205 84 2MB
English Pages 37 [51] Year 2018
ASEAN AND THE EC Trends in the Cost of Capital in Major EC Countries and Their Effects on the Production Structure
The Institute of Southeast Asian Studies was established as an autonomous organization in May 1968. It is a regional research centre for scholars and other specialists concerned with modem Southeast Asia, particularly the multi-faceted problems of stability and security, economic development, and political and social change. The Institute is governed by a twenty-two-member Board of Trustees comprising nominees from the Singapore Government, the National University of Singapore, the various Chambers of Commerce, and professional and civic organizations. A ten-man Executive Committee oversees day-to-day operations; it is chaired by the Director, the Institute's chief academic and administrative officer. The ASEAN Economic Research Unit is an integral part of the Institute, coming under the overall supervision of the Director who is also the Chairman of its Management Committee. The Unit was formed in 1979 in response to the need to deepen understanding of economic change and political developments in ASEAN. The day-to-day operations of the Unit are the responsibility of the Co-ordinator. A Regional Advisory Board, consisting of a senior economist from each of the ASEAN countries, guides the work of the Unit.
ASEAN-EC Economic Relations Series General Editors: Norbert Wagner, Tan Loong-Hoe, Narongchai Akrasanee
ASEAN AND THE EC Trends in the Cost of Capital in Major EC Countries and Their Effects on the Production Structure
Georg Erdmann Bruno Fritsch Center for Economic Research Swiss Federal Institute ofTechnology
ASEAN Economic Research Unit INSTITUTE OF SOUTHEAST ASIAN STUDIES
Published by Institute of Southeast Asian Studies Heng Mui Keng Terrace Pasir Panjang Singapore 0511 All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise, without the prior permission of the Institute of Southeast Asian Studies. © 1989 Institute of Southeast Asian Studies The responsibility for facts and opinions expressed in this publication rests exclusively with the authors and their interpretations do not necessarily reflect the views or the policy of the Institute or its supporters.
Cataloguing in Publication Data
Erdmann, Georg. ASEAN and the EC : trends in the cost of capital in major EC countries and their effects on the production structure / Georg Erdmann and Bruno Fritsch. 1. Capital -- Prices -- European Economic Community countries. 2. Production (Economic theory) 3. ASEAN countries --Foreign economic relations -- European Economic Community countries. 4. European Economic Community countries -- Foreign economic relations -- ASEAN countries. I. Fritsch, Bruno. II. Institute of Southeast Asian Studies (Singapore). ASEAN Economic Research Unit. III. Title. HD70 E8E66 1989 ISBN 981-3035-404
Printed in Singapore by Loi Printing Pte Ltd
Contents
List of Tables Foreword Acknowledgements
vii ix xi
I.
Introduction
1
II.
Components of the "Costs of Capital"
3
III.
Lessons from the Past
12
IV.
Some Implications for the European Economy and the ASEAN-EC Relationship
26
Bibliography
35
List of Tables
Table 1
Income Taxation and the Market Interest Rate
Table 2
Yield of Long-term Government Bonds
12
Table 3
Yield of Long-term Government Bonds in Real Terms
13
Table 4
Gross Investment in Machinery and Equipment plus Investment in Housing
14
Table 5
General Government Financial Balance
14
Table 6
Foreign Trade Balance
15
Table 7
Change in Consumer Prices
15
Table 8
Net Household Savings
16
Table 9
Gross Savings
16
Table 10
Total Tax Revenue
19
Table 11
Taxes and Social Security Contributions in 1985
19
Table 12
Personal Income Tax Rates
20
Table 13
Tax Rate on Retained Profits in 1984
21
Table 14
Corporate Tax Rates on Profits
22
Table 15
Average Fiscal Lifetime oflnvestments
22
Table 16
Treatment of Business Losses
23
5
viii
List of Tables
Table 17
User Cost of Capital in 1986
24
Table 18
Private Direct Investment Abroad
27
Table 19
Private Foreign Direct Investment
28
Table 20
Private Direct Investment Net
28
Table 21
Foreign Portfolio Investment Net
29
Table 22
Investment in Machinery and Equipment: Average Annual Growth Rate
30
Table 23
Foreign Direct Investment Net
32
Table 24
Portfolio Investment Net
33
Foreword
Structural change is the essence of economic growth both at the national and international level. Without structural change, stagnation will set in. The production structure in a country at a given point of time is the result of interactions between a number of factors, ranging from the demographic pattern and skill composition of the economically active population, to the available financial resources, the technology and the institutional framework. In addition, the structure of manufacturing is obviously also influenced by the patterns of demand. Changes in these supply and demand factors will affect the production structure and thus lead to structural change. The production structures of individual countries are increasingly linked and interdependent at the global level through international economic relations like trade in goods and services as well as movements of labour, capital, and other resources. Accordingly, changes in the production structure in one country will affect the structure of production in other countries and, hence, may have significant implications for the factors of production in these countries. Some factors of production may be adversely affected while others may benefit. Institutional changes may be required in order to adjust to the modified economic environment. Moreover, technological change may bring about yet unknown new developments in terms of products and production processes. The present study is part of an international research project on "The Development of Manufacturing in ASEAN and the EC and the Potential for Further ASEAN-EC Co-operation". This project is one component of the long-term research programme on ASEAN-EC Economic Relations launched by the ASEAN Economic Research Unit, Institute of Southeast Asian Studies, Singapore, with the generous support of the Konrad Adenauer Foundation, Federal Republic of Germany.
Foreword
X
The project on the development of manufacturing in ASEAN and the EC comprises studies on institutions and structural change; trends in the cost of labour and their effects on the production structure. trends in the cost of capital and their effects on the production structure; and trends in technological change and their effects on the production structure. These trends and their impact on structural change are analysed in the context of both the economies of ASEAN and those of the EC. This international research effort will promote a better understanding of the nature and causes of structural change in each regional grouping as well as the mutual impact of this change may have on both regions. We hope this study and others in the series will stimulate new ideas and reveal other areas for further ASEAN-EC cooperation.
Norbert Wagner Institute of Southeast Asian Studies Tan Loong-Hoe Institute of Southeast Asian Studies
November 1988
Narongchai Akrasanee Thailand Development Research Institute
Acknowledgements
This paper was prepared under the auspices of the international research project on "ASEAN-EC Economic Relations: The Development of Manufacturing in ASEAN and the EC and the Potential for Further ASEAN-EC Co-operation" launched by the Institute of Southeast Asian Studies (ISEAS), Singapore, with financial support from the Konrad Adenauer Foundation. Comments by Torsten Amelung and participants of a workshop on "ASEAN-EC Economic Relations: The Development of Manufacturing in ASEAN and the Potential for Further ASEAN-EC Co-operation", organized by !SEAS, are gratefully acknowledged.
I. Introduction
According to neo-classical economic theory, private investments are, among others, determined by the user cost of capital (Jorgenson 1963). The user cost of capital thereby is defined as the cost to the business firm of using a unit of capital for a period of time, expressed as a fraction of the machine's purchase price. In spite of the fact that the concept of the user cost of capital cannot cover the full range of factors which determine private investment decisions, it can be used as a screening device for the evolution of incentives or disincentives to investments. A long-term rise or fall of the user cost of capital will, ceteris paribus, lead to an inverse change of the investment trend in the economy. Further, changes in the multinational relation of the user cost of capital will probably have some impact on the international allocation of private investments. Recently, major shifts have taken place which in turn have changed the international competitiveness of European and OECD economies. These changes were triggered by the monetary authorities and national governments of these countries aiming at improving the ability to attract foreign private investments through direct subsidies or, more important, through significant tax reductions. However, in as far as these tax reductions are restraints on new investments only (instead of the whole economy), these measures do not improve the welfare position of the country, but create new allocation inefficiencies. In fact, economic and fiscal measures taken by the domestic governments result in shifts in the international flows of capital (direct investment and portfolio investment) which correspond to theoretical predictions. In a world with high capital mobility, economies with subsidized low user cost of new investments can attract high yielded capital from abroad whose marginal returns to investment do not cover the high cost of foreign capital to be transferred abroad. The (foreign) investor receives the benefit of high yields while the society suffers from low returns from investment.
2
Introduction
This analysis will discuss some of the consequences of the recent developments and changes affecting the user cost of capital. It is based upon five countries, namely, the United States, Japan, France, Germany, and the United Kingdom. The paper first demonstrates how the user cost of capital is to be calculated with respect to international comparisons; it then presents some figures about interest yields and tax rates which are condensed in form of estimates about the values of the user cost of capital given in the major EC and OECD countries; and finally it discusses the consequences of the recent evolutions on the international flow of private capital, among which the economic relation between ASEAN and the EC is of major importance.
II. Components of the "Costs of Capital" Formal Approach
The user cost of capital is thought to encompass several distinct cost components, most important of which are: Interest cost. For financing an investment, either money must be borrowed at the nominal interest rate "i" or else an investor loses the interest "i" he would receive by investing in a savings account the funds that he uses to buy the investment goods. Due to risk aversion, this observation is based upon the assumption that the alternative investment bears the same risk structure to the investor. Therefore, interest costs are subject to the risk associated with the investment; Physical deterioration. It affects the ability of capital goods to produce. The depreciation rate indicates the annual decline in value of the capital goods. Increase in the market value by inflation. Some capital goods may depreciate but at the same time their market value is rising due to the effects of inflation, which continuously raises the price of old and new capital goods; Capital income taxation. Firms make investment decisions by equating the marginal product of capital with the user cost of capital before taxes. However, as savers care about the level of their income after taxes, an investment must pay a higher before-tax interest rate and hence incur a higher user cost; Fiscal depreciation. Firms cut some of their corporation tax by reducing the value of depreciation of plant and equipment. The maximal amount of depreciation is determined by rules set by the government; Follow up cost. These are costs for after sales services, maintenance, repairs, and so forth; Subsidies. The government can reduce the user cost of capital by liberalizing depreciation rules allowing for the formation of hidden profits. Similarly, a large number of measures subsidizing investments may reduce the user cost of capital.
4
Components of the "Costs of Capital"
In the following exercise, some functional form will be developed showing how the variation of these factors affects the user cost of capital. Assuming first a situation where earnings are free of income taxation, the average user cost of capital cc(t) is
cc(t) q(t)
+ dep
cc(t) q(t)
q(t+ 1) - q(t + 1) - q(t) q(t)
x q(t)
... (1)
user cost of capital, purchase price for capital goods, expected level of annual earnings (revenues) plus interest payments for debt in relation to the purchase cost of investment goods, economic depreciation rate.
dep
In general, 1 IS a weighted average of profits paid to the holders of the company's assets plus the retained profits r, and the unit cost of debt k, which includes interest payments and the cost of banking, flotation cost, and so forth. According to the Modigliani-Miller theorem (1958), both r and k should be equal on perfect capital markets and only depend upon risk, but as the capital markets are usually organized in such a way that assets and debt instruments incorporate different degrees of default risk, this does not hold in practice. Accordingly, the marginal user cost of capital turns out to be
cc(t) q(t)
r_ret + r_dis +
X [
q(t) r ret r dis dE dA k
dep
1
+
(1
dE -d.A ) x k + dep
q(t+ 1) - q(1) q(t+ 1) - q(t) q(t) ] - [ q(t) ]
... (2)
purchase price for capital goods, rate of retained profits per unit investment, rate of distributed profits per unit investment, marginal propensity to finance new investments (assets) by equity, unit cost of debt, mainly the market interest rate, economic depreciation rate.
The situation becomes more complex, if income taxation is included. Generally speaking, any tax system gives rise to a wedge between the pre-tax return to an investment (that is, the gross return on real invesment minus its
Trends in the Cost of Capital in Major EC Countries
5
economic depreciation) and the ultimate return to the saver. The wedge is usually divided into two components: one which is legally levied on the business sector (say, through the corporate tax system) and which creates a wedge between the pre-tax return and the market interest rate; and another that is levied on the individual and creates a wedge between the market interest rate and the return to the saver. TABLE 1 Income Taxation and the Market Interest Rate (Assumption: 0 per cent inflation)
consumer time preference
< personal income taxation
market interest rate