed by its collapse in 2008, brought on a financial panic and a deep recession. The problems stemming from the housing collapse and financial crisis became a challenge for Fed Chair Ben Bernanke. In 2008 the Fed under Bernanke lowered the fed funds rate to almost 0%. In addition, the Bernanke Fed continued to expand the monetary base by purchasing long-term assets from banks when interest rates had already hit the floor. As the chart shows, unemployment trended down and the short period of deflation in 2009 was corrected. *Technically, there were six Fed Chairs over this period. However, G. William Miller’s tenure lasted just over a year from 1978 to 1979, and therefore is not included in this graph.
Fed transparency helps the public understand why it is taking certain actions. This helps the market understand what the Fed does in certain circumstances, and what the Fed is likely to do in similar situations in the future. The Fed’s “tilt” comment after each meeting provides a summary of the Fed’s outlook on the economy and information on the target federal funds rate. Transparency helps the Fed implement its monetary policy. Until a decade ago, the performance of monetary authorities illustrated how effective discretionary monetary policy could be. Price stability was remarkable, unemployment and output levels were near full employment levels, interest rates were kept low, and economic growth was solid. The global financial crisis and recovery over the past decade tested the limits of central banks in preventing economic catastrophe. On the one hand, some economists such as Janet Yellen (often referred to as “doves”) argue that greater Fed action is needed in times of economic hardship, while others (“hawks”) warn against the inflationary effects of too much monetary policy action. The concluding section of this chapter looks at the actions of the Fed and the European Central Bank in stemming the economic effects from a crisis, and how economic “doves” have gained significant influence in the way monetary policy has been implemented.
556
CHECKPOINT MODERN MONETARY POLICY In the past, monetary targeting was used to control the rate of growth of the money supply. Later, an alternative approach of inflation targeting, targeting the inflation rate to around 2%, became more prevalent. The Fed sets a target federal funds rate and then uses open market operations to adjust reserves and keep the federal funds rate near this level. The Taylor rule is a general rule that ties the federal funds rate target to the inflation gap and the output gap for the economy, and has done a good job in estimating the actual federal funds rate target set by the Fed. When inflation rises, the Fed uses contractionary monetary policy to increase the federal funds rate to slow the economy. When the economy drifts into a recession and inflationary pressures fall, the Fed does the opposite and reduces the federal funds rate, giving the economy a boost. Fed transparency helps us to understand why the Fed makes particular decisions and also what the Fed will probably do in similar circumstances in the future.
QUESTION: After years of quantitative easing, many worry that inflation will eventually become a
problem. Why should bond investors sell when the Fed or other central bankers decide that inflation is a growing problem? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
557
NEW MONETARY POLICY CHALLENGES For much of the past century, since the Federal Reserve Act created the Federal Reserve and with it monetary policy, policies were quite predictable and the role of the Fed was seen as an ever-present but never overreaching government body. A similar sentiment was felt toward the European Central Bank (ECB), formed in 1998 in the nineteen-member (as of 2016) Eurozone. These perceptions have changed over the past decade after both the United States and Europe experienced the worst financial crisis in nearly a century. Extraordinary times called for extraordinary efforts by the Fed and the ECB, using monetary policy beyond what is used in normal times. In the United States, the recession of 2007–2009 and the subsequent slow recovery led the Fed to take drastic actions never seen in its past. More recently, the ECB made large rescue packages for member nations that neared default on their debt, taking new drastic measures to save the euro from collapse or from members leaving the Eurozone. This section presents a brief summary of the challenges faced by the Fed and the ECB, and how both have used extraordinary powers to limit the economic impact of the crises.
The Fed: Dealing with an Economic Crisis Not Seen in 80 Years
The financial meltdown that plagued the global economy in the latter part of the last decade was caused by a perfect storm of conditions. First, a world savings glut and unusually low interest rates from 2002 to 2005 led to a housing bubble. Second, financial risk was not properly accounted for, as consumers were eager to buy homes (sometimes second homes) and banks were so eager to lend that they ignored previous lending standards. Third, investors and financial institutions (including pension funds) bought trillions of dollars of assets that depended on housing values increasing consistently in the future. When the housing bubble collapsed, the house of cards collapsed as well. Falling home values and rising mortgage payments caused homeowners to default, leading to many foreclosures. The foreclosures caused assets dependent on housing values to plummet, resulting in trillions of dollars in losses by financial firms and investors. Banks found themselves in trouble, and the government bailed out the banks by buying up bad loans to provide capital and liquidity in order to prevent bank runs and a sharp fall in lending. In response to the financial crisis, the Fed used its normal monetary policy tools and some that it hadn’t used since the 1930s. By December 2008 the Fed had lowered its federal funds target rate, using its normal monetary policy tool, to essentially 0%. By this time, the Fed turned to extraordinary measures when it began making massive loans to banks and buying large amounts of risky mortgage-backed securities. The Fed’s balance sheet ballooned in size from less than $1 trillion in 2008 to over $3 trillion in 2012, a level that well exceeds that in normal times. Further, its balance sheet allocation changed dramatically from one consisting of about 90% in safe Treasury securities to one comprising nearly half in more risky assets such as mortgage-backed securities. The Fed was the prime mover in dealing with the financial crisis, once it recognized it. One can argue that it took too long for the Fed to recognize the problem, and the Fed may have encouraged the housing bubble by keeping interest rates very low for too long. Further, the government’s response in bailing out financial institutions and other industries, along with a dramatic increase in the monetary base, led some to believe that the Fed overstepped its authority by exercising powers it did not have (such as its role in buying up troubled assets from banks) and expanding the monetary base too far, risking widespread inflation in the future. But as former Fed Chair Ben Bernanke said, if your neighbor’s house is on fire because he was smoking in bed, you deal with the fire first because if you don’t, your own house can burn down. You deal with your neighbor’s smoking problem later. The U.S. economy has mostly recovered from the financial crisis, but current Fed Chair Janet Yellen has remained cautious, allowing monetary policy to remain accommodative as economic growth improves. The Fed was not alone in taking drastic action during the financial crisis. The Fed’s counterpart in Europe, the ECB, took extraordinary action as well.
558
The Eurozone Crisis and the Role of the European Central Bank The Eurozone was created during a 1992 meeting in the Netherlands by twelve European nations that envisioned a single currency that would reduce transaction costs and facilitate and expand trade. The meeting resulted in the signing of the Maastricht Treaty, which set the monetary criteria that each member nation had to satisfy before joining the Eurozone. These criteria included, among others: 1. Maintaining an inflation rate no higher than 1.5% above the average of the three member countries with the lowest inflation 2. Maintaining long-term interest rates (on 10-year bonds) no higher than 2% above the average of the three member countries with the lowest interest rates 3. Maintaining annual deficits of less than 3% of GDP 4. Maintaining total debt of less than 60% of GDP 5. Having no major currency devaluation in the preceding two years When the euro was introduced in 1999, eleven of the twelve treaty members met the monetary criteria. Greece took two extra years to satisfy the criteria and was admitted into the Eurozone in 2001. Why were such stringent criteria needed? When a common currency is adopted, monetary policy becomes shared by all members. Therefore, a monetary crisis in one country can quickly spread to all countries. Germany, the largest and wealthiest member of the Eurozone, traditionally had maintained low inflation and a very stable economy. Although Germany had much to gain from the Eurozone, it also faced risks by integrating its monetary policy with countries whose economies were less stable. Because of Germany’s fear of inflation, the Eurozone was set up in a way that prescribed austerity measures as opposed to monetary expansion as a cure for debt. However, the severity of the Eurozone crisis that would ensue a decade later changed this focus, as even Germany had to accept that extraordinary actions were needed. Still, for much of the first decade, the euro was a success, with member nations keeping their debt under control while the ECB implemented monetary policy for the entire Eurozone. Moreover, the euro established itself as a major reserve currency, giving it significant clout among world financial institutions. However, conditions began changing in 2007 when several member nations saw their debts rise, requiring some to sell securities (sovereign debt) on future cash revenues to keep their debt-to-GDP ratio from exceeding the Eurozone limit. However, these quick fixes worked only for a short period. A bigger crisis was brewing that would test the ability of the ECB to save the euro from collapse. From 2008 to 2013, nearly half of the Eurozone nations faced some sort of financial crisis. In each situation, the ECB used its normal monetary policy tools in addition to extraordinary measures to lessen the economic impact of the crisis and to prevent nations from defaulting on their debt. A summary of key events faced by individual Eurozone members follows. Ireland: Ireland was one of the first member nations to face difficulties when its property bubble burst, causing all of its major banks to face insolvency in 2008. This led the Irish government to pass a law guaranteeing all bank deposits and the ECB to step in and lend billions of euros to Irish banks, an action that up to that point had never been taken on this scale. Greece: The global recession devastated Greece’s shipping industry, which led to deficits and then a debt crisis in 2010. By 2012 interest rates had risen to over 25%. Further, public riots threatened Greece’s ability to maintain public support for the euro and the conditions required to remain in the Eurozone. A series of bailout packages from the ECB and the International Monetary Fund (IMF) helped bring interest rates down, but unemployment remained high even in 2016. Moreover, citizens in Greece increasingly grew wary of debtcutting measures and structural reforms that made life increasingly difficult. Portugal: Th e third country to receive a bailout package from the ECB in exchange for promises of budget cuts and structural reforms was Portugal, in 2011. Th e crisis increased unemployment, which had reached 18% by 2013. However, improved economic conditions since then allowed Portugal to exit the bailout program in 2014 and return to mostly normal times, though the eff ects of the crisis still linger in some parts of the country.
559
Cyprus: In 2013 Cyprus became the fourth nation to receive a bailout package when heavy investments by investors and banks in private Greek industries went sour. It also became the first nation to borrow funds from the European Stability Mechanism (ESM), created by the ECB in September 2012 to provide loans to Eurozone members facing financial difficulties. Like Portugal, Cyprus improved its economy, allowing it to conclude its bailout program in 2016. Spain: Spain had faced an unrelenting economic crisis since 2008, as uncontrolled debt and unemployment led to many leadership changes. In 2013 the unemployment rate reached 25%, and throughout this period, the ECB bought Spanish government bonds and made extraordinary amounts of loans (around 350 billion euros) to Spanish banks, including new loans from the ESM. But unlike the countries discussed earlier, Spain never accepted a bailout, and strong economic growth in 2015 and 2016 (fueled by record tourism) has put Spain on a path to recovery. Ireland went from being the second wealthiest member of the Eurozone (after Luxembourg) to one facing the biggest financial crisis in 2008.
Italy: Italy has long had a high debt-to-GDP ratio, even before the crisis in other countries began. It has taken many steps to reduce its debt, which has stood over 100% of its GDP for much of the past decade, though much work remains. A key obstacle facing Italy has been the lack of economic growth. While other Eurozone nations experienced economic growth following the global economic crisis, Italy remained in a recession for several more years, and today remains among the slowest growing economies in the Eurozone. Slovenia: In 2007 Slovenia became the 13th member of the Eurozone. Slovenia’s economy is considerably smaller than the rest of the Eurozone, and banks were never fully privatized, resulting in political influences in banking decisions. These factors made Slovenia more prone to economic downturns, and led to its financial crisis. Fortunately, a strong rise in exports and successful reforms of state-owned companies led to healthy economic growth since 2013, setting a positive example of how good economic policy can resolve financial
560
crises quickly. In sum, the ECB took extraordinary actions that it had never taken in its history to prevent financial crises in individual countries from causing the collapse of the Eurozone. First, the ECB provided loans to banks and bought government debt, and created the ESM in 2012 to manage funds being disbursed. Second, the ECB negotiated deals with private banks and other investors to write off portions of debt and to restructure existing loans to governments. Third, it demanded that governments pass austerity measures, enact structural reforms, and be subjected to greater scrutiny. Like the Fed, the ECB’s balance sheet ballooned during the crisis, from about 1 trillion euros in 2007 to over 3 trillion euros in 2012. Why was the ECB so eager to take extraordinary actions to prevent countries from defaulting on their debt?
ISSUE The Challenges of Monetary Policy with Regional Differences in Economic Performance The Eurozone crisis of 2008–2013 led many to point to Europe as an experiment with monetary policy integration gone wrong. Members of the Eurozone were too different, not only culturally, but also economically. Prior to its formation in 1999, the richest member of the Eurozone, Luxembourg, had a GDP per capita that was more than twice the level of that of Portugal, which at the time was the poorest member of the original eleven countries, until Greece joined in 2001. In 2007 countries in Eastern Europe began joining, further spreading the difference between the richest and poorest members, which would all share the same currency and monetary policy determined by the European Central Bank (ECB). Although each member nation would have representation in the ECB based on population, Germany and France, the two largest members, dominate decisions. The challenge faced by the ECB is formulating a common monetary policy that best fits the economic conditions faced by its members. This is not easy. When one part of the Eurozone is booming (say, Ireland) and would benefit from contractionary monetary policy, while another is struggling with debt (Greece) and requires expansionary monetary policy, choosing a common monetary policy involves placing the priority of one country’s economic concerns over another. But is the situation in Europe the only one in which a common monetary policy needs to address wide variations in economic performance? The answer is no, and the best example of another monetary zone facing similar problems may surprise you . . . the United States. The United States shares many similarities with the Eurozone when it comes to monetary policy. Although the United States is one country, wide variations in economic performance still exist. In 2015 Delaware’s per capita income of about $72,000 was twice that of Mississippi’s $36,000. Further, U.S. monetary policy also must take into account territories that use the U.S. dollar, such as Puerto Rico, as well as countries such as Ecuador, El Salvador, and Panama, all of which have a per capita income even lower than Mississippi’s. The Fed’s decisions have a direct impact on all economies that use the U.S. dollar.
561
European Central Bank in Frankfurt, Germany. In sum, large monetary unions such as the Eurozone and the United States must weigh the priorities of one region against another when considering the policies they implement. Such a task makes the statement that monetary policy is as much art as science a realistic description facing central banks today.
Clearly, the number of Eurozone nations facing a financial crisis had reached a critical point by 2013. If any nation defaults and pulls out of the Eurozone, it could trigger a global loss of confidence in the euro. For example, investors might be less willing to invest in euro-denominated bonds and assets if the long-term stability of the currency came into question. Such a loss of confidence would itself reduce the stability of the euro, leading to a selffulfilling prophecy. Imagine what would happen if a U.S. state became so much in debt that it chose to give up the U.S. dollar and create its own, much devalued, state currency. The impact could be significant. However, the ECB used aggressive monetary policies to reduce the likelihood of a nation’s exit from the Eurozone. Just as the Fed stepped in to prevent regional crises in the United States by injecting financial capital and reducing interest rates, the ECB used expansionary monetary policies to help member nations facing economic crises. This is much easier said than done, as the Issue described, when different areas of a currency zone face varying levels of economic performance.
Why Would a Country Give Up Its Monetary Policy? What factors led Ecuador, El Salvador, and Panama to give up their ability to use monetary policy in favor of adopting the
562
U.S. dollar?
O
ne of the first tasks when traveling abroad is to exchange currency. In most countries, this is an easy task: Just visit a foreign exchange booth or withdraw money from a local ATM. Some countries that depend on tourism, such as Jamaica and Costa Rica, readily accept U.S. dollars despite having their own national currency. But for American tourists visiting Ecuador, El Salvador, or Panama, exchanging money isn’t even an option, because the official currency in these countries is the U.S. dollar. Why would a country adopt the U.S. dollar as its official currency, and what effect does it have on monetary policy? The decision for a country to use a foreign currency (in this case, the U.S. dollar) as its own official currency, called dollarization, is not in any way influenced or dictated by the United States. Ecuador, El Salvador, and Panama willingly gave up their own currency to adopt the U.S. dollar. And by doing so, these countries relinquished their ability to set monetary policy, because the supply of dollars and the interest rate are managed by the U.S. Federal Reserve. Why would a country give up control of its monetary policy?
Traveling to Ecuador? No need to exchange money. The official currency is the U.S. dollar. Panama adopted the U.S. dollar over a century ago to facilitate trade, given its strategic geographic location that attracts cargo ships from around the world crossing the Panama Canal. In the case of Ecuador and El Salvador, which adopted the U.S. dollar in 2000 and 2001, respectively, their situations were different than Panama’s. Prior to adopting the U.S. dollar, both countries had rampant inflation, caused by the inability of their central banks to keep money growth under control. High inflation decreases investor confidence because profits quickly lose their value. By adopting the U.S. dollar (and thereby preventing the government from adjusting the money supply), Ecuador and El Salvador sent a signal that they were serious about maintaining low inflation, which subsequently led to greater foreign direct investment. Still, problems persist in countries that dollarize, and the lack of an independent monetary policy makes it difficult to address fluctuations in the economy, especially when they differ from those of the United States. But for these countries and others that have dollarized their economies, the potential benefits outweigh the costs.
GO TO
TO PRACTICE THE ECONOMIC CONCEPTS IN THIS STORY
Still, the efforts of the ECB have not stopped European nations from voting to exit the Eurozone or the broader European Union. The European Union includes nations that do not use the euro including the United Kingdom (Britain), Sweden, Denmark, and several eastern European nations. In 2016, voters in Britain elected to leave the European Union in an unprecedented action coined Brexit, which caused uncertainty in financial markets and challenged the ability of the European Union and Eurozone to remain powerful influences in global markets. Today, most of the Eurozone countries that faced financial crises have recovered with some countries such as Ireland and Slovenia experiencing rapid economic growth. The exception is Greece, which continued to face challenges in 2016. But overall, economic growth remains tenuous throughout the region. This is not unlike the
563
recovery pattern experienced in the United States. In the United States, the housing market has mostly recovered, employment growth has been strong, stock markets have set new highs, and banks have strengthened their balance sheets. Still, as in Europe, problems such as deficits and weak growth remain, which means that the Fed will continue to rely on monetary tools to prevent problems from home and abroad from engulfing the economy. The next chapter is devoted to analyzing the major macroeconomic policy challenges involving both fiscal policy and monetary policy, allowing you to use the macroeconomic tools learned thus far to sketch out solutions.
CHECKPOINT NEW MONETARY POLICY CHALLENGES To control the financial panic of 2008, the Fed used its normal monetary policy tools and some that it hadn’t used in many decades. The European Central Bank is the Fed’s counterpart in Europe, setting the monetary policy for the nineteen-member Eurozone. A long and severe debt crisis occurred when several European nations neared default on their loans, requiring extraordinary actions, including bailout loans, by the ECB to keep the effects of the crisis from spreading to the entire Eurozone.
QUESTION: The collapse of the financial markets in late 2008 resulted in the Fed reducing interest rates to near 0%. Was it likely that the U.S. economy in 2009 sank into a Keynesian liquidity trap? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
564
chapter summary Section 1 What Is Monetary Policy? 13.1
Monetary policy is the process by which a country’s money supply is controlled to target interest rates that subsequently influences economic output and prices. Importance of Interest Rates on the Economy Higher interest rates affect aggregate demand by: 1. Making borrowing more expensive, forcing consumers and firms to cut spending and investing 2. Giving people more incentive to save than spend 3. Forcing the government to spend more on financing the national debt 4. Increasing the value of the U.S. dollar, making U.S. exports more expensive
Expansionary Monetary Policy: More money → lower interest rates → higher C, I, G, and (X − M) = increase in aggregate demand and output Contractionary Monetary Policy: Less money → higher interest rates → lower C, I, G, and (X − M) = decrease in aggregate demand and output
13.2
Twin Goals of Monetary Policy 1. Economic growth and full employment 2. Stable prices and moderate long-term interest rates
Bills, bills, bills. Higher interest rates cause debt payments to take a bigger portion of each paycheck, leaving less to spend on other goods.
565
Section 2 Monetary Theories 13.3
The quantity theory of money is a product of the classical school of thought, which concludes that the economy will tend toward equilibrium at full employment in the long run. Classical theorists do not believe that monetary policies are effective at all. Keynesians and monetarists believe that monetary policy can be effective in the short run, but not in the long run.
Keynesian Money Theory Increasing the money supply leads to greater investment when the economy is healthy. In times of severe recession, however, monetary policy is ineffective. Fiscal policy is the preferred approach to restore the economy.
John Maynard Keynes
13.4
Equation of Exchange (Classical Theory)
Because velocity (V) and output (Q) are believed to be fixed in the long run, any change in the money supply (M) results in a change in prices (P). Monetarist Theory Increasing the money supply reduces interest rates, which leads to greater consumption and investment. Monetary policy is therefore effective in the short run.
566
Fiscal policy is ineffective as it crowds out consumption and investment.
Milton Friedman
13.5
Demand Shocks Versus Supply Shocks Demand shocks affect the AD curve. Caused by factors such as consumer confidence, business sentiment, or export demand. Monetary policy is more effective because targeting one goal automatically targets the other.
Supply shocks affect the SRAS curve. Caused by factors such as changing input prices or technological innovation. Monetary policy is less effective because targeting one goal makes the other target worse.
Rising food prices cause a negative supply shock that is difficult to counteract with monetary policy.
Section 3 Modern Monetary Policy 567
13.6
Rules: Money grows by a fixed amount each year, preventing monetary policy from causing too drastic an effect because the economy is inherently stable in the long run. versus Discretion: A flexible money approach based on current economic conditions. It is useful in severe recessions when constant money growth might not be enough. Alternative to money targeting is inflation targeting: implementing policy to keep inflation at about 2% to faciliate long-term economic growth.
13.7
Taylor rule: Used to approximate the Fed’s actions on interest rates based on economic conditions: Fed Funds Rate Target = 2 + Inflation Rate + 1/2 (Inflation Gap) + 1/2(Output Gap)
Section 4 New Monetary Policy Challenges 13.8
The U.S. financial crisis in 2008 created a major challenge to the Fed, which had lowered the federal funds rate to near 0% but still faced an economy in deep recession. To continue expansionary monetary policy with interest rates at 0%, the Fed engaged in various quantitative easing strategies, including purchasing long-term assets from banks to expand the monetary base.
13.9
The nineteen member nations that form the Eurozone share a monetary policy set by the European Central Bank (ECB). In recent years, ECB has used aggressive monetary policy actions to prevent the effects of financial crises in individual nations from engulfing the entire region.
568
Protests on quantitative easing arose because people feared high potential inflation, which would reduce the value of money and savings.
KEY CONCEPTS expansionary monetary policy contractionary monetary policy equation of exchange money illusion liquidity trap easy money, quantitative easing, or accommodative monetary policy tight money or restrictive monetary policy monetary rule inflation targeting Taylor rule
QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS Check Your Understanding 1. Why is it important for the Federal Reserve Board to be independent of the executive branch of the federal government? 2. When the interest rate falls, why do people desire higher money balances? 3. Describe how open market operations alter the supply of money. 4. What does the equation of exchange, M × V = P × Q, help to explain? 5. How is the impact of expansionary monetary policy different when the economy is considerably below full employment than when it is at full employment? 6. How do sticky wages and prices make monetary policy effective in the short run?
Apply the Concepts 7. Suppose a rise in consumer confidence causes aggregate demand to increase, resulting in a short-run equilibrium that is above full employment output. What type of monetary policy might the Fed use to reduce inflationary pressures and to bring the economy back to full employment?
569
8. It seems that each time the Fed raises interest rates, the stock market has an awful few days. Why do higher interest rates have such an impact on the stock market? 9. If the Fed persistently pursues an easy money policy, what is the likely outcome? 10. When NASA scientists were operating the Mars rovers to get them to drive across the Martian landscape and collect and analyze rocks and crevices, the scientists complained that the 20-minute delay between when they issued a command and when the rovers responded made their job more challenging. Isn’t this somewhat similar to what monetary policymakers face? How is it different? 11. Suppose a devastating drought leads to higher food prices, causing a negative supply shock to occur. What type of monetary policy should the Fed use if the goal is to maintain price stability in the economy? What are the consequences of doing so? 12. Explain how the housing bubble at the beginning of the 21st century led to the Taylor rule target exceeding the actual federal funds rate. Could increasing the federal funds rate during this time have helped to reduce the severity of the last recession?
In the News 13. There are two forces that cause the economy to grow. One is real, the other is an illusion. The real force— entrepreneurial innovation and creativity—comes naturally as long as government policies do not drive it away. The artificial force is easy money. An increased supply of money, by creating an illusion of wealth, can increase spending in the short run, but this eventually turns into inflation. Printing money cannot possibly create wealth; if it could, counterfeiting would be legal.3 Does this quote illustrate the short-run versus the long-run aspects of monetary policy? Why or why not?
14. In 2016 Greece faced another set of hurdles in its ongoing saga of managing its debt. In order for Greece to maintain its obligations under the IMF and European Central Bank bailout packages, it must continue to cut government spending, particularly pensions that have put a strain on the budget. Greece’s leaders, meanwhile, have argued that the required spending cuts will push the economy back into recession. Using an AD/AS model, show what the required budget cuts might do to an economy that is still experiencing slow growth.
Solving Problems 15. Why are supply shocks so much harder than demand shocks for monetary policy to adjust? Use the grid below to show your answer to this question.
570
WORK IT OUT 16. In 2012 U.S. inflation was 2.1% and output was 4.8% below its long-run potential. Three years later, in 2015, U.S. inflation fell to 0.4% due to falling energy prices, and output improved to 1.8% below its long-run potential. a. b. c. d.
If the inflation target is 2%, what was the federal funds target in 2012 using the Taylor rule? If the actual federal funds rate was 0.1% in 2012, did the Taylor rule estimate the target accurately? Again assuming an inflation target of 2%, what was the federal funds target in 2015 using the Taylor rule? If the actual federal funds rate was 0.4% in 2015, did the Taylor rule do a better job predicting interest rates compared to 2012? Explain your answer.
USING THE NUMBERS 17. According to By the Numbers, what were the approximate interest rates for the following types of loans in December 2015: federal funds rate, discount rate, prime rate, 30-year mortgage rate? Why aren’t these interest rates all the same? 18. According to By the Numbers, in what region outside of the United States is the largest percentage of U.S. $100 bills in circulation held? Why is the answer not China, which holds the most U.S. debt?
ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS Checkpoint: What Is Monetary Policy? Expansionary monetary policy reduces interest rates in order to spur consumption and investment, leading to an increase in aggregate demand. A reduction in interest rates placed on student loans by the government, although
571
technically not monetary policy, produces a similar effect. When your monthly payments are reduced due to the interest rate reduction, you now have extra money to spend on other items. This extra consumption contributes to an increase in aggregate demand, much like an expansionary monetary policy. Checkpoint: Monetary Theories Those who prefer a large government role in the economy would best resemble Keynesians who believe in fiscal policy to increase aggregate demand. Keynesians would support raising tax revenues to reduce the debt. Those who advocate for a smaller government might be considered monetarists, who believe that fiscal policy tends to crowd out consumption and investment. Monetarists would support a reduction in spending to reduce the debt. Those who do not believe in either fiscal or monetary policy interventions might resemble classical theorists who believe that the economy should be left to market forces, and that the government should be as small as possible. Checkpoint: Modern Monetary Policy When the Fed begins to view inflation as a growing problem, it usually means that some form of contractionary monetary policy is to follow. This typically means that interest rates will rise and, most important for bond investors, bond prices will fall and bondholders will incur capital losses. Checkpoint: New Monetary Policy Challenges Reducing interest rates to low levels to stimulate credit and the economy was probably not sufficient by itself. But as consumer spending dropped off, businesses avoided new investments as markets declined or disappeared, suggesting that the economy may have been in a liquidity trap. Keynesian analysis got the nod from policymakers with the $787 billion fiscal stimulus package passed in 2009. 1
The original Taylor rule used logarithms to measure the output gap. For simplicity, we use the percentage difference between current and potential GDP. 2
William Poole, “Fed Transparency: How, Not Whether,” The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Review, November/December 2003, p. 5. 3
Brian Wesbury, “Economic Rehab,” The Wall Street Journal, June 7, 2006, p. A14.
572
14
Macroeconomic Policy: Challenges in a Global Economy
573
Understanding the obstacles facing our economy and the policy tools that are 574
available to overcome them
Learning Objectives 14.1
Describe what caused the housing bubble and the financial crisis.
14.2
Describe the extraordinary steps that Congress and the Fed took to prevent the collapse of the financial system.
14.3
Explain what Phillips curves are and what relationship they postulate between inflation and unemployment.
14.4
Describe how inflationary expectations can take on a life of their own and stymie policymakers.
14.5
Contrast adaptive expectations with rational expectations and describe their implications for policymakers.
14.6
Describe the major economic issues facing the macroeconomy today and in the future.
14.7
Discuss why jobless recoveries have become the norm following recessions.
14.8
Discuss the role that globalization has in the economy and how it affects macroeconomic policy.
B
etween 2003 and 2007, the U.S. housing market achieved gains at a rate never before seen in its history. As soon as a house or condo was put on the market, buyers were eager to snatch it up. Banks were eager to lend to these buyers and bent over backward to accommodate them, even lowering standards if need be. If
they did not, other banks were ready to jump in. The upshot: new types of loans targeted borrowers who otherwise would not have qualified for conventional loans. And the government facilitated the process by keeping interest rates low. These factors provided incentives for individuals and firms to consume and produce. Luxury condominiums were built throughout the country, especially in popular vacation destinations such as Miami, Phoenix, and Las Vegas. New housing developments formed, each adding hundreds or thousands of homes with the expectation that buyers would come. And they did, helped by banks that became even more aggressive in their lending, advertising attractive mortgages that required no down payment, interest-only payments, and little to no credit. Over this period, average home prices in the United States increased by 41%. In Nevada and Arizona, home prices rose by almost 80%. The growth in the housing market spurred other industries, such as home furnishings, insurance, and even automobiles. Individuals were eager to buy, developers were eager to build, banks were eager to lend, and investors were eager to put money in securities backed by the value of housing. Unfortunately, the house of cards eventually collapsed in late 2007. The financial crisis that ensued led to a restricted lending market, a severe recession, and a long jobless recovery.
575
What does macroeconomics have to say about the effects of a deep economic recession and a slow economic recovery? Quite a bit, actually. We have seen in previous chapters how the Fed and the federal government intervene in markets to promote long-term economic growth and stability in employment and prices. But this is much harder than it might appear to be: There is no magic formula easily discernible to all that will correct each problem. Before the 1930s, common wisdom was that the economy was best left alone. The Great Depression changed that, and ever since then the government’s role in economic stabilization—smoothing the business cycle—expanded substantially. This chapter studies the economic policies that address the macroeconomic issues facing the world today: slow economic growth, rising debt, long-run inflation, and persistent unemployment. One challenge is the existence of a potential tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. Another is the potential tradeoff between debt reduction and economic growth. These potential tradeoffs influence the macroeconomic policies chosen to guide the economy. The chapter begins with a broad overview of the factors leading to the 2007–2009 Great Recession (as it is now known) and the slow recovery. The chapter then studies several theories regarding the effectiveness of macroeconomic policy, including the Phillips curve on the potential tradeoff between unemployment and inflation, the rational expectations argument about the ultimate ineffectiveness of policy, and the new Keynesian response.
576
577
Finally, we discuss the economic issues that influence the future of our economy. We focus on the effects of jobless recoveries, rising debt, and globalization. We use the macroeconomic tools discussed throughout the book to analyze how economic policies affect our economy and our standard of living.
578
THE GREAT RECESSION AND MACROECONOMIC POLICY The 18-month recession that lasted from December 2007 to July 2009 was dubbed the Great Recession, not because of its length, which was not much longer than the typical recession, but rather for its severity and the impact it had on so many industries and countries. Further, the economic recovery that took place after the recession was slow, requiring many years for economic indicators to return to their prerecession levels. This section presents the factors that led to the Great Recession and the macroeconomic policies used to mitigate its effects.
From the Housing Bubble to the Financial Crisis
Owning a home is a dream shared by most people. During the first few years of the 21st century, a glut in worldwide savings and the Fed’s aggressive expansionary monetary policies following the 2001 recession led to low mortgage rates, helping many to achieve that dream of home ownership. Renters bought their first homes. Existing homeowners moved into larger homes or bought second homes. The resulting higher than normal demand drove up the price of housing. After a few years of rising prices, people started to think prices could only go up. This led some people to become speculators, which led to house “flipping”—purchasing a home with the intention of selling it as soon as possible for a tidy profit. Builders provide homes, but usually a third party brings the transaction to a close. A financial intermediary provides the financing for home buyers in the form of a mortgage. Traditionally, the standard is a 30-year mortgage with a fixed interest rate. The person taking out the mortgage to purchase the home made monthly payments, which consisted of interest on the loan and some payment toward the loan amount (the principal). Financial intermediaries, such as banks, usually had high standards that would-be home buyers had to meet. First homes, bigger homes, and second homes were the goals of many Americans during the housing bubble of the early 21st century.
This changed at the beginning of the new century, as banks eager to cash in on the lucrative housing market made loans easier to obtain. And, as long as housing prices kept rising, the borrower’s collateral (the house) would protect
579
the bank from losing money if the loan could not be repaid. Financial intermediaries encouraged home buying by offering adjustable-rate mortgages (ARMs). These mortgages offered a below-market interest rate for a short period (usually three or five years); the rate would then adjust based on the market interest rate. From a buyer’s point of view, a below-market rate, at least in the short term, was an inducement to buy. From a bank’s point of view, belowmarket rates generated business: They could expect ARM holders to seek out fixed interest rate mortgages after the initial period ended, which meant a second round of origination fees (paid whenever a mortgage is taken out). The housing boom of 2003 to 2007 saw even more innovations in the mortgage market, as financial intermediaries felt competitive pressure from new mortgage brokers and Wall Street firms that were only too happy to meet the growing demand. Two key things happened: Mortgage credit standards fell, and the market for collateralized debt obligations (CDOs) developed.
Subprime Mortgages and Collateralized Debt Obligations
Subprime mortgages are loans made to borrowers with poor credit. These loans carried high interest rates that were profitable for the banks as long as borrowers made payments on time. Because the economy was strong, defaults were minimal. Further, many financial institutions reduced their risk by selling these loans to other investors in the form of CDOs, also known as mortgage-backed securities (which make up most CDOs). subprime mortgage Mortgages that are given to borrowers who are a poor credit risk. These higher-risk loans charge a higher interest rate, which can be profitable to lenders if borrowers make their payments on time.
CDOs are essentially bonds backed by a collection of mortgages: prime, subprime, home equity, and other ARMs. Banks holding mortgages found they could offset the risk of default by selling them to consolidators who put together enormous packages of CDOs, with the mortgaged homes standing as the collateral behind the security offered. Wall Street then sold off slices of these mortgage pools to investors interested in the steady income from mortgage payments. Mortgages to subprime borrowers—those with higher credit risks—could be combined with solid mortgages, a little like diluting poison in a large lake to dissipate its effects. Banks and mortgage companies now were evaluating mortgage clients for loans that they did not intend to keep. They were simply collecting an origination fee and then immediately selling the mortgage to Wall Street. What in the past had been a long-term investment for banks and mortgage companies became nothing more than a business of advertising and selling loans quickly. Because Wall Street could package and sell as many loans as mortgage brokers could provide, banks had less incentive to keep high lending standards. Risk was being transferred elsewhere. Trouble started in 2007 when some of the people who took on subprime mortgages started to default. These people were stretched too thin. When their ARMs reset, they faced higher payments, sometimes double or triple the original monthly payments. Worse, the spike in foreclosures as well as homeowners trying to sell their homes to escape rising mortgage payments caused the value of houses to fall, which meant that borrowers wishing to refinance their homes (to make mortgage payments affordable again) were being turned away because the amount they were seeking to borrow exceeded the value of their now lower-value home. Compounding this, another problem arose. Risk ratings by bond rating agencies whose job it is to rate packages of mortgages turned out to be faulty. Wall Street knew the minimum requirements needed for a rating agency to assign a AAA rating to a CDO, and they manipulated the components to get that all-important rating. Also, rating firms were paid 6 times their normal fee to give the AAA rating to the mortgage packages, and were only paid if the CDO got the AAA rating, giving ratings agencies an incentive to lower standards. Investors wanted bonds with the security of a AAA rating, which gave the appearance of high-yield, low-risk investments. The bond packages sold well all over the world. The risk of each CDO was underestimated because of the overly rosy ratings. Two more problems would make this a growing house of cards. Because the mortgage packages were seen as low-risk investments, many investors borrowed money at the low prevailing interest rates to purchase greater quantities. They leveraged their capital to earn greater returns. But with leverage comes additional risk: A small drop in prices can easily wipe out a highly leveraged account. Table 1 shows how a leveraged investment magnifies the risk of losing money. In this case, a 10% drop in value of the security wipes out the leveraged account, while the nonleveraged account sees its value drop by just 10%. A leveraged account magnifies both gains and losses. leverage Occurs when a small amount of capital is used to support a larger amount of investment by borrowing. The risk of highly leveraged investments is that a small decrease in price can wipe out one’s
580
account.
TABLE 1
THE MAGNIFIED RISK OF LEVERAGED INVESTMENTS
Nonleveraged Investment
Leveraged Investment
Initial account value: $10,000
Initial account value: $10,000
Leverage ratio: 1:1
Leverage ratio: 10:1
Value of invested assets: $10,000 ($10,000 × 1)
Value of invested assets: $100,000 ($10,000 × 10)
Event: 10% drop in invested assets
Event: 10% drop in invested assets
Drop in value of investment: $1,000 ($10,000 × 10%)
Drop in value of investment: $10,000 ($100,000 × 10%)
New account value: $9,000
New account value: $0
To protect against this risk, investors purchased credit default swaps, an instrument developed by the financial industry to act as an insurance policy against defaults. The biggest issuer of credit default swaps, the American International Group (AIG), sold several trillion dollars of these swaps with only a few billion dollars in capital to back them up. Here again, we see risk underestimated and therefore mispriced. credit default swap A financial instrument that insures against the potential default on an asset. Because of the extent of defaults in the last financial crisis, issuers of credit default swaps could not repay all of the claims, bankrupting these financial institutions.
Collapsing Financial Markets
This brings us to the central event that brought down the financial system. By 2007, $25 trillion of American CDOs were in investment portfolios of banks, pension funds, mutual funds, hedge funds, and other financial institutions worldwide. The rate of subprime mortgage defaults skyrocketed, and because investors did not know what exactly was in their CDOs, they panicked. Consequently, buyers of CDOs evaporated, and prices fell as people began dumping CDOs at fire-sale prices. AIG could not cover the losses it had insured and went bankrupt. For banks, this was a catastrophe. Their CDOs were virtually worthless, and an important part of the banks’ capital was wiped out. To raise capital, banks called in loans and reduced lines of credit to businesses, which reduced the money supply, contracted the economy, caused job losses, and deepened the recession. The collapse of the housing market forced many homeowners out of their homes and contributed to the severity of the 2007–2009 recession.
581
In sum, the financial crisis was caused by a savings glut that led to low interest rates, which fueled a housing boom that led to new financial instruments and investment securities that depended on the value of housing staying high. A financial house of cards was created, and when one card at the bottom (subprime loans) lost strength, the entire edifice fell. Because all types of financial institutions worldwide were investors in CDOs, credit dried up, creating a credit crisis that precipitated a worldwide recession.
The Government’s Policy Response As long as the financial system takes on risks that it misperceives, we will have financial crises. Let’s look at the government’s policy response to the financial crisis: Bear Stearns: In July 2007 Bear Stearns, a large Wall Street investment bank, liquidated two hedge funds that invested in mortgage-backed securities as they started to collapse. By March 2008, with Bear Stearns on the verge of bankruptcy due to its holdings of mortgage-backed securities, the Fed engineered a takeover of Bear Stearns by Chase Bank. In essence, the Fed bailed out a rogue bank. This kept a lid on things for a while, but not for long. Lehman Brothers: Stung by criticism of its Bear Stearns bailout, the Fed let Lehman Brothers, the fourth largest commercial bank, fail on September 15, 2008. The Fed and the Treasury thought they were sending a message to the financial markets that imprudent lending behavior would result in tremendous costs to stockholders and executives. Unfortunately, this decision sent the financial markets into a tailspin, as banks lost faith in other banks, and insolvencies rose throughout the financial sector. AIG: The market received another shock in September when AIG announced it was bankrupt. The news of its bankruptcy turned AAA-rated CDO bonds into highly discounted junk bonds. To stem the panic, the Fed lent AIG over $100 billion. TARP: In October 2008 Congress responded to the crisis by passing the $700 billion Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP), authorizing the U.S. Treasury to purchase CDOs from banks to shore up their capital. The U.S. Treasury ended up investing in banks by injecting government money for preferred equity (stock), thereby increasing bank capital and eliminating insolvency. Public Concerns: Policymakers were concerned about public confidence in banks and worried that depositors might begin withdrawing funds, putting banks at further risk of failure. The Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) increased its guarantee on deposits from $100,000 to $250,000 per account. The 2009 Stimulus Package: One of President Obama’s initial pieces of legislation in his first term was passing the $787 billion American Recovery and Reinvestment Act, a fiscal policy aimed to boost aggregate demand following the financial crisis and recession. Industry Bailouts: The financial crisis had also depressed consumer demand, which led many industries to face
582
collapse. In 2009 the government loaned significant sums of money to General Motors, Chrysler, and Ford to save the U.S. automobile industry. Today, the U.S. automobile industry is profitable and strong: In 2015 each of the three major automobile companies made substantial profits and combined earned a record profit of $19.1 billion. Fed’s Quantitative Easing (QE) Programs: Over the next several years, the Fed would continue to buy mortgage-backed securities in order to remove these risky assets from bank balance sheets. The effort was unprecedented, with the Fed accumulating over $1.7 trillion in mortgage-backed securities by 2014 when QE ended. These extraordinary efforts prevented the widespread bank failures that had plagued the economy during the Great Depression and during the savings and loan crisis in the 1980s. For the Fed, it was crucial to maintain public confidence and keep the recession from becoming a full-blown depression. The Fed stepped far outside of its usual role of managing the money supply, interest rates, inflation, and unemployment, and took extraordinary, lender-oflast-resort measures to prevent a financial sector meltdown. This brief summary of the government’s response during the financial crisis outlines the breadth and depth of fiscal and monetary policies designed to avert a catastrophe. They have succeeded, but the cost may not be known for a decade.
The Financial Crisis and Its Effects The financial crisis that resulted in the 2007–2009 recession was the most serious downturn in the economy in over a generation. And the speed by which the economy deteriorated was alarming. The recession began at the end of 2007 and accelerated in 2008 until the middle of 2009. Real GDP declined by over 4% and unemployment reached 10% of the labor force. At the onset of the financial crisis, jobs were cut as consumers reduced their spending. They tightened their belts in an effort to reduce household debt levels and hunkered down for what they perceived as a severe recession on the way. As a result, 7 million people lost their jobs during this two-year period. Job losses reduced consumer confidence, further reducing consumer spending and aggregate demand. As demand dropped, businesses reduced their production capacity through layoffs and plant closings, shifting short-run aggregate supply leftward. Toward the end of the recession, prices began to fall as deflation set in for most of 2009. We have spent a considerable time in this book studying the harmful effects of inflation, yet now the economy faced deflation. Deflation can be a problem because it increases the real value of existing debt, making the debt more burdensome and requiring more purchasing power to make interest payments or pay off the debt. Policymakers faced the problem of preventing debt from becoming a more serious burden on households, which would further reduce aggregate demand and deepen the recession. The tools we learned about in previous chapters helped us to understand how the government managed the last financial crisis and the accompanying recession. Let’s take a further step, adding some challenges to the effective use of policy to smooth the business cycle. The next section focuses on the effectiveness of macroeconomic policy by considering the Phillips curve, which proposes a tradeoff between unemployment and inflation. If this tradeoff exists, policymaking becomes simple: Pick some rate of unemployment and face a corresponding rate of inflation. We also look at how the rational expectations model questions whether using macroeconomic policy to correct fluctuations in the business cycle can ever be effective at all.
CHECKPOINT THE GREAT RECESSION AND MACROECONOMIC POLICY A world savings glut and low interest rates from 2003–2007 led to a housing price bubble. Consumers were eager to buy homes, developers were eager to build them, banks were eager to lend money to purchasers, and investors were eager to invest in CDOs. Financial risk was not properly accounted for in the period leading up to the financial crisis, and ratings agencies gave too many CDOs a AAA rating that wasn’t deserved.
583
When the housing bubble collapsed, foreclosures on subprime mortgages sent the economy into a recession. To control the panic, the Fed used its normal monetary policy tools and some that it hadn’t used since the 1930s in its role as lender of last resort. Congress used fiscal policy in an attempt to nullify the drop in aggregate demand caused by the financial crisis.
QUESTION: The U.S. housing bubble in the early 21st century was caused by a number of factors that
provided incentives to individuals to buy houses, to businesses to build and sell houses, and to financial institutions to loan money. In hindsight, what are some policies that the government could have implemented to mitigate this housing bubble? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
584
EFFECTIVENESS OF MACROECONOMIC POLICY: PHILLIPS CURVES AND RATIONAL EXPECTATIONS The persistent unemployment that occurred after the 2007–2009 recession in what is known as a jobless recovery had economists debating the right policy to use. Fiscal policy was undertaken to boost market activity, at the cost of rising debt. And significant monetary policy actions were taken to inject the economy with more money, at the cost of potential inflation. Questions that arise from these policies include whether the effort to reduce unemployment could result in higher inflation, or whether macroeconomic policy has any short-term effects at all. We address these issues in this section by studying two theories developed in the 1950s and 1960s: the Phillips curve and rational expectations. With Phillips curve analysis, it first seemed that fiscal policy was easy: Pick an unemployment rate from column A and get a corresponding inflation rate from column B. Unfortunately, reality turned out to be much more complex. With rational expectations, the question was whether policy could ever be effective at all.
Unemployment and Inflation: Phillips Curves
Does a relationship exist between unemployment and inflation? In his early work, A. W. Phillips compared the rate of change in money wages to unemployment rates in Britain over the years 1861 to 1957. The negatively sloped curve shown in Figure 1 reflects his estimate of how these variables were related and has been called a Phillips curve in his honor. As you can see, when unemployment rises, wage rates fall. Phillips curve The original curve posited a negative relationship between wages and unemployment, but later versions related unemployment to inflation rates.
What explains this negative relationship between wages and unemployment? Labor costs or wages are typically a firm’s largest cost component. As the demand for labor rises, labor markets will tighten, making it difficult for employers to fill vacant positions. Hence, wages rise as firms bid up the price of labor to attract more workers. The opposite happens when labor demand falls: Unemployment rises and wages decline. This relationship can be seen in specific industries that have seen spikes or downturns in employment. For example, demand for health care professionals increased in the past decade, reducing unemployment in the industry. Those who pursue a career in nursing, medicine, or other health-related fields saw their salaries increase relative to those in other careers. On the other hand, the collapse of the financial and housing sectors forced many realtors, loan specialists, and construction workers out of work. Those lucky enough to find work often made less than they did during the housing boom. FIGURE 1
THE ORIGINAL PHILLIPS CURVE FOR BRITAIN (1861–1957)
585
A. W. Phillips compared the rate of change in money wages to unemployment rates in Britain from 1861 to 1957. The resulting nonlinear, negatively sloped curve is the first example of a Phillips curve. When unemployment rises, wage rates fall, and vice versa. Note that some dots represent multiple years.
The market relationship between wages and unemployment will clearly affect prices. But worker productivity also plays an important role in determining prices.
Productivity, Prices, and Wages
We might think that whenever wages rise, prices must also rise. Higher wages mean higher labor costs for employers —costs that businesses then pass along as higher prices. But this is not always the case. If worker productivity increases enough to offset the wage increase, then product prices can remain stable. The basic relationship among wages, prices, and productivity is Inflation = Increase in Nominal Wages − Rate of Increase in Labor Productivity For example, when wages increase by 5% and productivity increases by 3%, inflation is 2%. Given this relationship, the Phillips curve can be adapted to relate productivity to inflation and unemployment, as shown in Figure 2. Notice that when the rates of change in productivity and wages are equal, inflation is zero (point a). This occurs at the natural rate of unemployment, the unemployment rate when inflationary pressures are nonexistent. Therefore, higher rates of productivity growth mean that for a given level of unemployment, inflation will be less (the Phillips curve would shift in toward the origin). If policymakers want to use expansionary policy to reduce unemployment from un to u1, then according to the curve shown in Figure 2, they must be willing to accept inflation of p1. To reduce unemployment further to u2 would raise inflation to p2 as labor markets tightened and wages rose more rapidly. Figure 3 shows the Phillips curve for the United States during the 1960s. Notice the nearly smooth negative
586
relationship between the two variables, much like that in the last two figures. As unemployment fell, inflation rose. This empirical relationship led policymakers to believe that the economy presents them with a menu of choices. By accepting a minor rise in inflation, they could keep unemployment low. Alternatively, by accepting a rise in unemployment, they could keep inflation near zero. FIGURE 2
THE PHILLIPS CURVE
A rise in wages may cause a rise in prices, but if worker productivity increases sufficiently to offset the wage increase, product prices can remain stable. When the rates of change in productivity and wages are equal, inflation is zero (point a). This is the natural rate of unemployment. If policymakers want to use expansionary policy to reduce unemployment from un to u1, they must be willing to accept inflation of p1. Reducing unemployment further to u2 would raise inflation to p2 as labor markets tighten and wages rise more rapidly than productivity.
FIGURE 3
THE PHILLIPS CURVE—1960s
587
The Phillips curve for the United States during the 1960s gives a negative relationship between inflation and unemployment, much like that found in the last two figures. Using this relationship, policymakers concluded that an inflation rate of 3% to 4% was required to keep unemployment below 4%.
But just as policymakers were getting used to the ease of making policy by accepting moderate inflation in exchange for lower unemployment rates, the economy played a big trick on them. As Figure 4 shows, the entire Phillips curve began shifting outward during the early 1970s. What looked to be an easy tradeoff between inflation and unemployment turned ugly. Unemployment rates that, in the 1960s, had been associated with modest inflation of 2% to 3% quickly began requiring twice that rate in the early 1970s. By the late 1970s, these same unemployment rates were generating annual inflation rates approaching double digits. The reason for these shifts turned out to be the oil supply shocks of the mid-1970s and the rising inflationary expectations that followed.
The Importance of Inflationary Expectations
Workers do not work for the sake of earning a specific dollar amount, or a specific nominal wage. Rather, they work for the sake of earning what those wages will buy—for real wages. Consequently, when they bargain for wage increases, workers will take their past experiences with inflation into account. Taking inflationary expectations into account, wage increases can be connected to unemployment and expected inflation by adding a variable, pe, representing inflationary expectations, to the inflation equation introduced earlier: Inflation = Increase in Nominal Wages − Rate of Increase in Labor Productivity + Pe inflationary expectations The rate of inflation expected by workers for any given period. Workers do not work for a specific nominal wage but for what those wages will buy (real wages); therefore, their inflationary expectations are an important determinant of what nominal wage they are willing to work for. FIGURE 4
THE PHILLIPS CURVE FROM 1961–1981: INSTABILITY AND SUPPLY SHOCKS
588
Just as policymakers were getting accustomed to accepting moderate inflation in exchange for lower unemployment rates, the economy surprised them. The entire Phillips curve began shifting outward during the early 1970s. Unemployment rates that, in the 1960s, had been associated with modest inflation of 2% to 3% quickly began requiring twice that rate. The inflation-unemployment tradeoff worsened throughout the 1970s and into the early 1980s, largely due to oil price shocks and rising inflationary expectations. Inflation and unemployment continued to rise, creating stagflation. By 1980 annual inflation was over 10%, and unemployment was over 7%.
In other words, the same tradeoff between inflation and unemployment in the short-run Phillips curve existed as we saw before, but there is a unique tradeoff for each level of inflationary expectations. For example, suppose there are no inflationary expectations, and productivity is growing at a 3% rate when the economy’s unemployment rate is 4%. In this scenario, if nominal wages increase by 5%, inflation would be 5% − 3% + 0% = 2%. However, if inflationary expectations (pe) grow to, say, 4%, the Phillips curve will shift outward and the inflation rate now associated with 4% unemployment will be 5% − 3% + 4% = 6%.
Inflationary Expectations and the Phillips Curve
Panel B of Figure 5 shows a Phillips curve augmented by inflationary expectations. The economy begins in equilibrium at full employment with zero inflation (point a in panel B). Panel A shows the aggregate demand and supply curves for this economy in equilibrium at point a. Note that the economy is producing at full employment output of Qf, and this translates to the natural rate of unemployment, un, in panel B.
The Phillips curve in panel B is initially PC0 (pe = 0%). Thus, inflation is equal to zero and so are inflationary
expectations (pe). Now assume, however, that policymakers are unhappy with the economy’s performance and want to reduce unemployment below un. Using expansionary policies, they shift aggregate demand in panel A from AD0 to AD1. This moves the economy to point b; real output and the price level rise, to Q1 and P1. In panel B, meanwhile, the unemployment rate has declined to u1 (point b), but inflation has risen to 5%.
589
Workers had anticipated zero inflation; this unanticipated inflation means that real wages have fallen. Therefore, workers will begin asking for raises, and employers wanting to keep turnover at a minimum may well begin offering higher wages.
The Long-Run Phillips Curve
The long-run Phillips curve (LRPC), shown in panel B of Figure 5 as the vertical line at full employment (unemployment = un), shows the long-term relationship between inflation and unemployment when the inflation rate and the expected inflation rate are equal. The LRPC is the Phillips curve counterpart to the vertical long-run aggregate supply curve (LRAS) in panel A. FIGURE 5
AGGREGATE DEMAND, AGGREGATE SUPPLY, AND THE EXPECTATIONS-AUGMENTED PHILLIPS CURVE
Panel A shows the economy’s aggregate demand and supply curves, and panel B shows the economy’s Phillips curve, augmented by inflationary expectations. Using expansionary policies to reduce unemployment below un, policymakers shift aggregate demand in panel A from AD0 to AD1. This moves the economy to point b, with real output and the price level rising to Q1 and P1. Unemployment declines to u1 (point b in panel B), but inflation rises to something approaching 5%. If policymakers attempt to hold unemployment below the natural rate, the economy will endure accelerating inflation. The long-run Phillips curve (LRPC) in panel B shows the relationship between inflation and unemployment when the inflation rate is just equal to inflationary expectations.
Accelerating Inflation
As nominal wages rise, the result in panel A is that, over time, the short-run aggregate supply curve shifts leftward to SRAS1, thus moving the economy back to full employment at point c. In panel B, with inflation now running at 5%,
the Phillips curve shifts outward to PC1 (pe = 5%). Workers, however, now expect 5% inflation, and the economy moves back to point c. Unemployment has moved back to its natural rate, but inflationary expectations have risen to 5%. The aggregate price level, meanwhile, has risen from P0 to P2, or 5%. At this point, in order for policymakers to move the economy back to u1 (or Q1), they must repeat the process of expanding aggregate demand, only this time, the economy is starting from a higher Phillips curve because inflationary expectations are already elevated.
590
The implications of this analysis for fiscal and monetary policymakers who want to fine-tune the economy and keep unemployment below the natural rate are not pleasant. If policymakers want to keep unemployment below the natural rate, they must continually increase aggregate demand so that inflation will always exceed what is expected. Thus, policymakers must be willing to incur a permanently accelerating rate of inflation—hardly a popular idea. An oil crisis in the late 1970s caused inflation to spike and unemployment to rise, creating what economists call stagflation.
In the late 1970s and early 1980s, oil price shocks and rising inflationary expectations caused both inflation and unemployment to rise, creating what economists call stagflation. Where under the original Phillips curve the conclusion was that rising unemployment would be met by falling inflation, the 1970s witnessed rising unemployment and rising inflation as the Phillips curve shifted outward. By 1980 inflation was over 10% and unemployment was over 7%. stagflation Simultaneous occurrence of rising inflation and rising unemployment.
Returning Inflation to Normal Levels
To eliminate inflationary pressures when they arise, policymakers must be willing to curtail growth in aggregate demand and accept the resulting higher rates of unemployment for a certain transition period. How long it takes to reduce inflation and return to the natural rate of unemployment will depend on how rapidly the economy adjusts its inflationary expectations. Policymakers can speed this process along by ensuring their policies are credible, for instance, by issuing public announcements that are consistent with contractionary policies in both the monetary and fiscal realms. To reduce inflationary expectations, policymakers must be willing to reduce aggregate demand and push the economy into a recession, increasing unemployment. As aggregate demand slumps, wage and price pressures will soften, reducing inflationary expectations. As these expectations decline, the Phillips curve shifts inward, back to a position with lower inflation at the natural rate of unemployment. How fast this occurs depends on the severity of the recession and the confidence the public has that policymakers are willing to stay the course. The stagflation of the early 1980s required almost a decade to be resolved. Former Fed Chair Paul Volcker, who
591
insisted on keeping interest rates high in the face of fierce public opposition, deserves much of the credit for this triumph over inflation. This lesson about the importance of restraining monetary growth and focusing on stable prices was not lost on the next Fed Chair, Alan Greenspan. Throughout the 1990s, the Fed maintained a tight watch on inflation, which fell from around 4% to near 1%. The importance of keeping inflation low has continued to influence policymaking today. As long as the threat of inflation remains low, policymakers have been willing to use expansionary policy to promote economic growth and reduce unemployment, exactly what the Phillips curve suggests would be effective. These policies assume that inflation expectations adjust with a noticeable lag, allowing some tradeoff between inflation and unemployment to exist. Some economists, however, argue that consumers and businesses adapt their expectations so rapidly that their behavior tends to nullify much of policymakers’ actions, which we will discuss next.
ROBERT LUCAS
NOBEL PRIZE I
n the 1970s, a series of articles by Robert E. Lucas changed the course of contemporary macroeconomic theory and profoundly influenced the economic policies of governments throughout the world. His development of the rational expectations theory challenged decades of assumptions about how individuals respond to changes in fiscal and monetary policies. Lucas was born in 1937 in Yakima, Washington. At age 17, he was awarded a scholarship to the University of Chicago, where he studied history. He then went on to the University of California, Berkeley, to pursue a Ph.D. in history, but while there he developed a keen interest in economics. Without funding from Berkeley’s Economics Department, he returned to the University of Chicago, where he earned his Ph.D. in 1964. One of his professors was Milton Friedman, whose skepticism about interventionist government policies influenced a generation of economists. Lucas began his teaching career at Carnegie-Mellon University and later became a professor at the University of Chicago. Before Lucas, economists accepted the Keynesian idea that expansionary policies could lower the unemployment rate. Lucas, however, argued that the rational expectations of individual workers and employers would adjust to the changing inflationary conditions, and unemployment rates would rise again. Lucas developed mathematical models to show that temporarily cutting taxes to increase spending was not a sound policy because individuals would base their decisions on expectations about the future, and these temporary tax cuts would find their way into savings and not added spending. In other words, individuals were rational, forward-thinking, and perfectly able to adapt to changing economic information. When the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences awarded Lucas the Nobel Prize in 1995, it credited Lucas with “the greatest influence on macroeconomic research since 1970.”
Rational Expectations and Policy Formation
The use of expectations in economic analysis is nothing new. Keynes believed that expectations are driven by emotions. He suggested that investors in the stock market will jump on board trends without attempting to understand the underlying market dynamics. Milton Friedman developed his model of expectations using what are known as adaptive expectations, whereby people are assumed to perform a simple extrapolation from past events. Workers, for example, are assumed to expect that past rates of inflation, averaged over some time period, will continue into the future. Adaptive expectations are represented by a backward-looking model of expectations, which contrasts with the rational expectations model.
592
adaptive expectations Inflationary expectations are formed from a simple extrapolation from past events.
In the rational expectations model developed by Robert Lucas, rational economic agents are assumed to make the best possible use of all publicly available information about what the future holds before making decisions. This does not mean that every individual’s predictions about the future will be correct. Those errors that do occur will be randomly distributed, such that the expectations of large numbers of people will average out to be correct. rational expectations Rational economic agents are assumed to make the best possible use of all publicly available information, then make informed, rational judgments on what the future holds. Any errors in their forecasts will be randomly distributed.
Assume that the economy has been in an equilibrium state for several years with low inflation (2%) and unemployment (6%). In such a stable environment, the average person would expect the inflation rate to stay right about where it is indefinitely. But now assume that the Fed announces it is going to increase the rate of growth of the money supply significantly. Basic economic theory tells us that this action will translate into higher prices, bringing about higher future inflation rates. Knowing this, households and businesses will revise their inflationary expectations upward. As this example shows, people do not rely only on past experiences to formulate their expectations of the future, but instead use all information available to them, including current policy announcements and other information that gives them reason to believe the future might hold certain changes. If adaptive expectations are backward-looking, rational expectations are forward-looking.
Policy Implications of Rational Expectations
Do individuals and firms really form their future expectations as the rational expectations hypothesis suggests? If so, the implications for macroeconomic policy would be enormous; indeed, it could leave macroeconomic policy ineffective. To illustrate, let us assume that the economy depicted in Figure 6 is operating at full employment at point a. Short-run aggregate supply curve SRAS0 (P = 100) reflects current inflationary expectations. Suppose the Fed announces that it intends to increase the money supply. Expanding the money supply will shift aggregate demand from AD0 to AD1. This will increase the demand for labor and raise nominal wages. But what happens next? Natural rate theorists, using adaptive expectations, would argue that workers will be fooled into thinking that the increase in money wages represents a real raise, thus driving output and employment up to $16 trillion (point b). After a time, however, workers will realize that real wages have not risen because prices have risen by at least as much as wages. Aggregate supply will then fall to SRAS1 (P = 110) as price expectations climb and the economy gradually moves back to full employment at a higher price level (point c). In this scenario, the Fed’s policy succeeds in raising output and employment in the short term, but at the expense of a long-term rise in the cost of living. FIGURE 6
RATIONAL EXPECTATIONS: THE POLICY INEFFECTIVENESS HYPOTHESIS
593
Rational expectations theory suggests that macroeconomic policy will be ineffective, even in the short term. Assume that the economy is operating at full employment (point a) and short-run aggregate supply curve SRAS0 (P = 100). Now suppose that the Fed announces that it intends to increase the money supply. Expanding the money supply will shift aggregate demand from AD0 to AD1, and this will increase the demand for labor and raise nominal wages. Yet, as soon as the Fed announces it is going to increase the money supply, rational economic agents will use this information immediately to raise their inflationary expectations. Thus, output will remain unchanged, though the price level rises immediately to 110.
Contrast this with the rational expectations model. When the Fed announces that it is going to increase the money supply, perfectly rational individuals and firms will listen to this information and immediately raise their inflationary expectations. In Figure 6, output will remain unchanged because the price level will rise immediately to 110. No one gets fooled into temporarily increasing output or employment, even though the increase in the money supply still drives up prices. Therefore, any announcement of a policy change will result in an immediate move to a new long-run equilibrium, leaving the short-term aspects of the policy change ineffective. This suggests that if the Fed wants to use an increase in the money supply to raise output and employment in the short term, the only way it can do so is by not announcing its plans; it must essentially force individuals and firms to make decisions with substantially incomplete information.
A Critique of Rational Expectations
To date, empirical assessments of the ineffectiveness of macroeconomic policy based on rational expectations have yielded mixed results. In general, these studies do not support the policy ineffectiveness proposition. That is, macroeconomic policies do have a real impact on the economy, and monetary policies are credited with keeping inflation low over the past three decades. New Keynesian economists have taken a different approach to critiquing rational expectations theory. Both the adaptive and the rational expectations models assume that labor and product markets are highly competitive, with wages and prices adjusting quickly to expansionary or contractionary policies. The new Keynesians point out, however, that labor markets are often beset with imperfect information, and that efficiency wages often bring about short-term wage stickiness.
594
Imperfect information occurs when firms and workers do not have up-to-the-minute information on economic fluctuations due to timing lags, causing wages and prices to not react quickly. Efficiency wage theory disputes the notion that labor markets are like competitive commodity markets with equal prices. In other words, all labor is not equal. People need incentives to work hard, and paying workers an efficiency wage, or a wage above the marketclearing level, is one form of motivation to improve morale and productivity. efficiency wage theory Employers often pay their workers wages above the market-clearing level to improve morale and productivity, reduce turnover, and create a disincentive for employees to shirk their duties.
Imperfect information and efficiency wages suggest that wages and prices may be sticky because workers and firms are either unable or unwilling to make adjustments quickly to changes in the economy. This means that neither workers nor firms can react quickly to changes in monetary or fiscal policy. And this would give such policies a chance of a short-term impact. Although the policy ineffectiveness proposition has not found significant empirical support, rational expectations as a concept has profoundly affected how economists approach macroeconomic problems. Nearly all economists agree that policy changes affect expectations, and that this affects the behavior of individuals and firms that potentially reduce the effectiveness of monetary and fiscal policy. This section has considered two challenges to the effectiveness of macroeconomic policy. First, we looked at the Phillips curve, and showed that policies attempting to address unemployment could lead to inflation and a build-up in inflationary expectations. In other words, policymakers do not face an easy choice between rates of unemployment and rates of inflation. Second, we looked at rational expectations and showed how expectations could mitigate the effectiveness of policy. In the next section, we now want to apply these concepts to macroeconomic issues that are important in our future: economic growth, jobs, debt, and globalization.
CHECKPOINT EFFECTIVENESS OF MACROECONOMIC POLICY: PHILLIPS CURVES AND RATIONAL EXPECTATIONS The Phillips curve represents the negative relationship between the unemployment rate and the inflation rate. When the unemployment rate goes up, inflation goes down, and vice versa. Rising inflationary expectations by the public shifts the Phillips curve to the right, worsening the tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. If policymakers use monetary and fiscal policy to push unemployment below the natural rate, they will face accelerating inflation. Reducing inflation requires that policymakers curtail aggregate demand and temporarily accept higher rates of unemployment. Adaptive expectations assume that individuals and firms extrapolate from past events; it is a backward-looking model. Rational expectations assume that individuals and firms make the best possible use of all publicly available information; it is a forward-looking model of expectations. Rational expectations analysis leads to the conclusion that policy changes will be ineffective; however, market imperfections and information problems are two reasons why rational expectations analysis has met with mixed results empirically.
QUESTIONS: If an economy has high unemployment but low inflation, what would the Phillips curve suggest to be an appropriate macroeconomic policy? Would your answer change if inflationary expectations rise? If we assume that all individuals and firms have excellent foreknowledge as described by the rational expectations model, would that change your answer? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
595
MACROECONOMIC ISSUES THAT CONFRONT OUR FUTURE Macroeconomic theory developed over the last 200 years, especially during the 80 years after Keynes. Until recently, economists thought they had the understanding and the tools to make depressions or deep recessions a thing of the past. For the last 30 years, a general consensus grew among economists that monetary policy should handle most of the task of keeping the economy on a steady low-inflation growth path. The recent financial crisis and subsequent recession have made the profession question that conclusion. This downturn has reinvigorated those who felt that fiscal policy should have more of a role, as well as those who believed that government should have a smaller role overall. This section uses the theories and tools we have learned to understand the important issues that confront our economy today and in the future. Specifically, what are the pressing macroeconomic issues that will have the greatest effect on the next generation? What do macroeconomic theories tell us that policymakers can do? If you take one idea away from this course, it should be that there is not one economic model or one economic policy that fits all occasions or circumstances. It often seems that one set of policymakers see “cutting taxes” as the universal cure-all, while others see “more government spending” as the only solution. Both are wrong. Different circumstances call for different approaches. In this section, we set out the key points surrounding three important issues facing our economy today and likely in the future: (1) the existence of jobless recoveries and persistent unemployment, (2) growing debt and the threat of long-run inflation, and (3) the importance of achieving economic growth in a globalized economy. Throughout this book, we have presented different models and the circumstances in which macroeconomic policy can be effective in these situations.
Are Recoveries Becoming “Jobless Recoveries”?
Globalization, new technologies, and improved business methods are making the jobs of policymakers much more difficult and may even be changing the nature of the business cycle. The 1990–1991, 2001, and 2007–2009 recessions all deviated significantly from what has happened in past business cycles in that they were followed by jobless recoveries. Taming the business cycle has proven to be just as much of an art as a science. Whenever economists believe they have finally gotten a handle on controlling the economy, some new event or transformation of the economy has taken place, humbling the profession. There is no doubt that between 1983 and 2007, the federal government and the Fed did a remarkable job of keeping the economy on a steady upward growth path, with only two minor recessions. The 1990–1991 and 2001 recessions were mild, but the recoveries coming out of these recessions were weak, especially for those out of work and looking for a job. When output begins to grow after a trough in the business cycle, employment usually starts to grow. But when output begins to rise yet employment growth does not resume, the recovery is called a jobless recovery. jobless recovery A phenomenon that takes place after a recession, when output begins to rise, but employment growth does not.
We have already seen that business cycles vary dramatically in their depth and duration. The Great Depression was the worst downturn in American history, while the 2001 recession was one of the mildest. During that recession, the unemployment rate never rose above 6% and real output (GDP) fell only one-quarter of 1% throughout the downturn. But if the recession was mild, the recovery was not as strong as in typical business cycles. Figure 7 shows how the 2007–2009 recession compares to the two previous downturns and their recoveries. It indexes real output for all three downturns so that the most recent recession and recovery can be compared to those previous business cycles. Specifically, real GDP for each business cycle is indexed to the peak of the cycle. This involves dividing each quarter’s output by output at the peak and multiplying by 100 to index the values to 100. Thus, if one quarter after the peak, output has fallen by 1%, the index would be 99 at that point. In this way we can
596
get a graphical picture of how output is doing throughout the course of each cycle. Notice in this figure that both the 1990–1991 and 2001 recessions lasted just under three quarters (eight months each). For the 1990–1991 recession, this is shown by the two-quarter drop in real GDP to a little below 99; then the economy resumed an upward path. The 2001 downturn shows a slight dip in the first quarter, but then quickly rises back above 100. Clearly, both of these recessions were mild indeed. FIGURE 7
REAL GDP RELATIVE TO THE PEAK OF THE BUSINESS CYCLE
The 2007–2009 recession is compared to the previous two recessions in 1990–1991 and 2001 by indexing real output to the peak of the business cycle. The 2007–2009 downturn was deeper; in both of the previous recessions, GDP was back to the previous peak within 18 months.
FIGURE 8
EMPLOYMENT GROWTH RELATIVE TO THE PEAK OF THE BUSINESS CYCLE
597
Employment in the 2007–2009 recession is compared to the previous two recessions in 1990–1991 and 2001 by indexing employment to the peak of the business cycle. This downturn was deeper than the previous recessions. It took about five years before employment returned to its prerecession peak.
In contrast, the 2007–2009 recession was considerably more severe than both of the previous downturns. A year and a half into this recession, real output fell by over 4% and the decline in the economy was just leveling off. Figure 8 presents the same type of indexed graph for employment, though indexing the values monthly. Notice that for the 1990–1991 and 2001 recessions, employment had not reached its prior peak even after two years. In fact, employment took nearly three years to return to peak levels after the 1990–1991 recession, nearly four years after the 2001 recession and about five years after the 2007–2009 recession. In the past, the turnaround in employment to the previous peak was typically reached in two years. Several factors seem to drive jobless recoveries: rapid increases in productivity, a change in employment patterns, and offshoring. Productivity increases arising from improved telecommunications and online technologies make labor far more flexible than ever before. Now when the economy contracts, employers can more easily lay off workers and shift their responsibilities to the workers who remain. As a result, output may keep growing, or at least not drop much, even though fewer workers are employed. When the market rebounds, increased productivity permits firms to adjust to their rising orders without immediately hiring more people. This gives the firm more time to evaluate the recovery to ensure that hiring permanent employees is appropriate. This is why unemployment often keeps increasing even though the economy is recovering. Increased technology and productivity have enabled companies to use fewer workers to run their operations. In 2015 Snapchat had only 330 employees for its estimated 200 million active subscribers, a ratio of 1
598
employee per 600,000 users.
In addition, hiring practices have changed over the past few decades. Firms have begun substituting just-in-time hiring practices for long-term permanent employees. This includes using more temporary and part-time workers, and adding overtime shifts for permanent employees. By using temporary and part-time workers, and overtime, a firm can increase its flexibility while limiting the higher costs associated with hiring permanent employees until it has had time to evaluate the recovery and the demand for its products. Because the past three recoveries have been slow to add jobs, economists and policymakers are concerned that jobless recoveries have become the norm following recessions. The consequence of jobless recoveries is that reducing unemployment requires much more government action than before, especially expansionary fiscal and monetary policies. What type of fiscal and monetary policies can be used to address jobless recoveries? The VOW to Hire Heroes Act is an example of fiscal policy used to encourage employers to hire veterans returning from active duty.
599
Expansionary fiscal policy is most effective when government spending or tax cuts generate economic activity through the spending multiplier, which translates into jobs being created. Alternatively, fiscal policy can be used to provide incentives for employers to hire workers (such as tax incentives for hiring veterans) or employee incentives (such as increased tax deductions for low-income workers). Alternatively, expansionary monetary policy can be used to promote employment. For example, increasing the money supply and lowering interest rates reduce the cost of financing major projects, creating jobs. The Fed’s recent quantitative easing programs that bought up risky mortgage-backed assets reduced long-term interest rates, creating another boost to consumption and investment. Although plenty of policy options exist to address jobless recoveries, they do not come without costs. For example, a reduction in consumer or business confidence can reduce the willingness of consumers and firms to spend, diminishing the multiplier. Increased government spending can lead to greater debt and higher interest rates, which can crowd out private consumption and investment. Therefore, the intended effects of fiscal policy are mitigated. Further, increased money supply and quantitative easing programs can lead to inflation in the long run, as more money chases an economy’s output. Such effects can mitigate the long-term benefits of monetary policy. In sum, the potential consequences of using expansionary fiscal and monetary policies to reduce the unemployment rate are higher debt and potential inflation, important issues to which we turn next.
Will Rising Debt and Future Debt Obligations Lead to Inflation? Much of the debate among policymakers in recent years has centered on rising deficits and national debt. Indeed, fiscal deficits and national debt (at least in nominal terms) have risen to levels not seen in our history. The concern over debt has changed the politics in Washington, as a bitter debate ensued regarding the use of expansionary policies (such as stimulus spending and quantitative easing) to promote economic growth versus austerity measures (cost cutting) to reduce the deficit and the burden of the debt on future generations.
Rising Future Debt Obligations: Health Care and Social Security
Even if the current deficits are brought under control using a combination of government spending cuts and tax increases, the long-term debt obligations relating to Social Security payments and rising health care costs pose a bigger question about the ability to keep deficits and debt under control over the long term. As greater numbers of baby boomers (those born in the years following the end of World War II) retire, more will
600
begin receiving Social Security and Medicare benefits. In addition to greater numbers of beneficiaries, the cost of the benefits also rises. Social Security benefits increase based on the rate of inflation, while Medicare payments rise as the cost of health care increases. Recent legislation has slowed the rise in health care costs, but the overall cost remains difficult to sustain in the long term. In addition, the long-term debt obligations stemming from health care and Social Security do not fully appear in current deficit statistics, because these expenses are budgeted and paid out during the year in which the costs are incurred. Therefore, if costs rise faster than revenues, deficits will persist, adding to the national debt.
The Cost of Financing Debt
The cost of financing debt depends on the interest rate. Fortunately, the United States has enjoyed very low interest rates for much of the past decade. This not only helps individuals and firms looking to borrow, but also the government in financing its debt. A new 30-year Treasury bond issued in 2016 paid only about 3% per year. In 1986 a new 30-year Treasury bond paid about 8% per year. A difference of 5% in the interest rate represents a tremendous savings to the government. Another factor in the cost of financing debt is the willingness of countries to hold U.S. debt. Part of this depends on the demand for the U.S. dollar. The U.S. dollar remains the most widely held currency in the world. When U.S. dollars are held by foreigners, this amounts to an interest-free loan to the U.S. government (also referred to as seigniorage), because no interest is paid on currency. The willingness of people around the world to use and hold dollars allows the government to print these dollars without the immediate worry of inflation.
The Effects of Debt on Inflation
Addressing debt can be undertaken with fiscal policy as well as monetary policy. Fiscal policy to curb debt includes raising taxes or reducing government spending. However, neither of these policies is popular, especially the reduction of Social Security or health care benefits that make up over 50% of government spending. Further, contractionary fiscal policy can curtail economic growth, which is especially dangerous when recovering from a severe recession. For this reason, policymakers have turned to monetary policy. One of the dangers of using monetary policy to help address deficit and debt issues occurs with monetized debt, which is debt that is paid for by an increase in the money supply. In other words, debt is reduced by way of a lower real value of the dollar. Because U.S. Treasury securities have long been sought after as a safe investment by individuals, firms, as well as governments around the world, the U.S. government has not had to worry about the inflationary effects of its monetary policy in recent years. monetized debt Occurs when debt is reduced by increasing the money supply, thereby making each dollar less valuable through inflation.
ISSUE Inflating Our Way Out of Debt: Is This an Effective Approach? In late 2012, the news media posted headlines about the possibility of the Fed authorizing the minting of a trillion dollar coin that would be used to pay for most of the year’s fiscal deficit. By doing so, the minted coin would be sent to the U.S. Treasury to pay down the debt. Would such a strategy really work? Would there be any effects on the economy or on ordinary Americans? Although this type of policy is highly unlikely to occur (though more than one prominent economist had endorsed the plan), what may surprise you is that the Fed has used similar types of policies for years to address our rising national debt. When the money supply is increased, the Fed is using money that is created out of thin air to purchase treasury bonds (debt) from banks and other institutions. In other words, part of the government’s debt is held by other parts of the government using money it creates through its power to print money. Does this sound like an easy solution? Certainly, it’s easier than implementing fiscal policies to combat debt, which would require the
601
raising of taxes or the reduction of government spending, neither of which is popular, especially when much of government spending is used for our national defense or to take care of our senior citizens. Therefore, the government has relied more on monetary policy. When money is created to purchase debt instruments, this is referred to as monetizing debt. Recall that money is neutral. When more money chases a fixed output, prices must rise. Because aggregate demand was depressed after the last recession, inflation did not immediately rise. However, as consumer and business confidence improve, all of the money sitting on the sidelines will eventually enter into the economy and drive prices higher, leading to inflation. As inflation rises, the real value of the national debt falls.
Who, then, ends up paying for this reduction in debt caused by inflation? The answer is everyone who holds dollar-denominated assets, such as those with a savings or retirement account, or holders of bonds including foreign investors and governments. When prices rise, the real value of savings falls. In addition, a rise in inflationary expectations causes banks to raise interest rates, and can lead to an inflation spiral, resulting in even higher prices. In sum, the costs of financing debt by way of inflation are spread among everyone. Regardless of whether fiscal or monetary policy is used, we will all feel the effect of the debt in one way or another.
However, should world demand for U.S. Treasury securities fall as countries diversify their holdings to other assets (such as euro-denominated assets or gold-backed assets), the value of the U.S. dollar may fall. Because we purchase many goods and services from other countries, a weaker dollar increases the prices of many goods and services, leading to inflation. Therefore, although a weaker dollar and inflation both reduce the burden on the existing debt, a higher rate of inflation reduces the purchasing power of one’s income and savings, thereby reducing the standard of living. In order to stem the effects of higher inflation, contractionary monetary policy is needed once the economy has recovered enough to withstand an increase in interest rates. Such policies are not popular. In late 2015, the Fed started to raise interest rates, but very slowly to avoid scaring investors who worried about the start of another recession. Still, controlling inflation is the key to preventing more serious problems for the economy. Ultimately, a higher inflation rate may hinder productivity and economic growth.
Will Globalization Lead to Increased Obstacles to Economic Growth? Economic growth has been the driving force in improving our standard of living. However, the world is changing, and emerging countries such as China and India have experienced higher growth rates than the United States, Japan, and countries in Europe over the past two decades. Further, smaller developing countries, such as Gabon, Ethiopia, and Vietnam, have seen stellar growth rates that have pulled millions out of poverty.
602
Why has economic growth spread throughout the world in this way, and what does this entail for developed nations such as the United States? One of the most important changes to the world economy over the past generation has been the dramatic increase in international trade, international factor movements (foreign investment and immigration), offshoring (the movement of factories overseas), and international banking. The integration of the world’s economies has allowed more countries to specialize and reap the gains from trade that result. For developed countries such as the United States, Japan, and countries in Europe, increased globalization means increased competition for resources, especially talented labor, which now has many more opportunities than it did in the past. Therefore, pressures to innovate and to increase productivity have increased with globalization. Ethiopia, which experienced one of the worst famines in world history in 1985, today has an emerging economy with a high growth rate as it focuses on infrastructure, manufacturing, and trade.
What does this mean for macroeconomic policy? Not only does fiscal and monetary policy need to be tailored to fit the problems inherent in our own country, but how these policies affect other countries becomes important as well. Fiscal policies such as implementing trade restrictions or providing support for domestic industries tend to help one country at the expense of its trading partners. Taking these policies too far may encourage other countries to take similar actions, which would lead to fewer exports and a reduction in trade and economic growth. Monetary policies also affect other nations through trade and the exchange rate. Expansionary monetary policy, such as reducing the interest rate, has the effect of lowering the value of one currency against others. When this occurs, the price of imports rises and the price of exports falls, helping to improve the trade balance as consumers react by purchasing more domestically produced goods than foreign-made goods. But again, such policies can lead to retaliatory actions if taken too far. We turn our attention in the next two chapters to international trade and open economy macroeconomics. Both chapters deal with how countries interact with other countries, either through the trade of goods and services or through the exchange of currencies. Both have important implications for the ability of countries to grow and to improve their standards of living.
Life on the Autobahn: Germany’s Role in European Growth and Stability
603
How did Germany maintain a strong economy after its reunification in 1990 and then in a Eurozone that faced many financial crises?
T
he autobahn has long been a symbol of Germany’s quest for economic strength and prosperity. Led by its successful auto industry, Germany has achieved much economic growth over the last 50 years, and its corporate brands are among the most recognizable and respected in the world. Even more remarkable is how Germany withstood many challenges over the last 30 years that tested its ability to maintain its economic strength. What are some major events that shaped Germany’s economy over the last 30 years?
The autobahn has no speed limit in most areas, symbolizing Germany’s strength in the face of many economic challenges. One major test of Germany’s resilience came with the fall of the Berlin Wall in 1989 and the reunification of West Germany with East Germany in 1990. At the time of reunification, West Germany’s GDP per capita was more than twice that of East Germany. Despite vast economic differences, the reunified Germany invested heavily in capital improvements in the East where marginal returns to capital were strong, increasing labor productivity that led to rising incomes. Another major test was the formation of the European Union, which allowed workers and capital to move between member countries, along with the introduction of the euro, which merged the monetary policies of countries with different economic conditions. When nearly half of Eurozone members faced financial crises between 2008 and 2013, Germany led the European Central Bank’s efforts to increase lending while mandating reforms to put countries back on a path to growth. Finally, Germany played a vital role in the resettlement of refugees and migrants that began flooding into Europe in 2015 to escape war and/or poverty. In 2015 Germany accepted more than 1 million asylum seekers. Germany demonstrated its ability to show compassion to the plight of others while continuing to maintain economic growth and low inflation. Today, Germany remains a strong economic power that embraces diversity and has become a land of opportunity for many in a time when other countries are shutting their doors. It is a symbol of globalization that has given millions a new chance at life.
GO TO
TO PRACTICE THE ECONOMIC CONCEPTS IN THIS STORY
CHECKPOINT 604
MACROECONOMIC ISSUES THAT CONFRONT OUR FUTURE No single macroeconomic model can solve all economic problems. Jobless recoveries are spurred by increases in labor productivity, changes in employment patterns, and increased use of offshoring. Fiscal and monetary policies provide incentives to consume and invest, leading to job growth. Rising deficits were caused by expansionary fiscal policies used to stem the effects of the financial crisis. Future concerns of deficits and debt center on the rising costs of Social Security and Medicare, making the use of fiscal policy to mitigate rising debt difficult. Rising interest rates in the future will increase borrowing costs, making it more difficult to finance debt. Increased use of expansionary monetary policy can lead to long-run inflation, reducing the debt burden but also reducing the purchasing power of savings. Globalization has led to economic growth throughout the world, especially in developing countries. However, increased competition from abroad has made it more challenging for developed nations to maintain high growth rates over time.
QUESTIONS: In 2009 inflation was negative (also known as deflation); average prices fell mostly due to
a sharp decline in consumer spending and business investments from the recession. In early 2015, deflation occurred again, but this time it was caused by a sharp drop in energy prices. How does deflation affect the ability of households and businesses to manage debt? Does the cause of the deflation matter? Explain.
Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
605
chapter summary Section 1 The Great Recession and Macroeconomic Policy 14.1
Events Leading to the Great Recession A glut in worldwide savings in the early years of the 21st century reduced interest rates. Low interest rates and easy bank loans fueled a housing bubble. Risky subprime mortgages were packaged into securities that were inadequately investigated and given perfect AAA ratings. Loan defaults led to a reduction in home prices and the collapse of mortgage-backed securities. Banks lost money from poor investments, insurance companies could not cover losses, and the contagion spread to other industries and eventually to the entire economy.
14.2
The Government’s Policy Response Passed the $700 billion Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP) to bail out banks nearing bankruptcy. Loaned over $100 billion to AIG to prevent its insolvency in insuring risky assets by financial institutions.
606
Passed the $787 billion American Recovery and Reinvestment Act (stimulus package). Bailed out the U.S. automobile industry. Reduced the federal funds target rate to 0% and began a series of quantitative easing (QE) programs to purchase risky assets from banks.
Section 2 Effectiveness of Macroeconomic Policy: Phillips Curves and Rational Expectations 14.3
The Phillips curve shows a negative relationship between unemployment rates and inflation. As unemployment falls, firms bid up the price of labor. Greater employment increases aggregate demand, pushing prices higher. The Phillips curve presented policymakers with a menu of choices. By accepting modest inflation, they can keep unemployment low.
14.4
Phillips curves are affected by inflationary expectations. Rising inflationary expectations by the public would be reflected in a shift in the Phillips curve to the right, worsening the tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. If policymakers use monetary and fiscal policy to attempt to keep unemployment continually below the natural rate, they will face accelerating inflation.
Once inflation reaches a high level, the risk of stagflation occurs, in which high inflation is coupled with high unemployment. Reducing stagflation requires tough contractionary monetary policies to bring down inflation.
607
14.5
The adaptive expectations model assumes that people form their future expectations based on their past experiences. Therefore, it is a backward-looking model of expectations. The rational expectations hypothesis suggests that policymakers cannot stimulate output in the short run by raising inflation unless they keep their actions secret.
Market imperfections and information problems are two reasons why the policy ineffectiveness conclusions of rational expectations analysis have met with mixed results empirically. The rational expectations model assumes that rational economic agents use all publicly available information in forming their expectations, and is a forward-looking model of expectations.
Efficiency wages are paid in many professions as a way to keep employees from shirking or leaving the company. The existence of efficiency wages brings about wage stickiness, which makes rational expectations less likely.
Section 3 Macroeconomic Issues That 608
Confront Our Future 14.6
The use of fiscal policy or monetary policy, or both, depends on the type of issues confronting our economy. Important issues facing our country today and in the future include: Jobless recoveries, which are common after severe financial crises Rising deficits and debt Higher long-term inflation Globalization and its effect on economic growth
The growing population of seniors and the rising costs of Social Security and health care benefits are major factors affecting potential debt in the long run.
14.7
Jobless recoveries have become common after the last few recessions. Factors that have led to jobless recoveries include: Rapid increases in productivity Changes in employment patterns Offshoring
14.8
Globalization affects what we buy and what we produce, as goods and inputs move across borders.
609
Disney’s Epcot World Showcase gives tourists a brief tour of the world. Although Epcot is located entirely in the United States, evidence of globalization abounds. Disney hires thousands of foreign workers, exports services to foreign tourists, imports millions of dollars worth of foreign-made merchandise, and invests in theme parks and companies overseas.
KEY CONCEPTS subprime mortgage leverage credit default swap Phillips curve inflationary expectations stagflation adaptive expectations rational expectations efficiency wage theory jobless recovery monetized debt
QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS Check Your Understanding 1. Why does the Phillips curve become very steep when unemployment is low and rather shallow when unemployment is high? 2. Does the long-run Phillips curve make it difficult (if not impossible) for policymakers to increase output and employment beyond full employment in the long run? 3. Explain why inflation accelerates if policymakers use monetary and fiscal policy to keep unemployment below the natural rate. 4. Does having rational expectations mean that all economic actors act rationally and are always correct? 5. Would policymakers prefer a Phillips curve with a steep or a shallow slope? Why? 6. A negative supply shock (a huge natural disaster or significant energy price spike) would do what to the shortrun Phillips curve? To the long-run Phillips curve?
Apply the Concepts 7. Why would policymakers want to drive unemployment below the natural rate, given that inflation will result? 8. Why are inflationary expectations so important for policymakers to keep under control? When a supply shock such as an oil price spike hits the economy, does it matter how fast policymakers attempt to bring the economy back to full employment? 9. How are the long-run Phillips curve (LRPC) and the long-run aggregate supply (LRAS) curve related? 10. Would the credibility of policymakers’ (Congress and the Fed) commitment to keeping inflation low have an effect on inflationary expectations when the economy is beset by a supply shock? 11. Explain why those who favor the rational expectations approach to modeling the economy do not favor discretionary policymaking.
610
12. If efficiency wages are widespread throughout the economy but most workers feel they are significantly underpaid, will paying workers more prevent them from shirking?
In the News 13. Former Fed Chair Ben Bernanke noted that “in the 1970s the public had little confidence that the Fed would keep inflation low and stable.” As a result, when oil prices rose, wages and prices quickly followed. This caused the Fed to have to increase interest rates sharply to curtail inflation. Do people have a different perspective on the Fed today than they did in the past? 14. About every year, Congress is tasked with increasing the debt ceiling that allows the government to continue borrowing. In past decades, such legislation would pass easily because it was authorizing the payment of expenses already incurred. However, in recent years, some congressional leaders took the drastic approach of opposing to raise the debt ceiling as a way to reign in government spending. If these leaders were successful in preventing the debt ceiling from being raised, what would be some benefits and costs of this action?
Solving Problems 15. The Phillips curve of the 1960s showed a negative relationship between the inflation rate and unemployment. Use the following data on inflation and unemployment to plot a Phillips curve from 2011 to 2015. Does the same relationship between inflation and unemployment hold in 2011–2015 as it did in the 1960s? Year
Inflation Rate
Unemployment Rate
2011
3.2%
8.9%
2012
2.1%
8.1%
2013
1.5%
7.4%
2014
1.6%
6.2%
2015
0.1%
5.3%
611
WORK IT OUT 16. During the recession from December 2007 to June 2009, the U.S. economy lost a total of 7,163,000 jobs. How many jobs were lost per month, on average? Suppose that a healthy economy generates an average of 200,000 jobs per month. At this rate, how long would it take the economy to gain back the number of jobs it had lost? According to data from the Bureau of Labor Statistics, the U.S. economy gained 5,485,000 jobs from June 2009 to June 2013. What was the average number of jobs per month created during the first four years of recovery? Given your answers to the previous two questions, what does this suggest about the pace of economic recovery after the 2007–2009 recession?
USING THE NUMBERS 17. About how long prior to the 2007–2009 recession did consumer sentiment peak? Why didn’t the recession start immediately after the peak? 18. According to By the Numbers, what was the value of monthly real retail sales when it reached its lowest point in 2009? By what percentage did monthly real retail sales increase from 2009 to 2015?
ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS Checkpoint: The Great Recession and Macroeconomic Policy Had it been known that the collapse of the housing market bubble would have caused a severe financial crisis, the government could have implemented macroeconomic policies to slow the rise in housing prices. For example, the government could (1) use contractionary monetary policy to push interest rates higher, making it more expensive to
612
borrow money; (2) pass regulations on financial institutions requiring greater scrutiny of potential borrowers; (3) limit the types of risky loans that could be created; and (4) eliminate tax incentives on housing market profits to limit house flipping. Checkpoint: Effectiveness of Macroeconomic Policy: Phillips Curves and Rational Expectations The Phillips curve would suggest that unemployment can be reduced by accepting a higher rate of inflation. As long as inflation is very low, a small rise in inflation would be a small cost to pay for pushing the unemployment rate down. However, if inflationary expectations rise, it would require a greater inflation rate to achieve a lower unemployment rate. Here, policymakers must be careful not to let inflation exceed a level that might cause larger problems for the economy. Finally, if individuals and firms acted according to the rational expectations model, any increase in inflation would never lead to a reduction in unemployment. In this case, macroeconomic policy is ineffective in the short run, and the best prescription would be to leave the market alone to correct itself over time. Checkpoint: Macroeconomic Issues That Confront Our Future Deflation causes the real value of debt to rise, making it more difficult to repay. Yes, it does matter how the deflation occurs. In 2009 deflation resulted from a decrease in aggregate demand (from a decline in consumption and investment), causing both prices and output to fall. In 2015 deflation resulted from an increase in the short-run aggregate supply curve (from falling input prices). This means that while the real value of debt rises, rising outcome and income make it easier to pay back debt.
613
15
International Trade
614
Understanding why trade with other countries is essential for consumers and 615
producers
Learning Objectives 15.1
Distinguish between absolute and comparative advantage.
15.2
Describe the benefits of free trade.
15.3
Describe the terms of trade.
15.4
Describe the economic impacts of trade on consumers and producers.
15.5
Describe how trade is restricted by tariffs and quotas.
15.6
Discuss the various arguments against free trade.
15.7
Compare the different viewpoints of how trade is believed to affect the environment.
15.8
Analyze the debate on whether foreign workers benefit from trade or are exploited as a result of trade.
E
very day at the Port of Los Angeles, up to ten mega container ships arrive, each containing 10,000 to 19,000 TEU (20-foot equivalent units, or 20 feet × 8 feet × 8.5
feet standard containers) of goods from around the world. A standard tractor trailer can transport two TEUs, which means that up to 80,000 tractor trailers full of goods
are brought into the United States each day, at just one port. These cargo ships and trucks transport the goods we enjoy every day that are made in China, France, Brazil, Kenya, Australia, and the 180 other countries with which the United States has trading relations. Take a quick look in your closet, and count how many countries contributed to your wardrobe—shirts tailored in Hong Kong, shoes made in Italy, sweaters made in Norway, jackets made in China, and the list goes on. On occasion, you might come across something made in the United States, although it is a rarity in the apparel industry. Most Americans wear foreign-made clothing, over half drive foreign cars, and even American cars contain many foreign components. Australian wines, Swiss watches, Chilean sea bass, and Brazilian coffee have become common in the United States. We also buy services from other countries, for example, when we travel to Europe and stay in hotels and use its high-speed trains. The opportunity to buy goods and services from other countries gives consumers more variety to choose from, and also provides an opportunity to buy products at lower prices. Although the United States buys many goods from other countries, it also sells many goods to other countries— just not clothing. The “Made in USA” label is highly respected throughout the world, and the United States sells commercial airplanes, cars and trucks, tractors, high-tech machinery, and pharmaceuticals to individual consumers and businesses in other countries. It also sells agricultural goods and raw materials, such as soybeans, copper, and wood pulp. And it sells services, too, such as medical care, tourist services when foreigners visit the United States, higher education (foreign students studying at American colleges), and entertainment, including movies, software, and music.
616
Trade is now part of the global landscape. Worldwide foreign trade has quadrupled over the past 25 years. In the United States today, the combined value of exports and imports exceeds $5 trillion a year. Twenty-five years ago, trade represented about 20% of gross domestic product (GDP); today, it accounts for over 30% of GDP. Nearly a tenth of American workers owe their jobs to foreign consumers. Figure 1 shows the current composition of U.S. exports and imports. Note that the United States imports and exports a lot of capital goods—that is, the equipment and machinery used to produce other goods. Also, we export about 50% more services than we import, services such as education and health care. Third, exports of petroleum products are catching up to imports as the United States relies less on imports of oil as domestic oil production increases. Does all of this world trade make consumers and producers better off? This chapter examines the effects of trade on both the importing (buying) and exporting (selling) countries, and how trade affects the prices and availability of goods and services in each country.
617
618
FIGURE 1
U.S. TRADE BY SECTOR (2015)
This figure shows trade by sector. The United States imports and exports large amounts of capital goods, the equipment and machinery used to produce other goods. Also, nearly one-third of U.S. exports are services such as education and health care.
Improved communication and transportation technologies have worked together to promote global economic integration. In addition, most governments around the world have reduced their trade barriers in recent years. Trade must yield significant benefits or it would not exist. After all, there are no laws requiring countries to trade, just agreements permitting trade and reducing impediments to it. This chapter begins with a discussion of why trade is beneficial. We look at the terms of trade between countries. We then look at the tariffs and quotas sometimes used to restrict trade, calculating their costs. Finally, we will consider some arguments critics have advanced against increased trade and globalization. International trade allows consumers to buy goods (such as televisions) produced in many countries. Competition from trade allows for greater variety and lower prices.
619
620
THE GAINS FROM TRADE Economics studies voluntary exchange. People and nations do business with one another because they expect to gain through these transactions. Foreign trade is nearly as old as civilization. Centuries ago, European merchants were already sailing to the Far East to ply the spice trade. Today, people in the United States buy cars from South Korea and electronics from China, along with millions of other products from countries around the world. Virtually all countries today engage in some form of international trade. Those that trade the least are considered closed economies. A country that does not trade at all is called an autarky. Most countries, however, are open economies that willingly and actively engage in trade with other countries. Trade consists of imports, goods and services purchased from other countries, and exports, goods and services sold abroad. autarky A country that does not engage in international trade, also known as a closed economy. imports Goods and services that are purchased from abroad. exports Goods and services that are sold abroad.
Many people assume that trade between nations is a zero-sum game: a game in which, for one party to gain, the other party must lose. Poker games fit this description; one person’s winnings must come from another player’s losses. This is not true of voluntary trade. Voluntary exchange and trade is a positive-sum game, meaning that both parties to a transaction can gain. To understand how this works, and thus why nations trade, we need to consider the concepts of absolute and comparative advantage. Note that nations per se do not trade; individuals in specific countries do. We will refer to trade between nations but recognize that individuals, not nations, actually engage in trade.
Absolute and Comparative Advantage
Figure 2 shows hypothetical production possibilities frontiers for the United States and Canada. For simplicity, both countries are assumed to produce only beef (measured as a “side,” which is half of a steer) and guitars. Given the production possibility frontiers (PPFs) in Figure 2, the United States has an absolute advantage over Canada in the production of both products. An absolute advantage exists when one country can produce more of a good than another country. In this case, the United States can produce twice as much beef and 5 times as many guitars as Canada. This is not to say that Canadians are inefficient in producing these goods, but rather that Canada does not have the resources to produce as many goods as the United States does (for one thing, its population is barely a tenth the size of that of the United States). absolute advantage One country can produce more of a good than another country.
At first glance, we may wonder why the United States would be willing to trade with Canada. If the United States can produce so much more of both goods, why not just produce its own beef and guitars? The reason lies in comparative advantage. One country enjoys a comparative advantage in producing some good if its opportunity costs to produce that good are lower than the other country’s. In this example, Canada’s comparative advantage is in producing beef. As Figure 2 shows, the opportunity cost for the United States to produce another million sides of beef is 1 million guitars; each added side of beef essentially costs 1 guitar. comparative advantage One country has a lower opportunity cost of producing a good than another country. FIGURE 2
PRODUCTION POSSIBILITIES FOR THE UNITED STATES AND CANADA
621
The production possibilities frontiers (PPF) shown here assume that the United States and Canada produce only beef and guitars. In this example, the United States has an absolute advantage over Canada in producing both products; the United States can produce twice as much beef and 5 times as many guitars as Canada. Canada nonetheless has a comparative advantage over the United States in producing beef.
TABLE 1
COMPARING OPPORTUNITY COSTS FOR BEEF AND GUITAR
622
PRODUCTION U.S. Opportunity Cost
Canada Opportunity Cost
Comparative Advantage
Beef production
1 guitar
0.4 guitar
Canada
Guitar production
1 side of beef
2.5 sides of beef
United States
Contrast this with the situation in Canada. For every guitar Canadian manufacturers forgo making, they can produce 2.5 more sides of beef. This means a side of beef costs only 0.4 guitar in Canada (1/2.5 = 0.4). Canada’s comparative advantage is in producing beef, because a side of beef costs 0.4 guitar in Canada, while the same side of beef costs an entire guitar in the United States. By the same token, the United States has a comparative advantage in producing guitars: 1 guitar in the United States costs 1 side of beef, but the same guitar in Canada costs 2.5 sides of beef. Table 1 summarizes the opportunity costs of each good in each country and shows which country has the comparative advantage for each good. These relative costs suggest that the United States should focus its resources on guitar production and that Canada should specialize in beef.
Gains from Trade To see how specialization and trade can benefit both countries even when one has an advantage in producing more of both goods, assume that the United States and Canada at first operate at point a in Figure 2, producing and consuming their own beef and guitars. As we can see, the United States produces and consumes 40 million sides of beef and 40 million guitars. Canada produces and consumes 20 million sides of beef and 8 million guitars. This initial position is similarly shown as points a in Figure 3. Assume now that Canada specializes in producing beef, producing all that it can—40 million sides of beef. We will assume that the two countries want to continue consuming 60 million sides of beef between them. This means that the United States needs to produce only 20 million sides of beef, because Canada is now producing 40 million. This frees up some American resources to produce guitars. Because each side of beef in the United States costs a guitar, reducing beef output by 20 million means that 20 million more guitars can now be produced. Thus, the United States is producing 20 million sides of beef and 60 million guitars. Canada is producing 40 million sides of beef and no guitars. The combined production of beef remains the same, 60 million, but guitar production has increased by 12 million (from 48 million to 60 million). The two countries can trade their surplus products and will be better off. This is shown in Table 2. Assuming that they agree to share the added 12 million guitars between them equally, Canada will trade 20 million sides of beef for 14 million guitars. Points b in Figure 3 show the resulting consumption patterns for each country. Each consumes the same quantity of beef as before trading, but each country now has 6 million more guitars: 46 million for the United States and 14 million for Canada. This is shown in the last column of the table. One important point to remember is that even when one country has an absolute advantage over another, countries still benefit from trade. The gains are small in our example, but they will grow as the two countries approach one another in size and their comparative advantages become more pronounced.
Practical Constraints on Trade
At this point, we should take a moment to note some practical constraints on trade. First, every transaction involves costs. These include transportation, communications, and the general costs of doing business. Over the last several decades, however, transportation and communication costs have declined all over the world, resulting in growing world trade. Second, the production possibilities frontiers for nations are not linear; rather, they are governed by increasing costs and diminishing returns. Countries find it difficult to specialize only in one product. Indeed, specializing in one product is risky because the market for the product can always decline, new technology might replace it, or its
623
production can be disrupted by changing weather patterns. This is a perennial problem for developing countries that often build their exports and trade around one agricultural commodity. FIGURE 3
THE GAINS FROM SPECIALIZATION AND TRADE TO THE UNITED STATES AND CANADA
Assume Canada specializes in beef. If the two countries want to continue consuming 60 million sides of beef between them, the United States needs to produce only 20 million. This frees up resources for the United States to begin producing more guitars. Because each side of beef in the United States costs 1 guitar to
624
produce, reducing beef output by 20 million means that 20 million more guitars can be produced. When the two countries trade their surplus products, both are better off than before.
TABLE 2
THE GAINS FROM TRADE
Country and Product
Before Specialization
After Specialization
After Trade
Beef
40 million
20 million
40 million
Guitars
40 million
60 million
46 million
Beef
20 million
40 million
20 million
Guitars
8 million
0
14 million
United States
Canada
Although it is true that trading partners benefit from trade, some individuals and groups within each country may lose. Individual workers in those industries at a comparative disadvantage are likely to lose their jobs, and thus may require retraining, relocation, or other help if they are to move smoothly into new occupations.
ISSUE The Challenge of Measuring Imports and Exports in a Global Economy Before the growth of globalization of manufacturing, the brand names of products would indicate their origin. For example, Sony televisions were made in Japan, Nokia telephones were made in Finland, and a Ford car would be made in the United States using American steel, engines, cloth, and, of course, American labor. Today, a product’s brand name does not tell the entire story. Production has become very complex, with parts sourced from around the world. With such complexities in trade, how then are imports and exports measured? Do sales of Levi’s jeans count as U.S. exports? Although Levi’s arean American brand that has for much of its history been produced in the United States, today nearly all Levi’s jeans are made in Asia. Therefore, the American-brand jeans we buy count as an import. On the other hand, we also consume many products that may seem foreign, but are made in the United States. The majority of Toyota and Honda cars, for example, are assembled in American factories using American steel, glass, and other materials. The same is true to a lesser extent for luxury brands such as BMW, which produces many compact cars in South Carolina. For all but a few parts (such as the engine and transmission) that are made in Japan or Germany, these cars are as American as apple pie, and are not counted as imports. In order to measure imports and exports accurately, the United States Bureau of Economic Analysis tabulates data from documents collected by U.S. Customs and Border Protection, which details the appraised value (price paid) for all shipments of goods into and out of the ports of entry (whether by land, air, or sea). The value of imported and exported services is more difficult to measure, and is based on a survey of monthly government and industry reports to determine the value of all services bought from and sold to foreigners.
625
A domestic content label of an “imported” Toyota truck. The globalized economy has been spurred in large part by falling transportation and communication costs in the past few decades. Companies face ever greater competition, applying more pressure to reduce production costs. The expansion of the production process to a worldwide factory is just one way our economy has changed, and this trend is likely to continue into the future.
When the United States signed the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) with Canada and Mexico, many U.S. workers experienced this sort of dislocation. Some U.S. jobs went south to Mexico because of lower wages. States such as Texas and Arizona experienced greater levels of job dislocation due to their proximity to Mexico. Still, by opening up more markets for U.S. products, NAFTA has stimulated the U.S. economy. The goal is that displaced workers, newly retrained, will end up with new and better jobs, although there is no guarantee this will happen.
CHECKPOINT THE GAINS FROM TRADE An absolute advantage exists when one country can produce more of a good than another country. A comparative advantage exists when one country can produce a good at a lower opportunity cost than another country. Both countries gain from trade when each specializes in producing goods in which they have a comparative advantage. Transaction costs, diminishing returns, and the risk associated with specialization all place some practical constraints on trade.
QUESTIONS: When two individuals voluntarily engage in trade, they both benefit or the trade wouldn’t
occur—one party wouldn’t choose to be worse off after the trade. Is the same true for nations? Is everyone in both nations better off? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
626
THE TERMS OF TRADE How much can a country charge when it sells its goods to another country? How much must it pay for imported goods? The terms of trade determine the prices of imports and exports. To keep things simple, assume that each country has only one export and one import, priced at Px and Pm. The ratio of the price of the exported goods to the price of the imported goods, Px/Pm, is the terms of trade. Thus, if a country exports computers and imports coffee, with two computers trading for one ton of coffee, the price of a computer must be one-half the price of a ton of coffee. When countries trade many commodities, the terms of trade are defined as the average price of exports divided by the average price of imports. This can get a bit complicated, given that the price of each import and export is quoted in its own national currency, while the exchange rate between the two currencies may be constantly changing. We will ignore these complications by translating currencies into dollars, focusing our attention on how the terms of trade are determined and the impact of trade. terms of trade The ratio of the price of exported goods to the price of imported goods (Px/Pm).
Determining the Terms of Trade
To get a feel for how the terms of trade are determined, let us consider the trade in golf clubs between the United States and South Korea. We will assume the United States has a comparative advantage in producing golf clubs; all prices are given in dollars. Panel A of Figure 4 shows the supply and demand of sets of golf clubs in the United States. The upward-sloping supply curve reflects increasing opportunity costs in golf club production. As the United States continues to specialize in golf club production, resources less suited to this purpose must be employed, resulting in rising costs for golf club production. Because of this rise in costs as ever more resources are shifted to golf clubs, the United States will eventually lose its comparative advantage in golf club production. This represents one limit on specialization and trade. FIGURE 4
DETERMINING THE TERMS OF TRADE
627
Panel A shows the supply and demand of golf clubs in the United States; the upward slope of the supply curve reflects increasing opportunity costs to produce more golf clubs. The United States begins in pretrade equilibrium at $600 and South Korea’s initial equilibrium is at $1,000. With trade, Korean consumers will begin buying American golf clubs because of their lower price. American golf club makers will increase production to meet this new demand. Korean golf club firms will see sales of their golf clubs decline as prices begin to fall. Ignoring transport costs, trade will continue until prices reach $800. At this point, U.S. exports (2,000) are just equal to Korean imports (2,000).
Let us assume that the United States begins in pretrade equilibrium, with the price of golf club sets at $600 each. Panel B shows South Korea initially in equilibrium with a higher price of $1,000. Because prices for golf clubs from the United States are lower, when trade begins, Korean consumers will begin buying U.S. golf clubs. American golf club makers will increase production to meet this new demand. Korean golf club firms, conversely, will see the sales of their golf clubs decline. For now, let us ignore transportation costs, such that trade continues until prices reach $800. At this point, U.S. exports (2,000 sets of golf clubs) are just equal to Korean imports. Both countries are now in equilibrium, with the price of golf clubs somewhere between the two pretrade equilibrium prices ($800 in this case). Imagine this same process simultaneously working itself out with many other goods, including some at which the Koreans have a comparative advantage, such as interactive televisions. As each product settles into an equilibrium price, the terms of trade between these two countries are determined.
The Impact of Trade Our examination of absolute and comparative advantage has thus far highlighted the benefits of trade. A closer look at Figure 4, however, shows that trade produces winners and losers. Picking up on the previous example, golf club producers in the United States are happy, having watched their sales rise from 3,000 to 4,000 units. Predictably, management and workers in this industry will favor even more trade with South Korea and the rest of the world. Yet, domestic consumers of golf clubs are worse off, because after trade they purchase only 2,000 sets at the higher equilibrium price of $800. Contrast this situation in the net exporting country, the United States, with that of the net importer, South Korea. Korean golf club producers are worse off than before because the price of golf clubs fell from $1,000 to $800, and their output was reduced to 1,000 units. Consequently, they must cut jobs, leaving workers and managers in the
628
Korean golf club industry unhappy with its country’s trade policies. Korean consumers, however, are beneficiaries of this expanded trade, because they can purchase 3,000 sets of golf clubs at a lower price of $800 each. These results are not merely hypothetical. This is the story of free trade, which has been played out time and time again: Some sectors of the economy win, and some lose. American consumers have been happy to purchase Korean televisions such as Samsung and LG, given their high quality and low prices. American television producers (such as RCA and Zenith) have not been so pleased, nor have their employees, having watched television factories close and workers displaced as competition from abroad forced these companies out of business. Similarly, the ranks of American textile workers have been decimated over the past three decades as domestic clothing producers have increasingly become nothing but designers and marketers of clothes, shifting their production overseas to countries in which wages are lower. American-made clothing is now essentially a thing of the past. To be sure, American consumers have enjoyed a substantial drop in the price of clothing, because labor forms a significant part of the cost of clothing production. Still, being able to purchase inexpensive T-shirts made in China is small consolation for the unemployed textile worker in North Carolina. Trade allows American golf club producers to expand sales globally, while Korean golfers benefit from their availability.
The undoubted pain suffered by the losers from trade often is translated into pressure put on politicians to restrict trade in one way or another. The pain is often felt more strongly than the “happiness” felt by those who benefit from trade.
How Trade Is Restricted Trade restrictions can range from subsidies provided to domestic firms to protect them against lower-priced imports to embargoes by which the government bans any trade with a country. Between these two extremes are more intermediate policies, such as exchange controls that limit the amount of foreign currency available to importers or citizens who travel abroad. Regulation, licensing, and government purchasing policies are all frequently used to promote or ensure the purchase of domestic products. The main reason for these trade restrictions is simple: The industry and its employees actually feel the pain and lobby extensively for protection, while the huge benefits of lower prices are diffused among millions of consumers whose benefits are each so small that fighting against a trade barrier isn’t worth their time. The most common forms of trade restrictions are tariffs and quotas, though tariffs are used more frequently than quotas. Figure 5 shows the average U.S. tariff rates since 1900. Some economists have suggested that the tariff wars that erupted in the 1920s and culminated in the passage of the Smoot-Hawley Act in 1930 were an important factor
629
underlying the severity of the Great Depression. The high tariffs of the 1930s reduced trade, leading to a reduction in income, output, and employment, and added fuel to the worldwide depression. Since the 1930s, the United States has played a leading role in trade liberalization, with average tariff rates declining to a current rate of less than 2%.
Effects of Tariffs and Quotas What exactly are the effects of tariffs and quotas? Tariffs are often ad valorem taxes. This means that the product is taxed by a certain percentage of its price as it crosses the border. Other tariffs are unit taxes (also known as specific tariffs): A fixed tax per unit of the product is assessed at the border. Tariffs are designed to generate revenues and to drive a wedge between the domestic price of a product and its price on the world market. The effects of a tariff are shown in Figure 6. tariff A tax on imported products. When a country taxes imported products, it drives a wedge between the product’s domestic price and its price on the world market.
Domestic supply and demand for the product are shown in Figure 6 as S and D. Assume that the product’s world price of $400 is lower than its domestic price of $600. Domestic quantity demanded (4,000 units) will consequently exceed domestic quantity supplied (2,000 units) at the world price of $400. Imports to this country will therefore be 2,000 units. FIGURE 5
AVERAGE U.S. TARIFF RATES, 1900–2015
Tariffs and quotas are the most common forms of trade restrictions. Tariff rates in the United States peaked during the Great Depression. Over the last several decades, tariffs have steadily declined to an average of less than 2% today.
630
FIGURE 6
EFFECTS OF A TARIFF
What are the effects of a typical tariff? Supply and demand curves S and D represent domestic supply and demand. Assume the product’s world price of $400 is lower than its domestic price. Imports will therefore be 2,000 units. If the country imposes a tariff of $100 on this product, the domestic price rises to $500, and imports fall to 1,000 units. Domestic consumers now buy less of the product at higher prices. However, the domestic industry is happy because its prices and output have risen. Also, the government collects revenues equal to the shaded area.
Now assume that the firms and workers in the industry hurt by the lower world price lobby for a tariff and are successful. The country imposes a tariff of $100 per unit on this product. The results are clear. The product’s price in this country rises to $500 and imports fall to 1,000 units (3,500 − 2,500). Domestic consumers buy less of the product at higher prices. Even so, the domestic industry is happy, because its prices and output have risen. The government, meanwhile, collects revenues equal to $100,000 ($100 × 1,000), the shaded area in Figure 6. These revenues can be significant: In the 1800s, tariffs were the federal government’s dominant form of revenue. It is only in the last century that the federal government has come to rely more on other sources of revenue, including taxes on income, sales, and property. Figure 7 shows the effects of a quota. They are similar to what we saw in Figure 6, except that the government restricts the quantity of imports into the country to 1,000 units. Imports fall to the quota level, and consumers again lose, because they must pay higher prices for less output. Producers and their employees gain as prices and employment in the domestic industry rise. For a quota, however, the government does not collect revenue. Then who gets this revenue? The foreign exporting company receives it in the form of higher prices for its products. This explains why governments prefer tariffs over quotas.
631
quota A government-set limit on the quantity of imports into a country. FIGURE 7
EFFECTS OF A QUOTA
What are the effects of a quota? They are similar to the effects of a tariff, except that the government restricts the quantity of imports into the country to 1,000 units. Imports fall to the quota level, and again consumers lose as they must pay higher prices for less output. Producers and their employees gain as prices and employment in the domestic industry rise. With a quota, however, the government does not collect revenues.
The United States imposed quotas on Japanese automobiles in the 1980s. The primary effect of these quotas was initially to raise the minimum standard equipment and price dramatically for some Japanese cars and ultimately to increase the number of Japanese cars made in American factories. If a firm is limited in the number of vehicles it can sell, why not sell higher-priced ones whose profit margins are higher? The Toyota Land Cruiser, for instance, was originally a bare-bones SUV selling for under $15,000. With quotas, this vehicle was transformed into a luxury behemoth that sells for over $80,000 today, with all the bells and whistles standard. Although quotas on Japanese automobiles have long expired, Japanese automakers continue to produce a wide array of luxury automobiles.
ISSUE Do Foreign Trade Zones Help or Hurt American Consumers and Workers? 632
Driving through the gates of the Cartago Zona Franca in Costa Rica, one encounters a remarkable sight in a historic Central American town: large factories adorned with the names of large American companies in industries including pharmaceuticals, semiconductors, medical supplies, and household products. What are these companies doing in Costa Rica, and why did they choose to locate within this small gated compound? In Cartago, as well as in other cities throughout the world, clusters of multinational companies engage in manufacturing activities. These companies are taking advantage of the benefits offered by foreign trade zones, also commonly known as free trade zones or export processing zones. A foreign trade zone is a designated area in a country where foreign companies can import inputs, without tariffs, to be used for product assembly by local workers who are often paid a fraction of what equivalent workers would be paid in the company’s home country. By operating in a foreign trade zone, all inputs coming into a country are exempted from tariffs as long as the finished products (with some exceptions) are then exported from the country. Further, companies are often exempted from other taxes levied by the government. Countries such as China, the Philippines, and Costa Rica establish foreign trade zones to attract foreign investment, which creates well-paying jobs relative to wages paid by domestic companies. Countries with high literacy rates, like Costa Rica, are especially attractive because their workers can perform semi-skilled tasks such as assembling electronic and computer products or handling customer service calls. Foreign trade zones also are prevalent along border towns, such as those in Mexico, where easy transportation to and from the United States allows inputs and products to flow rapidly. Although companies operating in foreign trade zones benefit from lower production costs and the host country benefits from jobs created, not everyone is in favor of foreign trade zones. Various unions in the United States view foreign trade zones as facilitating the offshoring of American jobs. Offshoring occurs when part of the production process (typically, the labor-intensive portions) is sent to countries with lower input costs. What may be surprising, however, is that foreign trade zones and offshoring are not one-way streets. The United States has many foreign trade zones established for the same purpose: to attract foreign companies to invest in manufacturing plants. By moving production to the United States, European and Japanese companies produce goods such as cars while enjoying the same tax benefits as American companies operating abroad. In 2015 almost as many jobs were created by foreign companies in the United States as jobs lost from American companies moving production overseas.
The entrance to the free trade zone in Cartago, Costa Rica. There are both winners and losers in trade. But when all impacts are considered, including savings to consumers from lower product costs, imports of U.S. goods by foreigners, profits to U.S. affiliates, and the value of labor reemployed, the benefits tend to outweigh the costs. Clearly, those who lose their jobs suffer. But with a policy to provide training to displaced workers, the savings from offshoring can lead to greater investment and growth in the long run.
633
One problem with tariffs and quotas is that when they are imposed, large numbers of consumers pay just a small amount more for the targeted products. Few consumers are willing to spend time and effort lobbying Congress to end or forestall these trade barriers from being introduced. Producers, however, are often few in number, and they stand to gain tremendously from such trade barriers. It is no wonder that such firms have large lobbying budgets and provide campaign contributions to political candidates.
CHECKPOINT THE TERMS OF TRADE The terms of trade are determined by the ratio of the price of exported goods to the price of imported goods. The terms of trade are set by the markets in each country and by exports and imports that eventually equalize the prices. Trade leads to winners and losers in each country and in each market. Trade restrictions vary from subsidies to domestic firms to government bans on the import of foreign products. Tariffs are taxes on imports that protect domestic producers and generate revenue for the government. Quotas represent restrictions on the volume of particular imports that can come into a country. Quotas do not generate revenue for governments and are infrequently used.
QUESTION: When the government imposes a quota on foreign trucks, who benefits and who loses? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
634
ARGUMENTS AGAINST FREE TRADE We have seen the benefits of trade, and have looked at how trade undoubtedly benefits some and harms others. Those who are harmed by trade often seek to restrict trade, primarily in the form of tariffs and quotas. Because trade leads to some loss, those who are harmed by trade have made arguments against free trade. The arguments against free trade fall into two camps. Traditional economic arguments include protection for infant industries, protection against dumping, low foreign wages, and support for industries judged vital for national defense. More recent arguments focus on globalization (social and economic) concerns that embody politicaleconomy characteristics. These include domestic employment concerns, environmental concerns, and the impact of globalization on working conditions in developing nations. In what follows, we take a critical look at each of these arguments, showing that most of these arguments do not have a solid empirical basis.
Traditional Economic Arguments
Arguments against trade are not new. Despite the huge gains from trade, distortions (subsidies and trade barriers) continue because changing current policies will hurt those dependent on subsidies and trade restrictions, and these firms and workers will show their displeasure in the voting booth. All of these traditional economic arguments against free trade seem reasonable on their face, but on closer examination, they look less attractive.
Infant Industry Argument
An infant industry, it is argued, is one that is too underdeveloped to achieve comparative advantage or perhaps even to survive in the global market. Such an industry may be too small or undercapitalized, or its management and workers may be too inexperienced, to compete. Unless the industry’s government provides it with some protection through tariffs, quotas, or subsidies, it might not survive in the face of foreign competition. infant industry An industry so underdeveloped that protection is needed for it to become competitive on the world stage or to ensure its survival.
In theory, once the infant industry has been given this protection, it should be able to grow, acquiring the necessary capital and expertise needed to compete internationally. Germany and the United States used high tariffs to protect their infant manufacturing sectors in the 1800s, and Japan continued to maintain import restrictions up until the 1970s. Although the infant industry argument sounds reasonable, it has several limitations. First, protecting an industry must be done in a way that makes the industry internationally competitive. Many countries coddle their firms, and these producers never seem to develop into “mature,” internationally viable firms. Once protection is provided (typically, a protective tariff), it is difficult to remove after an industry has matured. The industry and its workers continue to convince policymakers of the need for continued protection. Second, infant industry protection often tends to focus on capital manufacturing. Countries with huge labor supplies would do better to develop their labor-intensive industries first, letting more capital-intensive industries develop over time. Every country, after all, should seek to exploit its comparative advantages, but it is difficult to determine which industries have a chance of developing a comparative advantage in the future and should be temporarily protected. Third, many industries seem to be able to develop without protections; therefore, countries may be wasting their resources and reducing their incomes by imposing protection measures. Clearly, the infant industry argument is not a compelling one for advanced economies such as those of the United States, much of Europe, and Japan. The evidence for developing nations shows some benefits but is mixed for the reasons noted above.
Antidumping
Dumping means that goods are sold at lower prices (often below cost) abroad than in their home market. This is
635
typically a result of government subsidies. dumping Selling goods abroad at lower prices than in home markets, and often below cost.
In the same way that price discrimination improves profits, firms can price discriminate between their home markets and foreign markets. Let’s assume that costs of production are $100 per unit for all firms (domestic and foreign). A state subsidy of $30 a unit, for example, reduces domestic costs to $70 per unit and permits the firm to sell its product in world markets at these lower prices. These state subsidies give these firms a cost advantage in foreign markets. Firms can use dumping as a form of predatory pricing, using higher prices in their domestic markets to support unrealistically low prices in foreign markets. The goal of predatory pricing is to drive foreign competitors out of business. When this occurs, the firm doing the dumping then comes back and imposes higher prices. In the long run, these higher prices thereby offset the company’s short-term losses. Dumping violates U.S. trade laws. If the federal government determines that a foreign firm is dumping products into the United States, it can impose antidumping tariffs on the offending products. The government, however, must distinguish among dumping, legitimate price discrimination, and legitimate instances of lower-cost production arising from comparative advantage.
Low Foreign Wages
Some advocates of trade barriers maintain that domestic firms and their workers need to be protected from displacement by cheap foreign labor. Without this protection, it is argued, foreign manufacturers that pay their workers less than a dollar an hour will flood the market with low-cost products. As we have already seen, this argument has something to it: Workers in advanced economies can be displaced by low-wage foreign workers. This is what has happened in the American textile industry. Once a handful of American clothing manufacturers began moving their production facilities overseas, thereby undercutting domestic producers, other manufacturers were forced to follow them. American consumers have benefited from lower clothing prices, but many displaced textile workers are still trying to get retrained and adapt to work in other industries. More recently, many manufacturing jobs have drifted overseas, and high-technology firms today are shifting some help desk facilities and computer programming to foreign shores. On balance, however, the benefits of lower-priced goods considerably exceed the costs of lost employment. The federal government has resisted imposing protection measures for the sake of protecting jobs, instead funding programs that help displaced workers transition to new lines of work.
National Defense Argument
In times of national crisis or war, the United States must be able to rely on key domestic industries, such as oil, steel, and defense. Some have argued that these industries may require some protection even during peacetime to ensure that they are already well established when a crisis strikes and importing key products may be impossible. Within limits, this argument is sound. Still, the United States has the capacity to produce such a wide variety of products that protections for specific industries would seem to be unjustified and unnecessary. The steel industry is one of several that are considered key domestic industries vital in times of national crisis. Therefore, industry executives frequently argue for protection against foreign competition.
636
So what are we to make of these traditional arguments? Although they all seem reasonable, they all have deficiencies. Infant industries may be helped in the short run, but protections are often extended well beyond what is necessary, resulting in inefficient firms that are vulnerable on world markets. Dumping is clearly a potential problem, but distinguishing real cases of dumping from comparative advantage has often proven difficult in practice. Low foreign wages are often the only comparative advantage a developing nation has to offer the world economy, and typically, the benefits to consumers vastly outweigh the loss to a particular industry. Maintaining (protecting) industries for national defense has merit and may be appropriate for some countries, but for a country as huge and diversified as the United States, it is probably unnecessary.
Recent Globalization Concerns Expanded trade and globalization have provided the world’s producers and consumers with many benefits. Some observers, however, have voiced concerns about globalization and its effects on domestic employment, the global environment, and working conditions in developing nations. Let’s look at each one of these globalization concerns.
Trade and Domestic Employment
Some critics argue that increased trade and globalization spell job losses for domestic workers. We have seen that this can be true. Some firms, unable to compete with imports, will be forced to lay off workers or even close their doors. Even so, increased trade usually allows firms that are exporters to expand their operations and hire new workers. These will be firms in industries with comparative advantages. For the United States, these industries tend to be those that require a highly skilled workforce, resulting in higher wages for American workers. Clearly, those industries that are adding workers and those that are losing jobs are different industries. For workers who lose their jobs, switching industries can be difficult and time-consuming, and often it requires new investments in human capital. U.S. trade policy recognizes this problem, and the Trade Adjustment Assistance (TAA) program provides workers with job search assistance, job training, and some relocation allowances. In some industries sensitive to trade liberalization, including textiles and agriculture, trade policies are designed to proceed gradually, thus giving these industries and their workers some extra time to adjust. Possible employment losses in some noncompetitive industries do not seem to provide enough justification for restricting trade. By imposing trade restrictions such as tariffs or quotas in one industry, employment opportunities in many other industries may be reduced. Open, competitive trade encourages producers to focus their production on those areas in which the country stands at a comparative advantage. Free trade puts competitive pressure on domestic firms, forcing them to be more productive and competitive, boosting the flow of information and technology across
637
borders, and widening the availability of inputs for producers. At the end of the day, consumers benefit from these efficiencies, having more goods to choose from and enjoying a higher standard of living.
Trade and the Environment
Concerns about globalization, trade, and the environment usually take one of two forms. Some people are concerned that expanded trade and globalization will lead to increased environmental degradation as companies take advantage of lax environmental laws abroad, particularly in the developing world. Others worry that attempts by the government to strengthen environmental laws will be challenged by trading partners as disguised protectionism. Domestic environmental regulations usually target a product or process that creates pollution or other environmental problems. One concern in establishing environmental regulations, however, is that they not unfairly discriminate against the products of another country. This is usually not a serious problem. Nearly all trade agreements, including the World Trade Organization agreements and NAFTA, have provisions permitting countries to enforce measures “necessary to protect human, animal or plant life or health” or to conserve exhaustible natural resources. Nothing in our trade agreements prevents the United States from implementing environmental regulations as long as they do not unreasonably discriminate against our trading partners. Will free trade come at the expense of the environment? Every action involves a tradeoff. Clearly, there can be cases in which the benefits of trade accruing to large numbers of people result in harm to a more concentrated group. However, trade policies can also be complementary to good environmental policies. For example, increased free trade in agriculture encourages countries with fertile lands to specialize in growing crops, while discouraging countries from farming marginal lands that require the use of environmentally damaging pesticides and chemicals. We have seen that trade raises incomes in developed and developing countries. How rising incomes affect environmental protections depends on the state of a country’s development. In poor, developing countries, environmental protection will not at first be a priority. Critics of globalization argue that rich nations will exploit weaker environmental regulations with trade and foreign direct investment. Yet many studies have found that not to be the case. In fact, as countries develop and incomes rise, the demand for environmental protection rises as the issue takes on added importance even in poorer nations. The result is what economists refer to as an environmental Kuznets curve, in which economic development initially harms the environment but then improves as incomes rise. An increased emphasis on environmental issues can be seen in countries such as Costa Rica, Brazil, and even India and China, as people in these countries demand a cleaner environment as incomes rise.
Trade and Its Effect on Working Conditions in Developing Nations
Some antiglobalization activists argue that trade between the United States and developing countries, where wages are low and working conditions are deplorable, exploits workers in these developing countries. Clearly, such trade does hurt American workers in low-wage, low-skilled occupations who cannot compete with the workers paid an even lower wage overseas. But it is not clear that workers in developing countries would be helped if the United States were to cut off its trade with those countries that refuse to improve wages or working conditions. For these workers, producing goods for export may be the only job opportunity they have. Restricting trade with countries that do not raise wages to levels we think acceptable or bring working conditions up to our standards would probably do more harm than good. Low wages reflect, among other factors, small investments in human capital, low productivity, and meager living standards characteristic of developing nations. Blocking trade with these nations may deprive them of their key chance to grow and to improve in those areas in which we would like to see change. Liberalized trade policies, economic freedom, and a legal system that respects property rights and foreign capital investment probably provide the best recipe for rapid development, economic growth, environmental protection, and improved wages and working conditions. In summary, trade does result in job losses in some industries, but the gain for consumers and the competitive pressures that trade puts on domestic companies are beneficial to the economy as a whole. Trade raises incomes in developing nations, resulting in a growing demand for more environmentally friendly production processes. Trade is not the reason for low environmental standards in developing countries; they result from low incomes, low standards of living, and poor governmental policies. Trade brings about higher levels of income and ultimately better working conditions.
638
Can One Country’s Festival Disrupt World Trade? How is China’s export sector so important that it can disrupt global trade during its annual Spring Festival?
A
round early to mid-February of each year (depending on the lunar calendar), one of the largest mass migrations of people begins in China—hundreds of millions of people pack onto crowded trains, airline seats sell out, and highways are jammed with cars in the world’s largest auto market. Although this might sound typical of a Memorial Day or Thanksgiving weekend in the West, the sheer scale of the Spring Festival in China makes most other holidays around the world appear minuscule. Just how big of an impact on the world does this Chinese festival have? The 15-day Spring Festival, which coincides with the Lunar New Year and culminates with the Lantern Festival, is so large that it actually disrupts global trade each year. Because China is the world’s largest exporter of goods, consumers and producers around the world depend on Chinese exports to stock their shelves and to provide parts for manufacturing. Moreover, many companies depend on custom orders, such as custom tote bags for a large conference or custom racing medals to be handed out to runners after a marathon. Often these orders are made months in advance to allow time for production as well as shipping, usually by cargo ship.
Because nearly everyone celebrates the Spring Festival in China, most workers take long vacations in February. Factories that employ migrants from the countryside become empty as workers leave to visit their families and friends. As a result, many factory orders are delayed or placed on hold during the festival, which can affect markets around the world as stores and customers wait for their orders to arrive. The sheer size and influence of China’s export sector can disrupt global trade when there is a halt in production. As a result, distributors anticipate delays by placing orders extra-early whenever possible around that time of year. One might wonder why factory managers do not provide incentives for workers to forgo the festival in order to fill customer orders. Most likely it’s because the managers themselves are leaving to see their families! The Spring Festival is a 4,000-year-old tradition and one not to be missed, even at the cost of disrupting world trade.
GO TO
TO PRACTICE THE ECONOMIC CONCEPTS IN THIS STORY
CHECKPOINT 639
ARGUMENTS AGAINST FREE TRADE The infant industry argument claims that some industries are so underdeveloped that they need protection to survive in a global competitive environment. Dumping involves selling products at different prices in domestic and foreign markets, often with the help of subsidies from the government. This is a form of predatory pricing to gain market share in the foreign market. Some suggest that domestic workers need to be protected from the low wages in foreign countries. This puts the smaller aggregate loss to small groups ahead of the greater general gains from trade. Also, for many countries, a low wage is their primary comparative advantage. Some argue that select industries need protection to ensure that they will exist for national defense reasons. Globalization displaces some workers due to foreign competition, and some advocates would restrict trade on these grounds alone. But on net, trade has led to higher overall employment as exports expand and the economy grows. Concern about the environment is often a factor in trade negotiations. But as trade increases incomes in developing countries, environmental awareness rises. Some believe that trade exploits workers in developing countries; however, trade has typically resulted in higher wages for these workers.
QUESTION: Trade between the United States and China increased significantly over the last two decades. China is now the United States’ second largest trading partner after Canada. Expanding trade has led to significant reductions in the price of many goods, including technology goods such as computers and tablets. However, some people have been vocal against policies that promote freer trade with China. What are some reasons why people would be against greater trade with China? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
640
chapter summary Section 1 The Gains From Trade 15.1
Absolute advantage: Occurs when one country can produce more of a good than another country. Comparative advantage: Occurs when a country can produce a good at a lower opportunity cost than another country.
The United States has a comparative advantage in both soybean production (due to an abundance of fertile land) and commercial aircraft production (due to an abundance of technology and human capital).
15.2
Trade is a positive-sum game, which means that both countries in a trading relationship can gain compared to not trading.
Section 2 The Terms of Trade 15.3
The terms of trade determine the prices of imports and exports. When countries trade many commodities, the terms of trade are defined as the average price of exports divided by the average price of imports. The Effect of Trade on Prices
641
15.4
Before trade, the prices charged for one good may be different in the two countries. The country with the lower price is likely to export the good; greater demand for that country’s good pushes prices higher. The country with the higher price is likely to import the good; lesser demand for that country’s good pushes prices lower. Market forces therefore push prices toward an equilibrium under free trade.
15.5
Tariffs are a tax on imports. They raise the domestic price of the good to the world price + tariff.
Winners: Domestic producers gain area A. Government gains area C in tariff revenues. Losers: Domestic consumers lose areas A + B + C + D due to higher prices. Net Loss: Areas B + D (deadweight loss from the tariff) Quotas are an alternative to tariffs that directly restrict the quantity of imports. Quotas have a similar effect on prices as tariffs, except no tariff revenue is generated.
Historically, trade barriers have been high. In the 1930s, the Smoot-Hawley Act placed an average tax of 60% on most imported goods, arguably prolonging the Great Depression. Trade barriers have fallen since, and in the past three decades have fallen dramatically to nearly free trade with all countries.
642
Section 3 Arguments Against Free Trade 15.6
Many strong arguments against free trade exist. In each case, trade protection in the form of a tariff, quota, or subsidy is sought to protect the domestic industry. Infant industry argument: States that a new industry requires protection to survive against established foreign competition. The problem is determining when these industries mature. Antidumping argument: Dumping occurs when a foreign firm sells its goods below cost or at a price below what it charges in its domestic market. Key industries argument: States that a country must be able to rely on its domestic industries for critical goods such as food, oil, steel, and defense equipment in times of conflict when trade might not be possible.
15.7
Environmental degradation argument: States that countries producing mass goods allow their environments to deteriorate. However, studies show that as countries develop and incomes grow, demand for environmental protection rises.
South Korea sustained environmental degradation during its economic development in the 1980s and
643
1990s. Today, it invests heavily in environmental protection and sustainable cities like Songdo outside the capital of Seoul.
In the early 1980s, Harley-Davidson sought infant industry protection against competition from established lower-cost Japanese motorcycles, giving it time to retool its factories to become more competitive. Protection against cheap labor argument: Argues that domestic workers need to be protected from cheap foreign labor. Most economists estimate that the benefits from lower-priced imports from free trade exceed the costs of lost employment. Further, increased trade generates jobs in export industries.
15.8
Exploitation of foreign workers argument: Argues that trading with developing countries where wages are low and working conditions are deplorable exploits workers in these countries. But restricting trade would probably do more harm than good. Trade may be their only chance to grow and improve their standard of living.
Although working conditions in factories in developing countries look miserable, they often are better than working conditions before trade. In addition, trade increases demand for workers, which leads to higher wages.
KEY CONCEPTS 644
autarky imports exports absolute advantage comparative advantage terms of trade tariff quota infant industry dumping
QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS Check Your Understanding 1. What is the difference between absolute and comparative advantage? Why would Lexi Thompson, who is better than you at both golf and laundry, still hire you to do her wash? 2. If the United States has a comparative advantage in the production of strawberries compared to Iceland, how might trade affect the prices of strawberries in the two countries? 3. Who are the beneficiaries from a large U.S. tariff on French and German wines? Who are the losers? 4. Why does a quota generate a larger loss to the importing country than a tariff that restricts imports to the same quantity? 5. What is the difference between an infant industry and a key industry? Why do producers in both industries desire protection against foreign imports? 6. How could free trade between the United States and China potentially lead to more jobs in the United States?
Apply the Concepts 7. Some American politicians claim that China’s trade policies are unfair to the United States, and that a large tax (tariffs) should be placed on Chinese imports to protect American workers and industries. Why might such a policy sound better than it actually is in practice? What are the dangers of imposing large taxes on Chinese imports? 8. Expanding trade in general benefits all countries, or they would not willingly engage in trade. But we also know that consumers and society often gain while particular industries or workers lose. Because society and consumers gain, how might the government compensate the few losers for their loss? 9. Some activist groups are calling for “fair trade laws” by which other countries would be required to meet or approach our environmental standards and provide wage and working conditions approaching those of developed nations in order to be able to trade with us. Is this just another form of rent seeking by industries and unions for protection from overseas competition? 10. Why is there free trade between states in the United States but not necessarily between countries? 11. Remittances from developed countries amount to over $500 billion each year. These funds are sent to their home countries by migrants in developed nations. Is this similar to the gains from trade discussed in this chapter, or are these workers just taking jobs that workers in developed countries would be paid more to do in the absence of the migrants? 12. Suppose Brazil developed a secret process that effectively quadrupled its output of coffee from its coffee plantations. This secret process enabled it to significantly undercut the prices of U.S. domestic producers. Would domestic producers receive a sympathetic ear to calls for protection from Brazil’s lower cost coffee? How is this case different from that of protection against cheap foreign labor?
645
In the News 13. Much of the world’s trade in goods occurs by cargo ship. Sometimes, the routes taken seem bizarre. For example, a container of goods being shipped from Shanghai to Hawaii might travel over 7,000 miles to Long Beach and then backtrack nearly 3,000 miles to Hawaii, as opposed to just traveling about 4,500 miles directly. Why would cargo companies use circuitous (and seemingly inefficient) routes to reach their destinations? 14. Since the Civil War, Hawaii had been a major producer and exporter of sugarcane. About the time Hawaii became a U.S. state in 1959, the sugar industry had already started its decline, and in 2015, the last sugar plantation in Hawaii closed. Explain how the sugar industry in Hawaii was affected by reductions in tariffs, world competition, and the opportunity costs of production relative to other states. Why does sugar continue to be produced in Florida and Louisiana but not Hawaii?
Solving Problems
WORK IT OUT 15. This figure shows the production possibilities frontiers (PPFs) for Italy and India for their domestic production of olives and tea. Without trade, assume that each is consuming olives and tea at point a.
a. If Italy and India were to consider specialization and trade, what commodity would each specialize in? What is India’s opportunity cost for tea and olives? What is Italy’s opportunity cost for tea and olives? b. Assume that the two countries agree to specialize entirely in one product (the one for which each country has a comparative advantage), and agree to split the total output between them. Complete the following table. Are both countries better off after trade?
Country and Product
Before Specialization
After Specialization
After Trade
6 million tones
__________
__________
Italy Olives
646
Tea
10 million tones
__________
__________
Olives
2 million tones
__________
__________
Tea
30 million tones
__________
__________
India
16. The following figure shows the annual domestic demand and supply for 16-GB flash drives.
a. Assume that the worldwide price of these 16-GB flash drives is $10. What percent of United States sales would be imported? b. Assume the U.S. government puts a $5 tariff per unit on flash drive imports. How many 16-GB flash drives would be imported into the United States? c. Given the tariff in question (b), how much revenue would the government collect from this tariff? d. Given the tariff in question (b), how much more sales revenue would domestic companies enjoy as a result of the tariff?
USING THE NUMBERS 17. According to By the Numbers, approximately when was the last time the United States had a trade surplus? As a percentage of GDP, what was the highest trade surplus the United States has achieved in the last 50 years? What was the highest trade deficit the United States has incurred in the last 50 years? 18. According to By the Numbers, most of the developed countries (Canada, Australia, the United States, Switzerland, and Hong Kong) have relatively low tariff barriers, while much of the developing world still has high tariffs on imports. What reasons might account for why these countries continue to have high tariffs?
647
ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS Checkpoint: The Gains From Trade Yes, in general, nations would not trade unless they benefit. However, as we have seen, even though nations as a whole gain, specific groups—industries and their workers who do not have a comparative advantage relative to other countries—lose. Checkpoint: The Terms of Trade When a quota is imposed, the first beneficiary is the domestic industry. Foreign competition is curtailed. If the market is important enough (automobiles), foreign companies will build new plants in the United States and compete as if they are domestic firms. A second beneficiary is foreign competitors, in that they can increase the price or complexity of their products and increase their margins. Losers are consumers and, to some extent, the government, because a tariff could have accomplished the same reduction in imports and the government would have collected some revenue. Checkpoint: Arguments Against Free Trade Growth in the volume of trade with China has led to lower prices on many goods Americans enjoy. However, although trade with China has led to significant benefits to Americans, the sentiment is not always positive for a number of reasons. First, many believe that China’s low prices (through its low wages as well as government efforts to keep the value of the U.S. dollar strong) forced many American factories to close or move overseas, causing job losses. Second, some believe China holds an unfair advantage due to poor working conditions and low environmental standards. Third, some believe that quality standards for Chinese products are low, leading to safety issues. These and other reasons have created a backlash against efforts to further reduce trade barriers between the two nations. However, these concerns have not diminished the benefits of low prices and the many American jobs generated through increased exports of American-made products to a growing consumer market in China.
648
16
Open Economy Macroeconomics
649
Understanding how fluctuations in exchange rates affect what we pay for goods and 650
services in a globalized economy
Learning Objectives 16.1
Define the current account and the capital account in the balance of payments between countries.
16.2
Explain the difference between nominal and real exchange rates.
16.3
Describe the effects of currency appreciation or depreciation on imports and exports.
16.4
Describe the effects of changes in inflation rates, disposable income, and interest rates on exchange rates.
16.5
Explain the differences between fixed and flexible exchange rate systems.
16.6
Describe the implications for fiscal and monetary policies when used with fixed and flexible exchange rate systems.
Y
ou probably are aware of international finance if you have traveled abroad. To purchase goods and services in another country, you need to have an amount of that country’s currency. True, you can use credit cards for major purchases, but you still need some currency for daily transactions. In Britain, you need to pay in British
pounds; in France, you need euros. British and French shopkeepers and public transportation officials will not accept U.S. dollars. This means that at the beginning of your trip, whether at the airport or at a bank, you have to exchange your dollars for the currency of the country you are visiting.
This process of exchanging money applies to international trade as well. You may pay dollars for your Burberry scarf or Louis Vuitton handbag in a store in the United States, but eventually your dollars have to be converted to pounds or euros when your payments make their way back to Britain or France, respectively. And if U.S. companies export goods abroad, they will want to bring dollars back to the United States, whether the goods are paid for originally in dollars or not. Furthermore, in today’s open economies, individuals can hold domestic and foreign financial assets. Your own financial portfolio might include foreign stocks, bonds, and currency, as well as domestic stocks and bonds. Buying and selling foreign securities and goods involves the buying and selling of foreign currency, also known as foreign exchange. We can see that foreign exchange transactions for tourism, trade, and investment would seem to be large in number and amount. In fact, foreign exchange transactions dwarf the volume of exports and imports, often by as much as 30 to 40 times, in the same way that the annual value of all stock transactions far surpasses the market value of all companies on the New York Stock Exchange. Most foreign exchange transactions are conducted not for trade but for financial or speculative purposes. The social benefit to emerge from this speculation is a highly liquid foreign exchange market that ensures the possibility of trade. The large volume of speculative trade in currencies means that
651
there will always be a market for international trade.
652
653
In this chapter, we want to look at foreign exchange markets to get a sense of how policymaking in the United States is affected by an open worldwide economy. We start with balance of payments accounts, which are to open economy macroeconomics what national income accounts are to an individual country’s macroeconomic accounts. This accounting structure is the basis for open economy analysis. We then examine the foreign exchange market in detail, looking at both the trade and financial aspects of those common foreign currency events: currency appreciation and depreciation. Finally, we put this all together when we view fixed and flexible exchange rate systems and discuss how an open economy affects monetary and fiscal policymaking.
654
THE BALANCE OF PAYMENTS All open economies have balance of payments accounts. Open financial markets permit economies to run trade surpluses and deficits. A simplified version of the U.S. balance of payments accounts for 2015 is shown in Table 1. These accounts were compiled by the Bureau of Economic Analysis of the U.S. Department of Commerce. The balance of payments represents all payments received from foreign countries and all payments made to them. Notice that the accounts are split into two broad divisions, the current account and the capital account.
The Current Account
The current account includes payments for imports and exports of goods and services, incomes flowing into and out of the country, and net transfers of money. current account Includes payments for imports and exports of goods and services, incomes flowing into and out of the country, and net transfers of money.
Imports and Exports
In 2015, U.S. exports of goods and services totaled $2,223.6 billion, with imports totaling $2,763.4 billion. This exchange produced a trade deficit of $539.8 billion because we imported more than we exported. Some balance of payments accounts break exports and imports into separate categories of goods and services; here, they are combined. This component of the current account is known as the balance of trade.
TABLE 1
THE BALANCE OF PAYMENTS 2015 (BILLIONS OF U.S. DOLLARS)
Current Account Exports
2,223.6
Imports
2,763.4
Balance of trade (exports – imports)
−539.8
Income received (inflow)
783.1
Income payments (outflow)
591.8
Balance on income (inflow – outflow)
191.3
Net transfers
−135.6
Current account balance
−484.1
Capital Account Change in foreign-owned
395.5
655
assets in the United States Change in U.S.-owned assets abroad
186.3
Net increase in foreignowned holdings
209.2
Statistical discrepancy
274.9
Capital account
484.1 Data from Bureau of Economic Analysis.
Income
Another source of foreign payments to the United States comprises income flows, which include wages, rents, interest, and profits that Americans earn abroad ($783.1 billion in 2015) minus the corresponding income foreigners earn in the United States ($591.8 billion). On balance, foreigners earned $191.3 billion less in the United States than U.S. citizens and corporations earned abroad in 2015. The iconic Plaza Hotel in New York City, which has appeared in several dozen movies, was purchased by foreign investors in 2004. The inflow of funds to the United States used to purchase the hotel appeared in the U.S. capital account that year.
Transfers
Direct transfers of money also take place between the United States and other countries. These transfers include foreign aid, funds sent to such international organizations as the United Nations, and stipends paid directly to foreign students studying in the United States or U.S. students studying abroad. These transfers also include remittances, money that people working in the United States send back to their families in foreign countries. Net transfers of money for 2015 from all sources totaled −$135.6 billion.
656
Adding all current account categories for 2015 yields a current account deficit of $484.1 billion. In 2015, the United States paid out $484.1 billion more than it received. Therefore, the United States had to borrow $484.1 billion from the rest of the world, or the net holdings of U.S. assets by foreigners must have increased by that same amount, or some combination of the two.
The Capital Account The capital account summarizes the flow of money into and out of domestic and foreign assets. This account includes investments by foreign companies in domestic plants or subsidiaries—a Toyota truck plant in Tennessee, for example. Note that the profits from such investments flow abroad, and thus they are in the income payments (outflow) category of the current account. Other foreign holdings of U.S. assets include portfolio investments such as mutual funds, stocks, bonds, and deposits in U.S. banks. American investors hold foreign financial assets in their portfolios, including foreign stocks and bonds. And American companies own plants and other assets in foreign countries. capital account Summarizes the flow of money into and out of domestic and foreign assets, including investments by foreign companies in domestic plants or subsidiaries, and other foreign holdings of U.S. assets, including mutual funds, stocks, bonds, and deposits in U.S. banks. Also included are U.S. investors’ holdings of foreign financial assets, production facilities, and other assets in foreign countries.
Because the United States ran a current account deficit in 2015, it must run a capital account surplus. Net capital inflows into the United States must equal $484.1 billion to offset the current account deficit. Indeed, foreign-owned assets in the United States increased by $395.5 billion, while U.S. ownership of foreign assets increased by $186.3 billion, resulting in a net inflow of capital of $209.2 billion. Because many accounts are subjected to estimation errors, a statistical discrepancy value of $274.9 billion is added to the net inflow of capital to bring the total capital account surplus to $484.1 billion. The key point to remember is that balance of payments accounts have to show a balance: A deficit in the current account must be offset by a corresponding surplus in the capital account, and vice versa. Keep this point in mind as we go on to look at foreign exchange and policy implications of an open economy.
CHECKPOINT THE BALANCE OF PAYMENTS The balance of payments represents all payments received from foreign countries and all payments made to them. The balance of payments is split into two categories: current and capital accounts. The current account includes payment for exports and imports, income flows, and net transfers of money. The capital account summarizes flows of money into and out of domestic and foreign assets. The sum of the current and capital account balances must equal zero.
QUESTIONS: China and Russia both have a high savings rate as a percent of GDP. The lack of
consumption relative to domestic investment leads to substantial net exports. Would this situation lead to a current account surplus or a current account deficit? Why? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
657
EXCHANGE RATES As we saw in the chapter opening, if you wish to go abroad or to buy a product directly from a foreign firm, you need to exchange dollars for foreign currency. Today, credit cards automatically convert currencies for you, making the transaction more convenient. This conversion does not, however, alter the transaction’s underlying structure. When you decide to travel abroad, the value of the dollar compared to the currency where you are going determines how expensive your trip will be. The value of the dollar fluctuates on a daily basis against most foreign currencies that are traded in the foreign exchange market. This section looks at the issues of exchange rates and their determination.
Defining Exchange Rates
The exchange rate is defined as the rate at which one currency, such as U.S. dollars, can be exchanged for another, such as British pounds. The exchange rate is nothing more than the price of one currency for another. Table 2 shows exchange rates for selected countries for a specific date (April 22, 2016), as found on the Web site xe.com. Exchange rates can be quoted in one of two ways: (1) the price (in domestic currency) of 1 unit of foreign currency, or (2) the number of units of a foreign currency required to purchase 1 unit of domestic currency. As Table 2 illustrates, exchange rates are often listed from both perspectives. exchange rate The rate at which one currency can be exchanged for another.
Nominal Exchange Rates
According to Table 2, 1 British pound will buy 1.44 dollars. Equivalently, 1 dollar will purchase 0.69 pound. These numbers are reciprocal measures of each other (1 ÷ 1.44 = 0.69). A nominal exchange rate is the price of one country’s currency for another. It is the most common way of stating exchange rates. However, nominal exchange rates do not take into account changes in prices between countries. Therefore, economists often use an alternative measure of exchange rates, called the real exchange rate, when analyzing their effects on the economy. nominal exchange rate The price of one country’s currency for another.
Real Exchange Rates
The real exchange rate takes the price levels of both countries into account. Real exchange rates become important when inflation is an issue in one country. The real exchange rate between two countries is defined as er = en × (Pd/Pf), real exchange rate A measure of a currency’s value relative to another, taking into account the price levels of both countries. It is equal to the nominal exchange rate multiplied by the ratio of the price levels of the two countries.
TABLE 2
EXCHANGE RATES (APRIL 22, 2016) Exchange Rates U.S. Dollars
Currency per U.S. Dollar
Australia (dollar)
0.775
1.290
Brazil (real)
0.283
3.526
658
Britain (pound)
1.443
0.693
Canada (dollar)
0.787
1.271
China (yuan)
0.154
6.485
France (euro)
1.129
0.885
India (rupee)
0.015
66.528
Japan (yen)
0.010
109.989
Mexico (peso)
0.057
17.436
Russia (ruble)
0.015
66.431
Switzerland (franc)
1.026
0.974 Data from xe.com.
where er is the real exchange rate, en is the nominal exchange rate, Pd is the domestic price level, and Pf is the foreign price level. The real exchange rate is the nominal exchange rate multiplied by the ratio of the price levels of the two countries. In plain words, the real exchange rate tells us how many units of the foreign good can be obtained for the price of 1 unit of that good domestically. The higher this number, the cheaper the good abroad becomes. If the real exchange rate is greater than 1, prices abroad are lower than at home. In a broad sense, the real exchange rate may be viewed as a measure of the price competitiveness between the two countries. When prices rise in one country, its products are not as competitive in world markets. Let us take British and American cars as an example. Assume that Britain suffers significant inflation, which pushes the price of Land Rovers up by 15% in Britain. The United States, meanwhile, suffers no such inflation of its price level. If the dollar-to-pound exchange rate remains constant for the moment, the price of Land Rovers in the U.S. market will climb, while domestic auto prices remain constant. Now Land Rovers are not as competitive as before, resulting in fewer sales. Note, however, that the resulting reduction in U.S. purchases of British cars and other items will reduce the demand for British pounds. This puts downward pressure on the pound, reducing its exchange value and restoring some competitiveness. Markets do adjust! We will look at this issue in more detail later in the chapter.
Purchasing Power Parity
Purchasing power parity (PPP) is the rate of exchange that allows a specific amount of currency in one country to purchase the same quantity of goods in another country. Absolute PPP would mean that nominal exchange rates equaled the same purchasing power in each country. As a result, the real exchange rate would be equal to 1. For example, PPP would exist if $4 bought a meal in the United States, and the same $4 converted to British pounds (about £2.8) bought the same meal in London. purchasing power parity The rate of exchange that allows a specific amount of currency in one country to purchase the same quantity of goods in another country.
If you have traveled abroad, you know that PPP is not absolute. Some countries, such as India and Thailand, are known as inexpensive countries, while others, such as Norway and Switzerland, can be expensive. The Economist provides an online interactive tool called the “Big Mac Index,” a lighthearted attempt to capture the notion of PPP. Table 3 presents some recent estimates of PPP and the Big Mac Index. It also shows the PPP implied by the relative cost of Big Macs, along with the actual exchange rate. When comparing these two, we get an approximate over- or understating of the exchange rate. Keep in mind that the cost of a McDonald’s Big Mac may be influenced
659
by many unique local factors (trade barriers on beef, customs duties, taxes, competition), and therefore it may not reflect real PPP. Also, in some countries where beef is not consumed, chicken patties are substituted; and in still other countries, fish or vegetable patties are used. An hour-long massage in Bangkok, Thailand, can cost as little as $10, while a quick ten-minute cab ride in Geneva, Switzerland, can run $30. Exchange rates often do not result in purchasing power parity between nations.
Prices of fast food in different nations often do not result in purchasing power parity.
TABLE 3
MEASURES OF PURCHASING POWER PARITY Big Mac Prices In Local Currency
In Dollars
Implied PPP of the Dollar
Actual Dollar Exchange Rate (January 2016)
Under (−)/Over (+) against the Dollar (%)
United States
US$ 4.93
4.93
1.00
—
—
Argentina
Peso 33.0
2.39
6.69
13.81
−52
Britain
Pound 2.89
4.22
0.59
0.68
−14
Canada
CAD$ 5.84
4.14
1.18
1.41
−16
China
Yuan 17.6
2.68
3.57
6.56
−46
660
India
Rupee 127
1.90
25.76
66.80
−61
Japan
Yen 370
3.12
75.05
118.65
−37
Mexico
Peso 49
2.81
9.94
17.44
−43
Norway
Krone 46.8
5.21
9.49
8.97
+6
Switzerland
CHF 6.5
6.44
1.32
1.01
+31
Taiwan
NT$ 69
2.08
14.00
33.23
−58
Thailand
Bhat 112
3.09
22.72
36.22
−37
Venezuela
Bolivar 132
0.66
26.77
198.70
−87
Data from the Big Mac Index interactive tool: economist.com/content/big-mac-index.
According to the Big Mac Index, in 2016 most currencies were undervalued to the U.S. dollar, with the exception of the Norwegian krone and Swiss franc. Although not perfect, changes in the Big Mac Index often are reflective of movements in true PPP, given that simultaneous changes in several of the factors that distort the index often reflect real changes in the economy.
Exchange Rate Determination
We have seen that people and institutions have two primary reasons for wanting foreign currency. The first is to purchase goods and services and conduct other transactions under the current account. The second is to purchase foreign investments under the capital account. These transactions create a demand for foreign currency and give rise to a supply of domestic currency available for foreign exchange.
A Market for Foreign Exchange
Figure 1 shows a representative market for foreign exchange. The horizontal axis measures the quantity of dollars available for foreign exchange, and the vertical axis measures the exchange rate in British pounds per U.S. dollar. The demand for dollars as foreign exchange is downward-sloping; as the exchange rate falls, U.S. products become more attractive, and more dollars are desired. Suppose, for example, that the exchange rate at first is $1 = £1 and that the U.S. game company Electronic Arts manufactures and sells its games at home and in Britain for $50 (£50). Then suppose that the dollar depreciates by 50%, such that $1.00 = £0.50. If the dollar price of a game remains at $50 in the United States, the pound price of games in Britain will fall to £25 because of the reduction in the exchange rate. This reduction will increase the sales of games in Britain and increase the quantity of dollars British consumers need for foreign exchange. FIGURE 1
THE FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET FOR DOLLARS
661
A market for foreign exchange is shown here. The horizontal axis measures the quantity of dollars available for foreign exchange, and the vertical axis measures the exchange rate in pounds per dollar. If exchange rates are fully flexible and the exchange rate is initially e1, there is excess demand for dollars: Q2 minus Q1. The dollar will appreciate and the exchange rate will move to e0. Alternatively, if the exchange rate is initially e2, there is an excess supply of dollars. Because there are more dollars being offered than demanded, the dollar will depreciate. Eventually, the market will settle into an exchange rate of e0, where precisely the quantity of dollars supplied is the quantity demanded.
The supply of dollars available for foreign exchange reflects the demand for pounds, because to purchase pounds, U.S. firms or individuals must supply dollars. Not surprisingly, the supply curve for dollars is positively sloped. If the dollar were to appreciate, say, moving to $1 = £2, British goods bought in the United States would look attractive because their dollar price would be cut in half. As Americans purchased more British goods, the demand for pounds would grow, and the quantity of dollars supplied to the foreign exchange market would increase.
Flexible Exchange Rates
Assume that exchange rates are fully flexible, such that the market determines the prevailing exchange rate, and that the exchange rate in Figure 1 is initially e1. At this exchange rate, there is an excess demand for dollars because quantity Q2 is demanded but only Q1 is supplied. The dollar will appreciate, or rise in value relative to other currencies, and the exchange rate will move in the direction of e0 (more pounds are required to purchase a dollar). As the dollar appreciates, it becomes more expensive for British consumers, thus reducing the demand for U.S. exports. Because of the appreciating dollar, British imports are more attractive for U.S. consumers, increasing U.S. imports. These forces work to move the exchange rate to e0, closing the gap between Q2 and Q1.
662
appreciation (currency) When the value of a currency rises relative to other currencies.
Alternatively, if the exchange rate begins at e2, there will be an excess supply of dollars. Because more dollars are being offered than demanded, the value of dollars relative to British pounds will decline, or depreciate. American goods are now more attractive in Britain, increasing American exports and the demand for dollars, while British goods become more expensive for American consumers. Eventually, the market will settle into an exchange rate of e0, at which precisely the quantity of dollars supplied is the quantity demanded. depreciation (currency) When the value of a currency falls relative to other currencies.
Currency Appreciation and Depreciation
A currency appreciates when its value rises relative to other currencies and depreciates when its value falls. This concept is clear enough in theory, but it can get confusing when we start looking at charts or tables that show exchange rates. The key is to be certain of which currency is being used to measure the value of other currencies. Does the table you are looking at show the pound price of the dollar or the dollar price of the pound? Figure 2 shows the exchange markets for dollars and pounds. Panel A shows the market for dollars, where the price of dollars is denominated in pounds (£/$), just as in Figure 1. This market is in equilibrium at £0.56 per dollar (point e). Panel B shows the equivalent market for pounds; it is in equilibrium at $1.78 per pound (again at point e). Note that 1 ÷ 0.56 = 1.78; therefore, panels A and B represent the same information, just from different viewpoints. FIGURE 2
THE FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET
Data for dollars and pounds are graphically represented here. Panel A shows a market for dollars in which the price of dollars is denominated in pounds (£/$). In panel A, the market is in equilibrium at £0.56 per dollar (point e). Panel B shows the equivalent market for pounds in equilibrium at $1.78 per pound (again at point e). A rise in the demand for dollars means that the dollar appreciates to £0.75 per dollar (point a in panel A). Panel B shows that the corresponding decline in demand for pounds (from D0 to D1) leads to a depreciation of the pound as the exchange rate falls from $1.78 to $1.33 per pound (point b). Note that a depreciating pound in panel B indicates a decline in the exchange rate, but this simultaneously represents an appreciating dollar. Thus, graphs can be viewed as reflecting either appreciation or depreciation, depending on which currency is being used to establish the point of view.
Assume that there is a rise in the demand for dollars. In panel A, the dollar appreciates to £0.75 per dollar (point
663
a), thus leading to a rise in the exchange rate. In panel B, the corresponding decline in demand for pounds (from D0 to D1) leads to a depreciation of the pound and a fall in the exchange rate from $1.78 to $1.33 per pound (point b). Notice that the pound’s depreciation in panel B produces a decline in the exchange rate, but this decline simultaneously results in appreciation of the dollar. These graphs could be viewed as showing either an appreciation or a depreciation, depending on which currency represents your point of view. For our purposes, we will try to use figures that show the exchange rate rising when the focus currency appreciates. Still, you need to be aware that exchange rates can be represented in two different ways. Exchange rate graphs are difficult and sometimes confusing; therefore, you will need to think through each graph you encounter.
Determinants of Exchange Rates
What sort of conditions will cause currencies to appreciate or depreciate? First, a change in our tastes and preferences as consumers for foreign goods will result in currency appreciation or depreciation. For example, if we desire to purchase more foreign goods, this will lead to an increase in the demand for foreign currency and result in the depreciation of the dollar. Second, if our income growth exceeds that of other countries, our demand for imports will grow faster relative to the growth of other nations. This will lead again to an increase in demand for foreign currency, resulting in the depreciation of the dollar. Third, rising inflation in the United States relative to foreign nations makes our goods and services relatively more expensive overseas and foreign goods more attractive here at home. This results in growing imports, reduced exports, and again leads to a depreciation of the dollar. Fourth, falling interest rates in the United States relative to foreign countries make financial investment in the United States less attractive. This reduces the demand for dollars, leading once again to a depreciation of the dollar. Note that if we reverse these stories in each case, the dollar will appreciate.
Exchange Rates and the Current Account As we have already seen, the current account includes payments for imports and exports. Also included are changes in income flowing into and out of the country. In this section, we focus on the effect that changes in real exchange rates have on both of these components of the current account. We will assume that import and export demands are highly elastic as prices change due to fluctuations in the exchange rate.
Changes in Inflation Rates
Let’s assume that inflation heats up in Britain, such that the British price level rises relative to U.S. prices. Production costs rise in Britain; therefore, British goods are more expensive. American goods appear more attractive to British consumers; therefore, exports of American goods rise, improving the U.S. current account. American consumers purchase more domestic goods and fewer British imports because of rising British prices, further improving the American current account. The opposite is true for Britain: British imports rise and exports fall, hurting the British current account. These results are dependent on our assumption that import and export demands are highly elastic with real exchange rates. Thus, when exchange rates change, exports and imports will change proportionally more than the change in exchange rates.
Changes in Domestic Disposable Income
If domestic disposable income rises, U.S. consumers will have more money to spend, and given existing exchange rates, imports will rise because some of this increased consumption will go to foreign products. As a result, the current account will worsen as imports rise. The opposite occurs when domestic income falls.
Exchange Rates and the Capital Account
The capital account summarizes flows of money or capital into and out of U.S. assets. Each day, foreign individuals,
664
companies, and governments put billions of dollars into Treasury bonds, U.S. stocks, companies, and real estate. Today, foreign and domestic assets are available to investors. Foreign investment possibilities include direct investment in projects undertaken by multinational firms, the sale and purchase of foreign stocks and bonds, and the short-term movement of assets in foreign bank accounts. Because these transactions all involve capital, investors must balance their risks and returns. Two factors essentially incorporate both risk and return for international assets: interest rates and expected changes in exchange rates.
Interest Rate Changes
If the exchange rate is assumed to be constant, and the assets of two countries are perfectly substitutable, then an interest rate rise in one country will cause capital to flow into it from the other country. For example, a rise in interest rates in the United States will cause capital to flow from Britain, where interest rates have not changed, into the United States, where investors can earn a higher rate of return on their investments. Because the assets of both countries are assumed to be perfectly substitutable, this flow will continue until the interest rates (r) in Britain and the United States are equal, or rUS = rUK Everything else being equal, we can expect capital to flow in the direction of the country that offers the highest interest rate, and thus, the highest return on capital. But “everything else” is rarely equal.
Expected Exchange Rate Changes
Suppose that the exchange rate for U.S. currency is expected to appreciate (Δε > 0). The relationship between the interest rates in the United States and Britain becomes rUS = rUK − Δε Investors demand a higher return in Britain to offset the expected depreciation of the British pound relative to the U.S. dollar. Unless interest rates rise in Britain, capital will flow out of Britain and into the United States until U.S. interest rates fall enough to offset the expected appreciation of the dollar. If capital is not perfectly mobile and substitutable between two countries, a risk premium can be added to the relationship just described; thus, rUS = rUK − Δε + x where x is the risk premium. Expected exchange rate changes and risk premium changes can produce enduring interest rate differentials between two countries. If the dollar falls relative to the yen, the euro, and the British pound, this is a sign that foreign investors were not as enthusiastic about U.S. investments. Low interest rates and high deficits may have convinced foreign investors that it was not a good time to invest in the United States. The United States is more dependent on foreign capital than ever before. Today, about half of U.S. Treasury debt held by the public is held by foreigners. Changes in inflation, interest rates, and expectations about exchange rates are important.
Exchange Rates and Aggregate Supply and Demand How do changes in nominal exchange rates affect aggregate demand and aggregate supply? A change in nominal exchange rates will affect imports and exports. Consider what happens, for example, when the value of the dollar depreciates. The dollar is weaker, and thus the pound (or any other currency) will buy more dollars. American products become more attractive in foreign markets; therefore, American exports increase and aggregate demand expands. Yet, because some inputs into the production process may be imported (raw materials, computer programming services, or call answering services), input costs will rise, causing aggregate supply to contract.
665
Let us take a more detailed look at this process by considering Figure 3. Assume that the economy begins in equilibrium at point e, with full employment output Qf and the price level at Pe. As the dollar depreciates, this will spur an increase in exports, thus shifting aggregate demand from AD0 to AD1 and raising prices to P1 in the short run. Initially, output climbs to Q1, but because some of the economy’s inputs are imported, short-run aggregate supply will decline, mitigating this rise in output. In the short run, the economy will expand beyond Qf, and prices will rise. In the longer term, as domestic prices rise, workers will realize that their real wages do not purchase as much as they did before, because import prices are higher. As a result, workers will start demanding higher wages just to bring them back to where they were originally. This shifts short-run aggregate supply from SRAS0 to SRAS1, thereby moving the economy from point a in the short run to point b in the long run. As the economy adjusts to a higher price level, the original benefits accruing from currency depreciation will be greatly reduced. Currency depreciation works because imports become more expensive and exports less so. When this happens, consumer income no longer goes as far, because the price of domestic goods does not change, but the cost of imports rises. In countries where imports form a substantial part of household spending, major depreciations in the national currency can produce significant declines in standards of living. Such depreciations (or devaluations) have occasioned strikes and, in some cases, even street riots; examples in recent decades include such actions in Argentina, Brazil, Mexico, and Indonesia. FIGURE 3
EXCHANGE RATES AND AGGREGATE DEMAND AND SUPPLY
Assume that the economy initially begins in equilibrium at point e, with full employment output Qf and the price level at Pe. Assume that the dollar depreciates. This will increase exports, shifting aggregate demand from AD0 to AD1 and raising prices to P1 and output to Q1 in the short run. In the long run, short-run aggregate supply will shift from SRAS0 to SRAS1, as workers readjust their wage demands in the long run, thus moving the economy to point b. As the economy adjusts to a higher price level, the benefits from currency depreciation are greatly reduced.
666
ISSUE Would a Stronger Chinese Yuan Be Good for Americans? Much discussion in recent years has focused on the accusation that the Chinese government manipulated the value of its currency, the yuan. What exactly did China do? When Americans purchase goods from China (and we purchase a whole lot of goods), normally dollars must be exchanged for yuan to pay for these goods. Factories in China need to pay their workers in yuan so that their workers can pay their rent and buy groceries. When dollars are exchanged for yuan, demand for yuan increases, which raises its value. Therefore, the yuan should appreciate against the dollar. When the yuan appreciates, it takes more dollars to obtain the same amount of yuan as before. Therefore, goods made in China, from toys you buy for your nephews and nieces to shoes, clothes, and electronics you buy for yourself, become more expensive. To prevent the prices of China’s exports from rising too much in the United States, the Chinese government bought up many of these dollars flowing into China, preventing them from being sold on the foreign exchange market. By holding U.S. dollars, the dollar value is kept from falling. In 2016, China held over 1 trillion in U.S. dollars. Who benefited from this policy and who lost out? The actions by the Chinese government to prevent the yuan from appreciating keeps prices of Chinese-made goods low for ordinary American consumers, especially benefiting those with limited budgets. Thanks, China, for helping the U.S. consumer. Who lost out? China’s policy made it harder for American (and other non-Chinese) companies to compete against Chinese imports. If the winners from this policy are American consumers and the losers are American businesses and their workers, policymakers are faced with quite a dilemma. Pressuring the Chinese to let its currency appreciate might be good for American companies, though it will lead to higher prices for many goods that we buy. Are we ready to see the cost of this policy come out of our pockets? Many Americans would be reluctant to support such an outcome, because it would have a similar effect as an increase in taxes or inflation. Both reduce the purchasing power of our income and savings.
Are you ready to pay more for everyday purchases? If the Chinese yuan appreciates, you may. Indeed, you can see that the debate about currency manipulation goes beyond whether one side is playing by the rules. Sometimes, fairness can be a costly proposition.
What are the implications of all this for policymakers? First, a currency depreciation or devaluation can, after a period, lead to inflation. In most cases, however, the causation probably goes the other way: Macroeconomic policies
667
or economic events force currency depreciations. Trade balances usually improve with an exchange rate depreciation. Policymakers can get improved current account balances without inflation by pursuing devaluation first, then pursuing fiscal contraction (reducing government spending or increasing taxes), and finally moving the economy back to point e in Figure 3. But here again, the real long-run benefit is more stable monetary and fiscal policies.
CHECKPOINT EXCHANGE RATES Nominal exchange rates define the rate at which one currency can be exchanged for another. Real exchange rates are the nominal exchange rates multiplied by the ratio of the price levels of the two countries. Purchasing power parity (PPP) is a rate of exchange that permits a given level of currency to purchase the same amount of goods and services in another country. A currency appreciates when its value rises relative to other currencies. Currency depreciation causes a currency to lose value relative to others. Inflation causes depreciation of a country’s currency, worsening its current account. Rising domestic income typically results in rising imports and a deteriorating current account. Rising interest rates cause capital to flow into the country with the higher interest rate, and expectations about a future currency appreciation or depreciation affect the capital account. Currency appreciation and depreciation have an effect on aggregate supply and demand. For example, currency depreciation expands aggregate demand as exports increase, but some (now higher-priced) imported inputs increase the cost of domestic production, reducing aggregate supply.
QUESTION: Cities along the U.S.–Canadian border, such as Vancouver, Niagara Falls, Detroit, and Buffalo, receive a substantial number of day visitors. For example, Americans might cross the border into Niagara Falls for a day of sightseeing, while Canadians might cross the border into Detroit to shop. Suppose that the value of the Canadian dollar appreciates against the U.S. dollar. How does this change affect tourism, businesses that depend on day-trippers, and the current account of the United States and Canada? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
668
MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY IN AN OPEN ECONOMY How monetary and fiscal policy is affected by international trade and finance depends on the type of exchange rate system in existence. There are several ways that exchange rate systems can be organized. We will discuss the two major categories: fixed and flexible rates.
Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rate Systems
A fixed exchange rate system is one in which governments determine their exchange rates, then adjust macroeconomic policies to maintain these rates. A flexible or floating exchange rate system, in contrast, relies on currency markets to determine the exchange rates consistent with macroeconomic conditions. fixed exchange rate Each government determines its exchange rate, then uses macroeconomic policy to maintain the rate. flexible or floating exchange rate A country’s currency exchange rate is determined in international currency exchange markets.
Before the Great Depression, most of the world economies were on the gold standard. According to Peter Temin, the gold standard was characterized by “(1) the free flow of gold between individuals and countries, (2) the maintenance of fixed values of national currencies in terms of gold and therefore each other, and (3) the absence of an international coordinating organization.”1 Under the gold standard, each country had to maintain enough gold stocks to keep the value of its currency fixed to that of others. If a country’s imports exceeded its exports, this balance of payments deficit had to come from its gold stocks. Because gold backed the national currency, the country would have to reduce the amount of money circulating in its economy, thereby reducing expenditures, output, and income. This reduction would lead to a decline in prices and wages, a rise in exports (which were getting cheaper), and a corresponding drop in imports (which were becoming more expensive). This process would continue until imports and exports were again equalized and the flow of gold ended. In the early 1930s, the U.S. Federal Reserve pursued a contractionary monetary policy intended to cool off the overheated economy of the 1920s. This policy reduced imports and increased the flow of gold into the United States. With France pursuing a similar deflationary policy, by 1932 these two countries held more than 70% of the world’s monetary gold. Other countries attempted to conserve their gold stocks by selling off assets, thereby spurring a worldwide monetary contraction. As other monetary authorities attempted to conserve their gold reserves, moreover, they reduced the liquidity available to their banks, thereby inadvertently causing bank failures. In this way, the Depression in the United States spread worldwide. As World War II came to an end, the Allies met in Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, to design a new and less troublesome international monetary system. Exchange rates were set, and each country agreed to use its monetary authorities to buy and sell its own currency to maintain its exchange rate at fixed levels. The Bretton Woods agreements created the International Monetary Fund to aid countries having trouble maintaining their exchange rates. In addition, the World Bank was established to loan money to countries for economic development. In the end, most countries were unwilling to make the tough adjustments required by a fixed rate system, and it collapsed in the early 1970s. Today, we operate on a flexible exchange rate system in which each currency floats in the market.
Pegging Exchange Rates Under a Flexible Exchange Rate System 669
Although most currencies fluctuate in value based on their relative demand and supply on the foreign exchange market, a number of countries use macroeconomic policies to peg their currency (maintain a fixed exchange rate) to another currency, most commonly the U.S. dollar or the euro. A common reason for a country to peg its currency to another is to maintain a close trade relationship, because fixed exchange rates prevent fluctuations in prices due to changes in the exchange rate. For example, most OPEC nations peg their currencies to the U.S. dollar as a result of their dependency on oil exports, a significant portion of which goes to the United States. Many Caribbean nations that depend on tourism and trade with the United States also peg their currencies to the U.S. dollar. Some countries do not maintain a strict fixed exchange rate with the U.S. dollar, but will intervene to control the exchange rate. For example, China has intervened in foreign exchange markets for strategic purposes, propping up the value of the U.S. dollar by holding dollars instead of exchanging them on the foreign exchange market. By keeping the U.S. dollar strong, the price of Chinese exports is kept low for American consumers, allowing China to continue expanding their export volume. Another reason for maintaining a fixed exchange rate is to improve monetary stability and to attract foreign investment. For example, several countries in western Africa peg their unified currency, the CFA franc, to the euro. By maintaining a fixed exchange rate, a country is essentially giving up its ability to conduct independent monetary policy. However, some countries such as Mexico and Argentina, both of which had pegged their currencies to the U.S. dollar in the past, were forced to abandon their efforts due to high inflation, which made their products too expensive in world markets. When traveling to Panama, it is not necessary to exchange money. Panama’s official currency is the U.S. dollar.
Finally, some countries chose to abandon their currency altogether by adopting another country’s currency as their own. Panama, Ecuador, El Salvador, Timor-Leste, and others, all chose to adopt the U.S. dollar as their official currency, a process known as dollarization. Not only did they give up their ability to use monetary policy, they also eliminated the risk of being unable to maintain fixed exchange rates with their original currencies. dollarization Describes the decision of a country to adopt another country’s currency (most often the U.S. dollar) as its own official currency.
There clearly are many approaches to foreign exchange used. But how does a fixed versus a flexible exchange rate system affect each country’s ability to use fiscal and monetary policy? We answer this question next.
Policies Under Fixed Exchange Rates 670
When the government engages in expansionary policy, aggregate demand rises, resulting in output and price increases. Figure 4 shows the result of such a policy as an increase in aggregate demand from AD0 to AD1, with the economy moving from equilibrium at point a to point b in the short run and the price level rising from P0 to P1. A rising domestic price level means that U.S. exports will decline as they become more expensive. As incomes rise, imports will rise. Combined, these forces will worsen the current account, moving it into deficit or reducing a surplus, as net exports decline. An expansionary monetary policy, combined with a fiscal policy that is neither expansionary nor contractionary, will result in a rising money supply and falling interest rates. This causes aggregate demand to rise to AD1 as shown in Figure 4. Lower interest rates result in capital flowing from the United States to other countries, which reduces aggregate output. FIGURE 4
MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY IN AN OPEN ECONOMY UNDER FIXED EXCHANGE RATES
When the government engages in expansionary policy, aggregate demand rises, resulting in output and price increases. A rising domestic price level reduces exports while rising incomes increase imports, worsening the current account. An expansionary monetary policy (holding fiscal policy constant) increases the money supply and reduces interest rates. Lower interest rates result in capital outflow, pushing aggregate demand back toward AD0. An expansionary fiscal policy (holding monetary policy constant) increases interest rates, leading to capital inflow, pushing aggregate demand further to the right to AD2.
The greater the capital mobility, the more aggregate demand moves back in the direction of AD0. With perfect capital mobility, monetary policy would be ineffective. The amount of capital leaving the United States would be just equal to the increase in the money supply to begin with, and interest rates would be returned to their original
671
international equilibrium.
ROBERT MUNDELL
NOBEL PRIZE A
warded the Nobel Prize in 1999, Robert Mundell is best known for his groundbreaking work in international economics and for his contribution to the development of supply-side economic theory. Born in Canada in 1932, he attended the University of British Columbia as an undergraduate and earned his Ph.D. from the Massachusetts Institute of Technology in 1956. For a year, he served as a postdoctoral fellow at the University of Chicago, where he met the economist Arthur Laffer, his collaborator in the development of supply-side theory. Supply-side economists advocated reductions in marginal tax rates and stabilization of the international monetary system. This approach was distinct from the two dominant schools of economic thought, Keynesianism and monetarism, although it shared some ideas with both. Mundell’s work had a major influence on the economic policies of President Ronald Reagan and Federal Reserve Chair Paul Volcker, whose tight money policies helped curb inflation. Mundell’s early research focused on exchange rates and the movement of international capital. In a series of papers in the 1960s that proved to be prophetic, he speculated about the impacts of monetary and fiscal policy if exchange rates were allowed to float, emphasizing the importance of central banks acting independently of governments to promote price stability. At the time, his work may have seemed purely academic. Within 10 years, however, the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates tied to the dollar broke down, exchange rates became more flexible, capital markets opened up, and Mundell’s ideas were borne out. In another feat of near prophecy, Mundell wrote about the potential benefits and disadvantages of a group of countries adopting a single currency, anticipating the development of the European currency, the euro, by many years. Since 1974, Mundell has taught at Columbia University.
Keeping exchange rates fixed and holding the money supply constant, an expansionary fiscal policy will produce an increase in interest rates. As income rises, there will be a greater transactions demand for money, resulting in higher interest rates. Higher interest rates mean that capital will flow into the United States. As more capital flows into U.S. capital markets, the expansionary impact of the original fiscal policy increases. Expansionary fiscal policy is reinforced by an open economy with fixed exchange rates as aggregate demand increases to AD2.
Policies Under Flexible Exchange Rates Expansionary monetary policy under a system of flexible exchange rates, again holding fiscal policy constant, results in a growing money supply and falling interest rates. Lower interest rates lead to a capital outflow and a balance of payments deficit, or a declining surplus. With flexible exchange rates, consumers and investors will want more foreign currency; thus, the exchange rate will depreciate. As the dollar depreciates, exports increase; U.S. exports are more attractive to foreigners as their currency buys them more. The net result is that the international market works to reinforce an expansionary policy undertaken at home. Permitting exchange rates to vary and holding the money supply constant, an expansionary fiscal policy produces
672
a rise in interest rates as rising incomes increase the transactions demand for money. Higher interest rates mean that capital will flow into the United States, generating a balance of payments surplus or a smaller deficit, causing the exchange rate to appreciate as foreigners value dollars more. As the dollar becomes more valuable, exports decline, moving aggregate demand back toward AD0 in Figure 4. With flexible exchange rates, therefore, an open economy can hamper fiscal policy. These movements are complex and go through several steps. Table 4 summarizes them for you. The key point to note is that under our flexible exchange rate system now, an open economy reinforces monetary policy and hampers fiscal policy. No wonder the Fed has become more important. Several decades ago, presidents and Congress could adopt monetary and fiscal policies without much consideration of the rest of the world. Today, economies of the world are vastly more intertwined, and the macroeconomic policies of one country often have serious impacts on others. Today, open economy macroeconomics is more important, and good macroeconomic policymaking must account for changes in exchange rates and capital flows.
TABLE 4
SUMMARY OF THE EFFECTS OF AN OPEN ECONOMY ON MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY IN A FIXED AND FLEXIBLE EXCHANGE RATE SYSTEM Flexible Exchange Rate
Fixed Exchange Rate
Reinforced
Hampered
Hampered
Reinforced
Monetary policy (fiscal policy constant) Fiscal policy (monetary policy constant)
During the financial crisis and recession of 2007–2009, the implications of monetary policy on exchange rates became important, as countries throughout the world were eager to use expansionary monetary policy to curtail the severity of the crisis. However, taking such action unilaterally can lead to adverse effects in other countries due to its effect on exchange rates, which affect trade and current accounts.
Hyder, Alaska: An American Town That Uses the Canadian Dollar How did an American town end up using Canadian currency, utility services, and schools?
I
n a number of countries throughout the world, the U.S. dollar is more than just a valuable reserve currency. It’s actually used as a medium of exchange. A few countries, including Panama, Ecuador, El Salvador, and Timor-Leste, have adopted the U.S. dollar as their official currency. But in many other countries, including Costa Rica, Bahamas, Cambodia, and Cuba, the U.S. dollar is accepted as legal tender as easily as their own currencies. In these countries, circumstances such as tourism and political instability encourage businesses to conduct transactions more often in U.S. dollars than in their own currency.
673
The 100 residents of Hyder, Alaska, live more like Canadians than Americans due to the town’s isolated location. But in one remote American town, the situation is reversed. Circumstances led its residents to conduct transactions in a foreign currency. Where is this place? Hyder, Alaska, is a town of 100 residents in the southeastern point of Alaska. There are no airports and very few boats that come in and out of its small harbor. And there is just one road going in and out of Hyder, and that road leads to Canada. Hyder is so economically wed to its larger sister city across the border, Stewart, British Columbia, that it relies on Canadian police, hospitals, utility services, and telecommunications (it has a Canadian area code). It also celebrates Canadian holidays because Hyder’s children attend schools in Canada. Most interestingly, Hyder adopted the Canadian dollar as its preferred currency. Although the American dollar is still legal tender in Hyder, its few businesses (with the exception of the U.S. Postal Service) conduct transactions in Canadian dollars. Much like why some countries use the U.S. dollar for convenience, businesses in Hyder use the Canadian dollar to reduce transaction costs by not having to exchange currency frequently. Because most of Hyder’s product suppliers are located in Canada, conducting transactions in Canadian dollars also means that the effects of exchange rate fluctuations are minimized. Hyder’s economic ties with its Canadian neighbor exemplify the importance of strong global relations and how that can benefit individuals and businesses.
GO TO
TO PRACTICE THE ECONOMIC CONCEPTS IN THIS STORY
Therefore, in October of 2008, six central banks including the Fed and the European Central Bank took a rare action of coordinated monetary policy, in which the central banks jointly announced a reduction in their target interest rates. As a result, countries engaging in a similar level of expansionary policy would prevent instability in exchange rates. As former Fed Chair Ben Bernanke put it, “The coordinated rate cut was intended to send a strong signal to the public and to markets of our resolve to act together to address global economic challenges.”2 The coordinated efforts of central banks continued over several years, especially when the Eurozone crisis intensified in 2011. The global economy is connected not only through trade and currency exchanges. Nearly all economic decisions have effects that extend beyond our country’s borders, from the types of goods that consumers purchase, to the goods firms produce and where they produce them, to how governments set policies that affect their citizens and those in other countries. As you complete your degree and prepare for your career, keep in mind the statement from Chapter 1 that has been illustrated throughout this book: Economics is all around us.
CHECKPOINT 674
MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY IN AN OPEN ECONOMY A fixed exchange rate is one in which governments determine their exchange rates and then use macroeconomic policy to maintain these rates. Flexible exchange rates rely on markets to determine exchange rates consistent with macroeconomic conditions. Some countries peg their currency to another to facilitate trade, to promote foreign investment, or to maintain monetary stability. Fixed exchange rate systems hinder monetary policy, but reinforce fiscal policy. Flexible exchange rates hamper fiscal policy, but reinforce monetary policy.
QUESTION: The United States seems to rely more on monetary policy to maintain stable prices, low
interest rates, low unemployment, and healthy economic growth. Does the fact that the United States has really embraced global trade (imports and exports combined are over 30% of GDP) and has a flexible (floating) exchange rate help explain why monetary policy seems more important than fiscal policy? Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.
675
chapter summary Section 1 The Balance of Payments 16.1
The current account includes payments for imports and exports of goods and services, incomes flowing into and out of the country, and net transfers of money. The capital account includes flows of money into and out of domestic and foreign assets. The sum of the current account and capital account balances must equal zero.
When foreign tourists visit Miami Beach, the money that is spent adds to the U.S. current account. When a foreign tourist purchases a vacation condo, the purchase of this asset increases the U.S. capital account. Foreign investment in the United States includes foreign ownership of domestic plants or subsidiaries; investments in mutual funds, stocks, and bonds; and deposits in U.S. banks. Similarly, U.S. investors hold foreign financial assets in their portfolios and own interests in foreign facilities and companies.
Section 2 Exchange Rates 676
16.2
The exchange rate defines the rate at which one currency can be exchanged for another. A nominal exchange rate is the price of one country’s currency for another. The real exchange rate takes price levels into account. The real exchange rate (er) is the nominal exchange rate (en) multiplied by the ratio of the price levels of the two countries: er = en × (Pd/Pf) If exchange rates are fully flexible, markets determine the prevailing exchange rate. If there is an excess demand for dollars, the dollar will appreciate, or rise in value. If there is an excess supply of dollars, the value of dollars will decline, or depreciate. The purchasing power parity of a currency is the rate of exchange at which currency used to purchase an amount of goods in one country can purchase the same amount of goods in another country.
Many services, such as playing a video game at a gaming center, are not easily traded. Therefore, price differences will exist based on the country’s standard of living, and often will not reflect purchasing power parity with other countries.
16.3
It is important to keep in mind which currency is being used to measure the price of others. Graphs can be viewed as showing either an appreciation or a depreciation, depending on which currency is being considered. In the figure, an increase in demand for U.S. dollars leads to its appreciation from 0.60 pounds per dollar to 0.75 pounds per dollar.
677
A shopping trip to the United States by British tourists increases demand for the dollar. Interest rates and exchange rate expectations affect the capital account. An interest rate rise in one country will cause capital to flow into it from the other country.
16.4
Real exchange rates affect the payments for imports and exports, and also affect the current account. Inflation leads to higher prices for exports, reducing their demand and worsening the current account. And greater domestic disposable income also worsens the current account as consumers increase spending on imports. Interest rates can differ between countries due to expected exchange rate changes (Δε) and a risk premium (x) when capital is not perfectly substitutable between countries. rUS = rUK − Δε + x
Section 3 Monetary and Fiscal Policy in an 678
Open Economy 16.5
A fixed exchange rate system is one in which governments determine their exchange rates, then use macroeconomic adjustments to maintain these rates. A flexible or floating exchange rate system relies on currency markets to determine the exchange rates, given macroeconomic conditions. Some countries choose to peg their currency to another in order to facilitate trade, attract foreign investment, or promote monetary stability.
Ecuador took an extreme form of fixed exchange rate by adopting the U.S. dollar as its official currency (a process known as dollarization).
16.6
The ability of a country to use fiscal policy and monetary policy is affected by the type of foreign exchange system in place. A fixed exchange rate system hinders expansionary monetary policy because lower interest rates lead to capital outflows, which slow the economy. A fixed exchange rate system reinforces expansionary fiscal policy because higher interest rates lead to capital inflows, which expand the economy. Flexible exchange rates hamper expansionary fiscal policy because higher interest rates lead to currency appreciation, which reduces net exports. Flexible exchange rates reinforce expansionary monetary policy because lower interest rates lead to currency depreciation, which increases net exports.
KEY CONCEPTS current account
679
capital account exchange rate nominal exchange rate real exchange rate purchasing power parity appreciation (currency) depreciation (currency) fixed exchange rate flexible or floating exchange rate dollarization
QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS Check Your Understanding 1. Describe the balance of trade. What factors contribute to our trade deficit? 2. Mexican immigrants working in the United States often send money back home (known as remittances) to help their families or to add to their savings account for the future. In 2015, these remittances surpassed $24 billion. How are these transfers recorded in the balance of payments accounts? 3. What is the important difference between the current account and the capital account, given that the sum of the two values must equal 0? 4. If the euro appreciates by 30%, what will happen to imports of Mercedes-Benz automobiles in the United States? 5. Describe the difference between fixed and flexible exchange rates. 6. Describe the difference between the nominal and real exchange rates. What does rising inflation do to a country’s real exchange rate?
Apply the Concepts 7. Assume that global warming and especially high temperatures in Northern California have rendered it impossible for wine grapes in the Napa Valley (and all over California) to grow properly. Unable to get California wines, demand jumps dramatically for Australian wines. How would this affect the Australian dollar? Is this good for other Australian exports? 8. If the European economies begin having a serious bout of stagflation—high rates of both unemployment and inflation—will this affect the value of the dollar? Explain. 9. Trace through the reasoning why monetary policy is enhanced by a flexible exchange rate system. 10. Zimbabwe devalued its currency in mid-2006, essentially turning a $20,000 Zimbabwe bill into a $20 bill. People were permitted only three weeks during which to turn in their old currency for new notes; individuals were limited to $150 a day and companies were restricted to $7,000 a day. Who do you think were the losers from this devaluation, especially considering the limited turn-in period for the old currency? 11. If it costs 300 U.S. dollars to purchase an iPad in the United States and 400 Australian dollars to purchase one in Sydney, then according to purchasing power parity, the exchange rate between the Australian dollar and the U.S. dollar should be 4:3. Why might purchasing power parity be different from the exchange rate? 12. When the dollar gets stronger against major foreign currencies, does the price of French wine rise or fall in the United States? Would this be a good time to travel to Australia? What happens to U.S. exports?
In the News 13. In 2012 the worldwide musical hit Gangnam Style by South Korean K-pop singer Psy contributed to a boost in tourism to South Korea. Tourists from China, Japan, and even the United States wanting to see the Gangnam
680
district in person helped South Korea’s economy in 2012. How does an increase in South Korean tourism affect the foreign exchange market for the South Korean won (its currency)? 14. The Eurozone crisis has led more than one nation to consider abandoning the euro and returning to its previous currency. If a nation were to exit the Eurozone and significantly devalue its currency against the euro and other major currencies, what are some implications for trade, the current account, and the standard of living for its citizens?
Solving Problems 15. Assume that the following exchange rates prevail: (U.S. $ Equivalent) 0.1904 0.9648 0.0812 2.6525
Argentina (peso) Canada (dollar) Mexico (peso) Bahrain (dinar)
How many Mexican pesos does it take to get 1 Bahraini dinar? If you had 20 U.S. dollars, could you take a ferry ride in Canada if it cost 25 Canadian dollars? If someone gave you 50 Argentinean pesos to settle a 150 Mexican peso bet, would it be enough?
WORK IT OUT 16. Suppose that you are given an opportunity to work in Tokyo over the summer as an English tutor, and you are provided with all living expenses and a 500,000-yen cash stipend that you plan to save and bring home. If the exchange rate is 120 yen per U.S. dollar, how much is your stipend worth in dollars if you exchanged your money right away? Suppose you predict that the exchange rate will change in the next few months to 110 yen per U.S. dollar. Would you receive more dollars if you exchange the yen now or later? Show your calculations.
USING THE NUMBERS 17. According to By the Numbers, if approximately $5.3 trillion of currency is traded each day in foreign exchange markets, about how much of this is traded in U.S. dollars? Euros? Japanese yen? 18. According to By the Numbers, if you travel to Jordan to visit the archaeological site of Petra and exchange 200 U.S. dollars, about how many Jordanian dinars would you receive? If you had traveled to Petra last year, would the amount of money received for your $200 have been different?
ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS Checkpoint: The Balance of Payments When a country has a high savings rate (relative to domestic investment), it is likely that its exports will exceed imports, resulting in a trade surplus. Both China and Russia are net exporters, which shows up as a current account surplus in their balance of payments accounts. Checkpoint: Exchange Rates When the Canadian dollar appreciates against the U.S. dollar, Canadian tourists visiting the United States receive more U.S. dollars for each Canadian dollar. Therefore, purchases by Canadian tourists in the United States become
681
cheaper. As a result, demand rises, helping American businesses that depend on Canadian tourists. Also, the increased flow of money into the United States helps improve the U.S. current account. Meanwhile, the opposite occurs for American tourists to Canada, who find it more expensive to visit Canada. Because the higher cost of travel will discourage some Americans from visiting Canada, Canadian businesses, such as those in Niagara Falls, will suffer. Also, the reduction in money being spent by Americans in Canada will hurt Canada’s current account. Checkpoint: Monetary and Fiscal Policy in an Open Economy As noted in this section, monetary policy is reinforced when exchange rates are flexible, while fiscal policy is hindered. This is probably only a partial explanation, because fiscal policy today seems driven more by “events” and other priorities, and less by stabilization issues. The deep recession a decade ago required heavy doses of both monetary and fiscal policy to keep the economy from a devastating downturn. Additional government spending, while huge, didn’t seem to pack the punch many thought it would. Maybe flexible exchange rates kept it from being as effective as anticipated. 1
Peter Temin, Lessons from the Great Depression: The Lionel Robbins Lectures for 1989 (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press), 1989, p. 8. 2
Ben Bernanke, Policy Coordination Among Central Banks, Speech at the Fifth European Central Banking Conference, The Euro at Ten: Lessons and Challenges, Frankfurt, Germany, November 14, 2008, http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20081214a.htm.
682
Sources for By the Numbers Chapter 1
Data for total number of bachelor’s degrees granted by major: Digest of Education Statistics, National Center for Education Statistics, U.S. Department of Education. Data for technology company CEO majors: “Study Finds Most Likely Tech Sector CEO Is Dave the Ivy League Ex-Yahoo Econ Major,” Forbes, September 28, 2012. Fortune 100 company CEO majors: Data from Curran Career Consulting. Percent of Fortune 500 companies founded by immigrants or their children: Data from Partnership for a New American Economy. Average pay by major: Data from Payscale.com Median salaries for economics jobs: Data from Payscale.com
Chapter 2
Farm productivity yields: Data from National Agricultural Statistics Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture. U.S. trade balance: Data from United States Census Bureau, U.S. Department of Commerce. Cost of firing workers by country: Data from World Development Indicators, The World Bank. American attitudes on environment and economic growth: Data from Gallup.com
Chapter 3
Data for growth of Uber drivers: Hall, Jonathan and Krueger, Alan (January 2015) “An Analysis of the Labor Market for Uber’s Driver-Partners in the United States.” Working Paper #587; Princeton University; Industrial Relations Section. Data for proportion of global video game revenues: Global Games Market Report; Newzoo.com Data for total value of the worldwide online gaming market: Global Games Market Report; Newzoo.com Total number of water bottles consumed: Data from IBWA (International Bottled Water Association) “Market Report Findings” Annual Update; www.bottledwater.org Total sales of bottled water: Data from IBWA (International Bottled Water Association) “Market Report Findings” Annual Update; www.bottledwater.org Data for College and university enrollment: Digest of Education Statistics, National Center for Education Statistics, U.S. Department of Education.
Chapter 4
683
Data for average in-state tuition at public universities by state: Trends in College Pricing, CollegeBoard.org Government subsidies for renewable energy by type: Data from Direct Federal Financial Interventions and Subsidies in Energy, U.S. Energy Information Administration. Minimum wage by state: Data from U.S. Department of Labor. U.S. farm subsidies: Data from Farm Subsidy Database, The Environmental Working Group, farm.ewg.org
Chapter 5
U.S. unemployment rate and real GDP growth by year: Data from Bureau of Economic Analysis, U.S. Department of Commerce; Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department of Labor. U.S. savings rate by year: Data from Bureau of Economic Analysis, U.S. Department of Commerce. U.S. gross domestic product: Data from Bureau of Economic Analysis, U.S. Department of Commerce. Gross world product: Data from World Development Indicators, The World Bank. State unemployment rates: Data from Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department of Labor.
Chapter 6
The Misery Index by year: Data from miseryindex.us State and federal unemployment benefits: Data from Pew Analysis of Congressional Budget Office data. Average yearly increase in Social Security benefits: Data from U.S. Social Security Administration, www.ssa.gov/news/cola/automatic-cola.htm The social costs of unemployment: Author calculations based on available data. Average cost of tuition at public and private universities by year and consumer price index: Data from National Center for Education Statistics, U.S. Department of Education; U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department of Labor. U.S. Index of Housing Prices: Data from Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED), Economic Research Division, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.
Chapter 7
U.S. real GDP per capita by year: Data from The World Factbook, Central Intelligence Agency. GDP and real GDP growth by country: Data from World Development Indicators, The World Bank; The Economist. Real GDP per capita and average life expectancy by country: Data from World Development Indicators, The World Bank. The tallest buildings in the world: Information compiled from various online sources.
Chapter 8
684
Government spending as a percentage of GDP by year: Data from Government Publishing Office: www.gpo.gov/fdsys/ Average government spending per person by country: Data from The World Factbook, Central Intelligence Agency. Total U.S. private domestic investment spending: Data from Bureau of Economic Analysis, U.S. Department of Commerce. Total U.S. spending by foreign consumers (exports): Data from Bureau of Economic Analysis, U.S. Department of Commerce. Top categories of personal consumption expenditures: Data from Bureau of Economic Analysis, U.S. Department of Commerce. Spending by local, state, and federal governments: Data from usgovernmentspending.com
Chapter 9
Media and entertainment revenues: Data from Statista.com Oil consumption in the United States and China in 1985 and 2015: Data from U.S. Energy Information Administration, U.S. Department of Energy. Total world aggregate demand: Data from The World Factbook, Central Intelligence Agency. Increase in NASDAQ stock index value: Data from CNBC.com Rates of home ownership by state: Data from U.S. Census Bureau, U.S. Department of Commerce.
Chapter 10
U.S. federal government revenues: Data www.cbo.gov/about/products/budget_economic_data U.S. federal government expenditures: Data www.cbo.gov/about/products/budget_economic_data
from from
Congressional Congressional
Budget
Office,
Budget
Office,
U.S. net government expenditures by year: Data from Historical Tables, Office of Management and Budget, The White House. U.S. external (foreign held) debt by year: Data from U.S. Department of the Treasury. Debt to the Penny (Daily History). Top ten creditors of U.S. Treasury Debt: Data from U.S. Department of the Treasury. Total U.S. national debt: Data from www.usdebtclock.org Total interest paid on the U.S. national debt: Data from Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED), Economic Research Division, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.
Chapter 11
The largest banks in the world: Data from www.relbanks.com/worlds-top-banks/assets The eight most circulated currencies and currency reserves in the world: Data from International Monetary Fund.
685
Total value of U.S. retirement accounts: Data from ICI Retirement Industry Report, Investment Company Institute. Total credit card debt in the United States: Data from U.S. Federal Reserve.
Chapter 12
U.S. monetary base by year: Data from Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED), Economic Research Division, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Euro monetary base: Data from European Central Bank. Number of U.S. bank failures by year: Data from Historical Statistics on Banking, Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation. Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation insured limits: Data from Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation. Federal Reserve balance sheet in 2005 and 2015: Data from U.S. Federal Reserve.
Chapter 13
U.S. 30-year mortgage, prime, discount, and federal funds rate: Data from Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED), Economic Research Division, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Total amount of U.S. dollars and coins in circulation: Data from Treasury Bulletin, Financial Management Service, U.S. Department of the Treasury. Total number of $100 bills in circulation: Data from Treasury Bulletin, Financial Management Service, U.S. Department of the Treasury. Facts about one million $1 bills: Data from Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. Holdings of U.S. $100 bills by region: Data from U.S. Federal Reserve.
Chapter 14
U.S. median existing home prices by year: Data from Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED), Economic Research Division, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. U.S. Index of Consumer Sentiment: Data from University of Michigan: Consumer Sentiment Index. U.S. monthly real retail sales: Data from Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED), Economic Research Division, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Total U.S. jobs lost during the Great Recession: Data from Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department of Labor. Total U.S. jobs created during the economic recovery: Data from Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department of Labor. Value of assets purchased by the Federal Reserve quantitative easing programs: Data from U.S. Federal Reserve.
Chapter 15
Trade deficit as a percent of GDP: Data from Foreign Trade Division, U.S. Census Bureau, U.S. Department of Commerce; FRED Database, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.
686
Trade-weighted tariff barriers: Data from World Development Indicators, The World Bank. Medical tourism services: Data from Companion Global Healthcare, Inc. Number of American cars sold in China: Author estimate based on sales reports from Ford, Fiat Chrysler, and General Motors. U.S. public sentiment on lower trade barriers: Data from 2014 National Survey of American Public Opinion, Chicago Council on Global Affairs. Buick sales in China and the United States: Data from General Motors.
Chapter 16
The most traded currencies in the world: Data from 2016 Triennial Central Bank Survey, Bank of International Settlements. U.S. Dollar Index: Data from Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED), Economic Research Division, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Total value of currency traded each day in foreign exchange markets: Data from 2016 Triennial Central Bank Survey, Bank of International Settlements. Percent of foreign exchange trades that are speculative: Information compiled from various sources. Value of currencies pegged to the U.S. dollar: Data from XE.com Composition of foreign exchange transactions: Data from 2016 Triennial Central Bank Survey, Bank of International Settlements.
687
Glossary absolute advantage One country can produce more of a good than another country. adaptive expectations Inflationary expectations are formed from a simple extrapolation from past events. aggregate demand The output of goods and services (real GDP) demanded at different price levels. aggregate expenditures Consist of consumer spending, business investment spending, government spending, and net foreign spending (exports minus imports): GDP = C + I + G + (X – M). aggregate supply The real GDP that firms will produce at varying price levels. The aggregate supply curve is positively sloped in the short run but vertical in the long run. allocative efficiency The mix of goods and services produced is just what the society desires. annually balanced budget Expenditures and taxes would have to be equal each year. appreciation (currency) When the value of a currency rises relative to other currencies. asymmetric information Occurs when one party to a transaction has significantly better information than another party. autarky A country that does not engage in international trade, also known as a closed economy. automatic stabilizers Tax revenues and transfer payments automatically expand or contract in ways that reduce the intensity of business fluctuations without any overt action by Congress or other policymakers. average propensity to consume The percentage of income that is consumed (C÷Y). average propensity to save The percentage of income that is saved (S÷Y). balanced budget multiplier Equal changes in government spending and taxation (a balanced budget) lead to an equal change in income (the balanced budget multiplier is equal to 1). barter
The direct exchange of goods and services for other goods and services.
business cycles Alternating increases and decreases in economic activity that are typically punctuated by periods of recession and recovery.
688
capital Includes manufactured products such as tractors, welding equipment, and computers that are used to produce other goods and services. The payment for capital is interest. capital account Summarizes the flow of money into and out of domestic and foreign assets, including investments by foreign companies in domestic plants or subsidiaries, and other foreign holdings of U.S. assets, including mutual funds, stocks, bonds, and deposits in U.S. banks. Also included are U.S. investors’ holdings of foreign financial assets, production facilities, and other assets in foreign countries. capital-to-labor ratio The capital employed per worker. A higher ratio means higher labor productivity and, as a result, higher wages. catch-up effect Countries with smaller starting levels of capital experience larger benefits from increased capital, allowing these countries to grow faster than countries with abundant capital. ceteris paribus Assumption used in economics (and other disciplines as well), that other relevant factors or variables are held constant. change in demand Occurs when one or more of the determinants of demand changes, shown as a shift in the entire demand curve. change in quantity demanded Occurs when the price of the product changes, shown as a movement along an existing demand curve. change in quantity supplied Occurs when the price of the product changes, shown as a movement along an existing supply curve. change in supply Occurs when one or more of the determinants of supply change, shown as a shift in the entire supply curve. circular flow diagram Illustrates how households and firms interact through product and resource markets and shows that economic aggregates can be determined by examining either spending flows or income flows to households. comparative advantage One country has a lower opportunity cost of producing a good than another country. complementary goods Goods that are typically consumed together. When the price of a complementary good rises, the demand for the other good declines, and vice versa. compounding The ability of growth to build on previous growth. It allows variables such as income and GDP (as well as debt) to increase significantly over time. compounding effect The effect of interest added to existing debt or savings leading to substantial growth in debt or savings over the long run. consumer price index (CPI) An index of the average prices paid by urban consumers for a typical market basket of consumer goods and services.
689
consumer surplus The difference between what consumers (as individuals or the market) would be willing to pay and the market price. It is equal to the area above market price and below the demand curve. consumption Spending by individuals and households on both durable goods (e.g., autos, appliances, and electronic equipment) and nondurable goods (e.g., food, clothing, and entertainment). contractionary fiscal policy Policies that decrease aggregate demand to contract output in an economy. These include reducing government spending, reducing transfer payments, and/or raising taxes. contractionary monetary policy Fed actions designed to decrease the money supply and raise interest rates to shrink income and employment, usually to fight inflation. cost-push inflation Results when a supply shock hits the economy, reducing short-run aggregate supply, and thus reducing output and increasing the price level. credit default swap A financial instrument that insures against the potential default on an asset. Because of the extent of defaults in the last financial crisis, issuers of credit default swaps could not repay all of the claims, bankrupting these financial institutions. crowding-out effect When deficit spending requires the government to borrow, interest rates are driven up, reducing consumer spending and business investment. current account Includes payments for imports and exports of goods and services, incomes flowing into and out of the country, and net transfers of money. cyclical unemployment Unemployment that results from changes in the business cycle, and where public policymakers can have their greatest impact by keeping the economy on a steady, low-inflationary, solid growth path. cyclically balanced budget Balancing the budget over the course of the business cycle by restricting spending or raising taxes when the economy is booming and using these surpluses to offset the deficits that occur during recessions. deadweight loss The reduction in total surplus that results from the inefficiency of a market not in equilibrium. decision lag The time it takes Congress and the administration to decide on a policy once a problem is recognized. deficit The amount by which annual government expenditures exceed tax revenues. deflation A decline in overall prices throughout the economy. This is the opposite of inflation. demand The maximum amount of a product that buyers are willing and able to purchase over some time period at various prices, holding all other relevant factors constant (the ceteris paribus condition). demand curve A graphical illustration of the law of demand, which shows the relationship between the price of a good and the quantity demanded.
690
demand schedule A table that shows the quantity of a good a consumer purchases at each price. demand-pull inflation Results when aggregate demand expands so much that equilibrium output exceeds full employment output and the price level rises. depreciation (currency) When the value of a currency falls relative to other currencies. determinants of demand Nonprice factors that affect demand, including tastes and preferences, income, prices of related goods, number of buyers, and expectations. determinants of supply Nonprice factors that affect supply, including production technology, costs of resources, prices of related commodities, expectations, number of sellers, and taxes and subsidies. diminishing returns to capital Each additional unit of capital provides a smaller increase in output than the previous unit of capital. discount rate The interest rate the Federal Reserve charges commercial banks and other depository institutions to borrow reserves from a regional Federal Reserve Bank. discouraged workers Discouraged workers are the portion of marginally attached workers who have given up actively looking for work and, as a result, are not counted as unemployed. discretionary fiscal policy Policies that involve adjusting government spending and tax policies with the express short-run goal of moving the economy toward full employment, expanding economic growth, or controlling inflation. discretionary spending The part of the budget that works its way through the appropriations process of Congress each year and includes national defense, transportation, science, environment, and income security. disinflation A reduction in the rate of inflation. An economy experiencing disinflation still faces inflation, but at a declining rate. dollarization Describes the decision of a country to adopt another country’s currency (most often the U.S. dollar) as its own official currency. double-dip recession A recession that begins after only a short period of economic recovery from the previous recession. dumping Selling goods abroad at lower prices than in home markets, and often below cost. easy money, quantitative easing, or accommodative monetary policy Fed actions designed to increase excess reserves and the money supply to stimulate the economy (increase income and employment). See also expansionary monetary policy. economic growth Usually measured by the annual percentage change in real GDP, reflecting an improvement in the standard of living. economics The study of how individuals, firms, and society make decisions to allocate limited resources to many
691
competing wants. efficiency How well resources are used and allocated. Do people get the goods and services they want at the lowest possible resource cost? This is the chief focus of efficiency. efficiency wage theory Employers often pay their workers wages above the market-clearing level to improve morale and productivity, reduce turnover, and create a disincentive for employees to shirk their duties. entrepreneurs Entrepreneurs combine land, labor, and capital to produce goods and services. They absorb the risk of being in business, including the risk of bankruptcy and other liabilities associated with doing business. Entrepreneurs receive profits for their effort. equation of exchange The heart of classical monetary theory uses the equation M × V = P × Q, where M is the supply of money, V is the velocity of money (the average number of times per year a dollar is spent on goods and services, or the number of times it turns over in a year), P is the price level, and Q is the economy’s real output level. equilibrium Market forces are in balance when the quantities demanded by consumers just equal the quantities supplied by producers. equilibrium price The price at which the quantity demanded is just equal to quantity supplied. equilibrium quantity The output that results when quantity demanded is just equal to quantity supplied. equity
The fairness of various issues and policies.
excess reserves Reserves held by banks above the legally required amount. exchange rate The rate at which one currency can be exchanged for another. expansionary fiscal policy Policies that increase aggregate demand to expand output in an economy. These include increasing government spending, increasing transfer payments, and/or decreasing taxes. expansionary monetary policy Fed actions designed to increase the money supply and lower interest rates to stimulate the economy (expand income and employment). exports Goods and services that are sold abroad. externally held debt Public debt held by foreigners, including foreign industries, banks, and governments. federal funds rate The interest rate financial institutions charge each other for overnight loans used as reserves. Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) A twelve-member committee that is composed of members of the Board of Governors of the Fed and selected presidents of the regional Federal Reserve Banks. It oversees open market operations (the buying and selling of government securities), the main tool of monetary policy.
692
Federal Reserve System The central bank of the United States. fiat money Money without intrinsic value but nonetheless accepted as money because the government has decreed it to be money. financial intermediaries Financial firms (banks, mutual funds, insurance companies, etc.) that acquire funds from savers and then lend these funds to borrowers (consumers, firms, and governments). financial system A complex set of institutions, including banks, bond markets, and stock markets, that allocate scarce resources (financial capital) from savers to borrowers. fiscal sustainability A measure of the present value of all projected future revenues compared to the present value of projected future spending. fixed exchange rate Each government determines its exchange rate, then uses macroeconomic policy to maintain the rate. flexible or floating exchange rate A country’s currency exchange rate is determined in international currency exchange markets. fractional reserve banking system Describes a banking system in which a portion of bank deposits are held as vault cash or in an account with the regional Federal Reserve Bank, while the rest of the deposits are loaned out to generate the money creation process. frictional unemployment Unemployment resulting from workers who voluntarily quit their jobs to search for better positions, or are moving to new jobs but may still take several days or weeks before they can report to their new employers. functional finance An approach that focuses on fostering economic growth and stable prices, while keeping the economy as close as possible to full employment. GDP deflator An index of the average prices for all goods and services in the economy, including consumer goods, investment goods, government goods and services, and exports. It is the broadest measure of inflation in the national income and product accounts (NIPA). GDP per capita A country’s GDP divided by its population. GDP per capita provides a useful measure of a country’s relative standard of living. government budget constraint The government budget is limited by the fact that G – T = ΔM + ΔB + ΔA. government spending Includes the wages and salaries of government employees (federal, state, and local); the purchase of products and services from private businesses and the rest of the world; and government purchases of new structures and equipment. gross domestic product (GDP) A measure of the economy’s total output; it is the most widely reported value in the national income and product accounts (NIPA) and is equal to the total market value of all final goods and services produced by resources in a given year.
693
gross private domestic investment (GPDI) Investments in such things as structures (residential and nonresidential), equipment, and software, and changes in private inventories. horizontal summation The process of adding the number of units of the product purchased or supplied at each price to determine market demand or supply. hyperinflation An extremely high rate of inflation; above 100% per year. implementation lag The time required to turn fiscal policy into law and eventually have an impact on the economy. imports Goods and services that are purchased from abroad. incentives The factors that motivate individuals and firms to make decisions in their best interest. infant industry An industry so underdeveloped that protection is needed for it to become competitive on the world stage or to ensure its survival. inferior good A good for which an increase in income results in declining demand. inflation A general rise in prices throughout the economy. It is a measure of changes in the cost of living. inflation targeting The central bank sets a target on the inflation rate (usually around 2% per year) and adjusts monetary policy to keep inflation near that target. inflationary expectations The rate of inflation expected by workers for any given period. Workers do not work for a specific nominal wage but for what those wages will buy (real wages); therefore, their inflationary expectations are an important determinant of what nominal wage they are willing to work for. inflationary gap The spending reduction necessary (when expanded by the multiplier) to bring an overheated economy back to full employment. informal economy Includes all transactions that are conducted but are not licensed and/or generate income that is not reported to the government (for tax collection). information lag The time policymakers must wait for economic data to be collected, processed, and reported. Most macroeconomic data are not available until at least one quarter (three months) after the fact. infrastructure The public capital of a nation, including transportation networks, power-generating plants and transmission facilities, public education institutions, and other intangible resources such as protection of property rights and a stable monetary environment. injections Increments of spending, including investment, government spending, and exports.
694
internally held debt Public debt owned by domestic banks, corporations, mutual funds, pension plans, and individuals. investment Spending by businesses that adds to the productive capacity of the economy. Investment depends on factors such as its rate of return, the level of technology, and business expectations about the economy. investment in human capital Improvements to the labor force from investments in skills, knowledge, and the overall quality of workers and their productivity. jobless recovery A phenomenon that takes place after a recession, when output begins to rise, but employment growth does not. Keynesian macroeconomic equilibrium The state of an economy at which all injections equal all withdrawals. There are no pressures pushing the economy to a higher or lower level of output. labor
Includes the mental and physical talents of individuals who produce products and services. The payment to labor is wages.
labor force The total number of those employed and unemployed. The unemployment rate is the number of unemployed divided by the labor force, expressed as a percent. Laffer curve A curve that shows a hypothetical relationship between income tax rates and tax revenues. As tax rates rise from zero, revenues rise, reach a maximum, then decline until revenues reach zero again at a 100% tax rate. laissez-faire A market that is allowed to function without any government intervention. land
Includes natural resources such as mineral deposits, oil, natural gas, water, and land in the usual sense of the word. The payment for land used as a resource is rent.
law of demand Holding all other relevant factors constant, as price increases, quantity demanded falls, and as price decreases, quantity demanded rises. law of supply Holding all other relevant factors constant, as price increases, quantity supplied rises, and as price declines, quantity supplied falls. leakages A reduction in the amount of money that is used for lending that reduces the money multiplier. It is caused by banks choosing to hold excess reserves and from individuals, businesses, and foreigners choosing to hold more cash. leverage Occurs when a small amount of capital is used to support a larger amount of investment by borrowing. The risk of highly leveraged investments is that a small decrease in price can wipe out one’s account. liquidity
695
How quickly, easily, and reliably an asset can be converted into cash. liquidity trap When interest rates are so low, people hold on to money rather than invest in bonds due to their expectations of a declining economy or an unforeseen event such as war. long-run aggregate supply (LRAS) curve The long-run aggregate supply curve is vertical at full employment because the economy has reached its capacity to produce. M1
M2
The narrowest definition of money that measures highly liquid instruments including currency (banknotes and coins), demand deposits (checks), and other accounts that have check-writing or debit capabilities. A broader definition of money that includes “near monies” that are not as liquid as cash, including deposits in savings accounts, money market accounts, and money market mutual fund accounts.
macroeconomic equilibrium Occurs at the intersection of the short-run aggregate supply and aggregate demand curves. At this output level, there are no net pressures for the economy to expand or contract. macroeconomics The study of the broader issues in the economy such as inflation, unemployment, and national output of goods and services. mandatory spending Spending authorized by permanent laws that does not go through the same appropriations process as discretionary spending. Mandatory spending includes Social Security, Medicare, and interest on the national debt. marginal propensity to consume The change in consumption associated with a given change in income (ΔC÷ΔY). marginal propensity to save The change in saving associated with a given change in income (ΔS÷ΔY). marginally attached workers Workers who were available for work and actively looked for it during the last 12 months, but not in the last 4 weeks. market failure Occurs when a free market does not lead to a socially desirable outcome. markets Institutions that bring buyers and sellers together, so they can interact and transact with each other. medium of exchange A function of money in which goods and services are sold for money, then the money is used to purchase other goods and services. microeconomics The study of the decision making by individuals, businesses, and industries. misallocation of resources Occurs when a good or service is not consumed by the person who values it the most, and typically results when a price ceiling creates an artificial shortage in the market. monetary rule Keeps the growth of money stocks such as M1 or M2 on a steady path, following the equation of
696
exchange (or quantity theory), to set a long-run path for the economy that keeps inflation in check. monetized debt Occurs when debt is reduced by increasing the money supply, thereby making each dollar less valuable through inflation. money Anything that is accepted in exchange for goods and services or for the payment of debt. money illusion A misperception of wealth caused by a focus on increases in nominal income but not increases in prices. money multiplier A formula that measures the potential or maximum amount the money supply can increase (or decrease) when a dollar of new deposits enters (exits) the system and is defined as 1 divided by the reserve requirement. multiplier Spending changes alter equilibrium income by the spending change times the multiplier. One person’s spending becomes another’s income, and that second person spends some (the MPC), which becomes income for another person, and so on, until income has changed by 1/(1 – MPC) = 1/MPS. The multiplier operates in both directions. national debt The total debt issued by the U.S. Treasury, which represents the total accumulation of past deficits less surpluses. A portion of this debt is held by other government agencies, and the rest is held by the public. It is also referred to as the gross federal debt. national income All income, including wages, salaries and benefits, profits (for sole proprietors, partnerships, and corporations), rental income, and interest. natural rate of unemployment The level of unemployment at which price and wage decisions are consistent; a level at which the actual inflation rate is equal to people’s inflationary expectations and where cyclical unemployment is zero. net exports Exports minus imports for the current period. Exports include all goods and services we sell abroad, while imports include all goods and services we buy from other countries. nominal exchange rate The price of one country’s currency for another. normal good A good for which an increase in income results in rising demand. normative question A question whose answer is based on societal beliefs on what should or should not take place. open market operations The buying and selling of U.S. government securities, such as Treasury bills and bonds, to adjust reserves in the banking system. opportunity cost The value of the next best alternative; what you give up to do something or purchase something. Also, it is the cost paid for a product in terms of the output of another product that must be forgone.
697
paradox of thrift When investment is positively related to income and households intend to save more, they reduce consumption. Consequently, income and output decrease, reducing investment such that savings actually end up decreasing. pensions A retirement program into which an employer pays a monthly amount to retired employees until they die. personal consumption expenditures Goods and services purchased by residents of the United States, whether individuals or businesses; they include durable goods, nondurable goods, and services. Phillips curve The original curve posited a negative relationship between wages and unemployment, but later versions related unemployment to inflation rates. positive question A question that can be answered using available information or facts. price ceiling A maximum price established by government for a product or service. When the price ceiling is set below equilibrium, a shortage results. price floor A minimum price established by government for a product or service. When the price floor is set above equilibrium, a surplus results. price level The absolute level of a price index, whether the consumer price index (CPI; retail prices), the producer price index (PPI; wholesale prices), or the GDP deflator (average price of all items in GDP). price system A name given to the market economy because prices provide considerable information to both buyers and sellers. producer price index (PPI) An index of the average prices received by domestic producers for their output. producer surplus The difference between the market price and the price at which firms are willing to supply the product. It is equal to the area below market price and above the supply curve. production The process of converting resources (factors of production)—land, labor, capital, and entrepreneurial ability—into goods and services. production efficiency Goods and services are produced at their lowest resource (opportunity) cost. production function Measures the output that is produced using various combinations of inputs and a fixed level of technology. production possibilities frontier (PPF) Shows the combinations of two goods that are possible for a society to produce at full employment. Points on or inside the PPF are attainable, and those outside of the frontier are unattainable. productivity How effectively inputs are converted into outputs. Labor productivity is the ratio of the output of goods and services to the labor hours devoted to the production of that output. Productivity and living standards are closely related.
698
public choice theory The economic analysis of public and political decision making, looking at issues such as voting, the impact of election incentives on politicians, the influence of special interest groups, and rent-seeking behaviors. public debt The portion of the national debt that is held by the public, including individuals, companies, pension funds, along with foreign entities and foreign governments. This debt is also referred to as net debt or federal debt held by the public. purchasing power parity The rate of exchange that allows a specific amount of currency in one country to purchase the same quantity of goods in another country. quota
A government-set limit on the quantity of imports into a country.
rational expectations Rational economic agents are assumed to make the best possible use of all publicly available information, then make informed, rational judgments on what the future holds. Any errors in their forecasts will be randomly distributed. real exchange rate A measure of a currency’s value relative to another, taking into account the price levels of both countries. It is equal to the nominal exchange rate multiplied by the ratio of the price levels of the two countries. real GDP The total value of final goods and services produced in a country in a year measured using prices in a base year. real GDP per capita Real GDP divided by population. Provides a rough estimate of a country’s standard of living. recessionary gap The increase in aggregate spending needed (when expanded by the multiplier) to bring a depressed economy back to full employment. recognition lag The time it takes for policymakers to confirm that the economy is in a recession or a recovery. Shortterm variations in key economic indicators are typical and sometimes represent nothing more than randomness in the data. reserve ratio The percentage of a bank’s total deposits that are held in reserves, either as cash in the vault or as deposits at the regional Federal Reserve Bank. reserve requirement The required ratio of funds that commercial banks and other depository institutions must hold in reserve against deposits. resources Productive resources include land (land and natural resources), labor (mental and physical talents of people), capital (manufactured products used to produce other products), and entrepreneurial ability (the combining of the other factors to produce products and assume the risk of the business). return on investment The earnings, such as interest or capital gains, that a saver receives for making funds available to others.
699
It is calculated as earnings divided by the amount invested. Rule of 70 Provides an estimate of the number of years for a value to double, and is calculated as 70 divided by the annual growth rate. saving The difference between income and consumption; the amount of disposable income not spent. scarcity Our unlimited wants clash with limited resources, leading to scarcity. Everyone (rich and poor) faces scarcity because, at a minimum, our time on earth is limited. Economics focuses on the allocation of scarce resources to satisfy unlimited wants as fully as possible. shortage Occurs when the price is below market equilibrium, and quantity demanded exceeds quantity supplied. short-run aggregate supply (SRAS) curve The short-run aggregate supply curve is positively sloped because many input costs are slow to change (sticky) in the short run. solvency crisis A situation when a bank’s liabilities exceed its assets. stagflation Simultaneous occurrence of rising inflation and rising unemployment. store of value The function that enables people to save the money they earn today and use it to buy the goods and services they want tomorrow. structural unemployment Unemployment caused by changes in the structure of consumer demands or technology. It means that demand for some products declines and the skills of this industry’s workers often become obsolete as well. This results in an extended bout of unemployment while new skills are developed. subprime mortgage Mortgages that are given to borrowers who are a poor credit risk. These higher-risk loans charge a higher interest rate, which can be profitable to lenders if borrowers make their payments on time. substitute goods Goods consumers will substitute for one another. When the price of one good rises, the demand for the other good increases, and vice versa. supply The maximum amount of a product that sellers are willing and able to provide for sale over some time period at various prices, holding all other relevant factors constant (the ceteris paribus condition). supply curve A graphical illustration of the law of supply, which shows the relationship between the price of a good and the quantity supplied. supply-side fiscal policies Policies that focus on shifting the long-run aggregate supply curve to the right, expanding the economy without increasing inflationary pressures. Unlike policies to increase aggregate demand, supply-side policies take longer to impact the economy. surplus Occurs when the price is above market equilibrium, and quantity supplied exceeds quantity demanded. It is also the amount by which annual tax revenues exceed government expenditures.
700
tariff
A tax on imported products. When a country taxes imported products, it drives a wedge between the product’s domestic price and its price on the world market.
Taylor rule A rule for the federal funds target that suggests the target is equal to 2% + Current Inflation Rate + 1/2(Inflation Gap) + 1/2(Output Gap). teaser rates Promotional low interest rates offered by lenders for a short period of time to attract new customers and to encourage spending. terms of trade The ratio of the price of exported goods to the price of imported goods (Px/Pm). tight money or restrictive monetary policy Fed actions designed to decrease excess reserves and the money supply to shrink income and employment, usually to fight inflation. See also contractionary monetary policy. total factor productivity The portion of output produced that is not explained by the number of inputs used in production. total surplus The sum of consumer surplus and producer surplus, and a measure of the overall net benefit gained from a market transaction. tradeoff between risk and return The pattern of higher risk assets offering higher average annual returns on investment than lower risk assets. underemployed workers Workers who are forced to take jobs that do not fully utilize their education, background, or skills. Underemployed workers often hold part-time jobs. unit of account Money provides a yardstick for measuring and comparing the values of a wide variety of goods and services. It eliminates the problem of double coincidence of wants associated with barter. vesting period The minimum number of years a worker must be employed before the company’s contribution to a retirement account becomes permanent. wealth effect Households usually hold some of their wealth in financial assets such as savings accounts, bonds, and cash, and a rising aggregate price level means that the purchasing power of this monetary wealth declines, reducing output demanded. willingness-to-pay An individual’s valuation of a good or service, equal to the most an individual is willing and able to pay. withdrawals Activities that remove spending from the economy, including saving, taxes, and imports. yield curve
701
Shows the relationship between the interest rate earned on a bond (measured on the vertical axis) and the length of time until the bond’s maturity date (shown on the horizontal axis).
702
Index Note: Page numbers followed by f indicate figures; those followed by t indicate tables; those followed by n indicate notes.
A Absolute advantage, 43–45, 44f, 44t, 381 Accommodative monetary policy, 332 AD. See Aggregate demand (AD) curve Adaptive expectations, 361–362 AD/AS model. See Aggregate demand-aggregate supply (AD/AS) model Ad valorem taxes, 387 Africa. See also specific countries economic growth of, 162
Aggregate demand (AD) curve, 214–218, 214f determinants of, 215–218, 216f, 217t exchange rates and, 414, 415f, 416 negative slope of, 214–215
Aggregate demand-aggregate supply (AD/AS) model, 211–231 aggregate demand and, 214–218, 214f aggregate supply and, 219–223 macroeconomic equilibrium and, 223–229, 223f
Aggregate expenditures, 183–207 consumption and saving and, 186–190, 188t investment and, 190–193, 191f models of. See Full aggregate expenditures model; Simple aggregate expenditures model simplifying assumptions and, 186 summing, 119
Aggregate investment schedule, 192–193, 192f Aggregate supply curve, 219–223 exchange rates and, 414, 415f, 416 fiscal policy and, 245–249, 246f long-run, 219–220, 219f short-run, 220–222, 220f
Airbnb, 147 Allen, Robert, 326n Allocative efficiency, 6, 34 Amazon.com, 56 American Recovery and Reinvestment Act, 355. See also Stimulus package Angola, oil deposits in, 170 Angry Birds, 59 Annually balanced budget, 253 APC. See Average propensity to consume (APC) Apple Computer Inc., profits and, 12 Appreciation, of currencies, 411–412, 412f APS. See Average propensity to save (APS) Argentina, currency of, 418 Asia, economic growth of, 162 Assets
703
allocation of, risk assessment and, 283 choosing, for investment in, 284 diversification of, by financial institutions, 278 financial, types of, 278–279 prices of, shifts in supply of loanable funds and, 276
Asymmetric information, market failure and, 92–93 Athens, Greece, Olympic Games in, 268 Australia plastic money in, 272 saving rate in, 199
Autarky, 380 Automatic stabilizers, 249–250 Automobile industry bailout of, 355 Japanese, quotas on exports of, 389
Autonomous investment, 192 Average propensity to consume (APC), 188, 188t Average propensity to save (APS), 188, 188t
B Bahamas, acceptance of U.S. dollar as legal tender in, 420 Balanced budget amendments, 253–255 Balanced budget multiplier, 202–203 Balance of payments, 406–407, 406t capital account and, 407 current account and, 406–407
Bank(s) central. See European Central Bank (ECB); Federal Reserve System Federal Reserve, 306–307, 306t housing bubble and, 353 leakages and, 301–302 money creation by, 296–300 reserves and. See Reserve(s) Swiss bank accounts and, 303 World Bank, 417
Banking system, fractional reserve, 298–300 Bar charts, 22, 22f Barter, 270 BEA. See Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) Bear Stearns, 354 Benefits, 2 Bernanke, Ben, 338, 421 Bhutan, capital-to-labor ratio in, 171 Big Mac Index, 409–410, 409t BLS. See Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) Board of Governors, 305 rules vs. discretion and, 333
Bonds, prices of, interest rates and, 279–280 Booms. See also Business cycles of 1990s, 191
Borrowing Fed as lender of last resort and, 307 financial system and, 277–278 government’s bias toward, 250–251 microloans and, 294, 295
704
short-term, 281–282 subprime mortgages and collateralized debt obligations and, 352–354
Bottled water industry, 54 Branson, Richard, 10 Brazil economic growth of, 160, 162, 200 GDP of, 121 public debt of, 256
Breit, William, 91n Bretton Woods agreements, 417 Brexit, 342 BRIC countries. See Brazil; China; India; Russia Bronco Wine Company, 73 Buchanan, James, 251 Budget annually balanced, 253 cyclically balanced, 253–254
Budget constraints, government budget and, 255 Budget deficits, 252 financing of, 255
Budget surpluses, 252 Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA), 162, 384, 406 Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) consumer spending and inflation measurement by, 135–136, 137 employment statistics and, 142 employment surveys of, 145
Burns, Arthur, 109 Bush, George H. W., tax increase under, 241 Bush, George W. tax cut under, 240–241 tax rebate under, 246
Business(es). See also Firms expectations of, shifts in demand for loanable funds and, 276 leakages by, 302
Business cycles, 108–114. See also Great Recession; Recession(s) dating of, 110–111, 113 definition of, 109–110, 109f, 110f measures of, 110–111 turning points and, 113
Busts. See Business cycles Buyers, number of, demand and, 62
C Cambodia, acceptance of U.S. dollar as legal tender in, 420 Cameroon, oil deposits in, 170 Canada NAFTA and, 46, 384, 393 Nunavut’s resources and, 14 public debt of, 256 saving rate in, 199
Candy Crush Saga, 59 Canterbery, E. Ray, 43, 71n Capacity, short- vs. long-term economic growth and, 166–167, 167f
705
Capital, 33 diminishing returns to, 171 human. See Human capital physical. See Physical capital
Capital account, 407 exchange rates and, 413–414
Capital accumulation, economic growth and, 39–40, 39f, 40f Capital goods, on hand, investment demand and, 192 Capitalist economies, 32 Capital-to-labor ratio, increasing, economic growth and, 171 Catch-up effect, 171 Causation, correlation vs., 28 C-CPI-U, 137 CDOs. See Collateralized debt obligations (CDOs) Census Bureau, 142 employment surveys of, 145, 147
Central banks. See European Central Bank (ECB); Federal Reserve System CES. See Current employment Statistics (CES) Ceteris paribus assumption, 6, 26–27 Changes in demand changes in quantity demanded vs., 62–63, 63f for loanable funds, 276 move to a new equilibrium and, 72–74, 72f, 74f, 74t
Changes in quality demanded, changes in demand vs., 62–63, 63f Changes in quantity supplied, changes in supply vs., 67, 67f, 68f Changes in supply changes in quantity supplied vs., 67, 67f, 68f of loanable funds, 275–276 move to a new equilibrium and, 71–72, 72f, 73–74, 74f, 74t
Chauvet, Marcelle, 110n Chile pollution in, 123 public debt of, 256, 257
China clothing production in, 386 comparative advantage of, 47 demand for energy in, 135 economic growth of, 160, 162, 165, 369 economy of, 32–33 GDP of, 121 high-speed rail network of, 171 intervention in foreign exchange markets, 417 island building by, 41 public debt of, 256, 257 saving rate in, 199 Spring Festival in, 394 U.S. debt held by, 258 value of currency of, 415
Choices, with limited resources, 8–9 Chrysler, 355 Circular flow diagram, 115–116, 115f Classical theory, 106, 186, 330t quantity theory of money and, 326–327, 327f
Clinton, Bill, tax increase under, 241 Closed economies, 380 Collateralized debt obligations (CDOs), 352–354
706
Collected Works (Samuelson), 91 Commodities, related, prices of, supply and, 66 Commodity money, 270 Comparative advantage, 43–45, 44f, 44t, 381–382, 381f, 382t in United States and China, 47
Competition, lack of, market failure and, 92 Competitive markets, government as promoter of, 176 Complementary goods, 62 Compounding of economic growth, 162, 163–165 of interest, 282, 282t Rule of 70 and, 164–165, 164t
Compounding effect, 282, 282t Congestion charges, 92 Constant dollar value, 139 Consumer Expenditure Survey, 137 Consumer price index (CPI), 136–137 Consumer spending, aggregate demand and, 215–216 Consumer surplus, 86–87, 88 Consumption aggregate expenditures model and, 186–190, 187f, 188t average propensity to consume and, 188, 188t crowding out of, 258–259 determinants of, 190 marginal propensity to consume and, 188–190, 189f, 224
Contract(s), government enforcement of, economic growth and, 175 Contractionary fiscal policy, 244–245, 244f Contractionary monetary policy, 324, 325f Corn Laws (1815), 43 Corporate profits, in GDP, 120 Correlation, causation vs., 28 Cost(s), 2 of information. reduction by financial institutions, 278 operating, investment demand and, 192 opportunity. See Opportunity costs of resources, supply and, 66 transaction, reduction by financial institutions, 278
Costa Rica acceptance of U.S. dollar as legal tender in, 420 foreign trade zones in, 389 GDP and happiness in, 123
Cost-push inflation, 226, 227f, 228, 229f Counterfeit money inflation and, 141 preventing, 272
CPI. See Consumer price index (CPI) CPI-U, 136, 137 CPI-W, 136, 137 CPS. See Current Population Survey (CPS) Creativity, wealth of nations, 14 Credit default swaps, 354 Crowding-out effect, 258–259 Cuba, acceptance of U.S. dollar as legal tender in, 420 Currencies appreciation and depreciation of, 411–412, 412f, 414 Canadian, use by Hyder, Alaska, 420
707
of China, value of, 415 foreign, holdings of, leakages and, 303 pegging of, to U.S. dollar, 417, 418 U.S. See U.S. dollar
Current account, 406–407 exchange rates and, 413
Current dollar value, 139 Current Employment Statistics (CES) Survey, 145 Current Population Survey (CPS), 145 Curves. See also Aggregate demand (AD) curve; Aggregate supply curve; Demand curves; Graphs; Supply curve shifts in, 27–28, 28f
Cyclically balanced budget, 253–254 Cyclical unemployment, 150 Cyprus, financial crisis in, 339
D Darby, Abraham, 34 Deadweight loss, 90 Debt cost of financing, 367–368 effect on inflation, 368–369 household, consumption and saving and, 190 monetized, 368–369 public (net; federal), 252–253, 253f
Debt obligations, future, rising, 367 Decision lags fiscal policy and, 250 monetary policy and, 310–311
Deficits, budget, 252 financing of, 255
Deflation, 136, 355 Demand, 57–63 aggregate. See Aggregate demand (AD) curve; Aggregate demand-aggregate supply (AD/AS) model changes in, changes in quantity demanded vs., 62–63, 63f determinants of, 60–62 for investment, 191–192 law of, 58–59 for loanable funds, 274–275, 274f for products, shifts in demand for loanable funds and, 276 willingness-to-pay and, 57–58, 58f
Demand curves, 59–60, 60f Demand-pull inflation, 226–227, 226f, 227f Demand schedule, 59 Demand shocks, monetary policy and, 330–331, 331f Department of Commerce (DOC), 114, 123 Depreciation, of currencies, 411–412, 412f, 414 Determinants of demand, 60–62 Determinants of supply, 65–67 Dickinson, North Dakota, employment in, 148 Diminishing returns to capital, 171 Discount rate, 309 Discouraged workers, 147 Discretionary fiscal policy, 240–243 Discretionary spending, 240
708
Disinflation, 136 Distribution, 32 DOC. See Department of Commerce (DOC) Dollar Canadian, use by Hyder, Alaska, 420 U.S. See U.S. dollar
Dollarization, 303, 320, 340, 341, 418, 420 Double coincidence of wants, 270 Double-dip recessions, 110 Dubai, diversification of economy of, 212 Dumping, as argument against free trade, 391
E Easy money, 332 eBay, 56, 86 ECB. See European Central Bank (ECB) Economic downturns. See Great Depression; Great Recession; Recession(s) Economic freedom, government as promoter of, 176–177, 178f Economic goals, failure to coincide, 13 Economic growth, 13, 38–42, 159–180 compounding of, 163–165 expanding resources and, 38, 39–40 extreme poverty and, 165 factors of production and, 167–169 globalization and obstacles to, 369 government’s role in promoting, 174–178 measurement of, 162–163, 163t production function and, 168–174 productivity and, 170–174 short- vs. long-term, 166–167 technological change and, 38, 40, 41f
Economic outlook, shifts in supply of loanable funds and, 275, 275f Economic shocks, monetary policy and, 330–332, 331f Economic slowdowns, global impact of, 106 Economic systems, 32–33 Economics basic questions of, 32–33 definition of, 4 efficiency vs. equity and, 6–7 in everyday life, 15 key principles of, 8–15 model building in, 6 positive vs. normative questions in, 7 reasons to study, 4–5
Economics (Samuelson), 91 Economies capitalist, 32 closed, 380 informal, 124 market, 32 market, laissez-faire, 32, 94 open, 380 planned, 32
Economists, disagreement among, 7 Ecuador, U.S. dollar as currency of, 303, 320, 340, 341, 418, 420 Education. See also Human capital financial aid and, 175
Edwards, Ralph, 10
709
Efficiency allocative. See Allocative efficiency equity vs., 6–7, 93 of markets, 12–13 production, 6, 33–35, 34f
Efficiency wage theory, 363 Electronic Arts, 410 El Salvador, U.S. dollar as currency of, 303, 320, 340, 341, 418, 420 Employed people, 143–144 Employee compensation, in GDP, 119 Employment. See also Unemployment; Wage(s) domestic, free trade and, 392–393 full, 150 saving programs based on, 283–284 statistics on, 142 trends in, 146 unemployment rate related to, 146
Entrepreneurs, 33 Environment discarded plastic bottles and, 54 free trade and, 393
Environmental Kuznets curve, 393 Environmental quality, GDP and, 122–123 Equation of exchange, 326 Equilibrium, 69–75, 70f changes in supply and demand and, 71–74 deviation from, 89–90 macroeconomic. See Macroeconomic equilibrium tax changes and, 201–202, 202t, 203f
Equilibrium price, 69 prices below, 90–91, 91f prices exceeding, 89–90, 90f
Equilibrium quantity, 69 Equity (fairness), efficiency vs., 6–7, 93 Escalator clauses, 139 “An Essay on the Principle of Population as It Affects the Future Improvement of Society” (Malthus), 172 Ethiopia, economic growth of, 162, 369 European Central Bank (ECB), 337, 340 European Union, 342 Eurozone crisis, 338–342 Excess reserves, 298 Exchange rates, 408–416 aggregate supply and demand and, 414, 415f, 416 capital account and, 413–414 current account and, 413 determinants of, 412–413 determination of, 410–413 expected changes in, capital account and, 414 fixed. See Fixed exchange rates flexible (floating). See Flexible exchange rates nominal, 408, 408t purchasing power parity and, 409–410, 410t real, 408–409
Expansionary fiscal policy, 243, 243f, 244f Expansionary monetary policy, 323–324, 324f Expectations about prices, demand and, 62 about prices, supply and, 66–67
710
adaptive, 361–362 business, shifts in demand for loanable funds and, 276 consumption and saving and, 190 demand and, 62 inflationary. See Inflationary expectations investment demand and, 192 rational, 361–363, 362f supply and, 66–67
Expenditures approach to GDP, 117–119 Exports, 380. See also International trade current account and, 406 measuring, 384 net. See Net exports prices of, aggregate demand and, 215
Express lanes, 92 External benefits and costs, market failure and, 93 Externally held debt, 258, 258t
F Facebook, 9 Factors of production. See also Resources economic growth and, 167–168
Farm prices, inflation and, 135 FDIC. See Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) Federal debt. See Public debt Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), 279, 355 Federal funds rate, 308 Federal funds rate target, 309, 310f, 311 Taylor rule and, 333–334, 334f
Federal government. See Government Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), 307, 320 Federal Reserve Banks, 306–307, 306t Federal Reserve System, 305–312 discount rate and, 309 federal funds rate and. See Federal funds rate; Federal funds rate target as lender of last resort, 307 monetary policy lags and, 310–311 open market operations and, 309 record of performance of, 336 reserve requirements and, 308 structure of, 305–307, 306f transparency and, 335–336
Ferguson, Niall, 270 Fiat money, 270 FIFA World Cup, 248 Financial assets, types of, 278–279 Financial crisis of 2007–2009, 13. See also Great Recession Financial intermediaries (institutions), 278 Financial system, 277–281. See also Bank(s); Borrowing; Investment; Money; Saving bond prices and interest rates and, 279–280 as bridge between savers and borrowers, 277–278 roles of financial institutions in, 278 stability of, economic growth and, 176 stocks and investment returns and, 280–281 types of financial assets and, 278–279
Firms. See also Business(es) market power of, short-run aggregate supply and, 222
711
Fiscal policy aggregate demand and, 240–245 aggregate supply and, 245–249, 246f automatic stabilizers and, 249–250 contractionary, 244–245, 244f discretionary, 240–243, 241f expansionary, 243, 243f, 244f under fixed exchange rates, 418–419, 418f under flexible exchange rates, 419, 420t, 421 following Great Recession, 238 government’s bias toward borrowing and away from taxation and, 250–251 implementation of, 249–251 infrastructure spending and, 246 investment expansion and, 247–248 mandatory spending and, 240, 241f in open economies, 416–421 regulation reduction and, 248 supply-side, 245 tax rate reduction and, 246–247, 247f timing lags and, 250
Fiscal sustainability, 259 Fisher, Irving, 326 Fixed exchange rates, 416–417 monetary and fiscal policy under, 418–419, 418f
Flexible exchange rates, 411, 416, 417–418 monetary and fiscal policy under, 419, 420t, 421 pegging exchange rates under, 417–418
Floating exchange rates. See Flexible exchange rates FOMC. See Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) Ford, 355 Ford, Henry, 172 Foreign currency, holdings of, leakages and, 303 Foreign exchange markets, 410–411, 411f. See also Exchange rates Chinese intervention in, 417
Foreign trade zones, 389 Foundations of Economic Analysis (Samuelson), 91 Fractional reserve banking system, 298–300 France in Eurozone, 340 public debt of, 256 saving rate in, 199
Franzia, Fred, 73 Freedom, economic, government as promoter of, 176–177, 178f Free trade, 390–394 government as promoter of, 176 recent globalization concerns regarding, 392–394 traditional economic arguments against, 390–392
Frictional unemployment, 149–150 Friedman, Milton, 328, 361 Fisher’s influence on, 326 monetarist model and, 328–329, 329f, 330t rules vs. discretion and, 333
Frisbees, market for, 87–88, 88f Full aggregate expenditures model, 201–205 government spending and taxes in, 201–203, 201f net exports in, 203, 204f recessionary and inflationary gaps and, 204
Full employment, 150
712
Functional finance, 255
G Gabon, economic growth of, 369 Gains from trade, 45–46, 45t, 46t, 380–384 absolute and comparative advantage and, 381–382, 381f, 382t consumer and producer surplus and, 89–93 practical constraints on trade and, 382–384
Game theory, Nash equilibrium and, 67 Gaming apps market, 59–60, 60f, 64, 69–70, 70f GDP. See Gross domestic product (GDP) GDP deflator, 138, 138f General Motors, 355 The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (Keynes), 184, 195, 228 Germany in Eurozone, 338–339, 340 hyperinflation in, 140–141 role in European growth and stability, 370 saving rate in, 199
G.I. Bill, 175 Global economy. See also International trade measuring imports and exports in, 384
Globalization, economic growth and, 369 GNP. See Gross national product (GNP) Godwin, William, 172 Gold standard, 417 Goods. See also Product(s) complementary, 62 inferior, 61 net exports of, in GDP, 118 normal, 61 public. See Public goods related, prices of, demand and, 61–62 substitute, 62
Gordon, Robert, 177 Government financing of, 251–256 as promoter of free and competitive markets, 176–178 role in promoting economic growth, 174–178
Government budget constraints, 255 Government spending, 118, 118f aggregate demand and, 217 in aggregate expenditures model, 201, 201f discretionary, 240 discretionary fiscal policy and, 241, 242f mandatory, 240 stimulus, following Great Recession, 228, 238, 246, 250, 355
GPDI. See Gross private domestic investment (GPDI) Graphs, 20–23 bar charts, 22, 22f ceteris paribus assumptions and, 26–27 information conveyed by, 22–23, 23f linear relationships and, 24, 25f models and, 23–24, 23f nonlinear relationships and, 25–26, 25f pie charts, 21 reading, 23 scatter plots, 20, 21f
713
shifts in curves and, 27–28, 28f of simple linear equations, 27, 27f time series, 20, 21f
Great Depression consumption decline and, 187 government role in economic stabilization and, 350 Keynes on, 195, 205 macroeconomic equilibrium and, 225, 225f spread of, 417 unemployment during, 142–143, 143f view of government’s role and, 228
Great Recession, 350, 352–356 cause of, 106 consequences of, 106 consumption decline and, 187 effects of, 355 Federal Reserve System and, 337–338 housing bubble and, 352–354 macroeconomic policy response to, 354–355 stimulus spending and. See Stimulus package unemployment during, 143
Greece in Eurozone, 338, 340 financial crisis in, 339 public debt of, 256–257
Greenspan, Alan, 335, 361 Gross domestic product (GDP), 115–125 circular flow diagram and, 115–116 comparing across countries, 122 environmental quality and, 122–123 expenditures (spending) approach to, 117–119 happiness and, 123 income approach to, 119–121, 120t nonmarket activities and informal economy and, 124 per capita, population and, 122 real. See Real GDP
Gross national product (GNP), 116 Gross private domestic investment (GPDI), 117–118, 117t, 190
H Half.com, 56 Happiness, GDP and, 123 Honda, 384 Honduras, GDP per capita of, 163 Horizontal summation, 60 Household debt, consumption and saving and, 190 Housing bubble, 352–354 Housing market, in United States, 350, 352–354 Human capital increasing, economic growth and, 40 investment in, economic growth and, 170–171 public education and financial aid and, 175
Hyperinflation, 140–141 money as store of value and, 271
I Implementation lags
714
fiscal policy and, 250 monetary policy and, 311
Imports, 380. See also International trade current account and, 406 measuring, 384
Incentives, 5, 10–11 Income. See also Poverty; Wage(s) current account and, 407 demand and, 61, 61f domestic, changes in, current account and, 413 expectations about, demand and, 62 national, 121. See also Gross domestic product (GDP); National income and product accounts (NIPA) of proprietors, in GDP, 120 rental, in GDP, 120 shifts in supply of loanable funds and, 276
Income approach to GDP, 119–121, 120t Income effect, aggregate demand curve and, 214 Index of Economic Freedom, 176 India demand for energy in, 135 economic growth of, 160, 162, 165, 369 GDP of, 121 public debt of, 256, 257 purchasing power parity and, 409 saving rate in, 199
Individual retirement arrangements (IRAs), 285–286 Industrial Revolution, beginnings of, 34 Industries automobile, 389 bottled water, 54 telecommunications, 30 textile, 386
Industry bailouts, 355 Infant industry argument against free trade, 391 Inferior goods, 61 Inflation, 132, 134–142, 135t adjusting for, 138–139 causes of, 135 changes in rates of, current account and, 413 consequences of, 139–140 cost-push, 226, 227f, 228, 229f counterfeit money and, 141 debt’s effect on, 368–369 demand-pull, 226–227, 226f, 227f extremely high, 140–141 future debt obligations and, 367 low, goal of, 13 measurement of, 135–138 money as store of value and, 271 Phillips curves and. See Phillips curves
Inflation overstating, 139 Inflation targeting, 333 Inflationary expectations Phillips curves and, 358–359, 360f short-run aggregate supply and, 222
Inflationary gaps, 204 Inflationary spirals, 243–244 Informal economy, 124 Information, asymmetric, market failure and, 92–93 Information costs, reduction by financial institutions, 278
715
Information lag fiscal policy and, 250 monetary policy and, 310
Infrastructure government as contributor to, 174 spending on, fiscal policy and, 246
Injections, 195, 196–197, 196f, 197f Input prices, short-run aggregate supply and, 221 Institutions, wealth of nations and, 14 Integrated Environmental and Economic Satellite Accounts, 123 Interest, 33 compounding of, 164, 282, 282t net, in GDP, 120
Interest rates aggregate demand and, 215 bond prices and, 279–280 changes in, capital account and, 413–414 consumption and saving and, 187 discount rate, 309 federal funds rate. See Federal funds rate; Federal funds rate target on public debt, 252–253, 254 reasons for importance of, 323
Internally held debt, 258, 258t International Monetary Fund, 417 International trade, 377–398 foreign trade zones and, 389 free trade and. See Free trade gains from trade and. See Gains from trade practical constraints on, 382–384 terms of trade and. See Terms of trade of United States, 378, 380f
Internet, markets and, 56 Investment(s) aggregate demand and, 216–217 aggregate expenditures model and, 190–193, 191f autonomous, 192 crowding out of, 258–259 demand for, 191–192 expanding, 247–248 return on, stocks and, 280–281
Investment in human capital, economic growth and, 170–171 Investment tax credits, shifts in demand for loanable funds and, 276 Invisible hand, 12, 84, 89 IRAs. See Individual retirement arrangements (IRAs) Ireland, financial crisis in, 339 Iron, production of, 34 Italy financial crisis in, 340 public debt of, 256–257
Ivory Coast, economic growth of, 162
J Japan economic growth of, 369 island building by, 41 productivity in, 170 public debt of, 256, 257
716
quotas on automobiles produced in, 389 saving rate in, 199 U.S. debt held by, 258
Jobless recoveries, 110, 152–153, 365–367, 365f, 366f Jobs. See Employment Jobs, Steve, 172
K Kazakhstan, economic growth of, 173 Kennedy, John F., 91 tax cut under, 240–241, 246
Keynes, John Maynard, 71n, 106, 108, 187n on aggregate spending, 184 classical perspective challenged by, 186 development of model by, 212 on expectations, 361 Fisher’s influence on, 326 The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money of, 184, 195, 228 on Great Depression, 195, 205 Keynesian model and, 106, 186, 328, 330t
Keynesian macroeconomic equilibrium, in simple aggregate expenditures model, 194–196 Keynesian model, 106, 186, 328, 330t. See also Aggregate expenditures; Full aggregate expenditures model; Simple aggregate expenditures model Kia Motors, 190, 191 Kokkelenberg, Edward, 114n, 123n, 124n Kuznets, Simon, 114, 115 Kuznets curve, environmental, 393
L Labor, 33. See also Employment; Unemployment; Wage(s) increasing, economic growth and, 40 ratio of capital to, economic growth and, 171
Labor force, 145 growth of, economic growth and, 170–171 increasing quality of, economic growth and, 170–171
Laffer curve, 247, 247f Laissez-faire market economies, 32, 94 Land, 33 economic growth and, 170 reclamation of, 41
Law of demand, 58–59 Law of supply, 64 Leading Economic Index (LEI), 111–112 Leakages by banks, 301–302 foreign currency holdings and, 303 by individuals and businesses, 302
Legislation price gouging, 97 restricting trade, 387 stimulus package and, 355 on veterans, 367
Lehman Brothers, 354 LEI. See Leading Economic Index (LEI)
717
Leveraging, 353 Levi’s, 384 LG, 386 Lincoln, Abraham, 257 Linear equations, simple, 27, 27f Linear relationships, 24, 25f Liquidity, 271 Liquidity trap, 328 Living standard, GDP and, 121–125 Loanable funds market, 274–277 shifts in demand and, 276 shifts in supply and, 275–276 supply and demand in, 274–275, 274f
London, England, traffic congestion in, 92 Long-run aggregate supply (LRAS) curve, 219–220, 219f, 325 determinants of, 220
Long-run macroeconomic equilibrium, 223, 223f Long-run Phillips curve, 359 Los Alamos National Laboratory, 175 Losses, deadweight, 90 LRAS. See Long-run aggregate supply (LRAS) curve Lucas, Robert E., 361, 362 Luxembourg, in Eurozone, 340
M Maastricht Treaty, 338 Macroeconomic equilibrium, 223–229, 223f cost-push inflation and, 227–229, 227f, 229f demand-pull inflation and, 226–227, 226f, 227f Great Depression and, 225, 225f long-run, 223, 223f short-run, 223, 223f in simple aggregate expenditures model, 194–196 spending multiplier and, 224–225, 224f
Macroeconomic policy, 349–372. See also Fiscal policy; Monetary policy future issues faced by, 364–370 globalization and obstacles to economic growth and, 369 Great Recession and, 352–356 jobless recoveries and, 365–367, 365f, 366f Phillips curves and rational expectations and, 356–364, 357f rising debt and future debt obligation and, 367–369
Macroeconomics, 5 Macroeconomy, markets and institutions in, 108, 108f Madawaska, Maine, paper mill in, 184 Malthus, Thomas, 43, 172 Mandatory spending, 240 “Manhattan Project,” 175 Marginal analysis, 11 Marginally attached workers, 147 Marginal propensity to consume (MPC), 188–190, 189f macroeconomic equilibrium and, 224
Marginal propensity to save (MPS), 188–190, 189f macroeconomic equilibrium and, 224
Market(s), 56–57
718
competitive, government as promoter of, 176 efficiency of, 12–13 for foreign exchange. See Foreign exchange markets for Frisbees, 87–88, 88f for gaming apps, 59–60, 60f, 64, 69–70, 70f laissez-faire, 32, 94 for loanable funds. See Loanable funds market for pet products, 56 price system and, 57 for sushi, 84
Market-clearing price. See Equilibrium price Market economies, 32 Market equilibrium. See Equilibrium Market failure, 92–93 Market power, of firms, short-run aggregate supply and, 222 Market supply curve, 65, 65f Marshall, Alfred, 71 Marshall, Howard, 13n, 43, 172n Martin, William McChesney, 333–334, 334f Marx, Karl, 195 Medicaid, mandatory spending for, 240 Medicare mandatory spending for, 240 national debt and, 259 rising future debt obligations and, 367
Medium of exchange, money as, 270–271 Mexico currency of, 418 GDP per capita of, 163 NAFTA and, 46, 384, 393
Microeconomics, 5 Microloans, 294, 295 Mill, John Stuart, 43 Misallocation of resources, 95 Mitchell, Wesley, 109 Model(s) aggregate expenditures. See Full aggregate expenditures model; Simple aggregate expenditures model classical. See Classical theory graphs and, 23–24, 23f Keynesian, 106, 186, 328, 330t monetarist, 328–329, 329f, 330, 330t
Model building, 6 Monetarist model, 328–329, 329f, 330t A Monetary History of the United States (Friedman), 328 Monetary policy, 319–344 accommodative, 332 contractionary, 324, 325f economic shocks and, 330–332 effectiveness of, 329–330, 330t Eurozone crisis and European Central Bank and, 338–342 examples of, 322–323 expansionary, 323–324, 324f federal funds target and Taylor rule and, 333–334, 334f under fixed exchange rates, 418–419, 418f under flexible exchange rates, 419, 420t, 421 Great Recession and, 323, 337–338 long-run effects of, 325–327, 327f in open economies, 416–421 policy tools of, 335 with regional differences in economic performance, 340 restrictive, 332 rules vs. discretion and, 333
719
short-run effects of, 325, 327–329, 332 timing lags and, 310–311 transparency and Federal Reserve System and, 335–336 twin goals of, 322
Monetary rule, 333 Monetized debt, 368–369 Money, 270–273 commodity, 270 counterfeit, 141, 272 creation by banks, 296–300 easy, 332 fiat, 270 functions of, 270–271 leakages and, 301–303 plastic, in Australia, 272 quantity theory of, 326–327, 327f supply of. See Money supply tight, 332
Money illusion, 327–328 Money multiplier, 301 Money supply, 271–273 M1, 272, 273 M2, 272, 273
Monopoly, market power and. See Market power Monopoly power. See Market power Mortgages, subprime, 352–354 MPC. See Marginal propensity to consume (MPC) MPS. See Marginal propensity to save (MPS) Multinational companies, foreign trade zones and, 389 Multiplier balanced budget, 202–203 injections and withdrawals and, 196–197, 196f, 197f money, 301 spending, macroeconomic equilibrium and, 224–225, 224f
Myanmar economic growth of, 162 increase in aggregate demand and, 218
N NAFTA. See North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) NAIRU. See Nonaccelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU) NASA. See National Aeronautics and Space Administration (NASA) National Activity Index, 111, 111f National Aeronautics and Space Administration (NASA), 175 National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), dating of business cycles by, 110–111, 113 National debt, 252 National defense argument, against free trade, 392 National income, 121. See also Gross domestic product (GDP); National income and product accounts (NIPA) National income and product accounts (NIPA), 114–121, 124–125 circular flow diagram and, 115–116, 115f GDP and. See Gross domestic product (GDP)
National Institutes of Health, 175, 247–248 National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA), 175 National Science Foundation (NSF), 175 Natural rate of unemployment, 150–151 Natural resources, 33 economic growth and, 170
720
The Nature of Capital and Income (Fisher), 326 NBER. See National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Net debt. See Public debt Net exports aggregate demand and, 217 in aggregate expenditures model, 203, 204f in GDP, 118
Net interest, in GDP, 120 New York City, rent controls in, 94 New York Stock Exchange, 56 Nicaragua, GDP per capita of, 163 NIPA. See National income and product accounts (NIPA) NOAA. See National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA) Nominal exchange rate, 408, 408t Nominal values, real values vs., 139 Nonaccelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU), 151–152, 151f Nonlinear relationships, 25–26, 25f Nordhaus, William, 114n, 123n, 124n Normal goods, 61 Normative questions, 7 North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), 46, 384, 393 Norway, purchasing power parity and, 409 NSF. See National Science Foundation (NSF) Numbered bank accounts, 303
O Obama, Barack, 204 stimulus package under, 205, 228, 238, 246, 250, 355
Ocean thermal energy conversion, 41 Oil prices employment and, 148 inflation and, 135 OPEC’s power to raise, 222
Olympic Games, 268 OPEC. See Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) Open economies, 380 monetary and fiscal policy in, 416–421
Open market operations, 309 Operating costs, investment demand and, 192 Opportunity costs, 9 comparative advantage and, 43–45, 44t, 381–382, 381f, 382t production possibilities frontier and, 36–38, 37f, 43–44, 44f, 381, 381f
Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) market power of, 222 pegging of currencies by, 417
P Panama, U.S. dollar as currency of, 320, 340, 341, 418, 420 Paradox of thrift, 198–199, 198f Peak(s), in business cycle, 109 Pegging, of exchange rates, 417–418 Pell Grants, 175
721
Pensions, 284–285 Permanent income hypothesis, 329 Personal consumption expenditures, 117 Pet-related products market, 56 Phillips, A. W., 356 Phillips curves, 356–364, 357f accelerating inflation and, 360 inflationary expectations and, 358–359, 360f long-run, 359 productivity, prices, and wages, 357–358, 358f, 359f rational expectations and, 361–363, 362f returning inflation to normal levels and, 361
Physical capital, government as contributor to, 174 Pie charts, 21 Piger, Jeremy, 110n Planned economies, 32 Plaza Hotel, 407 Point-of-Purchase Survey, 137 Political Justice (Godwin), 172 Poole, William, 335 Portugal in Eurozone, 340 financial crisis in, 339
Positive questions, 7 Poverty, extreme, economic growth and, 165 PPF. See Production possibilities frontier (PPF) PPI. See Producer price index (PPI) PPP. See Purchasing power parity (PPP) Preference(s), demand and, 61 Pressman, Steven, 43 Price(s) of assets, shifts in supply of loanable funds and, 276 below equilibrium, 90–91, 91f of bonds, interest rates and, 279–280 consumer. See Consumer price index (CPI) equilibrium (market-clearing), 69 exceeding equilibrium, 89–90, 90f expectations about, demand and, 62 expectations about, supply and, 66–67 of exports, aggregate demand and, 215 of inputs. See Input prices of oil. See Oil prices Phillips curves and, 357–358, 358f, 359f of related commodities, supply and, 66 of related goods, demand and, 61–62 sticky, 328
Price ceilings, 94–96, 94f Price floors, 96–98, 96f Price gouging laws, 97 Price level, 136 Price system, 57 Principles of Economics (Marshall), 71 Producer price index (PPI), 136, 137–138 Producer surplus, 86, 88 Product(s). See also Goods expectations about availability of, demand and, 62
Production efficiency and, 6, 33–35, 34f resources and, 33
722
Production efficiency, 6, 33–35, 34f Production function, economic growth and, 168–169 Production possibilities frontier (PPF), 35–38, 36f absolute and comparative advantage and, 43, 44f opportunity costs and, 36–38, 37f, 43–44, 44f, 381, 381f
Production technology, supply and, 65–66, 66f Productivity economic growth and, 170–174 Phillips curves and, 357–358, 358f, 359f short-run aggregate supply and, 221–222, 221f total factor, 172–173
Profit(s), 33 corporate, in GDP, 120
Property rights, economic growth and, 175–176 Proprietors’ income, in GDP, 120 Public choice theory, 251 Public confidence, policy response to financial crisis and, 354–355 Public debt, 252–253, 253f, 256–260, 256f crowding out of consumption and investment by, 258–259 financing of, 255 future problems due to, 259 interest rates on, 252–253, 254 portion held by foreigners, 257–258, 258t size of, 257
Public goods, market failure and, 93 Public policy. See Legislation; Regulation Puerto Rico, U.S. dollar as currency of, 340 The Purchasing Power of Money (Fisher), 326 Purchasing power parity (PPP), 409–410, 409t GDP adjusted by, 122
Q Qatar, FIFA World Cup in, 248 QE. See Quantitative easing (QE) Quantitative easing (QE), 311, 332 Quantity, equilibrium, 69 Quantity demanded, changes in, changes in demand and, 62–63, 63f Quantity theory of money, 326–327, 327f Quotas, import, 388–390, 388f
R Rational expectations, 361–363, 362f RCA, 386 Reagan, Ronald, 328 tax cut under, 240–241
Real exchange rate, 408–409 Real GDP, 122, 162–163, 163t per capita, 162
Real values, nominal values vs., 139 Recession(s), 109 double-dip, 110 jobless recoveries from, 110, 152–153, 365–367, 365f, 366f length of, saving rate and, 199
723
of 2007-2009. See Great Recession unemployment during, 110
Recessionary gaps, 204 Recognition lags fiscal policy and, 250 monetary policy and, 310
Reddy, Sundeep, 195 Regulation(s) of inputs, short-run aggregate supply and, 222 reducing, 248 shifts in demand for loanable funds and, 276
Rent, 33 Rental income, in GDP, 120 Rent controls, 94 Reserve(s) excess, 298 money multiplier and, 301 requirements for, 298–299, 308 reserve ratio and, 298
Reserve ratios, 298 Reserve requirements, 298–299, 308 Resources costs of, supply and, 66 expanding, economic growth and, 39–40 limited, 8–9 misallocation of, 95 natural. See Natural resources production and, 33 scarcity of, 14
Restrictive monetary policy, 332 Return on investment (ROI), 278 tradeoff between risk and, 280
Ricardo, David, 43 The Rise and Fall of American Growth (Gordon), 177 Risk assessment of, asset allocation and, 283 assessment of, choosing assets to invest in and, 284 tradeoff between return and, 280
ROI. See Return on investment (ROI) Roosevelt, Franklin D., 195, 205 Ross, Ian, 13n Roth IRAs, 286 Rule of 70, 164–165, 164t Russia economic growth of, 160, 162 public debt of, 256, 257
S Samsung, 386 Samuelson, Paul A., 91 Sandia National Laboratories, 175 Saving aggregate expenditures model and, 186–190, 187f, 188t average propensity to save and, 188, 188t determinants of, 190
724
employer-based programs for, 283–284 financial system and, 277–278 incentives for, shifts in supply of loanable funds and, 275 long-term, stock market crashes and, 285 marginal propensity to save and, 188–190, 189f, 224 rates of, length of recessions and, 199
Scarcity, 4 Scatter plots, 20, 21f Schools, financial aid and, 175 Sellers, number of, supply and, 67 Services, net exports of, in GDP, 118 Shaw, George Bernard, 195 Shortages, 70 Short-run aggregate supply (SRAS) curve, 220–222, 220f, 325 determinants of, 220–222
Short-run macroeconomic equilibrium, 223, 223f Short-term borrowing, 281–282 Simple aggregate expenditures model, 193–200, 194f macroeconomic equilibrium in, 194–196 multiplier and, 196–199, 196f–198f
Singapore island building by, 41 traffic jams in, 92
Skidelsky, Robert, 71n Slope of linear line, computing, 24, 25f of nonlinear curve, computing, 26, 26f
Slovenia, financial crisis in, 340 Smartphones, economic growth and, 38 Smith, Adam, 12, 13, 71, 84, 89, 195, 251 The Wealth of Nations of, 43
Smoot-Hawley Act of 1930, 387 SNAP (Supplementary Nutrition Assistance Program), mandatory spending for, 240 Socialism, 33 Social Security benefits under, 284 mandatory spending for, 240 national debt and, 259, 367
Solvency crises, 302 South Korea, saving rate in, 199 Soviet Union, former, economy of, 32–33 S&P. See Standard & Poor’s (S&P) Spaceport America, 10 Spain, financial crisis in, 339 Specialization, 10 Specific tariffs, 387 Spencer, Roger, 91n Spending. See Aggregate expenditures; Consumer spending; Government spending; Stimulus package Spending approach to GDP, 117–119 Spending multiplier, macroeconomic equilibrium and, 224–225, 224f SRAS. See Short-run aggregate supply (SRAS) curve Stagflation, 360 Standard of living, GDP and, 121–125 Standard & Poor’s (S&P), 238 Sticky wages and prices, 328
725
Stimulus package, 204, 238, 250, 355 failure to lead to inflation, 228 tax credits in, 246
Stock(s), investment returns and, 280–281 Stock market crashes, long-term savings and, 285 Store of value, money as, 271 Strathern, Paul, 13n, 172n Structural unemployment, 150 Subprime mortgages, 352–354 Subsidies, supply and, 67 Substitute goods, 62 Substitution effect, aggregate demand curve and, 214 Supply, 64–69 aggregate. See Aggregate demand-supply (AD/AS) model; Aggregate supply curve changes in, changes in quantity supplied vs., 67, 67f, 68f determinants of, 65–67 law of, 64 of loanable funds, 274–275, 274f of money. See Money supply
Supply curve, 64–65 market, 65, 65f
Supply shocks, monetary policy and, 331 Supply-side fiscal policy, 245 Surpluses, 69–70 budget, 252 consumer, 86–87, 88 producer, 86, 88 total, 89
Sushi, market for, 84 Sweden, saving rate in, 199 Swiss bank accounts, 303 Switzerland purchasing power parity and, 409 saving rate in, 199
Sycamore, Illinois, parking meters in, 135
T TAA. See Trade Adjustment Assistance (TAA) program TANF (Temporary Assistance to Needy Families), mandatory spending for, 240 Tariffs, 387–388, 387f, 388f TARP (Troubled Asset Relief Program), 354 Tastes. See Preference(s) Taxation, government’s bias away from, 250–251 Taxes ad valorem, 387 in aggregate expenditures model, 201–203, 201f changes in, equilibrium and, 201–202, 202t, 203f consumption and saving and, 190 cuts in, 240–241 discretionary fiscal policy and, 241–242 of inputs, short-run aggregate supply and, 222 supply and, 67
Tax rates, reducing, fiscal policy and, 246–247, 247f Taylor rule, federal funds targeting and, 333–334, 334f T-bills, 252 Technological change
726
economic growth and, 38, 40, 41f, 172 investment demand and, 192 shifts in demand for loanable funds and, 276
Technology(ies) government R&D and grants for, 175 production, supply and, 65–66, 66f
Telecommunications industry, 30 Temin, Peter, 417 Temporary Assistance to Needy Families (TANF), mandatory spending for, 240 Term auction facilities, 311 Terms of trade, 385–390 determining, 385–386, 385f impact of trade and, 386 tariffs and quotas and, 387–389, 387f, 388f
Textile industry, 386 Thailand, purchasing power parity and, 409 Thatcher, Margaret, 328 Tight money, 332 Time series graphs, 20, 21f Timing lags fiscal policy and, 250 monetary policy and, 310–311
Timor-Leste, U.S. dollar as currency of, 418, 420 Tokyo Disneyland, 75 Total factor productivity, 172–173 Total surplus, 89 Toyota, 384, 389 Trade. See also Exports; Imports; International trade; Net exports; Terms of trade free. See Free trade gains from, 45–46, 45t, 46t practical constraints on, 46
Trade Adjustment Assistance (TAA) program, 392 Tradeoffs, 2 between risk and return, 280
Trade restriction, 387–389, 387f, 388f Trader Joe’s, 73 Traffic congestion, congestion charges and, 92 Transaction costs, reduction by financial institutions, 278 Transfer payments current account and, 407 discretionary fiscal policy and, 242–243
Transparency, Federal Reserve System and, 335–336 Traveler’s checks, 272n Treasury bills, 252 Treasury notes, 252 Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP), 354 Truman, Harry S., 7 Truth or Consequences, New Mexico, 10 Tsukiji fish market, 84 Turkey, public debt of, 256 Turkmenistan, economic growth of, 162 Two-Buck Chuck, 73
U 727
Uber, 147 Underemployed workers, 147 Underwater cities, 41 Unemployed people, 144–145 Unemployment, 132, 142–153 cyclical, 150 definition and measurement of, 143–145 employment trends and, 146 frictional, 149–150 historical record of, 142–143, 143f, 144t jobless recoveries and, 110, 152–153, 365–367, 365f, 366f low, goal of, 13 monthly employment surveys and, 145 Phillips curves and. See Phillips curves problems with statistics and, 146–148 structural, 150
Unemployment Insurance Weekly Claims Report, 146 Unemployment rate, 132, 134 changes in, 151–152, 151f differences in, 153 employment related to, 146 natural, 150–152, 151f
United Arab Emirates, island building by, 41 United Kingdom public debt of, 256 saving rate in, 199
United States automobile industry of, 355 balance of payments of, 406–407, 406t capital-to-labor ratio in, 171 comparative advantage of, 47 currency of. See U.S. dollar debt rating of, 238 economic growth of, 162, 369 exports and imports of, 378, 380f express lanes in, 92 housing market in, 350, 352–354 hyperinflation during Revolutionary War and, 140 inflation in, 132, 134, 226, 227f, 228, 229f NAFTA and, 46, 384, 393 public debt of, 256 public education in, 175 quotas on Japanese automobile imports of, 389 saving rate in, 199 tariffs of, 387, 387f textile industry in, 386 unemployment in, 132, 134, 153
U.S. dollar as currency of other countries, 303, 320, 340, 341, 418, 420 dollar coins and, 271 pegging of OPEC nations’ currencies to, 417
Unit of account, money as, 271 Universal Studios, 71 Universities, financial aid and, 175 Unpaid family workers, 144
V Vesting period, 283 Vietnam, economic growth of, 369 Virgin Galactic, 10 Volcker, Paul, 361
728
VOW to Hire Heroes Act, 367
W Wage(s), 33 efficiency wage theory and, 363 foreign, low, as argument against free trade, 391–392 Phillips curves and, 357–358, 358f, 359f sticky, 328
Walmart, 12 Warsh, David, 91n Wealth consumption and saving and, 190 of nations, explanation for, 14
Wealth effect, aggregate demand and, 215 The Wealth of Nations (Smith), 43 Weekly Jobs Report, 146 West Point, Georgia, Kia Motors in, 190, 191 Willingness-to-pay (WTP), 57–58, 58f consumer and producer surplus and, 87
Willingness-to-sell (WTS), consumer and producer surplus and, 87 Winch, Donald, 172n Withdrawals, 195–197, 196f, 197f Words with Friends, 59 World Bank, 417 World Trade Organization agreements, 393 WTP. See Willingness-to-pay (WTP) WTS. See Willingness-to-sell (WTS)
Y Yield curve, 112, 112f
Z Zenith, 386 Zimbabwe, hyperinflation in, 140 Zuckerberg, Mark, 9
729
Table of Contents Title Copyright About the Author Vision and Story of Economics Principles for a Changing World Rethinking the Connection Between Author, Text, and Technology Thinking About Data Literacy Thinking About What Global Means Acknowledgments Brief Contents Contents 1 Exploring Economics BY THE NUMBERS Economics as a Career What Is Economics About? Why Should One Study Economics? Microeconomics Versus Macroeconomics Economic Theories and Reality Model Building Ceteris Paribus: All Else Held Constant Efficiency Versus Equity ISSUE Do Economists Ever Agree on Anything? Positive Versus Normative Questions Key Principles of Economics Principle 1: Economics Is Concerned With Making Choices With Limited Resources Principle 2: When Making Decisions, One Must Take into Account Tradeoffs and Opportunity Costs Principle 3: Specialization Leads to Gains for All Involved Principle 4: People Respond to Incentives, Both Good and Bad ISSUE Would a City Change Its Name for a Game Show? Principle 5: Rational Behavior Requires Thinking on the Margin 730
3 4 8 10 12 14 22 25 30 34 36 56 60 62 62 63 63 64 64 64 65 66 68 68 68 70 70 71 72
Principle 6: Markets Are Generally Efficient; When They Aren’t, Government Can Sometimes Correct the Failure Principle 7: Economic Growth, Low Unemployment, and Low Inflation Are Economic Goals That Do Not Always Coincide ADAM SMITH (1723–1790) Principle 8: Institutions and Human Creativity Help Explain the Wealth of Nations AROUND THE WORLD Nunavut: Land of Abundance and Scarcity Summing It All Up: Economics Is All Around Us Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS APPENDIX Working With Graphs and Formulas Graphs and Data Time Series Scatter Plots Pie Charts Bar Charts Simple Graphs Can Pack In a Lot of Information A Few Simple Rules for Reading Graphs Graphs and Models Linear Relationships Computing the Slope of a Linear Line Nonlinear Relationships Computing the Slope of a Nonlinear Curve Ceteris Paribus, Simple Equations, and Shifting Curves Ceteris Paribus: All Else Equal Simple Linear Equations Shifting Curves Correlation Is Not Causation
2 Production, Economic Growth, and Trade BY THE NUMBERS Growth, Productivity, and Trade Are Key to Our Prosperity Basic Economic Questions and Production Basic Economic Questions Economic Systems 731
72 73 74 74 75 76 77 81 81 83 84 85 85 85 87 88 88 90 92 93 93 95 96 97 97 97 98 100
101 105 106 106 106
Resources and Production Land Labor Capital Entrepreneurial Ability Production and Efficiency AROUND THE WORLD Ironbridge: The Beginnings of the Industrial Revolution Production Possibilities and Economic Growth Production Possibilities Opportunity Cost Increasing Opportunity Costs Economic Growth Expanding Resources Technological Change Summarizing the Sources of Economic Growth ISSUE Is the Ocean the Next Frontier? Land Reclamation and Underwater Cities Specialization, Comparative Advantage, and Trade Absolute and Comparative Advantage DAVID RICARDO (1772–1823) The Gains from Trade Practical Constraints on Trade ISSUE Do We Really Specialize in That? Comparative Advantage in the United States and China Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
3 Supply and Demand
107 107 107 107 107 108 108 111 111 112 113 114 116 117 119 120 122 122 122 125 126 126 128 132 132 134
135
BY THE NUMBERS The World of Markets Markets ISSUE Do Markets Exist for Everyone, Including Dogs and Cats? The Price System Demand Willingness-to-Pay: The Building Block of Market Demand The Law of Demand: The Relationship Between Quantity Demanded and Price The Demand Curve 732
139 141 141 142 143 143 144 145
Determinants of Demand Tastes and Preferences Income Prices of Related Goods The Number of Buyers Expectations About Future Prices, Incomes, and Product Availability Changes in Demand Versus Changes in Quantity Demanded Supply The Law of Supply: The Relationship Between Quantity Supplied and Price The Supply Curve Market Supply Curves Determinants of Supply Production Technology Costs of Resources Prices of Related Commodities Expectations Number of Sellers Taxes and Subsidies Changes in Supply Versus Changes in Quantity Supplied Market Equilibrium Moving to a New Equilibrium: Changes in Supply and Demand Predicting the New Equilibrium When One Curve Shifts ALFRED MARSHALL (1842–1924) ISSUE Two-Buck Chuck: Will People Drink $2-a-Bottle Wine? Predicting the New Equilibrium When Both Curves Shift AROUND THE WORLD Tokyo Disneyland: Is THAT the Line for Space Mountain?! Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
4 Markets and Government
147 147 148 148 149 149 149 152 152 152 153 153 153 154 155 155 155 155 155 159 161 161 161 165 166 168 170 175 176 179
181
BY THE NUMBERS Price Controls and Supports in the Economy Today Consumer and Producer Surplus: A Tool for Measuring Economic Efficiency Using Consumer and Producer Surplus: The Gains from Trade The Consequences of Deviating from Market Equilibrium 733
185 187 191 191
When Prices Exceed Equilibrium When Prices Fall Below Equilibrium NOBEL PRIZE: PAUL A. SAMUELSON (1915–2009) Market Failure Lack of Competition Information Is Not Shared by All Parties AROUND THE WORLD Singapore: Resolving Traffic Jams and Reducing Pollution Using Price Controls The Existence of External Benefits or Costs The Existence of Public Goods Market Efficiency Versus Equity Price Ceilings and Price Floors Price Ceilings Price Floors ISSUE Are Price Gouging Laws Good for Consumers? Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
5 Introduction to Macroeconomics
191 193 194 194 194 195 195 196 196 196 198 198 200 202 205 209 210 213
215
BY THE NUMBERS A Slow and Steady Macroeconomic Recovery Business Cycles Defining Business Cycles Dating Business Cycles Alternative Measures of the Business Cycle National Activity Index Leading Economic Index Yield Curve ISSUE The End of the Recession . . . It Does Not Feel Like It National Income Accounting The Core of the NIPA NOBEL PRIZE: SIMON KUZNETS (1901–1985) The Circular Flow Diagram Spending and Income: Looking at GDP in Two Ways Gross Domestic Product 734
219 221 221 223 224 224 224 225 226 229 229 229 230 230 232
The Expenditures (Spending) Approach to Calculating GDP Personal Consumption Expenditures Gross Private Domestic Investment Government Purchases Net Exports of Goods and Services Summing Aggregate Expenditures The Income Approach to Calculating GDP Compensation of Employees Proprietors’ Income Corporate Profits Rental Income Net Interest Miscellaneous Adjustments Summing Up Income Measures GDP and Our Standard of Living Different Ways of Comparing GDP Across Countries Population and GDP per Capita Environmental Quality AROUND THE WORLD Costa Rica: Pura Vida and Happiness Without a High Level of GDP Nonmarket Activities and the Informal Economy Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
6 Measuring Inflation and Unemployment BY THE NUMBERS The Twin Evils of Inflation and Unemployment Inflation What Causes Inflation? Measuring Inflation: Consumer Price Index, Producer Price Index, and GDP Deflator The Consumer Price Index The Producer Price Index The GDP Deflator Adjusting for Inflation: Escalating and Deflating Series (Nominal Versus Real Values) 735
233 233 233 235 235 236 236 236 237 237 238 238 238 238 240 240 240 241 241 243 246 250 251 253
255 259 261 262 263 264 265 266 266
Escalator Clauses Deflating Series: Nominal Versus Real Values The Effect of Overstating Inflation The Consequences of Inflation Hyperinflation ISSUE The Consequences of Counterfeit Money on Inflation Unemployment The Historical Record Defining and Measuring Unemployment Employed Unemployed Labor Force Monthly Employment Surveys The Household Survey The Payroll Survey Employment Trends Weekly Jobs Report Relationship Between Employment and the Unemployment Rate Problems with Unemployment Statistics Underemployment and Marginally Attached Workers AROUND THE WORLD The Boom and Bust of Dickinson, North Dakota Unemployment and the Economy Types of Unemployment Frictional Unemployment Structural Unemployment Cyclical Unemployment Defining Full Employment The Natural Rate of Unemployment Changes in the Unemployment Rate Around the Natural Rate Jobless Recoveries Prolong Unemployment Above the Natural Rate ISSUE Why Do Unemployment Rates Differ So Much Within the United States? Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS 736
267 267 267 267 268 269 271 271 273 273 274 274 274 275 275 275 276 276 276 277 278 280 280 280 280 281 282 282 282 283 283 286 290 290 292
7 Economic Growth
293
BY THE NUMBERS Why Should We Care About Economic Growth? Why Is Economic Growth Important? How Is Economic Growth Measured? Small Differences in Growth Lead to Large Differences in Income Over Time Power of Compounding Growth Rates Rule of 70 ISSUE Can Economic Growth Bring a Billion People Out of Poverty? Thinking About Short-Run and Long-Run Economic Growth Short-Run Versus Long-Run Growth Short-Run Growth Involves a Fixed Capacity Long-Run Growth Involves Expanding Capacity Factors of Production Production Function Applying the Production Function: Achieving Economic Growth Achieving More Land or Natural Resources Growth of the Labor Force Increasing the Quality of the Labor Force Increasing the Capital-to-Labor Ratio THOMAS MALTHUS (1766–1834) Improvements in Technology and Ideas Including Everything Else: Total Factor Productivity AROUND THE WORLD Kazakhstan: The Next Destination of Growth and Trade The Role of Government in Promoting Economic Growth Government as a Contributor to Physical Capital, Human Capital, and Technology Physical Capital: Public Capital and Private Investment Human Capital: Public Education and Financial Aid Technology: Government R&D Centers and Federal Grants Government as a Facilitator of Economic Growth Enforcement of Contracts Protection of Property Rights Stable Financial System Government as a Promoter of Free and Competitive Markets Competitive Markets and Free Trade Economic Freedom 737
297 299 299 300 301 302 303 306 306 306 306 307 309 311 311 311 311 312 313 313 314 314 317 317 317 317 318 318 318 319 319 319 319 319
ISSUE Did Economic Growth Peak a Century Ago? Prospects for Future Growth Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
8 Aggregate Expenditures
320 324 328 328 330
331
BY THE NUMBERS The Role of Spending in the Economy Aggregate Expenditures Some Simplifying Assumptions Consumption and Saving Average Propensities to Consume and Save Marginal Propensities to Consume and Save Other Determinants of Consumption and Saving Investment Investment Demand Aggregate Investment Schedule The Simple Aggregate Expenditures Model Macroeconomic Equilibrium in the Simple Model JOHN MAYNARD KEYNES (1883–1946) The Multiplier The Multiplier Works in Both Directions Paradox of Thrift ISSUE Do High Savings Rates Increase the Risk of a Long Recession? AROUND THE WORLD Brazil’s Beco Do Batman: How Graffiti Revived a Neighborhood The Full Aggregate Expenditures Model Adding Government Spending and Taxes Tax Changes and Equilibrium The Balanced Budget Multiplier Adding Net Exports Recessionary and Inflationary Gaps Recessionary Gap Inflationary Gap ISSUE Was Keynes Right About the Great Depression? Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS 738
335 337 337 337 339 340 343 343 344 346 348 349 350 352 353 354 355 357 359 359 359 361 362 363 363 364 364 367 371
QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
9 Aggregate Demand and Supply
372 375
376
BY THE NUMBERS The Sheer Size of Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Aggregate Demand Why Is the Aggregate Demand Curve Negatively Sloped? The Wealth Effect Export Price Effect Interest Rate Effect Determinants of Aggregate Demand Consumer Spending Investment Government Spending and Net Exports AROUND THE WORLD Myanmar: Opening a Country to a Boom in Aggregate Demand Aggregate Supply Long Run Determinants of Long-Run Aggregate Supply Short Run Determinants of Short-Run Aggregate Supply Input Prices Productivity Taxes and Regulation Market Power of Firms Inflationary Expectations Macroeconomic Equilibrium The Spending Multiplier The Great Depression Demand-Pull Inflation Cost-Push Inflation ISSUE Why Didn’t Stimulus Measures Over the Past Decade Lead to Inflation? Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS 739
380 382 382 383 383 383 383 384 385 385 387 390 390 391 391 392 392 393 394 394 395 397 397 399 401 402 404 407 412 412 415
APPENDIX Deriving the Aggregate Demand Curve
10 Fiscal Policy and Debt
416
418
BY THE NUMBERS Your Government and Its Financial Operation Fiscal Policy and Aggregate Demand Discretionary and Mandatory Spending Discretionary Fiscal Policy Government Spending Taxes Transfers Expansionary and Contractionary Fiscal Policy Fiscal Policy and Aggregate Supply Infrastructure Spending Reducing Tax Rates Expanding Investment and Reducing Regulations AROUND THE WORLD Qatar: A Nation Built for the Future Implementing Fiscal Policy Automatic Stabilizers Fiscal Policy Timing Lags The Government’s Bias Toward Borrowing and Away from Taxation Financing the Federal Government Defining Deficits and the National Debt Balanced Budget Amendments ISSUE How Big Is the Economic Burden of Interest Rates on the National Debt? Financing Debt and Deficits Why Is the Public Debt So Important? Is the Size of the Public Debt a Problem? Does It Matter If Foreigners Hold a Significant Portion of the Public Debt? Does Government Debt Crowd Out Consumption and Investment? How Will the National Debt Affect Our Future? Are We Doomed? Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
11 Saving, Investment, and the Financial System BY THE NUMBERS The Financial System and Its Sheer Size and Scope 740
422 424 424 424 426 426 427 428 432 433 433 434 435 438 438 438 439 442 442 444 444 445 448 448 449 450 450 453 457 458 460
461 465
What Is Money? The Functions of Money Medium of Exchange Unit of Account Store of Value Defining the Money Supply AROUND THE WORLD Using Plastic Money (Literally) in Australia Narrowly Defined Money: M1 A Broader Definition: M2 The Market for Loanable Funds Supply and Demand for Loanable Funds Shifts in the Supply of Loanable Funds Economic Outlook Incentives to Save Income or Asset Prices Government Deficits Shifts in the Demand for Loanable Funds Investment Tax Incentives Technological Advances Regulations Product Demand Business Expectations The Financial System The Bridge Between Savers and Borrowers The Roles of Financial Institutions Reducing Information Costs Reducing Transaction Costs Diversifying Assets to Reduce Risk Types of Financial Assets Bond Prices and Interest Rates Stocks and Investment Returns Financial Tools for a Better Future Short-Term Borrowing The Power (or Danger) of Compounding Interest Risk Assessment and Asset Allocation Saving for the Future: Employer-Based Programs 741
467 467 467 468 468 469 469 470 471 472 472 473 474 474 474 475 475 475 475 475 475 475 477 477 478 478 478 478 478 479 480 482 482 483 484 484
To Contribute or Not to Contribute? In What Assets Should One Invest? Other Retirement Savings Tools: Social Security, Pensions, and IRAs Social Security Pension Plans ISSUE Can a Stock Market Crash Increase Long-Term Savings? Individual Retirement Arrangements (IRAs) Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
12 Money Creation and the Federal Reserve BY THE NUMBERS Banks and the Federal Reserve How Banks Create Money Creating Money as If Out of Thin Air Fractional Reserve Banking System The Money Creation Process The Money Multiplier and Its Leakages Bank Reserves and the Money Multiplier Money Leakages Bank Leakages Leakages by Individuals and Businesses The Effect of Foreign Currency Holdings What Is the Actual Money Multiplier in the Economy? AROUND THE WORLD The Rise and Fall of the Famous (and Infamous) Swiss Bank Account The Federal Reserve System The Structure of the Federal Reserve The Board of Governors Federal Reserve Banks Federal Open Market Committee The Fed as Lender of Last Resort The Federal Reserve at Work: Tools, Targets, and Policy Lags Reserve Requirements Discount Rate Open Market Operations 742
484 485 485 485 486 486 488 489 493 494 495
497 501 503 503 504 505 508 508 508 509 509 510 511 511 514 514 514 515 516 516 518 518 519 519
The Federal Funds Target Monetary Policy Lags Information Lags Recognition Lags Decision Lags ISSUE What Can the Fed Do When Interest Rates Reach 0%? Implementation Lags Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
13 Monetary Policy
519 520 520 521 521 521 522 524 528 528 530
532
BY THE NUMBERS Monetary Policy in Action What Is Monetary Policy? The Twin Goals of Monetary Policy Examples of Monetary Policy in Action Why Is the Interest Rate So Important to the Economy? When Is It Optimal to Loosen or Tighten Monetary Policy? Expansionary Monetary Policy Contractionary Monetary Policy Monetary Theories The Short Run Versus the Long Run: What’s the Difference? The Long Run: The Classical Theory IRVING FISHER (1867–1947) Short-Run Effects of Monetary Policy Money Illusion and Sticky Wages and Prices Keynesian Model Monetarist Model NOBEL PRIZE: MILTON FRIEDMAN (1912–2006) Summary of the Effectiveness of Monetary Policy Monetary Policy and Economic Shocks Demand Shocks Supply Shocks Implications for Short-Run Monetary Policy Modern Monetary Policy 743
536 538 538 538 539 539 540 541 543 543 543 544 545 545 546 546 546 547 549 549 550 550 552
Rules Versus Discretion The Federal Funds Target and the Taylor Rule A Recap of the Fed’s Policy Tools Transparency and the Federal Reserve ISSUE The Record of the Fed’s Performance New Monetary Policy Challenges The Fed: Dealing with an Economic Crisis Not Seen in 80 Years The Eurozone Crisis and the Role of the European Central Bank ISSUE The Challenges of Monetary Policy with Regional Differences in Economic Performance AROUND THE WORLD Why Would a Country Give Up Its Monetary Policy? Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
14 Macroeconomic Policy: Challenges in a Global Economy BY THE NUMBERS The Long Road Back: The Great Recession and the Jobless Recovery The Great Recession and Macroeconomic Policy From the Housing Bubble to the Financial Crisis Subprime Mortgages and Collateralized Debt Obligations Collapsing Financial Markets The Government’s Policy Response The Financial Crisis and Its Effects Effectiveness of Macroeconomic Policy: Phillips Curves and Rational Expectations Unemployment and Inflation: Phillips Curves Productivity, Prices, and Wages The Importance of Inflationary Expectations Inflationary Expectations and the Phillips Curve The Long-Run Phillips Curve Accelerating Inflation Returning Inflation to Normal Levels NOBEL PRIZE: ROBERT LUCAS Rational Expectations and Policy Formation Policy Implications of Rational Expectations A Critique of Rational Expectations 744
552 553 554 555 555 558 558 559 561 563 565 569 569 571
573 577 579 579 580 581 582 583 585 585 586 588 589 590 590 591 592 592 593 594
Macroeconomic Issues That Confront Our Future Are Recoveries Becoming “Jobless Recoveries”? Will Rising Debt and Future Debt Obligations Lead to Inflation? Rising Future Debt Obligations: Health Care and Social Security The Cost of Financing Debt The Effects of Debt on Inflation ISSUE Inflating Our Way Out of Debt: Is This an Effective Approach? Will Globalization Lead to Increased Obstacles to Economic Growth? AROUND THE WORLD Life on the Autobahn: Germany’s Role in European Growth and Stability Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
15 International Trade
596 596 600 600 601 601 601 602 604 606 610 610 612
614
BY THE NUMBERS International Trade The Gains from Trade Absolute and Comparative Advantage Gains from Trade Practical Constraints on Trade ISSUE The Challenge of Measuring Imports and Exports in a Global Economy The Terms of Trade Determining the Terms of Trade The Impact of Trade How Trade Is Restricted Effects of Tariffs and Quotas ISSUE Do Foreign Trade Zones Help or Hurt American Consumers and Workers? Arguments Against Free Trade Traditional Economic Arguments Infant Industry Argument Antidumping Low Foreign Wages National Defense Argument Recent Globalization Concerns Trade and Domestic Employment Trade and the Environment 745
618 621 621 623 623 625 627 627 628 629 630 633 635 635 635 635 636 636 637 637 638
Trade and Its Effect on Working Conditions in Developing Nations AROUND THE WORLD Can One Country’s Festival Disrupt World Trade? Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
16 Open Economy Macroeconomics
638 639 641 644 645 647
649
BY THE NUMBERS The Foreign Exchange Market The Balance of Payments The Current Account Imports and Exports Income Transfers The Capital Account Exchange Rates Defining Exchange Rates Nominal Exchange Rates Real Exchange Rates Purchasing Power Parity Exchange Rate Determination A Market for Foreign Exchange Flexible Exchange Rates Currency Appreciation and Depreciation Determinants of Exchange Rates Exchange Rates and the Current Account Changes in Inflation Rates Changes in Domestic Disposable Income Exchange Rates and the Capital Account Interest Rate Changes Expected Exchange Rate Changes Exchange Rates and Aggregate Supply and Demand ISSUE Would a Stronger Chinese Yuan Be Good for Americans? Monetary and Fiscal Policy in an Open Economy Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rate Systems Pegging Exchange Rates Under a Flexible Exchange Rate System 746
653 655 655 655 656 656 657 658 658 658 658 659 661 661 662 663 664 664 664 664 664 665 665 665 667 669 669 669
Policies Under Fixed Exchange Rates NOBEL PRIZE: ROBERT MUNDELL Policies Under Flexible Exchange Rates AROUND THE WORLD Hyder, Alaska: An American Town That Uses the Canadian Dollar Chapter Summary KEY CONCEPTS QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS IN CHECKPOINTS
Sources for By the Numbers Glossary Index
670 672 672 673 676 679 680 681
683 688 703
747