In pursuit of Lakshmi: the political economy of the Indian state [1 ed.] 0226731383, 0226731391


294 67 76MB

English Pages (xvii, 529 pages) [557] Year 1987

Report DMCA / Copyright

DOWNLOAD PDF FILE

Recommend Papers

In pursuit of Lakshmi: the political economy of the Indian state [1 ed.]
 0226731383, 0226731391

  • 0 0 0
  • Like this paper and download? You can publish your own PDF file online for free in a few minutes! Sign Up
File loading please wait...
Citation preview

In Eursuit

I The Political Economy of the Indian State ^••/,

%Ta ^•^ ^^ ^-1

.

P.

'^J^ F

^.^. nt

*>1

_^^

mji

:14

Lloyd 1. Rudolph ^ u

'(& \u^

0(kS\

illlilMHall

ne Hoeber Rudolph

Ci

^

In Pursuit of

Lakshmi

Digitized by the Internet Archive in

2010

http://www.archive.org/details/inpursuitoflakshOOrudo

In Pursuit or

Takshmi The Political Economy of the Indian State

Lloyd I. Rudolph and Susanne Hoeber Rudolph

The

University of Chicago Press

Chicago and London

The The

60637 London

University of Chicago Press, Chicago University of Chicago Press, Ltd.,

©

1987 by The University of Chicago 1987 Printed in the United States of America All rights reserved. Published

96

94

95

93

92

91

90

89

88

87

54321

Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data

Rudolph, Lloyd L In pursuit of

Lakshmi.

Bibliography: p. Includes index.

— Economic policy — 1947— India — Economic conditions — 1947— and government — 1947—

1.

2.

India

Politics

.

Susanne Hoeber.

II.

HC435.R77

1987 0-226-73138-3 ISBN

ISBN 0-226-73139-1

Lloyd

I.

I.

.

3.

India-

Rudolph,

Title.

338.954

86-24903

(pbk.)

Rudolph and Susanne Hoeber Rudolph

are both professors of political science at the University

Hoeber Rudolph is president of and Lloyd I. Rudolph is chair of the Committee on International Relations at the University of Chicago. They are the authors of numerous books on India, among them The

of Chicago. Susanne

the Association for Asian Studies,

Modernity of Tradition (1967), also published by the University of Chicago Press.

She has no temples, but being goddess of abundance and fortune, she continues to be assiduously courted, and is not fall

likely to

into neglect. John Dowson, "Lakshmi," Hindu Mythology

From

in

A

Classical Dictionary of

thy propitious gaze, oh mighty goddess,

men

obtain wives,

children, dwellings, friends, harvests, wealth. Health, strength,

power, victory, happiness are easy of attainment to those upon whom Oh thou who purifiest all things, forsake not our thou smilest. .

.

.

our granaries, our dwellings, our dependents, our persons,

treasures,

our wives.

Hymn to

As the goddess of Lakshmi,

Lakshmi, Vishnu Purana

fortune, the epithet fickle

is

sometimes applied to

in contradistinction to Parvati, or Sati,

who

is

called the

constant, or faithful.

Edward Moor, The Hindu Pantheon

Even the Communists learnt that an Indian's vote was not wooed by Marx alone. In Bengal, the Congress was making a heavy play of the fact that its party symbol was a pair of bullocks on a yoke, which represented the peasantry.

The Communist

Party of India countered

by saying that its own election symbol, the ear of corn and a sickle, was an image of the Goddess Lakshmi, the goddess of

this

prosperity.

M. J. Akbar,

India:

The Siege Within

Contents

xv

Preface Introduction:

The Weak-Strong

State

and the Rich-Poor Economy Part 1 1.

1

STATE

Centrist PoUtics, Class PoHtics,

Class Politics

and the Indian

19

State

20

Confessional Politics

36

47 Bullock Capitalists and Backward Classes The Imperatives of National Power 55 The Constraints of Social Pluralism and Federalism 56 The Electoral System and Centrism 57

Minority Politics

2.

State

Formation

in India: Building

and Wasting Assets

49

60

The Subcontinental Empire 63 Historical Legacies: Liberal and Authoritarian Options in the Founding Period 68 The State and Its Permanent Government 74 Wasting Assets: The Erosion of State Institutions 83 The Military 87 The Electoral Process 89 The Police 91 Parliament 95

Historical Legacies:

Federalism 3.

The Struggle over

98

Stateness: Judicial

Review versus 103

Parliamentary Sovereignty

The Changing Meaning of Parliamentary Sovereignty 1 05 Judicial Review: Protection of Property

or Protection of Liberties^ vii

107

Contents

viii

Arena of Struggle: The Power and the Power to Destroy

to

Amend

09 Self-Restraint: Will Saving the Court Save a Government of Laws f 118 121 State Issues in the 1980s

Part 2 4.

1

POLITICS

The Congress

Party: Deinstitutionalization

and the

127

Rise of Plebiscitary Politics

The Congress Party and the Dominant-Party 127 System 132 The Deinstitutionalization of Congress Centralization and Personalized Sanjay Gandhi The Demise of Intraparty Democracy 144 148 Rajiv Gandhi's Construction of Congress

A Competitive

5. Janata's Historic Failure:

The Opposition Challenge and 160 Critical Election

1

40

Party System Aborts 159 the Promise of a

Janata's Historic Opportunity: Alternating-Party

Government

163 Policy Performance versus 1 72 Politics Fails 6.

Decline of Congress

Political

Dominance and

the

Performance:

Emergence of a 178

Bifurcated Party System

The Breakdown of Congress's Hindi Heartland 1 79 Base Minority Support for Congress: Special Relationship 187 or Minority Prudencef Congress in the 1 980s: Bifurcation and Volatility of

Political Universes

Part 3 7.

Demand

200

ECONOMY Polity

and

Command

Demand and Command Economic and

Command

Polities

Political Correlates

Politics

211

Polity

213

211 of Demand and

Contents

ix

8.

Types of

Politics

and Economic Performance

220

The Relationship between Politics and Economics 220 1952-53 to 1963-64: Democratic Regime/ Command Politics I 225 1974—75: 1964-65 to Democratic Regime/ Demand 228 Politics I 1975-76 to 1976-77: Authoritarian Regime/ Command Politics II 240 1977-78 to 1984-85: Democratic Regime/ Demand 240 Politics II Part 4 9.

DEMANDGROUPS

Demand Groups and

247

Pluralist Representation

Pluralism and Neocorporatism:

Some Conceptual

248 The Demand Group as and Policy 252

Actor

Distinctions

Pluralist

in Politics

255

Indian Variants of Pluralism

and State Domination of the Relations Regime

10. Involuted Pluralism

Industrial

Trade Union Militancy and

Its

259

260 and the

Failures

The Conditions of Labor: The Privileged Unp rivileged 262 The Nature of the Industrial Relations Regime 268 The Emergency Regime as an Experiment in 274 Corporatist Management of Labor The Procedural Environment and Trade Union Dependency 276 The Easy Path: Organizing Skilled Labor 279 The Conditions for Involution: Enervating Replication 280 Doctrinal Alternatives: Social

282 Regulated Conflict The Pay Commission Model Relations

Harmony

versus

in Industrial

286

Development Imperatives and the Desire 287 for Low Wages

X

Contents

11. Students as a

Demand Group:

Educational Policy

290

and Student Mobilization Students and Industrial Workers as Political

292

Classes

The Objective Conditions Shaping Students as a Demand Group 295 The Incidence of Student Protest and Its Goals 299 302 Policy Intervention in Student Conditions Spontaneous Changes in Enrollment Trends 304 Unemployment among the Educated and Student Mobilization 306 12. Policies

and

312

Politics of the Agricultural Sector

The

Land Reform and "Releasing of Production" 314

First Strategy:

Forces

the

The Second Strategy: Agricultural Technology and Self-Reliance 319 The Third Strategy: Basic Needs and Income 325 Redistribution The Fourth Strategy: Rural Employment and Increased 329 Investment in Agriculture 13. Agrarian Producers as a

Demand Group

Differentiating Agrarian Classes

333

335

The Polarization Thesis and Its Alternatives 346 Self-Employed Cultivators and the New 354 Agrarianism 364 Objective Conditions of the Rural Poor 3 76 Mobilization of the Rural Poor Conclusion

393

403 Appendix A: India's Hundred Largest Firms Appendix B: Agricultural Labor and Landholdings 407 411 Notes 501 Index

Figures

work

22

1.

Sectoral distribution of the

2.

Congress's share of seats in padiamentary and state assembly

force in India.

130

elections. 3.

4. 5.

Congress's share of votes in parliamentary and state assembly elections.

131

Voter turnout for parliamentary elections.

162

Indicators of

demand

politics: voter turnout, riots,

and student "indiscipline." Central government capital formation

workdays

226

lost,

6.

as a percentage of total

expenditure, according to regime type and politics type. 7.

8.

9.

Annual variation in industrial production according to regime type and politics type. Annual variation in food grain production according to regime type and politics type. Annual variation in wholesale prices according to regime type and politics type.

XI

230 232 234 236

Tables

1.

Hegemony: Leading-Country Shares

Indicators of Regional of Regional Aggregates

2. 3.

4.

5.

6.

7.

8.

9.

India's

5

Trade with the United States and Others

12

Comparison of Public and Private Sectors Among The Top One Hundred Firms 24 Increasing Dominance of Public-Sector Firms in the Organized Economy, 1978 — 82, as Measured by Total Paid-Up Capital 26 "Involution" in the Private Sector, 1978 — 82, as Measured 29 by Paid-up Capital per Firm Parliamentary Seats and Minority Population Proportions in Hindi Heartland States, 1977 48 Independents in the Party System over Eight Parliamentary Elections

139

Each Region's Seats and Votes as a Percentage of All-India Seats and Votes, 1967 Distribution of Congress Support in Parliament by Region,

180

1952-84

184

10. Divergence of Regional

Support for Congress from National

186

Support 11. Congress's Hindi Heartland Support as a Percentage of

Its

187

National Support 12. Distribution of Scheduled Caste Parliamentary Seats by Party,

1971-84

189

13. Distribution of Scheduled Caste Parliamentary Seats be-

tween Congress and Janata

in

Hindi Heartland and South,

1971-84

191

Support for Congress in State Andhra Pradesh and Karantaka,

14. Decline of Scheduled Caste

Assembly Elections in 1978 and 1983 15. Congress and Janata Support in Muslim Constituencies Compared with National Support 16. Variations in Muslim Support for Parties by Proportion of

Muslim Population: Parliamentary

Xll

Seats,

1977-84

193

194

196

1

Contents

xiii

17. Variations in

Muslim Support

for Parties

Muslim Population: Parliamentary Vote

by Proportion of

1977-84

Shares,

197

18. Distribution of Scheduled Tribe Parliamentary Seats by Party,

1971-84

198

Scheduled Tribe Support for Congress

Recent State Assembly Elections, Andhra Pradesh and Karnataka,

19. Stability of

1978 and 1983 20. Electoral Swings

in

199 in Congress's

National Vote over Eight

201

Parliamentary Elections 21. Regional Dispersion of National Vote over Eight

203

Parliamentary Elections 22. Volatility Index for Eight Parliamentary Elections in Five

204 227

Regions 23. Indicators of

Demand

Politics

24. Central Government's Capital Expenditure as a Percentage of Total Expenditure

Annual Variation 26. Annual Variation 27. Annual Variation 25.

in Industrial in in

Production

Food Grain Production Wholesale Prices, All Commodities

23 233 235

237

28. Index of Real Earnings for Employees in Manufacturing

1962-73

Industries,

263

29. Registered Unions, Unions Submitting Returns,

30. 31.

32.

and Average

Membership in Unions Submitting Returns, 1927—76 Growth in Number of College Students, 1950-79 Growth in Number of Colleges and Universities, 1950—81 Enrollment Growth Rates for Primary, Secondary, and

281 295

Higher Education

298 300

33. Student "Indiscipline" (Reported Incidents) 34. Expenditure

on Education

as a Percentage of Plan

303 304

Expenditure (Center and States) 35.

Changes

in

297

Plan Allocations to Levels of Education

36. Student Enrollment in First-Degree Courses of Study,

1975-76

to

37. Usual-Status

1983-84 Unemployment Rate among

305 First-

and Second-

306 Unemployment Rates by Residence and 309 Age Group, 1977-78 321 Growth in National Income, 1960-69 Changes in Holdings of Agricultural Households, 1954-72 336

Degree Holders 38. Usual-Status

39.

40.

41. Variation by State in Proportion of Family Labor to

Labor 42. Credit Shares of Poor Cultivators

Wage 344 373

Preface

This

and

book about

a

is

state in India.

the frailties of

some

the pursuit of

Wealth and power are

human

economy

terms:

We

elusive, subject not only to

We

have

is

sought by those

— what

book on Lakshmi be-

titled this

of the Indian state In Pursuit of

cause this fickle goddess's favor prosperity.

the people

design but also to ever-changing fortune

social scientists call conjunctures.

the political

now

weahh and power by

who

desire worldly

conceive of today's Lakshmi in national and secular

her favor was once sought by individual pious Hindus,

if

it is

communities, ranks, and conditions and by state actors concerned about national power, social justice, and collective goods. Five-year plans, even annual budgets, and the political sought by persons of

economy

all

them become the slokas and mantras knowledge and power produce results

doctrines that inspire

of an age less confident that

without the blessings of good fortune. Writing a book about the political economy of the Indian state over the past nine years has been an experience in discontinuity. Repeatedly,

events have pulled the rug out from under our scholarly the

book

in the

We began

feet.

midst of intense concern with governability and state

"overload," not only in India but also in advanced industrial democracies. India

was under emergency

rule. Indira

Gandhi had

dealt with

the Indian variant of a governability crisis by imposing an authoritarian regime.

endure.

We

had

to take seriously the possibility that

The momentous

sixth parliamentary election in

it

might

1977 over-

turned the authoritarian regime, restored constitutional democracy,

and suggested that Mrs. Gandhi's solution to the overload problem was unacceptable. In the process, India seemed to have acquired an alternating-party system. This too proved illusory. With all the heedlessness of Pandavas casting dice,^ the victorious Janata party destroyed a historic opportunity to establish a credible national party.

When

Indira Gandhi's Congress party returned to

power

in

1980

in

one-party-dominant system of the first national elections appeared to have returned. Mrs. Gandhi had promised a government that works but led the country into its most India's seventh national election, the

severe crisis. In June 1984, the Indian

XV

army shot

its

way

into the Sikh's

XVI

Preface

Golden Temple, and in October, Indira Gandhi was dead, shot by Sikh bodyguards. We had our last go at revisions in 1985, after Indira Gandhi's forty-year-old son, a dynastic heir and representative of the postindependence generation, restored national unity by v^inning an unprecedentedly large majority in the eighth parliamentary election and crafting a settlement for the Punjab crisis. India's

at that

time was characterized by

less

dramatic

When we

began writing, India seemed locked into a modest 3.5 percent annual increase in national income, what the late Raj Krishna, in his inimitable manner, characterized as the Hindu rate of growth. By 1985, Jagdish Bhagwati and others were asking "Is India's Eco nomic Miracle at Hand?" and answering in the affirmative.^ Dne consequence of the kaleidoscopic nature of political and economic change was to force us to rise above the flotsam and jetsam on the surface of political and economic events and reach for the more durable elements beneath. But we are aware that we are still at the mercy of conjunctures. We have many debts. We gratefully acknowledge the care with which Pradeep Mehendiratta, director of the American Institute of Indian Studies, has always attended to our multifarious problems. We thank the Smithsonian Institution, particularly Francine Berkowitz, for allowing us to think about the historical aspects of state formation, and the Committee on Southern Asian Studies and the Social Sciences Divisional Research Committee of the University of Chicago for facilitating our work on current problems. For thoughtful comment and criticism we thank Sanjib Baruah, James Warner Bjorkman, John Echeverri-Gent, Elfriede Fischer Hoeber, and George Rosen. For "pretesting" the manuscript in their undergraduate and graduate classes and giving us an impression of how we were doing and what was needed, we thank Tsou Tang of the University of Chicago, Brantly Womack of Northwestern Illinois University, Philip Oldenburg of Columbia University, James Warner Bjorkman, then at the University of Wisconsin, Franklin Pressler of Kalamazoo College, and Barnett Rubin of Yale University. Howard Erdman's eagle eye improved both style and content. Laura Jackson and Frances Haman became more familiar with Indian electoral data than they might have wished as they worked to construct the results of the 1984 and 1985 elections. Laura Jackson struggled with the construction of results from the newspapers before unofficial summaries became available from the Election Commission. She also practiced her art on the graphs. The chief election commischanges.

f

economy

Mr. R. K. Trivedi, and the secretary to the Election Commission, Mr. R. Ganeshan, were unfailingly courteous and help-

sioner of India,

I

Preface

xvii

ful in

supplying

and Maggu of

official data.

So were Messrs. Shankar Kumar,

Ullal,

DCM Data Products, New Delhi.

Katherine Sellers of the cartographic unit of the Geography Department at the University of Chicago prepared the final graphs. The

manuscript has gone through

M.

many

hands. In India,

we were

greatly

Sharma of Jaipur. In the United States, the first draft was created by means of the old technology, mere typewriters, by Kathy Anderson and June Mattick; the last version was a creature of the personal computer, as operated first by Mary Haynes and then by Betty and Earl Raaf. Richard Ulmann, director of the New York Council on Foreign Relation's 1980s project, launched this book by asking us in 1976 for a contribution to the project. The effort not only got out of hand, it has come to coexist with the decade it was meant to anticipate. Juliann Lipson's extraordinary subject and author indexes provide the reader with easy access to the book's ideas, evidence, and bibliaided by

ography.

L.

Introduction:

The Weak-Strong State and Rich-Poor Economy

the

India js_a political and economic paradox: a rich-poor nation with

weak-st rong

state.

We

try to unravel this

actions between polity and economy.

but not because India

is

paradox by examining

Our

a_

inter-

conclusions are contingent,

part of a mysterious East that resists formu-

by the Western mind. They are contingent because India is a populous subcontinent whose variety and complexity generate contradictory forces. If our formulations are contingent, it is because India lation

defies simple generalizations or easy projections.

When we

spea k of India^^eak-strong statCj

paradox of a

state that has, over the four

we mean

to convey the

decades since independence,

alternate3T>etween autonomous and reflexive relations with the sois em bedded. The strength of this state derives from and expectations created by 350 years of Mughal and British subcontinental rule. The result is a level of "stateness" and administrative capacity that exceeds those in other Third World and even some First World countries. It accounts for the vigor and effectiveness with which the state created a basic-industries sector in the 1960s. On

cietv^in

which^ it

the institutions

the other hand, the capacity of the state to penetrate the countryside

and

economy, particularly its agricultural which accounts for 67 percent of the work force and 39 per-

to influence the unorganized

sector



cent of the gross national product

(GNP)

— remains attenuated. The

mid-1960s impinged on the relative autonomy that characterized the state in the Nehru era. Moreover, the deinstitutionalization of the past decade has diminished the state's that is, to govern wisely capacity to make policy and manage conflict and well. rising levels of mobilization since the



Among the

Indian state's sources of strength has been a centrist pat-

tern of partisan politics that minimizes the political salience of

major

The country seems agreed ideologically on secularism, sopart cialism, and democracy, on the merits of a mixed economy policy. In foreign sosocialist, part capitalist and on a nonaligned

cleavages.





ciety as in politics, social pluralism prevails over class solidarity. Al-

though Bengal and Kerala are often governed by class-oriented Communist parties, India's many aspiring national parties as well as its one

Introduction

2

actual one, the Indian National Congress, are centrist. Contrary to

what one might expect

in a

country with great disparities of wealth, no

national party, right or

left,

pursues the politics of

class.

And in

a coun-

where secularization has advanced slowly and religious cleavages remain significant, there are no strong national confessional parties,

try

although there are important regional ones. The two economic forces that might support class politics

(^

nized workers and

private financial

and

industrial capital

— orga— are politi-

Organized workers are marginal because they are divided by party, union competition, and government manipulation. Private capital is politically marginal because private capitalism lacks cally marginal.

ideological legitimacy in face of the widely held belief that the profit

motive and private gain are inherently antisocial; because the private sector is overshadowed by the public, which occupies the economy's "commanding heights"; and because state control has made private

and labor face a third actor, the state, whose dominance of capital and employment in the organized sector dwarfs their influence in the conduct of policy, politics, and market relationships. To varying degrees and in different times and arenas, the capital dependent. Capital

third actor has served public interest or socialist objectives, the interests of private capital, interests. In the early

and

its

own

partisan, patronage,

and resource

1970s, the third actor came

increasingly to serve

wage workers and

capitalist farmers in

L^tself.

Class polarization between

and rural society is constrained by the leading role played in production and politics by small-scale, selfemployed "bullock capitalists," cultivators who benefited from land reform and the "green revolution" and who rely more on family labor and their own human capital than on wage workers and machines. The bullock capitalists oppose both industrial capital (state and private) and urban workers in the name of remunerative prices and better terms of trade between the countryside and the city. The Congress party, which has been the principal aggregative force for thirty-eight years, has played centrist politics with sufficient skill to win seven of India's massive agricultural sector

eight parliamentary elections.

Another source of strength for the Indian state was the country's "permanent government" its highly professional, technically expert, and well-institutionalized bureaucracy. Most Third World states have struggled at the time of independence to build qualified and effective career services, and most have failed. In India, the Indian Administrative Service (IAS) successor to the Indian Civil Service (ICS), which





was the

British raj's "steel

frame"

— provided the Indian

state

with

tal-

Introduction

3 ent,

expertise,

and continuity.

In

recent years, politicization

and

deinstitutionalization have affected IAS performance. Civil service

morale was badly damaged by the alternations of regimes and governments betv^een 1975 and 1980. The 1975 Congress-imposed emergency, the 1977 backlash against it that brought the Janata party to power, and the backlash against the backlash in 1980, when Indira Gandhi's Congress government returned to power, put a premium on loyalty and put professional independence at risk. Senior officers were transferred to remote posts for devoted service to fallen political ad-

1980, Indira Gandhi relied increasingly on palace ad-

visors. After

visors,

many

of

fidential advice

whom were senior civil

servants. In Nehru's time, con-

and deliberation on poUcy and

politics

had been the

province of cabinet colleagues, state chief ministers, the Planning

Commission members, and senior party leaders. Unmediated exposure to power left many civil servants intimidated and cautious. The international environment is far less salient for explaining Indian economic or political development than is the case for other Third World countries, unless it is salient in a negative sense, as an environment to exclude or keep at bay. India's economic and security dependency have been slight. Its participation in the international economy, which we discuss below, has been highly selective. Its goal has been self-reliance, a goal that has led it to participate in world markets less than other large Third World countries, in order to maintain control of the sources of economic power. Nonalignmen t, which was to a considerable extent founded and defined by India under Jawaharlal Nehru, has helped India moderate security dependency. It has been an

^

increasingly successful alternative to the superpower's bipolar definition of international politics

and

security, giving India

(and other

means to remain relatively independent of superpower/ blandishments. By featuring diplomacy more than armed strength,

countries) the

nonalignment has limited opportunities for India's military services to appropriate state power. Moreover, because nonalignment has been supported by parties of all political tendencies, it has minimized foreign policy cleavages in domestic politics, reinforced the centrist political consensus, and strengthened the hands of Jawaharlal Nehru, Indira Gandhi, and Rajiv Gandhi in Indian domestic politics. India's need for high-technology armaments has introduced some external constraints, such as its reliance on the Soviet Union as a major arms supplier. But this constraint has been balanced to an extent by arms acquisitions from Europe and, more recently, the United States. Nonalignment also enabled India to gain the advantages of international economic support for development while skirting the dis-

1

Introduction

4

advantages of dependency. After a decade of bilateral foreign aid, in which the United States played a leading role, India was instrumental in constructing less political multilateral frameworks, such as the In-

Development Association (IDA), of which

ternational

When

became the

it

were greatest, at the time of the third plan (1961—66), aid constituted 28 percent of plan investment, but as it built up its economy, the percentage shrank, to 10.6 percent in the sixth plan (1978-83). In 1983, India decided not to take advantage of the last tranche ($1.2 billion) of the

prime beneficiary in absolute terms.

International

Monetary Fund's (IMF's)

The Indian

statejs relative

India's needs

largest loan.

independence of the international system

complemented and reinforced by its leading role in the South Asia re^ioji. Its present dominant position followed the formation of Bangladesh in 1971, a development made possible by an Indian military victory over Pakistan. The South Asia region differs significantly from Southeast Asia, Latin America, Africa, and the Middle East in two crucial respects: the predominance of one power, India, and the small degree of political fragmentation. All five Third World regions share economic backwardness and liberation from colonial rule or imperial domination. But South Asia was less afflicted than other regions by political division into sovereign states during the imperial and decolonization eras. Rather than being the aftermath of diat the global level

visive competition

is

among

colonial powers, the South Asian states of

Lanka were shaped by the Mughal and British subcontinental empires, and Bangladesh emerged as the late fruit of internal war in Pakistan. As a result, fewer nationalist movements sought recognition in South Asia as independent states, and fewer and more viable states were founded. India, Pakistan,

and

Sri

India's relative position

among South Asian

by a degree of asymmetry not present regions (see table

or more) in

GNP,

stalled energy,

that leads

its

1).

India leads

its

states

characterized

is

in the other four

Third World

region decisively (by ratios of 2

:

population, armed forces, military expenditures, in-

and world trade;

region in

all six

Brazil

is

the only other single country

measures, and Brazil's proportions and

ratios are substantially lower than India's.

Asymmetry

increases the risks that lesser

powers face

if

they engage

and hence can constrain or eliminate intraregional state conand its consequence, flict. Although state asymmetry in South Asia has lessened the level and likelihood of conIndian predominance

in conflict





flict, it

has not eliminated

The

Soviet military intervention in Af-

December 1979 reintroduced superpower rivalry into the How India plays its dominant role determines whether or not

ghanistan region.

it.

in

c

ti

C

"^ "^ "O od (N ro

hv

Tf;

oo ON ^d T-H r^

^ K T-H

s

2"

q

ON

t/5

3Q

(Si

c c

1-1

;S

^ (N

q

NO NO

'^ *^ oo rsj

3-^

6 § ^ ^

S

-3 -^ to

Q

NJ ^^ J^ '-' fc> •«

60

< e o

^ 00 ON

K

(U

S So?

(1 1 OJ

(30

^ ^ -S^ 3 o « £ ,'^ O 5) bO^ Uh c>0 < UH T3

J

J2

U

e> S

oT

Introduction

6 lesser

South Asian

states will collaborate

with or reject India's regional

leadership. A regional bully that uses economic power and the threat of

force to get

accompany

way, insisting on the privileges and prerogatives that

its

great

power and

"responsibility," invites lesser states to

A

permissive "big brother" willing to pay

turn to outsiders for help.

any price for family harmony and compliance invites exorbitant demands and blackmail. In fact, India's behavior has fluctuated between these extremes, never reaching either but occasionally leaning toward one or the other. Powerful voices in government and among attentive elites, by calling attention to impending untoward consequences and the benefits of the neglected posture, have always constrained successive governments from moving too far to one extreme or the other. India's role as the predominant power in the South Asia region, like its leadership of the nonaligned movement at the global level, has added

more

to state sovereignty than

Sovereignty at

hom e

is

it

has subtracted.

more proble matic. Although often severely form of su ccessive Congress party

cjhallenged, the Indian state, i n the

government s, has shown co nsi derable ca pacity to rnanage^ manipulate, or repress a society that itself.

eager but only P^rtijljv _abl£jto_s2eak for

Despite a competitive party system, high levels of social mobi-

lization,

tional

is

and

life

a plethora of voluntary organizations, India's associa-

has proved too fragmented to agree or act on alternative na-

tional political doctrines that challenge Congress's version of the

nationalist legacy

during the

and

centrist consensus. Repression replaced politics

1975—77 emergency

regime. After

its

return in 1980, In-

government enacted preventive detention and laws, although it relied on them only intermittently. Its rela-

dira Gandhi's Congress antistrike

tionship to organized labor

was paradigmatic

of the state's relationship

and classes: tenuous control of the trade union sector resulted less from repression than from organized labor's competitive fragmentation into eleven weak national federations and many,

to organized interests

often powerful, local unions.

The parado x

of India's weak-strong state arises

tion of the Congress_party's durable

and foreign policy consensus, rneirit^and ajdynastj^

command

from jhe juxtapDsi-

of a centrist ideological

permanent governoir the one hand, with highly mobi-

social pluralism,

Hzed_albeit_fragmented social forces^that threaten governability, political sjukility,^_andnatj^^

the.othen Four developments

shape to .stat^w:eakness: (1) governments led by Indira Gandhi deinstitutionalized the Congress party and state struc-

fiave given concrete

embodied in deimmediate and hard-to-fulfill demands.

tures; (2) increasing levels of political mobilization,

i

mand groups

that press for

7

Introduction

have created an overload on the state; (3) unofficial civil wars among castes and classes have beset the countryside, particularly in North India;

and

(4) a

new^ religious fundamentalism

latent or low-level social cleavages,

making

it

is

difficult for the state to

"^

accompanied Prime Minister Indira Gandhi's successful attempts, between 1969 a^nd^l984^to centralize power in her own hand s. Beg inning in 1969, when she split the party by routing Deinsti tutiona lization

fairs

and hoped

to

manage

her),

who managed

and continuing

Congress party in

1972,

when

af-

she

used her personal triumph in state assembly elections to take the selection of chief ministers out of the hands of the Congress's state legislative parties, she systematically

eliminated actual and potential party

She thus undid the remarkable institutionalization of the party the state and district levels that had been the distinguishing mark of

rivals.

at

the Congress since 1920,

when Mohandas Gandhi

ganization unparalleled in Third

tional_jnd_s^£^partiesl

World

Ijnks^^^^^^^

countries.

built a political or-

By.^ttingjhe na-

organizations (to free herself

from demands on the one hand and to take personal change of resource allocations and patronage on the other), Mrs. Gandhi jeopardized_the support and legitimacy that a state generates when it engages in mutual substantive exchanges with local elites^ associations, and governments. Instead, she tended to reply on plebiscitary methods: direct, unmediated mass appeals enabled by ample funds (often of dubious provenance) and government's monopoly over the electronic media, the national name recognition and magic that the Nehru dynasty uniquely possesses, and the continuing but declining identification of Congress with both independence and sarkar (government in the generic sense). During the Indira Gandhi era, the Indian state like the



old regime before the French Revolution

— gained

but lost power, as the government loosened the

formal authority

state's

connections

with society by making them tenuous and arbitrary. In the mid-1980s, Rajiv Gandhi's efforts to revivify the party had not yet succeeded.

Th e^ deinstitutionalization

of party

was accompanied

of^the^autonomy and professionalism of

by:_the

state institutions.

erosjon

During the

was depleted as the independence, professional standards, and procedural norms of the Parliament, courts, police, civil service, and federal system gave way to centralization based on personal loyalty. Erosion was also the consequence of increased political mobilization, which invited authoritarian measures by threatening governability. The arrival and successes of new political classes untutored in the procedural decencies of a government Indira

Gandhi

era, India's political capital

uj^^f^

Jy^f^

exacerbating hitherto

accommodate them.

the "syndicate" (state party bosses

,

/

I

Introduction

8

and parliamentary conventions also washed away the legacies of British rule and the nationalist and Nehru eras. Nationalist politicians were succeeded by professional politicians and they in turn by a of laws

generation of political condottieri. Mrs. Gandhi's effort to maintain governability by centralizing

power

own

person and her secreparadoxically, to her son Rajiv's bein her

and palace retainers led, coming prime minister of a state diminished tariat

in

both legitimacy and

effectiveness.

'^ I ncreas ing levels of political mobilization have expressed themselves

through demand group's IKaTTiave pressed the state since the mid1960s. They have acted at least as much through extraparliamentary and extraconstitutional channels as through regular political institu-

on the European welfare state have developed the concept of the "overloaded" state, in which the overload arises from the increased responsibilities of the welfare state on the one hand and the heightened expectations of mobilized constituencies on the other. Because it is the state that stands surety for India's economic progress, demand groups have targeted the state, more than fate, nature, or private capital, as the defaulting party in the process of economic transstate beformation. The pioWems_of ungoyerna^ comes the target of protest against unfulfilled agendas are a challenge the Indian socialist state shares with European welfare states.^ The unofficial civil wars that have erupted in rural India since the mid-1970s have exposed the state's limited or perverse penetration of the countryside. Sporadic and unorganized, if not entirely spontaneous, local civil wars have often taken the form of group atrocities perpetrated by higher castes and classes against local Harijans, exuntouchables who generally are landless and work as agricultural la-

tions. Writers

borers. Such warfare reflects several trends: the decreasing willingness

of untouchable laborers to acquiesce to the molestation of their

women,

unjust wages, and debt dependency and their increasing willingness to the backlash by new and established elites against programs targeted toward poor constituencies and discriminatedagainst minorities; and the fact that, at the grass roots level, the state is too weakly articulated and dependent on powerful local elites to insure the security of persons and property or intervene effectively on behalf of citizens' civil rights and economic transformation. Overall, the medium-term prospects for state performance and po-

defy local

elites;

litical stability

are sufficiently positive to sustain steady

nomic growth. The beginning

if

slow eco-

of Rajiv Gandhi's term of office sug-

gested that he wished to strengthen

some

of the institutions that

deteriorated in his mother's time. But the deinstitutionalization, un-

Introduction

9 official civil

wars, and evidence of state violence and the "criminaliza-

encumrestoring the Indian state would

tion" of politics that characterized the early eighties heavily

bered Rajiv Gandhi and indicated that

be a formidable task.

Recent conversions, religious revivalism among Sikhs, Hindus, and Muslims, and related regional political movements accompanied by political extremism and violence remind us not only that Iran is not unique, but also that India's secular state,

tem are increasingly

at risk.

The_iiew

civil society,

p_oUtics._of

and

federal sys-

rdigion and region

expres s the aspirations and fears that accompany upvi^ard and do w^n-

ward mobility amonfi reconstituted religiou s comm nniries, castes^ classes, and people s. The prospects of these groups in political struggles depend on the ability of their elites to revitalize or create identities and organizations. Religious and regional ideologies often have proved more accessible, meaningful, and effective in the defense of interests than more abstract and less familiar secular ideologies of class, nationalism, or citizenship. Migration and the politics of region and religion feed on each other, as "locals" and "foreigners" (outsiders) struggle for their fair share of whatever benefits and opportunities a slowly expanding economy makes available. The circumstances of the early and mid-eighties have led to a gradual redefinition of the state's religious stance,

from a secularism that recognized individual

entitled to the free practice of religion to a secularism that

is

citizens

obliged

to recognize corporate religious groups clamoring for protection

and

advantage.

The

and subnationalism has created a dilemma for the state. A "strong" state response may generate more extremism and resistance; a "weak" state response may invite further mobilizations that challenge a state whose legitimacy and capabilities have been politics of revivalism

mid-1970s. Finding the proper balance of responsiveness and firmness, as Rajiv Gandhi has attempted to do, will be

in decline since the

critical to the

meaning of secularism

in the late eighties

and

nineties.

^ the p aradox of the Indian policy is the weak-_strong state, the paradox

of India's economy^isjts^rich-poor quality. India shares features of

an industrial country with a large GNR Specifically, in a world of 154 states, it ranks fifteenth in industrial production and twelfth in GNR^ India produces basic, heavy, and intermediate industrial goods (e.g., machine tools, steel, and mature-technology engineering products) for domestic conthe "Northern" (rich) industrial states in that

it is

sumption as well as for export, and it exports technology overseas via its own multinational firms. Other indicators of India's Northern

— 10

Introduction

status include

its

technical

and

scientific

personnel (ranked third in the

and its falling fertility rate and rising life expectancy. These assets create dilemmas for India. Should it continue to be placed among needy African and Asian "Southern" (poor) states whose economies have almost no organized sector? Do its interests coincide with those of other Southern countries that form part of world),

its

food

self-sufficiency,

"Group of 77," the organized voice of developing countries in economic issues? Is it not a "closet" Northern country within the South?

the

Yet the poor side of India's paradoxial condition clearly places

it

in

As much as 50 percent of India's population lives under variously drawn poverty lines, a proportion that has not changed since the 1950s. In 1981, 67 percent of the country's work force was in agriculture, a proportion that has changed very little since the ranks of the South.

decade of the century. These stark figures should not be taken to mean that very little has changed. Economic^evelopment mav^not the

first

have altered the basic param eters,.olpavjerty-aDcl-Lhe work force, but it has brought important and visiblej±Lang£SJ:Q_the.S0-cLal, cultural, and techn ological co ndkions^ rural society^ndj^nia^ej^ife In India, as in other parts of the Third World, reduced mortality rates (and higher

life

between 1971 and 1981 the population growth rate decreased almost imperceptibly from 2.48 to 2.475 percent per year instead of declining to an anticipated 1.9 percent.^ If poverty proportions remain constant and population growth rates do not decline much below 2 percent per year, at least four hundred million people will be living below a putative poverty line by the year 2000. Having said this, we want to remind our readers that such poverty estimates are seriously compromised by the large proportion of production, services, and exchange that is either nonmonetized or unaccounted for, and also that the calorie counts and consumption baskets, far from being standard, tend to exaggerate the quantity and quality of poverty in India. Even so, the glacial pace of poverty reduction contrasts with India's rapid development as an industrial self-reliant power. India's size itself is an asset and a liability an element on both sides of the rich-poor equation. The subcontinent is large enough to provide a potential market for indigenous manufactures and to reduce the appeal of or need for export-based growth, to warrant large investments in industrial growth and infrastructure, to provide the basis for diversification that can support independent development, and to create a critical mass in technical personnel and investment resources. On the other hand, every asset has to be divided, as it were, by 710 million. The poor side of the Indian equation that is, India viewed in per capexpectancy) have countered declines in

fertility;







Introduction

11

ita

rather than in aggregate terms

as a Southern state

and that

its



reveals that India properly ranks needs parallel those of other Southern

states.

has^sought to cont rol and. regulat^lhe impact of the inte£national environment on its domesticjeconomjc and^qliticaijSipices. Iridia

It

has done so successfully enough to minimize the dependency con-

many Third World economies. Our

straints that afflict politjcal

economy

of the Indian state, therefore, focuses

analysis of the

more on

inter-

nal determinants and dynamics thanj)ixexteinaJ_ones. India's development plans have been oriented tov^ard one overriding and widely

accepted national goal: maximizing self-reliance. Nehru's basic indus-

second five-year plan (1957—62), succeeded insofar as India, compared with other Third World (and many First and Second World) economies became relatively self-sufficient

tries strategy,

launched

in the

with respect to the production of capital and intermediate goods. The

(1951—66) has crewhich India home-produces most consumer du-

import substitution of the ated a situation in

Even

first

three plan periods

might prefer a lively Rabbit to the Birla's heavy-footed Ambassador, Indian consumers, until the mideighties, made do with the locally produced product. Iinj)^rt substituti on andJ^dnstrjaj diversification have, moreover, released India irom Tieavy reliance on finished industrial imports thereby freeing it from the depenHence on particular trading"pafFners that characterized its trade at the time of independence in 1947 and still characterizes the trade of many Southern countries. Unlike most Third World countries, India invested in agricultural technology. Agricultural production since the mid-1970s has made India self-sufficient with regard to food, an achievement that distinguishes it not only from most Third World countries but also from the Soviet Union and most of Eastern Europe. S elf-reliance has an external as well as an internal dimension, which is deterinined by aid, ex ter nal debt, inveansi Lai case

lodged by the Janata government against

(>)ngress's defense minister under the emergency.

I

he court asserted

the principle of the nonpc)liiical nature of state prosecutions even while

commodious

governments wishing to withdraw cases on purely political grounds. On the one hand. Justice Reddy asserted that "criminal justice is not a plaything and a court is not a playground of politicking.'"'' The court's function is to assure that the pub-

erecting a

lic

shelter for

prosecutor "had applied his mind as a free agent" and did not allow

himself to be the "stooge" of the executive.

On

the other hand, in

sanctioning the withdrawal of cases by both the (>)ngress and Janata

governments, the court's opinion offers special protection to politically motivated offenses.

The Janata government,

the court notes, withdrew the Baroda dyna-

mite case because "the motivating force of the party [Janata

was formed

which

1977 was the same as the motivatBaroda dynamite] conspiracy." The court

to fight the election in

ing force of the criminal |the

then poses a (jucstion: "To say that an offence is

|

is

of a political character

not to absolve the offender of the offence, but the question

is, is it

a

ground for the government to advise the public prosecutor to withdraw from the prosecution?" Indian history suggests it is indeed a valid ground: "A political offence is one which is committed with the

valid

I

The

121

Struggle over Stateness

object of changing the government of a state or inducing its

it

to change

poHcy," and these are "the kinds of offences with which

Mahatma

prime minister of India" as well president minister and were once charged. In conprime as the present sequence, "one cannot say that the public prosecutor was activated by any improper motive in withdrawing from prosecution."

Gandhi and

Is it

then

his spiritual son, the first

all right,

under

this doctrine, to

commit

crimes, provided

they are politically motivated? Apparently so. Three days after the su-

preme court handed down of Delhi used

it

its

judgment, the metropolitan magistrate

to dismiss the Jan Path riot case involving Sanjay

Gandhi and his Youth Congress followers. They were charged with mayhem and window smashing in New Delhi's central shopping area. Because the acts occurred during a political demonstration protesting special courts, unemployment, and the Janata government's policies corruption

— they



fell

under the authoritative judgment of the supreme

court protecting such offenses. sist

The magistrate

cites the court,

with prosecution where emotive issues are involved, in the

vindicating the law

may

"To

per-

name

of

be utter foolishness tending on insanity."

In the midst of the wholesale withdrawal of emergency cases, a

prominent Indian journalist argued that "we have not reached the stage of maturity in our development as a democracy" to make it possible for the Indian government to inquire into the transactions of close aides to the executive. Judges who have collaborated in the evaporation of cases "should be recommended for their common sense and realism" in avoiding a "confrontation between the concepts of popular sovereignty and an independent judiciary, if only because they cannot hope to win it."^^ Many leaders of India's legal profession do not deserve this judgment, written, in any event, before the Minerva Mills decision was handed down. However, this statement does suggest how the positive norm of judicial self-restraint toward the politically responsible executive can be used to defend judicial abdication in the interest of judicial survival.

State Issues in the

The

1980s

issues of institutional rivalry

have taken a more ambiguous form

1980s. The court shows the battle scars it incurred in the As Upendra Baxi noted, "During the Chief Justiceship of Ray and Beg, the Court progressively became an assembly of individuals and lost much of its corporate institutional character." ^^ Yet the end

in the late

seventies.

of Mrs. Gandhi's rule has eased the propensity of friends of the court to

STATE

122

view as suspect all executive proposals for court reform. It is easier than before to assess the weaknesses of the court system without rousing fears that the courts are under attack. Thus, when Mrs. Gandhi's government proposed transferring sitting judges of the state high courts to other states, this was viewed, with good reason, as a potential weapon against uncompliant judges. When Rajiv Gandhi's law minister proposed a system for drawing a third of each state court's justices from outside the state, at the beginning of their appointment to that court, it seemed more credible that the move was in line with the recommendations of the Law Commission for deprovincializing the courts. Even then, in reviewing appointments to the Uttar Pradesh high court, the supreme court accused the government of "picking and choosing" in ways that might produce "a sycophant judge at the helm of affairs," which was "a complete antithesis of an independent judiciary." ^^ The eighties brought new issues. Attention shifted among legal observers and actors, from the macrodrama at the national level of conflict between between the supreme court and Parliament to the myriad microdramas at the local level between the disadvantaged and the petty oppressive agents of the state: police rape, police blindings, so-

agency corruption, jail inhumanity. ^^ Justices such as Kirshna Iyer and P. N. Bhagwati, who had taken a permissive view, in the name of social justice, of a strong and even authoritarian state, led the move-

cial

ment against

the state's agents at the micro level. ^^ Legal aid, public

and voluntary agencies intervening on behalf of poor clients victimized by state agencies flourished in the postemergency climate. ^^ The "epistolary jurisdiction"^^ by which Justices Iyer and Bhagwati recognized even postcards from jail inmates as writ petitions focused attention on state impropriety and lawlessness. Some of the early euphoria has worn off the public interest law movement. Its limitations have become obvious. Overloaded courts interest litigation,

cannot handle the epistolary jurisdiction; courts have great difficulty enforcing their decisions; without a serious institutional base, public

law cannot survive; and "top-down" bureaucratic institutions for legal aid soon become routinized and unresponsive.^"* But public interest law continues as a powerful reminder that the state, written in

interest

lowercase

letters,

has

its

own

distinctive style of oppression.

Finally, attention has shifted in the eighties

from whether the courts

can provide justice to whether the courts can function at all.^"^ When the government of India sought to sue Union Carbide in a United

company's liability for the industrial accident at Bhopal that killed two thousand and injured many more, it claimed that Indian courts were too slow and ineffectual to deliver States court to establish the

The

123

Struggle over Stateness

timely and adequate justice to Indian citizens ing



a claim both humiliat-

and partly true/^

Nevertheless, the state issues of the 1970s persist. Several of the justices are criticized in their fraternity for

not observing a proper dis-

tance between themselves and the executive. Both Justices Bhagwati

and Desai have been so

Other justices doubt the legitimacy Justice D. A. Desai, like Justice Krishna

criticized. ^^

of the system that they serve.

Iyer before him, finds the judicial system "utterly alien to the genius of

and a "smuggled system." ^^ Yet others, such as Justice O. Chinappa Reddy, think fundamental rights have been given undue importance as against directive principles. ^^ The seniority issue, which was considered closed after the supersession wars of the 1970s, is also still alive. When Chief Justice Bhagwati faced retirment in 1986, the prospect that his successor by the seniority rule would be the more conservative Justice R. S. Pathak led Justice Bhagwati to press for another supersession by a chief justice with views more in keeping with the country"

his own.***^

remained at the center of the political between Parliament and court, constitu-

In the late 1980s, state issues

struggle. Institutional rivalry

tional controversies over the relative standing of judicial review

parliamentary sovereignty, and conflict between citizens' rights state interests will

and and

continue to orient leaders and parties seeking power.

is not explicit about a government based on a balance of powers and does not feature the pursuit of in-

Constitutional doctrine in India

stitutional self-interest as a restraint

on power. Yet India

will test

whether the prescription offered in Federalist 51 for the successful working of a division and balance of powers among several branches of government is viable. "The great security against a gradual concentration of the several powers in the same department," according to Federalist 51, "consists in giving those who administer each department the necessary constitutional means and personal motives to resist encroachments of the others. Ambition must be made to counteract ambition. The interests of the man must be connected with the constitutional rights of the place. ... In framing a government which is to be administered by men over men, the great difficulty lies in this: you must first enable the government to control the governed; and in the .

next place oblige

it

.

.

to control itself."

^^

The Janata government (1977—79), via the provisions of the fortyfourth amendment, and the supreme court, in reaffirming in Minerva Mills the basic structure doctrine of Keshavananda, restored a balance between judicial review and parliamentary sovereignty that gave the court and the parliamentary executive "the necessary constitutional

124

STATE

means and personal motives

to resist encroachments

by the other."

It

remains to be seen whether the court will continue to be filled by judges whose personal motives will connect with "the constitutional rights of the place." ^^ Chastened by the shocks and pressures of the

emergency and alternating party governments, the Chandrachud court, to accommodate the political interests of governments of the day, circumscribed the meaning of the federal principle and a government of laws. At the same time, it protected the doctrine of fundamental law

and the practice of

judicial review.

Whether balances struck over the

next decade will reflect judicial self-restraint that protects the constitution and fundamental rights or judicial abdication that sacrifices

both awaits the course of historical events and the country's judgment of them.

Part 2

POLITICS

The Congress

lL

Party: Deinstitutionalization and the Rise of Plebiscitary Politics

The Indian National Congress,

India's leading political party,

was

founded over a century ago, in 1885. It has dominated the country's public and political life ever since. Its success as the governing party of independent India distinguishes Congress from nationalist movements and governing parties in other Third World countries. When Congress successfully ousted and replaced the British raj, it inherited its standing as sarkar, governmental authority in the generic sense. It also benefited from the political capital that it had accumulated by leading the nationalist struggle for independence and victory over the country's colonial masters. For the first fifteen years after independence, the Congress party's nationalist reputation enhanced its legitimacy and that of the state

it

governed.

postindependence election

was one ties.*

At

When India held its first universal-suffrage

in

of the world's oldest its

1952, the sixty-seven-year-old Congress

and

best-institutionalized political par-

centenary celebration in 1985,

national elections

it

had won seven of eight

and governed independent India

for thirty-five of

thirty-eight years.

The Congress Party and

the Dominant-Party System

whose common language, interests, and lifestyle distinguished them from most Congress began as an organization of anglicized regional

elites

of the Indians they purported to represent. In the 1920s,

Mohandas

Gandhi transformed the Congress from an organization catering to anglicized elites to a cadre-led mass organization based on regional language areas. Gandhi not only rationalized and tightened Congress's organization and procedures but also combined individual and group organizational strategies. Congress became a popular organization based on personal primary membership on the one hand and an alliance of service and cultural societies and linguistic, ethnic, and religious groups on the other.^ Gandhi's campaign against untouchability agenda by repudiating caste hierarchy, a repudiation that burgeoning caste associations furthered by political efforts to improve their status.

explicitly introduced caste to India's public

127

POLITICS

128

and rationaUzed, encomthe Working Compassed national executive and legislative bodies mittee, the All India Congress Committee, and the pradesh (provinthat w^ere a liaison cial, later state) and district Congress committees

The post-Gandhi Congress,

differentiated

— —

with India's regions, social formations, and, to a lesser extent, producer groups. They reached traders, artisans, and cultivators in towns and villages.^ After independence, this is the Congress organization that with considerable

skill

won

the

first five

parliamentary elections, gov-

erned and developed the country, and managed two successions (the first after Jawaharlal Nehru's death in May 1964, the second after Lai

January 1966). The Congress party retained its organizational cohesiveness until November 1969, when a struggle be-

Bahadur

Shastri's in

tween the "syndicate" (an alliance of senior state and organizational party leaders) and the leader of the parliamentary party (and prime minister), Indira Gandhi, split the party for the first time. Lesser splits occurred again in 1977 and 1978. Except at the time of the Shastri succession in 1964, the Nehru dynasty faction led by his daughter, grandson, Rajiv, not only has defeated dissident factions, driven them into the political wilderness, or reabsorbed them but also has subsequently led the party to electoral victories that conIndira,

and

his

solidated the dynasty's hold over the party

and the country.

The Indian National Congress in the preindependence period was both a revolutionary nationalist movement that aspired to be the successor regime to the British raj

and an opposition party that aspired to

be an alternative government. Congress's early experience as both a governing and an opposition party taught India's political class that party politics and political participation could be competitive as well as revolutionary. This lesson powerfully shaped postindependence Unlike the revolutionary politics of violence and coups that

politics.

have characterized

many Third World

countries, regulated conflict in

and legislative arenas enabled government and opposition to survive and change sides by competing for popular support. In the nationalist era, India's political class and political community learned to participate in competitive parliamentary politics. The 1919

electoral

reforms introduced "dyarchy," governments sible to

in the

provinces respon-

popularly elected legislatures, in which certain subjects were

"transferred" to Indian ministers.

The Government

of India Act of

1935 provided for elections (1937) that led to the formation of fully responsible Congress governments in seven of eleven provinces. From 1922 through September 1939, when the Congress provincial ministers resigned, Indian politicians, drawn mostly from Congress ranks, were active participants in party and parliamentary government and

The Congress

129

Party

politics at the provincial level,

even while, at the national

level,

Con-

gress leaders pursued the confrontational politics of the independence struggle.

The dual

objectives of governance

and the revolutionary

struggle for independence fostered dual forms of political participa-

form of parliamentary and electoral

tion: (1) regulated conflict in the

party politics and (2) agitational collective action (particularly via

Gandhian

civil

disobedience) that entailed unregulated conflict with

authorities.

and collective action after independence. Indian subjects as voters were organized and mobilized by political parties seeking mandates to govern. They were also mobilized as revolutionary, albeit nonviolent, nationalists and as producers, consumers, and victims of private and state power by leaders of movements and demand groups seeking to bring about regime or policy change through agitational and extralegal means. The latter legacy inspires demand groups, whose form of politics will be discussed later These legacies shaped

in this

volume,

in

chapter

political participation

9.

became the lead player in a one-party-dominant system. Other parties were free to compete for power in electoral arenas to which entry was easy and constitutionally After independence, the Congress party

guaranteed, but they did not displace Congress, except in a few states. Congress's dominance in the

first

three general elections

was expressed

by overwhelming majorities of seats in Parliament and by victories in most of the states. The Congress won between 70 and 75 percent of the central parliamentary seats in the

first

three elections

and between 61

and 68 percent of the seats in state legislatures. That it did so with only 43 to 48 percent of the electoral vote is a mark of both the success and failure of the opposition: success in mobilizing more than 50 percent of the electorate; failure in dissipating

opposition parties competed as gress (see

figs.

2 and

its

potential seat majority

much with each

when

other as with Con-

3).

Simultaneous control of the central and state governments by the Congress party mitigated differences within the federal system. Con-

mechanisms and channels to coaccommodate divergent interests. Such party contexts supplemented the financial and administrative means normally available to the central government.'' As the hegemon of the dominant-party system. Congress was subject to "pressure at the margin" by opposition parties.^ Rather than trying to replace Congress governments of the day by forming coalitions or merging, opposition parties influenced Congress policies by working on like-minded factions within Congress. As much out of ne-

gress governments in Delhi used party

ordinate central and state governmental policies and to

POLITICS

130

cessity as out of choice, opposition parties

Asoka Mehta

responded to what the

referred to as "the poUtical compulsions of a

late

backward

country" by engaging in criticism but not in opposition for opposition's sake, because "the axiom of opposition's job to oppose would make economic development difficult."^ The dominant-party system

and the

roles of

Congress and the opposition parties within

100

it

provided

1

90

80-

70

60 CO

o CO

c u Q.

50

40

30



20 M.P. 10

M.LA

•52

•57

•62

"67

'71/2

•77/8

'80

'84/85

Elections by Year

parliamentary and state assembly elections. To calcu"1980" state assembly election, we have had to aggregate state elections for the period of 1979—83. The main election for nine large state assemblies was held in May 1980 (Bihar, Gujarat, Madhya Pradesh, Maharashtra, Orissa, Punjab, Rajasthan, Tamil Nadu, and Uttar Pradesh). Other elections were held as follows: 1979, Mizoram and Sikkim; 1980, Arunachal Pradesh, Goa, Pondicherry, Manipur, and Kerala; 1982, West Bengal, Haryana, Himachal Pradesh, and Nagaland; 1983, Assam, Delhi (Metropolitan Council), Meghalaya, Andhra Pradesh, Karnataka, Tripura, and Jammu and Kashmir (data from Asian Recorder [various issues]). For the "1985" state assembly election, we had the results from only nine states (data from India Today, March 31, 1985). For state and parliamentary elections through 1978 and for the 1980 parliamentary election, data were obtained from Election Commission reports; for 1984, from Government of India, Press Information Bureau, Lok Sahha Elections, 1984 (New De-

Fig. 2. Congress's share of seats in late seats for the

lhi,

1985).

The Congress Party

131

100

90

80

70

-

60 0)

o

>

50

c

o o 0)

40

.

Q.

30

20

MP. 10



M.L.A.

'52

'57

"62

'67

'71/2

'77/8

'80

'84/85

Elections by Year

of votes in parliamentary and state assembly elections. Data through 1984 are from Election Commission reports. The vote figures for 1977-78 are based on a calculation for the seventeen major states minus Gujarat, which voted in 1975. The votes for the 1980 and 1985 state assembly elections were still not available when this volume went to press in 1986.

Fig. 3. Congress's share

a fertile context for the rooting of India's democratic process during

two decades

independence. Congress party concerted and led the mediated Until the 1970s, the

the

first

after

mobilization of voters and the representation of interests.

It

was

in ten-

sion with rather than in control of or subordinate to public opinion

and organized

social groups, classes, interests,

In the context of policy choice

and resource

and

local notabilities.

by

cre-

groups and made

bar-

allocation,

ating political formulas that conciliated social

it

led

meant more than skill in creating political formulas, consensual policy agendas, and aggregated interests. In its early postindependence years. Congress retained some of that strong normative dimension that inspired it as a nationalist movement, a dimension that was capable of enlisting not only the interests but also the ideals of its members and those who identified with it. Congress

gains possible. But mediation

132

POLITICS

workers, candidates, and officeholders were meant to be bearers of Mohandas Gandhi's example and legacy, to live exemplary lives and selflessly

render service to achieve sarvodaya, the uplift of

all,

particu-

most disadvantaged and oppressed. They were also to engage in the more mundane tasks associated with competing for power and representing the needs and interests of ordinary citizens. For Gandhi, sarvodaya was essential if the Indian people were to be ready for and worthy of swaraj (self-rule). For him. Congress was both national independence and a service ora movement with a cause ganization that aimed to transform Indian society. The principled and disinterested conduct that Gandhi practiced and evoked contributed to popular trust in Congress, even among those, like Nehru, who were larly the





skeptical about Gandhi's ethical prescriptions for individual conduct, collective action,

and

social transformation.

At independence, Gandhi called for the dissolution of Congress as a

power and governmental office. The call was not heeded, even by those most closely associated with his political leadership. The nationalist generation and its

political party

engaged

in the pursuit of political

immediate successors followed Nehru, Gandhi's chosen successor, some because of his call to make the Congress party a vehicle for social transformation and principled conduct, others because the Congress party he led was a powerful organization that promised influence and benefits.

Congress as the legatee and bearer of the nationalist era brought many valuable institutional assets to the early years of the independent

beyond the party itself and the party system that it dominated to the political community, government, and state that encompassed them. During the Nehru era, the political capital that Congress brought to independent India was replenished, perhaps enhanced. But in the 1970s and early 1980s, India's institutional assets began to dissipate as Indira Gandhi sought to maintain power in the face of an increasingly mobilized and demanding electorate and seemingly intractable problems of governability.^ nation.

They reached

well

The

Deinstitutionalization of Congress

The

nationalist era's

committed

political generations

faded from view

Those for whom politics was an occupation, more a way to make a living and get ahead in the world than a cause worthy of sacrifice, filled Congress's offices and anterooms. In the nationalist era too, some Congressmen had lived off politics rather than for politics. in the 1960s.

The Congress Party

133

But in the 1960s they became the dominant element in the party's outlook and practice. The 1963 "Kamaraj plan," promulgated in the last year of a weary and chastened Nehru's life, attempted under the aegis of party president

strengthen

its

Kamaraj Nadar

to revive party

commitment and

professionalism. Party professionals, prominent cabinet

and state chief ministers left the perquisites and privileges of government office to do party work. The idea was to upgrade the esteem and prestige associated with party service as well as to improve ministers,

organizational effectiveness. After Nehru's death in

May

1964, party revitalization remained a prominent but elusive goal during Lai Bahadur Shastri's nineteen months as prime minister. its

Kamaraj Nadar successfully managed the succession at Nehru's death but did not, as Nehru hoped he would, succeed in strengthening the party. "Unfortunately," writes Stanley A. Kochanek, a close student of the Congress party, "organizational reconstruction was ignored during the four years of Kamaraj's tenure as Congress President.

.

.

.

The

and particularly the central office. Ironically, the man who came to the Congress Party leadership in the name of reconstruction failed most conspicuously to carry out his primary task."^ Instead, in the absence of inertia of the President affected the entire organization .

.

.

Nehru's vigorous central leadership, powerful state chief ministers began in Shastri's time to be more influential in national politics: the era of the "syndicate"

had dawned.

When

Indira

Gandhi attempted

after

three years in office to assert herself as Congress prime minister, she, the "Indicate," faced the syndicate as a rival force in the party's national affairs.

Under syndicate leadership. Congress ideology was more than ever perceived as empty rhetoric, mantras without meaning, repeated in manifestos and important party occasions. In Delhi, state capitals, and district towns, the politics of persons and factions crowded aside the politics of national purpose and high policy. The ground was being prepared for the electoral and organizational crises of 1967 and 1969, in the face of two consecutive bad monsoons (1965 and 1966), a draw in a major war with Pakistan (1965), and an unsuccessful devaluation (1966). In the fourth general election of 1967, Congress lost power in eight large states and almost did so nationally; two years later, it split for the

first

time.

January 1966, after the sudden and unexpected death of Lai Bahadur Shastri, Indira Gandhi had become prime minister of India. Granddaughter and daughter of two of Congress's great national leaders, Motilal Nehru and Jawaharlal Nehru, she seemed to the state In

bosses of the syndicate

who

controlled the organizational wing of the

POLITICS

134

more

and to be compliant than Morarji Desai, her rival for party leadership after Shastri's death. By 1969, having shed her diffidence and uncertainty, she was ready to challenge those who in their view had been her patrons and benefactors and party

likely to attract votes

who

continued to think of themselves as her mentors. In June, in an extraordinarily risky move designed to free herself from syndicate tutelage

and

a syndicate India,

by

constraints, she engineered the defeat of Sanjiva Reddy,

member whom

unofficially

the party

had nominated

for president of

backing V. V. Giri, an "independent" candidate

who, conveniently, had entered the race. In November, after a series of defeats within the organizational wing of the party, Indira Gandhi successfully defied the syndicate first

by endorsing

leftist political

posi-

had tabled but ignored and then by testing her strength in the parliamentary party. Congress MPs, however, were asked to choose not between the "Indicate" and the "syndicate" but once again between Indira Gandhi and Morarji Desai, whose imperious and selfrighteous manner had alienated not only many MPs but also his senior Congress colleagues in the "syndicate." Mrs. Gandhi emerged victorious by a margin of two to one. After the split, she led a minority government that had to rely on opposition party support (primarily from the CPI and the Dravida Munnetra Kazhagam [DMK], but she had freed herself from the constraints and tutelage of Congress's orga-

tions the party

nizational party.

and actions in 1969 seemed to many at the time to be those of a savior. She was perceived, particularly by those at the center and left of the party, as breathing new life and purpose into a moribund body. She did so, but not in the way anticipated by those for whom Congress was the party of Mohandas Gandhi, Vallabhbhai Patel, or even Jawaharlal Nehru. Although not foreordained, Indira Gandhi's 1969 victory over the "syndicate" proved in retrospect to be the beginning of party deinstitutionalization. Over the next five years it became increasingly clear that Mrs. Gandhi's ideological and policy stances at the time were useful tactics in the struggle for power within the party, not revitalizing commitments intended to strengthen the party organizationally and electorally. Personal loyalty, not party commitment, became the touchstone for preferment and promotion. The simultaneous rise of plebiscitary and personal politics under Mrs. Gandhi's guiding hand obviated the need for an organization capable of articulating with society, serving and leading the political community, and fighting elections. The rise of plebiscitary and demise of mediated politics resulted as much from unintended consequences of ad hoc actions as from design or conspiracy. As Indira Gandhi became Indira Gandhi's voice

The Congress Party

135

Congress's most vital resource, the key to poHtical power and personal

advancement, the party and the person tended to become one until, in the rich prose of then party president D. K. Barooah, the phrase "Indira is India, India is Indira" could be spoken to a grateful but anxious party following. As the myth of Indira Gandhi began to inspire and diminish India, the party that she led lost its institutional coherence and elan.

The Congress under Mrs. Gandhi's

leadership entered the 1971 par-

liamentary election at the head of a minority government dependent for

its

existence

ers believed that

new

Parliament,

had won

on opposition party support. Most informed observCongress was unlikely to win a majority of seats in the

much

less

capture the two-thirds or better the party

in the first three elections.

Gandhi's tactical and rhetorical

Hindi Heartland

skill

They had not counted on nor on the revulsion many

Indira voters

squabbling self-serving parties governments since 1967. By calling for an early (midterm) poll that ^'delinked" (separated) parliamentary from state assembly elections, Mrs. Gandhi was able to exploit her comparative advantage as India's only national political personality. Delinking also

in

that

had

make

states felt for the

led coalition

easier to turn the election in a plebiscitary direction

by matching one known personality with one appealing slogan, "abolish poverty." The result surprised the experts and practitioners; the Gandhi-led Congress was returned with levels of support reminiscent of Nehru's, a two-thirds majority in Parliament based on 43 percent of the vote. The daughter seemed to have redeemed the ideological and electoral legacy it

of the father.

Some

and class-oriented

observers held that the results heralded a

politics.^ Certainly

new issue-

delinking helped to "nationalize"

parliamentary elections by liberating them to an extent from a reliance on "vote banks" and local notabilities.

Her impressive personal victory freed Mrs. Gandhi from the constraints of national and state party decision making. At one stroke she was able to discredit her erstwhile Congress opponents and to substitute plebiscitary national outcomes for intraparty deliberations. She began to circumvent or ignore Congress's widely ramified organizations and procedures. At the time, her well-wishers thought the newly found freedom from conservative party oligarchs would enable her to use her mandate in realizing the promise of progressive policies at home and independence abroad. State assembly elections in early 1972 provided similar possibilities.

As the heroine of India's sixteen-day victory over Pakistan in December 1971, Mrs. Gandhi benefited from the emotional surge of a khaki election. Large seat if not vote majorities in most states again enabled

POIJTICS

136 Mrs. Ciandhi,

time

this

at the state level, to

[)wcrful regional leaders.

Victory

in the state

attributed to her personal following

among

brush aside seemingly

assembly elections was

the voters. Hiectoral suc-

cess once again validated authority within the party.

The

once

coattails

supplied by the Congress party's nationalist heritage, progressive image,

and organizational muscle were now thought to be supplied by

Mrs. dandhi's

sari.

Mrs. dandhi used her commanding presence stitute

in

the party to sub-

patrimonial considerations for organizational standing and ser-

was most apparent in the choice of state chief ministers. She overrode the established method of selecting them on the basis of support in state assembly parties and Congress committees. Instead, in the manner of the British raj, she '^nominated" loyalists, leaders more dependent on her favor and pleasure than on the support of represenvice.

I

his

tative party bodies

connected to state constituencies.

Party matters received low priority.'" Party organs at the center, state,

and

and those who ran them beconsequence unless they were thought to have

district levels fell into disuse,

came persons

of lesser

Mrs. (iandhi's ear or enjoy her favor. Starting state (>ongress

committees and

dents, were superseded by appointments

who was

in

1971, elections to

of their officers, particularly the presi-

made by

the (^ongress party

dandhi herself or one of her loyal dehe 1969 split removed most of the party's senior and expendents. perienced organizational leaders when men such as Kamaraj Nadar, a former president and architect of the 1964 and 1966 successions, the five most prominent ^'syndicate" members (Atulya (ihosh, S. K. Patil, and Sanjiva, Nijalingappa, and Brahmananda Reddy), and Morarji president,

either Mrs.

I

Desai, Mrs. (iandhi's (>ongress rival for the prime ministership in

Congress-O (for organizaSome constructed the meaning of the 1969 split and exit from

1966 and 1967, formed tion).

a rival party, the

what they took to be the lessons of similar intraparty struggle in 9S(). Soon after the death of jawaharlal Nehru's party rival, Vallabhbhai Patel, Prime Minister Nehru and (Congress president Purushotamdas landon, thought to be a I*atel surrogate, contested for ascendency, in the C^ongrcss canon, Nehru had saved the party from capture by conservative forces by forcing landon to resign and assuming the presidency himself." Ihe 1969 struggle was interpreted by Mrs. dandhi's 1

Nehruitc and "progressive" supporters as idc'()lo);y

and

a

comparable struggle over

policy.

With the benefit of hindsight, events beginning with the November 1969 split of the ( -ongress party can be given a tlifferent reading. he 1971 and 1972 elections, lor example, become the opening phase of a I

137

The Congress

Party

opened direct rehition between hidira Gandhi's personahzed leadership and individual voters rather than of an issueoriented politics that mobilized classes and interests in support of Congress programs and candidates," Both plebiscitary and issueplebicitary politics that

oriented politics radically reduce the explanatory significance of mediated politics based on vote banks, notabilities, and state-level factions.

But unlike issue

politics, plebiscitary politics

reduces ideological com-

mitments and policy preferences to one overriding question: whether or not to support the only person who is the dynastic heir to Congress's legacy and whose name and fame extend from the Himalayas to Cape Cormorin. The trend away from politics mediated by party organization and social groups was reinforced by aspects of Mrs. Ciandhi's character. She was a loner who did not feel comfortable with political peers and independent colleagues, neither trusting them nor inspiring their trust. She suspected rather than used autonomous political networks. Independent figures did not remain long in her cabinets or service. Out of these dispositions

mediated

politics

and

consequences arose her avoidance of the of party networks, and of political collegiality. Her their

avoidance of mediated politics was balanced by a considerable talent

mass communication, for eliciting trust and confidence at a distance. Large crowds came to take her darshan (auspicious viewing of a sacred object) and felt rewarded by being in her presence." By 1974, Congress governments at the center and in the states had squandered their electoral mandates. Fhe country was in crisis. Rather than implementing propoor redistributional policies and programs, the Gandhi government crushed the railway workers strike and faced for direct

Jayaprakash Narayan's movement for ''total revolution." '^ 1 he imposition of an authoritarian emergency regime in June 1975 signalled both the progressive deinstitutionalization of the Congress party radical erosion of Mrs. (iandhi's plebiscitary support.

month emergency regime

and the

The twenty-

accelerated state as well as party deinstitu-

tionalization by substituting

government of laws, and

fear for

consent. The apparently voluntary dismantling of intraparty

demochad ac-

fiat

for a

name of loyalty and discipline that companied reliance on "Indira waves" was compounded during the emergency by a miasma of fear. By "suspending" public liberties, particularly freedom of the press and representative and responsible government, emergency rule enveloped its perpetrators in an illusion of racy and procedures in the

public support. After extending the

life

of Parliament by one year, the

ernment eventually decided to face the electorate

in

Gandhi gov-

March 1977.

In-

POLITICS

138 dira

Gandhi was concerned

ing in the eyes of the

that her government's legitimacy

and military

civil, police,

services



was erodon whom

She had been shielded by loyalists anxious not to displease her and by the absence of public criticism from

emergency

rule depended.



knowledge of the grievances, political alienation, and resistance that emergency rule, particularly forced vasectomies, had created. She might not have risked an election had she been aware of how much her standing and the standing of her son and political heir, Sanjay Gandhi, had deteriorated. Janata, the party of the united opposition, swept to power on the crest of an antiemergency, prodemocracy wave.^^ In andemocracy or dictatorship the swering one fundamental question 1977 election result demonstrated the parallel and reinforcing effects of plebscitary politics and Congress deinstitutionalization.^^ Party deinstitutionalization was not only the result of centralized personal leadership and of splits and purges that deprived the party of seasoned national and state party professionals. It was also the result of substituting loyalists and favorites at state and constituency levels for party officials and candidates with local knowledge and support. Paul





Brass, for example, in his restudy of Uttar Pradesh politics after a

twenty-year interval, found that party

had access

officials

after deinstitutionalization to the

from Delhi no longer

kind of local informa-

tion or networks needed to select viable candidates or ministers. In

Mrs. Gandhi's time, the party leadership in Delhi had bypassed state and district party workers and notabilities to break the hold of factional leaders on the selection of candidates and ministers. Rather than conciliate those bypassed by brokering differences and balancing slates,

party

alty to the

officials

Nehru

When "waves"

from Delhi had

on those who professed loyknowledge or support.*^ deinstitutionalization seemed not

relied

family but lacked local

could win elections,

to matter.

Congress deinstitutionalization also took the form of declining party identification. Survey data analyzed by Eldersveld and Ahmed for the second and fifth years (1967 and 1971) of Indira Gandhi's party leadership

show

a precipitous decline,

from 70 to 47 percent,

was even more marked among strong Congress identifiers, from 94 to 55 percent, a decline greater than that for any other party.'^ The decline of party identification in India should not be confused with a comparable phenomenon in the

among

all

party identifiers.

The

decline

United States, because the causes are different: rise of

media

financing; in

in the

United States, the

independent voting, and personalized campaign India, party deinstitutionalization in the context of plebipolitics,

scitary politics.

The Congress Party

139

Deinstitutionalization in the form of a radical decline in party identification

would not matter

for elections

if

"waves," electoral surges

re-

mood, were adequate

sponsive to a particular personality or historical

But waves are unreliable, the result of unpredictable or uncontrollable circumstances, such as historical conjunctures, plebiscitary decisions, and personal popularity. Waves may be too ephemeral substitutes.

and

electoral

A

form of national decision making to respond to the needs of a complex and variegated country.

superficial a

decline in the proportion of elected independent candidates, such

as the

one that has occurred

in India,

analysis, as this decline has generally

would seem

to cast

doubt on our

been read as a sign of the

institu-

However, despite the deinstitutionalization of the Congress party, voters continue to prefer and reward party candidates, including Congress-I candidates. As table 7 shows, the proportion of independents elected has declined steadily, from 8.4 per-

tionalization of party voting.''^

cent in the

first

parliamentary election (1952) to 1.0 percent in the

eighth (1984) (column 3). Paradoxically, voters' preference for party

over independent candidates has been paralleled by a rising tide of in-

dependent candidacies: in 1952, only 28 percent of the candidates were independents; by 1984, 69 percent were. The 1971 parliamentary election was the first overtly plebiscitary campaign and the first to be delinked. Its results indicated three major changes in the relationship between party and independent candidates:

TABLE 7 Independents in the Party System over Eight ParHamentary Elections (2)

(1)

of Independent

Year

Contested Seats

Candidates

1952 1957 1962 1967

489 494 494 520 518 542 525 508

1971

1977 1980 1984

(4)

(3)

No. (and %)

%

of Seats

Won

by

%

of Votes

Polled by

Independents

Independents

(28)

8.4

15.8

(31)

7.9

19.4

(25)

5.5

12.3

(37)

6.7

13.8

1,134 (41) 1,224 (50)

2.7

8.4

1.7

5.5

2,821 (61)

1.5

6A

3,679 (69)

1.0

8.4

521 475 497 865

Sources: Robert L. Hardgrave, Jr., India: Government and Politics in a Developing Nation, 3d ed. (New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1980) (figures for 1952-77); Government of India, Election Commission, Report on the Seventh General Elections, 1 980, vol. 2 (New Delhi, 1981); and Government of India, Press Information Bureau, Lok Sabha Elections, 1984: A Computerised Analysis (New Delhi, 1984).

POLITICS

140

proportion of independent candidates running (from 1967 to 41 percent in 1971), a sharp decline in the pro-

an increase

in the

37 percent

in

portion of seats

won by independents

(from 6.7 percent in 1968 to 2.7

percent in 1971), and a sharp decline in the proportion votes polled by

independents (from 13.8 percent in 1967 to 8.4 percent in 1971). The inverse relationship betv^een the proportion of independents standing

and winning and the proportion of votes cast for independents suggests a marked discrepancy between the perceptions of the political class and those of the citizen voter. Higher proportions of the political class saw Congress deinstitutionalization as an opportunity to gain office without party affiliation and support, while voters, whose identification with particular parties had declined, still strongly preferred candidates with party commitments and ties. From 1971, when the notability politics of vote banks was put on the defensive by plebiscitary politics, independent candidates increasingly stood as spoilers. Typically, they had filed to get a party ticket but believed that, even if they did not win themselves, they could prevent the party candidate from winning. The voters took a different view by electing increasingly fewer of the increasingly more numerous independent candidates (compare column 2 with column 3). Voters made it clear that the deinstitutionalization of the Congress-I and other parties did not extend to their expectations about parties as the preferred vehicle for electoral choice. Particular parties

deinstitutionalization as the

framework

and a decline

may have

experienced

in voter identification,

but parties

of choice in the electoral process did not.

Sanjay Gandhi and Personalized Centralization

Congress deinstitutionalization was accelerated and deepened during the meteoric rise of Sanjay Gandhi, the younger of Indira Gandhi's two

During the emergency regime (1975—77), whose imposition Sanjay is said to have advised, Mrs. Gandhi collaborated in her son's efforts to establish a leadership position in the party and the nation. Many informed observers viewed such efforts as an attempt by Mrs. Gandhi to position him as her successor. In an effort to supply Sanjay with a power base, and in the name of rejuvenating the party, Mrs. Gandhi not only endorsed his "Five-Point Program" but also supported him in supplanting the party's regular organization by the Youth Congress committees in each of six thousand blocs (development administration units intermediately between villages, of which there are three hundred and fifty thousand, and dissons.

The Congress Party

141

which there are 352) and

promoting Youth Congresssponsored associations for physical training, sports, and so forth. When Youth Congress president Ambika Soni told congressmen assembled for the party's 1976 annual session that the parent organization had lost its vitality and asked it, for the sake of the party's future, to subordinate itself to the more vigorous Youth Congress, Mrs. Gandhi tricts

of

in

supported the suggestion.'^" Prior to the 1977 parliamentary election, Sanjay's star had risen enough among Congressmen loyal to the Nehru dynasty to risk allowing him to pick 150 to 200 of 542 Congress candidates from among his followers. They, like himself, were young, inexperienced, and unknown to the world of mediated politics in the constituencies for which they were given "tickets" (nominations). If the elections had turned out according to Sanjay's and his mother's expectations, Sanjay Gandhi would have become the leader of the Congress parliamentary party's largest faction.^' The **new blood" that Sanjay tried to introduce were often young men on the make, of dubious provenance, some with criminal records, whose loyalty was to Sanjay and the Nehru dynastic idea rather than to Congress as the party of secularism, so-

and democracy. The prospect of Sanjay's ascendency in the party triggered a second Congress split on the eve of the 1977 election and contributed to its defeat. Jagjivan Ram, the seniormost minister in Mrs. Gandhi's cabinet, and other party stalwarts resigned to contest the election with the newly formed Janata party." Ram was the leader of India's untouchables who, along with poor Muslims, were the principal victims of the Sanjay-inspired forced vasectomy program, an important cause of the vote swing against Congress in the election that followed. Three years later, in the January 1980 parliamentary election that climaxed her "comeback" by returning Congress-I to power, Mrs. Gandhi was more cautious than she had been in 1977 about Sanjay's role in the nomination process. Even so, it has been estimated that about 100 of the 351 party candidates who won parliamentary seats were or became Sanjay loyalists. In May 1980, when controversial midterm elections were held in nine oppositiongoverned states, Congress-I victories returned an even larger proporcialism,

tion of Sanjay loyalists.

The

who

responded to Sanjay's call to oppose the Janata government often had done so by taking to the streets or physically disrupting Janata-sponsored public events and courtrooms where Sanjay had been called to answer criminal charges. Some were lumpen political novices

capitalists,

make who expected Sanjay to and credit in their direction. Once

entrepreneurs on the

government

licenses, quotas,

shift

elec-

POLITICS

142 ted,

many proceeded

showing

little

to disrupt the legislatures in

which they served,

knowledge of parliamentary conventions or respect

for

the civility required for deliberation or regulated conflict.

The

selection of candidates for state assemblies

and Parliament

is an important determinant of party control and of its ideological, leadership, and programmatic orientation. Candidate selection, the giving of

"tickets," determines the relative strength of factions, which, in turn,

provide a route to ministerial posts and the perquisites of affects the prospects of those

who

office. It also

aspire to be chief ministers. In

what

from previous Congress practice? an account of candidate selection at the Rameshray Roy has provided end of the Nehru era: respect did Sanjay's selection differ

Selection of party candidates offers the

first series

of skirmishes be-

tween conflicting interests which grope for political articulation and control. If the party fails to adjust and reduce the intensity of the selecconflicting claims, it will go to the final battle bruised tion process is a crucial test of the party's flexibility and adaptability in coping with the pressures and counterpressures that impinge upon it from both within and without. 23 .

.

.

Roy's characterization depicts candidate selection as a party process that articulates with social forces, sometimes

accommodating or

yield-

ing to them, sometimes shaping or leading them. But candidate selec-

Gandhi ceased to be such top-down affair in which favorites,

tion as practiced by Sanjay stead, their

it

became

networks

Sanjay's

a

won

a process. In-

and

loyalists,

the prize.

ways of giving Congress

tickets contrasted sharply

those practiced in his grandfather's time. In the

Nehru

with

era and, indeed,

through the 1967 (fourth) general election, candidate selection

in-

volved a complex balancing of personal qualifications, ideological orientation,

and

factional alignment. Prospective candidates' credentials

were scrutinized for

integrity,

to party rules of personal

commitment

conduct

(e.g.,

to party goals, adherence

abstention from alcohol, wear-

ing khaddar), and participation in approved forms of service, the latter

two

criteria particularly

being residues of

Mohandas Gandhi's

influ-

ence. Tacitly considered were pragmatic factors, such as previous suc-

and current prospects of winning in one, standing in large or powerful social groups, and influence over political resources and networks. The principal organizational vehicles for the selection process were state-level Congress committees. In the sixties, district and even mandal committees (a smaller party unit) ac-

cess in holding a constituency

The Congress Party

143

The committees recommended MLA or MP candiCentral ParHamentary Board, whose members in principle

tively participated.

dates to the

made

the final choice, a choice that often validated committee recom-

mendations.''*

The board, which included

the party's

most

influential

national leaders, deputed "observers" to Congress committees in sev-

where they mediated

eral states,

conflicts in the light of the board's

and preferences. Insofar as these procedures were perceived as fair and motivated by concern for the collective good of the party, they minimized defections and independent candidacies by disgruntled aspirants for party tickets, moderating factionalism and reducing its poideas

litical costs.

In the 1950s,

with independence

still

had served or suffered in the nationalist favored. In the 1960s, local notabilities

a recent event, persons

movement were

who

particularly

and leaders of caste commusocial power into political re-

and willing to convert their sources for party use became more prominent. In either case the selecton process rewarded apprenticeship and time in rank, overt signs of party discipline and loyalty to the party. In Indira Gandhi's time, those who proclaimed and were seen to practice loyalty to the Nehru dynasty were more likely to get a ticket. Political influence, including the likelihood of getting a ticket, was increasingly determined not by apprenticeship, party service, and local standing but rather by location in manifold networks of personal loyalty and patronage, at whose apex stood Indira and Sanjay Gandhi. In the selection process for the 1980 parliamentary and state assembly elections, the party's apex bodies, which had umpired a bottom-up process, had been displaced by Indira and Sanjay Gandhi or their agents, who presided over a top-down process." In the May 1980 cannities able

didate selections, Sanjay or his lieutenants overrode, often literally in the last minutes before official nominations closed, slates of candidates selected over a

two-month period by

district

and

state-level

Congress

committees, in order to allocate tickets to adherents of factional leaders loyal to Sanjay or to supporters of Sanjay's choices for state chief

minister.^^

The

successful

(Congress

became hour.^^

won

outcome

of the

May 1980

state

majorities in eight of nine states,

chief ministers in six of them)

A month

later,

was

assembly elections

and Sanjay

loyalists

and last was dead. The

Sanjay's finest

the triumphant heir apparent

world would have to imagine what the future course of Indian history would have been had he lived to reap the fruits of his ascendency. Unlike his elder brother Rajiv, the airline pilot, Sanjay was an inexperienced

flyer.

He

crashed while violating the regulations against per-

POLITICS

144

forming acrobatics at low levels over New Delhi's presidential palace. He died as he had lived: daring, impetuous, contemptuous of the rules, a danger to himself and others. His death removed a controversial and divisive figure from the inner life of the Congress party. His mother, grandfather, and great-grandfather

had

led the

Congress and the na-

As a Nehru, he could use the family name to attract bigger crowds in most states than favorite sons or other aspiring national leaders. Those who wanted to get things done, to cut the red tape spun by bureaucrats and judges concerned about correct procedure and the rule of law, and those who saw in his meteoric career a way to make their political fortunes quickly, flocked to his side. The effect of Sanjay's leadership on the Congress was to deinstitutionalize it further by increasing its patrominial features. By the time of his death, the party had become his and his mother's bailiwick. tion.

The Demise

of Intraparty

The Congress party

Democracy

of the 1980s

was

the precipitate of Indira Gandhi's

struggle as leader of the parliamentary party to free herself

organizational wing and the state party bosses

who had

from the

controlled the

party since the mid-1960s. After Nehru's death in 1964, the influence of the organizational party's

— the Working Committee, often loosely referred the "high command" — had been diminished by the

apex bodies

to collectively as

"bosses" came to wield in national politics and

power

state leaders or

policy.

Some described the

result as party federalism, others as balkani-

and committee presidents demonstrated their role as national power brokers in 1964 and 1966 by presiding over the selection of Lai Bahadur Shastri and then Indira Gandhi as successors to Jawaharlal Nehru. As the party became more federal, it also lost some of its organizational autonomy. Its electoral prospects became increasingly dependent on local elites and the resources and networks they could deliver. The interest of aspiring, newly mobilized social groups in gaining access to power complemented the needs of competing Congress factional leaders in widening the bases of their support. These leaders tended to attract such support because they were more likely than opposition factional leaders to influence the allocation of government benefits. Even so, by 1967, when the party almost lost the fourth general election, growing democratization and heterogeneity seem to have zation. State chief ministers

outpaced the party's proverbial capacity to absorb anything; the great boa constrictor was suffering from indigestion.

The Congress Party

145

Although the party became more "federal" in the 1960s, it retained the forms and much of the substance of the intraparty democracy it had known in the immediate postindependence era. Periodic (usually biannual) organizational elections to offices and bodies at the district, state, and national levels were held through 1969, but they became increasingly problematic. Intraparty elections generated intense

and

dis-

power within the party exacerbated the problem of "bogus" memberships as contestants sought to win by buying or coercing rank-and-file support and as factionalized Congress authorities lost the capacity to intervene. At the same time, intraparty elections provided a means, however imperfect, for aspiring party leaders to validate and thus legitimize their claims to support ruptive factional conflict. Struggles for

within the party.

Mrs. Gandhi, the author of the 1971 and 1980 Indira waves that swept the party into power, became the party's principal political resource. In 1972, she suspended organizational elections. None have been held

since. Rajiv

Gandhi's pledge

at the

Congress-I centenary ses-

"power brokers" and restore intraparty democracy by holding elections was stymied by revolt and resistance from "Indira loyalists." Mrs. Gandhi used her plebiscitary endorsement by the people to legitimize her authority in the party. The result sealed the fate of intraparty democracy. It also ended the party's reliance on the organizational wing to conduct and win elections. Campaign resources could be paid for from the ample funds that flowed into the party coffers from interested and intimidated sources. As the government party, the Congress could use the powers of incumbency to target benefits in a timely manner and to take advantage of the help that committed bureaucrats were willing to render. The party in the 1980s could afford to ignore the power base that aspiring state leaders might attempt to build because it was free to bypass the local elites on which state factional leaders rely. Prior to Mrs. Gandhi's assassination in October 1984, the balance of power between the center and the states and between the parliamentary and organizational wings of the party had been reversed: members of the party's apex bodies as well as chief ministers and state Congress committee presidents were nominated from sion in 1985 to purge the party of

Delhi, not chosen by state party bosses, state legislature parties, or state

committees.

With the

benefit of hindsight, the problematic consequences of

and personal leadership seem clear, but they were not in the 1960s. Many of Mrs. Gandhi's measures seemed to address problems of party management. In the mid-sixties, the rule of party bosses (the syndicate) and the effects of rampant factionalism in the

plebiscitary politics

POLITICS

146 states struck tive,

many

observers and active politicians as vicious, destruc-

The Congress Party the selection of Con-

and corrupt. Stanley Kochanek's postscript to

of India (1968) and Rameshray Roy's account of gress candidates" (1966—67) characterize the effects of active participation by lower levels of the organization in tones that are often skeptical.

They

are cautionary tales that

intraparty democracy of that time.

appeared to have

warn us against romanticizing the The national organs of the party

lost their capacity to

moderate, broker, and channel

make

and govern itself from the bottom up. The costs of contentiousness seemed to overshadow the virtues and benefits of intraparty democracy. The party's inability to conduct internal elections that commanded confidence (bogus membership in some states rose to 50 percent) generated cynicism too. These developments explain why suspension of organizational elections in 1972 could be regarded as a way to avoid destructive conflict as well as a way for state and national party leaders to the conflicts

evade the

Nor

is

zational

let

loose by a party trying to

decisions

test of the vote.

the victory of the party's parliamentary

wing novel or problematic

mentary parties

wing over

its

organi-

for parliamentary systems. Parlia-

in India, as in other

parliamentary democracies, are

often the seat of ideological tendencies or factional groupings that

from those entrenched in the organizational wing. In the British Labour party, for example, the organizational wing and the parliamentary wing have often been at loggerheads, with the organizational wing typically taking the more radical stance. In India, by contrast, the parHamentary party has usually been the more progressive. In any case, leaders of parliamentary parties in Britain and India frequently acted independently of the policy decisions and discipline of their parties' organizational wings, and sometimes have become the dominant party differ

influence. In a classic instance,

Hugh

Gaitskell retained the leadership

November 1960, even though he make him adhere to the party confer-

of Labour's parliamentary party in

defied Aneurin Bevan's efforts to

disarmament. Similar clashes have occurred in India with comparable results. We have already referred to Nehru's successful use in 1951 of the threat of resignation as prime minister

ence's call for unilateral

remove the conservative, Hindu nationalist Purushotamdas Tandon from the office of Congress president. The move secured his ascendency thereafter in the organizational wing of the party. These examples provide a context for judging Indira Gandhi's claims, after 1967, that it was only by asserting the prerogatives of the parliamentary leader of the party that she could save it from the conservatism

to

and depradations of

its

organizational wing.

The Congress

147

Was

Party

deinstitutionalization a necessary or inevitable response to de-

cline in organizational

autonomy or

to increased centralization?

Was

Gandhi merely the victim of historical forces? Did she act more for example, out of necessity than choice? Another prime minister placed in the historical Shastri circumstances of the Bahadur Lai decade from 1965 to 1975, might also have acted to correct organizational imbalances and to protect the party leader's prerogatives. But Indira Gandhi went further than correcting imbalances and protecting prerogatives. Autonomous centers of power became suspect; loyalty was rechanneled from the party to its leader. These consequences go beyond efforts to deal with the tensions that are bound to arise between the organizational and parliamentary wings of a party within a federal system. Brokering and bargaining skills and ideological creativity might have restored balance between the party's state and national levels and between its organizational and parliamentary wings. Mrs. Gandhi preferred other means. The outcome suggests that human agency mattered, that the values and acts of a leader were a vital component in the deinstitutionalization of the Congress party. Party deinstitutionalization in India and elsewhere was overdetermined. The trend toward the erosion of party and unmediated national politics was not unique to India in the 1960s and 1970s. It bore a family resemblance to the fate of parties in American politics of the same period. National campaigns in India and America began to have less to do with local machines and their dedicated party workers and more to do with raising and spending large sums of money on opinion experts, instant organization, the mobilization of volunteers, and intense media efforts to start bandwagons rolling. The literature on party in America is replete with accounts of a decline in party identification and local organization, an increase in the proportion of voters who said they were independents, and a shift from organizational to media politics. The older-style ward committeemen who knew the voters Indira





were displaced by advertising firms, professional political consultants, and media specialists. Some observers read these trends as the demise ofparty.^^

Indian elections since 1971 have shared All-India

and

knowledge of seded. state

local candidates

Heavy expenditure

and

who

and

issues

(often based

local organizations

from the

of these features.

provided policy guidance and and committed party workers with their

state party officials

arbitrated local disputes

some

composed

have been increasingly super-

on "black" money) on

instant

of temporary workers hoping

have taken their place, as have a rural nation's equivalent of pervasive mass media fast-moving jeeps

to benefit

spoils of victory



POLITICS

148

equipped with loudspeakers, posters, leaflets. Most recently, sound and video cassettes have been added to the campaign repertoire. Rajiv Gandhi's 1984 and 1985 campaigns relied heavily on the newer forms

and methods. These changes are not necessarily the same as deinstitutionalization. In the United States, they were being interpreted as a new version of institutionalized parties. In India, in so far as such new forms and methods reflect professonalism and better management rather than personalism, they constitute a new form of institutionalized party rather than deinstitutionalization in the context of plebiscitary politics.

India

may

be no more ready than the United States to dispense

with party as an organization that links society to

politics.

Rajiv Gandhi's Construction of Congress Interpreting Rajiv Gandhi's ideas deinstitutionalization

is

more

and actions

difficult

in relationship to party

than interpreting those of Indira

and Sanjay Gandhi, but his efforts in the early years after his succession gave signs that he wished to reverse deinstitutionalization. Rajiv's presence in the party and in public life began only after Sanjay's death, and even then, until October 31, 1984, he remained more in the shadow of his mother than had been the case when Sanjay was the heir took some time for Rajiv to overcome what was believed to be a genuine reluctance on his and, even more, his wife Sonia's part about exposing themselves to the publicity and vicissitudes of political life. The life of an heir apparent

apparent. After Sanjay's death in June 1980,

was not one Rajiv seemed eager

to begin.

it

Whether calculated or

not,

shunning of politics and his initial reluctance to join it after Sanjay's death spoke to the Indian belief that those who do not desire power or pursue it are more fit to rule than those who do. When he gave up his career as an airline pilot some months after Sanjay's death and publicly began to help his mother, there seemed little doubt that she hoped and intended that he would succeed her. Rajiv's earlier

His intended course of action became apparent in 1981, when in a byelection he stood for and won his brother's vacant seat in the Uttar Pradesh constituency of Amethi. His in

doubt about

Youthful,

his ability to

don

initial

the family

years in politics

mande

left

many

of national leader.

handsome and personable, he was dubbed "Mr. Clean" by

the media, in part to contrast his conduct with his brother's unsavory reputation in his youth and as a politician. But he seemed to lack Sanjay's

fire,

guts, and,

more important,

political

appeal and

skill.

His

The Congress Party

149

role in four state little

assembly campaigns

own

to help his

in

1982 and two

or Congress-I's political

1983 did standing. His muchin

touted managerial role in the extraordinarily expensive preparations for Asian

Games

held in Delhi in the

fall

of 1982,

when new

roads,

and hotels sprouted throughout the city, raised quesabout whether Rajiv's politics would feature bread and circuses for the affluent. Some thought in February 1983 that the disappointments in the Andhra Pradesh and Karnataka state assembly elections in January were the reason for Rajiv's becoming one of the Congress-I's five general secretaries rather than, as some had expected. Congress flyovers, stadia,

tions

party president.

were devoted mostly to a cenprofessionalizing the party by training cadres and to

Rajiv's activities as a general secretary tralized effort at

efforts at consolidating Congress's position in various states. In

he played an active part in toppling state governments

(in

1984, Sikkim,

Andhra Pradesh, and Kashmir) in ways that raised questions about propriety and even constitutionality. His leadership of the 1984 parliamentary election campaign was perceived as communal. By attacking Sikh demands and conduct as separatist or fissiparous, he seemed to be exploiting the Hindu backlash to his mother's assassination. If the result could be heralded as a great victory for national unity and renewal, ciling

it

could also be interpreted as exacerabating rather than recon-

communal animosity between Hindus and

Sikhs. Rajiv Gandhi's

record as a Congress general secretary and in the immediate succession

open the question of whether his leadership would address Congress deinstitutionalization or continue the centralized personal

period

left

politics of fear

brother.

Had

and

loyalty associated with his

mother and younger

Rajiv been biding his time, a victim of his mother's

leadership and the historical circumstances that

he the youthful, forthright, confident leader of a

it

provoked? Or was

new

India

who would

rejuvenate the party?

The answer

to the question

evidence can be read in a

is

complicated by the fact that the same

number

of ways:

what looked

to

some

like

party rejuvenation and national renewal looked to others like a continuation of deinstitutionalization.

The reading depends

to an extent

on perceptions of motives and goals. Indira and Sanjay Gandhi's rhetoric and action can be read in the light of their intolerance for opposition, their drive for centralized patrimonial control, and the public perceptions that personal loyalty mattered most. Rajiv's actions can be

read in the light of a belief that he

is

a

more secure person than

his

mother was and that he has a greater tolerance for opposition if not disloyalty and more confidence that deliberation and bargaining among

POLITICS

150

autonomous and responsible men and institutions can yield legitimacy and workable solutions. He is more capable of trusting and of being trusted, more tolerant of opposition and autonomy, more appreciative of the need and virtues of decentralization. In an interview that he gave to Sunday in March 1983, he observed that "over the ten maybe 15 years, the party has stopped functioning as a last relatively

.

.

.

party.

.

.

.

We

have to restore the responsibilities of the lower

bearers, the block presidents

and

district presidents

and

office

really restore

a democratic functioning within the party." Decentralization was the "only way" the party could be made to work as a viable organization.

The

first

step for party revitalization, he held,

was party

elections.^^

Rajiv Gandhi's attitudes toward party building can be viewed from the perspective of the new space he has come to occupy in Indian politics.

More than

mother and grandfather, whose political rhetoric formulations of Congress politics and solidarity with

his

featured socialist

the poor and dispossessed, Rajiv speaks for the "France in India," the

100 to 150 million who live Hke the middle classes in advanced industrial societies. But a winning political strategy cannot easily be constructed without addressing the interests of the much larger pre- and nonindustrial sectors in household-based craft and agricultural production and the bazaar economy. Can the "France in India" and the Indian version of "yuppies" who are its vanguard build a party whose appeal and support exends to India's

new

agrarians, independent

have benefited from the land reforms and the green revolution, not to mention its marginal cultivators and agricultural

producers laborers?

who



which media politics is displacing organizational politics, Rajiv Gandhi is even better equipped than his mother was to fight elections. Both were concerned to extend television coverage prior to the eighth parliamentary elections in December 1984, so as to better exploit their incumbent government's monopoly over the electronic media. Rajiv has a natural and attractive television presence. In an era in which the cassette recorder is replacing the local notability and vote In

an era

in

banks, Rajiv's technological bent gives him an advantage. Rajiv Gandhi's record in the four deinstitutionalization arenas previously discussed yields a mixed picture. Under Indira and Sanjay

Gandhi, deinstitutionalization was particularly evident with respect to (1) intraparty democracy (i.e., the fate of party elections and of organizational decision making); (2) the sources of a leader's support and legitimacy (i.e., the extent to which they were located within the party or outside, in plebiscitary endorsements by the electorate); (3) the criteria used to select party candidates; and (4) the autonomy of state party leaders and organizations and the integrity of state governments.

The Congress Party

151

Rajiv Gandhi's view of intraparty democracy, the

first

aspect of de-

institutionaHzation, can be understood through his strategy as a party

general secretary and later as party president, through his approach to

party elections, and through his handling of intraparty opposition to

As a general secretary of the Congress party in 1983 and 1984, Rajiv Gandhi was less oriented to rebuilding the party at the state and local levels or reintegrating it with society than to creating a centralized national party bureaucracy whose local cadres could gather information for Delhi and communicate decisions made there. The emphasis was on top-down rather than bottom-up communications and authority. Rajiv's managerial ideology and professional style took the form of training camps, public relations campaigns, and information gathering and analysis by his "computer boys," all instruments of central control and coordination. Under Rajiv's party stewardship, one heard or saw little of "service" and "mass contact," Congress's organizational ideologies in the days of Mohandas Gandhi and Jawaharlal Nehru, when a socially connected party meant to change people and society. his leadership.

Rajiv Gandhi's actions as general secretary did not ignore ciety,

by or

ties to so-

but he pursued them through national organizations sponsored allied to

Congress, whose youthful leaders he often chose and

trained. Youth-oriented organizations, such as the

Women's Wing,

the

National Students Union of India, the Seva Dal (Service Organization),

and the Development Center of the Indian Youth Congress were resuscitated and refurbished. Like the Youth Congress in Sanjay's day, these organizations have proved to be the testing and recruiting ground for leading positions in the party and government. Rajiv purged many of Sanjay's followers, particularly those with questionable reputations,

who redeemed themselves by good conduct, abilloyalty. Two Youth Congress leaders became Rajiv

but recognized those ity,

and personal

Gandhi's parliamentary secretaries, and 438 "coordinators" appointed

by the Youth Congress's Development Center provided data for the selection and rejection of Congress candidates for the March 1985 state assembly elections.^* Party elections were mandated by the revised party constitution of 1974, and Rajiv Gandhi pressed hard for such elections in 1982 and 1983. There is little evidence however, to suggest that he then confronted the hitherto-intractable administrative problems and governance issues associated with holding party elections.^^ In August 1986, Rajiv Gandhi again called for reinstituting party elections. His hope was that by forcing state leaders to validate and thus legitimate their claims to support, elections would revitalize a

corrupt and unresponsive party. At the same time, he hoped to use an

POLITICS

152

election to strengthen his

own

following in the party. In a speech to the

December 1985, in Bombay, he told his followers: "We [Congressmen] obey no discipline, no rule, follow no principle of public morality, display no sense of social awareness, show no concern for the public weal. Corruption is not only tolerated

party's centenary celebrations in

but even regarded as the hallmark of leadership." Intraparty elections,

he told an interviewer, would address these evils. They would "expose all the paper tigers. We have not had elections for 13 years; so we have people

who

have

lost their base,

who

don't have any standing. That

exposed."" Whether elections can revitalize the party and retsore institutionalized leadership remains an open question. From the mid-sixties,

will all get

when

the party lost

its

capacity to insure fair procedures, elections

have exacerbated destructive factional struggles for power in the state parties. Some fear elections might reestablish the local and state power brokers who,

when

elections

were held

in the

days before 1972, had

enrolled and mobilized bogus as well as valid primary

members

to in-

dominance of their faction's influence in party affairs, including the outcomes of party elections. Rajiv Gandhi expected elections in August 1986 to return effective and responsible party officials responsive to his leadership, but revolt and resistance by displaced "In-

sure the

dira loyalists" blocked his efforts to hold them.

The suppression

of party leaders

who showed

signs of ambition

and

independent political bases was a mark of Indira Gandhi's deinstitutionalizing style. Rajiv Gandhi's response to intraparty opposition was complicated by the fact that he had to establish

initial

control over the

Congress party leaders have had to strike a balance between coopting challengers and disciplining potential rivals. Like his grand-

party.

father in conflict with

Purushotamdas Tandon

in the early

1950s

and his mother in conflict with Morarji Desai in the 1960s, Rajiv Gandhi in 1986 confronted and attempted to suppress a challenge by factional leaders. His challengers were leaders who had been close to Mrs. Gandhi. They resented their displacement in the party by Rajiv Gandhi's new men. Rajiv's expulsion from the party of former finance minister Pranab Mukherjee and suspension of several other senior members of the party in May 1986 can be read as paralleling the efforts of his grandfather and mother to establish their control of the party rather than as part of the pattern of deinstitutionalization.^^ Rajiv Gandhi has not significantly altered the plebiscitary character

and party leadership, the second aspect of deinstitutionalization. Catapulted into party and national leadership by his mother's assassination, he had litde choice in the 1984 parliamentary

of Indian politics

The Congress Party

153

election but to conduct the

tary election campaigns.

most

The

plebiscitary of India's several plebisci-

election featured a single overarching

concern, the actual and potential consequences of violent conflict be-

tween the Sikh minority and an amorphous but overw^helming and aroused Hindu majority. The choice before the voters was said to be between national unity and national disintegration. Rajiv was perceived by the voters, particularly "Hindu" voters, as the spokesman

and the vehicle of national unity. He benefited from being a Nehru and from being his martyred mother's only surviving son without having to pay, as she would have had to, for the incumbent Congress government's sins of commission and omission. These sins were forgiven or forgotten in the electorate's concern to restore order and hope. In the third deinstitutionalization arena, candidate selection, Rajiv

Gandhi's conduct is harder to interpret than in the arenas of intraparty democracy and leadership legitimation by party or plebiscitary support. On the one hand, his approach to candidate selection in the 1984 parliamentary and the 1985 state assembly elections was reminiscent of Sanjay Gandhi's in the 1980 elections; both operations were centralized, personal, and transformatory. On the other hand, Rajiv Gandhi showed greater concern for objective criteria and procedure.

The party

MP

candidates for the Congress parliamentary

somewhat akin

to the selection of delegates for presidential

selection of is

nominating conventions in the United States: elected delegates to presidential nominating conventions and Congress MPs choose the leader of the party and, potentially, of the government (the presidential candidate and the prime minister). Aspiring Congress prime ministers must command the support of a majority in their party before they can demonstrate to the president of India that they command the confidence of a majority in the lower house of Parliament.

1984 parliamentary election, Rajiv Gandhi, like Sanjay Gandhi prior to the 1980 parliamentary election, was believed to have Prior to the

considered using the nomination process to establish his supporters' ascendency in the parliamentary party. In the event, both acted more cautiously. Uncertain about the prospects of a "wave" that would

sweep Congress candidates to

victory, they feared the constituency

and splits by factional leaders and local power brokers whose nominees were not accommodated. Instead of "replacing" an anticipated 50 percent of 339 sitting MPs, Rajiv Gandhi like his brother in 1980 replaced about 25 percent, a proportion comparable to the "normal" level of attrition in prior elections. Similar caution was evident in the selection of candidates for seats held by opposition parties. Even though the financial aspects of effects of subversion, defection,





154

POLITICS

the election were highly centralized

handedly funded each

campaign material

MP

— the

— the

central party office even-

to the tune of Rs.

300,000 and provided

selection process largely respected estab-

lished local preferences.^^

1980 and even more so in 1984, Congress won decisive parliamentary victories. In subsequent midterm state assembly elections designed to capitalize on the party's national victories, both Sanjay and Rajiv Gandhi carried out the purge and personal faction building exercise they had contemplated but not attempted prior to the parliamentary elections. Having won an unprecedented 79 percent of the seats and 49 percent of the vote in the December poll, Rajiv Gandhi, prior to the March 1985 assembly elections, replaced 40 percent of In

Congress-Fs sitting

MLAs,

whom

were ministers. The severity with which Congress incumbents were eliminated created consternation among party stalwarts and factional leaders. The party cushioned backlash effects in those states most affected by giving "tickets" to sons or younger relatives of purged incumbents,^^ a practice reminiscent of

Mughal

sixty-three of

when sons in Mughal

times,

rajas replaced their fathers

of dissident or obstreperous service

and

at court.

Gandhi's greater commitment to objective criteria and

known

Rajiv

proce-

dures was expressed in a ten-point guideline that addressed deficien-

and constructed a new image: preference was to be given to youth, professionals, and women. ^^ The taint of public and private corruption that plagued the party, a taint that became particularly troublesome for the party in 1984, after the Antulay and Adik scandals, was to be removed by choosing candidates with unblemished records. As "Mr. Clean" and the yuppie leader of India's postindependence generations, Rajiv Gandhi meant to construct a party in his own image. Service in cies

party or party-sponsored organizations,

and propoor

commitment

to secularism

and prospects of success were also to be considered. (The MLAs from assembly segments of MP constituencies that Congress-I failed to carry in 1984 were barred). Given the confidence engendered by the party's unprecedented victory in December 1984, the thrust of the guidelines exercise was more to build an image of the party that matched that of its new leader than to produce precise demographic, ideological, characterological, or policies,

even electoral results. The guideline exercise stands

in contrast to

Sanjay Gandhi's efforts in 1980 to rebuild the party as a personal

fol-

lowing based on loyalty to him and his mother. Rajiv Gandhi's effort to reconstruct the party, while successful nationally in image and institutional terms, proved costly in electoral terms. Compared with the highly successful parliamentary and state

The Congress Party

155

January and June 1980, Congress-I did poorly in March 1985.^^ In December 1984, Congress-I had won 79 percent of the MP seats, but in March 1985 it could win only 57 percent. The voters treated the state assembly elections as opportunities to reward good and punish bad governments in the respective states rather than as an opportunity to heed Rajiv Gandhi's call to reaffirm in assembly performances

in

the state assembly elections the national

mandate he and the Congress-

December. Insofar as the March state assembly elections carried a message for the conduct of national politics, it was to suggest that voters favored the restraints and balance provided by a multiparty federal system. Electing as well as nominating a new breed I

had received

in

was more successful rhetorically than it was electorally. returned incumbent Congressmen in higher proportions

of candidate

The

voters

than they did

new nominees. ^^

March 1985 he and the Congress-I could ride the wave that had carried them to victory in December 1984. The wave had been largely determined by conjuncture, the Rajiv Gandhi lost his gamble that in

voters' response in a national election to Indira Gandhi's assassination

by the violence and threat of disintegration that followed. But the gamble did pay off to an extent. Despite Congress-I's poor showing in seats and votes, the result produced a new generation of state leaders and legislators attuned to Rajiv Gandhi's professional style and managerial outlook. Chief minister selection, like the nomination of MPs and MLAs, was another arena for party deinstitutionalization under Indira and Sanjay Gandhi. Rajiv Gandhi's doctrine and practice after he became prime minister, if not before, seems to have stemmed, and perhaps reversed, deinstitutionalization in this arena too. Indira Gandhi began the practice of ^'nominating" chief ministers in 1972, after she led the split and demoralized party to comeback parliamentary and state assembly victories in 1971 and 1972. "Nomination" had been practiced under the British raj; it was the process used by the viceregal state to choose loyal and usually qualified Indians to fill responsible or representative positions at the center and in the provinces. After Indira Gandhi's great plebiscitary and personal victories, state assemblies with Congress-I majorities asked her, the party leader and prime minister whose family name and personal fame some believed had swept them into office, to designate persons to lead them. Loyalty took precedence over party support; chief ministers served at Mrs. Gandhi's, not the legislature's, pleasure and often her pleasure proved short-lived and arbitrary. Chief ministers in some states were treated as if they were disposable, a practice that in Andhra Pradesh succeeded in alienating and angering a

and

to fear generated

156

POLITICS

and had supported Indira Gandhi in her darkest hour. In just four and a half years, between February 1978 and September 1982, Indira Gandhi had nominated five chief ministers to govern Andhra Pradesh,'*^ treatment that led to Congress-I's defeat in January 1983. In a midterm state assembly election, the state's voters repudiated Congress-I and regained their honor and dignity by handling an overw^helming victory to the Telugu Desam, led by Andhra screen hero, N. T. Rama Rao, who campaigned against the state that

had been

a Congress-I bastion

government's trampling upon "the

The "nomination"

self respect of the

which began

Telugu people.'"*^

1972, reached its apogee after the Sanjay Gandhi— managed state assembly elections in June 1980, when five Sanjay loyalists with little else to recommend of chief ministers,

them were among the

in

eight Congress chief ministers installed. De-

took the form of courtierly politics, the politics of favorites managed from Delhi, which crowded out, if it did not wholly displace, factional and institutionalization with respect to the selection of chief ministers

organizational politics at the state level.

was more than under Indira and

Rajiv Gandhi's handling of the selection of chief ministers respectful of sentiment in the state parties

Sanjay Gandhi.

It is

more

difficult to

say whether the differences are

the product of prudence under difficult circumstances or of a con-

scious

and deliberate

Rajiv Gandhi's role

effort to strengthen the party as

when he was

an

institution.

a party general secretary in toppling

opposition governments in three states (Andhra Pradesh, Kashmir, and Sikkim) did not indicate an understanding of or commitment to the constitutional proprieties of federalism.

when,

as

opportunity to end opposition rule

in

respect for these proprieties

On the other hand, he showed

prime minister, he rejected the Karnataka when Ramakrishna

Karnataka's Janata chief minister, offered his resignation to

Hegde, the governor after Congress-I had decisively carried the state in the December 1984 parliamentary election."*^ The circumstances of the March 1985 assembly elections in ten states were not, in any case, conducive to a Sanjay-like strategy for the selection of chief ministers; instead of replicating its success in the December 1984 parliamentary

had done poorly. Rajiv Gandhi approached the chief minister selection process cautiously. His conduct was reminiscent of the Nehru era when the naelections, the Congress-I

tional leaders

who

command" acted as umpires, and preferences among contending state

staffed the "high

but umpires with opinions

form governments in eight states and one union territory. In five states and in the union territory, Rajiv Gandhi's high command left incumbent chief ministers in office. factions. Congress-I

was

in a position to

The Congress Party

157 It

replaced only three chief ministers

and Rajasthan

— and

their



Madhya

in Bihar,

Pradesh,

replacement by veteran Congressmen with

strong support from their respective state organizational and legis-

was taken by most informed observers as tactical rather than strategic. Whether out of prudence or principle, Rajiv Gandhi did not attempt, as Sanjay Gandhi had, to impose loyal nonentities on intimidated and supine state legislative parties/^ lative parties

On

the other hand, the resignation of Vasantrao Patil

bent chief minister and party boss

in

Maharashtra



— the incum-

tells

a different

story about Rajiv Gandhi's relationship to Congress-I state parties

and

The assembly result in Maharashtra had been very was true of most states. After much soul searching and

chief ministers. close but this

controversy in Delhi and

Bombay about

replacing Vasantrao Patil with

an alternative leader, Vasantrao had become one of the five secondterm chief ministers. But on the occasion of Rajiv Gandhi's uncontested election as party president soon after, when Vasantrao was perceived to challenge Gandhi by calling attention to the party's rule against holding more than one office, his resignation was quickly arranged. This action was read inside and outside the party as a warning

not to interpret Rajiv Gandhi's commitment to decentralization and respect for state party leaders Similarly his replacement of

and organizations

Madhav

more

power

in the

Rajiv

"*"*

Singh Solanki as Gujarat chief

minister, in response to the mishandling of flected

as "weakness."

communal

rioting, re-

the prime minister's judgment than the alignment of

Gujarat state party.

Gandhi began

an elected prime minister by

his career as

treat-

and consideration. Indeed, this was so true that Congress-I chief ministers were heard to complain publicly about the advantages of being an opposition chief minister. Gandhi was even quoted as saying, in August 1985, that should there ing opposition chief ministers with respect

be elections in the troubled Sikh-majority state of Punjab, the people of the state might be best served

ernment, which indeed they did.

if

they returned an Akali Dal gov-

hard to imagine such a thought occurring to Indira or Sanjay Gandhi. The new look in center-state relations was given formal recognition in the summer of 1985 at a governor's conference. After being "advised" by Prime Minister Rajiv Gandhi, the governors repudiated the practice of aiding and abetting "toppling" operations after party splits or defections by giving untested new chief ministers many weeks to muster support before facing the assembly. Henceforth, they agreed, new chief ministers would have It is

to face the assembly to test their majority within

The

result of the governors' conference

two or

was hailed

three days.

as "a conscious

POLITICS

158 effort"

by the prime minister to strengthen party responsibiHty and the

federal system/^

The prime

minister's respect for his fellow politicians extended to

leaders of the national opposition parties as well as to state chief ministers.

As prime

minister, he took

them

into confidence

and sought to

achieve consensual solutions on hitherto-intractable issues such as the

Punjab, Assam, and reservations for "backward

classes."'*^

This cost

him support within Congress among members who believed party interest was not sufficiently protected in these settlements. Rajiv Gandhi's record as a politician is a mixed one. As a party general secretary working in his mother's shadow and even as prime minister in the period between his mother's assassination and Congress-I's unprecedented electoral victory,

his

conduct could not

easily

be dis-

tinguished from the deinstitutionalizing actions of Indira and Sanjay

Gandhi. After leading his party to victory and becoming prime minister in his own right, Rajiv Gandhi's conduct took a different turn. The party remained centralized and subject to its leader's managerial ideology and professional style, but it was less subject than it had been

under Indira Gandhi to arbitrary tests of personal loyalty that dissolve institutional commitment and procedural regularity. Talk of party elections indicated a preference for congressmen once again to seek local party support rather than rely exclusively on the favor of Delhi. Similarly,

the selection of chief ministers, while

it

sometimes reflected the

prime minister's more than the state party's preferences, showed a lighter hand from Delhi. The party under Rajiv Gandhi was not the institutionalized party of the Mohandas Gandhi or Nehru eras, nor was it the party of state bosses in the syndicate era. But collegiality, institutional autonomy, and decentralization seemed to have a better chance than they had had in a decade.

^

Janata's Historic Failure:

A

Competitive Party System Aborts

Since independence

dominated

some

at the center

forty years ago, India's polity

and

in

most

states

had been

by a single party, the Indian

National Congress. Although, in the aggregate, the opposition parties captured more than half the vote in every national election, disunity

among them

prevented them from displacing Congress as the national

governing party. Yet, in 1967 and even more so in 1977 (when they united in the Janata party), the opposition parties very nearly converted the elections of those years into critical elections that vs^ould

have reconstituted India's political universe. In

1967, an expedient "Grand Alliance" of national and regional

parties for the ity

when

first

time came close to winning a parliamentary major-

Congress's share of votes and seats plummeted from 45 to 40

and from 73 to 54 percent, respectively. As Stanley Kochanek noted, "The 1967 General Election marked the beginning of a transformation of the Indian political system from a dominant one-party system to a multi-party system." For Eric da Costa, then India's leading interpreter of public opinion and electoral behavior, the election "was the beginning of a break with the past," because most demographic and social groups were "rewriting their basic loyalties."^ Congress fared even worse in the 1967 state assembly elections, when its proportion of seats fell from 60 to 49 percent and opposition parties formed governments initially in six and later in eight of the then sixteen large states. In 1977, Janata's victories in both parliamentary and state assembly elections^ seemed to mark the end of the dominant-party system. Congress's thirty-year hegemony over India's national government and federal system was broken when Janata governments took office in Delhi and in nine of seventeen large states. Janata's successes and Congress's reduced but still substantial strength had put two fairly equal national parties at the center of the party system. Together, with about 77 percent of seats and votes, they appeared to constitute a competitive twoparty system. In the event, Janata failed to capitalize

on

its

historic opportunity.

Janata's political performance after 1977, like the ineffective policy

and governmental performance of opposition coalition governments in northern states between 1967 and 1972, diminished public confidence 159

POLITICS

160

in the national

opposition parties' capacity to govern. Between 1977

and 1979, Janata

failed to establish that

it

could be a meaningful

native to Congress as a governing party at the center.

nature of Janata's failure has to Indira Gandhi,

shamed and

alter-

The extent and

why

be appreciated to understand

was able in 1980 to power and an apparent resto-

discredited in 1977,

lead Congress to a triumphant return to

ration of the dominant-party system. Janata's failure to remain united

an alternative governing party also helps to account for the extraordinarily poor showing of the national opposition parties in the 1984 parliamentary election and the progres-

or to establish

its

credibility as

sive bifurcation of the party

which

is

system into national and regional arenas,

discussed in the next chapter.

Janata's unsuccessful challenge to Congress party

hegemony

in a

dominant-party system had consequences for the Indian state. Party alternation can encourage nonpartisan use of state institutions and personnel. The long-term interests of alternating governing parties provide each with good reasons to observe the golden rule of "do unto

you would have done unto you." Yet, the temptation to use the powers of incumbency to settle old scores and to win the next election pulls governing parties in the opposite direction. The Congress-I's abuse of power under the emergency regime gave the Janata government a historic opportunity to "restore democracy" and nonpartisanship in the use of public authority and resources. It restored the first,

others as

but

its

standards with respect to the second were hard to distinguish

from those of the Congress-I. Janata's pursuit of decentralization in politics, administration, public

some instances the effects of Congress-I's centralizing proclivities. The states of the federal system were accorded the recognition they once had had in finance,

and economic

activity arrested

and countered

in

and implementation. Since Congress-I's return to power in 1980, the one issue that all opposition parties national and can agree on is to conregional. Communist and non-Communist tinue the restoration of a viable and vigorous federal system that Janata began. In retrospect, although Janata could have done more to policy formulation





retore the nonpartisan India,

its

legacy

is

and

federal character of the liberal state in

not inconsiderable: the restoration of democracy

and the resuscitation of federalism.

The Opposition Challenge and To comprehend

why

the Promise of a Critical Election

the political universe of the 1980s,

the election of

1977 was not ultimately

we need

to

know

a critical election.^

The

161

Janata's Historic Failure

theory of critical elections has been used to explain transformatory

American and British politics. Because they are constitutive, critical elections preempt and, in a sense, substitute for revolution or a change in regime by enacting or establishing a new ordering

changes

in

of the political universe.

Major

shifts in voter preferences, party vote

shares, and/or turnout express interrelated changes in political ide-

ology, in the formation or reorientation of interest groups, ties,

or classes, and in the composition and

Such changes

in turn affect the party

ing, or reorienting specific parties

level of

communi-

voter participation.

system by adding, subtract-

and reshaping the pattern of party

competition.

Four indicators suggested that 1977 might be a critical election: (1) the change in party vote shares, in comparison with previous vote swings of less than 4 percent, went well beyond any previous election; Congress's share of the parliamentary vote dropped by 9 percent, from

43 to 34 percent (see chapter 4, formed and had contested and so that for the

first

a second national party

was

the sixth parliamentary election,

time a party other than Congress governed the coun-

try; (3) for the first time, all

fig. 3), (2)

won

national parties competed effectively in almost

(sixteen of seventeen) large states;

and

(4) the

one-party-dominant

system was displaced by a competitive two-party-plus system.

developments except the third were prefigured in the 1967 general elections, the last in which the parliamentary and the state assembly elections were linked (conducted simultaneously). With the significant exception of the Jan Sangh, the parties that came together in 1977 to form the Janata party formed an alliance in 1967 All of these

won

and overshadowed Congress in the state assembly elections. Between the 1962 and 1967 elections. Congress's share of parliamentary and state assembly votes declined from 45 to 40 percent and from 44 to 40 percent, respectively (see chapter 4, fig. 3); its share of parliamentary and state assembly seats decreased from 73 to 55 percent and from 60 to 49 percent (see chapter 4, fig. 2), and its control of the then sixteen large state governments was reduced from fourteen to eight. Congress's loss of support and the marked (5 percent) increase in turnout in 1967 (see fig. 4) reflected voter dissatisfaction with poor economic and military performance in the preceding two years. The depressing economic consequences of two consecutive bad monsoons, disappointment with the outcome of the 1965 war with Pakistan, and the unsuccessful devaluation of June 1966 were blamed on the Congress government. But Congress losses and opposition gains also reflected the electoral consequences of a more cohesive opposition. The "Grand Alliance" succeeded modestly in concentrating the majorthat very nearly

the parliamentary election

"^

POLITICS

162

64

64-

/

61

60

60U> CO

c 0) o

56-

V

52

/se



y

^67

55

/

1

o.

48

y

As

,



%^

3 o c 3

47

44 40

"



52

'57

'62

'67

'71

'77

'80

'84

Elections by Year

Voter turnout for parliamentary elections. Data through 1980 are from Election Commission reports. The turnout figure for 1984 is from an analysis by the Press Trust of India and the Computer Maintenance Corporation, New Delhi [India Abroad, Janu-

Fig. 4.

ary 18, 1985).

non-Congress vote: except for the second and eighth parUamentary elections in 1957 and 1984, when it was 52 and 51 percent, respectively, the non-Congress vote has exceeded SS percent in six of eight parliamentary elections. In the fourth election in 1967, the nonCongress electoral majority was for the first time sufficiently consoliity

dated to threaten Congress's parliamentary majority. In 1977, with the addition of the Jan Sangh,

an expanded version

1967 "Grand Alliance" united to form a party, the Janata. The authoritarian emergency regime had generated widespread antiof the

Congress sentiment, particularly in the Hindi Heartland states. In the election, Janata won 43 percent of the vote and SS percent of the seats; Congress-I, 34 and 28 percent. Again, as in 1967, voter turnout

was

60 percent, 5 percent above 1971 (fig. 4). For the first time, independent India was governed by a non-Congress government. In the state assembly elections that followed in June 1977 and February 1978, high, at

Janata gained control of nine of the seventeen large state governments.

These changes suggested that 1977 had been a

critical election.

But

the course of events over the next three years, including the disintegra-

and dramatic reversal of Congress fortunes in the January 1980 midterm parliamentary poll, belied the possibility. So too did Congress-Fs electoral victory in January 1984, when Rajiv Gandhi led the party to its most decisive parliamentary victory.

tion of Janata

163

Janata's Historic Failure

Why did

the

cal election?

1977

One

election

reason

is

fail

to realize

its

that the electoral

promise of being a

criti-

outcome of 1977 was

less

a victory for the Janata party's leadership, ideology, or policies than

it

emergency regime. The electorate was had said no to the Indira and Sanjay Gandhi Congress, but at best it had said "perhaps" to that as-yet-unknown entity, the Janata party. To consolidate its incidental gains, it had to convert the antiemergency vote into positive commitments by varied sectors of the electorate. To meet this challenge, Janata had to resolve the numerous strains inhera protest vote against Congress's

ent in

its

heterogeneous origins.

Janata's Historic Opportunity: Alternating-Party

Our account of Janata 's history, a study of

victory in the a

new

collapse

is

in part

departure.

an exercise

what might have been and

March 1977 parliamentary It

Government

its

in counterfactual

consequences. Janata's

election

had the makings of

created a historic alternative to India's Congress-

dominated nationalist and postindependence history. The victory not only transformed the party system but also opened the way to new departures in ideology and policy. The Janata government formulated and attempted to implement and institutionalize a neo-Gandhian alternative to the centralized state and industrially oriented growth strategy associated with Congress rule. It took seriously Mohandas Gandhi's concern to decentralize the state and the economy. It talked about and groped to find technologies that served rather than mastered their users and that enhanced workers' productivity rather than displaced them with machines. The federal system and local and village administrations were rejuvenated. State decentralization

was meant

would make public authority more

accessible to those

and independent cultivators were helped. Government invested in programs that created employment and generated income by relying on labor-intensive technology and the distribution of productive assets to those without it

to serve. Small-scale craft producers

them. For those without work or assets,

it

used food "surpluses" in

"food for work" programs that improved the rural infrastructure. By putting labor output rather than capital output at the center of its development strategy, it believed itself more able to redistribute personal income as well as increase national income. The state and the economy were to be reshaped to a human scale capable of sustaining community and meeting basic needs. The Janata government's neo-Gandhian ideology and programs were

POLITICS

164

not "new" or even novel.

had taken a minor ideological and programmatic theme from Congress's consensual score and made it a major one. Change under Janata rule, like change under Congress rule, proceeded at the margins of investment and programs. When Indira Gandhi's Congress-I government retuned to pov^er in 1980, it continued many of the Janata initiatives under different labels and someIt

w^hat modified policy rhetoric,

economic

difficulties

it

all

the while protesting that whatever

faced were not of

its

own

doing but had

re-

from the Janata government's mismanagement of the economy. At the same time, 1980 marked something of a turning point in Congress thinking with respect to technology. The capital goods phase of economic development in the public sector had succeeded in making the industrial economy relatively self-reliant if not efficient and profitable; the problem was how to arrest and reverse deteriorasulted instead

tion of the capital-output ratio in the public sector, not

more

in its

"smokestack"

how

to invest

industries.

In 1980, the new Congress-I government began to face questions with respect to the future course of political and economic develop-

ment. Did the future

lie

with a viable federal system, in which the

government had the authority and resources to decide and to act independently, or with centralization, a Delhi-dominated political system in which the states and local units of government and administration were primarily agents of the center? Did the future course of economic development lie with agriculture-led, employmentoriented, labor-intensive, and decentralized "appropriate" technology or with industry-led, growth-oriented, capital-intensive, and centralized advanced technology? The first course in each case would continue Janata's neo-Gandhian policy orientation; the second would reassert Indira Gandhi's centralism and take India's economic development on a new course, different from that of both the Nehru and the Janata eras. From 1980, Indira and Sanjay Gandhi began vaguely to consider giving high technology a more central place in India's planned development, and Rajiv Gandhi considered the same thing in more informed and concrete ways after his entry to politics. Such an emphasis on high technology would run counter to Congress's Gandhian heritage and to Janata's neo-Gandhian revival. The Janata era moved the question of "appropriate" technology and the related question of economic and governmental decentralization to a prominent place on the country's public agenda. Its ideas, policies, and performance had taken neo-Gandhianism from the drawing room to the drawing boards in ways that made it a viable option for the states

and

country.^

local

165

Janata 's Historic Failure

The Janata's

ideological

and policy

alternatives provided a statement

of national goals that challenged the tarnished ticulated with so

Nehru and

much

and decaying image

ar-

conviction and persuasiveness by Jaw^aharlal

C. Mahalanobis in the second and third five-year plans: heavy industry in the public sector was to occupy the commanding P.

heights of the

economy and

economy out of poverty into was not this statement that domi-

lead the

abundance and social justice. But it nated the outcome. The Janata vision

fell

victim to the failure and in-

two men who succeeded in becoming prime ministers, Morarji Desai and Charan Singh. Their ambition and rivalry proved more powerful than the historic circumstances of Janata's founding and the cohesion of its neo-Gandhian commitment. Why exactly was Janata unable to capitalize on its 1977 election victory? One reason was the conflicting historical legacies of the parties and fractions that constituted the fledgling party. The leaders of the erstwhile and subsequently reconstituted parties were old-time nationalists. Each had reason to believe that his claim to leadership of the new party was as good as or better than those of his rivals. The parties and fractions had become accustomed to functioning separately from each other and had adjusted their expectations to garnering the small rewards of permanent opposition. A second reason was that the party leadership avoided the mechanisms of party democracy elections that would have required bargaining and compromise among components. They resorted instead to decision making by respected geronadequacies of

its

leaders, particularly the



tocrats. Third, factional leaders resisted the integration of the func-

tional organizations active base of the

— such

as

component

youth and labor parties. Finally,

— that constituted the

it is

the failures of the party without taking account of

hard to understand

human

nature.

Am-

and folly were spectacularly on display for three years. Ashis Nandy was probably right to conclude that with such a display of intraparty matsyanyaya (the state of nature in the Indian classical tradition, in which big fishes eat little ones and each other), it was not surprising that, in 1980, Indians were prepared to reelect the biggest shark of all to overawe the others.^ Jayaprakash Narayan (popularly known as "JP") stood at the center of Janata's short-lived effort to reconstruct a Gandhian alternative compatible with a modern economy and state. He had come to his neo-Gandhian socialism and anachist partyless democracy via his sojourn in the United States as a casual agricultural laborer. Communist, and sometime postgraduate student; the democratic socialism of the Nehru Congress's labor department; his 1947 personal commitment bition, pride, hypocrisy,

POLITICS

166

to Gandhi's leadership

and world view; and

his coleadership,

with

Vinoba Bhave, of the ultimately sterile Bhoodan (Land Gift) movement to create a more equal society by voluntaristic means/ By 1974, JP appeared to be a spent force in Indian public life. Nehru had hoped that someday he would become India's prime minister, but that hope had proved illusory. His Gandhian values led JP to try to transform Indian society by moral rather than institutional means. He began his last and most effective effort to

transform Indian society in 1974, following the

Gandhi government's ruthless suppression of a nationwide workers' strike and growing authoritarian measures and actions. He called for "total revolution." However hyperbolic its language, the JP movement aimed first to save and then to deepen democracy by transforming moral standards and practices. JP held no position in the Janata government, in part because he was sick and dying, in part because, Hke Mohandas Gandhi, he was reluctant to hold office. But he did help Indira

to "settle" tral

who

should lead the party by invoking the politically neu-

doctrine of "seniority."

Two

of the triumvirate

who became Janata's

leaders, Morarji Desai

and Charan Singh, were professed Gandhians, the first a self-professed "ascetic" oriented to the urban business classes, the second India's most important agrarian and spokesman for independent cultivators. The third, Jagjivan Ram, had built his durable and extended career as a Congress minister on being of but not exclusively for the scheduled castes (as India's ex-untouchables are called in official parlance). His

nonideological pragmatism, tactical

skill,

and

identification with the

disadvantaged poor enabled him to become a credible leader of Janata's Gandhian renaissance. The Jan Sangh fraction too declared itself to be deeply committed to JP's interpretation of Mohandas Gandhi's ideas

component of the new party included many doctrinal orientations and organizational legacies. Not least among them was Gandhian socialism, an orientation that trade union socialists (e.g., George Fernandes) and "Sorelian" Lohia socialand

practice.

The appreciable

socialist

not Popular Front socialists (e.g., Madhu Limaye) could appreciate and support because of the redistributional thrust of its employment-oriented growth strategy and its concern for

ists

(e.g..

Raj Narain)

if

social justice.

mediated by JP's, Morarji Desai's, and Charan Singh's rendering of them, provided the ideological and policy framework of the new party, but its more proximate political orien-

Mohandas Gandhi's

ideas, as

were shaped by the renewed opportunity to translate "antiCongressism" into power and office. Unlike in their almost successful

tations

167

Janata's Historic Failure

effort in

1967 and abortive

1977 united

owed

in

1971, the "opposition" parties in one party rather than in a makeshift alHance. Their effort in

Mrs. Gandhi's emergency regime. She revitalized anti-Congressism by putting her opponents in jail, tearing up the rule book for competitive politics, and terrorizing ordinary citizens. Party leaders of all stripes, RSS and Communist cadres, Muslim unity

a great deal to

and Hindu pandits w^ere arrested or went underground. Adversaries and strangers found they shared a common danger and common enemy. The immediate need to fight for survival and the possibility of at last being able to use the anti-Congress vote to gain power and office divines

five non-Communist parties to respond to JP's appeal to So powerful was the magnet of anti-Congressism created by the Gandhi government's emergency excesses and destruction of freedom that the CPI broke its long-standing Congress alliance and the Communist party of India-Marxist (CPI-M) joined Janata in an antiCongress electoral front.

helped the unite.

The

became

five parties that

fractions in Janata

were a diverse

often in conflict with each other as with Congress.

lot, as

The question for March 1977

Indian history raised by the events of January through

was whether the rivalries to build a

parties joined in Janata could transcend their past

new

the circumstances of

future.

its

To do so required

a party that could use

origin to transcend deep-seated differences

over ideology and interest and reconcile personal ambitions in order

outcome was and Ram all of whom had lived beyond the biblical allotment of three score years and ten proved incapable of distinguishing adherence to principle and the collective good from pursuit of the main chance. The party's electoral failure in 1980 resulted as much from self-destruction as from Mrs. Gandhi's remarkable comeback. In 1980 as in 1977, the voters rejected bad government. Janata victories in the March and June 1977 parliamentary and state to govern effectively for five years. In the event, the

tragicomic.

The

principal protagonists, Desai, Singh,





assembly elections transformed the party's objective circumstances.

The common enemy was defeated and governing party responsible for

was now a the country's welfare and security. The discredited. Janata

election established the relative standing of the former parties that as-

pired to

become

a national party: Jan Sangh, led by A. B. Vajpayee, ex-

had ninety seats (31 percent); Bharatiya Lok Dal (BLD) led by Charan Singh, home minister, had fifty-five (19 percent); the socialists, led by George Fernandes, industries minister, had fifty-one (17 percent); Congress for Democracy, led by Jagjivan Ram, defense minister, had twenty-eight (10 percent); and dissident Conternal affairs minister,

POLITICS

168

gressmen (who had broken with Mrs. Gandhi prior to or during the emergency), led by Chandra Shekhar, party president, and Mohan Dharia, commerce minister, had six (2 percent). Contradictions abounded. Was the party to be confessional like its largest party fraction, the Jan Sangh, and promote the values and interests of the

tion

and pursue

Hindu community? Or class politics?

Was

the

secular like

new

its

socialist frac-

party to follow the social-

and conflictual strategy, support Congress-O's Gandhian commitment to consensual values and practice, or accept the Jan Sangh 's Hindu justifications of cosmic inequality and dharmic social harmony? Was the party to rely on the paternalism and noblesse oblige of the upper (twice-born) castes who led the Congress-O and Jan Sangh fractions to mobilize mass support vertically, or should it rely on horizontal mobilization of cultivator castes, the scheduled castes (untouchables), and wage workers? Should the party speak for the agrarian interests of rural producers or the industrial and trading interests of urban capitalists and labor aristocrats, lines of cleavage that tended to divide the BLD and the Congress for Democracy from the Congress-O and Jan Sangh and to separate Lohia and Gandhian socialists from trade union socialists? Within India's massive agricultural sector, should the party help the poor but less productive tenants and laborers by land redistribution, tenancy reform, and higher wages? Or should it help relatively prosperous but more productive bullock capitalists and large landholders by high farm prices and low input ists'

redistributionist

costs?

The contradictions

that these cleavages created for the Janata were

some measure they

and national centrist parties most of all. Congress used to be called a boa constrictor because of its capacity to swallow anything. The strain on the Janata was severe because it had become overnight not only a national centrist party but also India's majority and governing party.

not

A

its

exclusive concern; in

affect all parties,

necessary condition for remaining the majority national centrist

party was the capacity to create political formulas and bargains that reconciled or papered over

its

cleavages. Congress's long tenure as the

majority national centrist party was in part a measure of

its

capacity to

handle such contradictions. Compared with Congress, with its nationalist heritage and organizational legacy, Janata was disadvantaged by

and fragmented circumstances of its origin. The party began its effort to consolidate diverse factions with two main settlements, one in March 1977 on the question of national leadership and one in June on control of state governments. Both were resolved informally, behind the scenes, and "consensually," in the hope

the negative

169

Janata 's Historic Failure

of avoiding conflicts

ing personalities

among

the party's diverse fractions

and of strengthening the

and contend-

party's capacity to deal with

difficult decisions.**

To avoid an immediate and

among

potentially destructive test of strength

the three aspirants for prime minister

Singh, and Jagjivan

Ram — the

— Morarji Desai, Charan

party turned to two old Gandhians,

Jayaprakash Narayan and Acharya Kripalani,

for a decision. Their

choice of Desai as prime minister (and of his younger and

more

leftist

Congress dissident colleague Chandra Shekhar as party president) was legitimated by JP's charismatic laying on of hands and by Desai's seniority. Personal enmity and the conflicting status and economic interests of their support bases had kept Charan Singh and Ram from supporting each other's ambition to be prime minister. In the face of the Jan Sangh fraction's preference for Ram, Charan Singh wrote to JP in support of Desai,

whom

he regarded as the lesser evil. These considerations and developments sustained the plausibility of JP's choice. It

was

a gerontocratic decision in favor of a candidate twice rejected

the Congress parliamentary party.

From

the beginning, the choice of

Desai contradicted the fresh possibilities inherent

and

its

potential to be a

new

by

in

Janata doctrine

national alternative.^

The choice was not achieved by

the usual democratic or formal pro-

cesses within the Janata parliamentary party that tested the support of

the contending candidates. While evading such procedures saved the

party from starting

its

rule with a highly acrimonious controversy,

it

merely postponed the moment of reckoning."^ This evasion came to haunt the party when, in response to Charan Singh's efforts to discredit and displace Desai, Charan Singh and Chandra Shekhar endeavored to establish and broaden their support in the parliamentary, state assembly, and organizational wings of the party.

The second

settlement, after the June

1977

state

assembly elections,

from a tacit bargain between the party's two largest fractions, and the BLD, who divided the seven state governments and Delhi (a union territory) in which the party had run." As a result, Madhya Pradesh, Rajasthan, Himachal Pradesh, and Delhi were led by erstwhile Jan Sangh chief ministers or their equivalent and India's two largest states, Uttar Pradesh and Bihar, as well as Haryana and Orissa, were led by former BLD chief ministers. The socialist (including the Congress-O's former socialist Asoka Mehta) and BLD fractions had the major voice in setting the party's policy agenda. It was expressed in the party's manifesto ("Both Bread and Liberty: A Gandhian Alternative") and in the economic and industrial policy statements issued after Janata had taken charge of the resulted

the Jan Sangh

POLITICS

170

government. The settlement

among Janata's components

also included

and in the states. At the state and national levels, the initial settlements would have boded well if all the actors involved had made them in good faith and were prepared to abide by them. At the level of party organization, however, they boded less well. While the constituent parties dissolved themselves, the youth and student organizations attached to component organizations did not.^^ The most developed cadre organization associated with any of the predecessor parties, the RSS,^^ remained independent, a source of contention and ultimately the ostensible cause of the three splits that disintegrated Janata. In the state assembly elections that followed soon after the March 1977 parliamentary election, partisan fractions and distribution of ministerial posts at the center

individuals raised their

own

funds in disregard of efforts to create

Most fundamentally,

was not able, by organizational election an the time of the 1980 election, to conduct that might have obliged candidates to bargain for cross-fractional support. Fear of Jan Sangh/RSS ascendancy inhibited other fractions from agreeing to a contest and led ultimately to the splits of July 1979 and a

campaign

chest.*"*

the party

February 1980 and the Jan Sangh "expulsion" in April 1980.*^ Although the former Jan Sangh, with 30 percent of Janata's parlia-

mentary

was the

seats,

largest fraction in the

aspirant for prime minister, held fewer major

new

party,

had no

it

ministerial portfolios

than Congress-O, the BLD, or the socialists, controlled fewer and smaller state governments than the BLD, was weakly represented at the top echelons of the party's organizational wing, and had less influence on party policy than any other fraction.*^ The gradual effort by the Jan

response to Charan Singh's provocations, to correct this underrepresentation by strengthening its position in Janata-governed

Sangh, often states

in

and supporting Morarji Desai more than Charan Singh was

a

significant element in upsetting the fragile settlements of 1977. It

is

say whether the erstwhile Jan Sangh 's

difficult to

was whether most restraint

initial self

a matter of conviction, prudence, or tactics of

its

leaders

and

activists, quite

apart from

— that

its

is,

support-

were a new breed transformed into committed supporters of Janata's leadership and policy by the suffering and fraternity of the emergency and the imperatives of governmental responsibility, whether they were trimmers prepared to adjust their ideological goals and political aspirations for the sake of party harmony, or whether behind their Janata masks lay the faces of RSS communalists who sought to impose at the propitious moment a Hindu nation and a Hindu state on a vulnerable

ers,

and unsuspecting

India.

That each view

is

partially true helps explain

171

Janata 's Historic Failure

complex

Sangh fraction played in holding the Janata together during Charan Singh and Desai's struggle over the prime ministership and in occasioning its ultimate disintegration. the

role the Jan

Beginning with a relatively peaceful settlement with the BLD, which brought out the Jan Sangh 's capacity for secular alliances, the Jan

Sangh fraction migrated gradually toward Desai, whose sympathy and support for "Hindu" cultural policies it found attractive.'^ It ended up, as it had begun in early 1977, in an alliance with Jagjivan Ram in his unsuccessful 1979 and 1980 parliamentary and electoral bids to become India's first untouchable prime minister. Within a few months of the momentous March 1977 parliamentary election, political events began to undermine the conditions on which Janata 's precarious equilibrium depended. Mrs. Gandhi surprised the Janata and political observers when Congress won an early by-election in Azamgarh, Uttar Pradesh, and she was able to make political capital out of atrocities committed against Harijans in Belchhi, Bihar. Uttar Pradesh and Bihar are India's most populous states. Their large scheduled caste and Muslim minorities had turned on Congress in March 1977, and with their help Janata had swept all 139 parliamentary seats in the two states with unprecedented and often overwhelming majorities. Mrs. Gandhi had launched an energetic offensive to recapture the minorities. Azamgarh and Belchhi signalled that Indira Gandhi's abuses of power had not, as Richard Nixon's had under comparable circumstances in the United States, so discredited her that she was no longer a force to be reckoned with. In June,

when

voters in nine states

assemblies, Janata

won

went

to the polls to elect state

reassuring majorities in seven. But turnout

was 40 from 60 percent), as was Janata 's proportion of the vote (down 10 to 20 percent in most states) '* providing clear signals that the electorate in March had voted against the emergency more than it had for Janata and that Janata had to work radically reduced since

hard to hold

its

March (down

to

gains.

January 1978, the Congress split again over the question of Mrs. Gandhi's continued leadership, as the newly formed Congress-I (for In

Indira)

made

a strong

showing

elections in February 1978.

It

in a

won

second round of

state

assembly

large absolute majorities of seats in

Andhra Pradesh and Karnataka and finished a close third to Janata and Congress in Maharashtra. The results confirmed what had been feared by Janata leaders; that Mrs. Gandhi had managed to overcome the pariah status engendered by her authoritarian regime and was again a contender for national leadership. These fears were confirmed

on November

8,

when

1978, she turned back a massive Janata effort to

POLITICS

172

prevent her return to Parliament in a by-election by winning the Chikmagalur (Karnataka) seat. Such storm warnings should have alerted Janata that a positive political its

restoration of

meant

to

performance had to accompany

democracy and imaginative policy

initiatives

if

it

compete with the Gandhi-led Congress-I, but the warnings

were ignored.

Policy Performance versus Political Performances: Politics Fails

had more to do with its political than with its policy performance. The paradox of the Janata years was that its commendable policy performance in terms of ideas, programs, and economic indicators was obscured and then negated by the demeaning political dramas enacted by its leaders. Like political leaders elsewhere, India's leaders are "on stage" before the voting public, not just for television screen and the front page but also for the local gossip networks.

Janata's historic failure





prime minister, as party or opposition leader are defined institutionally and culturally, but their words and actions, their style and idiom, are of their own making. Within limits, political leaders define themselves through political drama. Roles are provided but

Their roles

scripts

and

as

plots are not. Unlike theater audiences, political audiences

do not suspend

disbelief; politics,

not the play,

is

the thing. In

democ-

and rewards of political drama are performances. As measured by economic

racies such as India, the resolutions

voters'

judgments of

political

indicators, the Janata government's policy performance, at least until

Charan Singh's budget of March 1979, compared favorably with the best the country had known since independence. Janata's restoration of democracy and constitutional government was approved if not politically rewarded. It was its leaders' political performance that proved the party's undoing.

dramas began in March 1978, just a year after Janata assumed office, when Charan Singh launched his efforts to displace Prime Minister Morarji Desai. Soon they encompassed Jagjivan Ram and ended in early 1980 with all three leaders discredited and the party in shambles. The political drama's scenes, sometimes played separately, sometimes together, featured personal, political, and institutional themes. Family members, particularly sons, were used to discredit or embarrass rivals; the March and June political settlements about national leadership and control of state governments, were violated, first surreptitiously, then openly, to promote frac-

The demeaning

political

tional interests; significant conventions that facilitate parliamentary

173

Janata's Historic Failure

government, such as collective cabinet responsibility, were also violated; and the search for a suitable institutional and legal response to the emergency regime was used as the occasion to gain personal and

Charan Singh, the advocate of strong measures to punish Mrs. Gandhi, sought her support to become prime minister, only to be outwitted and deposed by her. There was a fatally predetermined quality about the heedlessness with which two stubborn old men, Charan Singh and Morarji Desai, sought to ruin each other even as their common enemy was gaining

partisan advantage. In the end,

support. In the process of degrading each other, Janata's leaders de-

graded themselves; Charan Singh's not implausible attacks on Prime Minister Desai via the conduct of Desai's 55-year-old businessman son, Kanti, discredited

Charan Singh because he launched them from

and with the obvious goal of capturing his rival's seat. Desai's moralistic strictures on Charan Singh's violations of cabinet responsibility and the inappropriate conduct of Charan Singh's relatives squared ill with his tolerance of Kanti Desai's behavior and Janata's condemnation of Sanjay Gandhi's improprieties.'^ The political dramas were often full of pathos and sometimes absurd: Charan Singh displayed self-pity and tears during an interview soon after he was removed from the cabinet; Raj Narain sometime minister, Charan Singh's stalking horse, buffoon, and inadvertent pracinside the cabinet



titioner of guerrilla theater

— invented

a purity ritual for the party

by pouring holy Ganges water on himself near Mohandas Gandhi's samedhi (death memorial) and rubbing rose attar on unwilling diplomats summoned to benefit from his views; Desai practiced "urine therapy" (the drinking of one's tion, to the delight of the

own

urine) while preaching prohibi-

cartoon industry; Charan Singh and Mrs.

Gandhi exchanged bouquets and birthday

greetings while contemplat-

ing each other's destruction.

Charan Singh's first open challenge to Desai's leadership took the form of a letter to him, soon leaked to the press, reviving charges that Kanti Desai, the prime minister's son and personal aid, had used his father's position

charge

improperly or

illegally to further his

made more damaging by Janata's

art of attacking rival leaders via their sons official of the

interests, a

better-founded and more

rious criticisms of Sanjay Gandhi's improprieties.^"

August 1978, when an

own

and

A new

relatives

low

se-

in the

was reached

in

Kisan Sammelan, a farmers' orga-

was implicated in airing a sensational sex scandal involving Jagjivan Ram's son, Suresh. The son told the press that he and a woman companion had been kidnapped by supporters of Charan Singh and forced to pose for photographs in "comnization closely identified with Singh,

POLITICS

174

promising postures." The salacious pictures were circulated among eager members of Parliament by Raj Narain, then Charan Singh's close associate and cabinet colleague, and they later appeared in national magazines. The presumed object of this unsavory exercise was to make sure that if Charan Singh succeeded in ousting Desai, Ram would be a discredited alternative.

Soon

after the

second round of

state

assembly elections in February

1978, Raj Narain attacked Chandra Shekhar, the Janata party president, for his management of party affairs, particularly the selection of

Andhra Pradesh and Karnataka, where Janata had fared badly.^^ On April 21, Chandra Shekhar offered to resign, but Desai refused the offer. Instead, he took a hard line toward Charan Singh, for whom Raj Narain spoke, warning that persons, "howsoever big and important," who criticized their colleagues in public would expose themselves to disciplinary action,^^ including expulsion from cabinet and party. Charan Singh, who suffered a heart attack three days after Desai's reprimand and warning, responded by resigning on April from the party's national executive and parliamentary board. The conflict at the top, which challenged the March 1977 settlement about national government and party leadership, had a parallel state dimension. From his sickbed, Charan Singh alleged that "a section of the leadership" was encouraging efforts to replace the erstwhile BLD chief ministers of Haryana and Uttar Pradesh. These efforts reflected candidates in

Desai's attempt to secure his uncontested selection as party leader

widening

his

support

in the

parliamentary and

by

state assembly parties."

undermine the BLD fraction's hold on state governments coincided with and complemented the efforts of the Jan Sangh Desai's efforts to

to

make

its

influence within the party as great as

its

share of seats.

The

Jan Sangh 's offensive in turn jeopardized its national and state relationships with Charan Singh's BLD. Desai's Hindu cultural revivalism, noblesse oblige high-caste attitudes, and economic conservatism provided the political and ideological conditions for an evolving rapport ^"^

between Desai and like-minded members of the Jan Sangh fraction. Desai's cultural policies strongly appealed to the Jan Sangh fraction but alarmed the socialists, who, in response, created the secularism issue on which the power struggle in the party would be fought.

The

governments fueled the growing crisis at the top, but the proximate and principled cause of the first rupture between Desai and Charan Singh was the government's incipient battle for control of state

power and illegal acts during the emergency and earlier. The country was confronted with a situation not unlike that in the United States in 1974, when the House policy response to Mrs. Gandhi's abuse of

1

75

Janata's Historic Failure

impeachment proceedings against President Nixon led to his resignation. Was he to be prosecuted or pardoned? The Shah Commission had produced incriminating evidence comparable to that available against Richard Nixon;^'' w^ere Mrs. Gandhi and her associates to be prosecuted? If so, when and how?^^ Desai was forgiving, Charan Singh vindictive. ^^ Charan Singh interof Representatives's

preted Desai's professed concern for correct procedure as a cover for inaction. Desai believed that a

home

accuses the government of which he

is

who

minister (Charan Singh) a senior

member with

failure

on matters under his own charge had ulterior motives. On June 28, Charan Singh, circumventing the usual rule of cabinet unity and patently challenging the prime minister, called for Mrs. Gandhi's immediate arrest.^*^ The next day the cabinet, responding to the challenge to its collective responsibility, endorsed Desai's call for Charan Singh and Raj Narain to resign immediately. On June 30, they were gone. During the second half of 1978, the Desai government, under pressure from new circumstances, responded to the absent Singh's charge of impotence by supporting action against Mrs. Gandhi. In November, Mrs. Gandhi returned to Parliament by decisively winning the byelection at Chikmagalur (Karnataka). No sooner had she taken her seat (on November 20) and been elected chairman of the Congress-I parliamentary party than the privileges committee of the Lok Sabha tabled a report holding Mrs. Gandhi and several assistants guilty of breach of privilege and contempt of the House. After a heated debate in which Mrs. Gandhi accused the Janata government of converting the house into a "medieval star chamber," Desai's motion calling for Mrs. Gandhi's expulsion and imprisonment until the prorogation of the session six days hence carried 279 to 138. The farce of imprisonment that followed confirmed Charan Singh's fear that the public perceived the Janata government as "impotent." ^^ Leading members of the Janata government quickly began to create suitable conditions for Charan Singh's return to the cabinet. ^^ The conciliatory efforts bore fruit. On January 24, 1979, Charan Singh rejoined the Janata cabinet as home minister, but without his sometime alter ego. Raj Narain, and accepted equal status as deputy prime minister with his archrival, Jagjivan Ram. Though the Jan Sangh fraction had backed Desai's ouster of Charan Singh in July 1978, it now played the role of mediator in the reconciliation of the two antagonists. But this was the last time it was able to keep the party in equilibrium. Soon its increasing factional and ideological identification with Desai and the struggle at the state level, where the Jan Sangh engineered or supto act



^'^



^*^

POLITICS

176

ported the removal of three BLD chief ministers, broke its Hnks to the Charan Singh-led BLD.^^ By July 1979, when the Janata party and gov-

ernment finally broke up Singh belatedly noticed the Jan Sangh fraction's imputed communal stance. Communalism, in the form of "dual membership" in the Janata and the RSS, was the issue he used to justify splitting the party.^"*

The denouement was and outside the party who worked

Reunification preceded the end by six months.

expected by no one, even those in

From January, when Charan Singh rejoined the government, to July, when he finally split the party, he was isolated and in a weak bargaining position. The monsoon (July 1) session of Parliament began for

it.

No

one imagined that the debate on Congress-U leader Y. B. Chavan's no-confidence motion would be anything but pro forma. Only a lonely Raj Narain, abandoned even by Charan Singh after the party national executive expelled him on June 12, 1979, for yet an-

peacefully.

other irrepressible outburst against the party leaders,

ping away

at the unity of the party

from the outside.

was

He

still

chip-

appealed to

few old colleagues to keep him company in support of Chavan's motion. How this small trickle suddenly became a stream and then a flood, and how Parliament's mood suddenly shifted from resigned acceptance of Desai's Janata government to rebellion and rejection, is not quite clear, but Charan Singh's conversations with Indira Gandhi via Sanjay Gandhi and Raj Narain no doubt had some bearing on the fall of the Desai government.^^ On July 15, 1979, Morarji Desai, having lost his parliamentary majority, submitted his resignation. a

The Janata party eventually split into three parts: the "original" Janata, under president Chandra Shekhar; the Lok Dal (later the Dalit Mazdoor Kisan party [DMKP]), under Charan Singh; and the Bharatiya

Janata party (BJP), encompassing the former Jan Sangh. ^^Jagjivan

Ram came

to rest in the Congress-U, formed after the January 1978 Congress split.^^ The components roughly, though not precisely, approximated the elements that had joined to form the Janata in 1977.

outcome was by no means certain at the time Desai's government fell. There was a real possibility that, under other leadership,

But

this

Janata could have survived as the largest party even without Singh. But

same single-minded self-destructiveness that had dogged the party 1978 pursued it to the end. The probability that Jagjivan Ram, less tarnished than the others, could have formed a government and that an election could have been avoided, was blocked by Morarji Desai, who doggedly refused to resign leadership of the parliamentary party even when it became apparent that he could not form a government. To Charan Singh it appeared

the

since

1

77

Janata's Historic Failure

would become the prime minister of India. But he was mistaken. Mrs. Gandhi snatched the prize from him. She raised his hopes initially by voting for Chavan's no-confidence motion and subsequently by offering support to the government he and Chavan were allowed to form on July 22, on the condition they could muster a that at long last he

vote of confidence within the month.

^*'

But the promise dissolved when

she insisted that Charan Singh agree to protect her against present or past threats to her political career.^^ Without Congress-I's seventy-one

on August 20, the appointed day

votes

parliamentary majority, he

Having

failed,

by precipitating

Ram was

to prove his

failed.

Charan Singh again played into Mrs. Gandhi's hands the election. Desai had finally allowed Ram to be

elected leader of the truncated Janata, party.

Charan Singh

for

in a position to try to

still

the largest parliamentary

form a government, and many

observers believe he might have succeeded. But rather than open the way for his old rival to form a government by telling the president that he himself could not tion

and

a

midterm

do

so,

Charan Singh recommended

dissolu-

To Janata's consternation, the president recommendation of a failed prime minister

election.

acted in accord with the designate.

Mrs. Gandhi's strategy rested on the belief that an election was better for her than coalition politics in a Parliament where her party ranked fourth.''^ Her estimate was confirmed. The divided opposition

by one hundred seats, seats they would votes been counted together rather than

parties lost to the Congress-I

have

won had

their parties'

separately.

What had begun

as a bold

experiment

in party building, political

realignment, and national reconstruction along Gandhian lines ended in shambles.

A

potential critical election that promised to transform

the party system

was

dissipated in a

miasma

of debilitating efforts at

personal aggrandizement. Janata's term in office betrayed

founding and destroyed its promise as a great national party. Janata did not consolidate or expand its support because its leaders failed to inspire confidence in their integrity, ability, and vision. It performed well enough as government; its policies were imaginative and reasonably effective for over two years. But it failed to become a party organizationally or among the voters. It was not Janata's policy that failed. The voters rejected its political performance. Ironically, the party that took Mohandas Gandhi as an exemplary figure had not learned what he

had

its

tried to teach the Indian nation, that swaraj (self-rule) for India

required swaraj for

its

leaders

and

citizens.

6

Decline of

Congress Dominance and the Emergence of a Bifurcated Party System 1984 confirm the importance of historical conjunctures in the determination of political events and behavior. Indira Gandhi w^as assassinated on October 31, 1984. She had been prime minister for fifteen years. Her father, Jaw^aharlal Nehru, Mohandas Gandhi's principal associate in India's independence struggle, had been prime minister for seventeen years. The day after Indira Gandhi's death, November 1, 1984, Rajiv Gandhi, Indira's eldest son, was sworn in as her successor. Two months later, at the end of December, he led the Congress-I party to its most decisive electoral victory since 1952. In mid- 19 84, many political analysts had held that an Indira Gandhi-led Congress-I would lose ground in the upcoming eighth parliamentary election. A narrow majority comparable to the 1967 result was possible, but a plurality rather than a majority of seats, followed by a coalition government, seemed more likely to many observ-

The

events of late

These predictions took account of Congress-I's responsibility for the violence, alienation, and threat to national unity of the Punjab and Assam crises; the shady manner in which opposition state governments were "toppled" in Andhra Pradesh, Kashmir, and Sikkim; the

ers.

perception of pervasive corruption and abuses of power that the recent

Maharashtra had highlighted; and the insecurity engendered by a rising tide of societal and state violence. In domestic if not in international politics, Indira Gandhi was increasingly perceived as taking actions that were motivated by personal and party advantage rather than by what was good for the country. More important than these proximate causes of informed observers' expectations were long-term secular trends that indicated both erosion and volatility in Congress-I's regional and minority support base. In this chapter, we analyze these electoral trends and their consequences for Congress support and the party system, with respect to six regions (Hindi Heardand, West, South, East, North and Northeast and Islands) and three minorities (Muslims, untouchables, and tribals). As early as 1962, Congress began to lose its base in the Hindi Heartland, whose 42 percent of Parliament's seats makes it the largest of the five

Antulay and Adik scandals

178

in

Decline of Congress

179

was

regions.' This trend

among

minorities.

Dominance

paralleled by erosion of Congress's support

Though both

trends were strikingly reversed by the

postassassination election in 1984, they suggest a decay of the condi-

produced Congress dominance. The erosion of Congress's regional and minority support was paralleled by increasing volatility and unpredictability in regional party voting. Volatility affected Congress's regional support base and, from 1967, contributed to an emergent bifurcation between support for national and regional tions that originally

parties in parliamentary as well as state assembly elections.

1984 election may indicate the beginnings of a new party system, in which Congress is dominant at the center but not in most states. But the conjuncturally determined "waves" that contributed to the volatility of national election outcomes since at least 1971, and that were very much in evidence in 1984, suggest that the

The outcome

system

may

of the

be inherently

that characterized the

less stable

Nehru

than the dominant-party system

era. In the Rajiv

Gandhi

era, regional

parties operating within the federal system appear to be as important as centrist national parties in providing leadership natives. Put

and policy

alter-

another way, the majority of the electorate that supports

"the opposition" to Congress will be represented by combinations of

and national parties. At the same time. Congress rule at the center will rely on electoral alliances with regional parties and cooperation from the regional and national parties that govern many states. regional

The Breakdown of Congress's Hindi Heartland Base Regional determinants, while leaving terns

and changes

to be explained about pat-

compare favorably with other desocioeconomic status, urban-rural differences, and

in party support,

terminants (such as class) often

much

used to explain such changes.^

We

have used marginal

Congress's regional seat and vote shares to explain the transformation of the party system that began with the 1967 parliamentary

shifts in

election. Categorizing India's ritories into five

twenty-two

states

and eight union

major and one minor region, we have analyzed

ter-

re-

gional voting patterns for eight parliamentary elections.

Although the parliamentary majorities needed to form national governments require multiregional party support, seat majorities in the Hindi Heardand have proved essential in determining which party has been able to obtain such support. Our analysis shows the breakdown between 1962 and 1980 of the Hindi Heardand support that sustained

POLITICS

180

Congress dominance of the party system in the first two parUamentary elections. It also shows the return of Hindi Heartland support as sig-

overwhelming parliamentary Congress victory of 1984. Like Prussia in imperial Germany, the Hindi Heartland is by far India's largest region. Its six states, including the two largest, Uttar Pradesh and Bihar, and one union territory have provided five (all from Uttar Pradesh) of independent India's six prime ministers. With 42 pernificant in the

cent of Parliament's seats,

it

occupies more political space than the two

next largest regions combined (table 8). Its definition as a political region starts with a common language, Hindi, extends to its heartland

and economic backwardness, as measured by most statistical indicators, and eventuates in voting patterns distinct from those of other regions. For example, low average turnout makes it the only region whose proportion of votes polled has been consistently below its proportion of seats (table 8). The South, encompassing four states and one union territory, ranks second among the six regions, with 25 percent of total seats. Like the other two rimland regions (West and East), the South has a higher level characteristics of cultural parochialism

and

social

of political participation than the Heartland (table 8).

Its

proportion

of valid votes polled nationally has been consistently higher than

its

proportion of national seats, which reflects turnout disproportionate to its population and higher than the national turnout. The South 's

common

features include Dravidian (as

opposed to Sanskrit-based)

TABLES Each Region's Seats and Votes as a Percentage of All-India Seats and Votes, 1967

Hindi Heartland

South

West East

North Northeast and Islands

Source: See

Seats

Votes

(N=520)

(N= 146 miUion)

42 25 14 14 4

38

29 14 14 4

1

1

=

table 9.

Note: These proportions have been relatively stable but were subject to some variations on 1967, which was a representative year: the Hindi Heardand had 44 percent of the seats in 1957 and 1984 and 41 percent of the votes in 1957 and 1977; the South, 26 percent of the seats in 1957 and 24 percent in 1977 and 1980, and 27 percent of the votes in 1957 and 28 percent in 1977; the West, 13 percent of the seats in 1957 and 13 percent of the votes in 1977; the East, 13 percent of the votes in 1977; the North, 2 percent of the seats in 1957; and the Northeast and Islands, 2 percent of the seats in 1980.

Decline of Congress

181

Dominance

languages, higher levels of development by most socioeconomic in-

more cosmopolitan history and outlook than in the Hindi Heartland. At the same time, it is more internally differentiated dicators,

and

a

by language and

than the Hindi Heartland. Its mutually comprehensible than the w^ide range

political orientation

four languages are less

The upper South (Andhra Pradesh time the mainstay of the Indira Gandhi-

of dialects spoken in the Heartland.

and Karnataka) became led Congress

when

lower South (Tamil tural nationalist

rooted

its

Hindi Heartland support declined, while the

Nadu and

DMK

CPI-M and

for a

and

Kerala) favored regional parties, the cul-

AIADMK

in

Tamil

Nadu and

the locally

other local parties in Kerala. Since 1983, Andhra

Pradesh and Karnataka disavowed their Congress-I commitment by supporting a regional party (Telugu Desam) and national parties (Janata and BJP), respectively.

The Telugu Desam held

1984 padiamentary and 1985

state

assembly elections. Congress-I

carried Karnataka nationally, but Janata, just three

given a clear mandate to continue governing the

Bombay and British raj

firm in both the

months

later,

was

state.

Calcutta, former capitals of presidencies under the

whose hinterlands encompassed

the states of today's

West

and East regions, symbolize many of the characteristics that distinguish these two rimland regions. Equal at 14 percent with respect to proportion of seats. West and East are unequal with respect to economic growth. Both states of the Western region, Maharashtra and Gujarat, are leaders in industrial and agricultural production, while West Bengal, the largest of the East's three states, has lost ground in national rankings of state income and production as a result of Calcutta's commercial and industrial decline. The North, composed of a twice-truncated Punjab, Kashmir, and the union territory of Chandigarh, includes the two states whose politics is heavily influenced by the presence of majority non-Hindu reHgious communities; Kashmir is about 70 percent Muslim, and the Punjab is just over 50 percent Sikh. Although Punjab is at the top and ranked by per capital income, their politics are similar, in that party strategy and electoral behavior are heavily influenced by confessional parties (the Akali Dal and the National Conference) that represent Sikhs in the Punjab and Muslims in

Kashmir near the bottom of

states

Kashmir.

The

smallest region, the Northeast

and

Islands,

is

made up

of geo-

graphically and culturally peripheral states and union territories. thirteen seats constitute only 2 percent of the parliamentary total. region's poverty, relative deprivation, cultural alienation,

Its

The

and resistance

POLITICS

182

to immigrants

vanced

states

from Bangladesh (formerly East Pakistan) and more adof India have led to rebellions, civil strife, and incipient

secessionism.

Nehru era of one-party dominance. Congress relied for its on a tacit Hindi Heartland strategy. It won a disproportionate

In the

success

share of

its

votes

and

seats

from the

region's six states. This dispropor-

on strong support from India's principal disadvantaged minorities, Muslims and scheduled castes and tribes, w^ho came to believe in the nationalist era and in Nehru's time that Congress was their friend and protector. One finding of our regional analysis is that the elections of 1962, 1967, and 1977 marked a deterioration of Congress support in the Hindi Heartland that the 1971 and 1980 elections only partially reversed. The great return swing of the 1984 parliamentary election, when Congress won 95 percent of the seats in the Heartland, was moderated but not cancelled when Congress won the state assembly election of 1985 with more modest majorities of 66 percent of the seats. Table 9 reviews seat and vote data for the eight elections from 1952 to 1984. The first election, in 1952, was the best of the party's three Nehru-

tionate electoral support v^as in turn based

era parliamentary elections in the Hindi Heartland (50 percent of the

vote and 85 percent of the seats).

The outcome

exemplifies a leading

feature of the era of Congress dominance, the party's disproportionate

support

in the

Heartland. In 1952, Congress

won

12 percent more

and 5 percent more votes in the Heartland than its national averages, and its performance there in seats and votes was better than in any other region except the West (see table 9). After 1957, with the exception of 1971, Congress did not attract more seat and vote support in the Hindi Heartland than in the country as a whole until the recovery under Rajiv Gandhi's leadership in 1984. In 1962, Congress's vote share in the Heartland dropped below its national average, and in 1962, 1977, and 1980, both seat and vote proportions were below its seats

national average (table 10).

Comparisons between the 1952 election and elections held after 1967, when Congress dominance was challenged, demonstrate the changing nature of Congress support. Indeed, the challenge of 1967 was prefigured by Congress' weak showing in the Heartland in 1962. From 1962 onward, except in 1971 and 1984, Congress won higher percentages of votes and seats in the South and/or West than in the Hindi Heartland (see table 9). Another way of measuring Congress support in the Hindi Heartland is to express it in terms of the proportions of total national Congress

Decline of Congress

183

and votes located

Dominance

Hindi Heartland (see table 11). In 1952 and 1957, paradigmatic for the era of Congress dominance, 52 and 49 percent of all seats Congress won nationally and 44 and 42 percent of all votes were won in the Hindi Heartland. In 1962, both proportions declined dramatically, to 41 and 31 percent, respectively, recuperating somewhat in 1967. Even though Congress regained support in the Hindi Heartland in 1971, when Mrs. Gandhi engineered India's first midterm and first "delinked" election, the proportions of Heartland seats and votes were below the 1952 and 1957 levels. In the postemergency election of 1977, Congress in the Heartland won only 2 seats

in the

percent of the national total of seats and 28 percent of the national

were considerably increased from 1977 (to 43 percent of seats and 36 percent of the vote), they were still below those of both 1971 and 1967. In 1980, a united opvotes. In 1980, while the proportions

position vote in Uttar Pradesh

would have reduced the number

Congress seats from fifty-one to fourteen of eighty-five; in Bihar, from thirty to eleven of fifty-four.^ As it was, Congress-Fs vote in these two states was 17 and 9 percent below that of 1971, respectively. In the 1984 parliamentary election. Congress reversed its downward trajectory when it approximated its best Heartland seat and vote performance of 1952. of

upper South (Andhra Pradesh and Karnataka), and the West (Maharashtra and Gujarat) became the bastions of Congress support that the Hindi Heartland had been in the era of Congress dominance. Mrs. Gandhi's decision in 1978 to return to Parliament by standing in a by-election in Medak, Andhra Pradesh, rather than in her old constituency, Rae In the course of the 1970s, the South, particularly the

Bareli in Uttar Pradesh,

ern bastion.

It

was

made visible

on its SouthIndira Gandhi in

Congress-I's reliance

the upper South that rallied to

1977, saving Congress from destruction massively defected. Congress nationally

when

the Hindi Heartland

won only 28 and 34

percent of

seats and votes but the South as a whole delivered 11 percent of

its

and 41 percent of its votes (table 9). Voting support levels in the South as a whole (but not in Andhra Pradesh) even increased in 1980 and 1984 (to 44 percent in 1980 and 47 percent in 1984 [table 9]), but these gains were crosscut by the state assembly elections of 1983 and 1985, when Congress lost convincingly in Andhra Pradesh and in seats

Karnataka.

The West was

the other major region that in

and votes higher than the national averthe election of 1957, the West has consistendy sup-

gress with proportions of seats ages.

Except

in

1977 supported Con-

^ ''

' ^ ^

1111

^'

'^

^

'1'

T—

cx)

—"

^"

,

^

,





^^'^ 1111

1

o "^

o

V5

__

a o

jj j5



«^

5

OJ

4-1

TO

'*-'

\C

2 -^

jj

^^

^

-^

-O

(/5

TO

c

^-^

TO

_

-Q

-13

C TO

ii

c3

^

c/5

/

c

!;>

——

a. •

..

..

>^


_c TO

_c -shZ DC t uu ^ -^ -. TO 3 TO E

^

D

'^

L>

TO

«-

C •-

k^

-^

3 TO ^ 3 ^ u t; T3 — _r

__ ._ TJ _C

S^

V ^c

S ^

^Q

^

4-J

•-

Tf oo

»o

*^

-*




2

.2;

i_

3 C ni

..

rH

ON '^

1-H

^ ^

£?



-2 C

C/3

.2

2

^

r\ r^

NO


-fe!

O;

C/5

C/5

w

^ T3

^-^ rH-^

.2. ON CO E "—' (J _ ^ C ^ OJ C !> CO DC Oh 4J '^

C/5 4>

lU t/5

(/,

^ •2 S< § e^.Eu

2:^

O n — o !

T3

C/3

2 ^

00 h-

OO

^

NO Tf

=

(-0

»^

C/5

4^

Si 4-1

12

bO

Distribution

TABLE

E c 2 5 o S o U -2,U 4-j

3 3

2

bC

of

"I

•-

N/

Q

Q 5

6

2

OJ

^«.< '*'^

!3

ii

5i)-2i

iL.

^ r^ H rjj

t/5

^ c

I-

0-1

0,

2:>

E

^ g^ lu

*-

ON rH

(U

o

S ^ ^ or

42

0-T3

3

POLITICS

190

1952 and 1957 are not possible, because scheduled castes and tribes were mostly elected to double-member constituencies in which the other member was not scheduled caste or scheduled tribe.) This special relationship was shattered by the 1977 election. At the most general level, scheduled caste voters have voted for the winning party, whether Congress or other: Janata in 1977 and Congress in 1980 and 1983 (table 12). Most important, regardless of the winning party, their support for Congress in seats and votes (where we have the data) has been below the national averages. Conversely, their support for the Janata (and its successors) and regional parties has been above the national or state seat and vote averages.

elections of

Congress's failure to reestablish

its

uled caste voters in 1980 seems even

special relationship with sched-

more evident

if

the electoral out-

Hindi Heartland states where almost half (49 percent) of the seats reserved for scheduled castes are located, Janata closed out Congress-I in 1977 by winning, in all, thirty-eight scheduled caste seats (table 13). In 1980, Congress-I recaptured twenty-three of the thirty-eight seats, 23 percent below its

come

is

disaggregated by region. In the

five

share in 1971. Congress-I's recovery as measured in seats overstates in Uttar Pradesh,

which

is

not only India's

its

most apparent most populous state but also

recovery in constituency vote shares. This difference

is

the state with the highest proportion of scheduled caste voters (21 per-

and Lok Dal candidates in Uttar Pradesh's scheduled caste constituencies in 1980 won 58 percent of the vote, a proportion 24 percent higher than Congress-I's share, and 6 percent higher than the average Janata/Lok Dal share in Uttar Pradesh (52 percent).^ Congress-I, by contrast, polled only 34 percent in scheduled caste constitu-

cent). Janata

encies,

2 percent

less

than

its

average in the state as a whole.

In 1984, however, scheduled caste constituencies in Uttar Pradesh

swung

Gandhi-led Congress-I. Their level of voting support (67 percent) was 16 percent greater than the enormous swing to Congress-I in all Uttar Pradesh constituencies (51 percent in 1984 as against 36 percent in 1980) and 33 percent higher than decisively behind the Rajiv

Congress-I's proportion (34 percent in scheduled caste constituencies) in 1

1980.^ in

Some have

interpreted this extraordinary swing to Congress-

Uttar Pradesh's scheduled caste constituencies as a quasi-class

variant of the

"Hindu" and/or

and secessionism Congress-I voters,

in the

nationalist backlash to Sikh terrorism

Punjab. Scheduled caste voters, like other

may have sympathized with

the bereaved son of a

mother martyred by her Sikh bodyguards and been concerned that national unity and personal security had been put at risk by Sikh "extremism." But scheduled caste voters differed from other Congress-I

5

I

O

o o o o o o o

rt

VC rH

O

ro

O

rn

c o

&JD

C O

00

U

I

3 O '—

-o

c n

in o m o

O

(N rs

rsl

NC oo

O

oo

T-^

o o o

|\

W

^

4->

rt

oo

(N |\ ON

lO r^ ro

+

T

I

I

ro N£) (N T^

(N to r^ "^ '-H

o o o

O O ^ O «0 ro

o ^

O ^

VsO

+

' '

m

+ +

+ + +

Z

Q

U o ^—

o ^ o o rf

rt

C

rt OJ

00 (N

iJO

.2 '^ 'S

r--

^

ON |\

«0 l\ »0 '—I

o

^

o

r^ r\ OO ON ON

OO OO ON ON ON

U

a, .5

OO ON

M U D O


alternation at

and 1980s contrasted with the

the center and the states in the 19"'0s

relanveh stable electoral outcomes of the

tirst

three general elections.

The largest swing in Congress's national vote in the tirst three elections was 2 percent. Since 1967, the swings have exceeded 2 percent in five parliamentarv- elections and ha\-e been much higher in four: 5 percent in 19^~, ^ percent in 1^84, and ^ percent in both 19 and 1*^80 (table 20).'^ Volatilits" since l^^c^^

is

way pohncs changed

related to the

I'^^I ceneral elecnon. First,

it

reflects the

after the

decay of parr> organization

as a dcierminant of electoral policies, including candidate selection.

However

faction

ndden they ^^re

tions at the state ,ind district levels

m

the

Nehru

era, part>- organiza-

were able to make decisions about

and issues and to sustain some sense of parrv loyalrv and commitment to organizational goals. Since then, plebiscirar> politics has emphasized not onK loyalty to particular personalities

candidates, leadership,

TABLE 20 Ekctonil Swiass in Co«SfCSS% Natkoal Vmc

onrer

Sa-c 1*^52

H5~

— ^ "«

1962

.:?

V

^

100 102 100

—5

0%

lo-i

-^_>

19~ l«*«>

-9 +9

9S 89 9S

^

— r

- t'i*^^.

~ \

when Coi^;iress rcvxi^^ 45

Ekvtiocks

:-icxN.

1^7

"

> ^>^

"O

:;

2 3 «

.i2

.a "O -o c

TABLE 23 Indicators of

Demand

Politics

Student

Year

"IndiscipHne":

Workdays

Voter

Riots

Reported

Lost

Turnout

(Thousands)

Incidents

(Millions)

(%)

Democratic Regime/Command



1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963

— — — — — —

21

23

24 25 24 25 27 27 27 29 28

Politics

33

45.7

3.4 3.4

5.7 7.0 6.4

93

7.8

120

5.6

80 172

5.0

47.8

6.5

97

6.1

109

3.3

55.4



Democratic Regime/Demand

^

r ^"'*="'' Shastri

1965 J 1966^

1967 1968 1969 1970 ^I. Gandhi 1971 1972 1973 1974^

1976

1978 rOesai 1979 > 1980' 1981

1982 M. Gandhi 1983 1984. 1985 >R. Gandhi

I

3,064

19.0

68

3,861

20.6

64

4,380

16.5

55.3

6,365

20.5

33

35 42 45 56

67 63

7.7

607

13.8

2,665

17.2



— —

81

395 271

6.5

17.1

5,551

20.6

11,540

40.3

Regime/Command

80

— — — — — — — —

3,847

21.9

1,190

12.8

7,520

25.3

9,174

29.7

9,203

29.8

10,600

29.6

7,740

29.2

5,200

33.2

7,188

— —

— — —

Politics

Democratic Regime/Demand

1977^

Politics

— — — 61.3 — — —

33

Authoritarian

1975

(Nehru)

I

38.3^

49.4^



11

(I.

Gandhi)

— Politics

II

60.4

— — — 56.9 — — 64.0 —

Sources: Riots: Baldev Raj Nayar, Violence and Crime in India (Delhi: Macmillan, 1975); Government of India, Ministry of Home Affairs, Bureau of Police Research and

ECONOMY

228

more

and three-fifths or more of assembly seats in the 1952, 1957, and 1962 general elections/"* Economic performance was good to outstanding. The era encompassed the second and third five-year plans, which, in retrospect, appear as a kind of political and economic golden age. Government's investment effort, as reflected in the central government's capital formation, grew vigorously from about 25 percent of total expenditure just prior to the first five-year plan (1950—51) to an average of just below 50 percent (fig. 6 and table 24) during the second and third five-year plans. Industrial production spurted forward during the last two years of the second plan and the first four years of the third (1959-60 through 1964-65, [fig. 7 and table 25]). Subsequent of parliamentary seats

industrial production has not equalled the twelve-point average annual

Food grain production stayed abreast of population growth by increasing 20 percent between the last year of the first plan (1955—56) and 1964—65, the year before the great monsoon failure of 1965—66 (fig. 8 and table 26). In only two years of the 1956—66 period did the price index rise more than ten gain of these remarkable six years.

points

(fig.

1964—65

Demand

9 and table 27).

to

1974—75: Democratic Regime/Demand

politics surfaced in

75^ with a brief remission in

Politics

I

1964—65 and continued through 1974— 1971—72. Exogenous

factors contributed

by security, political, and economic events: military failure in wars with China (1962) and Pakistan (1965); the deaths of two prime ministers (Nehru in May 1964 and Shastri in January 1966); and the "worst weather on record" to this change; these included shocks caused

student indiscipline: Government of India, Min"Student Indiscipline" (1967, mimeograph). Report (annual), and Third Report of the National Police Commission, 1980 (Delhi, 1980); and Data India, September 18-24, 1978, p. 594; workdays lost: Government of India, Ministry of Labour, Labour Bureau, Indian Labour Statistics (Chandigarh and Simla, annual), and Indian Labour Yearbook (Chandigarh and Simla, annual); and Government of India, Ministry of Finance, Economic Survey (Delhi, annual) (the figures in Economic Survey are for fiscal years; e.g., 1978—79 corresponds to 1978 in the table). Notes: Data on riots and "student indiscipline" were not available after 1977 and 1982, respectively. As a result, our figures do not account for what may have been extraordinary increases in both. In the 1980s, riots and student indiscipline may have merged when highly mobilized student-led regional movements in Assam and Punjab

Development, Crime istry of

in India (annual);

Home Affairs,

engaged

in

(Punjab) or triggered (Assam) violence.

^Provisional,

and excludes Bombay

textile strike.

229 in

Types of

Politics

and Economic Performance

1965-66 when food production plummeted and

prices soared.''^

Together, these events created the necessary but not the sufficient conditions for the rise of demand politics.

United States president Lyndon Johnson practiced a disruptive and politically counterproductive "short tether" food aid policy. World

Bank, United

mained

States,

unfulfilled.

and consortium foreign aid commitments

One

of the

first

re-

acts of the inexperienced new^

prime minister, Indira Gandhi, w2ls to devalue the rupee (June 1966). Perceived as being imposed on India, devaluation politically embarrassed the Gandhi government and weakened its standing and authority.'^ Poor economic performance both reflected and compounded the effects of exogenous shocks on the rise of demand politics. Eco-

nomic

indicators for the fifth year of the third plan

sharply

downward.

Industrial as well as agricultural production de-

clined; plan investment, already adversely affected

defense spending after the China

slumped

further;

(1965—66) turned by the doubling of

war (October 1962)

(see fig. 6),

and prices shot up.

The fourth general

election (February— March 1967) illustrates the

mutually determinative relationship between type of regime and of

on the one hand and economic performance on the other. (fig. 5 and table 23) to protest poor economic performance and to vote against government's domestic and foreign economic policy failures. The result was virtual repudiation of Congress, the party pf nationalism and independence. Between the third general election i^ 1962 and the fourth in 1967, Congress's share of parliamentary votes and seats dropped from 46 to 40 percent and from 73 to 54 percent, respectively; its share of state assembly votes and seats, from 44 to 40 percent and from 60 to 49 percent,'^ and its control of sixteen state governments from fourteen to eight as regional parties or opposition party coalitions formed governments in half. In circular fashion, the electoral outcome fostered demand politics, as narrow and uncertain Congress majorities at the center and unstable and warring opposition coalitions in the states rendered governmental authority more suspect and vulnerable. The election results weakened public authority. At the center. Congress government was inhibited by a razor-thin majority. After Congress split in November 1969, its minority government remained in power until the 1971 parliamentary election, with the support of the CPI and DMK. With eight opposition-governed states, it lost some of its capacity to initiate and coordinate policy between the center and the state governments. At the state level, party parochialism and rivalry politics

Voters turned out in unprecedented numbers

o E O)

— U)

(i>

o

cc

.tr

()

o Q.

(Tl

X)

o c o ro E E 0)

^-^^

y>

0)

Q Q «>>

r 03

.t;

^ oc CO

e 4> ha

s u c

E

^O b o < O -J

(90

0)

Q D

c l-l

CD

h

m

— en

O *^

T)

o o

a.

^_»

"O

CO (•)

e o -4-1

u

1

^

V4M

c CO

o E E o

Q o

.

(Q

5« CJ

u>

> ^

1^

1

«o

3 C c O nJ

^ gimes were associated with good economic performance. The view that there is a positive relationship between authoritarian regimes and economic performance and the view that state sovereignty is necessarily better for economic growth in developing economies than popular sovereignty is not supported by our analysis of the Indian evidence. A second finding concerns the association between economic performance and indicators of demand politics: riots, student indiscipline, workdays lost, and voter participation. There was a striking association after 1965—66 between declining levels of economic performance and increases in demand politics indicators (fig. 5). These quantitative changes suggest a qualitative transformation of mobilization and participation that affected subsequent economic performance and growth regardless of regime or polity type. In the post-Nehru era, state actors faced a differently constituted political universe that

seemed to jeopardize growth. Yet events in the 1980s suggest otherwise. As industrial production spurted upward, so did the indicators of mobilization.

Mrs. Gandhi's

demand

politics

from 1970 to free herself from the pressures of had a profound effect on Indian political institutions effort

and conduct. Her strategy was to deinstitutionalize party. Parliament, public services, and the federal system. It was a strategy for narrowing or eliminating the channels through which demands might be articuengaging discontented or disgruntled constituencies and responding to or brokering their demands, Mrs. Gandhi sought

lated. Instead of

J

/

,

I

1

-*

ECONOMY

244

to escape them. This strategy ultimately failed

when demand

groups,

deprived of regular channels for expression, voiced their claims in the streets, that is, outside legal and conventional channels. The agitational politics of opinion "out of doors" developed highly elabo-

rated political art forms to persuade or coerce public opinion and elected

and appointed

ing chapter.

state officials. This

is

the subject of the follow-

Part 4

DEMAND GROUPS

Demand Groups and

^

Pluralist Representation

group representation in India is marked by pluralist rather than corporatist forms and processes; its pluralism differs from that in Interest

Our conceptual vocabulary for the disintroduces three terms "demand group/'

other industrial democracies. cussion of representation



"state-dominated plurahsm," and "involuted pluralism"

— to designate

and representation of interests in India. Unlike organized interests, the demand group relies on ad hoc rather than bureaucratic organization. It uses mass mobilization more than expert knowledge and technical bargaining but combines issues and movement politics with the politics of organized interests. Other characteristics of the Indian variant of pluralism are its domination by the state and its tendency to excessive multiplication and fragmentation, a process we call involution. Finally, the pervasive and powerful state not only constrains and manipulates interest group activity, it is also itself a major interest, competing with and usually winning out over societal interests. On the one hand, the state sets policy agendas. It controls legal and economic incentives and both fosters and manipudistinctive aspects of the organization

lates

involuted pluralism.

On

the other hand, in

its

various industrial,

and commercial manifestations, it commands more resources than the societal interests with which it competes. State producer interests and policy bodies occupy much of the representational "space" that is occupied in other industrial democracies by pluralist and corporatist structures and processes. They also speak and act on their financial,

own

behalf as institutional interests in the context of governmental

pluralism.

Two

parameters or

ducer interests

initial

conditions affect the organization of pro-

in India: (1) location in the

ganized economies and

(2) the

dominance

organized or

1, fig. 1) affects

formal representation of interest draws, and interest

group organization

specific to India.

workers are in the the base on which the all

also shapes the type of

it

The demand group,

particular variant of interest representation that

we

discuss below,

part a consequence of the scale of India's unorganized economy.

247

unor-

of the public sector within

the organized economy. That only 10 percent of

organized economy (see chapter

in the

is

a in

As we

DEMAND GROUPS

248

about two-thirds of the salaried and wage workers within the organized economy are employed by public-sector firms or government, and public-sector firms control Id percent of the paid-up capital employed by the hundred largest firms (table 4). Such state domination of the organized economy is a precondition for state domination of pluralist representation. Formally organized interests are more common and more important for policy choice and implementation in the organized economy than in the unorganized, where ad hoc issue and movement politics using agitational and symbolic means play noted

in

chapter

1,

a larger role.

7 we advanced the theory of demand and command polities, and in chapter 8 we put the theory in motion by relating various measures of command and demand politics to measures of economic performance. In the next four chapters, we shall analyze the dynamics In chapter

command and demand politics. Here we attend to how interactions between command and demand politics are mediated by the organiza-

of

and representation of interests. The framework of representation has an independent effect on the prevailing balance between command and demand politics. tion

Pluralism and Neocorporatism:

Some Conceptual

Distinctions

and corporatist modes, we posit interest rather than class as the basic motivating and organizing principle of political economy. Unlike most Marxist treatments, which take it as axiomatic and predetermined that only the mode and relations of production define social formations and that class so defined is the ultimate determinant of consciousness and action, we treat interest phenomenologically and contingently. Interests can be exIn treating representation in terms of pluralist

pressed through a variety of social formations



class, caste, tribe,

or

community; and profession or occupation defined in terms of skill, knowledge, and ethos as well as in terms of property relations. The existence, goals, and ascendance of such social formations are as much a matter of context and status group; religious, linguistic, or territorial

choice as of objective determination.

The most common conceptualization of pluralist representation is interest group pluralism.' American in its origin and development and closely related to liberalism, it became in the 1950s and 1960s a conceptual export that followed in the wake of a rising curve of American world power and influence. It posits an equilibrium model of competing but ultimately harmonious organized interests. Anybody who feels

Demand Groups and

249

Pluralist Representation

the need to represent his or her interest can participate by joining with like-minded persons in a formal organization. Tocqueville held that

America's associational

helped to combine liberty and democracy. Unless equal but isolated and powerless individuals were to combine in associations,

life

democracies would be prone to tyranny and citizens

unable to limit and influence state action. Associations in democracies served to constrain and direct popular sovereignty. Like classic theories of market economics, interest group pluralism relies

on an equilibrium model

interest

for reconciling the pursuit of individual

with realization of the public good.

An

invisible

hand

is

said to

guide market transactions and interest group bargains in ways that translate private into public interest. Just as buyers and sellers in mar-

goods they prefer for the prices they want to pay, so competing interest groups in policy arenas produce a policy outcome that kets get the

and deliberation among interdependent but competing interests eventuate in harmonious equilibriums that approximate what is best for all and for each. In America for some time, the frontier, abundance, and a rapidly expanding economy obscured, if not eliminated, the zero-sum possibilities of interest group competition. In time, sympathetic as well as hostile critics showed how the practice of interest groups pluralism led to consequences that were not anticipated by the model. Private power became the master of public power as vested interests appropriated public authority and resources by capturing state agencies. Just as inequalities of income, wealth, and power made for market imperfections that contradicted the assumption that consumers and workers could engage in mutually beneficial exchange with producers and employers, so the absence or inequality of organizational and political resources enabled vested interests to dominate policy choice and implementation. Many of those most in need of representation did not or could not benefit from interest groups. Members lost control or were alienated, as interest group bureaucrats became organizational masters. Those who managed interest group organizations found it difficult to distinguish their personal goals and interests from those of the members they were meant to serve. Contradictions became increasingly manifest between party government and executive leadership on the one hand, and the representational infrastructure through which interest group pluralism operated, on the other. Instead of equilibrium and harmony that yielded the public interest, stalemate among group interests and among separated and balanced institutions became common. The multiplication and comis

in the public interest. Persuasion, bargaining,

petition of interests often blocked legislative action.

DEMAND GROUPS

250

Despite these and other criticisms, interest group pluralism as the-

ory and practice persists in America, India, and other industrial democracies because it is more than an explanation of state-society relations. In part,

common

it

persists because associational

feature of industrial democracies.

It

like class,

is

a

also persists because the

right of citizen voters to associate independently sential aspect of liberty. If

life,

is

perceived as an es-

organized interests often represent the rich

and powerful more than the poor and oppressed and if "overmighty subjects" in industrial democracies sometimes dominate policy and the state, at other times associations limit state pov^^er in w^ays that protect their

1982

members' values and

interests.

The

w^orkers in Poland

who

in

behind Solidarity to challenge an oppressive regime and the disadvantaged minority communities (Muslims, Harijans) who in 1977 helped turn Indira Gandhi's authoritarian regime out of office suggest that liberty to associate can serve unvested as well as vested rallied

As long

and the elites that staff them serve themselves, the right to association and to independent representation that interest group pluraUsm makes possible will remain a collective good. Pluralism and neocorporatism can be viewed as contrasting models of state-society relations. They posit contrasting patterns for the organization and representation of interests and for the formulation and choice of public policy. The pluralist model arose from a normative theory that values liberty for individuals and the voluntary associations they should be free to form. Voluntary associations are meant to interests.

as sovereignty-seeking states

pursue the interests of their members independent of state sovereignty or the compulsions of corporate and bureaucratic governance. Pluralist

forms and processes of

and representation are and leaders in ways that

political participation

held to determine public choices of policies

both limit and direct state action. For these reasons, the pluralist organization and representation of interests has an elective affinity to de-

mand

rather than

command

politics.

Neocorporatism as a model for the organization and representation of interests echoes medieval and mercantilist forms for the compulsory and monopolistic representation of interests. Status orders (e.g., estates, Stande), craft producers (e.g., guilds) and state-licensed preindustrial commercial and manufacturing companies structurally prefigured neocorporatist forms and processes of representation. At the

same

time, neocorporatism

cratization,

economies.

is

a response to the concentration, bureau-

and interdependence of producer

interests in industrial

Demand Groups and

251

The neocorporatist model

Pluralist Representation

posits vested, hierarchical, monopolistic,

and compulsory apex bodies for producer interests organized in firms, unions, and professional associations.^ Led by bureaucratic professionals, apex bodies negotiate with each other and with state agencies to gain benefits, avoid losses, and concert policy in well-established poHcy arenas. State civil servants and apex body professional bureaucrats shape policy agendas and bargain over the formulation of policy for whole industries, sectors, or the national economy. Whether by de facto appropriation or de jure command, apex bodies acquire not only collective but also para-statal (public) authority that enables

govern and compel "members"



them

to

the individuals involved in firms, unions, and professional associations as well as the lesser intermediate organizations joined together in peak associations. The neocorporatist

organization and representation of interests has an elective affinity to command rather than demand politics because it favors state over voter sovereignty and public over private

Viewed

historically, pluralism in

power in policymaking. contemporary industrial democ-

been associated with older patterns of policy determination by legislatures, neocorporatism with the functional representation of organized producer and professional interests. As cabinet or presiracies has

governments have come to limit the influence of voters and interests acting through legislative representatives, the influence of the permanent government and of functionally organized producer groups has increased. The growth of oligopoly and monopoly in industry, labor, and professional markets was paralleled by the growth of hierarchical representative bodies that tended to impose policy choices rather than reflect members' preferences and to govern by compulsion rather than by consent. Under these emergent historical conditions, the pluralist vision of open, voluntary, and competitive but ultimately harmonious organized interests became harder to sustain. Concertdential

ing the functional interests of organized producers with professional

counterplayers in the permanent government was said to be a better

way

and public power and private and public interests than pluralism's invisible hand guiding many competitive and conflicting interests to outcomes that were in the public interest. As neocorporatist representation, bargaining, and concertation in statesanctioned policy arenas became more institutionalized, they tended to reconcile private

to rival or displace not only legislative determination of policy but also pluralist representation.

Anglo-American world that is the home of pluWestern Europe, Japan, and Latin America have proved more

In contrast to the ralism,^

252

DEMAND GROUPS

hospitable to neocorporatism. State-society relations in India are closer

Anglo-American relations than to those of the continental European world. India's associational life has not moved in the direction of a few monopolistic and compulsory apex bodies, capable of hierarchical domination of members' choices, but rather sustains a large variety of competitive associations, especially in the fields of labor and industry. In 1975, the Indira Gandhi authoritarian regime attempted to displace pluralist by neocorporatist forms in the organization and representation of interests. This effort proved abortive when the electorate in 1977 repudiated authoritarian rule and with it the initial attempts at state corporatism. What distinguishes Indian from Anglo-American pluralism is the emergence of the demand group as a representational form especially responsive to the unorganized sector, the extraordinary multiplication and fragmentation of pluralist associations that we call involution, and the role of the state sector, which crowds organized interests to the margin of the political and policy arenas and to

fragments their potential countervailing power.

The Demand Group

as Pluralist

Actor in

Politics

and Policy

examining Indian pluralism, we conceive of interest groups as encompassing two forms: organized interests and demand groups. We use the term "demand groups" to signal that this unit of Indian pluralism is different from organized interests in other industrial democracies. Formally organized interests exist in India and affect statesociety relations and the policy process but they have not been as important as demand groups, a more spontaneous and less formed type of collective action. The demand group is a form that interest representation can take in competitive, open democracies when political In

mobilization of mass publics outstrips or overflows the formal institu-

Demand

groups are an expression of movement and issue politics. They do not replace organized interests so much as they incorporate and transcend them. Unlike movement politics in other industrial democracies, which is usually an alternative

tions of the political process."*

and competitive with organized interests, movement politics in India tends to complement formally organized interest groups. By raising new issues and mobilizing support for them, demand groups transform state and national policy agendas and gain bargaining advantages.

to

Formally organized interests work arenas.

They attempt

and sometimes party

in institutionally defined policy

to influence legislatures, bureaucratic agencies,

policy.

They develop elaborate organizational

in-

Demand Groups and

253

Pluralist Representation

means of internal communication to members and external communication to relevant publics, and research staffs. Their means of influence include technical and professional expertise and legal and legislative skills. The idea of frastructure, including a headquarters bureaucracy,

an organized interest group implies a certain professionalization of the representative process.

The

force of

its

case rests at least as

much on

on the pressure of numbers. Demand groups, by contrast, do not w^ork primarily in institutionally defined policy arenas. They rely less on expertise and lobbying skill than on symbolic and agitational politics. The tactics and style of demand groups have become a highly elaborated political art form that technical persuasiveness as

speaks to India's indigenous political culture, mobilizes support, influences public opinion, and gains bargaining advantages. Its ad hoc and

spontaneous

tactics include public

dramas such

cal pilgrimages), hartals (shutdowns), rasta

as padyatras (politi-

rokos (road blocks), and

gheraos (lock-ins). The grandfather of such public dramas w^as Mohandas Gandhi's salt march to the sea in 1930. One of the more striking

postindependence manifestations was agrarian leader Charan Singh's eightieth "birthday party" in 1979, when one hundred thousand

North Indian cultivators arrived at Delhi's Boat Club grounds by tractor and bullock cart to attend the extravaganza. Interest groups work more in camera, demand groups out of doors. Demand groups tend to agitate first and bargain later. The force of their case rests on its dramatic visibility and demonstration of massive support and sometimes on the disruption of public services. The transactions of organized interest groups take place between their knowl-

edgeable professions and bureaucratic counterplayers, while the transactions of organized interest groups take place between their knowl-

edgeable professionals and bureaucratic counterplayers, while the transactions of demand groups take place between supporters mobi-

an issue on the one hand and governmental elites and public opinion on the other. While the organized interests represent dockworkers, steelworkers, functionally specific producer interests tobacco growers demand groups represent whole sectors agricullized in favor of







specific interests.

The demand group escapes some of the oligarchical aspects of formally organized interests: dominance by the organization's bureaucrats and professionals ("the iron law of oligarchy") and derrepresent or ignore the less well placed

taged

among

potential constituencies.

a propensity to un-

members and

Demand groups

the disadvan-

arise

when

or-

ganized interests and political parties fail to represent or reach them. Because demand groups attempt to mobilize large numbers, they must

DEMAND GROUPS

254

appeal to and involve the poor and pov^erless even liver

if

they do not de-

equal benefits to them.

The

natural habitat of the

demand group

is

India's

unorganized

economy, v^hich outnumbers the organized economy nine to one. While there is far from an absolute correlation betv^een the presence of formal interest organizations and location in the organized sector of the economy, organized interests are more common and effective in the organized sector. At the same time, the scale of the unorganized economy (agriculture, small-scale industry, and commerce) affects the balance between organized interests and demand groups in Indian politics and policy. Demand groups share the less bureaucratized and less professional character of producers in the unorganized economy. The difference between organized interests and demand groups is also shaped by different levels of consciousness and articulation. As producers and as voters, potential supporters of demand groups have had little or no experience with organized representation and participatory politics. Organized interests assume that there is a "group" with an interest that it knows and wishes to advance.^ The problem is to represent a manifest interest. The demand group has yet to recognize itself; it is still "becoming." The problem of demand groups is to create the group consciousness of an interest as well as to represent it. Demand groups are lineal descendants of the "opinion out of doors" and "self-appointed" and "self-serving associations" that, according to Edmund Burke and George Washington, threatened republican government and representative democracy. Today, as in the late eighteenth century, the "opinion out of doors" that demand groups mobilize is perceived by authorities and vested interests as threatening governability. But "world time" casts a different light on demand groups in contemporary India. Universal suffrage, associational life, organized opinion, and political parties have become, as they were not in the late eighteenth century, legitimate aspects of representative democracy. The "opinion out of doors" that helped to establish civil, political, and, later, social rights was thought to be an unfortunate and dangerous aberration that could be eliminated once its goals were achieved. But this was not to be the case. Persisting discrepancies between formal

and actual inequality of political and economic power justified the persistence of issue and movement politics. Demand groups persist but create dilemmas. They perfect democracy and promote more equal bargaining by mobilizing voters and lower constituencies slighted or ignored by organized interests. But they create problems of governability when they jeopardize public order and a government

equality

of laws.

Demand Groups and

255

Pluralist Representation

Indian Variants of Pluralism

The

group pluralism as an explanatory social science concept has been vitiated by the anomalies and contradictions that have accompanied its application in industrial democracies. Nevervalidity of interest

remains, with class-based theories, one of the reigning paradigms for explaining state-society relations in governance and policy. theless,

it

Efforts to keep the theory viable have

the

paradigm but make

variants

we

produced variants that recognize

amendments or innovations. Two explaining state-society relations and the state-dominated pluralism and involuted

significant

find helpful for

policy process in India are pluralism.

Under state-dominated pluralism, the political arena is populated by relatively autonomous interest groups, but they are overshadowed by an omnipresent state. Much of the organizational and representational "space" occupied by pluralist actors and processes in the AngloAmerican world and by societal corporatism in Western Europe is occupied in India by state agencies. This is not surprising in a state that opted, in the industrial policy resolutions of 1948 and 1956, for a

mixed economy in which the public sector would dominate the "commanding heights"; that nationalized finance capitalism banks and insurance in the 1960s; and that had at its command a proliferating series of state long-term lending institutions. By occupying the comanding heights of industrial and finance capital, the state also came to occupy the commanding heights of the representational infrastructure. At the same time, the line between the public and private sectors has become increasingly obscure, as state-controlled lending institutions and equity holders (e.g., the Life Insurance Corporation of







India, the Unit Trust of India)

— have

acquired sufficient equity in

private-sector firms to give them, potentially, the

power

to control

management.

The pervasiveness

and most

of the state in India also affects professional

occupational associations that occupy autonomous space in

other industrial democracies. While the "free professions" constitute a significant part of the

autonomous

associations in which middle-class

society organizes itself in Europe, this

is

less true in India.

The

vast

majority of doctors, scientists, engineers, teachers, and professors are

employees of government organizations. Because government is the generally principal employer of managers, technicians, and clerics speaking, the white-collar class

— the



interests of India's noncapitalist,

non-property-owning middle classes are closely related to those of the state.

DEMAND GROUPS

256

prominence does not mean that there are no arenas autonomy. The poHtical sociologist tells a different story of group than the political economist does. Religious communities, caste asa large range of sociations, cultural, ethnic and linguistic groups nonproducer social forces generally cannot be closely regulated or manipulated by the state. Although in the economic arena the state occupies much of the "space" occupied in America and Europe by pluralist and corporatist forces, in the social arena it occupies less. As a consequence, it faces powerful political and policy challenges from cultural, ethnic, and linguistic groups. The state dominates pluralist representation through its direction of the policy process as well as through its control of public-sector industrial and finance capital and its employment of professionals. The state controls the policy agenda, (e.g., policy initiatives and choice); it directs, through the use of incentives and sanctions, the organizational and market behavior of organized interests, firms, and industries; and it powerfully influences particular policy arenas by establishing favored relationships with one among a plurality of organized interests

The

state's





in that arena.

The Stanley

state controls the policy

Kochanek put

it

agenda to a remarkable degree. As

in his Business

and

Politics in India:

come from government

not from the larger society ... so most groups are forced to take a negative or defensive rather than a positive stance ... the pattern of public polhas concentrated vast powers in the hands of government icy .. officials. This power enables them to control and regulate the internal affairs and external conduct of business, trade unions, and other Far from being ... an outcome of interest group organizations. activity, as group theory would have it, public policy in India exerts a significant impact on group mobilization and on behavior.^

Policy initiatives usually

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

State control of the policy

agenda

is

most

clearly expressed in the Plan-

ning Commission's perspective, five-year, and annual plans. Inter alia, targets for most of the investment in the organized economy and for infrastructure (power, irrigation, transport, etc.) are set by Planning



Commission allocations. State incentives and sanctions what critics are exercised through at home and abroad call "permit-license raj" governmental licensing of production and production levels, control of foreign exchange and imports, and determination of agricultural prices and input costs. The state's monopoly of credit, together with its taxing powers, provides it with extraordinarily powerful means to encourage or deter market and organizational behavior.



Demand Groups and

257

The

Pluralist Representation

establishment of a special relationship with one of many organized interests in particular policy arenas is best illustrated by the arena of industrial relations, where the state, under Congress governstate's

ments, has maintained a special relationship with the Indian National Trade Union Conference (INTUC). Congress party governments have been in power at the center almost continuously since independence,

and

INTUC

has generally followed the party's

ment's and the state's

monopoly



policy line.

INTUC

— and thus the govern-

does not have a licensed

would be the case under neocorporatist arrangements. Its relationship with state agencies and the Congress-I party sometimes becomes strained when it tries to maintain both its competitive position in a pluralist universe and its special relationship with Congress governments. But without government support and patronage, INTUC could not have remained India's largest trade union federation, and without INTUC collaboration. Congress govto represent organized labor as

ernments could not have been as successful as they have in manipulating and controlling organized labor and industrial relations policy.

The second

found in India is involuted pluralism, one of the ways the state has dominated interest group pluralism. ^'Involution" refers to a continuing process and resultant strucdistinctive pluralist variant

tural condition, the excessive multiplication of less effectual units.

leading example

is

A

the agricultural involution that Geertz observed.^

Pluralist involution contrasts with the oligopolistic

and monopolistic

tendencies of interest group pluralism that can eventuate in neocorporatism. We use involution as a metaphor for the decline or loss of vigor that results

when

a viable intensively elaborated pattern of

development is extensively elaborated by continuous replication of units. Such replication not only weakens each successive unit but also weakens all units collectively and thus the activity as a whole. In this sense,

more becomes

less.

Involution

is

thus a regressive, debilitating

process that results in decreasing effectiveness or entropy, the reverse of evolution.

We

showed in chapter 1 how change in industrial capitalism includes a mild form of involution, as smaller private-sector firms are encouraged to multiply by government incentives and deterrents (chapter 1, table 5). In chapter 10, on organized workers as a demand group, we show a more pronounced process of involution as an increasing number of trade unions compete for a limited constituency of easily organized workers. In both instances, the effect of involution able the state to manipulate an increasing

number

of

weaker

is

to en-

units. In-

voluted pluralism as a form of representational mediation strengthens

command In

politics

summary,

and weakens demand

politics.

pluralist representation in India

is

distinguished by

two

DEMAND GROUPS

258 novel actors interest

— the demand group and the

— and

two novel

state as the largest

structural variants

producer

— state-dominated

plu-

ralism and involuted pluralism. These elements of the representational infrastructure have an independent effect

command and demand of

demand

pluralism, politics.

politics,

politics.

while the

Demand

on the prevailing balance

of

groups favor the ascendancy

state's role as

producer, state-dominated

and involuted pluralism favors the ascendancy of command

IO

Involuted Pluralism

and

Domination of the Industrial Relations Regime State

demand group to which we turn is organized labor, a major participant in the demand poHtics that escalated in the 1960s. Labor's demands became more prominent as the public sector expanded and

The

first

organized labor's role within

it

grew. While private employment in the

organized sector grew slowly after 1966

and 1981

—9

percent between 1966

— public employment increased by 69 percent, almost 5 per-

cent per year

percent for

compared with 2 percent

GNP. This

for population

and about 3.5

rapid expansion of state instrumentalities, from

nationalized banks through steel plants, fueled an increase of govern-

ment consumption expenditures and contributed to the decline in public investment over the 1965—75 period. The 69 percent growth in public employment was due in part to the nationalization of key industries, notably insurance and banking, in part to ad hoc responses to the problem of unemployment among the educated, and in part to diffuse patronage pressures to create and allocate jobs.' High inflation rates from 1966 to 1968, and again from 1973 to 1975, indexed to cost-ofliving ("dearness") allowances for public employees, exacerbated the

problems of paying for so substantial an addition to the work force. As the numbers and proportions of the organized-sector work force increased, the rate of strikes, lockouts, and labor unrest also increased dramatically (chapter 8, table 23). These developments paralleled the ballooning of student enrollment in higher education and the stuParadoxically, even while organized

dent unrest that accompanied

it.

labor was extremely active,

influence

its

on

politics

and policy did not

increase.

Organizedjaborjiasnot been able to olog>rand

politics, that

suggested in chapter tics

— labor and

arena. Neither

1

is

TtolrTourvror^upport a

that the

capital

ch^llenge^2?dia's^ centrist, ide-

two

left class

We

traditional adversaries in class poli-

— are marginal

forces in the Indian political

finds expression in political parties.

political marginality of

party.

We

attributed the

organized labor to several factors: workers in

the^orgamz^feconomy,^^ lOpercent of the total wo^forcej^the state^hich employs two-thirds of the^wo rkerslri the organi z ed econ^rny, constitutes an ambigu ous

259

DEMAND GROUPS

260

adversary because of

its

claims to be a

mgdd employer and the vehicle

and the multipli£ation and rivalry of national federations and oF industry and enterprise unions lead_to the progresfor socialist objectives;

sive inyprutioiT of the trade

O^J^^

uiii^^^^^^^

In exploring the state-dominated industrial relations in India,

have stressed the nexus between labor and the state. verges from the emphasis

common

Europe and America, w^hich is

in w^riting

on

control.^ India invites a focus

capital's relations to labor,

industrial relations in

because the state

work

on the is

many

it

place hierarchy,

state's rather

than

most important between labor and

labor's

counterpTayer. Even where relations^ are prirnarily capital, the state controls

we

analysis di-

stresses the labor-capital relationship as

revealed in the w^ork place, bargaining power,

and worker

Our

of the interac tions that elsewhere

fall

""

realm of collective bargaining. begin this chapter by characterizing the conditions that separate labor in the organized and unorganized sectors and that distinguish the labor force in the organized sector into a hierarchy of more and in the

^e

less

privileged strata.

We

then examine structural and ideological

forces that have shaped the industrial relations regime

organized labor to a marginal role in national

Trade Union Militancy and

Its

and confined

politics.

Failures

The expectations of public employees in the 1967-74 period, when the left Kumaramangalam faction was ascendant in the Congress, were shaped by the "socialist" orientation of Mrs. Gandhi's Congress governments. Freed from the profit and capital accumulation motives of private-sector capitalism, government firms could choose to share with their employees rather than appropriate the financial benefits of monopoly, administered prices, and tax-financed subsidies. Govern-

model employer. But government serwhile nominally dependent on the ideals and good will of their

ment, after vants,

all,

held

itself

model employer, could

to be a

also attempt to coerce the state in order to cor-

and advantages. In particular, the more skilled and privileged, who were also the best organized and most militant, used their organizational resources and capacity for mobilization to hinder, cripple, or stop the provision of services and production of goods by state agencies and public-sector firms. During this period, a number of groups struck for higher wages and better working conditions: employees of the Life Insurance Corporation of India and the rect grievances or gain benefits

261

Involuted Pluralism and Industrial Relations

nationalized banks; secretariat employees of the central and state governments; the Central Reserve Police of Uttar Pradesh; airline pilots;

doctors and engineers in the service of the central and state governments; employees of public-sector steel plants, particularly those at

Durgapur; and railv^ay employees (with two million employees, the Railway Board is India's largest employer). These strikes, inter alia, disrupted production and services and caused severe law and order problems. Table 23 in chapter 8 indicated the rapid increase in the number of workdays lost from strikes or lockouts and the number of workers involved in the period of 1961-75. Between 1965 and 1975, the number of workdays lost increased by almost 500 percent, a level of growth

over ten times greater than that for organized-sector employment.

Much

most

and conspicuous trade union activity and lower-middle-class employees whose condition was already good in comparison with that of the vast majority of the nation's wage earners. Just as Congress's INTUC did, left unions, such as the CPI- and CPI-M-affiliated All-India Trade Union Congress (AITUC) and Centre of Indian Trade Unions (CITU) took the relatively easy path of organizing and pressing demands on behalf of those who are easily organized and whose employer government responds readily. As a critic, Rakhahari Chatterji, has noted: of the

successful

benefited middle-class





The trade union little

leadership, especially of the

leftist variety,

was not

a

responsible in facilitating the government's high-handedness.

Generally, this leadership

showed

political

adventurism and social

encouragement to employees like the doctors, by highly skilled and well-paid engineers, technocrats, life insurance employees or airlines staff. When an enormous portion of the working population ... remained unorganized and severely low paid, the leftist leadership, rather than directing itself seriously towards them, opted for encouraging those struggles which were for luchi and mithai [sweets] on top of bread and butter. Consequendy, the general public was neither interested in nor sympathetic to those struggles even though they had to bear the harassment. And the unions' loss of public sympathy helped the government to put down even genuine irresponsibility

through

its

direct or indirect

strikes

struggles.^

were pyrrhic from the long-run perspective of trade unionism in India: militancy and disruption on behalf of the privileged lowered trade unions' public standing and weakened their appeal to unorganized workers. Prime Minister Gandhi could denounce unions

The

victories

^

DEMAND GROUPS

262

for economically harmful indiscipline

and

antisocial behavior.

The

agrarian party leader, Charan Singh, could castigate them as a privileged labor aristocracy and a principal beneficiary of urban parasitism.

The

union activity was nov^here more apparent than in Bengal prior to 1977. Calcutta's economic decline was hastened by violent internecine warfare among party-dominated unions, the Naxalite strategy of urban guerrilla warfare, wildcat strikes and labor indiscipline, the CPI-M's doctrine that during strikes and civil disturbances "people's" rights were more important than property rights, and sabotage in public-sector undertakings. Over the years, West Bengal usually has accounted for half or more of the workdays lost nationally: thirteen of the twenty-two million lost in 1975, nine of twelve million in 1976, and eighteen of forty million in 1979."* self-defeating nature of trade

Industrial unrest led

many

firms to close or flee elsewhere

and contrib-

uted to the recession of 1967. Between 1961 and 1971, private-sector employment declined by 13 percent as West Bengal fell from first to fourth in per capita income.

When

the

CPI-M formed

a coalition gov-

1977, a chastened, more prudent Jyoti Basu, a national leader of the CPI-M and the new chief minister, tried with only limited

ernment

in

success to reverse the deindustrialization of

what was once

India's

most

industrial state.

The Conditions

When

of Labor:

The

Privileged

and the Unprivileged

demands for higher wages and improved benefits, their demands reflected two concerns: the vicissitudes of real wages over time, and wage differentials within the organized sector. Government for its part was concerned with the relationship of emoluments in the organized sector to those in the unorganized sector. The available data on real wages does not distinguish public employees from other wage earners in the organized sector. However, we do have public employees raised

approximations that help to justify both public employees' claim that they were losing ground and charges that they were "privileged." These conflicting claims arise from the internal diversity among public employees, who include both civil servants, ranging from the lowest peon to the highest secretary to government, and employees of govern-

ment enterprises, for example, steelworkers, airline pilots, bankers, and bank clerks. These categories gain and suffer differentially, and have to be distinguished. Moreover, the private sector with which one might compare government employees is also internally diverse due to differences in the amount and quality of capital. In the Bombay area,

263

Involuted Pluralism and Industrial Relations

for example,

knowledgeable persons speak of the industrial chaturvar-

nas, the four castes, or status orders. In the mid-1970s, big multinationals, the first varna, paid workers Rs. 1,000-24,000 per month

plus benefits; big Indian firms, Rs. Rs.

350-1,100; and small

We

650-1,500; medium-sized 200-700.^

firms,

firms, Rs.

with manufacturing employees, even though the data are uneven and scattered. The real income of all manufacturing employees, a category that includes industrial workers in both public enwill start

and private

firms, remained static between the mid-sixties and the mid-seventies. The high demand-politics years of 1966-68 and 1973 were among those in which real wages declined (table 28). In 1967, wages reached an all-time low. At the same time, reports of per

terprises

capita annual earnings within the manufacturing sector

showed

great

from approximately Rs. 2,000 to Rs. 4,000.^ We surmise that the earnings of employees in public enterprises, especially central government public enterprises, were at or near the top of this range.^ There are significant wage differentials by manufacturing product, differentials that attach to levels of technology. Public enterprises do not variation,

enter the low-technology, low-paying manufacturing areas. Thus, the for 1975-76*^

Annual Survey of Industries

showed

that low-technology

and tobacco) paid average daily wages of under Rs. 10; industries using middle-range technologies (e.g., textile and paper manufacturing, machine spinning,

industries (e.g., the processing of food, beverages,

the production of clothing), Rs.

10-20; and those using mature

tech-

TABLE 28 Index of Real Earnings for Employees in Manufacturing Industries, 1962—73 Year

Index

Year

1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968

103

1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1976 1977 1978

103

94 97 95 91

94

Index

101 101 101

103 95* 100''

112 118

Sources: Government of India, Ministry of Labour, Labour Bureau, The Indian Labour Yearbook (annual) and Pocket Book of Labour Statistics, 1 983 (Chandigarh and Simla, 1983).

Note: For employees earning 'Provisional.

''New base.

less

than Rs. 400 per month.

DEMAND GROUPS

264 nologies

(e.g.,

loys, iron

and

Rs. 20-30.^°

the manufacture of plastics, petroleum, chemicals, alsteel,

When

and machine tools) (mainly in the public sector), real wages declined, as they did in 1966-68 and

1973, the decline probably affected low-paid employees in private manufacturing, especially medium- and low-technology private-sector firms, more than well-paid workers in high-technology public-sector firms.

Workers in public enterprises are relatively more protected against inflation by indexed dearness allowance programs than many workers in the private sector. (This contrast

does not hold for large, high-

technology private firms, which provide inflation protection similar to that provided by the government.) Inflation had a Umited effect on

most public employees (i.e., those receiving less than Rs. 1,000 per month) ^' because of the dearness allowance. Furthermore, government's dearness allowance and wage and salary increases have had a leveling effect on the civil service component of public employment, because they are applied progressively, that is, in ways that protect the real incomes of lower- more than higher-paid employees. ^^ Emoluments of lower-level clerks eroded only 2 percent, while emoluments of higher-level officers eroded as much as 37 percent. A similar conception of equity was leveling wages at the executive levels of public-sector industry.

^^

Income

differentials

among the more powerful and

privileged public

government wage

employees affect industrial relations. The and income structure is beset by odd and apparently irrational disparities between civil servants and those working for public-sector firms and also among the employees of public-sector industries and firms. The economic condition of employees in public enterprises central

sometimes

reflects the nationalization of private firms that

paid high

wages. The Life Insurance Corporation of India, the nationalized commercial banks, and the shipping and air corporations were viewed by

Commission on Wages and Prices (1978) as "islands of privilege." Each of these enterprises is characterized by strong, unified, even militant labor organizations. The commission showed that the Life Insurance Corporation and nationalized commercial banks paid their employees, especially those at the lower ranks, 50 to 100 percent more than did government departments.'^ The commission was torn between its preference for standardizing pay across units and the need to recognize the autonomy of public corporations and of the collective bargaining process. Public corporations wanted the freedom to strengthen commitment and improve productivity by manipulating incentives. They feared that the gray uniformity of standard wages would the

265

Involuted Pluralism and Industrial Relations

defeat such efforts. There were low-order disparities as well. Low-level class III employees at the Life Insurance Corporation received higher

pay than

class

I

employees, an instance of the egalitarian thrust of wage

policy within government." Anomalies within industries often fuel discontent as well as

and among firms and weaken incentives.

While old and new islands of privilege create disparities, the vast bulk of government employees, those earning less than Rs. 1,000 but benefiting from progressive dearness allowances, could comfort themselves with the growing equality of incomes created by substantial erosion in the emoluments of all-India and senior administrative services. For example, the real income of the most senior "privileged" IAS, which had declined appreciably betweenn 1960 and 1973, declined another 41 percent between 1973 and 1978."' The range from top to bottom of the central government's pay scale, expressed as a ratio, shrank between 1973 and 1978 from 15:1 to 10: 1.'" Government did not attempt to compete with the salaries of private firms. Along with the pressures on senior officials described in chapter 2, the declines in salary range and real income probably affected their morale and standing and may have contributed to the spread of corruption

among them. If

some workers

others, the issue of

in the

organized sector seem more privileged than

whether workers

in the

organized economy as a

whole were more privileged than those in the unorganized economy had become by 1980 a central issue in national politics. Wage and salaried workers in the organized economy (industrial and service sectors) are probably better off than agricultural laborers, most self-employed cultivators, and small household manufacturers in the unorganized economy. Given the present state of the data on income, expenditure, consumption, price levels, and benefits from public goods, it is difficult to obtain clear information about income inequality generally and about differences between the agricultural sector and unorganized economy on the one hand and the industrial sector and organized economy on the other. Nevertheless, Dharma Kumar, after reviewing disagreements and findings in the literature on income distribution, concluded (with respect to macrosectoral differences) that the decline from 51 to 44 percent in agriculture's share of total product between 1960-61 and 1969-70 "can be taken as a very rough sign that the '" ratio of average rural to urban per capita income has fallen."

The available evidence gives some additional indication of the income differences between employment in the organized and unorganized economies. According to the 1971 census, 26.3 percent of workers were agricultural laborers,'"" 43.3 percent were cultivators, 9.4

266

DEMAND GROUPS

percent were employed in manufacturing, and 8.8 percent were in

assumed that the laborers are low and approach subsistence. All

"other services" of the tertiary sector/^

It is

generally

wages of agricultural states and union territories have statutory minimum wages, ranging 1976 from Rs. 3 in Andhra Pradesh to Rs. 8 in West Bengal,^^ but the absence of official

means or unions

to enforce them, they are

in in

more

observed in the breach than in practice. Whatever the daily wage, payments in kind, or perquisites may be, for most workers they are paid

when work is 1974—75 was said

which for casual adult male workers in to average 185 days of the year.^^ Dharma Kumar, following Herdt and Baker, concluded that all-India real wages in agriculture were lower in 1968—69 than in 1954—55." On the other hand, Ahluwalia, who estimated the proportion of the rural poor under the poverty line, shows that the proportion declined between 1968 and 1974.^^ Even if, as seems to be the case, real wages in industry, as in agriculture, have remained more or less constant since independence, per capita income levels in the organized economy are much higher than those in the unorganized economy (primarily agriculture and household or small-scale production of goods and services). According to the Labour Bureau, the average per capita annual earnings of approximately 5.5 milHon workers ^^ in manufacturing industries in 1973—74 was Rs. 3,131.^^ To compare the approximate magnitude of difference between the annual per capita incomes of the organized and unorganized economies, we make the assumption that agricultural laborers worked 185 days in the same year and were paid in cash, payments in kind, or perquisites the equivalent of Rs. 3.27 per day.^^ The result would be an average annual income of Rs. 604. Differences in consumption baskets, price levels, or direct consumption of self-produced wage goods could not substantially affect the more than 5 1 income differential between industrial and agricultural workers. Again, to reach approximate magnitudes, we think it unlikely that the forty-one million or so dwarf cultivator households that is, those who operated holdcould have generings of between 0.01 and 2.5 acres in 1970-71^*^ ated incomes (in cash or kind) approaching the Rs. 3,131 annual per capita income of wage workers in manufacturing in 1973 — 74. Similar magnitude differences hold for the household industry sector. In 1971—72, the average per capita daily earning of 1.4 million workers in the household industry sector of the unorganized economy was Rs. 5.84, compared with Rs. 11.36 for those in the same industries within the organized economy, meaning that those in the unorganized economy earned about half as much as those in the organized only

available,





:





267

Involuted Pluralism and Industrial Relations

economy producing mations,

the

we conclude

same

product.^*"

of workers in the urban organized

On the basis of these approxi-

income

(if

not the consumption)

economy

is

at least twice that of

that the average

workers in the rural unorganized economy. Rural-urban differences did not emerge as a live national issue until the second half of the seventies, when the politics of the new agrarianism began to take shape. Farmers' agitations in Mahaharashtra, Tamil Nadu, Karnataka, Gujarat, and Punjab and national kisan rallies in the early eighties

made

tor's privileged position

plain that the issue of the organized sec-

it

had come of age and would be

central to the

domestic politics of that decade.

The Indian wage and income structure raises difficult problems of justice and equity in its own and in comparative contexts. Capital accumulation for Soviet industrialization was in part based on a 2 1 differential between industrial and agricultural wages and an even more pronounced difference for investment in the two sectors.'" In consequence, output grew enormously in industry but stagnated in agriculture. In India, spontaneous processes more than policy interventions :

have produced a comparable result for wages if not for capital accumulation or investment, yet output in agriculture has grown enough to give India a self-sufficiency in food grains not achieved in the Soviet

Union. Redressing the balance in favor of agriculture by improving the terms of trade and investment ratios would presumably reduce govern-

ment investment

in the industrial

more than

in the agricultural sector,

with hard to estimate consequences for economic growth and productivity of capital It is

and

difficult to

ployment

is itself

labor.

judge the extent to which the growth of public emproblematic. Does

it,

on balance, increase and im-

prove public services or promote development? National accounts

make

own

sta-

judgment when they count public employment as a "nondevelopmental" expenditure. To what extent should it be counted as alleviating unemployment among the educated? To what extent as appropriation by an autonomous, expanding, and self-interested third actor, the Indian state? tistics

their

implicit

In the organized sector, "islands of privilege" have emerged, especially

among

public employees but also

privileged layers

among

the

in the private sector.

Bombay chaturvarnas and among

As the public

enterprises suggest, such islands reflect differentials in capitalization,

technology, and

management



power. Leveling within the public sector service employees and employees of public enterprises

litical

civil

market and pofor example, between

that are associated with

to deprive public enterprises of

what

little

— threatens

autonomy and capacity

to

DEMAND GROUPS

268

anomalous position allows. Islands of privilege also reflect the capacity of workers to mobilize and organize, and the bargaining advantages their economic and political circumstances create. Disproportionate organization and mobilization of white-collar professional and skilled labor reveals that organized labor has elected to follow the path of least resistance, to work with the conscious and accessible rather than with vulnerable and dependent unskilled laborers in industry and agriculture. The doubtful assertion that in the rural sector the rich are getting richer and the poor poorer may in fact be more applicable to wage and income differentials within the organized economy. employ incentives

On

their

the other hand, not

all

public employees are privileged.

Nor

is

an industrial work force whose average real wages have stagnated since at least 1951 and probably since the turn of the century likely to feel privileged. Marked vertical as well as less marked but nevertheless strongly felt horizontal disparities among industrial workers have compounded workers' sense of injustice. In the eighties, policymakers

and spokesmen

for the

new agrarianism have increasingly drawn

atten-

and agricultural workers. Government's capacity to define and implement "acceptable inequalities" through its wages and incomes, industrial relations, and sectoral policies has been severely strained by these perceived tion to the disparity between the incomes of industrial

disparities.

The Nature

of the Industrial Relations Regime

Anglo-American interest groups.^^ Such pluralism features union-employer relations based on private and voluntary agreements among a large number of individual actors, firms, and unions and restricts state action to the regulation of entry, bargaining, and conflict. In Europe, unions often convert this competitive situation into an oligopolistic one, aspiring to the power and standing of apex organizations.^^ Their relatively India's trade unions share the competitive pluralism of

cohesive labor federations are in a position to bargain at the national

with industry associations and the state. This has not happened in India. The industrial relations regime within which Indian unions and national federations and firms operate inhibits both competitive

level

pluralism and oligopolistic competition interests. Instead, state strategies

in

which the

state,

among

organized producer

have created an involuted pluralism

by dominating the arena of industrial

conflict,

269

Involuted Pluralism and Industrial Relations

many weak and

controls

divided organizations rather than a few co-

hesive ones.

The competitive

model dominates the Indian trade unions' image of themselves and the world in which they live. Indian apex pluralist

unions are multiple;£ntry kxeJatively easy. Their internal structure is characterized less by democratic and participatory arrangements and

more by

autonomy

structural

makes

levels that

it

at regional, municipal,

difficult for national leadership to

lowers. Indian unionsjio not concert with the state.

ception

is

INTUC,

and shop

The

many

the Congress party's trade union that allows

gains from

its

semiofficial standing.

(It

fol-

possible ex-

to be co-opted, reliably complies with government's directives, rives

floor

speak for

itself

and de-

did not, for ex-

ample, participate in the 1982 strike against preventive detention and antistrike legislation.)

The prospect

model can assume the form and consequent influence of European pluralism that the Indian

oligopolistic is

made

less

likely by the radically different balance of forces that characterizes producer groups in India. When oligopolistic pluralism is successful in Western Europe, labor federations, management, and the state approach each other as relatively equal adversaries. In India, both la-

bor and employer organizations are weaker relative to the state. The growth of the public sector through the fifties and sixties, by locating

60 percent of investment and 65 percent of organized-sector employment in the public sector, has weakened the standing of private producer groups. Labor's situa tion is compromised by the fact that the socialist sj:ate_daimsjo^be;^nd_pften is, the model employer. Agreements are far more determined by state goals and interests than by '' bargains struck between employers and employees. Trade unions conceive of themselves as acting within a selfdetermining pluralist world, while in fact the industrial relations reginie_is characterized by involuted pluralism and state domination. We use the term ^'involution" as a metaphor for a decline or loss of vigor

from replication of units whose increase in number is accompanied by a decline in effectiveness. In Geertz's original metaphor, involution is used with respect to wet rice regimes to designate the intensive cultivation and overelaboration of tiny productive units in ways that results

that proved self-defeating.^^

It is

a regressive, debilitating process that

tends toward entropy, the reverse of evolution or vigor. It serves the interests of the state to keep labor fragmented and prevent it from concentrating in

its

force along oligopolistic lines, hence

policymaking and minimizing

its

political role.

weakening

On

its

voice

the other hand.

DEMAND GROUPS

270

thousands of short-run micro-interest calculations by the manifold components of the trade union sector insure that labor collaborates in

damages its collective macro-interest. The state's strategy parallels its management of private industrial capital, which is also fragmented and kept subservient by the state's occupation of the commanding heights, by licensing, regulation, and control of investment and production. State domination of the industrial arena has been shaped both by the paternalistic doctrines and practices of the administrative state under the British raj and by public choices that reflect Congress party ideology and state interests. State domination of the industrial relations regime features state-controlled compulsory procedures rather than open-ended bargaining among interested parties; the superior standing of government as an allegedly disinterested and fair third party; and its role as a spokesman for the public's interest in order, the provision of services, and the maintenance of production and development. The state believes itself responsible for imposing solutions from above. In the manner more of the civil than the common law tradition, the emoluments and working conditions that wage boards and industrial tribunals hand down for particular cases are meant to follow the disembodied principles found in legislation and in the reports of pay and other expert commissions. They are not meant to be the product the fragmentation that

of contested public policies or of open-ended collective bargaining,

based on

trials of

strength

among employers and employees. At the rhe-

good is held to be served by harmony rather than conflict. Because the demands of organized labor, like those, of other interest groups, are considered partial and self-interested, they are seen to be in conflict with the public interest and national goods. State domination stands in tension with lively and tenacious pluralist doctrine and practice. The doctrine has been shaped by Indian and international versions of the doctrine of regulated conflict and democratic trade unionism^^ and has been represented by significant spokesmen of Indian labor at each of the abortive attempts to alter the torical level, the collective

Industrial Relations Act of 1926.

It

holds that tentative approxima-

harmony and the public interest can result from regulated conand bargaining. The state should provide and apply agreed proce-

tions of flict

dures and assume a facilitative role in order to support industrial

democracy and regulated conflict. It should supervise elections to determine legitimate and representative bargaining agents, determine and validate unfair labor practices, and accept conflict in the form of open-ended collective bargaining. Regulated conflict among interested parties can be desirable and legitimate not only because it can produce

271

Involuted Pluralism and Industrial Relations

approximations of the public interest but also because the use of

power

authority and the

it

makes

available to rulers

is

partisans of a pluralist approach note that the state, as

and the

larger employer,

is

an interested party even while

state

The management suspect.

it

retains spe-

maintaining order, providing essential services, realizing development objectives, and representing organized interests. Whether involuted pluralism and state domination or regulated con-

cial responsibilities for

flict

will characterize Indian trade

unionism

in the future

depends

in

on economic as well as on political conditions. Indian trade unionism is favored by what Theda Skocpol calls "world time," recognizing that apparently similar chronological sequences have different causes and meanings because they occur in contexts transformed by prior sequences elsewhere. ^^ The efflux of world time helps workers in industrializing countries such as India to benefit from the successful struggles of workers in countries that were industrialized earlier. The historical situation of trade unions in Great Britain, the first country to be industrialized, was significantly different from that in Germany, for example, which was industrialized somewhat later, and from that in part

India, industrialized later

still. ^^

Britain denied organizing rights to

trade unions because laissez-faire doctrine held that "combinations"

and employers from entering into work contracts. Manufacturing workers were employed without benefit of factory, much less social and welfare, legislation.^^ Today, the rights of workers to combine in organizations and bargain collectively, to be protected by factory legislation, and to benefit from the social rights of restrained equally free workers

a welfare state are internationally recognized,

if

not always honored.

Workers benefit too from the fact that factory acts and have become conventional attributes of welfare states.

social rights

Yet later industrializing states share the suspicion their predecessors

entertained for

all

interest groups.

Those who ruled eighteenth-century

Britain suspected the mobilization of "opinion out of doors" by orga-

nized associations, because they did not regard popular participation as legitimate.

while they

The

may

rulers of late industrializing states such as India,

accept democratic participation, continue to fear asso-

ciations because they threaten the

formed or vulnerable Trends

in the

autonomy and

interests of

weakly

states.

nature and composition of the Indian

work

force differ

the postindustrial democracies.

from recent developments in Although India has already become the world's fifteenth-largest industrial economy,'" its work force and labor movement are experiencing very different changes than those in the advanced or postindustrial economies of America and Western Europe. In America and Western greatly

DEMAND GROUPS

272

Europe, a decreasing proportion of workers are employed

in industrial

and the rate of increase in office (white-collar) jobs is declining. Workers in low-skilled, low-paid, and unorganized personal service employment (e.g., fast food restaurants) and in high-skilled, high-paid, but unorganized knowledge and communications industry jobs are becoming a larger proportion of the work force. Partly as a result of such changes in the composition of the work force and partly as a result of related changes in ideological and political conditions, organized labor in "advanced" economies is in decline as a bargaining force in the economy and in electoral and policy domains. Even parties on the left have found that, because they have to rely increasingly on middle-class support to win elections and govern, they have to repre(blue-collar) jobs,

sent middle-class interests as

much

as

— or more than — working-class

interests.

In India,

by contrast, trends and developments

in the

composition

and organization of the work force and in the labor movement remain favorable to the economic, political, and policy prospects of organized labor. Not only is industrial and office employment still on the rise absolutely and proportionately but India's middle-class professionals (e.g., doctors, engineers, and airline pilots) are also disproportionately unionized and militant compared with those in America and Western Europe. While unorganized agricultural workers in India, like the lowskilled or unskilled workers in personal service jobs in the West, inhibit the economic bargaining and political and policy influence of organized labor, it seems likely in the 1980s that they will become increasingly organized and militant, as they have already done in Kerala and parts of Tamil Nadu.'*^ In the face of Indian unions' better prospects

often high levels of labor unrest, analysts

and the fluctuating but

and leaders continue

to differ

over whether labor's and the country's interests are better served by the present pattern of state-dominated pluralism or by a regulated conflict.

Some

commitment

to

argue, for example, that the Congress-I gov-

ernment's July 1981 ordinance,^' which formalized already extant discretionary authority to declare strikes illegal, was necessary if not de-

strengthened government's hand in guiding and controlling industrial relations in ways required for order and development.^^ Others find that pervasive state guidance and control is the sirable,

because

it

problem, not the solution.

It

shortcircuited the development of re-

sponsible representation and bargaining by denying or obfuscating real conflicts of interests behind a facade of economic and administrative rationality. flict

The

and regulated condemocracy and the further narrowing of

failure of collective bargaining

to strengthen industrial

273

Involuted Pluralism and Industrial Relations

the right to strike will continue to drive conflicts of interests

among

employees, employers, and the state into the streets, where agitations and violence breed repression and counterviolence. State management in the face of

an expanding, better-organized, and better-coordinated

movement

labor

is

likely to

exacerbate the vicious circle of extremism

by workers and the state. Seven conditions Kav^^ontributedto the present balance of forces bemeen labor and the state, t o the we akness of trade unions, and to the strength of state initiatiyes:

The emergency regime of 1975-77 strengthened management of industrial relations. 1.

corporatist

has created a legal and procedural environment that encourages unions to depend for recognition and benefits on govern2. State policy

ment and management more than on pacity to represent

its

interests.

their

3.

The

relative

it

their ca-

Many unions have collaborated to per-

petuate this procedural environment where particular actors even while

membership and

favors their interests as

it

disfavors the position of labor in general.

abundance of cheap labor and

a labor

market domi-

nated by unskilled labor, a condition general to developing economies, weakens the capacity of trade unions to bargain effectively. This condibeing increasingly modified in the Indian case by the exception-

tion

is

ally

rapid development of technical and professional classes that are

not averse to unionization. 4.

The

ideological, partisan,

and

territorial

fragmentation of unions

and the much more rapid proliferation of unions than of unionized workers weaken the capacity of organized labor to affect economic bargaining, political competition, and policy formulation. Proliferating unions have tended to struggle of a relatively fixed

sum 5.

sum

among

themselves over the control

of organized workers rather than

expand the

of organized workers.

The world view

of

dominant

elites, for a

mixture of bureaucratic

and neotraditionalist reasons, values efficiency and harmony. It distrusts and opposes the concept of regulated conflict on normative grounds, as irregular, chaotic, and disharmonious. 6. Wage and income policy has evolved as an extension of the Indian bureaucracy's technocratic efforts to regulate its own pay and benefits structure, treating employees in the public sector on the "pay commission" model, as if they were an extension of the state services, rather than attempting to develop a distinct political and social policy for the economic consequences of an emerging working class. 7.

cial

The

state has

won wide

acceptance for

responsibility for nation building

its

claim that

it

has a spe-

and economic development.

DEMAND GROUPS

274

This claim impinges on industrial relations, creating the need for labor commitment and discipline, uninterrupted production and productiv-

growth, and low wages to boost saving and capital formation. These determinants are all central to the present balance of forces in the Indian industrial relations regime. We will examine each in light of ity

the evolving political and economic situation in India and trends in the

nature of the

work

Two

force.

qualifications should be noted. First,

by place and time.

trade union activity varies

It is

subject to phases or

moods induced by events and developments in salient political environments. Ahmedabad with its legacy of Gandhian consensualism and Calcutta with

its

competitive radicalism create different contexts

The

for trade union activity.

legalism and consultationism that charac-

was succeeded by militancy.'*^ Second, the determinants we analyze are neither immutable nor wholly determining of involution and weakness. When we examine the prospects for industrial relations in the late eighties at the end of this account, we will discuss alternative possibilities based on organized labor's changing relationship to management and the state. terized

Bombay from

the mid-fifties to the mid-sixties

The Emergency Regime Management of Labor The emergency regime

as

of

an Experiment

1975-77

in Corporatist

contributed to the involution and

weakness of trade unions. Trade union demands and labor "unrest" were conspicuous among the factors leading to the emergency. As Rakhahari Chatterji has noted, "In an important sense, the Emergency was about the working class." The emergency was preceded by a railway workers' strike that shook the country in May 1974. It was the first political challenge by a trade union to the central government at the national level. The strike, by a multimillion-member union in the state sector, revealed the weakness of established industrial relations doctrine and practice and the state's vulnerability to a unified national challenge.^' It also demonstrated that opportunistic trade union rivalry easily destroys unity and that state repression could be sufficiently ruthless and systematic to break India's largest combination of industrial workers. The strike was never wholly effective."*^ Within three weeks, Mrs. Gandhi's government had broken it. Its repression greatly demoralized the trade union movement and led its leaders to shift their strategy from primary attention to the working class to one that stressed middle-class professionals and white-collar

political

'^'^

employees.

275

Involuted Pluralism and Industrial Relations

After the emergency

was declared, the Congress government extended long-established mechanisms designed to promote "harmonious" relations between workers and employers, in ways that sought to strengthen corporatist linkages in industrial relations.

Within weeks

of the emergency proclamation, government established a National

Apex Body (NAB), composed

of twelve trade union

and eleven em-

ployer representatives, to deal with industrial relations in the private sector/'' Three of the four principal party-related trade unions (INTUC [Congress],

AITUC

but CITU, the

up

[CPI],

CPI-M

and Hind Mazdoor Sabha

affiliate,

[socialist]) joined,

did not participate. At least ten states set

parallel bodies. Bipartite national

committees were brought into

being by the central government in major private industries. In the

name

of

worker participation

management,

governments also established or revived bipartite committees at the shop floor and enterprise levels for all public and private firms employing more than five hundred persons. The two-tiered committees were composed of nomiin

state

nated representatives of labor and management. Apex-level national consultative committees were formed for dustries: steel

and

coal.

The terms

two major public-sector

in-

of reference of such industry-level

committees included production targets, wage levels, and welfare measures. In announcing the steel industry committee, ministry sources pointed out that "labour participation and cooperation had been the

main factors responsible for the record steel production from April to October in 1975." ^« The NAB approach abandoned the tripartism of the Indian Labour Conference and the Standing Labour Committee, moribund since 1971. It built on the rival bipartite approach to industrial relations found in the works committees and joint management councils established by the Industrial Disputes Act of 1947 and the additional legislation of 1958.^'

The earlier tripartite organizations were strongly state corporatist. The state rejected any trade union voice in setting agendas for the Indian Labour Conference and the Standing Labour Committee meetings

and

restricted labor

bodies.

management

By comparison,

to a strictly consultative role in these

the structure of

NAB

seemed more responsive

to trade union preferences for bipartite industrial relations organiza-

and for the voluntary, open-ended collective bargaining they implied. Such appearances were deceptive. The substitution of bipartism for tripartism under the emergency regime was spurious because of the tions

tacit

but powerful leading strings implicit

and repression and

that government's threatening rhetoric

in

government's intimidation

more production for less and actions supported.

the explicit policy of

cost

DEMAND GROUPS

276

The emergency regime preempted bargaining on key

issues

when

it

froze wages, phased out the wage-based 8.33 percent annual bonus/^

transferred increments in the dearness allowance to a compulsory sav-

and de facto banned strikes. Government's objective in which had been creating the NAB was to put industrial relations "bedevilled by strife, indiscipline and neglect of production and proon an "even keel," a euphemism for higher production ductivity" with lower labor costs.^* For about a year, this objective was achieved. The NAB responded to the prime minister's appeal for "harmony and higher production" by unanimously approving a proposal to achieve industrial peace." The government also asked the NAB to concern itself with wider policy questions, such as the proposal for a seven-day workweek and the question of what to do about layoffs in a recession." However, a rash of wildcat strikes and an upturn in the price level early ings scheme,





1977 revealed the short-term viability of corporatist compulsion. The corporatist approach to management of producer interests in the organized economy generally, and in industrial relations in particular, was not merely a formulation of the emergency. As will become apparent, emergency methods were an exaggerated and repressive version of the more general Indian approach to industrial relations comin

mon

to national centrist parties.

The Procedural Environment and Trade Union Dependency

A

second condition of trade union involution is the state's industrial relations policy as expressed under normal competitive politics. The state has created a legal and procedural environment that induces unions to depend on government and management more than on their

membership

for recognition as bargaining agents

and

for dispute

setdement." Three procedural issues are at stake: the absence of a secret ballot, the absence of a single bargaining agent, and the strong restraints

on

strikes.

Under present

legislation, trade

union support

in

determined by counting the names on membership rolls, which are easily manipulated records, rather than by what opponents India

call

is

the "populist"

method

of secret ballot elections. Present legislation

also facilitates the multiplication of bargaining agents in the terprise, a situation in

manipulate the

same en-

which management or government can

easily

rivals.

Because check-off authorizations rather than secret ballot elections determine the extent of a union's support and because only rarely can one union qualify as the sole negotiating agent, workers in an enter-

277

Involuted Pluralism and Industrial Relations

prise or industry are often represented

by

unions more interested each other than against management. These procedures assume that powerful friends and patrons in management politics are more helpful in securing members and benefits than is collecrival

in scoring against

tive bargaining backed by the threat of strike. Strikes are legal under very limited circumstances. Unions must, in any case, go through draw^n-out procedures prior to striking. As a result, strikes are often

acts of desperation as well as illegal. ^^

Unions usually shy away from them, preferring instead to rely on compulsory adjudication and failing that, arbitration procedures that government in any case often requires.

Trade union demands for more competitive and open-ended procedures have been lukewarm at best. Because

INTUC,

for long the

largest national labor federation, has been affiliated since in

1947 with the

ruling Congress party,

it

its

creation

has had good reason for col-

laborating with the present state-dominated arrangements. Using the

advantages gained from Congress's incumbency, it became more influential than AITUC, the labor federation Congress despaired of con-

and whose leadership eventually passed into CPI hands. Given INTUC's strong vested interest in procedures that minimize competi-

trolling

has favored verification of extant registers as a basis of

tion,

it

tion

and opposed

election based

on

secret ballot.^^

Its

certifica-

opposition to

the secret ballot has been a significant element in the failure of

Con-

governments to commit themselves to competitive procedures. ^^ On the other hand, several smaller apex unions affiliated with opposition parties also have a vested interest in procedures that reward gress

weak

unions.

Opposed

to a single bargaining agent, they support the

present proportionate representation and bargaining arrangements that enable minority unions to participate in negotiations with agement.^**

They

man-

also support corporatist bipartite or tripartite bodies

that enable the smaller federations to participate in national policy

formulation.

The unions on

the

left

have also given only ambivalent support to

noncorporatist procedures. Because two of the three largest national federations,

CPI

split)

AITUC and CITU

(founded

are connected with the

two

in

1970, six years after the

principal

Communist

parties,

CPI and the CPI-M, they espouse the ideological view that industrial relations must reflect the interests of the working class and that AITUC's organized labor is at the forefront of progressive forces. ideological line has been beset with contradictions and ambiguities. The S. A. Dange faction, ascendant until the emergency and active unthe

^"^

til

Dange was expelled from

the party in 1981, supported a strategy of

DEMAND GROUPS

278

what it perceived as the progressive Congress party of Jawaharlal Nehru and his daughter, Indira Gandhi. CITU, whose party patron, the CPI-M, has governed in Bengal and Kerala, has tried to take a line more independent of the state. Yet it too has found it prudent to adapt to the legal and economic conditions that make trade unions dependent on the state. Because the state, INTUC, and most national federations have a alliance with

vested interest in the system of corporatist dependency, they pay only lip service to

the widely accepted goal of open-ended collective bar-

gaining based on a single bargaining agent and the right to strike.

The

ambivalence of both unions and the state with respect to procedures such as the secret balthat would institutionalize regulated conflict



lot,

the single bargaining agent,

strike

— has stalemated

and

a

wide scope for the right to

reform industrial relations. The Janinitiatives of 1978 and 1980 both found-

efforts to

and Congress legislative ^° ered on the rock of this ambivalence. The pervasiveness of compulsory adjudication and arbitration and the increasingly limited circumstances under which strikes are legal perpetuates government's tutelary relationship to unions. Government ata

dominance of dispute settlement procedures begins with the requirements for conciliation of the Industrial Disputes Act of 1947, the main legislative instrument of government intervention in labor affairs. Together with similar state acts, it mandated compulsory conciliation in disputes affecting essential services and optional conciliation for other cases. The National Commission on Labour noted as early as 1969 that "the optional provisions appear to be acquiring compulsory status in non-public utilities also."^* As government, via legislative and discretionary measures, narrowed the conditions and terms under which legal strikes could occur, the use of compulsory adjudication and arbitration expanded. One of the most frequent causes of industrial disputes and certainly the most vital issue for labor's economic interest is wage determination.^^ It is an area in which government's role is also dominant. As the Labour Bureau's 1974 report on wage fixation in industry and agriculture noted, "wage determination in India is mostly done by state action and compulsory arbitration, while collective agreements play an ^^ important part on matters of wage fixation in foreign countries." Recommendations over time by ad hoc administrative bodies and pay commissions appointed by government are the source of policy for wage regulation. When such recommendations are endorsed by government, they are implemented by quasi-expert, quasi-judicial boards and tribunals. Meant to be autonomous bodies, these institutions de-

279

Involuted Pluralism and Industrial Relations

termine wages on the basis of case law procedures. One might instance the Rau Court of Inquiry of 1940, which set a dearness allowance (D.A.) for railroad employees, thus launching the general practice of

paying D.A.'s, or the Central Pay Commission of 1947, which established norms for considering how much price rises should be neutralized via D.A.'s for different

income

levels.

These seminal recom-

mendations in turn influenced the determinations of wage boards, whose heyday was in the fifties but which almost vanished from the scene until revived by the Congress-I government in April 1981.''^ Established for different industries, these boards were

composed

of

man-

agement, labor, and independent experts appointed by government. Government described them as an alternative to collective bargaining, but the National Commission on Labour saw them as an obstacle to

The recommendations of such ad hoc administrative bodies and of wage boards are applied to specific disputes, in cases that constitute a body of precedent (e.g., Madras Press Labour Union, Madras v. Artisan Press, Ltd., Madras) by a network of labor collective bargaining.

courts

— the

industrial tribunals of various states, the

late Tribunal,

The Easy

and the

All India Industrial Tribunal.^^

Path: Organizing Skilled Labor

The macroeconomic circumstances

omy

Labour Appel-

of labor in an industrializing econ-

and bargaining capacities of trade unions. Abundant and cheap labor has limited the economic leverage of trade unions in most industrializing countries, and so has seriously constrain the organizing

the undifferentiated, unskilled nature of the labor required in low-

technology industries. The exception to the prevalence of abundant

and cheap labor was America, where until well into the nineteenth century, abundant land limited the availability of labor for industry and farm earnings put a floor under industrial wages. The first of these constraints on trade unions, abundant and cheap labor, is more ^''

significant for India than the second, the unskilled nature of the labor force. In the

ment

framework

of "world time," Indian

economic develop-

since independence has involved a high proportion of skilled

workers employed in industries based on mature or advanced technology or in a rapidly growing tertiary (service) sector. It is much more difficult for trade unions to organize or bargain on behalf of unskilled and semiskilled workers who are easily replaced than on behalf of skilled workers whose skill constitutes a monopoly of sorts. The de facto organizing and bargaining strategies of Indian trade unions have

DEMAND GROUPS

280

featured skilled industrial, white-collar, and professional workers,

while their often Marxist-inspired rhetoric has featured the struggle for working-class rights and power. Trade unions have taken advantage of the scarcity value of skilled labor while avoiding the challenge of

organizing the unskilled. Despite affiliation with parties that purport

working class, their approach has been more like the skilled-labor strategy of Samuel Gompers' American Federation of Labor than the working-class strategies initially pursued by the German Social Democrats or the British Labour party. The result has been to focus trade union attention on a relatively small fixed sum of easily organized and strategically positioned workers rather than on expanding the sum of organized workers by reaching less accessible, more vulner-

to speak for the

able ones.

The Conditions The most

for Involution: Enervating Replication

measure of the labor movement's involution is its progressive fragmentation. The labor movement is fragmented at the apex as well as at the level of local industries and firms. At the apex, trade union federations are fragmented along ideological and party lines. In the period of 1920—28 and again in 1938—40, there was only one national federation (AITUC) but by 1970—74 there were eleven. ^^ At the local level, such fragmentation is compounded by the mushrooming growth of unions that results from competition among trade union entrepreneurs, many of them pawns of party or management. They establish themselves on the industrial scene under cover of legislation that allows certification on the basis of as few as seven members.^^ Fragmentation at both the national and local level is exacerbated by government and management manipulation of the diverse and divided unions to assure acceptable representation and favorable policy and dispute outcomes. Trade union membership statistics, incomplete and inadequate though they are, support the notion of progressive fragmentation. For statistical purposes, there are three types of unions: those that do not bother to register themselves and are therefore statistically invisible, those that register themselves but do not respond to the reporting requirement for information about their membership size, and those that register and "submit returns," including information on membership. The Trade Unions Act of 1926 does not require registration. The significant

probably quite significant; it may be as large as one-third to one-half the number of officially recognized

number

of unregistered unions

is

281

Involuted Pluralism and Industrial Relations

unions (table 29) with one-fourth as many members.^*^ "Registered'* unions do no more than minimally establish their legal identity by reg-

government. They are unable or find it inconvenient to provide information about themselves to government. istering their existence with

They

lack the administrative resources or stable

membership of the Unions

third category of trade unions, "unions submitting returns."

submitting returns have the apparatus to collect basic information concerning their membership and submit it annually to government. Registered unions are sometimes dummy organizations formed by trade unions, politicians, or

management

to influence or disrupt rec-

ognition or bargaining procedures. Unions submitting returns have higher levels of administrative capacity and stability, are more willing to accept public scrutiny, tions.

As

is

apparent

more among that

is, it

less likely to

this

is

be

dummy

in table 29, proliferation has

registered unions than

has occurred

may assume

and are

among

among

organiza-

occurred

much

those submitting returns,

the less stable and less organized.

even more true of unregistered unions.

Some

We

states

have been more prone to proliferation than others, depending on local circumstances and on which national federation has been dominant. In states such as Rajasthan and Karnataka, where CITU, the CPI-M affiliate, is the

more

leading national federation, the trade union environment

is

and the work force more committed and better represented than in West Bengal, the oldest industrial area, where political stable

TABLE 29 Registered Unions, Unions Submitting Returns, and Average

Submitting Returns,

No. of

1927-28 1937-38 1946-47 1955-56 1960-61 1966 1971 1976

in

Unions

Unions Submitting Returns Average

Registered

Year

Membership

1927-76

Unions

No.

Membership

29

28

3,594

420 1,725

343 998

1,335

8,095

4,006

11,312

6,813

14,686

7,244

22,484 26,193

9,029 6,698

1,137

567 589 606 606 707

Sources: Labour Bureau, Indian Labour Yearbook for 1947-48 (Simla, 1948) (p. 106), 1967 (Simla, 1968) (p. 82), and 1975-76 (Simla, 1976); and Government of India, Ministry of Information and Broadcasting, India, 19S0: A Reference Annual (Delhi, 1981), p. 389.

DEMAND GROUPS

282 Struggles flict

among

national federations enhance fragmentation and con-

at the enterprise

and industry

level/°

Because of the incomplete nature of membership statistics for unregistered unions and for registered unions submitting no returns, the data to confirm fragmentation can come only from unions submitting returns. As these unions are better organized than the other two categories, the figures probably understate the overall degree of fragmentation.

Our index

of fragmentation

is

average membership per union,

was 3,594 per union 1955-56, and 710 in 1976 (a

v^hich show^s a long-term decline (see table 29). in

1927-28, 1,137

in

1937-38, SGI

in

It

slight increase).

and involution is found in the private industrial sector, where a work force whose numbers have stagnated intersects with the phenomenal growth of registered unions.

The

cutting edge of fragmentation

Fragmentation generates

conflict. Private-sector industrial disputes are

about ten times as frequent as those in the public sector.^^ By contrast, in the public sector, unions have not been subject to such fragmentation. Public employees are likely to belong to larger national trade unions organized to parallel large departmental and public-sector undertakings or industries such as the nationalized banks, the Post and Telegraph Department, and the railways. They are more likely to be-

long to unions "submitting returns," whose number has remained relatively stable (table 29) even while government and public-sector employment grew by 44 percent between 1966 and 1975. These figures suggest that even while the ing, the real struggle

by

sum

effective

is

expand-

sum

of easily

of organized workers

unions

is

over a fixed



who organized workers. Adding hard-to-organize, low-paid workers do not work for government, for privileged multinationals, or large domestic business, but who work for the underprivileged industrial sector



is

a less rewarding enterprise.

Doctrinal Alternatives: Social

Harmony

versus Regulated Conflict

State-dominated pluralism in industrial relations vasive Indian tradition that features social

reflects a

more

per-

harmony and has been em-

bodied over time in ideologically diverse and even opposed political forces. State-dominated pluralism continues the bureaucratic world view of the viceregal administrative state. The metaphors of the guardian and of the steel frame used to characterize the British raj captured

and ruled that included hierarchy, and discipline. Such a vision was not uncon-

a Platonic relationship between ruler

administrative rationality,

283

Involuted Pluralism and Industrial Relations

genial to the rationalist calculus

and

social engineering that inspired

the planned development of Congress's socialist intellectuals. Their so-

understanding of class conflict quickly yielded to the thought that such conflict was destructive in a state dominated by socialist pol-

cialist

The viceregal tradition and planned socialism acquired strange bedfellows in this commitment to harmony, which parallels a similar commitment in Mohandas Gandhi's doctrine of trusteeship. Dimissing icy.

Gandhians hold that, because wealth was would use their wealth for the benefit of the

the notion of class conflict, socially created, the rich

poor and that

all

would observe

their duties as defined

by a commonly

shared social norm.^^

By contrast, the doctrine of regulated conflict that provides the framework for pluralist bargaining in Anglo-American and, to a lesser extent. Western European industrial relations has not made much headway in India. Regulated conflict requires (1) a public philosophy that welcomes adversary relations and political competition because they promote truth and the public interest, (2) economic and social differences that are more crosscutting than reinforcing, (3) agreement on the institutional and procedural means for competition and bargaining, and (4) enough symmetry among adversaries' competitive and bargaining resources to insure a rough approximation of countervailing power. It is

None

of these conditions holds in India.

difficult to find a voice



official, journalistic,

or scholarly

— that

unmasking the often spurious consensualism and disinterest of state corporatist claims. Workdays lost are interpreted as an index of the breakdown of law and order and of a loss of production rather than as a legitimate cost of industrial democracy.^^ The view that conflict has a positive role was represented in moderate form by the National Commission in Labour in 1969. Its thoughtful and substantial report failed to command government support, while the opinions of the dissenting INTUC commission members reflected the prevailing world view and carried the day. The suspicion of group conflict based on group selfishness appeared legitimates the role of conflict in

in the

remarks of the

late Jagjivan

Ram, then

minister of labor,

when he

inaugurated the national commission. Despite his profession of support for the principle of collective bargaining, the core of his speech suggested that he did not credit the pluralist premise that interest group conflict could approximate the public interest. Collective bargaining would

damage

the interests of society as a whole: sociologically, the basis of the trade

union

group bond was the need to protect the group from opposing

differ-

After

all,

historically

and

DEMAND GROUPS

284

ent groups and to promote its interest against the interests of the group in opposition. The basis of the group bond was thus not creative association as in a cooperative, but negation and hostiUty and

The consequences that the acquisitive action of one group might have on society as a w^hole did not figure into the self-preservation.

calculation of the contending groups.^'*

Ram was not alone.

epitome of the talented expert bureaucrat, in his testimony before the commission as governor of the Reserve Bank of India, reminded the commissioners of the colonial and laissez-faire origins of collective bargaining but failed to recall for

them

its

The

L. K. Jha, the

social democratic provenance:

British

self-interest

had a great genius

make their what is known as

for coining phrases, to

appear to be virtuous.

If

we look

to

a well enshrined and highly respected principle, its roots lay in the British Laissez Faire. Collective bargaining was the magic answer to avoid exploitation of labour. That ancollective bargaining,

which

is

swer did not originate in countries which had planning; much less in the countries which were socialist. The basic concept of what is a 75 proper wage is not something to be decided by trial and error.'

The INTUC

from the commission's report agreed with Jha. After opposing collective bargaining, they went on to decry the freedom to strike. They noted that the word "bargaining" was invariably used when *'there is a commodity involved" and that "progressive thinkers all over the world [believe] that labour is not to be treated as a commodity," and they concluded that they would, "therefore, like to avoid the

vogue."

^^

dissenters

word 'bargaining' notwithstanding that it is very much in The dissenters' profound distaste for bargaining and conflict

was matched by their serene confidence in the and protect the good of the community:

state's

capacity to

know

community, should be the real and ultimate master, and therefore, its interests should be paramount. The state,

The

third party, the

as the representative of the right at all times

and

and

community must,

in all stages of

therefore, have the

an industrial dispute to step

direct the parties to call off the strike or the lockout.

.

.

.

in

We

do not agree with our colleagues who want to reduce the appropriate government to the status of a mere petitioner before the Industrial Relations Commission, which Commission in its wisdom may disagree with the Government and may refuse to adjudicate a dispute which the Government as Government might feel it to be its

therefore

duty to refer for adjudication.^^

285

Involuted Pluralism and Industrial Relations

Raj Krishna, one of India's leading economists and an influential member of the Janata government's Planning Commission, lacked Jha's confidence in the Indian bureaucracy. "The greatest single constraint on industrial growth in India," he argued, "is bureaucratic overcon-

he too supported the bipartisan consensus that wages and industrial disputes are matters for expert and official determination and trol." Yet

resolution:

To promote industrial peace, national guidelines for wage contracts must be established. They should link increases in wages to increases in objective indexes of performance in every industry and to increases in cost of living indexes as determined by expert bodies.

Whenever collective bargaining fails, arbitration must then be compulsory. The arbitration judgments should conform to the national guideUnes.^*^

There are a few contrary voices. The "Giri approach" although defeated in its time, continues to serve as a rallying cry for moderate dissenters searching for a respectable way to challenge the state dominated system of industrial relations. V. V. Giri, already at independence a veteran union leader, served as labor minister between 1952 and 1954 and later as president of India. As labor minister, he held that compulsory adjudication discouraged genuine collective bargaining, which he tried to make statutory. His efforts to move in this direction aroused the opposition of INTUC, the newly formed Congress party affiliate, and government ministries. Giri was forced to withdraw his proposals, resigned soon thereafter and was replaced by Khandubai Desai, a former president of INTUC. As the Ramaswamys wrote:

"When

Labour Minister, collective bargaining ^^ suffered a setback from which it has yet to recover." The inability of the Janata government in 1978 and the Congress-I government in 1980 to pass much-needed new industrial relations legislation reflects the ambivalence of both governments and the uneasy standoff between interests and world views that has paralyzed action. Those elites who value social harmony, while more numerous and vociferous, are not sufficiently confident of their ground or powerful Giri resigned as

.

.

.

enough to crush those who value regulated conflict. Despite their 1 975 - 77 differences over democracy and dictatorship, both the Janata and the Congress shared a common view that independent collective bargaining and conflict, especially strikes, expressed antisocial goals and attitudes more often than they promoted the industrial democracy

and working-class

interest they professed to

value.**''

286

DEMAND GROUPS

The Pay Commission Model

in Industrial Relations

State policy for the trade union sector has been fashioned not in re-

sponse to the conditions of an industrial work force but by analogy to the regulation of the state bureaucracy. The in-house traditions of the

Anglo-Indian bureaucracy for assessing and rationalizing its own pay and benefits structure have gradually been extended to the public sec-

and the organized economy more generally, introducing yet another element of policymaking from expertise and principle rather than bargaining. The Home Ministry appoints pay commissions to study the personnel policies and emoluments schedule of the government establishment and to make recommendations for their improvement.^^ The pay commission outlook has influenced subsequent committees and commissions concerned with wage and income policy. In Western Europe, state efforts to determine such policy are constrained by competition and bargaining among political parties, labor and industry federations, and expert knowledge. Indian policy, by contrast, has remained largely a bureaucratic matter, relatively insulated from trade union and political pressures and relatively out of touch with the world of social research. Pay commissions provided a reliable vehicle for rationalizing anomalies and inequities within a hierarchical civil service. When, in the fifties, public employment expanded dramatically to become the largest component in the organized economy, the pay commission spawned a number of descendants. These included the aborted Chakravarti Committee of 1973, the Labour Bureau's report on wage fixation, and the Bhootalingam Study Group on Wages, Incomes and Prices, under the Janata government in 1978.*^^ All shared the in-house, apolitical, technocratic orientation of their pay commission progenitor. The terms of reference and membership of the Bhootalingam group were such as to elicit no response from the trade unions. Among the reasons for the failure of its report as a policy document were its lack of trade union support and its thin research and analysis. Created in 1969 to coordinate public-sector industries and located in the Finance Ministry, the Bureau of Public Enterprise extended the pay commission's establishment mentality to the burgeoning public sector and added to it the Finance Ministry's concern for fiscal responsibility and expert opinion. Governing public-sector wages by a pay commission-like model was seriously proposed by the Bureau of Public Enterprise, leading to fears that collective bargaining would be banished from public-sector units. Rather than concerning itself with the wider, more amorphous, and disputed political and economic considerations that affect labor comtor

287

Involuted Pluralism and Industrial Relations

mitment and productivity, the bureau pursued administrative rationalization and financial probity. It is strongly suspect in trade union circles, v^hich see it as a tool of government and management with little concern for labor.^^ In confronting the problem of increasing production and profits in the public sector, it has turned more to the option of disciplining labor and curbing wages and less to the harder task of upgrading management and technology.

Development Imperatives and the Desire

A

final factor

for

detrimental to labor's interest

is

Low Wages the state's self-proclaimed

two potentially contradictory forms, maximizing industrialization based on capital-intensive investment and maximizing employment based on labor-intensive methods. Both development strategies entail cheap labor. If labor remains a responsibility for development.^"* This takes

low-cost factor of production under capital-intensive methods, savings

development methods that spread employment while attempting to meet market competition from manufactured products also entail low wages. The state's development goals accord with a wide range of economic theory for capital formation can be increased. Labor-intensive

that concludes, "unpalatable as

a policy of

low wages."

it

may

be, the

economy

in India

needs

^^

The state's commitments to represent the whole community, to be a model employer, and to be a friend of labor ultimately have proved less important than these development imperatives. Labor's political weakness and trade union involution serve government's development goals. In 1955, Oscar Ornati summed up the immediate postindependence industrial relations scene in India

by remarking that "within the cur-

rent Indian socio-political climate, recurrent pious expressions glorify-

unhampered bargaining are no more than lip service and a goal agreed upon as desirable.'"*'' Much of what we

ing the virtues of to an ideal

have said suggests that Ornati's remarks remain relevant

at the ideologi-

cal level because they help to explain the persistence of state-dominated

pluralism in India's industrial relations. Since the mid-fifties, however,

macroeconomic changes have affected the composition of workers in the organized economy and the structure of organized labor. By the early eighties, India had become the fifteenth-largest industrial economy. The number of its technical and professional personnel ranked third in the world.

proliferation this chapter.

These changes

and involution

On

facilitated the process of trade

that have been the

union

dominant themes of

the other hand, they have also facilitated contrary de-

288

DEMAND GROUPS

velopments that could open the way to more symmetrical and independent bargaining relationships with management and political relationships with the state. Industrial relations have been affected by the

emergence of national-scale labor organizations that parallel newly created, state-managed, industrial, financial, and commercial enterprises. They have been affected too by the emergence of independent national federations, particularly CITU. INTUC, the Congress party's chosen instrument, and AITUC, affiliated with Congress's sometime political ally, the CPI, have adopted pro-Congress ideological orientations and political commitments that make it difficult for them to challenge the state management of industrial relations favored by Congress.*^ CITU is better placed ideologically and politically to challenge Congress's state corporatist doctrine and practice because its patron, the CPI-M, has been a resolute Congress opponent. As a result, its claim to represent the interests of the working class and to oppose those of a Congress-dominated state is more credible and effective than those of its two principal rivals. To an extent, it has become the spokesman for a view of industrial relations that recognizes regulated conflict as desirable and legitimate. Finally, industrial relations have been affected by the successful formation of local, regional, and national labor fronts. They have united workers hitherto divided by rivalries among local unions and national federations. They have created conditions of countervailing power capable of challenging industry associations and the state. At the local level, the

Delhi textile labor alliance challenged Delhi's textile industry

firms by maintaining a long, even though ultimately disappointing,

Maharashtra's industrial areas, the charismatic Datta Samant successfully capitalized on postemergency (1977-80) worker militancy to raise the wage floor of India's largest industrial state. Samant's strike. In

short-run success

may entail

longer-run

difficulties. It

was based on

the

personal leadership and loyalty characteristic of the entrepreneurial trade unionism that has fostered proliferation and fragmentation. Unlike the

Delhi textile alliance, which united unions affiliated with a

spectrum of national federations, Samant's front was achieved in opposition to them. His utilitarian mobilizations have gained wage benefits at the expense of working-class consciousness and trade union solidarity. Yet it is the demonstration effect of Samant's efforts and those of the Delhi textile workers alliance that could signal a change in industrial relations.

At the national level, the Congress-I government's July 27, 1981, antistrike ordinance and the parallel legislation passed by Parliament in September united eight opposition trade union federations in a na-

289

Involuted Pluralism and Industrial Relations

tional front, the National Coordination

Committee. The front was

reminiscent of the broad spectrum of political forces brought together during and after the emergency, when political parties on both left and right

ism.

worked together to save democracy by opposing authoritarianIn 1981, it was the threat to organized labor, particularly the right

to strike, that united

Sabha

(socialist),

CITU

(CPI-M),

AITUC

(CPI),

and the Bharatiya Mazdoor Sangh

Hind Mazdoor (BJP).

What had

not been possible at the party

level since the struggle against authoritarianism collapsed under Janata rule did become possible in the face of the threat of summary trials followed by imprisonment and fines for

those inciting or participating in an

illegal strike. Left

and

right joined

oppose the Indira Gandhi -led Congress-I. Opposition trade union federations agreed that the state in the form of the Congress-I act was an unequivocal threat to organized labor. However, unlike Solidarity in Poland, whose opposition to authoritarianism, corruption, and economic mismanagement electrified the country and soon mobilized farmers and middle-class professionals in support of united industrial workers' demands, India's broad labor front was isolated from cultivators and middle-class professionals, and it did not include INTUC. While India's 1981 labor front did not succeed in blocking or in mobilizing broad national support, it was, like the repressive antistrike bill and the appearance of national unions and local and regional labor fronts, the possible harbinger of new possibiliforces to

ties in industrial relations.

NationaLievel trade unions and labor fronts are creating conditions

th^jnay be

incornpatibTe^with state-dominated pluralism. History

does not allow us to argue that greater industrialization and larger

work

forces necessarily favor the

more

oligopolistic patterns of interest

aggregation that characterize the strong trade union presence in

European

many

Such trends are not universal; the United States, for example, is characterized by pluralist trade union organization. Even so, the European experience is strongly suggestive. Despite the embattled political circumstances of Indian trade unions and their increasingly limited freedom to engage in legal strikes, the emergence of states.

aggregation would indicate the possible reversal of processes that pro-

duce political weakness and involution. Industrial relations in India in the 1980s will continue to combine state corporatist and pluralist features, but it may take much more repression to prevent pluralist features from becoming pronounced and from assuming a more oligopolistic

and

influential form.

11

Students as a Demand Group: Educational Policy and Student Mobilization

unemployed youth, have become an important demand group in Indian politics. They caught the country's attention in the mid- and late 1960s, when student "unrest" and student "indiscipline" began to affect state and national politics and entered Home Ministry calculations of trends affecting law and order. It was an era of worldwide student politics, not only in the Third World, where students were sometimes the vanguard of regime change, but also in advanced industrial societies, such as France, Germany, and the United States, where they challenged the authority and policies of governments and universities. While students in India share some of the characteristics of students elsewhere, their history and circumstances are sufficiently distinct to justify treating them in the framework of our demand group analysis rather than in the framework of Third or First World political systems. Student political participation and mobilization in India is referred to officially and in the media as student "unrest" or student "indisStudents, including educated

These are cultural constructions implying that students, like "the natives" under colonial regimes, can become "restless" and, like badly socialized children, unmannerly and disrespectful. The cultural construction of students as, potentially, a lesser breed without law and as less than adult (i.e., mature and responsible), as wards rather than citizens of the state, helps to explain why students have rarely been counted as an interest group or a political actor. Being neither producers nor consumers and neither workers nor capitalists and lacking an

cipline."

unidentifiable social function, they

do not

fit

interest group, class, or

however, a demand group lens is used, students become visible as an important actor in Indian politics not only since independence but also in the nationalist era. Recently industrializing countries reverse sequences experienced by functional theories of social action.

If,

those that industrialized early: state-enforced and -funded schooling and universal suffrage preceded or paralleled rather than followed industrialization.

It

is

only since World

War

II

that higher education

Europe's advanced industrial economies expanded beyond elite boundaries. By contrast, in India the expansion of education began in

290

291

Students as a

independence and the onset of universal suffrage, more or paralleling the effort to industrialize. These contrasting sequences

soon less

Demand Group

after

affected the relative

numbers of potential

in the political process: thirty years after

students had

demand groups independence, the number of recruits for

grown to almost half that of organized labor. In 1979, 22 million workers in the organized economy, be-

there were about

tween 7 and 12 million trade union members, 4.6 million students enrolled at the intermediate level and above, and 3 million unemployed educated persons (again at the intermediate level and above) in the live registers of government employment exchanges, the latter a conservative measure at best. The stage had been set for students to be a political class and a demand group in Indian politics. The character of student groups stands somewhere between the continuity and professionalism generated by capital and organized workers on the one hand and the ad hoc quality of agriculturalists' demand groups on the other. Student organizations, like those of workers, develop out of the large-scale organizations in which both groups are concentrated. Like labor organizations, student organizations are ag-

gregated in national, party-affiliated federations, but the control of

such federations over local activities

The short generational

is

minimal, as in the case of labor.

cycles that define the role of students, along

with their dependent status as consumers, rather than producers,

works against the institutionalization of student interests in ideology and organizations, lending them an ephemeral quality. The organizational expressions of students lack the bureaucratic professionalism

and continuity of firms and unions. Like

cultivators, students

do not

run a high risk of job loss when they participate in strikes and protest movements and their activity as a demand group consists of ad hoc

movements far more than of regular, institutionalized pressure and fluence on the bureaucratic and legislative process. Students played a major role in the nationalist movement, and at

in-

in-

dependence they were already a significant political class. But in 1947, higher education was an elite phenomenon. Twenty years later, higher education had been significantly democratized by increasing the numbers and proportions of students in ways that multiplied the links between college students and society. While we cannot say precisely what critical

mass

is

needed for a group to become

a political class,

during

the expansion of the sixties students did achieve such a critical mass. Students as a demand group have not generally offered a challenge to

the centrist ideological and policy consensus, although they have threatened centrist regimes. Their agitational politics and mobilizations gave

them the appearance of revolutionary

potential. Yet student

DEMAND GROUPS

292 politics

has been mainly about issues internal to universities, issues

arising out of students' interest in certification

ditions of their "w^ork"

and the oppressive con-

— examinations, grades,

fees, hostels,

admis-

been of the business unionism rather than the Students have provided the cadres of mainstream

sions. Their style has class politics variety.

When they have eshave often reflected regional poused demands in Tamil Nadu, Assam, and Punjab, for example. In this chapter, we will explore the objective conditions that accomparties

more than

of left

and

right organizations.

explicitly political causes, those



panied the phenomenal expansion of higher education and created an even larger, more discontent body of educated youth. The favoring of higher over lower levels of education laid the groundwork for the

marked by the exponential increase of participation in extraparliamentary and student student "indiscipline" politics in 1966—67, 1973—75, and sporadically since. We will also explore the attempt, after 1977, to put the genie back in the bottle through policies that restricted expansion and reallocated priorities between levels of education. Finally, we will review the effect of unemployment on student alienation. growth

in student mobilization,

Students and Industrial Workers as Political Classes Students are

more than

able industrial workers and public employees

to be a political class. Like workers, students are concentrated in large institutions that provide the

community

essential to a

common

con-

sciousness. Unlike workers, they are not economically dependent

on

While their immediate interest in credentials, fees, examinations, hostels, and jobs dominates their consciousness, their relatively unfettered condition leads them to search for personal identity and social meaning in ideologies and issues. The often undemanding conditions of their work free them for the work of partisan and their institutions.

movement

politics.

Unlike workers, they can begin practicing politics

"work." The different historical contexts in which Indian workers and students entered the political arena account for their differences in commitment and political consciousness. Rural recruits to factory employment in eighteenth-century England were often thrown into inhuman conditions, faced with unfamiliar rationalized work routines, and subjected to degrading and unhealthy living conditions that were radically different from (if not necessarily "worse" than) those they had known on the farms and in the rural communities from which they came. If

as a profession while carrying

on

their other

293

Students as a

they had

known

Demand Group

and exploitation before, it had been mitigated by tacit social controls, local institutions, and the obligations of masters and servants. They resisted the new urban conditions of work, often violently. While no one would argue that the process of industrializatoil

tion in India has taken place without suffering by

has been

less violent

its

participants,

it

than that of the

first industrializers. The Luddite response to factory employment of some British workers in the eighteenth century has not characterized Indian factory workers in the

twentieth. Instead,

compared with

their

European counterparts,

In-

dian workers in the early stages of industrialization appear remarkedly committed.' This difference is in part a consequence of the factory and social legislation, associational rights, later industrializing nations

after the latter

and public philosophies that

have adopted from early industrializers

became welfare

states. It also reflects different patterns

of urban migration. Often workers are brought to the Indian city for

work

communities by known foremen-cum-recruiters and settled together in localities already populated by people of their kind. While there are tremendous variations in their work and living conditions, such workers have adapted to industrial discipline more readily than rural students enrolled in urban colleges have adapted to academic discipline and its uncertain rewards. It is the students, not the workers, who are not committed. Like rural recruits to urban factory work at the dawn of industrialization, they are uprooted and alienated. To the first-generation literates from factory

as segments of kin and/or village

rural areas or backgrounds,

who formed

the bulk of the millions in-

volved in the rapid expansion of higher education in independent

"work" and the institutional discipline education seemed more uncongenial than jobs dia, the

In-

of urban university

urban factories seemed to workers recruited from rural areas. Students were uprooted from a world they only thought they were willing to lose.^ They were brought together under one roof for reasons they dimly perceived and little understood or accepted. Alienated, for the most part, from the in

education they endured, students came to share the conditions of work and the consciousness that fed discontent and rebellion. Many found that

what they were asked

meaningless.

Many rural

to

do and

learn

was incomprehensible or

students in urban colleges are first-generation

background that academic administrators and college teachers assume or require. Perhaps most important is the specter of unemployment among the educated that hovers over college students and recent graduates.' literates

who

lack the

work

habits,

life

goals,

and

cultural

Students adapted to their alienated circumstances by developing consciousness and organization, often with the help of political inter-

DEMAND GROUPS

294 ests

within and outside the university context/ Discontented with

employment prospects, and more concerned with certification and employment than with learning/ they struck, demonstrated, and agitated as much against academic rules, tests, and fees as against government policies.

their education

If

and with

their

the shaping conditions for student politics in India have

dents more

of a political class than workers, they have

still

made

stu-

not played

Third World countries. In Thailand, South Korea, and Iran, for example, students have been in the vanguard of national movements that changed reas decisive a role in national politics as students in other

gimes. Only from time to time, under crisis circumstances, have Indian students provided the cadres and

movement

become

politics that threatened to

tionally even regimes. In Tamil

Nadu

the vanguard of issue or

change governments and excep1965 and in Gujarat in 1974,

in

students launched and led massive anti-Hindi and anti— price rise

and toppled governments. In the or collaborated with regional movements in Assam

agitations that challenged policies

1980s, students led

and Punjab. Nationally, students provided the cadres

for the Jayapra-

kash Narayan— led movement in 1974—75 that threatened to displace Indira Gandhi's Congress-I government and induced it to save itself by imposing an emergency regime. Even when they have threatened regimes, students have not threatened the centrist consensus. If the JP movement spoke of "total revolution," its main tenets were decentralization, honest government, and a more just society, hardly revolutionary goals in the Indian context. Ordinarily, Indian students

have provided the personnel and

sources for partisan and factional politics. careers

and the

benefits of

power have

The easy

political re-

access to political

led students to participate in

rather than challenge the established political system. Success in stu-

dent government elections opens the

way

to political careers in par-

tisan politics. Sanjay Gandhi's mobilization of educated

and ambitious

but frustrated youth in the Youth Congress was paradigmatic of this process. During the emergency (1975-77) and again after Congress-I's

1980 parliamentary and state assembly electoral victories, the Youth Congress was resuscitated and transformed. As Sanjay Gandhi's personal vehicle, it became the means for him to displace the "adult" Congress organization and those who held office in its name. Sanjay's success in building a support base of educated youth and young entrepreneurs indicates the propensity of student politics to respond to mainline political opportunities. After Sanjay's death, his brother Rajiv also used the Youth Congress to build his strength.

295

Students as a

The

Demand Group

Objective Conditions Shaping Students as a

Demand Group

The number of students in higher education, at 4.6 milHon in 1975-76, approached the number of workers in organized labor, at 7 to 12 milHon. Their concentration in formal organizations ily

The number

susceptible to mobilization.

made

students read-

of students in higher

education grew even more rapidly than that of government and publicsector employees, increasing by over a million in each of the three five-

1960-61 and 1975-76. Enrollment increased by 220 percent between 1960-61 and 1970-71 (table 30), compared year periods between

with 42.5 percent for government and public-sector employees."" The unprecedented increase in enrollment between 1960 and 1970 over-

whelmed extant

institutions

the student role in

The

demand

and created the objective conditions

for

politics.

largest spurt in enrollments

began

in the five-year period im-

TABLE 30 Growth

in

Number

of College Students,

Year

1950-79

No.

1950-51 1955-56 1960-61 1965-66 1970-71 1975-76 1976-77

Increase in

Increase

736,124

312,798

1,094,991

358,867

74 49

2,095,217

1,000,226

91

3,502,357

1,407,140

4,615,992

1,113,635

67 32

617

4,616,609

1978-79

%

_

423,326

(4,875,558)

(259,566)

4,192,934 (5,049,957)

Source: This

No.

(

(6)

-423,675

-9

+ 174,399)

(+4)

based on the Education Ministry's annual (but three to five years The table we have used is entitled "Number of Pupils in Recognized Institutions by Stages of Instruction," which, in recent years, changed its title to "Number of Pupils by Stages of Institutions," and then returned to the previous title. For higher education, we have aggregated figures for intermediate, late)

table

is

publication. Education in India.

B.A./B.Sc, M.A./M.Sc, research, professional, technical, and special education, undergraduate diploma, and "other education" (collegiate). Notes: The stabilization and then decline of 1976-79 partly reflect the application of the so-called ten-plus-two pattern, in which students previously educated in eleventhand twelfth-year intermediate or preuniversity courses, whom we counted for higher education, were shifted to the eleventh and twelfth years of higher secondary education. The shift has implications not only for education but also for political mobilization, which has been less active, though not negligible, at the secondary level. Numbers in parentheses include students shifted to the secondary level under the ten-plus-two program and indicate that there would have been a decline in growth rate even without the shift.

Data were not available

for

1977-78.

DEMAND GROUPS

296

mediately preceding 1966—69, years characterized by

demand

poli-

Higher-education enrollment increased by 91 percent between 1960—61 and 1965—66 and by 67 percent in the next five years

tics.

(1965-66 and 1970-71), with the growth rate tapering off somewhat to 32 percent in the five years preceding the emergency (1971—77). At the end of the emergency regime and under the Janata government

(1976—79), for the first time in two decades, the rate dropped to a negative figure or one only slightly exceeding the rate of population growth, depending on how one defines higher and secondary education (see notes to table 30).

The unprecedented growth of higher education was a response to powerful political demands pressing for a pace of expansion that quickly outran adequate funding. State governments, constitutionally responsible for education,^ ignored the advice of planners and education officials in Delhi,

new

ties of

who

institutions

counseled that adequate staffing and

facili-

and appropriations were beyond the means of

the states. Instead, state governments responded to the insistent de-

urban middle-class and rural notable constituents college seats by creating intellectually and physically jerrybuilt institutions or underfunding expanding enrollments in existing ones. State legislators responded by demanding that government sanction both neighborhood colleges in their districts and regional state universities. Educational entrepreneurs and sect and caste benefactors took advantage of the degree boom by founding private colleges that entailed government subventions. Motives of profit, influence, and po-

mands of for more

litical

influential

power conspired

to accelerate foundings as local politicians cre-

ated colleges to secure the reliable political machine a loyal staff and students could provide.** Parents, who wanted their children to have

more secure incomes and social status that degrees were thought to provide, fueled the demand for seats in increasingly malleable institutions. The number of universities multiplied from 27 in 1950

the higher,

to

119

in

1975

(table 31).

Until the early 1970s, enrollment in higher education

grew

faster

than national income and population, which grew at age of 3.5 percent since independence and 2 percent in recent years, respectively. Spending on education in real terms lagged well behind

an annual aver-

growth

rates.

The

result

was

deteriorating conditions as per capita ex-

penditures dramatically declined.

Higher education also grew at a faster pace than secondary and primary education, a fact that had the only pardy intended consequence of expanding the sector of education that was most likely to act politi-

297

Students as a

TABLE

31

Growth

in

Number

Demand Group

of Colleges and Universities,

1950-81

Colleges

No.

Year

1950-51 1955-56 1960-61 1965-66 1970-71 1975-76 1980-81

o/ /o

No.

Increase

816

__

%

Increase

_

1,204

47

2,140

78

5,632

163

27 32 45 79

6,886

22

100

8,395

21

119

19

128

8



Sources: Government of

Universities



19

.

40 76 27

India, Ministry of Planning, Statistical Abstracts: India,

(Delhi, 1978); Ministry of Education, Education in India,

1975-76; Ministry

1977

of Infor-

mation and Broadcasting, India, 1 980. Note: We have defined "colleges" broadly, because we are interested in the political rather than educational implications of the numbers of institutions and their enrollments.

Our

figures include universities, "institutions

deemed

universities," "institutions

of national importance," boards of intermediate and secondary education, research institutions, institutions for higher

education (degree standard and above), postmatriculaand intermediate predegree or junior col-

tion diploma/certificate (below degree level),

This provides a higher figure than that given in Government of India, University Grants Commission, Report for the Year 1979-80 (New Delhi, 1980), appendix 8, p. 120, which excludes junior colleges and colleges having only diploma or certificate courses. Our definition of "universities" includes "institutions of national importance" and "institutions deemed to be universities." The latest figure available for colleges is 8,529 for 1976-77. leges.

cally (table 32).

Of

the funds allocated to education under the fourth

plan (1969-70 to 1973-74) only 30 percent went to the elementary level/ which accounted for 68 million enrolled students, while 18 percent and 25 percent went to secondary and higher levels, respectively,

with enrollments of only 22 and 3.5 million. (The balance was

allo-

cated to vocational and special education,)'" Fifth-plan allocations

showed a comparable pattern. The much lower per capita expenditure

for elementary education

cannot be accounted for in terms of the lower costs associated with elementary education. Higher education received a disproportionate share of the available funds in part because of the political influence of the urban middle classes and rural notabilities on public policy and the absence of countervailing pressure for allocations to elementary edu-

Even when poor nonliterates had the political resources to press for elementary education, most of them valued the short-run returns from their children's labor more than the longer-run and uncertain benefits of literacy and more advanced education. cation.

DEMAND GROUPS

298 TABLE 32

Enrollment Growth Rates for Primary, Secondary, and Higher Education

Secondary

Primary

%

Higher

%

In-

Enrollment

Enrollment

crease

1950-51 1955-56 1960-61 1965-66 1970-71 1975-76 1978-79

18,677,641



4,817,011

24,511,331

31

6,826,605

33,631,391

37 45

10,942,293

48,912,678 55,167,533

12

21,773,019

42 60 57 46

63,108,492

14

25,999,227

19

72,390,000

14

27,090,000

4

Sources: See table 30. Figures

for

crease



17,132,945

1978-79

are

%

In-

Year

Enrollment

423,326 736,124

In-

crease



1,094,991

74 49

2,095,217

91

3,502,357 4,615,992

67 32

4,192,934

-9

(5,049,957)

(+4)

from Ministry of Information and

Broadcasting, India, 1980, p. 47.

Notes: Primary education includes, in most states, grades 1-5, although in 1950-51 was greater variation. Secondary includes the middle, senior basic, and higher stages, that is, grades 6 through 11 or 12. We have not included in either category school-level (precoUege) technical and professional courses or "other" and special education. All three are relatively small categories. See table 30 for explanation of parenthetical numbers. For disparities between the text and this table, see note 9.

there

Skewed

allocations favoring higher education, besides accelerating

the mobilization of students, generated other advantages and disad-

vantages for India's economy. The failure to invest adequately in human capital at the elementary level limited productivity grov^th in the agricultural

and

industrial sectors of the

economy and

limited the

quality of opportunity in the society as a v^hole. Skev^ed funding also

helped to perpetuate the disproportionate influence of the educated few in the political system and produced a large cadre of educated un-

employed. On the other hand, investment in human capital in higher education created the world's third-largest professional class, an asset that distinguishes India from most other Third World developing countries, providing inter alia what plentiful oil revenues cannot buy.

proved to be a critical component in India's economic growth, a significant element in India's economic independence and technological capacity, and a source of the substantial remittances of foreign exchange that have mitigated India's balance of payments and

The

class has

foreign debt problems.

The conventional wisdom

that

bemoans

the decline of higher educa-

tion in India does not ordinarily take into account the creation of na-

and managerial institutions (such as the of Technology and Management), postgraduate de-

tional, high-level engineering

Indian Institutes

299

Students as a

gree programs,

Demand Group

and advanced research

institutions in the natural

and

The humanistic,

lib-

social sciences or the agricultural universities."

eral arts conception of higher education that prevailed under British

rule

was designed

and administrators to serve the create technical and scientific talent for eco-

to turn out clerks

imperial mission,'' not to

nomic development. The new institutions, by contrast, have not only transformed the pattern and capabilities of higher education in India but have also played a vital development role. India's investment in higher education and research stands in marked contrast to Chinese doctrine and practice. In China, particularly during the Cultural Revolution (1966-76), radical egalitarianism, ideological

and

political distrust of the expert, fear that meritocratic for-

mal education might lead to the

capitalist road,

sending students to the country to work

and the practice of

in the agricultural sector gen-

erated consequences inimical to schooling generally and to higher education and research in particular.

The

costs to China's

development

performance and potential became apparent only after Mao Tse-tung's death, when the new regime began to reveal his policy errors and began energetic efforts to undo and reverse them. Thus, in considering the disproportionate expansion of higher education in India, developmental gains must be considered along with the negative effects on education and the increases in political mobilization.

The

Incidence of Student Protest and

The

pattern of educational expenditures from elementary through

Its

Goals

higher education also laid the groundwork for the disillusionment and alienation that fueled

demand

politics.

Too

often, elementary

and

sec-

ondary education did not adequately prepare students for higher education, and all three levels often failed to prepare students for jobs or careers. The too-rapid expansion of higher education led to collegiate slums, custodial institutions, and high levels of wastage. Perhaps most important, many degree holders failed to find jobs, remained unemployed for long periods, or could only find jobs for which they were "overqualified," jobs that blighted their aspirations and often their potential. The incidence of student agitations and violence rose steadily throughout the 1960s, accelerated exponentially after the fourth general election in 1967 to a crescendo in 1974, the year before the emergency, receded with the emergency, rose to new heights in the late 1970s, and remained high into the early 1980s (table 33). The magnitude of the increase is striking. In the mid- and late 1960s,

DEMAND GROUPS

300 TABLE

33

Student "Indiscipline" (Reported Incidents)

Year

Year

Incidents

1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970

Incidents

93 120

1971 1972

4,380

80 172 97 109 395 271 607

1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983

5,551



2,665

3,064 3,861

6,365

11,540

3,847 1,190

7,520

9,174 9,203

-

10,600 7,740

5,200 7,188

Sources: Government of India, Ministry of Home Affairs, "Student Indiscipline" (1967, mimeograph). Report, 1979-80 (Delhi, n.d.), Report, 1980-81 (Delhi, n.d.), and Third Report of the National Police Commission (Delhi, 1980); and Data India, September 18-24, 1978, p. 594.

observers considered extraordinary the great increase in student indiscipline (from

109 incidents per year

1963 to 607

1966) that characterized the period of poHtical unrest beginning with Jawaharlal Nehru's death in 1964 and continued with the food shortages of in

in

1965—66, the Indo-Pakistan war of 1965, and the challenge to Con1967 election. Yet these rates were dwarfed by those of the late seventies, which rose to 9,000 and 10,000 incidents per year. The early seventies was the time of the student-led Nav Nirman agitation in Gujarat and Jayaprakash Narayan's student-supported drive for "total revolution" in North India, especially in Bihar and eastern Uttar Pradesh. The year 1974 was characterized by the highest rates of student indiscipline ever, far above those for the emergency years of 1975—76, when strong measures repressed campus turmoil. The goals of student mobilizations in the 1960s to 1980s included both bread-and-butter interest issues and wider political objectives. gress in the

An

inquiry that

we conducted

in the late sixties into factors associated

with student indiscipline supported the proposition that expansion

proceeding without regard to resources, and the low prospects associated with such overexpansion, were indeed probable causes of indiscipline.

The inquiry compared 112 high-performance

colleges (with at

60 percent of students passing exams) and 154 colleges with high '^ rates of indiscipline to the all-India averages on a number of indicators. least

301

Students as a

Demand Group

Colleges on our indiscipline

list

were more

likely to

be low-prospect

and science rather than high-prospect professional schools, to have low proportions of faculty to students and books to students, to spend Rs. 1,000 or less per student, to have high proportions (30-60 arts

percent) of students in the less well

endowed

preuniversity or inter-

why we have described student movements as largely a response to bread-and-butter issues. The inquiry, however, also suggested the significance of the more mediate courses. These factors help suggest

and psychological "alienation" thesis. Urban colleges with many rural students, who found themselves in an unfamiliar environment and away from the usual social definitions and restraints, made up a disproportionately high share of the indiscipline-prone colleges. These were colleges with 20-70 percent rural students. Colleges whose student bodies were almost entirely rural, that is, made up of rural students in rural settings, were not especially conspicuous in the diffuse

indiscipline group.

'"*

These distant and proximate causes of student unrest spawned acand place but increasingly involved state and national politics. ^^ As enrollments increased throughout the 1960s, students increasingly joined protest and movement politics, often acting as the vanguard. The groundwork for such action had been laid in the nationalist period, when Mohandas Gandhi had called on students to leave colleges and join the movement. During the 1960s, students played an increasingly visible and influential role in party politics. They found that leadership in student organizations was the career path to "tickets" (nominations), elected office, and even ministerial posts."" In the early 1970s, students again began to play an increasingly importion that varied over time

movement politics, as they had during the nationalist era. As movement politics shifted its objectives from blocking or demandtant role in

ing policies to bringing

down governments and changing

regimes, stu-

and of the problem of governability. This led to the widespread agitation in 1974 against the ineffective and discredited Congress government in Gujarat and to its defeat in June 1975 in a state midterm election.'^ The election results were announced the day after Prime Minister Indira Gandhi was held guilty of corrupt electoral practices and threatened with disqualification from Parliament for six years, and they are assumed to have influenced her June 25th decision to declare an emergency. So too dents became a critical

did Narayan's

much

of

its

component

movement

of national politics

for "total revolution." Students provided

leadership and support,

first in

Bihar, then in Gujarat,

and

then throughout northern India." Mrs. Gandhi had every reason to fear that the parties and political forces brought together by the JP

DEMAND GROUPS

302

movement might

carry the day in the general election scheduled for

February 1976.

Nav Nirman and

the JP

movement,

as regime-threatening student

movements, were exceptions rather than the norm in Indian student politics. ^^ However, they suggest that ordinary interest and party politics does not exhaust student potential. When the emergency was imposed in June 1975, most student, faculty, and staff associations were suspended. An uncommon peace descended on the college and university world. Students attended classes and took examinations. Unrest virtually vanished. The threat of repression and intimidation worked wonders for the moment. Faculty who deplored the emergency praised the unaccustomed peace. In northern India particularly, committed vice-chancellors with their handpicked aides and advisors took charge. They not only dispensed with the teacher, student, and staff



organizations recognized in university statutes but also, in several notable instances, excluded the faculty

from admissions and faculty

re-

cruitment and selection procedures. Coupled with the state corporatist strategy of patronizing, licensing, or creating like-minded professional

Mrs. Gandhi's emergency regime appeared for a time to lay the groundwork for political and ideological

and

intellectual organizations,^^

control of higher education.

The completeness with which the emergency was able to subdue the universities and students was startling. While students had played a major

role in precipitating the

they played no

emergency by

their protest

movements, was

special role in the defeat of the emergency, which

accomplished through the ordinary

political

procedures of the elec-

toral process.

Policy Intervention in Student Conditions

Student "indiscipline" and "unrest," like workers' strikes, cannot be dealt with merely as a law-and-order problem to be solved by repression less

and patriotic exhortation. Both policy intervention and more or spontaneous changes in the general economic conditions of gradu-

can affect the civic incorporation or alienation of students. The Janata (1978-83) and Congress-I (1980-85) versions of the sixth five-year plan constituted important policy interventions. Both governates

ments significandy reduced welfare allocations generally and educational allocations in particular. Allocations fell from a high of 6.9 percent in the third plan, height, to a

when

the

demand

low of 2.2 percent of the sixth

for education

(see table 34),

was

at its

with a slight

303

Students as a

TABLE

Demand Group

34

Expenditure on Education as a Percentage of Plan Expenditure (Center and States) Education Expenditure

Third plan (1961-65), actual

6.9

Annual plans (1966-69), actual Fourth plan (1969-74), actual Fifth plan (1974-78), actual (three years) and

4.6

4.9

anticipated (one year)

3.7

Draft sixth plan (Janata) (1978-83), outlay

2.8

Sixth plan, (Congress-I) (1980-85), outlay

2.2

Seventh plan (1985-90), ouday

3.5

Sources: Ministry of Information and Broadcasting,

India,

1

980; table 5.2, Ministry of

Economic Survey, 1979-80 (New Delhi, 1980), table 2.5, p. 106; Planning Commission, Sixth Five Year Plan, 1980-85, (Delhi, 1981), table 21.2, p. 361, and Seventh Five Year Plan, 1985-90, 2 vols. (Delhi, 1985), tables 3.4(a), 3.4(b), pp. 27, 28. Finance,

recuperation to 3.5 percent in the seventh. The notion that spending

on education and heahh programs and in

human

ners

capital

is

faciHties represents investment

accepted only to a limited extent by Indian plan-

and administrators.^'

Within these overall reductions reallocation of funds

in proportion, there

among educational

levels.

was

a relative

Janata's concern for

in-

creasing the assets, opportunities, and income of the poor produced

plan ratios more favorable to elementary (and adult) education and less

favorable to secondary and higher education (table 35). Elemen-

45 percent and social (adult) education 10 percent (increases of 12 and 9 percent), as against 14 percent for secondary and 13 percent for higher education (a reduction of 14 percent)." When a Congress-I government returned to powder in January 1980 tary education received

and redrafted the

some funding

sixth plan,

to secondary

it

revised the Janata pattern, restoring

and higher

at the

expense of elementary

education.

One consequence

of treating education primarily as a low-priority

welfare cost rather than a high-priority

human

capital investment

to reinforce spontaneous trends toward a decline in the

growth

was

rate of

enrollments. As tables 30 and 32 show, of the three levels of education, higher education, the level that generated most student mobilization,

has experienced the most pronounced shrinkage in enrollment growth. Higher education's average annual rate of enrollment growth in the three decades between 1950 and 1980 has been 12, 15, and 4 percent respectively. In

1978-79,

how one counted

it

was only -9 or + 4

percent, depending

the "ten-plus-two" level (see table 30).''

on

DEMAND GROUPS

304 TABLE 35 Changes

in Plan Allocations to Levels of

Education (Percentages)

Four FiveYear Plans Sixth Plan

and Annual Plans

Fifth Plan

Janata

Congress-I

(1950-69)

(1974-78)

(1978-83)

(1980-85)

Elementary

33

33

Secondary

17

18

45 14

36 17

University

20

23

13

19

Social (adult education)

3

1

10

5

Cultural programs

1

3

3

3

Other

8

10

6

9

18

12

9

11

Technical

Sources: Ministry of Information and Broadcasting, India, 1980, table 5.2; Planning Commission, Sixth Five Year Plan, 1980-85, table 21.2, p. 361.

Spontaneous Changes in Enrollment Trends Policy interventions were not the only factor affecting enrollments.

We

spontaneous forces of the job market also marginally can affected choices among degree programs as well as reduced enrollments in higher education generally. Tables 36 and 37 summarize the infer that the

enrollment and employment situations, respectively. The most striking response to the job market was occasioned by the high unemployment rates affecting the graduates of arts

and B.A. programs, by

far the

most

numerous of all degree progress (table 36). Enrollments in these programs, whose graduates registered usual-status (chronic) unemployment rates of 22 percent in 1980, higher than for graduates of any other program, declined significantly, from 45 percent in 1975—76 to 39 percent in 1983-84 (table 36). On the other hand, enrollments in postgraduate second-degree programs (M.A., M.Sc, and Ph.D.), whose graduates have very low unemployment rates (table 37), increased, from 9.8 percent in 1975-76 to 11.1 in 1979-80, at the expense of first-degree courses.^"* In these fields and levels, enrollments were responsive to changing job markets trends. However, enrollments in the next two most numerous first-degree programs, (science and commerce) (table 36), with unemployment rates of 21 percent and 18 percent, respectively (table 37), did not decline in the face of

weak employment

Commerce

en-

management swept

the

prospects.

rollments went up, as a fashion for business

country, while science enrollments remained steady. Enrollments in en-

305

Students as a

Demand Group

gineering and technology (B.E.), a high-opportunity

field

where

enroll-

ment has a propensity to remain steady because of high costs per student and government's de facto monopoly on foundings, nevertheless increased from 4.0 to 4.7 percent in 1983-84. Medical enrollments (M.B., B.S.) have declined to 3.6 percent, again because of high perstudent costs and government's tight control of foundings. How^ever,

governments have recently begun yielding to considerable political pressure for additional foundings generated by the earning prospects of medicine. The government of Karnataka has been in the lead in allowing private entrepreneurs, relying for their funding on very high capitation fees paid by applicants, to open new medical colleges. If allowed to expand in Karnataka or spread to other states, the prac-

state

tice

may

number in

affect the recent steady state of medical enrollments.^^

of doctors per capita in India

is

among

The

the world's lowest, but

prosperous urban areas approaches the numbers for comparable

The demand for places in medical schools enormous and unrestrained by the fact that ten thousand doctors were unemployed in 1980. The demand was unrestrained not only beareas in industrial societies.

is

cause of the high incomes available in urban areas but also because of the prospects of migration to

North America and the United Kingdom.

Despite protests from national professional bodies, other states, in the

absence of federal intervention,

may

follow Karnataka's

lead.^''

These spontaneous trends, together with policy intervention, have mitigated but not eliminated the most obvious objective conditions contributing to student unrest. They have sharply reduced the rate of

TABLE

36

Student Enrollment in First-Degree Courses of Study,

1975-76

to

1983-84

Enrollment (%)

1975-76

1979-80

1983-84

Arts

44.5

40.6

39.1

Science

19.1

19.2

19.8

Commerce

22.4

17.1

19.5

Education

3.2

2.8

2.2

Engineering/technology

4.0

4.5

4.7

Medicine

4.3

4.2

3.6

1.2

1.5

1.3

Veterinary science

0.3

0.3

0.3

Law

5.8

6.7

5.4

Other

0.5

0.7

0.7

Agriculture

Sources: University Grants Commission, Report for the Year 1979 -HO, appendix 6, figures exclude preuniversity and p. 118, and Report, ] 983-54, appendix 6, p. xiii. The intermediate enrollments.

DEMAND GROUPS

306 TABLE 37 Usual-Status

Unemployment Rate among Type

First-

and Second-Degree Holders, 1980

%

of Degree

Unemployed

Engineering (B.E.)

7.09

Medical Graduate (M.B.,

6.50

B.S.)

Agricultural

11.41

Veterinary medicine

3.60

Education (B.Ed.)

15.67

Arts (B.A.)

22.43

Arts (M.A.)

4.00

20.57

Science (B.Sc.) Science (M.Sc.)

-

4.87

Commerce (B.Com.) Commerce (M.Com.)

17.63

All degrees

15.76

6.52

Source: Planning Commission, Sixth Five Year Plan, 1980-85, annexure 13.9, p. 220. Note: rate is calculated as the percentage of unemployed among "economically active" degree holders.

enrollment increase in higher education so that

mates the population growth

rate. If

this rate

now

approxi-

disproportionate spending on

human capital for the tertiary (service) sector of the economy, it may be that spending proportionately more on elementary and secondary education may help develop human capihigher education developed

tal in

the primary (agricultural)

Market

and secondary

(industrial) sectors of

and policy intervention also seem to have marginally shifted degree preferences toward degrees offering better job prospects. Nevertheless, absolute levels are such that unemployment among the educated continues to be an important conditioning factor for the existence and sometimes the direction of student the economy.

forces

politics.

Unemployment among

the Educated

and Student Mobilization

and youth in general tends toward alienation and rebellion or toward incorporation in established forms of regulated conflict and political competition depends in considerable measure on yet another objective condition, the level and meaning of unemployment among the educated. The objective conditions of such unemployment are not sufficient to explain student politics and its role in demand politics. How the educated perceive their opportunities, rights, and political influence is shaped but not

Whether the

politics of students in particular

307

Students as a

Demand Group

wholly determined by their

levels and kinds of employment. Uncertain and unsatisfactory unemployment along with irrelevant or inadequate education prepares the ground for student politics. But it is how students construe the ambiguous career probabilities before them that finally determines the intensity and direction of student and youth politics, whether they will respond to what they perceive by angry protest or by prudent lowering of their expectations. Tracing the links between the prospect of unemployment, student consciousness, and student mobilization is made more difficult by the considerable variation in unemployment estimates and the ambiguous

nature of the conditions lying behind the estimates. If data professionals disagree by magnitudes of more than 100 percent about the extent of unemployment,

how

should the observer

who

is

interested in

unemployment on student perceptions interpret unemployment is a life-stage phenomenon that is less common in older age groups and if many of those listed on unemployment registers are actually employed how do these contingencies affect the consequences of its

impact?

If

the perception of students anticipating their future? Different statements of the seriousness of the problem have different

and consequences. Hypothetical unemployment on the estimated growth of the labor force in relathe estimated growth in unemployment produce the most

political implications

calculations based tion to

horrifying magnitudes. Recent official estimates of hypothetical or so-

unemployment include 32.6 million in 1977, 52.6 million in 1978, and 122 million in 1988 (anticipated).^^ These figures suggest unemployment rates in the range of 20—25 percent of the labor called backlog

force.

Such estimates were used

plan but

now

elicit

in

connection with the fourth five-year

some skepticism among

planners.

These very high estimates must be distinguished from the actual rates of employment compiled by the National Sample Survey (NSS), which are relatively modest, in the range of 4 or 5 percent.^" In 1977-78, the thirty-second round of the NSS found that nationally (all-India) 3.04 percent of those between 15 and 59 years of age were

unemployed (weekly status). ^^ Even if one defines unemployment more broadly, using the "dailystatus" unemployment rate (which includes daily unemployment among persons who have some employment each week, the unemployment rate does not reach very high levels. Janata and Congress-I's sixth plan calculations agreed that daily-status unemployment, which always has higher rates than weekly-status or usual-status unemployment, affected about twenty-one million persons, or 8 percent of the labor force.'" The hypothetical unemployment estimated by the time the fourth

DEMAND GROUPS

308

plan was being formulated had grown so astronomically as to strain its claim on credulity even more than its claim on the exchequer. The figure produced by empirical methods, on the other hand, seems modest

by comparison with unemployment rates in industrial economies. Its small size, which conflicts with the intuitive expectations raised by India's poverty, is no doubt related to the conceptual and empirical problems involved when employment is largely in the unorganized sector, among self-employed farmers and small operators or wage workers enmeshed in patron-client relations. Are agricultural workers unemployed when, due to the season, their landlords don't need them for agricultural work but, also due to the season, they cannot work their own plots either? Are self-employed weavers unemployed when, due to low demand, they work their looms only eight months of the year? At any rate, hypothetical unemployment and the variations in employment for the urban and rural labor force do not pinpoint the range and changing magnitude of educated unemployment. The thirtysecond round NSS figures do suggest that unemployment increases with

level of education.

They show

that the usual-status ("chronic")

was 2.28 percent among illiterates, 3.61 percent among those who had finished primary school, 15.5 percent among those who had finished secondary school, and 15.76 percent among college graduates and above. The live register statistics of the employment exchanges also suggest that more than 50 percent of the jobseekers are educated.^^ The educated, by this calculation, experience far more unemployment than do other people, the average usual-status unemployment for all persons being only 4.33 percent.^^ Even if we

unemployment

rate

take these figures with a pinch of

salt,

noting, for example, that the

educated unemployed will register more in employment exchanges than the uneducated, they remain striking. The absolute number of the unemployed among those who have passed through higher education is between 4 and 7 million, depending on the definition of higher education and the source of data. If we

add together the 1.3 million (1979) first-degree holders in the live registers and the very large number of students who have only a partial higher education, the "intermediate" students and those who have taken the same intermediate years as part of their high school educa-

on the live registers rises to 3 million for 1979." From our point of view, which focuses on college-level students as the social group that has become a political class, this figure is the most tion, the figure

important.^''

The

disparities

between modes of estimation are

lated to the nature of the live registers.

The

total

at least partly re-

unemployment

re-

ported by them has risen tenfold over twenty-eight years, a change that

309

Students as a

Demand Group

partly reflects changes in coverage, that

is, the increase in the number employment exchanges from 126 in 1951 to 563 in 1980.'^ In addition, a 1968 survey of registrants by the director general of employment and training in the Ministry of Labour revealed that 42.3 percent of the job seekers on live registers were already employed, and an additional 7 percent were students.^'' On the other hand, many unemployed persons do not register themselves, as many as 50 percent according to some estimates. Changes in the live registers as a social institution and their dependence on "consumer" initiative make them a more variable source of data than the NSS with its dependence on samples and on

of

the routinized initiative of professional

The

existence of

some

staff.

unemployed youth not only influences the consciousness, expectations, and plans of college students, but creates a population prepared to join movement politics when conditions are ripe. Unemployment among the educated, however defined, will increase. It increased by as much as 36 percent between 1980 and 1985, from 3.4 million to 4.6 million (including matriculates). One would expect this growth to increase the three million college-educated

chances for political mobilization. Yet students, groups, are

difficult to

meld into a national

like all

class

other social

because of their

re-

gional and ethnic fragmentation. Furthermore, the condition of "edu-

unemployment" appears to be an age-related phenomenon that persons "grow out of," quite possibly by taking jobs for which they are cated

at least formally overqualified. It

unemployment ban males, and it

the

Do

rate

is

is

in the

15-to-29-year age range that

highest, 17.63 percent (usual status) for ur-

declines precipitously thereafter, to 3.03 percent

unemployment as a permanent threat? Or are they aware that it will be, for most of them, a passing condition? As we have seen, unemployment is a statistical concept or artifact. (table 38).

TABLE

students regard

38

Usual-Status

Unemployment Rates by Residence and Age Group, 1977-78 o/ /o

Age Group

(yr)

5-14 15-29 30-44 45-59 60+

Urban

Rural

8.46

3.05

17.63

6.02

3.03

1.74

1.71

1.14

All ages

Source: Thirty-second round NSS 13.2, p. 214.

data,

Unemployed

m

1.66

.64

8.77

3.26

Sixth Five Year Plan,

1980-85, anncxurc

— DEMAND GROUPS

310

subject to the perils of conceptualization and measurement.

We

have

unemployment can be a state of mind; that is, many urban unemployed do not list themselves on live registers and many of those who do are already employed or students. Hov^ many college educated have to be unemployed to make their successors desperate? also seen that

Four million, as afflict

at present? Six million? Similar state-of-mind-problems

discussions of rural unemployment.

heve they are unemployed

when

Do

agricultural w^orkers be-

they cannot find

work 50, 100, or 150

days a year?

Throughout this account we have assumed, in line with the commonsense wisdom of Indian policy intellectuals and politicians, that unemployment among the educated is a significant element in student discontent and influences students to mobilize. Our investigation suggests that overall unemployment rates are not high by comparison with rates in industrialized countries, but that the rate for the age group that overlaps with students

— 15—29 years —

is,

at

17.63 percent, well

above the national rate of 4.23 percent, producing a

minimum

four million unemployed holders of intermediate and

first

figure of

degrees.

Judging the effect of this figure on the political mobilization of students, however, is by no means easy. We do not know whether most students regard early unemployment as an inevitable life stage, a warning to adjust their expectations to lower levels, or a battle cry to challenge an unjust system. We do not know what increments in the extent of unemployment among the educated under what historical or sociological conditions will create a critical

mass

We know

the educated matters, but

that

unemployment among

rate of "student

the mobilization of this class, eighties.

However,

we

when and how it matters. indiscipline," which we take as an indicator

have not yet learned to specify

The

for revived mobilization.

just

was

still

of

rising at the beginning of the

in the late seventies, the historical

phenomena

that

and exacerbated its discontent the expansion of higher education and overexpansion in relation to resources had been slowed down by acts of policy and spontaneous adjustments. Unemployment among the educated was expected to increase, but its meaning to students and its significance for mobilization had fueled the creation of

this class



remained ambiguous. In the mobilizations of the sixties

and

seventies, students for a time

appeared as a more visible political class than organized workers, perhaps because rapid educational expansion, combined with the inade-

quacy of facilities and the considerable migration of rural students to urban institutions, created higher levels of alienation than existed among industrial workers absorbed into organized employment.

311

Students as a

Throughout

Demand Group

postindependence career as a demand group, students have rarely challenged the centrist consensus, even when they have challenged particular centrist regimes. They have concentrated mainly on interest, not class, issues, especially those affecting their en-

vironment

their

— examinations,



and their prospects, employment. However, by virtue of their relative freedom from the dependency and from the control associated with embeddedhostels, admissions

especially

work

become an effective political class in partisan and movement politics. They have shown their potential, in 1974-75 in Gujarat, in the JP movement in North India, and more recently in Assam and Punjab. Although the student wave that crested between 1965 and 1975 in world and Indian politics has for the moment receded, students remain one of the principal components in India's demand politics. ness in

relations, students are also able to

Policies

and

Politics

of the Agricultural Sector

Large proportions of India's population, work force, and national inare accounted for by the agricultural sector, yet its voice in national politics and policy during the years of the Nehru settlement

come

(1950—64) was little heard or attended to. Seventy-two percent of the labor force was employed in agriculture, which produced almost half of the net domestic product. Eighty percent of the population lived in

and

much

urban voters.^ But until Nehru's death in May 1964, agricultural interests and values were poorly represented in New Delhi. Low levels of planned rural areas,

rural voters participated in politics as

investment in agriculture reflected

its

as

limited influence.

There were structural reasons for the limited effectiveness of agrarian demand groups during the years of the Nehru settlement. By the nature of their work, agricultural producers are scattered. Unlike urban workers and students who are concentrated in large industrial or commercial enterprises and in universities, they work under dispersed conditions that inhibit their capacity to communicate, organize, and mobilize. At the ideological level, conditions have not been favorable either. Mohandas Gandhi's concern for rural employment and development went into eclipse with his assassination on January 30, 1948. Nehru recognized Gandhi's concerns and constituency when he launched the Community Development Program in 1952 (on Gandhi's birthday, October 2) and panchayati raj in 1959, but his mind and heart lay with industry. It and only it could make India powerful and independent. Starting with Lai

Bahadur

Shastri's

government (1964-66) and

celerating in the 1970s, agricultural producers have ingly visible

tiveness

is

and audible

in national policy

and

become

politics.

ac-

increas-

Their asser-

partly the result of long-term changes that are not specific to

the rural sector, such as the spread of education

and

political organiza-

and consciousness. It is also the result of increased agricultural commercialization and prosperity creating powerful economic intertion

ests.

Most important,

it is

policy from state capitals

the cost of

new

(e.g.,

inputs and

312

the result of the migration of agricultural

land reform policy) to

commodity

prices).

New Delhi

(e.g.,

313

Policies

The form

and

of agrarian

bility politics to

party

Politics of the Agricultural Sector

demand politics has changed too, from notaand demand group politics. In the fifties and

sixties, local notabilities

used vertical mobilization of dependents and

and cabinets to influence state governments. Myron Weiner was right about the 1950s and early 1960s when he observed that "thus far, the Indian countryside has not produced effective peasant movements capable of exerting a major influence on government policy." Mn 1959, Nehru's plan to move toward direct representation in state legislatures

Chinese-inspired production cooperatives was defeated at the Nagpur annual session of the Congress party, and this defeat was a harbinger of things to come. In the mid-

and late sixties. North Indian cultivators hero of Nagpur, Charan Singh, who had split from Congress to form an explicidy agrarian party, the BKD, later BLD.' With Janata 's victory in 1977 and the farmers' movements in the early rallied to the

1980s, agrarian politics came of age. Agricultural producers joined

making demands,

in

workers and students had, using direct action techniques such as roadblocks and "long marches." The issues have changed and with them the arenas for action. In the fifties and sixties, the key issues were land reform, compulsory procurement of food grains, and taxation of agricultural production and income. All fell within the constitutional jurisdiction of the states. As as

technological upgrading (the green revolution) transformed Indian ag-

from the

1960s on, policies that fell within the purview of the central government, such as commodity and input prices, bericulture

late

came more important. The

states continue to

command

attention as

sources of agricultural credit and agricultural services. But countryside

Bharat versus India, to use Sharad Joshi's phrase, has become an important cleavage in national politics, if not the princi-

versus the

city,

pal one.

The

central

government can control demand

nized sector better than in the unorganized.

become attenuated

in the

Its

politics in the orga-

reach and penetration

unorganized economy, particularly

New

its

mas-

manage demand politics in the organized and unorganized sectors was highlighted under the emergency (1975-77). The central government was able to control wages and extract compulsory savings from organized workers and to repress student strikes and violence. It was not able to impose wholesale trading in food or an agricultural income tax. The sive agricultural sector.

Delhi's contrasting capacity to

increased organizational resources and mobilization capability of agricultural producers

and the increased

role of the central

agricultural policy have strengthened Delhi's

sector even as

it

hand

grows more capable of articulating

government

in

in the agricultural its

demands.

DEMAND GROUPS

314

Four policy strategies for agriculture have paralleled and sometimes shaped the evolution of demand politics in the agricultural sector and rural society. The first, the agricultural strategy of the Nehru era (1947—64), featured land reform. Nehru's advisers pictured land reform (intermediary abolition) as enhancing equity and productivity, larger proportions of second-plan investment were allocated to industry than agriculture. The second strategy began soon after Nehru's death and extended into 1971. It featured new agricultural technology. It was production oriented and aimed at self-reliance in food. The third strategy began with Mrs. Gandhi's gharibi hatao (abolish poverty) appeal in the 1971 parliamentary and 1972 state assembly elections. It emphasized basic needs and income redistribution. The fourth was launched in 1977 by Janata's agrarian-oriented government. It emphasized rural employment and asset creation, continued to stress income redistribution, and sought to relate increased investment in agriculture to a demand-investment cycle based on enhanced and redistributed rural and agricultural incomes. It continued with new names on estabUshed programs under the Gandhi-led Congress-I government that took office in February 1980. All four strategies developed within a

common

constraint: that for

the foreseeable future, the problems of rural poverty have to be solved

on the land. Industrialization has not reduced the rural labor force, which has remained static at about 72 percent of the national labor force for the last sixty years."*

The

First Strategy:

Land Reform and "Releasing

the Forces of

Production"

was shaped by two purposes: to advance justice and equity among agricultural producers and to increase agricultural production without diverting resources from the priority goal, creation of basic and heavy industry. Intermediary abolition sought to alter the balance of agrarian economic and politi-

The

cal

agricultural strategy of the

Nehru

era

power by vesting operational control of land

in tillers of the soil.

Intermediary abolition expropriated with compensation the feudal landlord classes of zamindars and jagirdars. Nehru's effort in 1959 to collectivize agriculture failed.

So too did a second wave of land

re-

of holdings not

form based on ceilings and designed to reduce the size affected by or benefiting from intermediary abolition. If the strategy's dominant orientation was toward equity, its secondary orientation was

315

Policies

growth.

It

and

was believed

Politics of the Agricultural Sector

that the redistribution of land acquired after

the imposition of ceilings could significantly enhance production by ^'releasing the forces of production." Because basic and heavy industry

absorbed the

lion's

share of planned investment,

agriculture. In the event, the fifties

came not from

growth

in agricultural

little

was

left

production

structural reorganization or from

new

for

in the

inputs and

technologies (which were, in any case, not yet available) but from bringing additional land under cultivation.

The intermediary abolition in the mid-fifties succeeded because the ideology and policy of the Nehruvian Congress suited an interested and mobilized producer class. It has been estimated that the abolition of intermediary holdings reduced tenancy from

60 to 25 percent and from 40 to 75 percent.^

owner cultivators profound effect on Indian politics. A

increased the proportion of

Abolition had a

class that

might

have played historical roles comparable to those played by Britain's landed gentry and aristocracy, Prussia's Junkers, Japan's daimyos and samurai, or Latin America's latifundia masters was removed from the

As a result of intermediary abolition, about twenty million tenants became owners and about 14 million acres were acquired and distributed. The state also acquired large amounts of privately owned forestland, grazing land, and wasteland.'' Abolition also had unanticipated consequences, including the expulsion of uncounted numbers of tenants from land that landlords claimed for "selfhistorical stage.

cultivation."^

The

abolition of intermediaries transformed agrarian relations by

shifting the locus of rural

power from feudal landlords

oriented independent cultivators,

whom we

lock capitalists. Marginal tenants, dwarf

to market-

categorized earlier as bul-

holders,

and agricultural

la-

borers did not benefit from intermediary abolition. Change occurred at the

top and near the top of the agrarian pyramid. The landlord poli-

tics that

persisted in Pakistan were eliminated. Political control of the

agrarian sector at the state and local levels shifted to independent cultivators and large landowners, who were more diverse socially than

economically, ranging from high-caste Rajputs to the lower-caste Hindus lumped together in the administrative and policy term, "backward

Large landowners were sufficiently influential in state politics to veto or block New Delhi-inspired agricultural policies, that threatened their interests such as ceilings legislation. The agrarian strategy of the 1950s included an attempt in 1959 to institute cooperative farming. The attempt failed. It suffered from the classes."

inadequate or erroneous information about the Chinese model that

DEMAND GROUPS

316

Nehru and his advisors and collaborators used to frame their proposal. The initiative also revealed astonishing economic and political miscalculations. Accepting erroneous economic information was not Mao's death in 1976, the data supporting the Dhazhai model were accepted by Western observers less ideologically sympathetic than the two Indian delegations dispatched to China in 1956; reports from China crediting productivity gains to local initiative and self-help based on cooperative management of capital and labor were surprising; until

widely credited in the United States. Influential members of India's

Planning Commission also believed the productivity claims

made

on behalf of Chinese agrarian reorganization. The two delegations brought back seemingly credible accounts of high levels of labor mobilization in cooperative

farming areas, intensive utilization of under-

employed labor in the construction of physical assets, reclamation of wasteland, and water management.^ They concluded that the reports

30 percent increases in agricultural production over a threeas they may year period were not only valid for the intensive projects but general to China. These methods, they believed, could have been be transplanted to India.^ After Mao's death in 1976, increased availability of long-term aggregate statistics and revelations discrediting the Dhazhai approach destroyed the myth that China's agriculture had been transformed by collectivization and ideology. In fact, long-term food grain growth rates for China lagged behind those for India. Between 1954-57 and 1971-74, China's annual growth averaged 2 percent while India's averaged 2.5 percent. After 1976, and particularly after 1980, when China's agriculture became more like India's with the implementation of the "responsibility system," China's and India's ^° average annual growth rates in food grain production were similar. Some Indian planners shared Mao's belief that ideological commitment, land redistribution, and agrarian reorganization could accomplish as much as or more than investment in agriculture. In 1956, of 15 to





during the second five-year plan, the Planning Commission's deputy chairman, V. T. Krishnamachari, circulated a note in which he reiterated the view that

more

efficient use of labor-intensive

could assure an increase of 40

techniques

percent in agricultural production dur-

ing the second plan without any increase in investment outlay."

The

was not wholly fanciful in view of the great productivity differences, especially on rice land, between India and East Asia. In fact, the figure

norm

for increases in agricultural production for five-year plan peri-

both China and India has been about 15 percent. The political miscalculation was to underestimate the high levels of ideological, institutional, and political control that lay behind the Chi-

ods

in

317

Policies

and

Politics of the Agricultural Sector

nese effort. Nehru's appreciation of and talent for party organization were never strong. Indian planning officials were better at formulating

than at implementing policy. The fact that implementation

is

the focus

unwanted legislation in India became more evident in the 1970s. Together, Nehru and the planning officials persuaded themof resistance to

purported Chinese gains could be achieved without the imbued with suitable ideological fervor and dismantling open competitive politics. The selves that

costs of creating a massive cadre organization

party delegations that returned from China emphasized the voluntarism of Chinese reforms. Nehru and the planners seem to have thought that introduction of an additional layer of administration, the

new block-level administration of the Community Development Program initiated in 1952, supplemented by "non-official leadership,'"^ would be able to inspire, organize, and manage the collective transformation of Indian agriculture.

To achieve productivity

via collective farming, the

the Indian National Congress in of

what was seem

1959 approved

called cooperative joint farming.

Its

Nagpur

a resolution in favor

revolutionary possi-

to have dawned on Congress members only been introduced. It said that bilities

session of

after

it

had

the future agrarian pattern should be that of cooperative joint farming, in which the land will be pooled for joint cultivation, the farmers continuing to retain their property rights, and getting a share

from the net produce

proportion to their land. Further, those own the land or not, will get a share in proportion to the work put in by them on the joint

who

actually

farm [our

work

in

the land, whether they

italics].'^

Depending on which of the

would count, nonand landowners or cultivating tenants laborers could be expected to benefit most. Many Congress delegates thought the last passage was the one that would count, and envisioned de facto expropriation. It is hard to imagine why the Congress leadership supposed the resolution would be placidly accepted. And it is hard to underitalicized passages

cultivating

stand

why Nehru thought

could be enforced without massive coer-

it

cion and ideological mobilization. cion even

if

others were.

The

He was

not prepared to apply coer-

resolution did not encounter opposition

passage through the Congress state and national party committees prior to Nagpur, because few thought Nehru and his Congress in its

allies

and supporters meant

it.

In the event, the resolution

was

swiftly followed by a crescendo of

DEMAND GROUPS

318

Congress party, and the formation of India's only conservative party, the Sv^atantra, to defend property rights in land.^"* Led by rural notabilities, it counted on support from the much-expanded class of independent cultivators who, after criticism, the prospect of a split in the

landlord abolition, also had a stake in landow^nership. Their leader-to-

be in North India, Charan Singh, led the forces in the Congress party that defeated the

Nagpur

resolution.

Mao's prediction, that abolition

of landlords without other measures, such as collectivization, will deter later

land reform was amply borne out. Landlord abolition simulta-

neously deprived agrarian reform politics of

its

most conspicuous

tar-

and resulted in the embourgoisement of the beneficiaries. The retreat of Nehru and the Planning Commission from the cooperative joint farming resolution was accelerated by signs that China might not be the friendly Asian power that Nehru supposed. In March and April 1959, a major rebellion in Tibet was followed by the flight of the Dalai Lama to India. A few months later, evidence surfaced of Chinese encroachments on the Indian border in Ladakh. Both cast an unfavorable, if irrelevant, light on Chinese models. The defeat of the Nagpur resolution marked the end of efforts at the national level to bring about large-scale structural change in Indian agriculture and triggered early manifestations of agrarian politics. Congress's efforts to lower ceilings on landholding became suspect beause they were now read as threatening property rights in agriculture. Meant to redistribute land to tenants and landless laborers at the expense of large landowners, efforts to lower ceilings survived the Nagpur debacle but encountered stiff resistance at the state level, where landed property interests were entrenched and powerful. The result was flawed, easily evaded legislation and ineffective implementation after get

protracted delays. Agriculture

and

ceilings legislation

and

is

a state subject under the constitution,

implementation are state responsibilities. New Delhi could bring state Congress comits

Congress party leaders in mittees and Congress governments to water but had difficulty making them drink. Their leadership and electoral support were based on cultivators and large landowners who were reluctant to pass and even more reluctant to implement the second wave of land reform. Neither the ceilings legislation of the early 1960s nor that of the early 1970s has borne

much

fruit.

The CPI-M-led governments

in

West Bengal and Kerala have passed

and implemented second-wave land reform legislation. In Kerala, "land to the tiller" legislation implemented in the seventies affected 40 percent of all operational holdings by transferring control from "large" landowners to their tenants.'^ West Bengal tenancy and admin-

319

Policies

and

Politics of the Agricultural Sector

although yet to be fully documented by nongovernhave made tenants more secure and enabled them to be

istrative reforms,

ment

sources,'**

active participants in the enforcement of legislation

and allocation of resources by local government and administrative bodies. During the Nehru era, India was able to pursue an industrial strat-

egy by relying on PL. 480 grain shipments from America. These shipments made adequate amounts of food available at relatively low prices to India's

urban and industrial population. Some

criticized reliance

on

480 food as a form of dependence. Others argued that it was bad for India's agriculture because it depressed farm prices, thereby depriving the Indian farmer of the incentive needed to increase production. P.L.

Nehru used the food aid to pursue investments in industry that he believed would make India economically independent. The P.L. 480 food aid made it possible for India to avoid the political costs of extracting food from the countryside. India would industrialize like the Soviet Union but would avoid sacrificing lives and freedom to do so. It was a bargain that benefited both participants. Nehru got what he wanted while American farmers, who were producing enormous surpluses during these years, got the prices and income they wanted. The publicly funded purchases of the Commodity Credit Corporation helped maintain a floor under American agricultural prices. Once the "structural" solution of collective farming was defeated, Nehru no longer reon Indian farmers to feed the country. In any case the technological means new seeds, chemical fertilizers, increased major and minor irrigation that could justify large-scale investment in agriculture were not yet available. Gains in agricultural production were achieved in the 1950s but they were the result of increases in the amount of land under cultivation. lied

— —

The Second

Strategy: Agricultural Technology

The second

agricultural strategy focused

puts, increased investment in self-reliance.

It

grew out of

and Self-Reliance

on new technologies and agriculture, and food production

in-

for

a series of independently caused but con-

juncturally related events: the death, in

May 1964

of Prime Minister

Jawaharlal Nehru, the primary advocate of the industrial strategy, and his replacement by Lai Bahadur Shastri, more a country than a city

1965 Indo-Pakistan and Vietnam wars that led United States president Lyndon Johnson to put Indian food supplies on a short and arbitrary tether and, as a result, led Indian officials and policy intellectuals to give top priority to food self-sufficiency; World Bank and

man;

the

DEMAND GROUPS

320

United States bargaining with the Government of India that Hnked increased investment in agricuhural programs (along with devaluation,

economic

liberalization,

and an export

drive) to the availability of in-

creased foreign aid for planned investment and for meeting balance of

payment problems; disappointment with the capacity of the industrial strategy to address the problem of rural poverty by generating large increases in employment; and the timing of scientific and technological breakthroughs, particularly the adaptation to Indian conditions of

new

high-yielding varieties of seed, such as the dwarf wheat initially

bred in Mexico.

By

the early 1960s,

modest

levels of

investment in agriculture began

blamed for low levels of food output. The agricultural product, which had grown by thirty-three index points (or about 3 percent per year) between 1950 and 1960, remained stagnant throughout the first half of the 1960s, except for one good year (1964—65). Population increased between 1961 and 1971 at a rate of 2.2 percent per year. Table 39 suggests the considerable disparity between increases in agricultural and manufacturing income that characterized the 1960s. The effects of low agricultural growth greatly diminished the positive effect on national income of the increases in mining and manufacturing. By 1964, when Shastri succeeded Nehru, agriculture had become a critical political issue for central and state cabinets. It sharply divided proponents of Nehru's industrial strategy in the Planning Commission from proponents of an agricultural strategy, who included some cabinet ministers and many state chief ministers. The Planning Commission sought to retain second- and third-plan investment proportions for industry in the fourth-plan draft and to fend off proportional increases in spending on physical inputs, such as chemical fertilizers or irrigation. It argued that if there was a food shortage, it was due to hoarding, not to production shortages, and could be solved by market intervention, such as government control of wholesale trade in food, to be

not by diverting investment to agriculture.

The Shastri,

and most

been slighted

ment

Subramaniam, Prime Minister ministers thought that agriculture had

minister of agriculture, state chief

in the

in agriculture

C.

Nehru era. Stagnation called and a more generous incentive

for greater invest-

price policy to in-

crease production.'^ These considerations were strengthened by reports in 1964 that the combined efforts of scientists supported by the

Rockefeller Foundation and the Indian Council of Agricultural Re-

new

maize and that plant geneticists funded by the Rockefeller Foundation had achieved a breakthrough by creating a hybrid of Mexican wheat and Japanese dwarf strains that

search had developed

varieties of

IS could achieve twice the output of Indian varieties.

ON

so so

I

oo

o so I

00 10

ON

oo VD I

SO

^

.y

^

ON

f-

£ X c S o u C

SO I

On

SO ON

On ^ SO O ON -C

SO so

I

ON

ON

o

S

''^

*->

r\

c

---

«0 ON

T-H I

d

ro

d

>.

"^

I

ON -H

3

ID

C

^

^ u«

rt '-^

^

.^

'^

rt

^ E

^^

C .3

—«

;/)

C «

^ O

ij ul

U

C

3

s^

—«

"rt

c

Z



r"

o

3

.

of: u ^ OS

O

d ^H

3 ^

i

(N

o o

0^ < —1

c u

u

1

Cil

1

G n

J

r^ ON

Ul (U

Vi *->

T—

C/5

-TD

o J5

o oo II

c

X

.2

^0

g

NO ON -^

lO OO

NO

0-)

-D

e o

e 3 C c

U

T3

o ^

C/5

3 O

G

lU (/5

FUl

C ""

is

-5

u >

^

rt

_c

-C

o

4->

-^ t^

C

U

II

^

c

_c

>.

J

^


^ J«

Q 1

E ^ >o ^ ^

c O £X" 2; E

c c c o C >, W OS C!h ^ O t>0

t^roroooVOioVOONrn^ONON t^ t^

'^*

o

^' lo

K

Vsd

'sd

od

o

ON

w

^

-3 60

E

D.

•— S S ::^

•=;

^^

E

bO*^

6 PLh

I 3

Gh

(U

-S

'c;

§1^ E ^ ^

— ^ ^

C "^ -^ J5 .5 60. S 3 ^2 *-^ -O E3 ii :5 S 5 o iS o ^ 60 O > 3 3 ..^ -7: c/5

--^

J5

J>

-

..

H

^ > r— f^OJ > « H ^ O '^ 6 •• C i5 >1^.2 ^ J3 S

I

o o

ON ON

o

00 00

Q

4->

CO 10

s

3

1^

CO

-T3

'-'3

(U

—I

;>->

(/: 1

^

o,^ oj

y

o o

o o d d




K

00

C "

E2

^ ^ ^ t/5

TD

ra

""Co:: S o ^^

4-1

^-^ p

1/5

rt

^ 55

i-(

O

rt

"-I

i-T"

4->

.

PU

sp-su s=tO ^ as