180 1 4MB
English Pages 340 [334] Year 2009
Accounting for Services
Accounting for Services The Economic Development of the Indonesian Service Sector, ca. 1900-2000 Daan Marks
a
Amsterdam, 2009
This publication has been made possible with the support of the Unger-Van Brerofonds.
isbn 978 90 5260 336 0 © 2009 Daan Marks and Aksant Academic Publishers,Amsterdam All rights reserved, including those of translation into foreign languages. No part of this publication may be reproduced in any form, by photoprint, microfilm or any other means, nor transmitted into a machine language without written permission from the publisher. Lay-out: Hanneke Kossen, Amsterdam Cover design: Studio Dien Bos, Amsterdam Aksant Academic Publishers, p.o. Box 2169, 1000 cd Amsterdam, The Netherlands
Contents
Acknowledgements 13
1
Introduction 17 1.1 The context 17 1.2 Bridging a gap 19 1.3 Theoretical context: the service sector and economic growth 20 1.3.1 Definition and classification of services 20 1.3.2 The service sector and economic growth 23 1.3.3 Economic factors affecting the development of the share of services in real output 27 1.3.4 Socio-economic factors affecting the development of the service share in total output 30 1.4 National accounting: aim, advantages and disadvantages 31 1.5 Indonesia’s economic history and its pecularities 34 1.5.1 Indonesia’s economic history in a bird eye’s view 34 1.5.2 Some peculiarities in studying Indonesia’s economic history 38 1.6 Outline of the book 40
2 National accounting for services in Indonesia 41 2.1 Introduction 41 2.2 History of Indonesian national income estimates 41 2.3 Statistical sources 43 2.4 Estimating value added in services 46 2.4.1 Transport and communications 46 2.4.1.1 Rail transport 47 2.4.1.2 Road transport 47 2.4.1.3 Water transport 51 2.4.1.4 Air transport 52 2.4.1.5 Communications 52 2.4.2 Trade 53 2.4.2.1 Trade margins in colonial times 53 2.4.2.2 Trade margins in Indonesia’s national accounts 55 2.4.3 Government 59 2.4.4 Ownership of dwellings 61
2.4.5 Financial sector 64 2.4.6 Other services 66 2.5 Assessing the reliability of the estimates 68 3
The development of the Indonesian service sector: a quantitative analysis 71 3.1 Introduction 71 3.2 Developments in employment structure 72 3.3 Value added in the service sector 79 3.3.1 Economic structure 79 3.3.2 Growth in the service sectors 81 3.4 Labour productivity 85 3.5 Concluding remarks 88
4
Roads to riches? Transportation and economic development in Indonesia 91 4.1 Introduction 91 4.2 Transportation and economic growth: theoretical framework 92 4.2.1 Fogel’s social savings 92 4.2.2 A spatial price equilibrium model 93 4.2.3 Other theoretical foundations 95 4.2.4 Evolution of transport networks 98 4.3 Transport developments in Indonesia, 1900-2000 100 4.3.1 Water transport 100 4.3.2 Rail transport 112 4.3.3 Road transport 122 4.3.4 Air transport 127 4.4 Concluding remarks 129
5
Involution and growth: the ambiguous role of the trade sector in the economic development of Indonesia 131 5.1 Introduction 131 5.2 Foreign trade: an engine of growth? 132 5.2.1 A century of foreign trade 132 5.2.2 Changes in the direction of trade: regionalisation of trade 137 5.2.3 Trade policy 140 5.2.4 Foreign trade as engine of growth 144 5.3 Domestic dynamics in the trade sector: involutionary growth? 145 5.3.1 Employment and labour productivity 145 5.3.2 Changes in the organisation of distribution 147 5.3.3 Involutionary growth 151 5.4 Concluding remarks 156
6
Unity or diversity? Market integration through trade and transport 159 6.1 Introduction 159 6.2 Stable food prices, market integration and economic development 161 6.3 Intertemporal rice price stabilisation in Indonesia: government intervention 162 6.4 Spatial price differences in Indonesia 169 6.4.1 A simple approach 169 6.4.2 Advanced testing for market integration: method 171 6.4.3 Advanced testing for market integration: results 174 6.5 Concluding remarks 181
7
Conclusions 183 7.1 Accounting for services 183 7.2 The economic development of the Indonesian service sector, ca. 1900-2000 184 7.3 Transport, trade and integrating markets 185 7.4 The service sector: tertiary? 188
Appendices 1 National accounting for transport and communications 191 2 National accounting for trade 259 3 National accounting for government services 279 4 National accounting for housing 293 5 National accounting for financial services 299 6 National accounting for other services 307
References 321
List of Tabels
Table 1.1 Table 1.2
isic classification of activity 22 Changes in service shares over time, France, United Kingdom, and United States 28
Table 2.1 Table 2.2 Table 2.3 Table 2.4 Table 2.5 Table 2.6 Table 2.7 Table 2.8 Table 2.9 Table 2.10 Table 2.11 Table 2.12 Table 2.13 Table 2.14 Table 2.15 Table 2.16 Table 2.17
Main bps publications relevant for this study 46 Taxis in Surabaya, 1925-1929 48 Value added by taxis in Indonesia, 1929 48 Value added of road transport, 1930 49 Degree of urbanisation, 1890-1930 49 Trade margins in the Netherlands, 1913 and 1987 54 Peasant crops, volumes traded at 10 per cent margin 56 Trade margins for different export commodities 56 Trade margins used by Neumark on other commodities 57 Salaries and wages paid by the colonial government, 1922-1931 Number of dwellings in Indonesia, 1930 61 Monthly expenditure on rent in guilders, August 1925 62 Total output housing sector, 1930 63 Housing in Indonesia’s i-o tables 64 Other services in the i-o tables 67 Value added by other services 68 Quality of Indonesian service sector estimates, 1930 69
Table 3.1 Table 3.2 Table 3.3 Table 3.4 Table 3.5 Table 3.6 Table 3.7 Table 3.8 Table 3.9
By-employment in 1905 population count 73 Consequence of by-employment in the 1905 population count 74 Peasants engaged in by-employment in 1905, by category of employment 76 Annual growth in employment by sector, 1930-2000 78 Composition of the service sector, 1900-2000 79 Average annual sectoral growth rates, 1900-2000 84 Labour productivity in Indonesia’s service sector, 1905-2000 86 Average annual labour productivity growth, 1905-2000 87 Decomposition of labour productivity growth, 1930-2000 88
Table 4.1 Table 4.2 Table 4.3 Table 4.4 Table 4.5 Table 4.6
Registered merchant fleet in the Netherlands-Indies, 1890-1939 100 Inter-island freight and productivity of kpm and pelni, 1950-1960 107 Tonnage, cargo and productivity of inter-island fleet, 1957-64 107 Cargo and passengers carried by pelni, 1962-1967 109 The Indonesian merchant fleet, 1968-2000 109 Average annual growth in grt and loaded cargo, 1968-2000 110
60
Table 4.7 Table 4.8 Table 4.9 Table 4.10 Table 4.11 Table 4.12 Table 4.13 Table 4.14 Table 4.15 Table 4.16 Table 4.17 Table 4.18
Productivity in inter-island shipping, 1993-1997 110 Railway and tramway companies in Java, Madura and Sumatra 113 Developments in rail transport, 1890-1940 116 Average annual growth of rail transport, 1890-1939 116 Developments in rail transport, 1949-2000 119 Road conditions, 1967 123 Road development plan, 1957 124 Average annual growth in motor vehicles, 1949-2000 125 Number of vehicles per 1,000 inhabitants, 1950-2000 125 Average annual growth in length of road, 1959-2000 125 Length of road per 1,000 inhabitants, 1954-2000 125 Air transport developments in Indonesia, 1930-2000 127
Table 5.1 Table 5.2 Table 5.3 Table 5.4 Table 5.5 Table 5.6 Table 5.7 Table 5.8 Table 5.9 Table 5.10 Table 5.11 Table 5.12
Composition of imports into Indonesia by economic categories, 1950-2000 136 Exports from the Netherlands-Indies by destination, 1900-1939 138 Imports into the Netherlands-Indies by origin, 1900-1939 138 Exports from Indonesia by destination, 1952-2000 139 Imports to Indonesia by origin, 1952-2000 139 Trade and economic growth in Indonesia, 1900-1997 145 Occupational structure, 1905-2000 146 Labour productivity in Indonesia’s service sector, 1905-2000 147 Average annual labour productivity growth, 1930-2000 147 Trade margins in rural Java, 1982 150 Employment in trade sector, 1905-2000 150 Share of urban self-employed in total labour force in a selection of economically advanced countries, 1930-1999 154
Table 6.1 Table 6.2 Table 6.3
Net rice imports as percentage of domestic supply, 1900-2000 164 Augmented Dickey-Fuller unit root tests 176 Cointegration results for Semarang, Medan and Banjarmasin, 1949-2006 178
Table A1.1 Table A1.2 Table A1.3 Table A1.4 Table A1.5 Table A1.6 Table A1.7 Table A1.8 Table A1.9 Table A1.10
Estimation of value added in rail transport, 1890-1939 193 Key indicators for railway transport, 1948-2000 198 Railway transport according to i-o tables 200 Value added of railway transport, 1890-2000 201 Motor vehicles, 1910-1940 206 Cars in operation in Indonesia, 1913-1940 207 Value added by taxis in Indonesia, 1929 208 Value added by road transport, 1930 209 Value added by road transport, 1900-1940 210 Key indicators for road transport, 1949-2000 212
Table A1.11 Road transport according to i-o tables 214 Table A1.12 Value added by road transport, 1900-2000 216 Table A1.13 General water transport statistics, 1891-1940 220 Table A1.14 Statistics on kpm, 1891-1940 223 Table A1.15 Value added by water transport, 1891-1940 227 Table A1.16 Loading and unloading in Indonesian harbours, 1952-2002 229 Table A1.17 Arrival of ships and vessels in selected harbours, 1938-1959 230 Table A1.18 Value added by sea transport according to i-o tables 232 Table A1.19 Value added by inland water transport according to i-o tables 232 Table A1.20 Value added by sea transport and inland water transport according to i-o tables 232 Table A1.21 Value added by water transport, 1891-2000 233 Table A1.22 Indicators for air transport and value added, 1928-1940 237 Table A1.23 Ticket prices, knilm, 1929-1933 238 Table A1.24 Prices for freight, knilm, 1929-1933 238 Table A1.25 Indicators for air traffic, 1948-1973 239 Table A1.26 Government airlines services (domestic and international), 1964-2000 240 Table A1.27 Private airlines services (domestic), 1964-2000 242 Table A1.28 Value added by air transport according to i-o tables 244 Table A1.29 Value added by air transport, 1928-2000 245 Table A1.30 Estimation of value added by communications, 1901-1940 248 Table A1.31 Income of ptt, 1938-1955 251 Table A1.32 Value added by communications according to i-o tables 251 Table A1.33 Key indicators for communications, 1956-2000 252 Table A1.34 Value added by communications, 1901-2000 255 Table A2.1 Profit margins, Hagemeijer and Internatio, 1914-1939 259 Table A2.2 Trade margins based on i-o tables, 1975-2000 261 Table A2.3 Value added in trade sector, 1900-2000 273 Table A3.1 Table A3.2 Table A3.3 Table A3.4 Table A3.5 Table A3.6 Table A3.7 Table A3.8
Government administration and defence, 1951-1954 279 Government administration and defence in Indonesia’s national accounts, 1958-2000 281 Government administration and defense according to Indonesia’s i-o tables 281 Government budget: personnel expenditures, 1969/1970-1999/2000 282 Government budget: other expenditures, 1969/1970-1999/2000 283 Government budget, 1950-1968 284 Number of civil servants, 1930 285 Government payroll, 1926 285
Table A3.9 Table A3.10 Table A3.11 Table A3.12
Government finance, 1867-1939 286 Government budget, 1900-1907 287 Government budget, 1908-1940 288 Value added by government services, 1900-2000 290
Table A4.1 Table A4.2 Table A4.3 Table A4.4
Monthly expenditure on rent, August 1925 293 Monthly rents, 1930-1960 294 Monthly expenditure per family in Jakarta, 1953 294 Value added by housing, 1900-2000 296
Table A5.1 Value added by the financial sector, 1900-1940 300 Table A5.2 Financial sector in Indonesia’s i-o tables, 1971-2000 304 Table A5.3 Value added of financial sector, 1900-2000 304 Table A6.1 Other services in the i-o tables 307 Table A6.2 Value added by other services for benchmark years, 1930-2000 308 Table A6.3 Value added by other services, 1900-2000 309 Table A7.1 Number of people employed and population size, 1905-2005 314
List of figures
Figure 1.1 The three-sector model 24 Figure 1.2 Map of Indonesia with its major cities 35 Figure 2.1 Gross profit margins of Hagemeijer & Internatio, 1914-1939 55 Figure 3.1 Figure 3.2 Figure 3.3 Figure 3.4 Figure 3.5
Occupational structure, 1905-2000 72 Economic structure, 1900-2000 80 Economic structure, 1966-2005 80 Development of value added in transport and communications, 1900-2000 82 Development of value added in the service sector, 1900-2000 82
Figure 4.1 Figure 4.2 Figure 4.3 Figure 4.4 Figure 4.5 Figure 4.6 Figure 4.7
Model of the benefits of transport 94 Schematic representation of the relationship between transport and economic development 97 Transport network evolution 99 Share of prahu shipping in local trade, 1929-1939 102 kpm transportation costs, 1891-1939 103 The kpm shipping network, 1891 and 1940 104 Water transportation costs, 1900-2000 111
Figure 4.8 The railway network of Java and Madura, 1899-1925 114 Figure 4.9 The railway network in Sumatra, 1925 115 Figure 4.10 Rail transport costs, 1890-1957 117 Figure 4.11 Developments in numbers of passengers and freight carried by rail, 1890-2000 119 Figure 4.12 Developments in passenger-kilometres and ton-kilometres, 1890-1900 120 Figure 4.13 Rail transport costs, 1890-2000 121 Figure 4.14 Development of road transport costs, 1890-1995 126 Figure 4.15 Air transport costs, 1930-2000 129 Figure 5.1 Figure 5.2 Figure 5.3 Figure 5.4 Figure 5.5 Figure 5.6 Figure 5.7 Figure 5.8
Foreign trade values in Indonesia, 1900-2003 133 Indonesia’s openness to foreign trade, 1900-2000 134 Foreign trade taxes as percentage of total government revenue 141 Openness and growth, 1900-1997 144 Marketing structure Indonesia, ca. 1900-1940 148 Marketing structure in rural Java, 1982 149 Share of urban self-employed in the total labour force, 1965-2003 154 Relative levels of labour productivity, trade sector versus other service sectors, usa, Brazil, Mexico and Indonesia 157
Figure 6.1 Figure 6.2 Figure 6.3 Figure 6.4 Figure 6.5 Figure 6.6
Rice price fluctuations, 1920-2006 163 Price fluctuations, Java vs Outer Islands, 1949-2006 165 Marketing structure of rice 168 Functioning of Bulog 169 Fluctuations between markets, 1925-2006 171 Map of Indonesia with its major cities 175
Figure 7.1 From parasite to catalyst 189
Acknowledgements
‘What is this Favour Bank? (…) It’s the most powerful bank in the world, and you’ll find it in every sphere of life’ — Paolo Coelho, the Zahir
In the above passage the Brazilian author Paolo Coelho writes about the Favour Bank. It is a bank in which one makes deposits, not in cash, but in favours. One day, the depositor will ask for a favour himself, and that is the time for someone to pay off his outstanding debts. When I was a teenager I always told people that my ultimate dream was to become rich. The best way to get rich, I thought, was by becoming a banker. Therefore only few would have expected me to choose an academic career, since writing a dissertation clearly does not make you rich in monetary terms. But just like in economics, one should also account for the non-monetary remuneration. Taking this into account writing this thesis has definitely enriched me. Moreover, it enables me at this moment to act as a banker and pay off some of my outstanding debts from my account at the Favour Bank. First of all I thank my supervisor, Jan Luiten van Zanden. He offered me the opportunity to drown myself in the economic development of Indonesia, while at the same time his guidance and suggestions always kept me on track. To broaden my horizon, trips to do research or present papers in Indonesia, Japan, Australia and Uruguay, to name just a few destinations, were always supported. With a smile I recall the numerous hours we spent in traffic jams (macet, ya!) in Jakarta and Bogor. I am particularly grateful to Thomas Lindblad. Sharing an interest in both economics and Indonesia, he supervised me through my ma thesis and drew my attention to a PhD position to do research on the economic development of Indonesia. In the course of my research I profited greatly not only from his comments and suggestions, but also from his extensive network in the field of the economic history of Indonesia. It was a pleasure to have him as a co-promotor. I benefited greatly from Jan-Pieter Smits’ expertise in the research on the service sector. Pierre van der Eng guided me from a distance through the principles of national accounting and the many statistical sources on Indonesia, and gave very
13
| Acknowledgements
detailed comments on my work during my stay at anu in Canberra. I am also grateful to the Indonesia Project at anu, and specifically to Chris Manning and Hal Hill for offering me the opportunity to spend a short period in the stimulating research environment there. I am indebted to the personnel of the various libraries and archives where this research was carried out. I especially appreciate the efforts of Rini Hogewoning and Josephine Schrama at the Royal Netherlands Institute of Southeast Asian and Caribbean Studies (kitlv). My numerous requests for excessively heavy statistical yearbooks were met with surprise, but never with complaint. A number of colleagues at the International Institute of Social History (iish) made the sometimes lonely process of writing a dissertation more social. Regrettably I cannot thank them all, but I do want to mention a few of them. During uncountable coffee breaks and on many occasions outside the institute the important and, more often, less important issues in life were discussed with Christiaan van Bochove, Jelle van Lottum and Rob Wadman. Moreover, together we formed the iish cycling team, which was complemented with Aad Blok, Marti Huetink, Frank de Jong and team manager Jacques van Gerwen, for the Amstel Gold Race in 2007 and 2008. Last but not least, Danielle van den Heuvel provided some welcome balance to the gender bias in topics discussed during breaks. The joint work with Ewout Frankema on inequality in Indonesia was a welcome and inspiring sidestep. Our discussions helped to shape my thinking about economic development and have greatly improved this dissertation. Dennie Oude Nijhuis has become a close colleague through the PhD-training program of the N.W. Posthumus Institute. During my visits to Indonesia Menno, Ratih and their children Ananda and Igor always made me feel at home in their house. My friends of ‘Bruusk’ regularly brightened my days with numerous pointless emails. Combined with our regular encounters this was often a welcome distraction from my work. The same holds for my best friend Julian Spierenburg. Our nearly daily phone contact, regular visits to the gym and playing in the same soccer team on Sunday kept me in touch with ‘normal’ life. Special thanks go to my family. They are very much at the basis of this dissertation. In 1995 we made our most exotic trip as a family, to Indonesia. It was then that my interest and fascination for Indonesia were triggered. My parents, John and Geertrui Marks, have always provided a warm, stable and supportive family environment in which I could flourish. Their confidence and encouragement have been a continuous source of strength. With this dissertation I proudly follow in the footsteps of my father. I also want to thank my brother, Geert Jan, and my sister, Vera, for their on-going interest and morale support, but even more for the discussions about other things than work (mainly soccer, my mom would say). From the very beginning, my parents-in-law, Lex and Hetty Wunderink, have made me feel most welcome in their family. Moreover, being convinced of my capacities they challenged me to be ambitious. Therefore it is no exaggeration to say that
14
| Accounting for Services
without them my career could have been very different. Furthermore, being slightly ahead of me in the process of writing a dissertation Lex could very well relate to my sometimes changing moods. Over the last few years family and friends provided the necessary and welcome distraction from my work. In this respect I want to mention Rachid Baghat and Ruth ten Broeke. Hopefully I have not bored them too much with talking about my research during family gatherings. My friends Nanko van den Brule and Robert Tielenius Kruijthoff have continuously showed interest in my work, but, if unnecessary, fortunately hardly ever for more than five minutes. I very much enjoyed the company of Sven, Charlotte and their beautiful daughter Hannah de Heer, Stefan and Inger Wunderink, Herman and Diane Wunderink, and Freek and Fia Wunderink on numerous occasions both at home and elsewhere around the globe. They are much more than just family-in-law. Special reference should be made here to my grandmother-in-law An Bouvy, who has taught me not only numerous proverbs, but also, I think unconsciously, many important lessons for life. Unfortunately none of my own grandparents outlived the completion of this dissertation. But I am thankful for their great interest during their lives in both my personal life and my career, and I am sure they would be proud of this book. The last one to thank is my wife, Esther. You are not only my beloved one but also my soul mate. It is your love, unconditional support and encouragement that helped me through the sometimes difficult moments in writing this thesis. And together we enjoyed the many happy moments. To some these words might sound obligatory, but only you know how sincere and true they are. Whatever and wherever the future will bring us, together we have the world in our hands. It is therefore that I dedicate this book to you.
15
| Acknowledgements
1
Introduction
1.1
The context In the lecture Simon Kuznets delivered in Stockholm when he received the Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences in 1971, he encouraged researchers not to concentrate only on industrial countries but to analyse less developed countries (ldcs) as well. ‘For the less developed countries the tasks of economic research are somewhat different: the great need is for a wider supply of tested data, which means essentially data that have been scrutinised in the process of use for economic analysis. […] One may hope, but with limited expectations, that the tasks of refining analysis and measurement in the developed countries will not be pursued to the exclusion or neglect of badly needed studies of the less developed countries, studies that would deal with the quantitative bases and institutional conditions of their performance, in addition to those concentrating on what appear to be their major bottlenecks and the seemingly optimal policy prescriptions.’ (Kuznets 1973: 258) By now more than 35 years have passed and a growing number of researchers – some perhaps encouraged by Kuznets – have studied the less developed countries and constructed databases to meet the quantitative needs that Kuznets refers to. This has resulted in quite an impressive body of literature. However, there are still some important gaps to fill. One theme that has not yet received the attention it deserves is the role of the service sector in the economic development of ldcs. As economist Dorothy Riddle argues in her in-depth study on the service sector: ‘Development economists characteristically view services as a “developed” country issue, of little concern to developing nations. The excitement, the dynamism, the key to growth is believed to lie in the manufacturing sector.’ (Riddle 1986: 1) The reason for this is probably that the service sector is often considered to be subordinate. At the beginning of the process of economic development, agriculture is the most important sector. Initially, with low levels of productivity, there is little if any
17
| Introduction
surplus above the subsistence requirements, so that economic activity of most members of society falls into the primary sector. As agricultural techniques improve, productivity rises and the size of the surplus grows, enabling the development of a manufacturing or secondary sector, which produces both equipment and consumer goods to satisfy some less basic needs over and above subsistence levels. As the wealth and productive potential of the society grow further, even more sophisticated needs are provided for by the service or tertiary sector (Fisher 1939; Clark 1940; Fuchs 1968; Kuznets 1971; Riddle 1986). Along this line of reasoning the service sector is not particularly important in ldcs, since industrialisation has not yet taken place, or is still only in its infancy. This may explain why most studies on economic development in ldcs have concentrated on agriculture, with some attention to industry, but with only occasional reference to services. I believe, however, that the service sector plays a crucial role in economic development, at least in ldcs. For example, without a well-functioning transport system, trade opportunities will be limited. And if trade opportunities are limited, this will discourage specialisation and industrialisation, which will hamper economic growth. Referring to the case of Indonesia, economic historian Howard Dick, for example, states: ‘In a nation pledged to “Unity in Diversity”, few industries could be more important than interisland shipping. Yet since Independence problems plaguing interisland shipping have continued […]’ (Dick 1987a: back flap) Without a well-functioning financial system, as another example, industrialisation is doomed to fail, because machines cannot be financed. Moreover, good-quality education and health care ensure that an economy has a labour force of the necessary quality. And the government sets the rules of the game in which an economy functions. Or in other words: ‘Agriculture, mining and manufacturing are the bricks of economic development. The mortar that binds them together is the service industry.’ (Shelp et al. 1984: 1) Yet, the service sector is one of the least understood parts of the global economy. It receives only minimal attention in country analyses, policy deliberations, and development funding strategies (Riddle 1986: 1). This neglect of the service sector is also illustrated by the three most common labels for the service sector: ‘tertiary’, ‘residual’ and ‘post-industrial’. Economist Allan Fisher (1935; 1939) introduced the term ‘tertiary’ to refer to the service sector. Since ‘tertiary’ denotes a relative rank or position, he unintentionally assigned services as economic activities to positions of lesser importance. Colin Clark (1940: 375), a British economist and statistician, wrote in 1940 that ‘there remains an important residual which we may describe for convenience as “service
18
| Accounting for Services
industries”’. Like Fisher, Clark intended to point out that there were economic activities other than agriculture and manufacturing. However, the term ‘residual’ has the implication of that which is left over. Sociologist Daniel Bell (1973) referred to the service sector as the ‘post-industrial sector’ and to the ‘post-industrial society’ as one in which the service sector is dominant, reflecting the assumptions that service industries did not develop until after industrialisation. But this terminology is based on the development process of only a few West European economies. Hence the role of the service sector deserves a far more prominent place in developmental research than it has received so far. Services are neither of lesser size or importance than other sectors, nor do they have a parasitical dependence on manufacturing activity. By analysing the role of the service sector in the economic development in Indonesia this study aims to show that services play a vital and dynamic role in the economic development of ldcs. Indonesia is an excellent case-study for this kind of research, because of its erratic development path combined with its rich statistical sources. This makes it possible to meet Kuznets’ appeal for studies that deal with the quantitative bases and institutional conditions of their performance. This study will focus on the quantitative bases and institutional conditions of the service sector in order to determine how it contributed to the economic development of Indonesia during the twentieth century.
1.2
Bridging a gap The most intriguing question about the economic development of Indonesia during the twentieth century is why the country’s growth performance has been so erratic and displayed such a high degree of discontinuity. Why was Indonesia at independence so poor after having experienced a comparatively impressive export-led economic expansion in the several decades prior to the worldwide economic depression? Why did the economic growth performance improve so much during the New Order government of President Suharto after the dismal experiences of the Old Order Government of President Sukarno? Does this erratic performance convey a fundamental structural weakness in the Indonesian economy that in turn may even help us in understanding why the country plunged into such a deep economic crisis in the late 1990s, the worst one in the region and the worst in several decades? These questions are all connected with the fundamental question of the nature of long-term economic development in Indonesia. The study of the modern economic history of Indonesia, covering the period from the beginning of the twentieth century until the present day, has so far been less systematic than is possible with the available source material. Indonesia is exceptionally well endowed with rich statistical sources, especially with regard to the late colonial period; these sources offer the potential to support a rigorous and systematic quantitative approach to vital questions concerning the economic growth performance in the long run. The gap between current historiography and avail-
19
| Introduction
able sources needs to be bridged by an appropriate methodological framework and a rigorous analysis. Such a methodological framework is provided by the historical national accounts, as discussed in section 1.4. The central research question in this study is: ‘What role has the service sector played in the economic development of Indonesia during the 20th century?’ The service sector in Indonesia is not a complete blank spot in the literature. A number of studies have been written on branches of the service sector, often with a historical perspective. However, a systematic quantitative study of the role of the service sector in the economic development of Indonesia has not yet been undertaken. By filling this lacuna this study aims to contribute to debates about the dynamics of long-term economic growth in general and more specifically in Indonesia.
1.3
Theoretical context: the service sector and economic growth
1.3.1
Definition and classification of services So far I have assumed that intuitively one knows what a service is. A hairdresser or a waitress clearly offers a service. And cars, rice, or computers are obvious examples of goods. But what is it that distinguishes a service from a good? From a scientific point of view, the distinction between goods and services requires more analysis, not just a reliance on common sense, ad hoc definitions, and individual intuition. However, a definition of services within an economic analysis is not so straightforward (Petit 1986: 8). This section will discuss some different perspectives on how to define the service sector. Subsequently, three ways to categorise this sector will be considered. The intellectual godfather of modern economics, Adam Smith (1776: 295) already drew a dichotomy between goods and services. He stressed the perishable characteristic of services: ‘They perish in the very instant of their performance’. This intangible aspect allows for neither storage nor further transaction. Hence, for classical economists, services do not contribute to an increase in the volume of exchange: ‘Services seldom leave any trace or value behind them’ (Smith 1776: 295). According to Marx (1909) services were even associated with unproductive labour. More recent attempts to define the service sector have tried to isolate unique characteristics of services by establishing criteria with analytical usefulness. Economic On trade, see, for example, Touwen 2001; Lindblad 1994. On transport, see, for example, Dick 1987a; À Campo 1992; Weisfelt 1972. On government, see, for example, Booth 1988.
20
| Accounting for Services
historian Ronald Hartwell (1973: 359-360) mentions three main groups of characteristics that have been identified: The first includes lack of durability, unstockability, and producer–consumer intimacy, as well as intangibility; the second is concerned with the unit of production, and argues that services are produced in small units of production that are labour-intensive rather than capital-intensive, with a high ratio of value added to the value of total inputs; the third concentrates on the labour force of the service sector which includes a strategically important, but relatively small professional group (of high-value human capital) and, in comparison with other sectors, a high proportion of female, self-employed and part-time workers. While I recognise the usefulness of the above criteria, they do not give an unambiguous analytical framework for discussion. Other authors have argued that it might be better to think of the tertiary sector as a residual (Horlings 1995: 63; Smits 1995: 19). In this broader definition the sector comprises all activities other than agriculture and industry. The rationale behind this approach is that there is more agreement about what constitutes productive activities that are defined as agricultural or industrial. Economist T.P. Hill (1977) most thoroughly discusses the problems of defining the service sector. He argues that common factors shared by all services include, firstly, that they bring about some change in the condition of some person or good, with the agreement of the person concerned or economic unit owning the good. Secondly, the change is the result of the activity of some other economic unit. Therefore, he concludes: ‘A service may be defined as the change in the condition of a person, or of a good belonging to some economic unit, which is brought about as the result of the activity of some other economic unit’ (Hill 1977: 318). Hill’s definition has been widely used in the literature and is generally applicable. It clearly determines if one is dealing with a good or a service (see for example Griliches 1992; Stibora and De Vaal 1995; Kögel 1999). Therefore, the current study uses this definition as well. Having discussed some different definitions of the service sector, we can now think about how to categorise this sector. A distinctive feature of service activities is their heterogeneity. Therefore there are several ways to separate them into categories. One way is according to the classification of the sociologist Joachim Singelmann (1978). He divides the service sector into four categories. These categories draw a functional distinction between: i. Distributive services, which cover the distribution of commodities, information and passenger transport (i.e. trade, transport, communications). ii. Producer services, which are those services mainly consumed by enterprises. Producer services are an intermediate input in the production process (i.e. banking, insurance, real estate and business and professional services). iii. Social services, which are non-market activities provided by the government, and non-profit organisations (i.e. government, military, medical services, education and religion).
21
| Introduction
iv. Personal services, which are those services mainly consumed directly by final consumers (i.e. domestic servants, catering, recreation and entertainment, etc.).
Another method of categorisation is to divide the service sector into three groups. The first group concerns services with a clearly discernible output, price and set of inputs. The value added of these services can be calculated by subtracting intermediate expenses from the value of output. Such activities include, among others, trade, transport and communications. The second group consists of services for which production cannot be measured properly, as for some of these activities a market price does not exist. Total inputs must serve as a proxy for value added. The drawback of this method is that it precludes an analysis of productivity. Government activities are the best example of these kinds of services. Finally, housing is treated separately, since this industry presents a strange case with respect both to the definition of its output and to its combination of no employment and a large contribution to gross national product. A third way to categorise services is based on the International Standard of Industrial Classification (isic), as shown in table 1.1. According to the system of national accounts all activities classified under isic code 6 to 9 are considered to comprise the service sector. To these activities ownership of dwellings or housing has to be added. Because the objective of this research is to reconstruct and analyse the service sector within the framework of national accounts, as discussed in section 1.4, I will use this final classification as starting point.
22
Table 1.1
isic classification of activity
isic Code
Sector
1
Agriculture, Hunting, Forestry and Fishing
2
Mining and Quarrying
3
Manufacturing
4
Public Utilities: – Electricity – Water – Gas
5
Construction
6 61 62
Distribution Wholesale trade Retail trade
7
Transport, Storage and Communication
71 711 712 713
Transport and storage Land transport Water transport Air transport
| Accounting for Services
1.3.2
isic Code
Sector
72
Communications – Postal services – Telecommunications
8 81 82 83
Finance, Insurance, & Real Estate (FIRE) Banking services Insurance services Real estate
9 91 92 93 931 933 94 95 96
Services and Government Public administration and defence Sanitary and similar services Social and related community services Education Health services Recreational and cultural services Personal and household services International and other extra-territorial bodies
Source: United Nations 1993
The service sector and economic growth In 1940 Colin Clark wrote that ‘we find a very firmly established generalisation that a high level of real income per head is always associated with a high proportion of the working population engaged in tertiary industries’ (Clark 1940: 6-7). He therefore concluded that the most salient component of economic progress is the movement of working population from agriculture to manufacture, and from manufacture to commerce and services. This is still a common view among economists. ‘Economic growth’ here means a substantial and sustained long-term growth of real income per head of population. ‘Structural change’ means the transfer of resources among the three sectors of the economy – the primary (agriculture), the secondary (industry) and the tertiary (services) – so that the percentage shares of employment and output are altered. According to Clark, economic growth and structural change go hand in hand, so that, as the economy develops, the service sector becomes a more and more important part of economic activity. The conventional view, introduced by Fisher (1935) and Clark (1940) independently of each other, is that various sectors of an economy develop according to a natural sequence. In the initial stages of economic development, agriculture is the most important sector, because with low levels of productivity all labour is required to produce at a subsistence level. As agricultural techniques improve, productivity rises and surpluses arise, enabling the development of a manufacturing or secondary sector. As wealth and productive potential of the society grow further, even more sophisticated needs are provided for by the service or tertiary sector. This evolution is illustrated in figure 1.1.
23
| Introduction
Figure 1.1 The three-sector model
Source: Gershuny and Miles 1983: 250
Fisher (1935, 1939), who proposed the conceptual breakdown of the economy into three sectors – primary, secondary, tertiary – noted that economies could be classified structurally in terms of wealth, according to the proportions of population employed in agriculture. In his view the share of population employed in this sector was inversely proportional to wealth. Clark (1940) stated that economic progress in the sense of a rise in the average real national income per head of the working population may take place (a) as a result of improvement in real output per head in all or any of the three fields (agriculture, industry, services) or (b) as a result of transference of labour from the less productive to the more productive fields. His argument is that labour will be reallocated from manufacturing industries, which experience high rates of productivity growth but stagnating demand, to services, which experience lower rates of productivity growth but rising demand. Clark’s findings are based on detailed empirical data for a large number of, mostly industrialised, countries. The French economist Jean Fourastié (1949) described the low rate of productivity growth in the tertiary sector, combined with a shift in demand to services, as the great hope for twentieth century employment. In Europe before the industrial revolution the small size of the service sector and its high costs were a barrier to growth. In the case of transport, for example, only a drastic reduction in the cost of transport enabled the mobility of production factors, which was vital for growth. For several branches of the service sector there is an explanation of why they can cause or at least coincide with economic growth.
24
| Accounting for Services
Trade (isic 6): The economic functions of distribution are, for producers, to widen the market; for consumers, to provide ‘place and time utility’; and, for both, to provide information (Hartwell 1973: 380). As manufacturing becomes more localised, commodity production is geographically separated from the consumer market. Raw material producers, manufacturers and consumers, who earlier had lived and worked together, are increasingly separated; therefore market linkages need to develop to complete the circular flow of production, trade and consumption. Transport and communication (isic 7): Historians have argued that ‘a transport revolution’ preceded and accompanied all industrial revolutions; economists, similarly, have shown that modern economic growth is correlated positively with transport facilities and that investment in transport is of strategic importance in inducing and sustaining growth (Kindleberger 1958: 96; Fogel 1964; Fremdling 1975). Improved transport is part of the essential infrastructure of an advanced economy. Not only does it directly lower the costs throughout economies, it also makes markets accessible (by allowing the growth of larger-scale enterprises) and labour mobile. Equally as important as transport services to shift goods and people was the development of other types of communications, which reduce the costs of information to producers and consumers. This sub-sector facilitates a more systematic collection of information and a more effective distribution of it. Financial services (isic 8): Growth generates an increased demand for money, shortterm credit and long-term capital and, hence, institutions which that can fulfil these demands. These are institutions which link surplus- and deficit-spending units, and which facilitate borrowing and lending by substituting the financial intermediary’s liabilities. To meet these financial needs, banks, money and exchange markets, stock exchanges and capital markets all expand. Such institutions lay the foundations of a well-integrated system of public and private finance (Cameron 1967, 1972). Government and other services (isic 9): A notable feature of economies is the growth of the government. Much of this growth can be summed up in the phrase ‘welfare state’, which came into being initially to redress income inequalities and to remedy poverty, but later expanded to include macroeconomic management of economies in the interests of greater efficiency and faster growth. Welfare and growth have become the twin aims of contemporary government and bureaucracy (Hartwell 1973: 378). Economic development provides opportunities alongside older professions. It adds a wide range of new professions (for example, architecture, engineering, industrial management, accountancy, dentistry, etc.). This development is, among others, important because it multiplies the absolute and relative size of the most skilled proportions of human capital in economies, and hence boosts further economic growth. Moreover, this segment of the service sector also comprises consumer ‘goods’ such
25
| Introduction
as culture and recreation, whose demand expands with increasing income and leisure. Despite these convincing arguments about why economic growth and growth of the service sector should coincide, there is substantial discussion about the exact sequence and relationship between the two. Hartwell, for example, argues that a significant characteristic of the industrial revolution was the emerging service sector: ‘For Western Europe it is important to remember that before the industrial revolution, industry already coexisted with agriculture, and that the expansion of industry, even in the new form of factory production, was not entirely new. It was the expansion of the non-agricultural and the non-industrial sector – thus the service sector – that created the most significant break with the past with the onset of industrialisation in the advanced economies.’ (Hartwell 1973: 362) Similar conclusions are drawn for the role of the service sector in the economic development of the Netherlands. Within the research project “Reconstructing National Accounts of the Netherlands and the analysis of the development of the Dutch Economy in the period 1800-1940” both Edwin Horlings (1995) and Jan-Pieter Smits (1995) have shown that the Dutch service sector, especially trade and transport, was of crucial importance to the process of modern economic growth. Kuznets (1966, 1971), in studying the changing composition of output and employment during the growth of the advanced economies, reached several relevant conclusions. Regarding employment, for instance, there has been an unambiguous secular tendency for the share of total agricultural employment to fall, the share of manufacturing employment to rise, and the share of service employment to rise substantially, generally more than manufacturing. Regarding output, however, Kuznets found a secular tendency for the share of agriculture in total output to fall, for the share of manufacturing to rise, and for the share of services to have no systematic relationship with the growth of output. The productivity of agriculture has generally been below the national average, while that of manufacturing and of services have been above it. When the productivities of manufacturing and services are compared, however, the data are more difficult to interpret. So Kuznets’ conclusion is that employment in the service sector indeed rises, but whether this leads to a rise in the share of services in total output is not clear. Economist William J. Baumol (1967) also questioned the so-called three-sector hypothesis. He argues that the share of services in real output is constant over time. According to Baumol’s model, the share of service sector employment is larger in high-income countries, and grows with rising income, because of the low productivity level of the service sector. Victor R. Fuchs (1968), an American economist, has written one of the most comprehensive studies on the expansion of service employment. His findings sup-
26
| Accounting for Services
port Baumol’s cost-disease hypothesis according to which demand shifts play only a minor role and the share of service employment increases mainly because productivity growth in services is lagging. This does not mean that the proportion of real service output increases over time. In the next section I will explain this.
1.3.3
Economic factors affecting the development of the share of services in real output The positive association between economic growth and the share of services in the distribution of the labour force has been noted and documented. Clark (1940) traced the observation of this relationship back to Sir William Petty in the seventeenth century and proposed that the shift of the working population from agriculture to manufacturing and from manufacturing to services in the course of economic growth be called Petty’s Law (see also Zimmerman 1967: 705-706). Kuznets (1966, 1971), Fuchs (1968) and others have suggested that the relative expansion of service employment could be due either to high income elasticities in the demand for services or to slower growth in the productivity of service industries. The common view that services are characterised by relatively high income elasticities is based on the idea that commodities fill one set of human wants (the basic necessities) and services another (the desire for luxuries) (Fisher 1935: 31). This hierarchy of needs, which states that as income grows a higher share of income will be used for the purchase of luxuries (in this case services), is defined by Engel’s Law. The fact is, however, that changing times bring different forms through which wants are satisfied, and it is easy to go astray by identifying luxuries with services. In empirical research on the service sector in France, the United Kingdom and the United States, Kravis et al. (1983) test this relationship between the share of services in gdp and economic growth. Their analysis focuses on final-product services. They find that that, as income rises, the share of expenditure on services indeed rises quite sharply over time, at least when shares are calculated in the current prices of each period. However, when service shares are measured in constant prices, the secular rise in shares disappears completely in the cases of France and the United Kingdom and is sharply reduced for the United States. These results are summarised in table 1.2. The obvious inference is that, as income rose, service prices must have been rising relative to commodity prices. Kravis et al. (1983) point out that the income elasticity of demand is only one factor that influences the changes over time in the division of consumers’ expenditures between services and commodities. Some generalisations can probably be legitimately made about income elasticities for broad categories of wants – for example, that the demand for recreation tends to be highly elastic with respect to income – but such generalisations do not lead to a clear conclusion about shifts in the relative importance of services and commodities in consumer expenditure. Even a broad category of wants can be satisfied in a variety of ways, some involving a service and others involving a commodity. Higher incomes, for example, may lead to the
27
| Introduction
substitution of a commodity for a commodity (meat for bread), or of a service for a service (an expensive restaurant meal for a cheap one), or of a service for a commodity (restaurant food for home-cooked food), or of a commodity for a service (readyto-serve food for household help).
Table 1.2
Changes in service shares over time, France, United Kingdom, and United States Shares of services in gdp Current prices
Constant prices
1959-1960
31.3 %
38.0 %
1977-1978
37.9 %
36.5 %
1957-1958
39.5 %
50.6 %
1967-1968
43.8 %
50.5 %
1977-1978
47.6 %
49.7 %
France
United Kingdom
United States
1947-1948
33.2 %
42.4 %
1957-1958
44.8 %
49.6 %
1967-1968
48.8 %
50.8 %
1977-1978
49.7 %
49.0 %
Source: Kravis et al. 1983: 195
Another set of factors that determines whether the expansion path moves towards services or towards commodities concerns technology. Consider, for example, the possible ways for an individual to satisfy an income-elastic desire for entertainment in the form of a musical experience. The most direct physical sensation associated with the musical experience is going to a concert. Until a century ago this was the only option to have such an experience. Nowadays, various disembodied sources of music are available (cds, dvds, radio, television, internet, etc.), but access to these sources requires the purchase of commodities (cd players, dvd players, computers, cds, dvds, etc.) instead of the purchase of a service in the form of a concert ticket. So there can be a substitution effect between services and goods. These changes are called social innovations or the emerging of a self-service economy (Gershuny 1978). A third factor, with which the income elasticities and the technological factors interact, sometimes in a causative way, is relative prices. The existing structure of relative prices at a given moment may influence the relative size of income elasticities for different means of satisfying a broad want. For example, whether high income elasticity in demand for recreation in case of an increase of income leads to a relative expansion of spending on services or on commodities is likely to depend on which ways of providing the desired form of recreation are the cheapest. The influence that prices may exercise on the income elasticities of close substitutes may vary with the level of income. Relative prices will in turn be influenced by technological change and productivity gaps. If the cost-reducing aspects of techno-
28
| Accounting for Services
logical change affect commodities more often than services, commodity prices will tend to fall relative to services prices. This behaviour of relative prices is more likely as services tend to be produced in a more labour-intensive way than commodities and that wage rates rise relative to the rent of capital with development. The explanation for this is the following. With similar prices for traded goods in all countries, wages in the industries producing traded goods will differ from country to country according to differences in productivity – a standard conclusion from Ricardian trade theory. But in each country the wage level established in the traded-goods industries will also determine wages in the industries producing non-traded goods (mainly services). Because international productivity differences are smaller for such industries, the low wages established in poor countries in the traded-goods industries will also apply to the non-traded-goods industries. The consequence will be low prices in low-income countries for both services and other non-traded goods, and at the same time high prices in high-income countries for both services and other non-traded goods. So both technological and productivity differences cause a rise in service prices relative to commodity prices. Their influence in tilting the balance in favour of the satisfaction of wants through services to the satisfaction through commodities may help to explain the limited expansion of real share of services in final expenditures despite the fact that services often seem to contribute to income-elastic wants. But not only income elasticity is important, also the price elasticity of demand for services. It seems clear, then, that there are no strong a priori grounds for expecting demand for final products classified as services to increase as income rises. A possible fourth cause of a growth in service activity relative to total output is intermediate sub-contracting. Because of the increasing demand for ‘intermediate’ or ‘producer’ services from elsewhere in the economy the service sector will grow. Instead of employing particular sorts of specialised service labour, firms subcontract or outsource work to specialists. Examples include catering, security and cleaning. Dutch economist Tom Elfring (1989), for example, found that in seven oecd countries employment growth in producer services was about twice as high as the average for the entire service sector. This finding is partly a result of measurement problems. In the system of national accounts firms are classified according to their main product. Therefore the performance of identical tasks will be classified as manufacturing employment when carried out by a manufacturing firm, and as a service when carried out by a specialised service firm. For example, book printing by a publisher will be classified as manufacturing, while book printing by a university will be classified as service. Fifthly, an increase in the share of services can be explained by the phenomenon of ‘occupational tertiarisation’. As just mentioned, there is more to service employment than just service industries. And while most attention has concentrated on the industrial dimension, much of the explanation for the growth of tertiary jobs comes from change in occupational structure within industries. In a study on the service sector in developed countries, Jonathan Gershuny and Ian Miles (1983) found, for
29
| Introduction
example, that the ratio of white-collar workers to manual workers increased over time. The proportion of manual workers in the work force is thus reduced even in industries classified as manufacturing. In summary, in the existing literature we find five economic factors that affect the share of services in an economy: 1) Engel’s Law, whereby increasing wealth leads to the development of demand for increasingly sophisticated service functions; 2) Social innovation changes, meaning changes in the mode of provision of particular service functions; 3) A productivity gap, which is the consequence of the relatively low productivity growth (and consequently the relatively fast increase in prices) in some final service industries. This is called the cost-disease; 4) Intermediate sub-contracting in which activities which were part of the production process within one industry are sub-contracted to an intermediate producer service industry; and 5) Occupational tertiarisation whereby the employment structure within industries is changed, normally reducing the proportion of manual workers in the workforce. Some factors increase the share of services in total output, while others have the opposite effect. Since we do not know which are the dominating factors, it is impossible to predict the exact development of the service sector in different countries. With more case studies like this one, it might be possible in future to make better generalisations about the role of the service sector in the economic development of a country. However, a quite widely accepted notion is that productivity in services has the tendency to grow at a slower rate than that of goods. Because of the increasing share of the service sector in the total output of advanced economies, this would mean a slower overall rate of economic growth in countries characterised as service economies. It is certainly possible that this is exactly the phenomenon that advanced economies are experiencing now.
1.3.4
Socio-economic factors affecting the development of the service share in total output Besides purely economic factors, Nanno Mulder (1999) in his dissertation on the service sector in Brazil, Mexico and the usa, also draws attention to the role of socioeconomic factors that might influence the development of the service sector. He describes four possible factors. To begin with, Mulder points out that income distribution plays a role. Lowincome groups have different spending patterns from high-income groups, and as such the distribution of income has important consequences for the overall rate of substitution of agricultural products and manufactures for services in consump-
30
| Accounting for Services
tion. High income inequality increases the consumption of luxury services such as domestic servants and expensive leisure activities. However, the demand for more basic services such as education, health care and telecommunications is constrained, as middle- and low-income groups receive smaller fractions of income. Furthermore, changes in demographic trends and labour force participation affect the development of the service sector. Population growth and age structure have important consequences for the relative demand for education and health care. The necessity of schooling largely depends on the share of young people in the total population, which is determined by birth rates and infant mortality. On the other hand, the share of elderly in the total population affects the demand for health care to a large degree. An increasing labour participation rate is also an important factor for service demand, especially when the increasing participation of women is concerned. That boosts the necessity of laundry services, nursery schools and prepared food and restaurant services, which have traditionally been in the domain of women. Moreover, urbanisation affects the demand for services. City dwellers buy relatively more products in stores, while rural citizens grow a portion of their own food for consumption. Rural people also engage more in barter trade, while urban households have a higher demand for communications and recreational services (Falvey and Gemmell 1996). Another difference between cities and rural areas lies in the alternative sources of subsistence income available in the absence of job opportunities in the formal sector. In cities, if the number of jobs available is low, most people enter the informal service sector, whereas in rural areas surplus labour is concentrated in agriculture. Finally, the role of the government influences the share of services. Not only because government services are part of the service sector, but also because an expanding government increases the demand for services. Usually this involves increased expenditure on health care and public education, because these are considered indispensable for improving people’s well-being and productivity, and as such form a precondition for economic development (Mulder 1999: 16). Having discussed the definition of, categorisation of and theoretical issues concerning the service sector and economic growth, I now shift attention to a framework within which the developments of the service sector relative to other economic sectors can be captured, namely the system of national accounts.
1.4
National accounting: aim, advantages and disadvantages ‘National economies cannot be observed directly, but can only be observed via the national accounts. National accounts statistics make the size, development and composition of these national economies visible by translating them in monetary terms indicating their economic importance. The [system of ] national accounts is therefore often referred to as the barometer of the national economy.’ (Bos 2003: 41)
31
| Introduction
The System of National Accounts (sna) is the internationally agreed standard on how to compile measures of economic activity. It provides a comprehensive accounting framework within which economic data can be compiled and presented in a format that is designed for purposes of economic analysis, decision-taking and policy-making (United Nations 1993). Work on national accounts and international comparisons of real income levels started in the seventeenth century. The oldest known attempt to estimate total economic activity was made by William Petty in 1665 and 1676 for England. In 1696, Gregory King made a rough comparison of performance in France, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. Individual scholars further developed his approach over a period of 250 years, with substantial clarification of what the scope of the accounts should be, and a larger accumulation of estimates for individual countries. In the 1950s the first standardised system of national accounts was produced, the result of close consultation between statisticians in Western Europe and North America to ensure that the guidelines were properly implemented. The system of national accounts measures the total volume of economic activities in a country by means of three complementary lines of approach: 1) Output/value added approach This approach sums up all the value added by every producer in the economy in the course of producing goods and services. 2) Expenditure approach The expenditure approach sums up all final expenditures on goods and services in the economy and adjusts for contribution from exports and imports. 3) Income approach The income approach sums up all income accruing from production in the economy. This comprises compensation of employees (wages, salaries, etc.), provision for consumption of fixed assets (depreciation, allowances), net operating surplus and indirect taxes. The sna has distinct advantages for historical research. To begin with, the three lines of approach by definition have the same result. This enhances the possibility of (cross)checking the outcome (Van Zanden 1993: 230). Moreover, the results are comparable by other studies set up according to the same approach. In addition, the accounts are compiled for a succession of time periods, thus providing a continuing flow of information. Kuznets therefore states that:
For an exhaustive survey of the history of national accounting, see Studenski 1958.
32
| Accounting for Services
‘Acceptable long-term records of national income and wealth and of their customarily distinguished components constitute indispensable minimum information in the study of economic growth.’ (Kuznets 1955: vii-viii) Obviously, the historical application of national accounts also has its drawbacks. The concept is geared towards twentieth-century industrial nations, which were highly integrated and market-oriented. For example, the definitions relate only to transactions within the market mechanism. However, the share of non-monetary transactions has decreased in the course of economic development, and the extent to which regions were involved in market-oriented production varied widely (Horlings 1995: 34-35). These non-monetary transactions should be included, although estimating the value is sometimes difficult. Another problematic example is the provision of public services. Government is essentially a non-market organisation; its product cannot be measured in terms of output volume and market price. As a consequence it is very difficult to accurately assess the importance of this sector to economic development. As mentioned before, because of the intangible character of several service sectors, it is not always possible to measure output directly. In those cases, labour input is taken as a substitute. But taking labour input as a substitute for output means that productivity growth in the service sector is implicitly assumed to be 0. This can be seen from the following equation: productivity = output/input Assuming output and input to be substitutes, the outcome of the above equation is always 1, and thus productivity growth is equal to 0. This is obviously a very rigid assumption (Krantz 1994: 21). A further disadvantage of the system of national accounts is that it is questionable whether this concept can be used to analyse the development of a region or country that is neither economically nor politically united (Horlings 1995: 35; Smits 1995: 25). However, the system of national accounts contains no presumptions regarding the homogeneity or the measure of integration of an economy. After all, the same objections can be made against present-day national accounts for India, China or the United States. But it stresses the need for a regional breakdown of macro-economic variables for analytical purposes. Historical national accounting clearly has its shortcomings. But as yet there is no alternative model with which economic growth can be measured more accurately. Carefully constructed national accounts therefore form an indispensable input for economic analysis. Quoting Horlings (1995: 33):
33
| Introduction
‘The historical application of the system of national accounts provides the best mean to chart the quantitative development of an economy without overstating or undervaluing sectors or regions.’ This book will apply the system of national accounts to study quantitatively the development of the service sector for the specific case of Indonesia.
1.5
Indonesia’s economic history and its pecularities This section sketches some broad developments in Indonesia’s economic history for those readers who are not familiar with the country and its history. This will enhance understanding of the subsequent chapters in which basic knowledge of the major events in Indonesian history in the twentieth century is assumed.
1.5.1
Indonesia’s economic history in a bird eye’s view Indonesia is a large archipelago situated between the Indian Ocean and the Pacific Ocean, with more than 17,000 islands, of which roughly 6,000 are inhabited. The largest islands are Java, Kalimantan (the largest part of the island Borneo), Sumatra, Sulawesi and Papua (formerly Irian Jaya, which is the western part of New Guinea). Indonesia’s total land area measures 1.9 million square kilometres, while its sea measures 7.9 million square kilometres. Because Indonesia consists of large stretches of lowland as well as numerous mountainous areas, its tropical climate varies from hot and humid to more moderate in the highlands. Apart from having fertile land suitable for agriculture, Indonesia is rich in a range of natural resources, varying from petroleum, natural gas and coal, to metals such as tin, bauxite, nickel, copper, gold and silver. The size of Indonesia’s population is about 228 million (2008), of which the largest share (roughly 60 per cent) lives in Java. Indonesia has had a turbulent history. Europeans arrived in Indonesia from the sixteenth century seeking to monopolise the sources of valuable nutmeg, cloves and cubeb pepper in Maluku. In 1602 the Dutch established the Dutch East India Company (voc) and became the dominant European power. Following bankruptcy, the voc was formally dissolved in 1800, and the government of the Netherlands established the Netherlands-Indies as a nationalised colony. By the early twentieth century Dutch dominance extended to what was to become Indonesia’s current boundaries (see figure 1.2). From an economic perspective the period 1900-1942 can be characterised as the heyday of the colonial export economy (Touwen 2008). Sugar, coffee, pepper For the most comprehensive history of Indonesia going back to ca. 1200, see Ricklefs 2001. Comprehensive studies on the economic history of Indonesia include Booth 1998, Hill 2000 and Dick et al. 2002.
34
| Accounting for Services
Figure 1.2
Map of Indonesia with its major cities
© Jelle van Lottum
and tobacco, the old export products, were increasingly supplemented with highly profitable exports of petroleum, rubber, copra, palm oil and fibres. An increasing share of these foreign exports was supplied by the islands other than Java, called the Outer Islands. This resulted in the intensification of internal trade within the archipelago and generated an increasing flow of foreign imports. Agricultural exports were cultivated both on large-scale European agricultural estates and by indigenous smallholders. When the exploitation of oil became profitable in the late nineteenth century, petroleum earned a respectable position in the total export package. The momentum of profitable exports led to a broad expansion of economic activity in the Indonesian archipelago. Improvements in the road system, railway system (in Java and Sumatra) and the integration of the port system in the world market also led to internal economic integration. In the process of integrating Java and the Outer Islands an important contribution was made by the kpm (Koninklijke PaketvaartMaatschappij, Royal Packet Company), serving economic integration as well as imperialist expansion (À Campo 1992). Subsidised shipping lines into remote corners of the vast archipelago carried away export goods, supplied import goods and transported civil servants and military personnel. The world depression of the 1930s turned the tide. The prices of Indonesia’s exports plummeted; by 1935 their value was about 32 per cent of that in 1929 (cei xiia 1991: Table 2B; Ricklefs 2001: 234). The sugar industry in Java collapsed never to recover. In some products, such as rubber, copra and oil, production was stepped up to compensate for lower prices. In reaction to the Depression the Dutch colonial
35
| Introduction
government abandoned its laissez-faire economic policies and introduced protectionist measures. Various import restrictions were launched, making the economy more self-sufficient, as for example in the production of rice, and stimulating domestic integration. Due to the strong Dutch guilder (the Netherlands adhered to the gold standard until 1936), it took a relatively long time before economic recovery took place (Touwen 2008). The Japanese invasion (1942) and subsequent occupation during the Second World War ended Dutch colonial rule, and encouraged the previously suppressed Indonesian independence movement. Two days after the surrender of Japan, on 17 August 1949, the nationalist leaders Sukarno and Hatta, declared independence. The Netherlands tried to re-establish colonial rule, but a bitter armed and diplomatic struggle ended in December 1949, when due to international pressure the Dutch formally acknowledged Indonesian independence. Thus, after independence the Indonesian economy not only had to recover from the hardships of the Japanese occupation and the war for independence, but also from the slow recovery from the 1930s Depression. During the period 1950-1965, there was little economic growth, most of this growth taking place in the years from 1950 to 1957 (Booth 1998: 60). What little growth there was must be attributed to the low initial level in 1950 when gdp was still well below that attained in 1940 (Booth 1998: 53). Growing resentment of foreign domination of the economy led in December 1957 to the expulsion of Dutch nationals and the government takeover of Dutch companies and precipitating the process of economic decolonisation (Lindblad 2002; see also Lindblad 2008). The subsequent growth performance between 1958 and 1965 was poor (Booth 1998: 65). This can be largely attributed to political instability and inappropriate economic policy measures taken by the Sukarno government. Exchange rate problems and an absence of foreign capital were harmful to economic development, and a lack of prudent fiscal and monetary policies resulted in hyperinflation by the mid-1960s. An attempted coup in September 1965 led to a violent army-led anti-communist purge in which approximately half a million people were killed. Politically, General Suharto took over power from President Sukarno in 1966, and was formally appointed president in March 1968. His New Order administration was supported by the West, whose investment in Indonesia was a major factor in the subsequent three decades of substantial economic growth. Supported by a team of experts in the field of economics, Suharto succeeded in reducing inflation and bringing Indonesia on an unprecedented growth path. In the subsequent period industrial output quickly increased, including steel, aluminium and cement but also products such as food, textiles and cigarettes. From the
Reasonable estimates range from 100,000 to 1,000,000. A figure of roughly half a million is accepted by the Indonesian government (Cribb and Brown 1995: 106).
36
| Accounting for Services
1970s onward the increased oil price on the world market provided Indonesia with a massive income from oil and gas exports. Suharto managed to apply part of these revenues to the development of a technologically advanced manufacturing industry. After 1981 growth dropped. Stagnation in the rise of oil prices, combined with the imposition of opec quotas, reduced income from oil considerably. Moreover, in the early 1980s the world economy suffered from a recession. A number of policy reforms resulted in a more diversified export economy, less reliance on oil and gas and, subsequently, accelerated output growth. Referring to this period of stable economic growth, the World Bank Report of 1993 speaks of an ‘East Asian Miracle’ emphasizing the macro-economic stability and the investments in human capital (World Bank 1993: vi). In the late 1990s, however, Indonesia was the country hardest hit by the Asian financial crisis, which led to popular protests and Suharto’s resignation on 21 May 1998. The Reformasi era following Suharto’s resignation has led to a strengthening of democratic processes, including a regional autonomy program, the secession of East Timor, and the first direct presidential election, in 2004. Political and economic instability, social unrest, corruption, natural disasters, and terrorism, however, have slowed progress.
37
Major dates in Indonesian (economic) history 1800
The bankrupt Dutch East India Company (voc) is formally dissolved and the colonial state is established.
1870
Beginning of a liberal policy of deregulated exploitation of the Netherlands-Indies.
1888
Founding of the shipping line Koninklijke Paketvaart Maatschappij (kpm) that supported the unification and development of the colonial economy.
1901
The ‘Ethical Policy’ is launched.
1914
First World War breaks out; the Netherlands is a neutral country in the war.
1917
Netherlands-Indies trade with Europe cut off by the war.
1929
Great Depression.
1942
February: Japan occupies Indonesia during Second World War, overthrowing the Netherlands-Indies, and installs its own imperial structure.
1945
15 August: Japanese surrender to Allied powers.
1945
17 August: ‘Proclamation of Indonesian Independence’ by Sukarno and Hatta. Sukarno becomes president.
1945-9
Struggle for independence.
1949
27 December: International pressure leads Netherlands Government to transfer power to the United States of Indonesia,
1957
21 February: President Sukarno announces his ‘Conception’ (Konsepsi) of the nature of Indonesia. This will eventually lead to Guided Democracy.
1957
December: Takeover of Dutch enterprises.
1963
1 May: Following pressure from the United Nations and the us government, the Netherlands yields West Irian (Papua) to temporary un supervision.
| Introduction
1.5.2
1965
30 September: An abortive coup in Jakarta results in the murder of six army generals.
1965
1 October: A counter-coup led by General Suharto that leads to the overthrow of Sukarno.
1965
October to 1966, March: A violent anti-communist purge leads to the killing of approximately half a million Indonesians.
1965
13 December: The rupiah is devalued by a factor of 1,000 in an effort to control inflation.
1966
11 March: General Suharto forces Sukarno to delegate presidential powers to Suharto himself.
1967
10 January: New investment laws designed to bring in foreign capital are passed.
1967
7-12 March: A Special Session of the Provisional People’s Consultative Assembly strips Sukarno of his powers and appoints Suharto acting president.
1968
March: Parliament confers full presidential title on Suharto; Sukarno is under effective house arrest.
1970
21 June: Sukarno dies.
1973
International petroleum prices begin to rise steeply.
1979
Second round of steep increases in petroleum prices.
1982
opec meeting agrees on production cutbacks. Sharp increase in domestic petroleum prices.
1997
June: Pacific Ocean trade winds shift heralding the onset of the El Niño; severe drought across much of Indonesia follows in the ensuing months accompanied by highly destructive forest fires.
1997
July: The collapse of the Thai baht starts the East Asian financial crisis; over the ensuing months Indonesia is the country hardest hit.
1998
21 May: After being deserted by his cabinet, Suharto resigns from presidency. Habibie assumes presidency.
Some peculiarities in studying indonesia’s economic history In studying the economic history of a country one is always confronted with some country-specific characteristics. In the case of the reconstruction of the Indonesian service sector a number of peculiarities need to be discussed, since these will have great impact on the study undertaken. To begin with the period between 1942 and the mid-1960s is characterised by intermittent economic and political chaos. Uncontested Dutch colonial rule ended in 1942 with Indonesia’s occupation by the Japanese, although effectively 1941 is often considered as the last full, normal year. The following years are associated by most Indonesians with scarcity, forced labour and brutal physical punishment. The economic decline that took place during this period had both structural and institutional causes (Dick et al. 2002: 164). On 17 August 1945 Indonesian nationalists declared independence. This marked the beginning of a four-year during war of
38
| Accounting for Services
independence, which postponed economic recuperation until sovereignty was transferred in December 1949 (Van der Eng 2002: 144). These years of occupation and war not only disrupted the everyday life of most people, but also resulted in a virtual stagnation of data collection. Very meagre information has survived this period, so that little is known about the economic situation during these turbulent years. For this reason economic historians usually deal summarily with this subject (Booth 1998; Dick et al. 2002). Pierre van der Eng (1992, 2002), the pioneer of applying historical national accounting to the case of Indonesia, for example, chose in his first publication on estimates of the Indonesian national income to include these years. In his later publication he omitted the years 1942-1949. Following Van der Eng (2002), I have chosen not to incorporate national accounts estimates for this period in this study. The almost complete lack of data makes it impossible to come up with estimates that can be linked in a meaningful way to either the colonial or the post-independence period. A second peculiarity in the economic history of Indonesia is geographical. Indonesia is assumed to be a united economic space by now. But when the Indonesian nation became independent, the national economy had statistically just been invented. Statistical recognition of a national economy did not, however, mean that it had substantive form (Dick et al. 2002: 10). At that time one can question whether the islands of Indonesia were really parts of a cohesive national economy. Therefore one should be careful when talking about the Indonesian economy. As historian Jeroen Touwen (2008) points out, there are huge differences between densely populated Java, which has been dominant in the economic and political sphere, and the Outer Islands, which has generally been a large, sparsely populated area. Among the Outer Islands it is possible to distinguish between areas which experienced reasonable levels of economic growth stimulated by the export trade (Palembang, East Sumatra and Southeast Kalimantan for example), and areas which stayed behind and profited only slowly from the modernisation that took place elsewhere (Benkulu, Timor and Maluku for example) (Touwen 2001). In the literature, the Outer Islands have remained in the shadow of Java. This is mainly because few primary sources are extant for historians. But Dick et al. rightly argue that ‘It is too readily assumed that little happened because little was recorded’ (Dick et al. 2002: 107). The distinction between Java and the Outer Islands is acknowledged here and where possible elaborated, but it has been beyond the scope of this study to construct regional national accounts enabling a detailed quantitative analysis. A third unique characteristic in studying the economic history of Indonesia is the distinction between the indigenous economy and the dualist economy. Dutch political economist J.H. Boeke (1953) introduced the term ‘economic dualism’, referring to a modern Western and a stagnant Eastern sector. Although the term ‘dualism’ was often used to indicate western superiority, more recently it has been replaced by a more objective analysis of the dualist economy. But in the Netherlands-Indies there was not only the distinction between Europeans and indigenous people, but also a
39
| Introduction
third group, the ethnic Chinese. To fully understand Indonesian economic history it is important to account also for such distinctions.
1.6
Outline of the book The structure of this thesis is based on three pillars: 1) the reconstruction of the service sector within the System of National Accounts (sna); 2) analysis of two leading service sectors in the economic development of Indonesia, namely transport and trade; and 3) analysis of the dynamics between developments in the service sector and economic growth. Chapter 2 deals with the methodology of the reconstruction of the service sector within a national accounting framework. The results of this meticulous exercise are presented in the appendices. Chapter 3 is devoted to the presentation and interpretation of the estimates. In the second part of the book the two leading sectors within the service sector are studied in detail: transport and trade. These two are by far the most important service sectors both if we look at their share relative to total employment and if we consider their contribution to total gdp. Chapter 4 discusses developments in the transportation sector and shows how these have contributed to economic development. Chapter 5 elaborates on the ambiguous role that the trade sector has played in the economic development of Indonesia. On the one hand, the trade sector has been an engine of growth, but on the other hand it has served as the sector of last resort, where those unable to find employment in other sectors ended up. Chapter 6 brings together the findings of chapters 4 and 5 and functions as the third pillar of this study. By analysing market integration in Indonesia it is possible to assess to whether the transport and trade sector have indeed contributed to Indonesia economic development process. Chapter 7 sums up the main findings of this study and challenges the view that the service sector has been ‘tertiary’ in the development process. In the case of Indonesia, accounting for services is a necessary condition for understanding the country’s development path.
40
| Accounting for Services
2 National Accounting for Services in Indonesia
2.1
Introduction ‘We need statistics not only for explaining things, but also in order to know precisely what there is to explain. […] It is impossible to understand statistical figures without understanding how they have been compiled. It is equally impossible to extract information from them or to understand the information that specialists extract for the rest of us without understanding the methods by which this is done – and the epistemological backgrounds of these methods. Thus, an adequate command of modern statistical methods is a necessary (but not sufficient) condition for preventing the modern economist from producing nonsense.’ (Schumpeter 1954: 14) This chapter serves precisely the aim that economist and political scientist Joseph Schumpeter is supporting, namely a discussion of the estimation methods used to capture economic activity in the service sector within the system of national accounts. This is a necessary condition for the analysis in the subsequent chapters. This chapter starts with an overview of the history of Indonesian national income estimates, followed by an account of the data sources. After an extensive discussion of the estimation methods, some remarks will be made about the reliability of the estimates.
2.2
History of Indonesian national income estimates Before the Second World War a few tentative estimates of national income of Indonesia were published of which Louis Götzen’s (1933), then head of the Government Tax Accounting Service of the Netherlands-Indies, attempt was the most substantive. He found that the tax burden on Europeans and ‘Foreign Orientals’ (primarily Chinese) was higher than that on Indonesians, when he estimated total income for these population groups. Dutch economist Jacques Polak (1943), who had then just finished his PhD at Princeton University, was the first to prepare estimates resembling the present-day concept of national accounting. Combining the income and the production approaches, he produced estimates by industrial origin for the years 1921-1939 for indigenous Indonesians. To estimate total income for Europeans and
41
| National Accounting for Services in Indonesia
‘Foreign Orientals’ he used income tax data. Despite the fact that he had to make do with sources available in the United States, these estimates are regarded as having a considerable degree of reliability (Arndt and Ross 1970: 33). However, his work was not published upon completion, probably because it showed that average income in the group of Europeans was 45 times higher than average income among indigenous Indonesians (Dick et al. 2002: 141). Daniel Neumark (1954), who was the United Nation’s advisor of the National Planning Bureau (Biro Perancang Negara), published national income estimates for 1951-1952. His estimates were criticised on several methodological and conceptual grounds (Baga 1954: 33-35; Bakker 1954; Hollinger and Tan 1956/57; Muljatno 1957). Moreover, Neumark had to rely on statistical data that were less than satisfactory. In 1958 the un supported the establishment of a special Bureau for Economics and Finance (Biro Ekonomi dan Keuangan) within the National Planning Bureau. Attempts were made to compile national accounts, but estimating national income did not have priority. In one of these attempts Indonesian economist Muljatno Sindhudarmoko (1960) extended Neumark’s work to the years 1953 and 1954, using the same methods and concepts as Neumark. Later he estimated the national accounts for the whole period 1951-1959. Muljatno was very well aware of the shortcomings of his estimates. But he argued: ‘One instrument to obtain a picture about the (structural and functional) state of the economy in a country is the National Accounts. In the beginning it is indeed difficult to obtain reliable estimates for the National Accounts, but we need these calculations as a starting point in order to understand the difficulties. In the end knowing what these difficulties are will enable us to arrive at better estimates.’ (author’s translation of Muljatno 1960: 163). In 1966 the Indonesian Central Bureau of Statistics (Biro/Badan Pusat Statistik, bps) published national income estimates covering the years 1958-1962, and another in 1967 for the years 1960-1964 (bps 1966, 1967). The level of reliability of these estimates, however, left much to be desired (Arndt and Ross 1970: 35). When un technical assistance was resumed at the end of 1967, bps made a new effort to produce national account estimates following the concepts, definitions and methods recommended in the un’s revised 1968 sna. The procedures used for its estimation are basically the ones still employed today. This resulted in revised national accounts for the period 1960-1968 (bps 1970).
‘Salah satu alat untuk mendapatkan gambaran tentang keadaan (strukturil dan funksionil) ekonomi dari pada suatu Negara ialah perhitungan Pendapat Nasional. Memang pada mulanja banjaklah kesukaran2 untuk memperoleh angka2 Pendapat Nasional jang mendekati kebenarannja, tetapi kita harus mulai dengan perhitungan2 ini untuk mengetahui kesukaran tsb. agar achirnja dapatlah kita memperoleh angka2 jang makin lebih baik.’
42
| Accounting for Services
In 1969 improvements in national accounting were made possible through the first attempt to construct input-output (i-o) tables for Indonesia. Its first i-o table for 1969 was compiled as part of a collaborative project between the National Institute of Economic and Social Research (Lembaga Ekonomi dan Kemasyarakatan Nasional, leknas) and Kyoto University. The final reports were published in 1973 (leknas 1973a, 1973b). A more elaborate i-o table was produced for 1971 in a joint research project also involving the Institute of Developing Economies (ide); it was published in 1977 (ide 1977). This work has become the model for later i-o tables compiled by bps for 1975, 1980, 1985, 1990, 1995 and 2000, which in turn have been the basis for the various national accounts constructed since then. Indonesia’s national accounting system has experienced four major rounds of revisions, each coinciding with a change in the base year: 1971, 1983, 1993 and 2000. The revisions each time yielded significantly higher gdp estimates in the overlapping years. But since detailed supporting tables and explanations of the underlying accounting procedures and assumptions are sparse, it is hard to tell exactly which changes caused the differences. Since the 1980s, Angus Maddison (1989a, 1989b), one of the most influential authors in the field of long-run economic growth, and especially Van der Eng (1992, 2002) have undertaken attempts to reconstruct Indonesian national accounts through extrapolations of existing estimates as far back as 1700. But these important contributions are far from perfect and often rely on some very bold assumptions. Moreover, because of methodological problems their estimates are only in constant prices. The discussion above indicates that historical time series on total output and national income in Indonesia are available. However, the different estimates are incompatible due to changes in definitions as well as the significant degree of underestimation in the past. Simply linking these estimates to form a series would ignore such inconsistencies. Therefore the contribution of this study is to construct historical time series on value added in the service sector for the period 1900-2000 in a consistent and transparent way in both current and constant prices, in which definitions are reconciled.
2.3
Statistical sources Among Asian economies, Indonesia is exceptionally well endowed with detailed statistics on virtually all sectors of the economy. The statistical series were originally set up by the Dutch colonial administrators and some run as far back as to the 1820s. The institutions responsible for the collection, compilation and publication of economic statistics were the Centraal Kantoor voor de Statistiek (cks) in the colonial period and the Biro/Badan Pusat Statistik (bps) after independence (both may be translated as Central Bureau of Statistics). There was a considerable degree of continuity in this work that will ease the problems of linking series from the colonial period to the later period.
43
| National Accounting for Services in Indonesia
In the early nineteenth century statistical data were mainly collected in order to get impressions of the taxable base in the Javanese economy. Data on the number of households, for example, were used to allocate the compulsory cultivation of cash crops. Because of inconsistencies across residencies, in collecting data these statistical enumerations failed to provide a comprehensive statistical overview of Java (Van der Eng 1996a). Later these enumerations were standardised and conducted annually. Problems concerning statistical reporting remained, though, caused particularly by the philosophy behind the cultivation system. This system was based on indirect colonial rule (and therefore data collection) through indigenous heads and discouraged extensive direct contact between local colonial administrators and the indigenous population. Since 1834 the aggregated, but imperfect, statistical data, including population and various aspects of the indigenous economy, were published as appendices to various annual reports of the colonial government. Data were largely compiled by local colonial administrators, not by professional statisticians, on the basis of extensive surveys and censuses. Around 1850 it was common knowledge that the accuracy of the data was questionable (Van der Eng 1996a). In the second half of the nineteenth century the colonial administration was extended with specialised departments such as Finance (1855), Public Works (1855), Education, Religion and Industry (1866), Justice (1870), and Agriculture (1905). Since the collection of statistical data was transferred to these departments, annual reports were increasingly compiled with statistical data from them, rather than from local colonial administrators. The available statistical data therefore became increasingly abundant, although their accuracy remained in doubt, because civil servants were generally not trained to collect such data and check their accuracy. Therefore, the annual reports attached three labels to the data: ‘rather accurate’, ‘estimated’ and ‘based on guesses’. Around 1900, most data were collected and compiled by the various departments. But (semi-) governmental bodies, such as the Java Bank, the colony’s central bank, and the state railway company in Java, and private companies, such as the inter-island shipping company kpm, also produced data. Accuracy and coverage therefore depended on the purpose for which data were collected. Annual statistical digests had already been published for the Dutch colonies since 1887, when the first Jaarcijfers voor het Koninkrijk der Nederlanden: Koloniën appeared as a publication of the Statistical Association of the Netherlands. After 1897, this publication was compiled by the Dutch Central Bureau of Statistics. They relied heavily on data from the Koloniaal Verslagen (Colonial Report, kv), but also used other sources. After 1922, it was replaced by the Statistisch Jaaroverzicht (Statistical Abstract, sjo), which after 1931 was in turn replaced by the second volume of the Verslag van de Direkteur over de Kultures (Report of the Director of Cultivation, 1834-1850), Koloniaal Verslag (Colonial Reports, 1851-1930) and Indisch Verslag (Indian Report, 19311940).
44
| Accounting for Services
Indisch Verslag (Indian Report). These publications together comprise a continuous statistical record for the final five decades of the colonial era up until 1941. In 1925 the central bureau of statistics (Centraal Kantoor voor de Statistiek, cks) was established. During the 1930s the cks published several Statistical Pocketbooks in Dutch; the final one of the series was published in English after the war (Statistical Pocketbook of Indonesia, 1941). These publications mainly reproduced material from the Indisch Verslag, Vol. 2, but also contained some additional material. From 1925 to 1941 the cks also published a series of Mededeelingen (Bulletins), many of which contained valuable time series on topics such as international trade, food production and prices. After Indonesian independence it took until 1975 for scholars to become aware of this huge body of data contained in the Dutch colonial publications. Their awareness and interest resulted in the ‘Changing Economy in Indonesia: A Selection of Statistical Source Material from the Early 19th Century up to 1940’ series, numbering 16 volumes. This series provides relatively consistent data on, for example, population, foreign trade and food production. Besides being an invaluable source of data for the quantitative study of Indonesian economic history, the volumes are also an excellent bibliographic guide to statistical sources and to the secondary literature (Booth 1999: 3). During the Japanese occupation (1942-1945), Indonesia was subdivided into three administrative areas. Not much is known about statistical reporting in the Outer Islands. In Java the Japanese authorities continued the cks, which was incorporated in 1944 in the Office for General Research (Chosashitsu). Nevertheless, the publication of statistical data was discontinued, while details on data compilation are minimal. The Indonesian Revolution (1945-1949) caused further disruption. The Chosashitsu was continued by the Republic of Indonesia as the Kantor Penjelidikan Oemoem (kpo), and it was moved to Yogyakarta in 1946. The Dutch re-established the cks in Jakarta in 1947. It gradually resumed statistical reporting, although it was limited to the areas under Dutch control. After the transfer of sovereignty in December 1949, the cks and the kpo were merged to form the Kantor Pusat Statistik (kps). During the 1950s many of the statistical reporting practices established in the late colonial period were resumed. The statistical pocketbooks were again published in the early 1950s and a monthly statistical bulletin (Statistik Konjunktur) was established. As discussed before, in this period a national accounts division was set up to prepare gdp estimates (Neumark 1954; Muljatno 1960; United Nations 1964). Despite the deteriorating economic conditions a number of new initiatives were undertaken in the early 1960s. In 1961 the first national population census since 1930 was carried out, followed by the first agricultural census in 1963 and the first industrial census in 1964. In 1963/64 a National Socioeconomic Survey (Survai Sosial Ekonomi Nasional, Susenas) was introduced. Besides the Central Bureau of Statistics a number of other government organisations collected statistics. Most notably, Bank Indonesia, Indonesia’s central bank
45
| National Accounting for Services in Indonesia
(successor of the Java Bank since 1953), published an annual report containing among other items, monetary and balance of payments data, and data on government revenues and expenditures.
Table 2.1
Main bps publications relevant for this study
Population Census
1961, 1971, 1980, 1990, 2000
Inter-census Population Survey
1976, 1985, 1995
Agricultural Census
1963, 1973, 1983, 1993, 2003
Economic Census (Industrial Census)
1964, 1974, 1985, 1995
Input-Output tables
(1971), 1975, 1980, 1985, 1990, 1995, 2000
Statistical Pocketbook/Yearbook of Indonesia (Statistik Indonesia)
Annually (since 1951)
Source: Adapted from Booth 1999: 14. Note: The 1971 Input-Output table was a joint research project between bps and the Japanese Institute of Developing Economies (ide).
Since the late 1960s, with assistance from the United Nations and bilateral agencies, a major revision of the national accounts data for the years 1960-1968 was published. Since then gdp figures have been published on an annual basis. In 1971 another Population Census was held, followed by the first inter-census Population Survey (Supas) in 1976. In the same year a National Labour Survey (Survai Angkatan Kerja Nasional, Sakernas) was carried out. Since 1968 Statistical Pocketbooks of Indonesia have been published annually. Beginning in 1975 to this was added an annual Statistical Yearbook of Indonesia (Statistik Indonesia). Moreover, after a trial in 1971, the national accounts estimates have since 1975 been based on five-yearly Input-Output tables. Over the 1980s and 1990s the range of publication of the bps has steadily increased.
2.4
Estimating value added in services The estimation within the framework of national accounts for the colonial period has to be done from scratch, whereas the period since independence official estimates made by the Central Bureau of Statistics (bps) combined with Input-Output tables produced every five years since 1975 serve as a starting point. In the remainder of this chapter the estimation procedures for the different service sectors are discussed.
2.4.1
Transport and communications According to the System of National Accounts, the output of transportation is measured by the value of the amounts receivable for transporting goods or persons. In economics a good in one location is recognised as having a different quality from the
46
| Accounting for Services
same good in another location, so that transporting from one location to another is a process of production in which an economically significant transformation takes place even if the good remains otherwise unchanged.
2.4.1.1
Rail transport Using the production approach, current price estimates can be derived from the profit-and-loss accounts of the different railway companies. During colonial times the State Railway Enterprise (Staatsspoorwegen, ss) was the most important, but not the only provider of railway services. The two other main providers of railway services were the Deli Spoorweg Maatschappij (dsm) and the Nederlandsch-Indische Spoorweg Maatschappij (nism). The sources give detailed information on total revenues, expenditures and number of passengers and amount of goods transported. Estimates on the cost structure are obtained from annual reports of the above mentioned railway enterprises (i.e. ss, dsm, and nism). With this information it is possible to estimate value added in current prices on an annual basis. Constant price estimates are obtained by deflating the current price series using passenger and ton-kilometre weighted composite indices as the extrapolator. The same procedure can be applied for the period 1950-1960 for which the annual reports of the State Railways are published. From 1960 onwards estimates are taken from Indonesia’s official national accounts. These estimates are constructed following the same method as used for the other periods. Because of the relatively straightforward procedure in estimating value added, it is believed that inconsistencies in estimation methods are not large in this sub-sector. The exact methods, sources and results are presented in appendix 1.
2.4.1.2
Road transport Road transport is much more difficult to estimate, since one cannot simply rely on annual reports. Therefore different methods have to be explored. For the colonial period the following estimation procedures were applied.
Traditional road transport According to the 1930 population census, 166,521 persons (or 0.27 per cent of the total population or 52.7 per cent of people working in the transport sector) were working in the sub-sector road transport. I assume that 15,000 of them were working as taxi drivers (see below) and 65,000 for bus and truck companies (3 per bus/ truck); this would mean that approximately 95,000 people were working as drivers of traditional means of transportation. It is unlikely that they earned significantly more than an unskilled labourer. Therefore it is assumed that on average someone working in this sector earns a wage close to that of an unskilled labourer (cei xiii 1992: 120). This means that the contribution of traditional road transport to gdp was 95.000 * 0.50 guilders per day * 320 days = 15.2 million guilders in 1930.
47
| National Accounting for Services in Indonesia
Transport by car The source Statistiek van het Taxi-verkeer in de Stad Soerabaja (Statistics on Taxi Traffic in the City of Surabaya) gives information about the revenues earned by taxis. Gross revenues were estimated at between 15 and 20 guilders per day in 1929, with an average of 17.50 guilders. So if all taxis were in use together they earned 843 x 17.50 = 14,752.50 guilders per day or 5.4 million guilders on a yearly basis. With 258,489 inhabitants this means that on a yearly basis 20.83 guilders per inhabitant is spent on transport by taxi. Moreover, if we look at statistics on automobile services in 1931, we also find average earnings per day per car of 17.17 guilders (Statistical Abstract 1935: 339). There were three kinds of operating expenses for a taxi driver: fuel, rent and maintenance. A taxi used at most 40 litres a day or roughly 14,600 litres a year, so all 843 taxis together used 12,307,800 litres per year. Since a litre of gasoline in 1929 cost 0.23 guilders total expenditure on fuel amounted to around 2,830,794 guilders. Most taxis in Surabaya were owned by Chinese. Of the 843 taxis 471 or 55.9 per cent were Chinese-owned. Renting a taxi for a day usually cost around 10 guilders (Djojosoedarman 1941). Costs for maintenance are not available, but are here assumed to be 5 per cent of total revenue. Total revenue: Cost of fuel: Maintenance (5 %): Value Added:
5,384,662.50 guilders 2,830,794 guilders 269,233.15 guilders 2,284,635.35 guilders (or 2,710.15 guilders per taxi)
Assuming, on average, a constant ratio between number of cars and taxis across Indonesia, and a similar cost structure, value added for transport by car is estimated at roughly 37.2 million guilders in 1929. Table 2.2
Taxis in Surabaya, 1925-1929 Of which taxis
1925 1926 1927 1928 1929
Number of cars 3,119 3,263 3,435
Number 400 800 750
% 12.8 24.5 21.8
4,166
843
20.2
Source: Statistiek van het taxi-verkeer in de stad Soerabaja, Soerabaja Bureau van de Statistiek, 1930.
Table 2.3
Value added by taxis in Indonesia, 1929 Number of cars
Taxis
Value added per taxi
Value added total
Surabaya
4,166
843 (=20.24 %)
2,710.15
2,284,635.35
Indonesia
67,863
13,735 (=20.24 %)
2,710.15
37,223,910.25
Source: See text.
48
| Accounting for Services
Trucks and buses No information is available about revenue and operating expenses of trucks and buses. Therefore some very bold assumptions have to be made. I assume that, because more people are needed (for, among other things, loading/unloading, administration, etc.) to operate a bus or truck, the value added of these means of transportation are twice as high as that of a taxi. This is in line with the assumptions made by Neumark (1954: 377) and Muljatno (1960: 176) who both had access to information from the Ministry of Communications and the Ikatan Motor Indonesia (Indonesian Motor Union). The following calculation then gives us the value added of trucks and buses in 1930: Number of trucks * value added per truck (= 2 * value added by a taxi) + number of buses * value added per bus (= 2 * value added by a taxi) = 16,077 * 5,420 guilders + 5.590 * 5,420 guilders = 116,513,740 guilders
Table 2.4
Value added of road transport (in thousands of guilders), 1930 Traditional road transport
Taxis/cars
Trucks/buses
Total road transport
15,200
37,224
116,514
168,938
1930 Source: See text.
Table 2.5
Degree of urbanisation, 1890-1930 Population
Urban population
Rural population
% of total
% of total
Java & Madura 1890
24,035,914
1920
34,984,171
1930
41,718,364
1920
14,366,054
1930
1,162,855
4.8
22,873,059
95.2
2,035,129
5.8
32,949,042
94.2
3,013,306
7.2
38,705,058
92.8
511,303
3.6
13,854,751
96.4
19,008,869
734,097
3.9
18,274,772
96.1
1920
49,350,225
2,546,432
5.2
46,803,793
94.8
1930
60,727,233
3,747,403
6.2
56,979,830
93.8
Outer Islands 1890
Indonesia 1890
Source: cei xi 1991.
To arrive at value added constant price estimates the following procedure is followed. • Traditional road transport is extrapolated based on an urbanisation index (see table 2.5).
49
| National Accounting for Services in Indonesia
The underlying reasoning is that urbanisation functions as a proxy for the level of market activity. In a subsistence economy, all people live in rural areas, and there is no need to market their products; hence demand for (traditional forms of) transport is limited. • Taxis/cars are extrapolated based on the number of cars in Indonesia. Since data about the number of registered cars are until 1935 quite inaccurate the number of cars was estimated using the information on imports of cars, and assuming a life time of 10 years for cars (cei ix 1989: 84). Thus: Cars in operation (t) = Imports of cars (t) + Cars in operation (t-1) – 0.10 * Cars in operation (t-1) Value added in current prices is obtained by assuming that value added in this sector followed the development of the cost-of-living index. This index is taken from Van Leeuwen (2007). The constant price series is inflated by this index. The results of these exercises are summarised in appendix table A1.9. The estimation of gross value added at current prices in Indonesia’s post-independence national accounts was rather intransparent. The available information does show that estimation methods were essentially the same as used herein for the colonial period, so that a more or less consistent series is obtained. In nearly all cases, however, the underlying data are not available, so that we have to rely on the aggregated estimates. For the 1960s and the 1970s the following estimation methods were applied by bps: • Bus transport: From 1960 through 1965 the estimates were based on average cost and revenue data of pn Damri, the most important state-owned bus enterprise, and on information on the bus fleet in operation supplied by the Directorate of Road Transport (Badan Lalu Lintas Darat, blld). Gross revenue since 1966 had been calculated using statistics on total number of buses in operation, annual average mileage per bus, average number of passengers per bus and average tariff per passenger-kilometre. This information was obtained from the Police Department, the Private Road Transport Association (Organisasi Angkutan Darat, Organda) and Damri. Average cost percentages were estimated by Organda. Gross value added at constant prices was obtained by extrapolation by an index of the number of buses in operation. • Truck transport: From 1960 through 1965 value added at constant prices was calculated as the product of the total number of trucks in operation according to blld and average costs per truck in 1960 derived from a survey conducted in West Java. From this series current prices were derived using Damri’s index of average wages and salaries per employee
50
| Accounting for Services
as an inflator. From 1966, a similar method to that for bus transport was used, i.e. calculating gross revenue as product of ton-kilometres and average tariffs based on the same sources as for buses. Cost percentages were estimated by Organda. Constant prices were obtained using an index of the vehicle fleet in operation. • Becak (cycle rickshaw) transport: The total number of becak in Indonesia was estimated on the basis of the number of those registered in Jakarta in 1966 through 1968, and the ratio of urban population in Indonesia to Jakarta population. These estimates were extrapolated back to 1960 by the growth of urban population. Average revenue, intermediate consumption, and gross value added per becak were derived from a case study conducted in Jakarta in 1968 by the National Income Division. Assuming that the average revenue per becak has followed the development of the cost-of-living index throughout the period, average revenue in 1968 was extrapolated by this index, and the current price average obtained multiplied by the number of becak operated in each year. An unchanged cost structure in this period was also assumed. Constant price estimates were prepared using for extrapolation an index of the total number of becak. These valuable surveys by bps and Organda have, unfortunately, never been published, nor have I been able to locate them in Indonesian archives or libraries. From the 1980s onward information about the estimation methods becomes even scarcer. The sources state that estimation was based on the number of commercial cargoes and passenger vehicles liable for inspection, gathered from the Road Transport Office (Dinas Lalu Lintas Angkutan Jalan Raya, dllajr) annual report, collected by the Transport and Communication Statistics Division of bps. Average output and intermediate input ratios by vehicle types were made available through a survey conducted by bps. None of these reports has been published or are in any other way made available. Due to the very limited data availability, some crude procedures have to be followed, which particularly build on the i-o tables. The years for which i-o tables were published are used as benchmark years, from which estimates for other years are obtained by extrapolation based on a volume index of number of motor vehicles and inflated for the years within. The various key indicators for this procedure are given in appendix tables A1.10 and A1.11. The complete time-series for value added in road transport are presented in table A1.12.
2.4.1.3
Water transport During the colonial period the most important supplier in inter-island shipping was the kpm. In 1930 it was estimated that kpm covered 42.9 per cent of total inter-island shipping traffic or almost 80 per cent of inter-island shipping under the flag of the Netherlands-Indies (Statistiek van de Scheepvaart over het jaar 1930). Since the profitand-loss accounts of this company are available it is possible to estimate its value added for the period 1900-1940.
51
| National Accounting for Services in Indonesia
In the 1960s estimates were based on Bank Indonesia’s statistics of Indonesianowned and chartered tonnage in inter-insular and ocean trade. Gross value added at constant prices was obtained by deflating current price estimates by the cost-ofliving index. From the 1980s onwards output and current prices were estimated by multiplying the number of cargoes and passengers transported by tariff per unit of cargo and passenger, respectively. Average output data were derived from shipping enterprise reports, while data on cost structure were based on i-o tables. Cargo and passenger data were provided by the Indonesian National Shipowner Association (insa), bps and other sources. Gross value added at constant prices was calculated by extrapolation using weighted composite indices of cargoes and passengers transported. Just as with the other sub-sectors, these underlying reports and surveys were never published. Apart from loading and unloading statistics, other data on cargo and passengers or systematic data on the number of ships sailing under the Indonesian flag have never been published by bps. So, again, for the period 1950-2000 the i-o tables had to serve as a starting point from which estimates for the other years are arrived at by extrapolation. The details of these estimations procedures are discussed in appendix A1.3. The complete time-series are presented in table A1.21.
2.4.1.4
Air transport Value added in air transport can also be estimated using the production approach. In 1928 the Royal Netherlands-Indies Airline (Koninklijke Nederlandsch-Indische Luchtvaartmaatschappij, knilm) started its operation. Based on its annual reports the value added of air transport can be estimated for the period 1928-1940. For the period after independence the same estimation method has been used. Gross value added was estimated by the production approach, based on output and cost structure data that were obtained through airline enterprises survey by bps. Gross value added at constant prices was computed by using a weighted composite production index of passenger-kilometre and ton-kilometre of cargo transported. It will come as no surprise that these surveys have not been published either. The i-o tables again are the most valuable source for estimation for the period since independence. The results are presented in table A1.28.
2.4.1.5
Communications This sub-sector covers the activities of the post, telegraph and telephone offices. During the colonial period the communications sector was in hands of the stateowned enterprise ptt (Staatsbedrijf der Posterijen, Telegrafie en Telefonie). The contribution to national income is obtained as the sum of wages and salaries, interest and operating surplus. The data available for this sector are, like those for rail and air transport, quite comprehensive and taken from the annual reports of the ptt. The method of estimation throughout the second half of the twentieth century was also the production approach. Output at current prices was gathered from financial reports of these companies. Value added was also from the financial
52
| Accounting for Services
report in the form of summing wages and salaries, profit or loss, depreciation and other components of the value added. Value added and output at constant prices were estimated by extrapolation. The time-series for this sector are presented in table A1.34.
2.4.2
Trade Activities included in this sub-sector are the ones concerned with buying and selling products, either new or used goods, for distribution without changing the characteristics of the products. According to the 1993 System of National Accounts, traders are treated as supplying services rather than goods to their customers by storing and displaying a selection of goods in convenient locations and making them easily available for customers to buy. Their output is measured by the total value of the trade margins realised on the goods they purchase for resale. A trade margin is defined as the difference between the actual or imputed price realised on a good purchased for resale and the price that would have to be paid by the distributor to replace the good at the time it is sold or otherwise disposed of. The margins realised on some goods may be negative if their prices have to be marked down. They must be negative on goods that are never sold. The key is therefore to assess the trade margins on different kinds of goods over time.
2.4.2.1
Trade margins in colonial times Data on trade margins during the colonial period are almost non-existent. Sivasubramonian in his research on the national income of India in the twentieth century and Horlings in his work on the Netherlands between 1800 and 1850 were confronted with similar data problems (Sivasubramonian 2000: 338; Horlings 1995: 342). Smits, on the other hand, gives some very detailed information on trade margins in the Netherlands. According to his calculations for the trading firm Van Eeghen in Amsterdam the gross profit margin was in the 1850s on average between 25 to 30 per cent for imports and the net profit margin between 10 and 12 per cent. Compared to trade margins for the Nederlandsche Handel-Maatschappij (Netherlands Trading Company, nhm), he concludes, this seems to be a rather modest estimate. Furthermore Smits found that the trade margin on imports declined to around 6 per cent in 1890 and 5 per cent in 1913 (Smits 1995: 314-315). For domestic trade Smits based his trade margins on two studies by the Dutch Central Bureau of Statistics (cbs). This resulted in the gross profit margins in table 2.6.
53
| National Accounting for Services in Indonesia
Table 2.6
Trade margins in the Netherlands, 1913 and 1987
Product
Wholesale
Retail
Wholesale
Retail
1987
1987
1913
1913
Foodstuff
11.2
21.7
17.4
33.7
- General
9.7
19.2
15.1
34.3
- Sweets
17.9
34.7
27.8
53.9
- Fruits & vegetables
14.1
28.7
21.9
44.6
- Alcoholic beverages
13.8
16.0
21.4
24.8
- Tobacco
4.5
14.6
7.0
22.7
- Milk
6.2
20.2
9.6
31.3
- Meat
12.1
34.8
18.8
54.1
- Clothing
21.4
37.0
33.3
57.6
- Furniture
26.8
37.2
41.6
57.7
- Household products
20.6
34.1
32.0
53.0
- Drugstore products
27.1
31.9
42.1
48.1
- Paper
22.3
32.5
34.7
50.6
Raw materials - Agriculture
13.6
10.7
- Textiles
7.8
6.2
- Metals
9.6
7.6
- Wood
28.3
22.4
Construction materials
25.0
19.8
- Chemicals
12.7
Source: Smits 1995: 323.
Another researcher who did find trade margins is French economic historian JeanPascal Bassino. For Vietnam he found a wholesale gross margin of about 35 per cent, corresponding to a net margin of about 20 per cent. For international trade he assumed a net margin of 3 per cent of fob prices for exports and a similar margin on cif prices for imports. A retail margin of 6 per cent was identified for rice. For all other products he assumed a margin of 10 per cent. His calculations result in a revenue of retail service per worker which is extremely low, which does not seem unlikely given the large number of street peddlers etc. in Asian countries, who earn hardly more than a subsistence level. However, for the Netherlands-Indies no direct data on trade margins for the colonial period have been found. The archives of Dutch trading houses, such as Internatio, Handelsvereniging Amsterdam (hva, Trading Association Amsterdam) and the
Based on unpublished data made available by Bassino as part of his ongoing work to estimate gdp in Vietnam between 1880 and 1954.
54
| Accounting for Services
nhm do not yield information that enables the calculation of disaggregated trade margins. In order to estimate an aggregated trade margin, only a very crude method can be adopted. This is by dividing total turnover by gross profit. The annual reports of Internatio and Hagemeijer provide this information, as can be seen in figure 2.1. This method results in trade margins that vary significantly between an average of 17.6 per cent for Hagemeijer and 4.5 per cent for Internatio. It is hard to believe that such large and consistent differences really existed, especially because trends in profitability are fairly similar, as can be seen in figure 2.1. The difference is probably caused by different accounting methods, and the ‘true’ profit margin lies somewhere in between.
Figure 2.1 Gross profit margins of Hagemeijer & Internatio, 1914-1939 45%
8%
40%
7%
35%
6%
30%
5%
25% 4% 20% 3%
15%
2%
10%
1%
5% 0%
0% 1914 1916 1918 1920 1922 1924 1926 1928 1930 1932 1934 1936 1938 Hagemeijer
2.4.2.2
Internatio
Source: De Jong 1995; see also appendix table A2.1.
Trade margins in Indonesia’s national accounts 1951-1952: Neumark When constructing national accounts for Indonesia for 1951 and 1952 Neumark estimated commodities and articles entering into commerce by main groups of articles and commodities. For agricultural commodities he concluded that reliable estimates were not available; he therefore chose a rather rough net margin of 10 per cent, assuming that the proportions of the various crops were traded domestically as given in table 2.7.
55
| National Accounting for Services in Indonesia
Table 2.7 Peasant crops, volumes traded at 10 per cent margin Crops
Percentage by volume
Rice
20
Maize
10
Peanuts
5
Soya
2.5
Potatoes
90
Fruit & Vegetables
5
Source: Neumark 1954: 381.
For trade margins on export trade Neumark used a figure for a commission of 2 per cent for all estate crops exported, except for palm oil, kernels and Deli tobacco, since these crops were mostly exported by the producers themselves, and consequently the value of the services of exporting may be retained in the value of the product instead of being added to trade. Export crops grown by peasants were estimated at a margin of 15 per cent, since such crops involve a great deal more collecting and handling than in the case of estate crops. For live animals and products of animals and products of animal origin an export margin of 20 per cent was allocated to trade. Other margins used by Neumark for export trade are given in table 2.8.
Table 2.8 Trade margins for different export commodities Commodity Estate export crops
Trade margin 2%
Peasant export crops
15 %
Live animals and products of animal origin
20 %
Wood, etc.
10 %
Forest products
15 %
Other products of vegetable origin
15 %
Mining productsa
15 %
Source: Neumark 1954: 381. a: Excluding oil products, tin and bauxite, which are exported by the mining companies.
For imported rice, Neumark used a trade margin of 15 per cent since it was mostly handled in bulk and was also mostly higher in price than locally produced rice. Therefore he concluded that a margin of 20 per cent was unlikely. For other imported consumer goods, excluding imported kerosene, which was accounted for elsewhere, a margin of 40 per cent was taken. Margin on imported raw materials and auxilary products, which are mostly purchased in bulk by a comparatively small number of buyers, was estimated by Neumark to be 20 per cent. Other margins used by Neumark can be found in table 2.9.
56
| Accounting for Services
Table 2.9 Trade margins used by Neumark on other commodities
Commodity Trade margin Durable consumption and capital goods 25 % (of which 17.5 % value added) Locally manufactured goods 35 % Forestry and forestry productsa 40 % Fish 30 % Cattleb ±75 % Goats and sheep ±25 % Pigs ±75 % Chickens/duckse ±35 % Source: Neumark 1954: 382-384. a: Assumed is that 40 % of charcoal and firewood produced entered into trade. b: Assumed is that 20 % of cattle and buffaloes, 30% of sheep and goats, 50% of pigs, 65%. of poultry and 60% of eggs did not enter into trade. The meat per animal was assumed to be 120 kg for cattle and buffaloes, 40 kg for pigs and 8 kg for sheep and goats.
1953-1954: Muljatno Building on the earlier estimates of Neumark (1954) for the years 1951-1952, Muljatno (1960) reconstructed the National Accounts of Indonesia for the years 19531954. Although Muljatno in many aspects continued the work by Neumark, he was critical about one aspect of his work, namely that he was often unclear about his sources and exact methods of estimation (Muljatno 1960: 162). Muljatno is indeed precise about this. The trade margins used by Muljatno are discussed below. Export trade: According to information from als (Algemene Landbouw Syndicaat, Common Agricultural Syndicate) a commission of 3 per cent was obtained on the yield of exported estate crops and 15 per cent on farm crops. Profit on exported animal husbandry was estimated to be 20 per cent, forestry 10 per cent, and other food crops 15 per cent. Import trade; According to information obtained from yubm (Yajasan Urusan Bahan Makanan), the profit from selling imported rice was 10 per cent. Consumer goods could earn 30 per cent, raw and auxilary materials 20 per cent and capital and durable goods 27.5 per cent. The profit obtained from raw earth oil was directly taken from firms that import these goods.
Domestic trade: 1) Food: For food the estimates were taken from Neumark (1954); he gives the profit from trade in food as about 10 per cent, while the part of the production that was traded as: rice 20 per cent, corn 10 per cent, peanuts 5 per cent, soya beans 2.5 per cent, and vegetables and fruit 5 per cent. The remainder was used for own consumption.
57
| National Accounting for Services in Indonesia
2) Fishing: According to information from Ocean Fishing Agency (Djawatan Perikanan Laut), the profit obtained from trading fish varied between 20 and 50 per cent. Therefore 30 per cent was taken as an approximation. 3) Animal husbandry: Of all animal husbandry the following amounts were not traded: cattle 20 per cent, sheep and goats 50 per cent, pigs 50 per cent, chicken 65 per cent and eggs 65 per cent. Profit was calculated not by the number of animals, but from kilograms of meat, excluding chicken and eggs. The figures used are: cattle about 120 kg of meat, a sheep or goat 8 kg and a pig 40 kg. Prices were taken from bps. Profit on trading a chicken was Rp. 3 in 1953 and Rp. 4 in 1954, and 15 per cent on eggs. 4) Forestry: Domestic use of wood per year was estimated to be 36 million m3 with a price between Rp. 23 and Rp. 24 per m3 in 1953 and 1954. Only one-quarter of this was traded, and probably only people in cities actually bought wood. Of this, three-quarters was traded on wholesale markets and the remaining quarter through retail trade. The profit made from the wholesale trade was 20 per cent and from the retail trade 50 per cent. For trade bamboo the profit was only 2 per cent. 5) Manufactures: The value of manufactures was Rp. 16,678,000 in 1953 and Rp. 17,329,000 in 1954. Of this, 15 per cent was traded between industries with the profit of the remainder being 40 per cent. 6) Domestically used sugar: Based on the difference between industry prices and retail prices the profit made from trading sugar was 6 per cent.
Official estimates by bps: 1960s In the 1960s and 1970s bps used the methods as formulated in the System of National Accounts. Estimates were derived from the value of the marketed surplus of the production in agriculture, fishing, forestry, mining, manufacturing and the marketing of exports and imports of merchandise. The marketed proportions were estimated on the basis of information supplied by the Departments of Agriculture and Trade and by other agencies. The proportions used were: for farm food crops 30 per cent; farm non-foods 75 per cent; estate crops 100 per cent; livestock 50 per cent; fishing 75 per cent; forestry 50 per cent; mining 100 per cent; large and medium manufacturing 100 per cent; household industry 50 per cent; and import/export 100 per cent. Throughout the period fixed percentages are used. Fixed trade margins were applied to these marketed surpluses estimated by the Department of Trade. These margins were 20 per cent for exports, 50 per cent for imports and 20 per cent for domestically produced goods. These estimates were derived from the National Sample Survey of 1963.
1970s to the present: estimates based on Input-Output tables With the appearance of the first i-o tables, constructed in 1975 the trade margins are no longer based on irregular surveys, but taken directly from this publication.
58
| Accounting for Services
However, gross value added of the trade sub-sector is still estimated by using the commodity flow method. After computing the output of agriculture, mining and quarrying, manufacturing and import commodities marketed through the trade sub-sector, the results were multiplied by ratios of traded merchandise, and trade margins derived from i-o tables (see appendix table A2.2). The conclusion from the preceding discussion of different trade margins is that, over time, trade margins do not seem to fluctuate much. I have therefore chosen to use fixed margins of 12.5 per cent for agricultural goods, 11.5 per cent for manufactured goods, 20 per cent for imports and 15 per cent for exports. These percentages are mainly based on estimates from the i-o tables, and seem in line with the other sources that were discussed. Furthermore, I assume that in 1900 50 per cent of total agricultural output is for own consumption, falling to 10 per cent in 2000. The results of these estimation procedures are summarised in appendix table A2.3.
2.4.3
Government The conventional practice in national income estimation is to evaluate government services – other than those of government enterprises – in terms of expenditure made for them. Government activities can best be split into administrative and commercial activities. The former are valued at the cost of these services, that is, as equivalent to the wages and salaries paid by government administrative departments and the latter on the same basis as other productive enterprises. The government sector includes the public administration under government services. Under commercial activities railways, post and telegraph, opium production, salt production, etc. These major commercial activities are treated separately.
Government administration in the colonial period For the colonial period a few useful sources for the estimation of the government sector are available. To begin with the number of people employed by the government is known for 1930 from the census. Moreover the Colonial Reports give the number of government employees as of 1 March 1932. A direct estimate of the payroll paid by the government can be made for one single year, namely 1926. For that year the total wages and salaries paid to all employees have been published (Colonial Report 1929: 430); unfortunately this has not been published for other years. Additionally, this figure seems to underestimate the total number of persons employed, because it is highly unlikely that the number of civil servants increased from 149,783 in 1926 to 516,176 in 1930. Probably, people working in the desa were not accounted for in the earlier figures. An alternative method has also been applied. From the Netherlands-Indies budgets for several benchmark years the wages paid are taken for the different departments. Assuming that the ratio of wages paid to total expenditure per department is constant we arrive at an estimate of this sub-sector. In table 2.10 figures are taken
59
| National Accounting for Services in Indonesia
from a study by the colonial administrator H.M.J. Hart (1932). We see that between 1922 and 1931 salaries made up between 29.5 per cent and 37.1 per cent of total expenditures. This corresponds with my own findings for 1907, when salaries and wages accounted for 34.5 per cent of total expenditures. It therefore seems reasonable to estimate total value added of the government sector for the colonial period as 34.5 per cent of total expenditures to which 5 per cent is added as approximation of depreciation, as is also done in Indonesia’s present-day national accounts. Table 2.10 Salaries and wages paid by the colonial government, 1922-1931 (in million guilders, excluding state enterprises) Total expenditure
Interest
Pensions
Salaries
Salaries as % of total
501
73
38
148
29.5%
1923
436
79
41
145
33.3%
1924
402
85
45
143
35.6%
1925
415
83
48
152
36.6%
1926
431
83
50
160
37.1%
1927
466
84
52
169
36.3%
1928
502
98
55
176
35.1%
1929
502
86
62
182
36.3%
1930
508
81
62
185
36.4%
1931
517
85
65
192
37.1%
1922
Source: Hart 1932: 313.
Government administration in Indonesia’s national accounts since independence In the period 1951-1954 figures about wages and salaries were taken directly from the different ministries. In the national accounts estimates of the 1960s production accounts for the central government were derived from actual routine budget expenditure statements of the Budget Directorate of the Department of Finance. Fixed capital consumption was calculated as 5 per cent of net value added, i.e. compensation of employees. The compensation of employees in local government was calculated as the product of average annual income per employee and employment figures. Employment estimates were based on information from the Department of Interior and on the Census of Civil Servants. For the 1980s and 1990s the contribution of this sector to gross domestic product consisted of routine wages and salaries of central and local government employees, the wage component of the development budget and 5 per cent depreciation. The estimation was based on realised government expenditure gathered from the Ministry of Finance and bps. The available data allow for a consistent estimation of value added in government services. The expenditure on personnel is taken from the budgets, augmented
60
| Accounting for Services
by 5 per cent depreciation. The expenditure on personnel was estimated to be, on average, 34.5 per cent of the budget for the period 1900-1940 and 39.3 per cent on average for the period 1950-2000. The results are summarised in appendix table A3.12.
2.4.4
Ownership of dwellings In the sna the contribution of house property to national income is taken as equivalent to the net rental income of dwellings. No distinction is made between owneroccupied houses and rented houses. The rental value of shops and other industrial buildings is not counted as housing, but as part of the product of the respective industries. This treatment of owner-occupied housing is quite remarkable, since there is no employment imputed with the process of production, and therefore capital is the only production factor. Therefore one has to be careful when relating gdp to employment for the purpose of estimating and comparing productivity. In the absence of any proper statistics an option to estimate gross value added is to assume that ownership of dwellings corresponds to a constant percentage of the gross value added of all other activities at both current and constant prices. This is also the method used by bps in the 1960s, which assumed a 2 per cent contribution to gdp. Van der Eng (2002) applied a different method. He estimated gross value added in housing using population and the sub-total of all other sectors as indicators, each with a weight of 0.5. The assumption is that growth of per capita income induces people to invest in the quality of houses, which increases the rental value of dwellings. But it seems that with the available information more reliable estimates can be made. From the 1930 census we learn that there were in Java and Madura a total of 8,784,000 Indonesian dwellings. Of these 352,000 were brick dwellings, while 4,837,000 were classified as ‘other than brick dwellings with permanent roofs’. There were further a total of 48,000 European dwellings (mainly brick), 121,000 Chinese and 11,000 other dwellings. Figures for the rest of Indonesia are not available but can be extrapolated from these data.
Table 2.11
Number of dwellings in Indonesia, 1930 Indonesian European
Number of dwellings in Java & Madura
Chinese
Other
Total
8,784,000
48,000
121,000
11,000
8,964,000
40,891,093
192,571
582,431
52,269
41,718,364
4.7
4.0
4.8
4.8
4.7
18,246,974
47,846
650,783
3,919,715
11,926
135,200
13,314
4,080,155
Estimated total number of dwellings in Indonesia 12,703,715
59,926
256,200
24,314
13,044,155
Population in Java & Madura Ratio population/dwelling in Java & Madura Population in Outer Islands Estimated number of dwellings in Outer Islands
Sources: Author’s calculations based on Volkstelling 1930.
61
| National Accounting for Services in Indonesia
63,266 19,008,869
Besides giving the number of dwellings per population group in Java and Madura, the 1930 census also tells us how many people from the different population groups were living in Java and Madura. From this we can calculate how many people on average lived in one house for the different population groups. If we assume that this ratio was the same in the Outer Islands, we can derive the number of dwellings in the Outer Islands by multiplying this ratio by the number of people of the different population groups living in the Outer Islands. This information is also taken from the 1930 census. In this way we arrive at an estimate of the total number of dwellings in Indonesia in 1930. The results are shown in table 2.11. Now that we have an estimate of the total number of dwellings it is possible to calculate the contribution of housing to gdp. To arrive at this estimate information on expenditure on housing is needed. This information can be obtained from household surveys. One such survey is that by the Centraal Kantoor van de Statistiek (cks) in 1928 on 314 urban households. The relevant results are presented in table 2.12. In 1939 cks published a study on 95 labourer households in Jakarta. This survey revealed that rents for these labourers, who can be classified as largely unskilled labourers, varied between 0.50 and 5.00 guilders (cks 1939: 12). Initiated by the Lembaga Penyelidikan Ekonomi dan Masyarakat (Institute of Economic and Social Research) at the University of Indonesia, Ibrahim and Weinreb (1957) conducted a study on living expenditures in Jakarta in 1953. In a sample of 250 urban households they found an average rent for civil servants of Rp. 16.00, for a labourer of Rp. 9.70 and for a trader Rp. 1.40 (see also table appendix A4.3).
Table 2.12 Monthly expenditure on rent in guilders, August 1925 Income class
Number of families
Average expenditure
A (2400) Total
On rent
Source: cks 1928.
Moreover historians Freek Colombijn and Martine Barwegen (2005) give some detailed information on rents in Indonesian cities between 1930 and 1960. Their findings can be found in appendix table A4.2. They found that cheap houses without brick walls, sometimes referred to as ‘indigenous houses’, had rents up to 20 to 30
62
| Accounting for Services
guilders. Very cheap houses in Medan, Bandung, Semarang, Malang and Surabaya brought in between 1.00 and 6.00 guilders. Dwellings of 1.00 and 2.00 guilders were usually meant for single coolies. Rents for middle-class residents were in the range of 20 to 80 guilders. Upper-class houses were 80 guilders or more. Table 2.13
Total output housing sector, 1930 Total number of dwellings
Total monthly rent paid
3,776,240
12,219,240
30,548,101
473,000
291,989
764,989
7,649,886
48,000
11,926
59,926
1,498,150
8,964,000
4,080,155
13,019,841
39,696,137
Average rent
Number of dwellings in Java & Madura
Cheap house
2.5
8,443,000
Middle-class
10
Upper-class
25
Total
Number of dwellings in Outer Islands
Yearly rent
476,353,644
Source: See text.
One problem, however, is that we have only fragmentary information on rents, whereas we know that rents fluctuated sharply (Colombijn & Barwegen 2005: 533). Moreover, the available data do not allow the construction of time-series for prices of different categories of houses. I therefore take 1930 as a base year. The population census enables us to divide the houses into three categories: 1) upper-class: European brick dwellings (48,000), 2) middle-class: Indonesian brick dwellings (352,000) and Chinese dwellings (121,000), and 3) cheap houses: others. Multiplying these figures with an average rent of 2.5 guilders for cheap houses, 10 guilders for middle-class houses and 25 guilders for upper class houses we arrive at an estimate of 27.0 million guilders per month for Java and Madura. Assuming that the same share of the Indonesians in the Outer Islands lived in brick dwellings (i.e. 4 per cent), we can extrapolate this figure for Indonesia as a whole. This results in a total annual rent paid of roughly 476 million guilders. This figure, however, also includes maintenance and other costs that are not considered value added. Therefore we have to find a value added/output ratio to arrive at an estimate of the value added of the housing sector in 1930. This will be taken from the Input-Output tables as discussed below.
The housing sector in Indonesia’s official national accounts While in the 1960s and 1970s value added for ownership of dwellings was still estimated as a fixed percentage of total gdp, this method changed in the 1980s. From then on gross value added was estimated based on household consumption expenditure, particularly expenditure on housing, for a base year. Gross value added at constant prices was obtained by using number of housing units as the extrapolator, while gross value added at current prices was estimated by inflating the gross value added at constant prices using the housing component of the consumer price indices as the inflator.
63
| National Accounting for Services in Indonesia
To convert the rental value of dwellings into value added we have to deduce the costs of maintenance and repair. From the i-o tables we derive these value added/ output ratios, presented in table 2.14. Apparently the ratio remains rather constant. It therefore seems justified to assume a value added/output ratio for 1930 of 85 per cent. Moreover, this ratio comes close to what Horlings (1995: 96) used for the Netherlands, namely 90 per cent. Table 2.14 1975
Housing in Indonesia’s i-o tables (in millions of Rupiah) Value added
338,289
Output
404,914
va/output ratio 1980
1985
83.5%
Value added
1,387,180
Output
1,559,815
va/output ratio
3,345,708
Output
3,846,750 87.0%
Value added
6,262,256
Output
7,200,695
va/output ratio 1995
88.9%
Value added va/output ratio
1990
Value added
23,081,658
Output
26,657,489
va/output ratio 2000
87.0%
Value added Output va/output ratio
86.6% 31,871,905 38,645,602 82.5%
Sources: i-o tables, various issues.
Estimates for the period 1950-2000 are based on the value added estimate of 2000, which is extrapolated based on the number of households in Indonesia. This constant price series is inflated by the housing component of the consumer price index to arrive at current price estimates. In this way, we obtain estimates which are consistent with our estimates for the colonial period. Moreover, these are an improvement upon the housing estimates made by bps, which assume housing to be a fixed percentage of gdp. The results are presented in appendix table A4.4.
2.4.5
Financial sector According to sna 93 the output of financial intermediation companies in banking, insurance services and pension fund services cannot be directly measured since such companies do not normally charge their customers for their services except for some minor incidental services. Banks earn their main source of income by the difference between the interest earned by providing loans and the interest paid on deposits. Pension funds and insurance companies accept contributions and invest them in order to pay their customers. Their output has to be measured indirectly.
The banking system in the Netherlands-Indies, 1900-1940 In the Netherlands-Indies a number of major banking institutions were active. These were the Java Bank, which functioned as the central bank, a few large com-
64
| Accounting for Services
mercial banks (i.e. Nederlandsche Handel-Maatschappij, nhm; NederlandschIndische Escompto Maatschappij, niem; and Nederlandsch-Indische Handelsbank, nihb), the Government Pawnshop Service, the savings banks and the Government Credit System, consisting of volksbanken (district or regency banks), desabanken (village banks) and desalumbungs (rice credit-banks). The barriers between the different classifications were actually quite large. Van Laanen, for example, notes that ‘the large banks formed a typical example of nonindigenous corporate enterprises active in Netherlands India. Their contact with the village community as a borrower, given the latter’s slender capital resources, inevitably remained extremely limited. In addition, the banks posed a considerable psychological barrier to potential indigenous clients’ (cei vi 1980: 31). The division is maintained in estimating the value added of the financial sector in the Netherlands-Indies between 1900 and 1940. The procedure adopted is the following. For estimating value added by the ‘big four’ (i.e. the Java Bank, nhm, niem and nihb) the financial report of the Java Bank is taken as a starting point. Although for the others annual reports are actually available, they have a number of short-comings: 1) they are often less detailed, 2) it is often hard to sub-divide income in the Netherlands from income in the Netherlands-Indies, and/or 3) it is hard to sub-divide income from banking and income from trade activities. Therefore I have chosen to use annual reports by the Java Bank, which give a very detailed statement of income and expenditures. Value added for the Java Bank is then divided by the share of credit extension of the Java Bank in total credit extension of the ‘big four’. For the other financial institutions, i.e. the Saving Banks, the Government Pawnshop service and the Government Credit banks, detailed financial accounts are available, which make it possible to estimate value added in a direct way. The data and results are summarised in appendix table A5.1.
Estimation methods for the financial sector, 1950-2000 In the 1950s data on profit and wages for banks and insurance companies were directly taken from the firms. Input from 70 banks, scattered over Indonesia, was obtained, while only a few insurance companies provided information. But based on information from the tax agency, estimates could be made about the income of these insurance companies (Neumark 1954; Muljatno 1960). From the 1960s onward a distinction is made between 1) banking, 2) insurance and 3) other financial services. Banking: In the late 1960s and 1970s income and expenditure statistics covering all state banks and the majority of private banks were collected and compiled by Bank Indonesia. On the basis of this information production accounts were compiled, imputing a service charge defined as interest received minus interest paid. In the 1980s and 1990s data on output and gross value added at current prices was collected directly from Bank Indonesia (bi). From 1989 onwards interest paid
65
| National Accounting for Services in Indonesia
for or received from bi Certificates and foreign loan commitment fees were not regarded as earnings or costs for private bank activities, but as part of activities of the Central Bank in its capacity as monetary authority. Insurance: From the late 1960s onwards the estimation of output and gross value added of insurance at current market prices has been based on data from the annual reports of insurance companies, obtained from the Financial Institution Directorate, Ministry of Finance. Gross value added of life insurance at constant prices has been calculated by extrapolating it by total number of policies. The extrapolation of the output of social insurance is performed by using the number of participants and the number of casualty insurance and the general wholesale price index. Other financial services: In the late 1960s and 1970s value added by village banks and rice credit-banks has been estimated at 50 per cent of interest received on the basis of norms observed in private banks, and of rough estimates of the wages and salaries bill. Constant and current price series have been prepared using indices of the number of debtors of village banks and of prices of agricultural products, both based on statistics compiled by bps. In the 1980s output and gross value added of other financial activities were calculated as a fixed percentage (5 per cent) of banks’ output and gross value added at current as well as constant prices. From the 1990s other financial services has been estimated using annual financial reports from different firms, such as pension funds, pawnshops, exchange traders, etc. A large discrepancy appears to exist between the national account estimates and the estimates in the i-o tables for the year 2000. Van der Eng (2005) attributes this difference to two changes of method. Firstly, since 2000 bps has been able to provide data that include secondary banks. Secondly, and more importantly, the implementation of the so-called Financial Intermediation Services Indirectly Measured (fisim) results in much higher estimates (Lynch 1998). In order to obtain consistent estimates this estimate from the 2000 i-o tables is not used. Since Input-Output tables usually act as an ‘anchor’ for both future estimates, and revisions of earlier national accounts (Van der Eng 2005: 245), I have followed his practice by taking the estimates in the i-o tables as starting point. The intermediary years are extrapolated weighted by total credit extension and inflated by the consumer price index. The results of this exercise are presented in appendix table A5.3.
2.4.6
Other services The remaining services are those for which income is difficult to measure on an annual basis due to lack of useful data. The services are the catering services, the so-called social and community services (such as, medical services, education, and
66
| Accounting for Services
entertainment), and other services (such as domestic servants). A very crude estimation procedure for this is assuming that the category ‘other services’ makes up 20 per cent of total value added in services. This is based on information from the i-o tables, which shows that on average this category indeed was roughly 20 per cent of total value added in services (see table 2.15). A different procedure can be followed as well. From the different population censuses information was taken on the number of people working in 1) hotels and restaurants; 2) community services; and 3) other services. It is assumed that those working in sub-categories 1) and 3) earn hardly more than a labourer; this wage is taken from economic historian Bas van Leeuwen (2007: 240-242). In sub-category 2) most people are probably rather well-educated since surgeons, teachers, etc. are part of this. Therefore it is assumed that they earn the equivalent of a craftsman’s wage, also taken from Van Leeuwen (2007: 240-242). This gives the benchmark estimates presented in table 2.16. Table 2.15
Other services in the i-o tables va other services
Total va
Total service va
(1)/(2)
(1)/(3)
(1)
(2)
(3)
1971
282,432
4,270,399
1,713,109
6.6%
16.5%
1975
894,419
13,694,242
4,816,366
6.5%
18.6%
1980
3,436,021
48,330,072
16,199,908
7.1%
21.2%
1985
8,287,882
97,645,877
38,824,139
8.5%
21.3%
1990
18,521,224
207,801,303
84,383,984
8.9%
21.9%
1995
50,377,773
535,564,814
232,727,515
9.4%
21.6%
2000
99,748,684
1,366,500,301
511,411,697
7.3%
19.5%
Sources: i-o tables, various issues.
These benchmark estimates are interpolated based on both government and private expenditure on education taken from Van Leeuwen (2007: 240-242). Constant price estimates are obtained by deflation using the consumer price index (cpi) from Van Leeuwen (2007). The results of this are presented in appendix table A6.1. The contribution of the service sector is obtained by adding up the estimates described in the preceding sections. This yields value added in both current and constant prices. In the next chapter the results of these calculations are used for a quantitative analysis of the Indonesian service sector.
Remarkably, this is almost exactly the share that Horlings found for the Netherlands in 1850 (Horlings 1995: 96-97)
67
| National Accounting for Services in Indonesia
Table 2.16
Value added by other services 1930
Hotel and restaurant
1971
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
354,753
468,193
752,435
2,255,866
877,188 1,200,927 2,875,664
938,491 1,282,011 1,353,099
2000
Social and community services
169,520
2,929,112
3,102,347
3,059,388
Other services
394,865 1,803,413 2,455,954 3,581,832 4,125,191 4,200,799
5,526,795
4,761,291
363,549
253,018
155,105
Unspecified
990,473
1,608,285 1,878,199
Current daily wage Labourer
0.41
9.70
87.81
642.26
1,323.24
1,954.31
4,961.50
12,354.99
Craftsman
0.88
42.02
406.13
847.78
1,517.83
4,299.49
7,869.97
19,597.58
99.54
21,829
Yearly income (in million fl/Rp)
219,034 1,340,042 3,293,699 6,949,871 17,782,329 46,929,120
Note: Assuming 320 working days a year. The wage for a labourer in 2000 is extrapolated by the growth in the wage of a craftsman. Sources: See text.
2.5
Assessing the reliability of the estimates It is also necessary to briefly assess the reliability of the estimates. Whereas it is rather difficult to make a precise estimate of the margin of error, it is possible to make a qualitative statement on the reliability for the individual series. Since the wider availability of detailed statistics on the different (service) sectors one would assume that the official estimates from bps, at least since the 1970s, have a lower margin of error than those for the colonial period. Therefore the year 1930 is chosen as a benchmark to assess the reliability of the estimates between 1900 and 1960. This margin of error is most probably higher than the one for the bps estimates and can therefore be considered a minimum reliability. Following Horlings (1995: 103-104) and Smits (1995: 60), Feinstein’s (1972: 2122) classification is used to divide service industries according to the quality of the estimates. A specific margin of error is assigned to each service sector. The following categories for the quality of the estimates are distinguished: A: Excellent, margin between 1% to 5% B: Good, margin between 5% to 15% C: Fair, margin between 15% and 25% D: Weak, margin between 25% and 50%
68
| Accounting for Services
The reliability of the sector as a whole is calculated by weighting these margins based on the percentage share of each industry in total tertiary value added in 1930. The results of this procedure for Indonesia are found in table 2.17. Railways, air transport and communication are all classified in category A, because the necessary data could be taken directly from the source. Moreover, the calculations do not require too many manipulations. In category B are grouped water transport, foreign trade, government and the financial services. For these industries information is relatively abundant, and the additional information provides enough coverage to state that the resulting picture is quite reliable. At the same time, however, some rather bold assumptions have to be made. Examples are kpm’s contribution to total value added in water transport, the development of the wage sum of the central government, and the ratio between value added and credit extension in the financial services. Estimates for domestic trade and housing are considered to be fairly reliable. For these sectors there is sufficient data to make estimates for benchmark years, although requiring some additional estimates and assumptions are required. The development of trade margins, for example, is assumed to remain constant. Furthermore, it is difficult to disaggregate the development of house rents to different types of dwellings.
Table 2.17 Quality of Indonesian service sector estimates, 1930 A
B
C
D
Transport - Rail
x
- Road
x
- Water
x
- Air
x
Communication
x
Trade - Foreign
x
- Domestic Government
x x
Housing Financial sector
x x
Others
x
Notes: Quality of estimates: A: Excellent, margin of error between 1% to 5%; B: Good, margin of error between 5% to 15%; C: Fair, margin of error between 15% and 25%; D: Weak, margin of error between 25% and 50%.
If these margins are weighted on the basis of the percentage share of each industry in total tertiary value added in 1930 the result is a margin of error between 15 and 25 per cent. This seems a very acceptable margin of error. Horlings (1995), for example,
69
| National Accounting for Services in Indonesia
estimated the reliability of his service sector estimates for the Netherlands, 18001850 to be between 15 to 30 per cent, whereas Smits (1995) for the period 1850-1913 came to a margin of error between 10 to 15 per cent. In addition, for the analysis of long-term economic development a certain margin in the absolute figures is not too problematic. As long as the estimation methods are consistent, the relative developments of the various industries will be of sufficient reliability.
70
| Accounting for Services
3
The Development of the Indonesian Service Sector
A quantitative analysis
3.1
Introduction Horlings (1995: 35) has argued that ‘historical national accounting is a useful tool for measuring economic growth, but cannot be more than a starting point for the analysis of economic development process’. Earlier Ole Krantz (1983: 131), a Swedish economist who worked on the Swedish historical national accounts, concluded that ‘processing national accounts data along methodologically proper lines can create new analytical purposes’. In the preceding chapter and the appendices the reconstruction of the Indonesian service sector within the framework of national accounts has been done. Now that we know how the statistics have been compiled, it is time for the analysis and searching for ‘new analytical purposes’. The aim of this chapter is to provide a first analysis of the quantitative development of the Indonesian service sector between 1900 and 2000. The underlying question that I try to answer is whether Indonesia has transformed in what Kuznets would call a ‘modern’ economy’, i.e. sustained increase in per capita income combined with rapid population growth and sweeping structural changes (Kuznets 1966: 1). According to Kuznets this process is the result of productivity gains in all sectors of the economy and an increase in the scale of production and consumption. Therefore in this chapter I analyse to what extent ‘sweeping structural changes’ took place in both the occupational structure and the production structure. Combining these elements enables us to assess what happened to labour productivity in the different sectors. The remainder of this chapter is organised as follows. First I discuss developments in the occupational structure. In section 3.3 changes in the economic structure are analysed. Section 3.4 examines the development of labour productivity in the service sector in a comparative perspective. Section 3.5 concludes.
71
| The Development of the Indonesian Service Sector
3.2
Developments in employment structure According to Kuznets (1971) an indicator of economic development is the share of agriculture in employment and output. He found that, as countries develop, the share of the labour force working in the agricultural sector falls. At first this is due to an increasing share employed in the industrial sector. In a later stage of development economic theory predicts that the share of employment in the service sector will start to rise. For Indonesia various data sources on the labour force are available. The most important are the population censuses, held in 1930, 1961, 1971, 1980, 1990 and 2000. Furthermore, inter-census surveys were conducted in 1976, 1985 and 1995. Moreover, since 1976/7 National Labour Force Surveys (Survai Angkatan Kerja Nasional, Sakernas) are conducted annually with the exception of the years 1981, 1983 and 1984. For 1905 a population count is available, which is considered of poor quality in absolute terms. However, it gives a fairly accurate picture of the relative distribution of the labour force. Together these data give a good picture of long-term developments in employment structure in Indonesia. Figure 3.1 summarises the findings on an aggregated level.
Figure 3.1 Occupational structure, 1905-2000 100% 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 1905
1930
1961 Agriculture
72
1971 Industry
Services
1980
1990
2000
Others
Note: The category ‘Others’ mainly consists of ‘activities not adequately defined’. The 1905 figures are adjusted for by-employment (see table 3.2). Sources: 1905: Jaarboek koloniën, 1909/10; 1930: Volkstelling 1930; 1961: Sensus Penduduk 1961; 1971: Sensus Penduduk 1971, Seri D; 1980: Hasil Sensus Penduduk 1980, Seri S; 1990: Hasil Sensus, Seri S. 2000: Statistik Indonesia. See also appendix 7.
| Accounting for Services
As can be seen in figure 3.1, only a small number of people were employed in the service sector at the start of the twentieth century. Not surprisingly, the majority of the labour force was occupied in agriculture. However, one has to be careful when analysing these 1905 data. To begin with, the phenomenon of by-employment, i.e having more than one job, was in this stage of development rather common (see also Alexander, Boomgaard and White 1991). Furthermore, the share of the category ‘others’ in 1905 was strikingly high at 17.1 per cent. This share is most likely not evenly distributed over the primary, secondary and tertiary sector, and probably biased towards the tertiary sector. Table 3.1
By-employment in 1905 population count Java & Madura
Outer Islands
Total
Agricultural workers Land-owners
3,787,564
1,744,040
5,531,604
341,110
152,007
493,117
Landless Renting land Wage labourers
2,599,557
252,934
2,852,491
Total
6,728,231
2,148,981
8,877,212
Non-agricultural workers 31,172
10,485
41,657
Local government
Central government A
322,640
46,219
368,859
B
26,910
10,074
36,984
Religious services
A
8,272
10,325
18,597
B
8,009
5,654
13,663
Teachers
A
10,166
4,415
14,581
B
5,993
2,379
8,372
Trade
A
187,070
24,317
211,387
B
455,202
52,967
508,169
Transport workers
A
63,144
14,853
77,997
B
54,044
12,661
66,705
Industry
A
145,609
46,489
192,098
B
384,891
72,190
457,081
62,866
49,835
112,701
Proto-industry Domestic servants Others
Total work force
100,181
10,057
110,238
A
483,698
63,431
547,129
B
1,625,204
149,013
1,774,217
9,482,712
2,524,296
12,007,008
Note: A: already included as agricultural worker (thus having a secondary job); B: not yet included. Source: Koloniaal Verslag 1907, appendix A.
73
| The Development of the Indonesian Service Sector
The 1905 figures provide some evidence for the prevalence of by-employment. Table 3.1 presents the raw data from this count. If we take all categories classified with an A (indicating already being included under agricultural labourers) and not including the category agricultural wage labourers, it turns out that 18.2 per cent of all peasants in Java and Madura had a secondary job. For the Outer Islands this figure was 9.8 per cent, while for the Netherlands-Indies as a whole it is 16.1 per cent. This was equal to 12.9 per cent, 8.3 per cent and 11.9 per cent of the labour force for Java and Madura, the Outer Islands and the Netherlands-Indies respectively. The question remains to what extent the issue of by-employment distorts the overall picture of the occupational structure. The statistics available from the 1905 population count allow us to take by-employment into account and adjust the figures accordingly. Table 3.2 shows the results of this adjustment when it is assumed that those classified as also employed in agriculture (category A in table 3.1) are assigned for 50 per cent of their time to agriculture and 50 per cent to their secondary job. Table 3.2 gives both adjusted and unadjusted figures. The unadjusted figures consider only the main occupation (category B in table 3.1). It shows that almost 74 per cent of the population in the Netherlands-Indies in 1905 had agriculture as their main occupation. However, if we correct for the fact that a significant number of agricultural workers also worked part of the time in non-agricultural sectors, this percentage declines to 68 per cent. Clearly, taking the phenomenon of by-employment into account does change the overall picture. Table 3.2
Consequence of by-employment in the 1905 population count 1905 (adjusted)
1905 (unadjusted)
No.
%
No.
%
8,162
68.0%
8,877
73.9%
666
5.5%
570
4.7%
1.
Agriculture, hunting, forestry and fishing
2.
Mining and quarrying
3.
Manufacturing
4.
Electricity, gas & water
5.
Construction
6.
Trade, hotels and restaurants
614
5.1%
508
4.2%
7.
Transport & communications
106
0.9%
67
0.6%
8.
Financial sector, real estate and business services
9.
Community, social and personal services
412
3.4%
211
1.8%
0.
Activities not adequately defined
2,048
17.1%
1,774
14.8%
Total
12,007
100.0%
12,007
100%
Note: Adjustment is done by assuming that those with a dual employment are assigned for 50% to agriculture and for 50% to their other profession. Source: Based on table 3.1.
74
| Accounting for Services
Peasant by-employment can be categorised into rural manufacturing industries, petty trade, transport and services. It is believed that the officials who compiled the work force data encountered considerable difficulties in ascertaining the actual number of peasants engaged in the first three categories, so they lumped together a large number of people employed by manufacturers, traders and transporters as being engaged in services or as activities not adequately defined (Fernando 1989: 158). Table 3.3 shows that manufacturing, mainly on a small scale, attracted around 100,000 people who were classified as peasants and as seasonal or part-time workers. Petty trading was slightly more important as secondary employment. Almost 165,000 traders, or 31 per cent of all traders, still had their roots in agriculture. Rural manufacturing and petty trading undertaken as by-employment were usually conducted on a small scale, centred around the peasant household. These activities required only a very small capital input, but consequently generated only a small cash income. Often this was just enough to meet the needs of families, but hardly enough to improve their social standing (Fernando 1989: 155). The transport sector was also a substantial source of by-employment, but because draught animals, carts and boats required a fairly large capital outlay this was beyond the capacity of most peasants. I believe that the extent to which by-employment distorts the overall picture of occupational structure depends very much on the stage of economic development. In initial stages of development most households will depend solely on agriculture. The first steps of economic diversification will be taken alongside the existing agricultural occupation. Only in the later stages of development will a majority of labourers find full-time wage employment outside agriculture; at this point, consequently, by-employment will decrease. Moreover, workers in the non-agricultural sector may have a secondary job in a different sub-sector of the non-agricultural sector. This is probably more often found in later stages of development as a survival strategy of the urban poor. A similar argument is made by Australian labour economist Chris Manning (1998) concerning under-employment in Indonesia. He argues that with economic development under-employment is expected to decline, because of a shift from family work and self-employed jobs in agriculture into non-agricultural wage employment. At later stages of development more flexible work arrangements may lead to an increase in those working less than a full-time working week (Manning 1998: 189, footnote 28). In the specific case of Indonesia I would argue that not taking by-employment into account does change the picture. Evidence suggests that before 1890 distortion of the occupational structure through by-employment is negligible. Arminius (1889) presented an account of the hours worked for the head of the family. Allowing for one day off per week it turns out that in all three cases the men worked more than 7.5 hours per day throughout the entire year. Clearly, this does not leave much time for a secondary job. For the 1970s the evidence is mixed. One study found that
75
| The Development of the Indonesian Service Sector
76
| Accounting for Services
6,581
4,604
1,693
30,278
100,382
Pasuruan
Besuki
East Java
Java
27
29
41
27
14
28
83
24
15
24
27
22
30
31
48
31
20
86
Source: Koloniaal Verslag 1907, appendix A.
6,560
18,318
Kedu
Surabaya
6,968
Semarang
Kediri
5,981
Banyumas
10,840
11,881
Pekalongan
Madiun
22,946
West Java
4,010
3,176
Cirebon
47,158
9,373
Priangan
Central Java
6,416
Batavia
Rembang
3,981
63,691
42,532
8,545
13,455
10,057
6,848
3,627
12,075
2,292
2,070
3,873
197
3,643
9,084
1,598
1,713
1,739
4,034
63
67
82
59
66
73
86
60
82
77
56
61
71
63
61
59
40
88
164,270
38,895
2,552
9,462
8,647
5,886
12,348
65,317
7,957
20,979
14,013
10,158
12,210
60,058
14,199
25,591
8,592
11,676
No. of peasant % of all man- No. of peasant % of all No. of peasant manufacturers ufacturers transporters transporters traders
Residency
Banten
Peasants engaged in by-employment in 1905, by category of employment
Table 3.3
31
24
37
20
16
20
49
27
31
35
19
36
21
45
47
48
25
81
% of all traders
185,309
27,183
702
18,557
5,044
1,925
955
35,451
1,960
6,679
16,446
1,901
8,465
122,675
52,993
23,086
9,327
37,269
21
11
5
19
7
4
52
9
17
8
51
1
10
49
66
22
37
95
No. of peas% of all in ants in services services
126,206
67,282
1,020
17,566
34,852
8,809
5,035
26,424
5,515
6,446
8,654
2,113
3,696
32,500
3,614
3,816
23,380
No. of peasants in unspecific work 1,690
19
22
13
17
27
16
84
10
15
8
25
3
17
30
16
14
51
% of all in unspecific work 14
male heads of agricultural households worked more than 8 hours per day, and their wives worked even longer (Edmundson and Sukhatme 1990: 265-266). A different study found that, in ten villages in Java in 1980-81, of 2,393 persons 1,297 were solely employed in agriculture, 665 were employed in the non-agricultural sector and 431 had mixed employment (Kasryno 1986: 294). This means that 18.0 per cent of the total labour force in these villages was engaged in by-employment, which is roughly equal to the proportion in 1905. The 1930 census is considered to be of quite a high standard (cei xi 1991: 28-29). However, the category ‘activities not adequately defined’ was still large, with 9.6 per cent, and information to correct for by-employment was missing. Nevertheless it is believed that the 1930 employment figures give a fairly accurate picture of the occupational structure. Therefore it is promising that this census seems to support the findings for 1905: agriculture was by far the most important sector with more than two-thirds of the labour force. During the first decades of the twentieth century there seems to be a moderate shift to the manufacturing sector. The number of people employed in the service sector did not change much, nor did the composition of the occupational structure within the service sector. Data on employment are unavailable for the period between 1930 and 1961. The ‘excellently’ prepared census planned for 1940 was abandoned when the Second World War broke out (Van de Graaff 1955: 147). This war and the subsequent struggle for independence seriously reduced data collection. Consequently, it was not until 1961 that a new population census was held. The results of this census reveal some interesting features. Not surprisingly, employment in agriculture was still dominant. What is striking, though, is that also in relative terms employment in this sector was even larger than in 1930. At the same time the share of employment in industry decreased from 11.0 to 7.9 per cent. In 1961 the service sector absorbed 18.3 per cent of the total labour force. This growth of service sector employment is in part probably merely partly a statistical reality, since the category ‘activities not adequately defined’ dropped from to 9.6 per cent in 1930 to 1.9 per cent in 1961. Still this increase is partially real, mainly because of a rapidly growing bureaucracy. This was a consequence of Sukarno’s policy of ‘Socialism a la Indonesia’ which resulted in an expanding central government. Because of this pattern, in which the share of the labour-intensive or traditional sectors in total output increased while that of the modern, capital-intensive sectors declined, Anne Booth (1998: 70-72), an authoritative historian of the Indonesian economy, calls this a period of structural retrogression. After the 1961 population census we see some signs of what Kuznets would call modern economic growth. The share of agricultural employment decreases to 45.3 per cent in 2000. It is striking that between 1980 and 1990, a period that was characterised by relatively slow economic growth and a re-orientation of the economy, this share remained almost constant. Another remarkable feature is that the share of industry in total employment increased only slowly from 7.9 per cent in 1961 to 13.7 per cent in 1990 and 16.9 per cent in 2000.
77
| The Development of the Indonesian Service Sector
The case of Indonesia reveals two important findings. Firstly, in an early phase of development service sector employment is already significant and higher than industrial employment. Secondly, growth in service sector employment is not preceded by growth in industrial employment, but rather coincides with or is even followed by it. This contradicts the Fisher-Clark hypothesis of economic development, which states that there is a shift in employment first from agriculture to industry and in a later phase to services (Fisher 1935, 1939; Clark 1940). This argument can be further strengthened if we look at annual growth in employment. Looking at the growth rates of the different sectors in table 3.4, we see that during the twentieth century service sector employment growth is constantly high. Particularly until 1971 this growth is higher than in industry. When industrialisation takes off from the mid-1970s onwards, growth in industrial employment becomes slightly higher than that in service sector employment.
Table 3.4
Annual growth in employment by sector, 1930-2000 Agriculture
Industry
Services
Labour force
1930-1961
1.7%
-0.4%
3.2%
1.5%
1961-1971
0.7%
4.5%
4.5%
2.1%
1971-1980
1.2%
5.4%
5.8%
2.5%
1980-1990
2.1%
5.8%
4.0%
3.3%
1990-2000
-0.4%
4.1%
3.8%
2.1%
Source: Appendix 7.
Horlings (1995) found that the Netherlands did not follow the ‘sectoral model’ (i.e. shifts in employment from primary to secondary to tertiary) either. He argued that, ‘instead of transfers of labour from agriculture into industry and then into services, the structure of the Dutch economy became more advanced without significant growth of industry’ (Horlings 1995: 107). This scenario seems to hold for its former colony as well. In the case of the Netherlands, Smits attributed this development path to important linkages between agriculture and the service sector, especially distributive services (Smits 1990: 90). The story in Indonesia is rather different. It is not so much linkages between agriculture and services that is responsible, but rather the failure of the industrial sector to absorb the large group of labourers pushed out of the agricultural sector and trying to find work in the urbanising regions. A large number of these labourers ended up in low-productivity service sectors. This will be further elaborated upon in chapter 5.
78
| Accounting for Services
3.3
Value added in the service sector
3.3.1
Economic structure Table 3.5 shows the development of the sectoral contribution to service sector gdp based on the reconstruction of the service sector as discussed in chapter 2. A number of interesting conclusions can be drawn from this table. Firstly, trade was by far the most important service sector at the beginning of the twentieth century and remained so during colonial times. A possible explanation for this is that the Dutch considered the Netherlands-Indies a ‘win-gewest’ (profit-generating territory), which should produce for the international market. After independence, however, trade remained the leading service sector, although its contribution to total service sector gdp fell from 56 per cent in 1970 to 40.4 per cent in 2000. Secondly, transport and communications, of relatively small importance in 1900, developed gradually, contributing 14.1 per cent to the service sector gdp in 2000. An important factor behind these developments was the technological changes that took place in this sector especially during the first half of the twentieth century. Whereas in 1900 transport took place either by sailing vessel, train for long distances or by becak, dogcart or other forms of traditional transport for shorter distances, in 1940 one could also choose between motor vessels, air transport, automobiles or buses. Nevertheless, the sector’s contribution to the total service sector gdp was reduced between 1939 and 1950. This was mainly due to a fall in rail transport and stagnation in growth of road transport. These developments were linked to the Japanese occupation and the subsequent war of independence between 1945 and 1949 which both caused severe damage to the infrastructure.
Table 3.5
Composition of the service sector, 1900-2000 (current prices) Transport & Government communications
Trade
Financial sector
Housing
Other services
1900
7.0%
9.3%
46.1%
0.6%
35.1%
1.8%
1910
8.4%
8.8%
47.4%
1.2%
31.8%
2.5% 2.6%
1920
10.8%
6.9%
51.1%
1.6%
27.1%
1930
16.4%
12.6%
43.0%
2.2%
20.7%
5.1%
1939
16.4%
9.0%
45.4%
1.6%
23.9%
3.7%
1950
6.1%
22.5%
51.9%
0.9%
18.1%
0.5%
1960
11.1%
22.0%
52.6%
1.1%
12.4%
0.8%
1970
15.3%
8.7%
56.0%
2.8%
15.4%
1.8%
1980
12.5%
11.0%
53.7%
5.0%
9.1%
8.8%
1990
14.6%
12.7%
45.5%
10.6%
7.9%
8.8%
2000
14.1%
17.9%
40.4%
7.1%
8.3%
12.2%
Source: Author’s calculations from appendices 1-6.
79
| The Development of the Indonesian Service Sector
Figure 3.2 Economic structure, 1900-2000 (in constant 1993 prices) 100% 90% 80% 70% 60% Services
50%
Industry Agriculture
40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 1900
1910
1920
1930
1940
1950
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
Source: Van der Eng 2002.
Figure 3.3 Economic structure, 1966-2005 (current prices) 100% 90% 80% 70% 60% Services
50%
Industry Agriculture
40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 1966
80
1970
1974
1978
1982
Source: Timmer and De Vries 2007.
| Accounting for Services
1986
1990
1994
1998
2002
Thirdly, the development of the financial sector is remarkable. The size of the financial sector remained very small until the 1970s, but rapid growth resulted in a contribution of this sector of 10.6 per cent in 1990 and dropping to 7.1 per cent in 2000 as a result of the Asian crisis. Fourthly, the role of the housing sector is striking, contributing between 20.7 and 35.1 per cent to total service sector gdp during the colonial period. This can be explained by the fact that this sector grew very gradually, mainly linked to growth in population. Housing is a necessity good, like agricultural products. Even with low levels of income, this sector therefore made up a relatively large share of total service sector gdp between 1900 and 1939. What can we say about the share of the service sector to total gdp? The reconstruction of Indonesia’s national accounts is an ongoing research project. At this moment estimates in current prices are not available yet for agriculture and manufacturing. Therefore only some rough measures can be applied to get an idea of the importance of the service sector relative to total gdp. First of all we can use the constant price estimates from Van der Eng (2002). Using constant price series for the purpose of analysing economic structure is inferior, because it does not take into account relative price changes. Nevertheless, it does give a hint of the importance of the service sector in the total economy (figure 3.2). From 1966 to 2005, it is possible to provide further evidence about the economic structure of the Indonesian economy, since for this period current price estimates are available for the entire economy (figure 3.3). Figures 3.2 and 3.3 show that during the twentieth century the service sector contributed roughly 40 per cent to total gdp. Apparently, the service sector was already large in the early stages of development. Clearly, this is inconsistent with the linear stage theories (Fisher 1935, 1939; Clark 1940).
3.3.2
Growth in the service sectors Instead of looking at the structure of the service sector, examining the growth paths of the different service sectors also reveals some interesting patterns. Figures 3.4 and 3.5 show the development of value added in the different transport and communications sectors and of the different service sectors respectively. Figure 3.4 illustrates that the transport and communications sector as whole grew steadily, although with small drops in the early 1920s, the early 1930s and the turbulent 1960s. What also becomes clear from this figure is that the different sectors of which the transport and communications sector consists show widely varying development paths. Initially railway transport was the leading sub-sector comprising more than half of the total value added in the transport and communications sector. Growth
For further details on the project see: http://www.iisg.nl/indonesianeconomy/
81
| The Development of the Indonesian Service Sector
Figure 3.4 Development of value added in transport and communications, 1900-2000 (in millions of fl/Rp at constant 1993 prices) 100.000.000 10.000.000 1.000.000 100.000 10.000 1.000 100 1900
1910
1920
1930
1940
1950
Railways Water transport Communication
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
Road transport Air transport Total transport & communication
Source: Author’s calculations from appendices.
Figure 3.5 Development of value added in the service sector, 1900-2000 (in millions of fl/Rp at constant 1993 prices) 1.000.000.000
100.000.000
10.000.000
1.000.000
100.000
10.000 1900
1910
1920
1930
1940
Total transport & communication Financial sector Trade
82
Source: Author’s calculations from appendices.
| Accounting for Services
1950
1960
1970
1980
Government Ownership of dwelling Total
1990
2000
stagnated in the early 1920s, however, due mainly to increasing competition from road transport. Nevertheless, average annual growth in road transport between 1915 and 1930 was 6.2 per cent. Communications also grew rapidly during the colonial period, with annual average growth of more than 13 per cent in the period 19001930. Developments in water transport were steady, although less impressive. Air transport was possible only beginning in 1928, with the foundation of the Koninklijke Nederlandsch-Indische Luchtvaartmaatschappij (knilm). As this sub-sector was beginning from scratch, it is not surprising that growth rates were high, while the amount of value added generated in this sector was only small. After independence developments in rail transport remained problematic. Though it was the leading sector in 1900, it kept losing ground, becoming the smallest contributor to transport and communications gdp after 1970. Growth is even negative for the period 1960-1973. Air transport, on the other hand, kept growing at impressive rates. Road transport recovered from the cessation of growth during the 1930s and grew continuously from 1950 onwards. A take-off in growth in water transport was reined in after the war of independence by on-going conflicts between the kpm and the Indonesian government. This culminated in the expulsion of kpm from Indonesian waters in December 1957. However, after 1965 growth picked up and the growth spurt between 1968 and 1973 was especially impressive. Developments in communications were relatively moderate, although on average annual growth in this sector was still 5.2 per cent. Together with rail transport, however, it is the only sector for which growth rates are lower after independence than during the colonial period. Figure 3.5 illustrates the growth paths of the sectors of which the service sector consists. On average, annual growth in the service sector was 2.2 per cent between 1900 and 1939, 6.1 per cent between 1950 and 2000 and 3.6 per cent for the whole period. This is somewhat higher than growth in agriculture, and a little lower than growth in industry. But, as we have seen before, different subsectors followed different development paths. To begin with, developments in the financial sector were very erratic. The sector was of only minor importance during the colonial period, with heavily varying growth rates. It took until the late 1960s before growth in this high value added sector took off. The double-digit growth that followed was very impressive, but unfortunately the sudden drop caused by the Asian crisis in 1998 was just as impressive. Growth in transport and communications has already been discussed above. The role of government was especially important in the period 1973-1986. Large oil revenues provided the means for the government to navigate the economic development of Indonesia. Large investments were made in programmes in the education and public health sectors; a large part of the increase also went on salaries of civil servants (Booth 1998: 187). Ownership of dwellings grew gradually with an average annual growth rate of 2 to 3 per cent. This growth was mainly based on the growing population requiring more houses with only a portion due to improvements in the housing conditions.
83
| The Development of the Indonesian Service Sector
84
| Accounting for Services
4.0
11.2
1.2
2.9
2.8
1.9
1.3
Government
Financial sector
Ownership of dwellings
Trade
Total service sector
Agricultureb
Industryb 3.8
1.3
-0.1
0.7
1.7
-3.5
-3.5
1.0
2.7
3.6
4.3
1.9
5.7
-0.3
8.4
6.7
5.7
5.1
15.7
3.6
19501960
0.5
0.9
-0.4
0.6
1.9
-1.4
-6.2
-0.1
-5.9
9.7
7.3
6.2
-9.0
19601967
13.5
6.0
10.7
12.2
1.9
32.8
4.3
12.1
10.2
28.9
23.2
8.9
-2.2
19681973
9.4
3.7
11.5
9.2
11.9
16.5
16.7
10.0
6.5
18.5
3.1
14.1
1.8
19731982
7.7
4.3
6.3
3.9
6.2
13.4
6.0
8.0
6.7
6.7
7.8
8.6
8.1
19821986
11.3
3.2
10.5
10.7
10.8
17.1
7.4
7.8
7.7
8.2
9.4
7.3
9.6
19861997
Notes: a: Air transport started only in 1928 with the foundation of the knilm; b: only for the period 1900-1998. Sources: Agriculture and Industry from Van der Eng (2002); other sectors: Author’s estimates from appendices.
3.3
1.6
3.0
2.8
1.4
3.9
4.3
-2.5
4.9
Total transport & communications 6.2
-3.3
Air 13.4
-0.9
15.6
1.4
-0.4
communications
-0.7
Water transport
12.7
-5.0
19301939
10.5
6.7
Road transport
2.1
19151930
transporta
7.5
19001915
Average annual sectoral growth rates, 1900-2000
Railways
Table 3.6
0.0
0.0
-8.4
-13.4
-11.2
-28.8
10.6
3.1
8.4
-13.4
-3.4
4.1
3.7
19972000
2.6
1.6
2.2
2.4
1.4
4.9
2.3
3.6
10.0
0.1
7.3
2.4
19001939
6.3
3.2
6.1
5.7
5.0
10.8
4.9
7.2
5.2
9.8
7.8
10.0
2.3
19502000
3.8
2.1
3.6
3.3
2.2
6.0
4.2
5.3
7.6
3.8
7.3
1.4
19002000
As mentioned before, the trade sector was and is the most important service sector in Indonesia, although the economic growth that Indonesia experienced brought other service sectors to development as well. Remarkably, growth in the trade sector between 1900 and 1939 was limited to an average annual growth of 2.4 per cent. After independence, especially after Suharto came to power, average annual growth in the trade sector has increased to 5.7 per cent. This increase is mainly due to the linkages with industry. No industry can exist without some distribution network. When a good is produced, someone needs to bring it to the market. Therefore it is not surprising to see that growth in trade coincided with the industrial development that has taken place in Indonesia since the 1970s. The developments in the service sector are once more summarised in table 3.6. This table shows the average annual growth rates for the different service sectors. Arguments to support the periodisation in that table are the following: 1930 was the start of the world-wide depression, which affected Indonesia. In 1967/1968 Suharto came to power. This marked not only a change in political leadership, but also a shift in mission, namely to economic development (Dick et al. 2002: 194). The year 1973 saw the first oil boom; the second followed in 1978. The period 1982-1986 is characterised by recession and the re-orientation of the Indonesian economy. This resulted in a resurgence of the economy which was brought to a sudden end by the Asian crisis in 1997.
3.4
Labour productivity The employment figures from section 3.2 can be combined with the service sector estimates in section 3.3. This makes it possible to draw some conclusions about developments in labour productivity. The labour productivity estimates are presented in table 3.7. Since the population count of 1905 is considered of poor quality in absolute terms, resulting in an under-estimation of the number of people in most sectors, a correction had to be made to prevent an over-estimation of labour productivity. Therefore it was assumed that the labour force participation rate was equal to that in 1930 and 1961, namely 34 per cent. Assuming that the 1905 population count does give a reliable picture of the relative distribution of the labour force across sectors, we arrive at better labour productivity estimates. From 1930 onwards estimates are quite reliable. They are based on a well-conducted population census combined with careful estimates of value added in the different sectors. A number of interesting observations can be made.
I used the formula: Labour force participation rate (=34 per cent) x population in 1905 x relative sectoral share of employment in 1905.
85
| The Development of the Indonesian Service Sector
To begin with, labour productivity in the service sector turns out to be, as expected, higher than in agriculture. Labour productivity in industry, however, is, except in 1930, significantly higher than in the service sector, as much as four times higher in 2000. Table 3.7
Labour productivity in Indonesia’s service sector, 1905-2000 (in 1993 Rp per labourer) Agriculture
Industry (excl. oil and gas)
Trade
Transport & communications
Total service sector
Total labour productivity
4,145.7
2,887.8
1,515.1
2,158.8
1,919.9
1905
825.0
1930
978.0
3,288.9
3,894.5
2,924.9
3,612.9
1,428.3
1961
814.2
3,690.8
2,410.6
3,227.2
1,699.4
1,210.2
1971
996.8
3,877.7
1,982.0
3,233.9
1,480.0
1,403.9
1980
1,337.2
5,260.3
3,428.8
5,125.7
2,633.8
2,254.9
1990
1,530.8
7,010.2
4,391.2
6,266.3
4,117.1
3,313.2
2000
2,009.4
9,472.5
3,255.7
6,165.0
4,213.0
4,341.5
Note: gdp estimates in 1993 constant prices. Employment figure for 1905 arrived at by assuming a labour force participation rate equal to that in 1930 and 1961, namely 34 per cent, and that the relative contribution of the 1905 enumeration is reliable. Sources: Employment figures: see appendix 7; gdp estimates: for Agriculture and Industry: Van der Eng (2002). Other sectors: Author’s estimates.
Mulder (1999) came to different results in his study on the service sector in Brazil, Mexico and the United States. He found that productivity in services was indeed highest at the beginning for all three countries, just as in the case of Indonesia. Over the course of time, productivity levels in services and other sectors converged, because of slower growth in productivity in services. In Indonesia such a convergence in productivity cannot yet be found. Labour productivity in manufacturing in Indonesia is still significantly higher than in the other sectors. This suggests that the shift in labour to services that has been taking place raises the overall performance less than does a shift to manufacturing. These findings support similar conclusions drawn by Alexander and Booth (1992), and suggest that the service sector in Indonesia accounts for a much greater share of the non-agricultural labour force than was the case in countries such as France, Italy, Japan or Taiwan at a comparable stage of development (Alexander and Booth 1992: 285). The findings above are strengthened if we look at growth rates in labour productivity. As can be seen in table 3.8, growth in labour productivity in industry was especially high in the 1970s, when industrialisation took off in Indonesia. The decrease in labour productivity in trade between 1961 and 1971 and again between 1990 and 2000 is probably because the labour surplus as a result of the crises that took place in these periods was mainly absorbed in this sector.
Similar findings were reached by Maddison (1980), Ohkawa (1993) and Syrquin (1986).
86
| Accounting for Services
Growth in labour productivity in transport and communications has been quite steady. This can probably be attributed to the technological developments in this sector and the investments the government has been making in infrastructure. Table 3.8
Average annual labour productivity growth (in percentages), 1905-2000 Agriculture
Industry (excl. oil and gas)
Trade
Transport & communications
Total service sector
Total labour productivity
1905-1930
0.68%
-0.89%
1.21%
2.57%
2.15%
-1.18%
1930-1961
-0.59%
0.37%
-1.54%
0.32%
-2.40%
-0.53%
1961-1971
2.04%
0.50%
-1.94%
0.02%
-1.37%
1.50%
1971-1980
3.32%
3.45%
6.28%
5.25%
6.61%
5.41%
1980-1990
1.36%
2.91%
2.50%
2.03%
4.57%
3.92%
1990-2000
2.76%
3.06%
-2.95%
-0.16%
0.23%
2.74%
Source: Based on table 3.7.
With the inputs so far it is possible to estimate the contribution of structural change to productivity growth. This method is usually called the shift-share method and was introduced by labour economist Solomon Fabricant (1942). The shift-share methodology is still popular in decomposing aggregate productivity growth (see Syrquin 1984 for an overview; for more recent applications, see Van Ark 1996; Mulder 1999; Timmer and Szirmai 2000; Lains 2004). The formula is:
where lp denotes labour productivity, Y output, L the labour force and S the share of labour in each sector. The difference in aggregate labour productivity levels at time 0 and t can be written as:
The first term on the right-hand side represents the intra-sectoral productivity growth, and corresponds to that part of the productivity change which is caused by productivity growth within the sectors. The second term is referred to as the static shift effect, and represents the effect of the change in sectoral employment shares on overall growth. This effect is positive when labour moves to branches with relatively high productivity levels. The third effect measures the dynamic shift effect, and is positive when labour shifts to sectors which improve their productivity per-
87
| The Development of the Indonesian Service Sector
formance. The sum of the second and third term is referred to as the total structural change effect. Table 3.9
Decomposition of labour productivity growth, 1930-2000 1930-1961
Labour productivity growth per year
-0.53
Intra-sectoral growth Structural change
1961-1971 1.50
1971-1980 2.53
1980-1990 3.92
1990-2000 2.74
81.7
55.9
75.3
75.1
59.4
- Total
18.3
44.1
24.7
24.9
40.6
- Static
21.4
55.4
14.5
16.6
35.1
- Dynamic
-3.2
-11.3
10.1
8.3
5.6
Source: Author’s calculations from table 3.8.
The results of this exercise are given in table 3.9, which shows that between 1930 and 1961 labour productivity growth was negative, and that this could be mainly attributed to a fall in intra-industry labour productivity. The structural change, or in this case the structural retrogression, accounted for 18.3 per cent of the fall in labour productivity. Between 1961 and 1971 productivity growth was limited, with only 1.5 per cent average annual growth. Structural change accounted for 44.1 per cent of this labour productivity growth, although it has to be noted that the dynamic effects were negative. Between 1971 and 1980 labour productivity growth is mostly explained by productivity growth within sectors. Only in the final decade of the twentieth century do we again see signs of structural change in which the static effect is dominant. This means that a shift of labour took place to more productive sectors, not accounting for the changes in productivity in these sectors.
3.5
Concluding remarks According to Kuznets (1966) the process of ‘modern economic growth’ is accompanied by important structural changes. The aim of this chapter was to assess whether these changes have taken place in Indonesia by looking at developments in occupational structure, economic structure and labour productivity. With regard to occupational structure, it was shown that the share of agricultural employment decreased slowly, and even increased between 1930 and 1961. Moreover, in an early phase of development, service sector employment was already significant, and far more important than industrial employment. Growth in service sector employment was not preceded by growth in industrial employment, but rather coincided with or was even followed by it. This challenges the linear development theory or the Fisher-Clark hypothesis. The economic structure of the service sector has undergone significant changes. At the beginning of the twentieth century, trade was the most important service sector, followed by housing. This reflected two characteristics of the Indonesian
88
| Accounting for Services
economy. Firstly, a rather low level of income resulted in a relative large share spent on a necessity good such as housing. Secondly, the relatively large trade sector was a consequence of the colony’s role as win-gewest for the Netherlands. After independence, housing lost in importance, and the trade sector contributed less to total service sector gdp, resulting in a more diversified structure. Nevertheless, the trade sector and the transport and communications sector remained the service sectors that contributed most to total gdp. Labour productivity in Indonesia’s service sectors has not been very impressive. Although compared to agricultural productivity it is both higher in level and growing more rapidly, it cannot keep up with developments in the industrial sector. It seems that Indonesia’s major service sectors are still the traditional sectors, which have relatively low value added. Looking at these three measures we see a clear transformation of the economy during the twentieth century, especially during the 1970s. Nevertheless, a decisive transition to a modern economy with sweeping structural changes has not yet taken place in Indonesia. Agriculture is still the largest sector, in terms of both employment and income. Moreover, within the service sector most employment and most income are still in the more traditional service sectors such as transportation and trade, which were already quite important in the colonial period. Therefore we shift our attention in the next two chapters to these apparently key service sectors in the economic development of Indonesia.
89
| The Development of the Indonesian Service Sector
4
ROADS TO RICHES?
Transportation and economic development in Indonesia
4.1
Introduction The thousands of islands, often separated by vast distances, that comprise the Indonesian archipelago stretch out over approximately 5,000 kilometres from west to east and almost 2,000 kilometres from north to south. The land area of the country, approximately 1.9 million square kilometres, is spread over more than 13,000 islands. Such a geographical setting requires an efficient transportation network for both political and economic reasons. From a national accounting perspective, the transportation sector usually shows only small variations over time in the contribution to gdp. Krantz (2000) notes that the needs of transport as expressed in economic terms have been relatively constant during both the industrialisation and the modernisation processes. As we saw in the previous chapter, this pattern also holds for Indonesia where the contribution of transport to gdp varies between 2 and 7 per cent. However, this does not mean that no major changes have occurred. On the contrary, some modes of transport have more or less disappeared while others have grown significantly in importance. Another important point that needs to be stressed is that contribution to gdp is not always the best measure on which to assess the importance of an economic sector. In the case of transportation it can be argued that an efficient transport infrastructure is a necessary but not sufficient condition for economic growth. As transportation and development expert Wilfred Owen states: ‘Many factors contribute to economic and social progress, but mobility is especially important because the ingredients of a satisfactory life, from food and health to education and employment, are generally available only if there is adequate means of moving people, goods and ideas.’ (Owen 1987: xi) In the extreme case of no transportation network at all (or infinite transportation costs), local specialisation is impossible and autarky is the only possible economic outcome. If this assumption of infinite transportation costs is loosened it can be shown that transportation developments can be a catalyst for economic growth. Owen (1964, 1987) has shown that many developing countries lack year-round mechanised transport. Movement in these countries is often still by unreliable,
91
| Roads to Riches?
high-cost, labour-intensive methods. On the other hand, in advanced economies transportation has developed rapidly with the advent of cheap, mass air travel, high and rapidly rising levels of personal mobility based on car ownership, and containerisation of general freight. All this has encouraged new levels of internationalisation in industry and commerce. For those favoured by these developments the world has shrunk to village scale (Hilling 1996: 1-2). The aim of this chapter is to show this role of transportation in economic development for the specific case of Indonesia during the twentieth century. It will be demonstrated that the transportation sector not only fundamentally changed during this century, but also that declining transport prices over time have enabled further economic development in Indonesia. The remainder of the chapter is organised as follows. Section 4.2 discusses theoretical foundations for the relation between transportation and economic growth. In section 4.3 developments in Indonesia’s transportation system are discussed. Section 4.4 concludes.
4.2
Transportation and economic growth: theoretical framework In the development literature, transportation is usually considered indispensable for economic growth. This idea is treated as an axiom: more efficient transportation modes and networks lead to higher economic growth. Although it is intuitively appealing, intuition is not scientific evidence. In order to obtain a better understanding of the relation between transport and economic growth we need a theoretical framework. Fogel’s theory of social savings and the spatial price equilibrium model provide us with a theoretical foundation.
4.2.1
Fogel’s social savings In his seminal work Railroads and American Economic Growth Nobel Prize winner Robert Fogel (1964) challenged the axiom of indispensability commonly attributed to the railways. Simply showing that more goods and passengers were transported tells only part of the story. It indicates that production in this sector increased. It does not show, however, to what extent it contributed to or, put differently, facilitated economic growth in other sectors. In this respect Fogel states: ‘Evaluation of the axiom of indispensability thus requires not only an examination of what the railroad did but also an examination of what substitutes could have done. Railroads warrant the title of indispensability only if it can be shown that their incremental contribution over the next best alternative directly or indirectly accounted for large part of the output of the American economy during the nineteenth century.’ (Fogel 1964: 10)
92
| Accounting for Services
Fogel proposes a way to test this ‘incremental contribution’, namely by the concept of ‘social savings’. He argues that if a certain tonnage of goods moves from one primary market city to a secondary market city carried out by some combination of transportation means at some definite costs, then, with enough data, one could determine both this cost and the alternative cost of shipping exactly the same bundle of goods from the primary to the secondary market in exactly the same pattern without the railway. The difference between these two estimates is the social savings attributable to the railway in the inter-regional distribution of agricultural products. In formula this would give: Social Savings = Cost of transportation without railways – Cost of transportation with railways A word of caution is due here. The true social savings would have been smaller, because society would have adapted to a situation without railways. For example, production might have shifted or improvements in water transport might have taken place. Such adjustments would have reduced the loss in national income. However, due to data constraints, it is not possible to measure this reduced loss in national income caused by the absence of the railways (Fogel 1979). Despite these shortcomings, his method is widely used in the study of economic history. The concept of social savings is used by Fogel to compare the incremental contribution of railways compared to other means of transportation. In this chapter I propose to use the concept to analyse intertemporal improvements in transportation. In other words, what are the social savings of transporting a comparable bundle of goods over the same distance in, for example, 1930 compared to 1990. Or in a formula: Social Savings = Cost of transportation (t1) – Cost of transportation (t2) This would be similar to searching for periods in which the consumer price index increases significantly faster or slower than transportation costs. In these cases there is also a change in the social savings. One has to be careful in interpreting results, though, since an increase in prices can also be due to improvements in quality, speed, safety and reliability of transportation.
4.2.2
A spatial price equilibrium model As mentioned before, in the literature transportation is often considered to be indispensable for economic growth. Another interesting approach to show this is by
For an overview of early literature see O’Brien 1977, 1983. For recent examples see Leunig 2006 and Summerhill 2005.
93
| Roads to Riches?
applying a Spatial Price Equilibrium (spe) model. With this model it can be shown that the benefits of infrastructure arise in another market, resulting in more welfare (Lakshmanan et al. 2001). Figure 4.1 gives a representation of spe. The left panel shows the demand and supply curves for a certain good in market A. In autarky equilibrium is given by YA=QA, where Y is demand and Q is supply, and the local market price PA would prevail. The right panel shows demand and supply for the same good in a different market, market B. Now suppose that transport cost between the two markets is equal to t, which is smaller than the autarky price difference between the two markets. It is then profitable and efficient to transport goods from the lower-price region to the higher-price region. In our figure it is assumed that PA > PB and that PA-PB > t.
Figure 4.1 Model of the benefits of transport M arket A
DA
M arket B
SA SB
PA a
b
c d t PB
e
f
g h
DB
2 2 QA QA = Y A Y A
Y B 2 Y B =QB
QB 2
Source: Lakshmanan et al. 2001: 142.
In the after-trade equilibrium (denoted with superscripts 2) in market A, because of the lower price, supply declines to QA2 and demand rises to YA2 leading to excess demand. In market B the opposite occurs. The higher price raises supply to QB2 and The spatial price equilibrium (spe) model was first presented in an article by Samuelson (1952). Later it was further developed by among others Takayama and Judge (1971) and Takayama and Labys (1986).
94
| Accounting for Services
lowers demand to YB2 with excess supply as a result. This makes market A a net importer and market B a net exporter. Now we can answer the question of how large the benefits of transportation are. This can be done with the concepts of consumer and producer surplus. In a competitive market consumers only pay the going market price. Consumers who are willing to pay more benefit from buying at the market price. Their well-being is increased. Thus, consumer surplus is the increase in economic well-being of consumers who are able to buy the product at a market price lower than the highest price that they would be willing and able to pay for the product (Pugel 2004: 22). For producers a similar argument exists. Producers receive the going market price, while producers who would have been willing to supply at a lower price benefit from selling at the market price. This net gain is called producer surplus, the increase in the economic well-being of producers who are able to sell the product at a market price higher than the lowest price that would have drawn out their supply. In market A consumer surplus increases by area a+b+c+d, while producer surplus decreases by area a+b. In market B consumer surplus declines by area e+f while producer surplus rises by e+f+g+h. The ultimate benefits of being able to trade are equal to area c+d+g+h. It is not difficult to see that the lower the transportation costs (t) the larger the net gain in economic welfare (areas c+d and g+h). This gain can mainly be attributed to the increased local specialisation which it enables. But it should be stressed that the benefits are not equally distributed. In market A the consumers gain whereas the producers lose, while the opposite occurs in market B.
4.2.3
Other theoretical foundations In an interesting survey of the benefits of transportation Lakshmanan et al. (2001) mention various effects that transportation can have on the economy. Firstly, the construction of infrastructure itself creates employment and generates income during the construction phase. On the other hand, if such a project is financed by a tax increase or an increase in interest rates due to government borrowing on the capital market, this would have a negative impact on consumption and investment which would counter the initial positive effect. Secondly, as shown above by the spe model, improvement in infrastructure leading to lower transport costs implies tendencies towards local specialisation and larger trade flows. If factors of production are mobile and respond to differences in factor payments substantial shifts in economic activity may occur. This effect is reinforced if economies of scale occur. Thirdly, lower transportation costs can have ‘reorganisational benefits’, such as market expansion, spatial concentration and tighter scheduling. As a result transport infrastructure leads not only to larger trade flows, but also to a more transportintensive way of organizing production.
95
| Roads to Riches?
Fourthly, Lakshmanan et al. (2001) argue that it is conventional wisdom that improvements in transportation lead to better-functioning labour markets. More workers can be recruited within reasonable commuting distances, leading to a reduction in unemployment and vacancies due to spatial frictions, and a better match between the demand and supply side of the labour market. In the long run the effects are more diffuse. Urban economic theory predicts that a decrease in transport costs will lead to a shift in settlement patterns towards a more diffuse pattern of land use (Fujita 1989). This will lead to an increase in commuting distances. There is indeed overwhelming evidence that commuting distances in many countries have increased considerably, mostly because of voluntary movement of households relocating to another dwelling. Lakshmanan et al. conclude on this basis that it is probable that the welfare-improving effects for households are larger than the productivity-improving effects for firms. Fifthly, better transportation leads to an increase in the number of suppliers and demanders in the market. This can have a favourable effect on consumer welfare because it reduces the probability of collusive behaviour between suppliers. Similar arguments are also made in a United Nations report on the relationship between transport and economic development (United Nations 1999). In this report it is argued that better transport facilities lower production costs in three ways. To begin with, improved transport lowers the delivered costs of inputs to the producer. In a study of two groups of villages in Bangladesh, Ahmed and Hossain (1990) found that output was 31 to 42 per cent higher in the group with better access to transportation. They attributed this difference principally to the lower delivered cost of fertiliser. Furthermore, importance of continuity of input supply increases as the degree of industrial sophistication increases. Finally, improved transport can broaden the labour pool to which a production facility has access. Besides lowering production costs, better transportation also raises producer prices. Clearly lower transportation costs result in lower marketing costs. Moreover, irregular and infrequent transport services require purchasers to hold high levels of stock to ensure that they can guarantee a continuous supply to their customers. With better transportation a producer can lower inventory costs, thus saving money. In this way the risk of spoilage of perishable goods is reduced. Another advantage of improved transportation is that it attracts further investments. In a study by Creightney (1993) it was found that for countries in the early phases of development good-quality infrastructure was preferable to tax incentives for attracting foreign investments. If we add to this improved productivity the possibility of economies of scale it is clear that the transport sector can serve as a catalyst for economic development. A schematic representation of the potential of the transport sector is provided in figure 4.2.
For a Dutch case study, see Rouwendal and Rietveld 1994.
96
| Accounting for Services
Source: United Nations 1999: 21.
97
| Roads to Riches?
In c re a s e d in v e s tm e n t in tra n s p o rt
Im p ro v e d tra n s p o rt
Low er s p o ila g e a n d h ig h e r d e liv e re d q u a lity
R educed in v e n to rie s
Low er m a rk e tin g c o s ts
R e d u c e d in p u t c o s ts
B e tte r a c c e s s to s k ille d la b o u r
M o re re lia b le s u p p ly o f in p u ts
H ig h e r p ro d u c e r p ric e s
Low er p ro d u c e r c o s ts
G re a te r in v e s tm e n t
H ig h e r p ro d u c tiv ity
E c o n o m ie s o f s c a le in p ro d u c tio n s
Im p ro v e d p ro fita b ility
In c re a s e d o u tp u t
M o re p ro fita b le tra n s p o rt s e rv ic e s
G re a te r d e m a n d fo r tra n s p o rt
Figure 4.2 Schematic representation of the relationship between transport and economic development
We have to bear in mind though that transport does not automatically lead to development. In this respect Gauthier (1970) distinguishes between three possible relationships between transport and development. A positive effect, where an innovation in transport is directly and demonstrably responsible for an expansion in economic activity; a permissive effect, in which transport does not itself stimulate economic growth but is such that is does not inhibit such growth when other stimuli are operating; and a negative effect where the returns on investment in transport are less than from the same investment in direct production.
4.2.4
Evolution of transport networks This section concludes with the discussion of a model published by Taaffe, Morrill and Gould (1963), which offers a theoretical approach to transport network evolution in a Third World context. Although relatively old, this model is still very popular in the transport economic literature. The model is summarised in figure 4.3. In phase A a series of separate trading posts and minor ports along the coast is established. These act as points of interaction where locally produced or traded goods are exchanged for imports or money. In phase B the hinterland is penetrated by trading routes, bringing the traders into contact with new groups of people and different resources. Taaffe et al. argue that this is the most important phase, since later phases typically evolve along these penetration lines (Taaffe et al. 1963: 506). Phase C comprises the extension of these hinterlands through the construction of feeder routes from the trunk lines, while phase D is characterised by the interconnection between the different local systems and the emergence of intermediate urban centres (N1 and N2). In phase E a process of selection starts, because the increasingly integrated networks reduce the need for many ports. Often this means that trade is increasingly concentrated in the largest city or the one with the most favourable port facilities and location. Phase F consists of the development of national trunk-line routes or ‘main streets’. These developments to a large extent explain how transport networks evolved in Indonesia with the first trade settlements on the North coast of Java and from there penetrating the hinterlands, with Jakarta and Surabaya as main ports. Already in the early nineteenth century a ‘main street’ avant-la-lettre was constructed with the Great Mail Road (Jalan Raya Pos) connecting Batavia and Surabaya. In the next section these general theories are used to explain and analyse developments in the transport sector in Indonesia.
For an excellent article on the Jalan Raya Pos and its impact see Nas and Pratiwo 2002.
98
| Accounting for Services
Figure 4.3 Transport network evolution
99
Source: Taaffe et al. 1963: 504.
| Roads to Riches?
4.3
Transport developments in Indonesia, 1900-2000 With the general considerations in mind concerning the relationship between transport and economic development, this section will discuss the developments in the different transportation sectors, namely water transport, road transport, rail transport and air transport, in Indonesia during the twentieth century.
4.3.1
Water transport 1900-1940: monopolisation profits Water transport during the colonial period was characterised by two main features: firstly, the increasing importance of motor vessels, and secondly the leading role of the Koninklijke Paketvaart Maatschappij.
Table 4.1
Registered merchant fleet in the Netherlands-Indies, 1890-1939 (in number and net tonnage (1,000m3)) Java & Madura
Outer Islands
Netherlands-Indies Steamships and motor vessels
Nr.
Ton.
Nr.
Ton.
Nr.
Ton.
Sailing vessels Nr.
Total
Ton.
Nr.
Ton.
1890
1,108
150
691
85
78
77
1,721
158
1,799
235
1900
1,468
166
929
123
116
113
2,281
176
2,397
289
1907
1,640
286
1,155
168
190
247
2,605
207
2,795
454
1920
2,518
516
3,278
90
224
470
5,572
136
5,796
606
1930
2,555
731
3,698
108
327
696
5,926
143
6,253
839
1939
1,506
748
2,798
138
378
702
3,926
184
4,304
886
Note: 1907 is chosen instead of 1910. In 1908 minimum tonnage to qualify for registration was significantly reduced. This severely blurred the figures. It was only in 1915 that the registration figures resumed a more normal pattern (cei ix 1989: 42). Figures are in net tonnage. The net/gross tonnage ratio is approximately 60:100 (cei ix 1989: 70). Source: cei ix 1989: table 1.
Table 4.1 clearly shows that steamships and motor vessels became increasingly important in the merchant fleet. In 1890 only 4.3 per cent of all ships were steamships or motor vessels, although they already comprised almost 33 per cent of total capacity. This increased to 8.8 per cent and 79.2 per cent respectively in 1939. The increase in the importance of steamships and motor vessels did not mean that sailing vessels became unimportant (Sulistiyono 2001: 204). Although from a national accounting perspective their contribution to gdp was marginal, they formed an important link in the transportation chain. The sailing vessels, or prahu, functioned as feeder ships, and thus provided important transport services complementary to those of modern shipping (Dick 1975: 69). For example, between Banjarmasin and East Java, where the kpm had no regular line and in 1921 carried only 200 lasts,
100
| Accounting for Services
other vessels carried 10,200 lasts of which 8,700 lasts were carried by prahu (Dick 1987b: 106). Other interesting findings from table 4.1 are the increasing size of steamships and the continually higher average tonnage figure for Java compared to the Outer Islands. This is probably due to the more rapid modernisation of the Java merchant fleet under influence of the large-scale expansion of steam-packet services, which were concentrated in Java (cei ix 1989: 19). The second feature of water transport in colonial Indonesia was the importance of the kpm. Between 1891 and 1916 the number of kpm vessels increased from 28 to 93, while their gross tonnage increased from 82,000 to 450,000 m3 (an average annual growth of 7.1 per cent), and the number of miles sailed from 752,000 to 2,899,000 (5.6 per cent per annum). Between 1916 and 1939 the number of ships increased from 93 to 134, the gross tonnage from 456,000 to 907,000 m3 (3.0 per cent per annum) and the number of miles sailed from 2,899,000 to 4,111,000 (1.5 per cent per annum). Tonnage of the kpm ships amounted between 60 and 80 per cent of the total tonnage of steam and motor vessels and between 50 and 60 per cent of the tonnage of the total Netherlands-Indies merchant fleet (cei ix 1989: 25 and table 6: 70-71). The monopolisation of water transport by kpm was aided by policies pursued by the colonial government (À Campo 1992: 85). The monopoly enabled kpm to use profits from the main trunk lines to cross-subsidise regular scheduled services to all corners of the archipelago (Dick 1987a: 1 and 130). Dick shows how in some instances the company explicitly aimed at aggressively competing prahu shipping. In some areas kpm interfered in trade ‘not to make short-term profits, but to reduce the profitability of prahu shipping to the point where new prahu would no longer be built and the fleet would gradually diminish by attrition’ (Dick 1987b: 107). Due to the Depression of the 1930s kpm’s strategy to push competitors out of the market became less effective. The dramatic decline in commodity prices led to a sudden boom in demand for cheap transport. Prahu shipping benefited, which resulted in a sharp increase in the prahu share of trade in the early 1930s (figure 4.4). In most regions the prahu share reached a peak some time between 1931 and 1933 and then began to decline. Dick (1987b) attributes this decline to a reversal of the process, with kpm regaining its dominant position. The monopolisation of water transport by kpm is also apparent if we look at the average transport costs in constant prices. These average costs are calculated as follows. Firstly, revenue from passenger and freight transport respectively is taken from kpm’s annual reports. Then the number of passengers and the amount of freight is taken from De Boer and Westerman (1941, appendix 10 and 11). Dividing
A last was an elastic unit whose weight and volume dimensions varied according to the commodity. As a rough rule of the thumb, 1 last =1 cubic metre = 1 ton (Dick 1987b: 106, footnote 2).
101
| Roads to Riches?
revenue by the volume indices and subsequently dividing them by a cpi (Van der Eng 2002) gives us average transportation costs in constant prices.
Figure 4.4 Share of prahu shipping in local trade, 1929-1939 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 1929
1930
1931
Northwest Sulawesi
1932
1933
Gulf of Bone
1934
1935
Southeast Sulawesi
1936
1937 Selayar
1938
1939
Nusa Tenggara
Source: Dick, 1987b: 112-113.
Figure 4.5 shows that both passenger and freight transportation costs decreased quite significantly between 1891 and 1911. The outbreak of the First World War apparently affected transportation rates in the Netherlands-Indies as well. From 1920 onwards transportation costs started to rise. Two phenomena may contribute to rising transportation costs: higher input prices or higher profits. In the case of kpm this last explanation is more plausible, resulting from the monopoly position it had. This is underlined if we look at the profits as percentage of total revenue. Between 1916 and 1939 this ratio was on average 31.2 per cent. It is interesting to note that already in the early twentieth century there was some discussion about kpm’s monopoly. In public discourse the board of kpm repeatedly denied to have a monopoly, but in internal correspondence the term ‘our monopoly’ was widespread. Maritime historian J. à Campo (1992: 271) rightly concludes that it is hard to deny kpm’s monopoly position. If we connect these findings with the theoretical framework of Fogel and the Spatial Price Equilibrium Model we conclude that kpm played a key role in connecting different regions of the archipelago, creating a nation-state and enabling economic development in these regions. The monopoly enabled kpm also to include remote, sparsely populated areas within its network by compensating losses incurred on
102
| Accounting for Services
these lines by higher freight tariffs on other lines (cross-subsidies) (Koopmans, Sonneveld and van Winden 1994: 8; Dick et al. 2002: 99).
Figure 4.5 kpm transportation costs, 1891-1939 (in constant 1993 prices) 1,800 1,600 1,400 1,200 1,000 800 600 400 200 0 1891
1895
1899
1903
1907
1911
1915
Freight
1919
1923
1927
1931
1935
1939
Passages
Sources: Author’s calculations.
Dick adds to this that kpm’s operations were ‘trade-creating’ (Dick 1987a: 11). kpm developed non-contract services to ports and areas which were potentially of commercial significance, but which at the time did not yet justify regular contract lines. Nevertheless, from an economic perspective one could argue that the high and increasing transportation costs since the 1920s, resulting from kpm’s monopoly position, slowed down economic growth, or at least lowered welfare as visualised in the spe model in figure 4.1. However, the wide network of routes, high quality and reliability of services, and great care in cargo-handling, with claims being settled promptly and fairly, were highly valued. Therefore Dick stated that ‘traders do not seem to have shown much dissatisfaction with the costs of shipping by kpm’ (Dick 1987a: 12). Moreover, kpm was not completely free in setting its rates. As a government check upon the monopoly proposals for rate increases had to be submitted to the Department of Economic Affairs for approval. Since increases also meant greater government expenditure for shipment of the large tonnage of official cargoes, this was not just a formality (Dick 1987a: 158).
103
| Roads to Riches?
Figure 4.6 The kpm shipping network, 1891 and 1940
Source: De Boer and Westermann 1941: appendix 1.
1945-1965: competition and institutional damage The period immediately following the Pacific War and the declaration of Indonesian independence was turbulent, and developments in water transport were no exception. Mainly due to the severe losses incurred by kpm during the war, maritime transport was affected by urgent demands and acute tonnage shortages. Whereas in 1939 the kpm fleet comprised 136 ships, at the end of the war only 26 remained, scattered across the Pacific and Indian Oceans. The initial impulse was to reconstruct the fleet completely and to resume all former operations. After the war, the colonial government stated that priority should be given to the reconstruction of shipping ‘above any other single sector of the economy’ (À Campo 1998: 13). At the end of 1946 kpm operated twenty-two regular lines, a number that doubled within five years, while total route mileage rose from 46,000 to 160,000 geographical miles (À Campo 1998: 6).
104
| Accounting for Services
After the refusal by kpm to set up a mixed enterprise, jointly owned by kpm and the Indonesian government, in 1952 the latter established a shipping company of its own, pelni (Pelayaran Nasional Indonesia). Its ultimate aim was to usurp the role of kpm in interisland and short-distance sea transport. pelni started operations with thirteen ships but within five years its fleet had grown to thirty-eight ships totalling 38,000 tons. As most vessels clearly were too small for long-distance shipping, pelni incurred heavy losses, which contrasted painfully with kpm’s continuing profits (À Campo 1998: 26; Dick 1987a: 17). Freight rates were set by the government and pelni tended to conform to kpm’s levels – undercutting would increase losses and overcharging would reduce its market share – but it did not enter into arrangements on routes or schedules. pelni usually consigned new ships to existing kpm routes without prior notification, which resulted in a sub-optimal allocation of tonnage. Contacts at a personal level were pleasant, but the Indonesians did not accept offers for advice or support. ‘They prefer to take their own line. In the Asian perception consultation [with] the Dutch seems to amount to loss of face’ (À Campo 1998: 27). It had become sufficiently clear that cooperation between pelni and kpm was not the Indonesian goal. In the Indonesian cabinet political sentiments increasingly over-ruled economic considerations, much to the despair of pragmatic and competent Indonesian officials (À Campo 1998: 27). kpm had little choice but to continue its pre-independence policy of internal contraction and external expansion. kpm went on reducing its Indonesian activities by laying off personnel, transferring dispatch from its own agencies to commissioned agencies and contracting out other activities. Unprofitable lines were discontinued, while the government no longer allowed kpm to operate foreign charters on regular lines. Despite lavish profits, hardly any investment was made in Indonesia. Investments in new ships that kpm did make were for trade outside Indonesia (Dick 1987a: 15). The kpm-pelni competition rested on the opposing interests of a large profitable ‘colonial’ firm and a poorly performing national company. With the substitution of kpm by pelni being only a matter of time, kpm’s attitude towards the Indonesian economy became ‘to get as much out of it [as it could] as long as it lasted’ (À Campo 1998: 29). A recurrent issue of conflict was rising costs and raising rates. The relative price stability of the early 1950s was spoiled by inflationary measures taken by successive cabinets. kpm insisted that rising costs must be offset by rising freight rates. Regulations, however, made it nearly impossible to pass costs on to shippers. In the meantime there was an increasing urge in politics for nationalisation of the kpm. The development of a national shipping industry through the nationalisation of kpm had been considered since 1945, but Indonesian politicians never succeeded in mapping out a viable procedure. Proposals for a joint venture failed because of kpm’s insistence on majority ownership. The idea of nationalisation had not been dropped altogether, however, and was revived after the unilateral renuncia-
105
| Roads to Riches?
tion of the 1949 round-table agreements by the government of Indonesia in February 1956. Strained by social unrest and political tensions, the situation was becoming rather paradoxical. The Indonesians wanted to get rid of kpm, yet feared its departure. kpm wanted to stay, but was prepared to relocate. As both sides were acting adversely to their perceived interests, the relationship was inherently unstable. Sunar Suraputra, president of the Central Shipping Authority (Pepuska) characterised the situation as ‘[a]n equilibrium in which both are equally strong, or rather both are equally weak, an equilibrium lacking a solid foundation’ (À Campo 1998: 33-34). kpm calculated that strong measures against it would do much more harm to Indonesia than to itself. At least until the middle of 1957 kpm remained confident that the Indonesian government assessed the situation the same way. Still, it took two important precautionary measures. Firstly, it insured its entire fleet with Lloyds against seizure. Secondly, in November all captains received a sealed letter containing instructions in case of emergency to be opened when they received a coded message. The breakthrough was triggered by a wave of political protest and trade union action. Defeat of a motion calling upon the Netherlands to relinquish sovereignty of Dutch New Guinea brought matters to a head. On 1 December 1957 Dutch aircraft were prohibited from landing, Dutch-language newspapers and magazines were banned, and an official national strike was called for the following day (Dick et al. 2002: 184). On 3 December 1957 local trade union representatives occupied kpm’s head office in Jakarta. Having lost effective control the directors immediately instructed all ships to flee to foreign ports; thirty-four escaped, but twenty-nine were held in Indonesian ports by crews or military guards. Another eleven were seized on the high seas. The Indonesian government, which most probably had approved and, according to some, even coordinated the action, legalised the takeover in retrospect (Dick 1987a: 24). On 7 December kpm held the government responsible, and gave ‘notice of abandonment’ of forty ships to Lloyds in London. The huge claim for 114.5 million guilders, which would have to be paid if the ships were not released within four months, was a great shock that might have serious consequences for Lloyds, as British ambassador McDermott made clear to the Indonesian government. In February 1958 Lloyds sent its representatives to Jakarta for direct negotiations with the Indonesian government. They put the Indonesians under great pressure by threatening to raise insurance rates or even to withdraw all ship insurance, which would have raised food prices or even caused shortages. Prime Minister Djuanda decreed that all ships be released on 20 March 1958, while forbidding kpm to re-enter interinsular shipping. All ships had to leave Indonesian waters on short notice (À Campo 1998: 34-35).
Penguasaan Pusat Kapal-kapal (Pepuska) was established in September 1950 with the aim of developing an Indonesian shipping business by constructing, selling and hiring ships for Indonesian companies. In 1952 Pepuska was taken over by pelni.
106
| Accounting for Services
In the period immediately following the expulsion of the kpm it seemed that water transport was not as negatively affected as might have been expected. The vacuum that had been created was filled quite swiftly (Ali 1966: 35). Within two years total shipping capacity was at a level comparable to that before the expulsion of kpm (tables 4.2 and 4.3). In table 4.2 kpm is compared to pelni and in table 4.3 the magnitude and productivity of the total Indonesian interisland fleet are summarised. Table 4.2
Inter-island freight (in 1,000 m3) and productivity of kpm and pelni, 1950-1960 kpm
pelni
Transported goods
Total gross tonnage
Productivity
1950
3,610
176.6
20.4
1951
4,079
185.9
21.9
1952
3,835
178.5
21.5
1953
3,630
170.1
21.3
1954
3,312
184.9
17.9
Transported goods
Total gross tonnage
Productivity
20.5 36.8 437.7
51.1
8.6
1955
3,176
187.3
17.0
720.2
36.4
19.8
1956
2,999
190.5
15.7
968.4
46.3
20.9
1957
1,006.4
58.0
17.3
1958
808.2
89.7
9.0
1959
1,254.7
134.6
9.3
1960
1,514.9
154.2
9.8
Note: Productivity is measured by dividing transported goods by total gross tonnage of the fleet. Source: Statistical Pocketbook of Indonesia, 1958 and 1961.
Table 4.3
Tonnage, cargo and productivity of inter-island fleet, 1957-64
Year
Tonnage owned (in 1,000 tons)
Tonnage chartered (in 1,000 tons)
Total tonnage
Total cargo
Fleet productivity
pelni
Private
Total
pelni
Private
Total
1957
30.5
21.1
51.6
18.9
28.3
47.2
98.8
in 1,000 tons n.a
n.a
1958
57.7
28.0
85.7
38.4
24.8
63.2
148.9
n.a
n.a
1959
80.8
58.8
139.6
61.1
47.2
108.3
247.9
2,797
11.3
1960
93.4
71.1
164.5
77.6
56.1
133.7
298.2
2,713
9.1
1961
108.8
125.7
234.5
116.1
60.9
177.0
411.5
3,027
7.4
1962
132.1
113.2
245.3
100.8
43.5
144.3
389.6
2,281
5.9
1963
154.0
158.9
312.9
90.2
43.9
134.1
447.0
2,800
6.3
1964
144.2
191.5
335.7
29.6
20.6
50.2
385.9
3,300
8.6
Note: Productivity is measured by dividing transported goods by total gross tonnage of the fleet. Source: Dick 1987a: 28.
However, the most important finding here is the significantly decreasing productivity of water transport after kpm was expelled from Indonesia. Where kpm had
107
| Roads to Riches?
productivity rates, as measured by tons of goods transported divided by total gross tonnage, of around 20, this fell to levels below 10 for the total Indonesian fleet after 1960. One could attribute this decline to a fall in trade. This is not the case, however. Between 1957 and 1962 domestic trade grew from 10.3 million tons to 11.0 million tons (Sulistiyono, 2003: 237). Dick (1987a: 26), quoting an unpublished un report, attributes the decline to five main factors: 1) Instead of the normal time of three weeks, pelni ships were by 1963 spending three months and by 1966 four months out of commission in docking and repair. 2) About four months were spent idle in port awaiting cargo handling, fresh water supplies, bunkers or clearance. 3) Even when cargo was being handled the rate was about 60 per cent lower than previously normal rates. 4) Sea time was about 10 per cent greater because of fouled bottoms and the disappearance or failure of navigational aids. 5) Load factors had fallen from an acceptable 60 per cent to about 35 per cent because of excessively large and badly routed ships. This shows that it was not so much lack of capital in the form of ships that slowed down developments in the water transport sector. It was lack of organisational knowledge and skills combined with the elimination of efficient networks between traders and shipping companies. These were lost as a result of the troubled nationalisation of this important sector. Or in other words the expulsion of kpm meant severe institutional damage (Marks forthcoming). Dick notes that ‘by eliminating the kpm the Indonesian Government achieved a symbolic political victory, but at the very high cost of destroying the inter-island transport system’ (Dick 1987a: 25). And although shipping capacity was swiftly recovered, the knowledge and efficient networks were not replaced, leading to a highly inefficient and unreliable water transportation sector and therefore disintegrated markets. Interisland shipping services that had facilitated economic growth for years now became an obstacle for further development. This had repercussions in other economic sectors. These findings directly link the troublesome economic de-colonisation and the deterioration in macro-economic performance during the 1960s. This link, I believe, is not sufficiently acknowledged in the literature concerning the economic development of Indonesia. Dick is a notable exception, although he actually blames kpm’s monopoly position rather than the difficult de-colonisation process: See Bertocchi 1994, Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson 2001, and Bertocchi and Canova 2002 for the relation between de-colonisation and economic growth. Divergent opinions in Lindblad 2006, Sulistiyono 2003: 251-252, and Sulistiyono 2006: 123. They conclude that economic slowdown only started to gain ground in the early 1960s, while the take-over and nationalisation of Dutch firms took place in 1957/1959.
108
| Accounting for Services
‘It is unfortunate that the aggressive use of monopoly power by the kpm denied Indonesians access to modern shipping until 1941. [...] This undoubtedly contributed to the problems encountered after Independence and must be set against the very substantial economic benefits brought by the kpm.’ (Dick 1987a: 11)
1965-2000: moving forward In the mid-1960s the Indonesian government became aware that inefficiencies in inter-island shipping threatened the Indonesian economy in general. Minister of Sea Communication Ali Sadikin stressed the importance of rationalising domestic shipping (Sulistiyono 2003: 262). Because of simplified licensing procedures shipping companies had sprung up ‘like mushrooms in the monsoon’ (Dick 1987a: 27). Measures taken towards this end did not have immediate effect, however. The political and economic instability also affected developments in inter-island shipping. For example, the tight monetary policies which the government adopted to control inflation reduced the general level of economic activity. Table 4.4 shows how between 1962 and 1967 both freight and passenger transport shrank significantly.
Table 4.4
Table 4.5
Cargo and passengers carried by pelni, 1962-1967 Cargo (m3)
Passengers
1962
1,448,200
408,351
1963
1,041,036
388,442
1964
803,288
343,314
1965
678,268
266,353
1966
425,000
353,817
1967
606,572
221,657
Source: Sulistiyono 2003: 266.
The Indonesian merchant fleet, 1968-2000 Total fleet in grt
Oil tankers in grt
1968
711,500
133,134
1970
642,530
87,736
1975
859,378
87,576
Bulk carriers in grt
General cargo Container ships in grt in grt
Other types in grt
578,366 480,640
74,154
16,881
643,917
111,004
1980
1,411,688
164,341
78,199
963,640
1985
1,936,420
481,268
128,255
912,355
58,888
205,508 355,654
1990
2,179,000
578,000
138,000
931,000
77,000
455,000
1995
2,779,387
745,985
205,305
1,204,936
60,623
562,538
2000
3,394,000
812,000
335,000
1,433,000
92,000
722,000
Note: grt is an abbreviation for gross register tonnage and measures the total internal volume of a vessel. Ships of 100 grt and over. Source: United Nations, Review of Maritime Transport.
109
| Roads to Riches?
Table 4.6
Average annual growth in grt and loaded cargo, 1968-2000 loaded cargo
grt 1968-1970
-3.3%
1970-1975
5.0%
6.1%
1975-1980
8.6%
3.9%
1980-1985
5.4%
1.6%
1985-1990
2.0%
11.8%
1990-1995
4.1%
9.6%
1995-2000
3.4%
-2.3%
1970-2000
4.5%
4.6%
Source: Author’s calculations from table 4.5, and Statistical Yearbook Indonesia, various issues.
After 1970 inter-island shipping was brought back on a moderate, although far from impressive growth path. Between 1970 and 2000 the total Indonesian merchant fleet increased from 642,530 gross rate tonnage (grt) to 3,394,000 grt, or on average 4.5 per cent annually. The composition of the fleet did not change much. Growth in loaded cargo was more volatile. However, average annual growth for the entire period was at 4.6 per cent, quite similar to that of the merchant fleet. That growth in water transport was only moderate is a consequence of improvements in road transport (discussed below) that have shifted general cargo to road transport. This is especially the case for short distances. At the same time, road/ ferry links have enabled road transport to erode what formerly was the preserve of sea freight (Dick and Forbes 1992: 272). Examples are ferries across the Bali Strait between Ketapang (Java) and Gilimanuk (Bali), and across the Sunda Strait between Merak (Java) and Bakahuni (Sumatra). These developments shifted freight between Java and Bali and between Java and Sumatra from water to road. Road transport is often preferred by traders because door-to-door consignment eliminates doublehandling.
Table 4.7
Productivity in inter-island shipping, 1993-1997 Number of ships
dwt
Tons of cargo
Productivity
1993/94
978
1,050,286
18,667,282
18
1994/95
979
3,646,058
60,683,540
17
1995/96
1,109
4,046,649
66,521,296
16
1996/97
1,393
4,215,945
79,794,447
19
Source: Department of Communications 1999: 18.
As brought forward in the discussion on Fogel’s social savings theory from the viewpoint of performance, it is not so much growth but rather efficiency and low transportation costs that matter. Regulation measures resulted in a rather competitive market which was quite easy to enter. For example, under the second Five-Year devel-
110
| Accounting for Services
opment plan (Rencana Pembangunan Lima Tahun, repelita ii) the emphasis was on replacement and expansion of the fleet. To this end the government established a National Fleet Development Corporation (Pengembangan Armada Niaga Nasional, pann). pann provided both rehabilitation loans and new and second-hand dry cargo tonnage. Dick (1985) notes that this modernisation and expansion of the inter-island fleet led firms in the inter-island shipping industry to engage in both price and nonprice competition. As can be seen in figure 4.7, this increased competition resulted in a significant fall in water transportation costs. From 1971 onwards transportation costs in constant prices were at least half of those in 1939. Moreover, productivity was also quite high. In 1982 the majority of shipping firms had a productivity of more than 10 tons of cargo per year per deadweight ton of capacity (Dick 1985: 101). Yet this was still only half of kpm’s productivity in the 1950s (see table 4.2). In the mid-1990s productivity had increased to levels comparable to that of kpm in the 1950s. However, interisland transport continued to be hampered by irregularity in service, which from a development perspective is rather important (Leinbach and Chia 1989: 125).
Figure 4.7 Water transportation costs, 1900-2000 (in constant 1993 prices)
1900
111
1910
1920
1930
1939
1971
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
Note: Figures are arrived at by dividing revenue by a constructed volume index of passengers and freight transported for the period 1900-1940 and loaded and unloaded cargo for the period 1950-2000 (see appendix). This outcome is divided by the cpi to arrive at constant price estimates. Source: Author’s calculations.
| Roads to Riches?
4.3.2
Rail transport 1900-1940: rise and fall The first railways in Indonesia date back to 1867, when a 26 kilometre section from Semarang to Tanggung (Central Java) was opened to traffic. This line was operated by the private Nederlandsch-Indische Spoorweg Maatschappij (Netherlands-Indies Railway Company, nism). Initially the development of the railway network was rather problematic, however. It proved extremely difficult for private companies to raise enough capital, and therefore the government was obliged to offer additional financial assistance other than the guarantee of interest of 4.5 per cent on the capital invested that had been granted initially (cei ix 1989: 28; Reitsma 1928: 22-23). The difficult start of the nism resulted in a debate about the desirability of state construction and/or state exploitation. The liberal government in the Netherlands had always preferred private enterprises, but in the end State Railways were considered necessary for strategic purposes (Staargaard 1929: 2; Oegema 1982: 14). Eventually, more than ten years after the opening of the first railway, the state became directly involved in the construction of railways. Originally parliament agreed on a law to build a railway line at government expense, but to grant the running of it to a private company. However, when no private company could be found to run the exploitation of the line the government took responsibility for this itself. As a result the Staatsspoorwegen (State Railways, ss) opened its first line between Surabaya and Pasuruan in 1878. After gradual expansion in 1894 a continuous railway line was in place between Batavia and Surabaya, running via Yogyakarta. This reduced the journey between those cities from about two weeks by horse-hauled carriages to 32.5 hours by train. The railway network in Java thus developed quite steadily in the late nineteenth century (table 4.8 and figure 4.8), aided by the fact that, around 1880, the success of the existing railway companies resulted in increased enthusiasm among private investors. Their interest was mainly directed at the construction of ‘tramways’. These tramways were usually related to agricultural developments. Sugar plantations and factories, tobacco and rubber plantations, and forestry companies benefited greatly from these new modes of transport. The lines also acted as feeders to the main lines. Far fewer railways were built in islands other than Java. Apart from a ss line of 47 kilometres in South Sulawesi, which was completed in 1922 and closed down in 1930 due to lack of profits, these railway lines were all located in Sumatra (cei ix 1989: 29). Construction in Sumatra began in 1876 with a tram line of five kilometres from Ulelhee to Kota Raja (now Banda Aceh), although this line was meant for the use of military transport. Gradually this line was expanded and in 1919 it was connected to The journey actually took three days, because trains did not run at night and the presence of different gauges required passengers and goods to be transferred in both Yogyakarta and Solo.
112
| Accounting for Services
another railway system on Sumatra, namely that of the Deli Spoorweg Maatschappij (Deli Railway Company, dsm). The dsm, which opened its first section of railway line in 1886, was the only private company operating in the Outer Islands. The dsm served the fertile Deli region with its large estate agricultural sector. In West Sumatra the first railway section was opened by ss in 1891. In South Sumatra the construction of the railway system did not start until 1911. In 1914 the first section of the Lampung part was completed as was the first section of the Palembang part in 1915. Only in 1927 were these two parts connected (cei ix 1989: 30, see also figure 4.9). Table 4.8
Railway and tramway companies in Java, Madura and Sumatra
Name
Location
Construction period
Length in 1939
Nederlandsch-Indische Spoorweg Mij West Java, Eastern Central and East Java
1867-1924
855 km
Staatsspoor- en Tramwegen in Nederlandsch Indië
1878-1928
2,761 km
Java West Sumatra
1891-1921
263 km
South Sumatra
1914-1932
661 km
Aceh
1876-1917
512 km
Notes
Deli Spoorweg Mij
North Sumatra
1886-1937
554 km
Javasche Spoorweg Mij
Tegal-Balapulang, Northwest Central Java
1885-1886
(24 km) To scs 1895
Bataviasche Ooster Spoorweg Mij
Jakarta-Krawang
1887-1898
(63 km) To ss 1898
Semarang-Joana Stoomtram Mij
Semarang-Cepu, Northwest Central Java
1882-1923
417 km
Semarang-Cheribon Stoomtram Mij
Semarang-Cirebon, Northern Central Java
1897-1914
373 km
Oost-Java Stoomtram Mij
Surabaya area
1889-1924
36 km
Serajoedal Stoomtram Mij
Maos-Wonosobo, Serayu River Valley
1896-1917
126 km
Poerwodadi-Goendih Stoomtram Mij
Purwodadi-Gundih, Central Java
Pasoeroean Stoomtram Mij
Pasuruan area, East Java
1896-1912
32 km
Probolinggo Stoomtram Mij
Probolinggo area, East Java
1897-1912
41 km
Kediri Stoomtram Mij
Kediri-Jombang, East Java
1897-1900
121 km
Malang Stoomtram Mij
Malang area, East Java
1897-1908
85 km
Madoera Stoomtram Mij
Bangkalan-Kalianget, Madura
1898-1913
213 km
1894
(17 km) To sjs
Modjokerto Stoomtram Mij
Mojokerto area, East Java
1898-1907
Babat-Djombang Stoomtram Mij
Babat-Jombang, East Java
1899-1902
(71 km) To ss 1916
Solosche Tramweg Mij
Solo-Boyolali, Central Java
1908-1911
(27 km) To nis
Source: Tim Telaga Bakti Nusantara 1997.
113
| Roads to Riches?
78 km
Railway service improved gradually during the first half of the twentieth century. After the opening of new lines, replacement of the 1435 mm gauge with the 1067 mm, and after the ban on running trains at night was lifted in 1912 it was possible to travel from Batavia to Surabaya in 13.5 hours in 1929, gradually reduced to 11 hours and 27 minutes in 1939 (Veenendaal 2004: 77). Figure 4.8 The railway network of Java and Madura, 1899-1925
Source: cei ix 1989: 120-121.
114
| Accounting for Services
Figure 4.9 The railway network in Sumatra, 1925
Source: cei ix 1989: 122.
115
| Roads to Riches?
Developments in rail transport, 1890-1940
Table 4.9
Java & Madura Track
Outer Islands
Passengers Freight (x1,000) (x1,000 ton)
Track
Passengers (x1,000)
Indonesia Freight (x1000 ton)
Track
Passengers Freight (x1,000) (x1,000 ton)
1890
1,463
14,071
1,208
130
1,386
165
1,593
15,457
1,373
1900
3,183
35,575
3,014
391
2,429
534
3,574
38,004
3,548
1910
4,220
67,459
6,674
925
4,874
960
5,145
72,333
7,634
1920
5,138
165,693
12,157
1,428
15,677
1,986
6,566
181,370
14,143
1930
5,518
117,928
13,108
1,877
15,045
2,718
7,395
132,973
15,826
1939
5,414
76,463
8,014
1,974
11,894
2,767
7,388
88,357
10,781
Source: Author’s calculations from cei ix 1989: table 12.
Table 4.10 Average annual growth of rail transport, 1890-1939 Java & Madura Track
Outer Islands
Passengers Freight
Track
Netherlands-Indies
Passengers Freight
Track
Passengers Freight
1890-1900
7.3
8.8
8.7
10.5
5.2
11.3
7.6
8.5
9.0
1900-1910
2.6
6.0
7.5
8.1
6.5
5.5
3.4
6.0
7.2
1910-1920
1.8
8.5
5.6
4.0
11.2
6.8
2.2
8.7
5.8
1920-1930
0.7
-3.0
0.7
2.5
-0.4
2.9
1.1
-2.8
1.0
1930-1939
-0.2
-4.2
-4.8
0.5
-2.3
0.2
-0.0
-4.0
-3.8
Source: Author’s calculations from cei ix 1989: table 12.
As can be seen in tables 4.9 and 4.10, growth in railway transport was quite impressive between 1890 and 1920. With an average annual growth in passengers of around 8 per cent and a growth in freight of around 7 per cent, railway transport became one of the most important transportation modes, especially in Java. This growth coincided with a significant decrease in transportation costs by rail between 1890 and 1920. If we divide total revenue from passenger transportation and freight respectively by the passenger-kilometres and ton-kilometres and then divide this by a cpi we arrive at a measure of transportation costs in constant prices.10 The results are depicted in figure 4.10. Freight costs and passenger fares were declining between 1890 and 1920. Between 1920 and 1942 prices fluctuated. Apparently, no major technological or institutional changes happened that could further drive down the price of rail transport. Moreover growth in rail transport came to an end, because the introduction of
10 Actual passenger-kilometres and ton-kilometres are not directly available. However, we do have statistics on the number of passengers and volume of freight for Indonesia as a whole. Moreover we know how the average distance travelled by passengers and freight evolved from dsm annual reports. If we multiply these we arrive at estimates of passengerkilometres and ton-kilometres.
116
| Accounting for Services
the automobile in Indonesia offered a more comfortable and cheaper alternative to railway transport. Figure 4.10 Rail transport costs, 1890-1957 (constant 1993 prices)
450
1,800
400
1,600
350
1,400
300
1,200 Per ton-km (RHS)
250
1,000
200
800
150
600
100
400
50
Per pax-km (LHS)
200
0
0 1890 1895 1900 1905 1910
1915 1920 1925 1930 1935 1940 1945 1950
1955
Source: Author’s estimations from dsm annual reports.
In his PhD dissertation on the meaning of dsm in the economic development of Sumatra’s Eastcoast, Jacobus Weisfelt states that competition of road transport starting in the early 1920s had significant negative effects on the number of passengers. dsm tried to counter these developments by lowering prices, but without much success (Weisfelt 1972: 96-97). Freight transport by rail was initially less affected by road transport. Bulk transport from the estates in most cases still went by rail. In the case of dsm in Sumatra there was competition from water transport by kpm. But compared to the great number of small road transport firms, kpm was a clear and visible competitor. Neither kpm nor dsm wanted to get involved in fierce competition, and therefore it was decided to share the bulk transport. This explains why prices of freight transport actually increased between 1920 and 1935. Lack of competition and arrangements with possible competitors did not force prices down. Moreover, railway companies in this way could make up for the lower prices for passenger transport due to competition from road transport.
117
| Roads to Riches?
But it was not only price competition that was used to secure the position of the railways. Other actions were taken as well, such as the increase in the number of trains, resulting in more certainty in the availability of transport; an increase in the number of stops; less rigorous compliance with rules by, for example, allowing passengers to carry excess luggage (Weisfelt 1972: 99). Similar developments were found in Java. During the 1920s annual reports of the different railway companies all show declining income from passenger transport, which is offset by an improvement in the volume of freight transport mostly due to the good agricultural production in this period (Haarman 1930: 205). The decline in income from passenger transport is explicitly attributed to competition from road transport. For 1933 it was estimated that the negative effect on income of the ss due to competition from automobiles was 9.98 million guilders for passenger transport and 3.04 million guilders for freight transport, or 44 per cent of total revenue of the ss (Van Nus 1935: 2).
1945-1965: consolidation and rehabilitation Following Indonesia’s declaration of independence on 17 August, 1945 the Japanese railway administration handed over the railways to Indonesian freedom fighters on 28 September of that year. When the Dutch returned to Indonesia in 1946, the Staatsspoorwegen/Verenigd Spoorwegbedrijf (ss/vs) was created, which comprised not only the former public railway company, but also all private railway companies.11 The only exceptions were the dsm on Sumatra, which remained a private company until its nationalisation in 1959, and the Bataviasche Verkeers Maatschappij, who offered only local transport in Jakarta and its surroundings. Later the ss/vs became the Djawatan Kereta Api (dka). At the transfer of sovereignty the railways were in an appalling state. Years of neglect and war had resulted in destruction of and damage to the rolling stock, track and other structures. The railways required subsidies to keep operating, many lines could not be run at a profit, obtaining sufficient spare parts for locomotives was a major problem and the track conditions were deplorable.12 Despite these problems rail transport slowly recovered in 1950s. The number of passengers rose substantially from 51 million in 1948 to 158 million in 1960. This volume of passenger transport was similar to the record level in the 1920s. Freight increased from nearly 3.5 million ton in 1948 to 6.5 million ton in 1960. Dick and Forbes (1992: 261) even state that for intercity travel, rail was at the time the fastest and most reliable means of land transport. By 1965 not only were more passengers carried than in the colonial period, the average distance travelled had increased from 20 kilometres to nearly 60 kilometres
11 Both ss/vs and dka made payments to the shareholders of the private corporations for the use of their property (Sutter 1959: 903). 12 See for example Bank Indonesia, annual report, 1957/58: 155-156.
118
| Accounting for Services
per passenger. At the same time developments in freight stayed behind. Rail freight succumbed to road competition. Dick (2000) attributes this to massive pilferage and to the fact that transportation by rail requires feeders and transhipment costs at both end of the journey. These developments are illustrated in figure 4.11.
Table 4.11 Developments in rail transport, 1949-2000 Passengers
Freight
Number
Pax-km
Ton
Ton-km (x million)
(x1,000)
(x million)
(x1,000)
1949
65,014
1,532
4,976
434
1960
158,000
-
6,564
1,159
1965
125,000
7,322
4,397
973
1970
50,000
3,378
3,958
855
1980
41,754
6,089
4,859
961
1990
58,212
9,290
12,537
3,190
2000
191,600
19,228
19,544
5,009
Note: Pax-km is an abbreviation for passenger-kilometres. Source: Statistical Yearbook Indonesia, various issues.
Figure 4.11 Developments in numbers of passengers and freight carried by rail, 1890-2000
250,000
25,.000
200,000
20,000 Freight (RHS)
Passengers (LHS) 150,000
15,000
100,000
10,000
50,000
5,.000
0
0 1890
1900
1910
1920
1930
1940
Passengers (x1,000)
1950
1960
Freight (x1,000)
Source: cei ix 1989, and Statistical Yearbook of Indonesia, various issues.
119
| Roads to Riches?
1970
1980
1990
2000
1965-2000: losing ground In 1963 all public railways in Indonesia were unified under a new administration, Perusahaan Negara Kereta Api (pnka). In 1973 the pnka was renamed pjka (Perusahaan Jawatan Kereta Api). Dieselisation and the abandonment of most unprofitable lines improved pjka’s financial position, but it continued to require subsidies from the government.
Figure 4.12 Developments in passenger-kilometres and ton-kilometres, 1890-1900 25,000
6,000
5,000
20,000 ton-km (RHS)
4,000 15,000 3,000 10,000 2,000 5,000
pax-km (LHS)
0
1,000
0 1890
1900
1910
1920
1930
1940
Passenger-km (x million)
1950
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
Ton-km (x million)
Source: Author’s calculations from cei ix 1989, dsm annual reports, and Statistical Yearbook of Indonesia.
These organisational changes could not prevent rail transport experiencing a significant decline during the 1970s. In this period tramway lines were abandoned, as they were no longer economically viable. By the mid-1970s, in the face of vigorous bus competition, passenger traffic had collapsed to only 22 million.13 The rehabilitation of Jakarta’s metropolitan network and the introduction of fast intercity trains eventually helped to revive passenger transport from 58.2 million in 1990 to 191.6 million in 2000. Dick states that this is ‘impressive enough by pre-war standards,
13 Bank Indonesia, annual report, 1976/77: 121.
120
| Accounting for Services
but at [current levels] of population and mobility [it is] no more than a niche operation’ (Dick 2000: 195). One important point is not yet accounted for: the significant increase in average distance travelled. In 1939 the average distance travelled by a passenger was around 30 kilometres. This steadily increased after independence to almost 160 kilometres in 1990. Thus, although fewer passengers were carried, they travelled longer distances resulting in a significant increase in passenger-kilometres as can be seen in figures 4.11 and 4.12. This reflects a shift in preference. For shorter distances transport by road is preferred, while rail is considered more convenient for long-distance travel. In conclusion, developments in the Indonesian railways sector were impressive in the first decades of the twentieth century. In this period rail transport played a significant and increasingly important role in carrying both freight and passengers, although this was largely confined to Java. This period is also characterised by a large drop in railway transportation costs, which can function as a catalyst of economic growth. After 1920 rail transport lost ground, mainly due to competition with road transport. Prices rose again and we see a drop in both passengers and freight transport by rail in the 1930s.
Figure 4.13 Rail transport costs in constant prices, 1890-2000
1890
121
1900
1910
1920
1930
1939
1971
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
Note: Costs are obtained by dividing total output by a volume index and the cpi, and then standardising this to 100 in 1990. Source: Author’s calculations.
| Roads to Riches?
After independence passenger transport picked up again, but freight transport lagged behind. From the early 1980s the number of passengers and the amount of freight carried by the railway sector increased sharply. Combined with the larger distances travelled this resulted in a moderate revival of rail transport. Taking into account the increase in population and in economic activities in other sectors, it seems fair to conclude that today rail transport plays only a marginal role in Indonesia. This also becomes evident if we look at the contribution of railway transport to gdp. As we saw in chapter 3 this was at its peak in the 1920s with more than 3 per cent. In 2000 railways only contributed 0.2 per cent to the gdp. At the same time railway transportation costs have decreased significantly after independence and contributed to economic development in the way discussed in the paragraph above on the theoretical framework.
4.3.3
Road transport 1900-1940: paving the way to development Road developments actually started in the nineteenth century. The most important initiative in this respect was the construction of the Grote Postweg (Great Mail Road) by Governor-General Daendels in 1808. By 1892 the road system in Java comprised approximately 20,000 kilometres. Between 1892 and 1938 the total length of roads in Java increased to only about 27,000 kilometres. The slow growth in building new roads can be explained by the emphasis in the first half of the twentieth century on the improvement of existing roads. During the 1920s a start was made with asphalting, and by 1938 about 32 per cent of the roads were asphalted (cei ix 1989: 26-27). In the Outer Islands developments were slower and were much more fragmented than in Java. Between 1892 and 1938 the length of roads in the Outer Islands increased from 11,000 to 42,000 kilometres, of which approximately 9 per cent was asphalted in 1938. To put these numbers in perspective, the Outer Islands comprise 94 per cent of Indonesia’s total land area, whereas Java and Madura only make up 6 per cent. cei ix (1989) gives some figures about traditional road transport in Java and Madura around 1900. According to this publication the number of passenger vehicles increased to 43,000 and the number of goods vehicles to 113,000. The construction of railways meant that, as noted in the previous section, traditional road transport started to concentrate on short-distance transport, while long-distance transport went by rail. For the period after 1900 hardly any figures on traditional road transport are available. Most probably, traditional means of transport experienced some competition from motorised road transport, but at the same time urbanisation could have increased demand for short-distance transportation and thus for traditional modes of transport. Although there are some accounts of people having a car in the NetherlandsIndies as early as 1890, motorised transport only took hold from 1910 onwards
122
| Accounting for Services
(Djojosoemarman 1941: 606). In 1910 there were approximately 1,000 motor vehicles in Java. From 1925 to 1940 the number of passenger cars rose by an annual average of 2.5 per cent and buses and trucks by a staggering 25.1 per cent (cei ix 1989: 28). Strikingly, the increase in buses and trucks is not evenly distributed between Java and the Outer Islands. This category increased significantly in importance relatively to Java in the Outer Islands. cei ix attributes this to the complete or partial lack of rail systems in the Outer Islands (cei ix 1989: 28). This argument is also made by Orrt in his survey of road transport in the early 1930s (Orrt 1933: 489).
1945-1965: severe infrastructural damage In Indonesia the road network severely deteriorated between 1939 and 1959 (Leinbach 1986: 193; Leinbach and Chia 1989: 66). Not only were roads vulnerable to rapid deterioration from monsoon rains, but bridges were not rebuilt and roads were reclaimed by the rainforest. The lack of repair and maintenance had devastating consequences for road transport. Most of the deterioration took place during the Japanese occupation and Indonesian revolution. Growth rates from 1950 onwards look quite impressive, but this is only because the road system had to start from a very low level. In 1949, for example, the number of passenger cars was only onethird of what it had been in 1939; the total number of cars had been reduced to half during the same period. At the end of the Old Order, the road transport system of Indonesia was still in a deplorable state. In 1967 less than 20 per cent of the length of national roads and only 15 per cent of provincial roads was assessed as being in good condition. Of the local roads, which constituted 60 per cent of all roads, none was reckoned to be in good condition (Dick and Forbes 1992: 260). This meant that transportation between villages and market towns was difficult, and sometimes, especially in the wet season, impossible. Dick and Forbes continue: ‘Journeys were slow because of the need to weave between potholes, cross temporary bridges, and, in the wet season, plough through mud’ (p. 261).
Table 4.12 Road conditions, 1967 Roads maintained by government:
Good
20%
Fair
29%
Bad
43%
Very bad Provincial roads:
Good
123
35%
Bad
41%
Source: Bank Indonesia, annual report, 1966/67: 271.
| Roads to Riches?
15%
Fair Very bad
8%
9%
The poor condition of the roads is further illustrated if we look at the plans laid out by the government for the improvement and extension of the network. In 1957 it was estimated that the length of roads had to be extended by 100%, and that modernisation and improvement were needed for most of the roads. The projected costs were 120 billion rupiah (see table 4.13). Table 4.13
Road development plan, 1957
Sumatra Kalimantan
Total length of road system
Road extension
Length of roads to be modernised/improved
Estimated costs in million rupiah
27,860
28,000
28,000
49,000
4,280
18,000
4,000
21,000
East Indonesia
16,180
17,000
16,000
29,000
Java
29,280
12,000
12,000
21,000
Indonesia
77,600
75,000
60,000
120,000
Source: Bank Indonesia, annual report 1957/58: 204.
1965-2000: rehabilitation and growth During the New Order investments in road transport were significant. About 55 per cent of expenditure in transport had been allocated for the development and maintenance of the road system (Leinbach 1986: 196; Dick and Forbes 1992: 264). This high proportion reflects both the size of the task of repairing the road network and the importance of it: the restoration of commerce was believed to depend essentially on improvements in the transport system (Leinbach 1986). Initial investments were directed at emergency repairs in West and South Sumatra as well as in East and West Java (Leinbach 1989: 469). In the 1970s the total number of motor vehicles increased from 0.8 million to 3.9 million, an average annual growth of 15.4 per cent. In the 1980s growth was 7.9 per cent. This trend was dominated by motorcycles, whose share rose to 70 per cent of all motor vehicles. The regional distribution of vehicles in 1968 and 1986 had been fairly stable, with Java accounting for a little more than 75 per cent of all automobiles. Some of the rapid growth in vehicle numbers is due to road improvements. The length of roads increased between 1968 and 1985 by some 2.5 times, and between 1985 and 2000 by about 1.7 times. In the late 1970s Indonesia was still well behind comparable countries, such as India, which had three times the road length per capita and almost eight times as much road per unit of area (Dick and Forbes 1992: 267). Probably more important has been the improvement in the condition of roads. The proportion of asphalted roads rose from 24 per cent in 1970 to 41 per cent in 1985 and 57 per cent in 2000.
124
| Accounting for Services
Table 4.14
Average annual growth in motor vehicles, 1949-2000 Cars
Trucks
Buses
Motor cycle
Total
Total excl. Motorcycles
1949-1965
14.1
10.3
11.7
26.0
15.9
12.5
1965-1970
6.3
3.4
4.6
11.1
8.2
5.3
1970-1980
9.4
15.0
12.5
17.8
15.4
11.4
1980-1990
6.8
7.3
16.6
7.8
7.9
8.0
1990-2000
7.9
4.8
3.3
7.6
7.1
6.2
1990-1997
9.1
5.3
3.4
8.6
8.1
6.9
Source: Statistical Yearbook of Indonesia, various issues.
Table 4.15
Number of vehicles per 1,000 inhabitants, 1950-2000 Cars
Trucks
Buses
Motorcycle
Total
Total excl. Motorcycles
1950
0.28
0.22
0.07
0.07
0.65
0.58
1960
1.08
0.79
0.19
1.40
3.47
2.06
1970
2.06
0.88
0.20
3.79
6.94
3.14
1980
4.34
3.21
0.59
18.12
26.25
8.13
1990
7.33
5.71
2.61
33.94
49.59
15.65
2000
14.41
8.10
3.16
64.32
89.98
25.67
Source: Number of vehicles see appendix, population: Maddison 2003.
Table 4.16 Average annual growth in length of road, 1959-2000 Asphalted
Non-asphalted
Total
1959-1965
6.33%
1.82%
0.70%
1965-1970
-0.35%
0.41%
0.21%
1970-1980
10.22%
5.16%
5.15%
1980-1990
7.36%
5.72%
6.36%
1990-2000
4.13%
-0.15%
1.92%
1990-1997
5.01%
-0.61%
2.12%
Source: Statistical Yearbook of Indonesia, various issues.
Table 4.17
Length of road per 1,000 inhabitants, 1954-2000 Asphalted
Non-asphalted
1954
0.17
0.41
Total 0.58
1960
0.14
0.39
0.83 0.79
1965
0.20
0.40
1970
0.18
0.37
0.73
1980
0.40
0.51
0.99
1990
0.73
0.77
1.61
2000
0.96
0.65
1.69
Source: For length of road, see appendix; for population: Maddison 2003.
125
| Roads to Riches?
Due to lack of data it is much more difficult to estimate developments in the costs of road transport than in the other transport sectors. Some scattered sources do allow a very rough estimate, though. To begin with, Meijer (1987: 43) states that transporting a ton of rice from Belawan to Medan by dogcart, covering a distance of 21 kilometres, cost 8 guilders around 1890. Transportation of a ton of tobacco over the same distance was estimated at 10 guilders. This implies a rate between 0.38 and 0.48 guilders per ton-kilometre. In a report on the automobile service of the nism, Van den Broeke (1920) gives figures for revenue from freight transport and the number of ton-kilometres served in 1918. These were respectively 7,856 and 18,433 guilders, implying the revenue per ton-kilometre to be 0.43 guilders. For the years 1968 and 1969 we can rely on data collected by Mudge (1972: 185). He found that average freight rates in ton-kilometres for both intra- and inter-provincial transport were Rp. 7.46 and Rp. 8.73 respectively. In a comparison between freight transport in Tanzania and Indonesia, Hine et al. (1997) estimated the average rate per ton-kilometre for 3-axle trucks to be Rp. 70 in 1995. If we, as before, divide these numbers by the cpi (Van der Eng 2002), we arrive at estimates for the costs of road transport for 5 benchmark years (figure 4.14).
Figure 4.14 Development of road transport costs, 1890-1995 (1993 constant prices)
3,722.5
2,211.3
1890
126
1918
Source: See text.
| Accounting for Services
134.1
134.4
63.2
1968
1969
1995
The results illustrate the impact of the introduction of the car. In 1918 transportation by car was not yet widely available and still a costly mode of transport, although it was already significantly cheaper than transportation by dogcart at the end of the nineteenth century. In 1968 road transportation costs were only 5 per cent of those in 1918. Between 1968 and 1995 freight costs per ton-kilometre fell again by 50 per cent, due to the repair and extension of the road network. Developments in road transport have clearly reduced costs and have had great impact on the integration and specialisation of different regions and thus on economic development in Indonesia.
4.3.4
Air transport
1928-1945: introduction of a new technology While the first successful flight with an airplane in Indonesia took place in 1911, it was only in 1928 that an airline company in colonial Indonesia was set up, the Koninklijke Nederlandsch-Indische Luchtvaart Maatschappij (Royal NetherlandsIndies Airlines, knilm). Initially knilm offered services between the main cities in Java. In 1930 it opened a scheduled service to Singapore. knilm’s activities grew steadily. The annual number of passenger kilometres grew from 3.2 million in 1930 to 10.0 million in 1939 or 12.2 per cent on average per year. The growth in the number of passengers was less impressive, from 13,984 in 1930 to 18,792 in 1939. This means that the growth in passenger-kilometres was mainly due to the longer distances travelled by passengers. In the early years freight played only a marginal role in air transport.
Table 4.18
Air transport developments in Indonesia, 1930-2000 Growth in Pax-km
1930-1939
12.2%
Growth in Ton-km
Average load factor, pax
Average load factor, freight
5.8%
x
x
1948-1970
9.7%
x
x
x
1970-1980
18.8%
18.5%
53.8%
49.5%
1980-1990
7.9%
9.6%
54.4%
48.7%
1990-2000
1.4%
0.5%
59.5%
47.6%
1990-1997
7.1%
6.8%
57.4%
47.3%
Source: Author’s calculations from knilm, annual reports and bps, Statistical Yearbook of Indonesia various issues.
1945-1965: a relatively smooth transition Indonesia’s national airline, Garuda Indonesian Airways (gia), was founded in 1949. On 28 December 1949 President Sukarno was a passenger on the company’s first flight, from Yogyakarta to Jakarta (Sutter 1959: 892). In 1950 the 40-year monopoly concession that had been granted to the knilm in 1940 was replaced. In
127
| Roads to Riches?
this new concession monopoly rights were granted to Garuda, which was set up as a joint venture between the Indonesian government and the klm. Initially the Indonesian government held 51 per cent of the shares. For the first ten years the Royal Dutch Airline, klm, would manage the new corporation. klm made serious work of this by both making its own personnel immediately available and at the same time beginning intensive training of Indonesians so that they could gradually take over the service. According to Sutter, when, on 31 March 1950, Garuda was officially incorporated it ‘sprang full-blown into the air with a fleet of 27 airplanes, trained personnel, airports, and scheduled flights, with the usual pioneering hardships of any airline having been borne by the predecessors’ (Sutter 1959: 893). In this way a vacuum in air transport after the transfer of sovereignty was avoided. There was some discontent with this construction, however. Many nationalists were dissatisfied with the Dutch hegemony in the company’s management and this issue was repeatedly discussed in parliament (Sutter 1959: 893). In order to resolve this issue, the Indonesian government continued to make plans for earlier nationalisation. klm sold its shares in 1954 to the Indonesian government, but continued to provide technical assistance until 1958. The period 1945-1965 shows a growth in number of passenger carried from 284,000 in 1952 to 433,000 in 1965. Meanwhile passenger-kilometres rose from 159 million to 537 million or 9.1 per cent annually. Air transport seems to be the only transportation sector which was not negatively affected during the Old Order, although it is hard to tell if growth had been higher under a different scenario.
1965-2000: air transport revolution Air transport really took off in the 1970s. With an average annual growth of more than 18 per cent both in passenger-kilometres and ton-kilometres, one could speak of an air transport revolution. In the 1980s growth was moderate compared to earlier periods, but still significant with almost 8 per cent annually for passengers and nearly 10 per cent for freight. This growth path more or less continued until the Asian crisis in 1997. Air transport was severely hit by this crisis. Between 1997 and 1999 both passenger-kilometres and ton-kilometres halved. It is interesting to see that this did not affect the load factor. Apparently, airlines cut back on (unprofitable) routes. Moreover, since 2000 a spectacular growth in air transport can be seen due to the proliferation of low-cost carriers. Overall we see that air transport has grown impressively since its introduction in the late 1920s. This is also reflected in the costs of air transportation in constant prices. As we can see from figure 4.15, prices have declined significantly since the beginning of operations. The Asian crisis caused a major, but temporary, setback. Since the fall of Suharto new airlines have mushroomed. While before 1999 there were five scheduled carriers and a few charter operators, in 2004 there were 23 scheduled airlines operating, and 37 licenses had been issued. Air transport is growing rapidly, with the number of air travellers doubling every three years. In
128
| Accounting for Services
2003, 16 million trips were taken, compared with 6.6 million in 1999.14 Apparently, the lack of technological and organisational innovations has put pressure on the costs.
Figure 4.15 Air transport costs in constant 1993 prices, 1930-2000
1930
4.4
1939
1971
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
Note: Figures are arrived at by dividing revenue by an unweighted volume index of both passengers kilometres and ton-kilometres. This outcome is divided by the cpi and then standardised to 100 in 1990. Source: Author’s calculations.
Concluding remarks The existence of a developed transportation network is a necessary but not sufficient condition for economic growth. It is often termed indispensable for economic growth. In section 4.2 a theoretical foundation for this claim was laid. It was shown that efficient transportation systems have significant effects on economic welfare and economic growth. Cheap and reliable transportation modes enable local specialisation, higher producer prices, lower producer costs and higher productivity, or in Fogel’s terms ‘Social Savings’. If we look at developments of the transportation sector in Indonesia we can distinguish three phases. The first phase was from 1900 until 1940, under Dutch
14 http://go.worldbank.org/PF2AFG64V0 accessed 21 January 2008.
129
| Roads to Riches?
colonial rule. During this period a relatively efficient transportation network was constructed. During the first two decades of the twentieth century in particular railways played an important role, although this was largely confined to Java. In this period kpm was important for state formation (À Campo 1992) and succeeded in offering reliable and safe transport over water. From a welfare perspective it can be argued that kpm’s monopoly was not optimal, but at the same time the larger profits made on trunk lines enabled kpm to cross-subsidise less-profitable routes, thus creating both a politically and economically integrated colony. From the 1920s onwards road transport gained significance. The introduction of automobiles, trucks and buses made it possible to move passengers and goods without additional feeder services. Railway transport was especially negatively affected by these developments. Growth stagnated and the railway sector did not really recover until the late 1980s. In 1928 the first airline was established in Indonesia, but its contribution remained marginal during the colonial period. The second phase, from the Japanese invasion in 1942 until the fall of the Sukarno government in 1966, was largely characterised by infrastructural and institutional damage. On-going competition and struggle between kpm and the Indonesian state-owned shipping company pelni escalated into the expulsion of kpm in 1957. Although the problems of capacity were rapidly solved, organisational problems harmed the water transport sector. Over-capacity, unreliable schedules and other inefficiencies negatively affected not only growth in this sector, but also that of the economy as a whole. At the same time railways and roads were severely neglected. Only developments in air transport were satisfying. The third phase is the New Order period from 1966 until Asian crisis in the late 1990s. Significant investments in roads, the re-organisation and deregulation of the water transport sector, and repair of the railways combined with continuing growth in air transport caused what Dick and Forbes (1992) call ‘a quiet revolution’. During the twentieth century we also see a significant decrease in transportation costs, which means that important social savings have been made (Fogel), consumer and producer surplus have increased (Spatial Price Equilibrium Model) and that lower producer costs and higher producer prices combined with economies of scale have led to higher productivity. In conclusion, the Dutch paved the way for developments in the transportation sector, but growth was delayed during the Old Order. Since the 1970s, however, Indonesia has accelerated along this growth path. Nevertheless, there is potential for further growth in the transportation sector and consequently in the Indonesian economy as a whole. Most developments have been biased towards Java and, to a lesser extent, towards Bali and Sumatra. Especially in the Outer Islands but also in Java and Madura transportation networks are still considerably less efficient than in Western countries. Moreover, other problems have risen, such as severe traffic congestion in Java. If such problems can be overcome in the future, prices may decrease and the transport sector may serve as a catalyst of economic growth.
130
| Accounting for Services
5
INVOLUTION AND GROWTH
The ambiguous role of the trade sector in the economic developmentof Indonesia
5.1
Introduction A widely held belief in economics is that openness to trade accelerates economic development. Classic economic treatises by luminaries such as Adam Smith and David Ricardo showed early on the potential gains of trading between nations. For elaborations of these theories, Paul Samuelson and Bertil Ohlin were rewarded the Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences in 1970 and 1977 respectively. Nevertheless, strong critics of globalisation continue to exist. Those opponents argue that trade accentuates and deepens poverty, both in rich and in poor countries. Advocates of globalisation, however, claim that trade promotes growth, and in turn growth reduces poverty (Bhagwati and Srinivasan 2002). Much of the evidence in support of and against globalisation has been based on cross-country growth regressions. Srinivasan and Bhagwati argue that ‘In fact, while such regressions can be suggestive of new hypotheses and be valuable aids in thinking about the issue at hand, we would reiterate that great caution is needed in using them at all as plausible “scientific” support’ (Srinivasan and Bhagwati 1999: 38). Therefore they call for nuanced and in-depth studies to get a better understanding of the relationship between trade and economic development. The case of Indonesia is especially interesting. As Booth argues: ‘Indonesia’s involvement in the world economy did transform the local economies of the producing regions through the provision of infrastructure and the growing demand for inputs and services. And yet, the transformation of Indonesia into an open export-oriented economy in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries did not lead to rapid structural change, and sustained economic development.’ (Booth 1998: 203) This observation points to the ambiguous role that the trade sector has played in the process of economic development in Indonesia. On the one hand, Indonesia’s export orientation has enhanced economic growth in some periods, but failed to do so in other periods. At the same time, domestic dynamics transformed the sector from one in which the happy few reaped the benefits to one of last resort. Numerous
131
| Involution and Growth
workers who were pushed out of the agricultural sector and whom manufacturing industries failed to absorb found employment in petty trade, which is characterised by low entry barriers and great flexibility. This happened not only in periods of economic turmoil, as for example in the 1960s and after the Asian crisis in 1997/98, but also in the process of urbanisation. The aim of this chapter is to offer further insights into this ambiguous relationship between the trade sector and economic development in Indonesia. The remainder of this chapter will be organised as follows. The first part of the chapter, section 5.2, treats developments related to foreign trade. It will be shown that openness to trade has been instrumental for Indonesia’s economic development. However, this openness was restricted by protective trade policies in a number of periods, affecting Indonesia’s growth pattern. In section 5.3 another important characteristic of Indonesia’s trade sector will be discussed, namely the declining labour productivity in this sector as a result of the enormous influx of labourers unable to find work elsewhere. It will be argued that this process bears a striking resemblance with Clifford Geertz’s famous theory of agricultural involution (Geertz 1963). Section 5.4 concludes.
5.2
Foreign trade: an engine of growth?
5.2.1
A century of foreign trade Before the first Dutch merchant ships arrived in Java in 1596, foreign trade was already a quite common aspect of the indigenous economy: ‘The Indonesian products – cloves, nutmeg, mace, pepper, sandalwood, sapanwood, gold, tin, precious stones, drugs and medicinal products, and rarities such as birds, tortoise shell, and so forth – were shipped to the north and the west, traded in exchange for Indian and Persian textiles, slaves, money, and uncoined metal, and/or Chinese goods – silk and silk cloth, porcelain, lacquered objects, copperwork, paper, medicinal products, sugar, sumptuous handicraft goods – the largest part of which latter were reshipped to the west from the Indonesian staple ports.’ (Van Leur 1934: 121) In the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries the archipelago’s trade came increasingly under European and especially Dutch control and was organised in their interests (Booth 1989: 67). Initially growth in trade was only limited. Hanson, for instance, shows that Indonesia’s growth rate of per capita export values was substantially lower than that of a number of other countries in Asia, Africa and the Americas between 1860 and 1900 (Hanson 1980: 28). This pattern changed around the turn of the twentieth century. While the last decades of the nineteenth century were characterised by slow growth, import and
132
| Accounting for Services
exports rose substantially from the late 1890s until 1913. Among imports, there was a rise in consumer goods in particular. Growth in exports can mainly be attributed to sugar and petroleum products, and to a lesser extent to copra, tobacco and tea. Tin and coffee exports declined significantly due to reduced volumes of exports (cei xiia 1991: 17). Booth argues that increased investment in economic infrastructure combined with higher payments to indigenous workers on sugar estates and rapid growth in the plantation labour force in East Sumatra favoured the domestic economy. She concludes that in this period trade led to a higher rate of growth in the domestic economy than would have occurred with less or no involvement in foreign trade (Booth 1990: 289). As a result of the First World War the nominal value of trade rose sharply. This was mainly due to price rises, while increases in volume lagged behind. The total value of trade reached a peak in 1920. During the 1920s the volume of exports grew significantly, but declining prices resulted in lower trade values. The Depression of the 1930s severely affected Indonesia. Both imports and exports declined steadily between 1929 and 1934. After the depreciation of the guilder in 1936, levels picked up, rising up to 1940. Figure 5.1
Foreign trade values in Indonesia, 1900-2003 (in constant 1993 rupiah)
1,000,000
100,000
10,000
1,000
100
10
1 1900
1910
1920
1930
1940
1950
Exports
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
Imports
Note and sources: Trade figures are taken from cei xiia 1991 and bps, Statistik Indonesia, various issues. These are deflated by linking the following price indices: the export price index for 1900-1940 from van Ark 1988; the import price index for 1913-1939 from cei xiia 1991; the import and export price indices for 1950-1970 from Rosendale 1975; and the linked implicit price indices for 1970-2003 from the national accounts.
133
| Involution and Growth
There was some growth in export volume in the early 1950s above the level achieved in the late 1930s (Booth 1998: 205). However, compared to the dramatic expansion of world trade that occurred in the 1950s and 1960s, Indonesia’s trade performance was disappointing. Whereas world trade grew by about 7 per cent per annum between 1953 and 1966, Indonesian export volume grew by less than 1 per cent per annum (Hanson 1980: 14). Only in the latter part of the 1960s did Indonesia’s trade performance improve. Since 1958 foreign trade had been tightly controlled by the state. Exports levels had to be approved and originated from state enterprises, while imports required licences that were held by state trading companies. After the regime change, the New Order government took substantive liberalisation measures to bring the economy on a growth path. These measures also included the trade sector. The liberalisation measures resulted in a dramatic increase in foreign trade as a percentage of gdp. Starting at only 14 per cent in 1965, this proportion increased to more than 20 per cent in 1970, and then more than doubled to 46.8 per cent in 1980. In 1990 the total trade as percentage of gdp reached 54.7 per cent, even rising to over 70 per cent in 2000 (figure 5.2). Figure 5.2
Indonesia’s openness to foreign trade, 1900-2000
0,40 0,35 0,30 0,25 0,20 0,15 0,10 0,05 0 1900
1910
1920
1930
1940
1950
Exports/GDP
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
Imports/GDP
Note: 5-year moving averages. Source: Import and export figures: see figure 5.1; gdp figures calculated in current prices from Van der Eng 2002.
134
| Accounting for Services
In real terms, the value of Indonesia’s export increased substantially during the 1970s and remained stable during the 1980s. However, there was a radical change in the composition of exports. Prior to 1973 Indonesia’s exports were dominated by non-fuel primary products. Within the agricultural sector, natural rubber, coffee, tea, palm oil and timber were traditionally dominant, accounting for about 45 per cent of total export earnings in 1970. The share of crude petroleum exports was still modest being one-third of the total. The performance of manufactured exports was limited in the 1970s with an average share of 12 per cent, because industrialisation was not yet underway and trade policies were pursued that favoured import substitution. After the boom in oil prices starting in 1973, the share of fuels in total exports increased dramatically and reached a peak in 1982 with a share of more than 80 per cent of total export earnings. The improvement in Indonesia’s export performance during the 1970s was not only due to the favourable export prices, but also to policy reforms introduced by the government. In 1978 the rupiah was devalued from Rp. 415 to Rp. 625 per us$. In the same year the government issued a Certificate Export system under which export subsidies were granted to offset tariffs and taxes on imported inputs and the high costs of domestic inputs. The ban on the exportation of logs was introduced in 1980 to encourage investment in processing industries, especially plywood mills. In response to the collapse of the oil prices in the early 1980s and the consequent need to boost earnings from non-oil exports, the government introduced a number of trade policy reforms. The rupiah was devalued again in 1983 by 28 per cent (from Rp. 703 to Rp. 970 per us$) and again in 1986 by 31 per cent (from Rp. 1,134 to Rp. 1,664 per us$). Since then the rupiah has been allowed to depreciate slowly but predictably against the dollar. Moreover, the government introduced a duty drawback program in 1986 to replace the export certificate system. In this new system, producer exporters who exported 85 per cent or more of their total production were granted import inputs free of restrictions and were exempted from import duties (Dick 2002: 212; Prawiro 1998: 269). In addition, regulatory restrictions for exporters were reduced in 1987 and an export ban on raw and semi-processed rattan was imposed in 1988. All these policies resulted in structural changes in Indonesia’s exports. The total value of Indonesia’s exports showed a slow increase during the 1980s, but its composition changed significantly. A large portion of the exports of traditional commodities has changed from primary products to manufactured exports. The share of the agricultural sector in total exports dropped from 48 per cent in 1970 to 11.6 per cent in 1990. Exports of minerals also declined after reaching a peak of 80 per cent of the total in 1982. Its share decreased to about 40 per cent in 1990. Exports of manufacturing goods, on the other hand, grew rapidly. Their share in total exports increased from 14 per cent in 1980 to more than 47 per cent in 1990. From 1987, non-fuel exports have surpassed those of oil and gas. Hill even labels this rise in exports of manufactures ‘a watershed in Indonesia’s modern economic development’ (Hill 2000: 84).
135
| Involution and Growth
Exports of manufactured goods consisted mainly of resource-intensive and labour-intensive goods that were consistent with Indonesia’s comparative advantage (Hill 2000: 83). Around 45 per cent of the total manufacturing exports were in resource-based manufacturers and 40 per cent concentrated in the labour-intensive sector. The remaining share comprised the capital-intensive goods. Imports are commonly divided into three categories, consumer goods, raw materials and capital goods. Since 1970 the share of consumer goods in total imports has declined significantly, from about 25 per cent in 1970 to only 4 per cent in 1990 and rising again to 8.6 per cent in 2000. This decrease was partly due to the increased self-sufficiency in food production that was achieved in the mid-1980s (Hutabarat 1992: 93). Table 5.1
Composition of imports into Indonesia by economic categories, 1950-2000 (in current million us$) Consumer goods Value
Raw materials and auxiliary goods
%
Value
%
Capital goods Value
Total
%
1950
191.9
43.7
170.6
38.9
76.5
17.4
1955
190.6
30.2
335.4
53.1
105.1
16.7
439.0 631.1
1960
214.5
37.1
236.3
40.9
126.9
22.0
577.7
1965
230.8
33.2
243.0
35.0
220.9
31.8
694.7
1970
251.1
25.1
376.5
37.6
373.9
37.3
1,001.5
1975
677.5
14.2
1,961.1
41.1
2,131.2
44.7
4,769.8
1980
1,543.4
14.2
4,807.6
44.4
4,483.4
41.4
10,834.4
1980a
1,414.4
13.1
7,931.6
73.2
1,488.4
13.7
10,834.4
1985a
380.5
3.7
8,159.9
79.5
1,718.7
16.8
10,259.1
1990a
876.9
4.0
14,893.1
68.2
6,067.0
27.8
21,837.0
1995a
2,350.4
5.8
29,586.6
72.8
8,691.7
21.4
40,628.7
2000a
2,718.7
8.1
26,018.7
77.6
4,777.4
14.3
33,514.8
Compound annual growth rate: 1950-1960
1.1%
3.3%
5.2%
1960-1970
1.6%
4.8%
11.4%
2.8% 5.7%
1970-1980
19.9%
29.0%
28.2%
26.9%
1980-1990
-4.7%
6.5%
15.1%
7.3%
1990-2000
12.0%
5.7%
-2.4%
4.4%
Note: a: In the early 1980s the classification of imports was revised. This is not accounted for in the timeseries published by bps. After the revision intermediate goods are defined to include all food and beverages intended mainly for industry (such as wheat for the domestic flour milling industry), all fuels and lubricants except those intended for direct household consumption, and all industrial supplies and parts and accessories for capital goods. This meant that many imports that were previously classified as capital goods were now re-classified as raw materials (see also Sundrum 1986: 52-53). Source: bps, Statistik Indonesia, various issues.
136
| Accounting for Services
Rice imports had become a large portion of the country’s imports during the 1970s and the early 1980s. In 1980 the imports of rice amounted to 2 million tons with a value of nearly us$ 700 million, about half of the total consumer goods imports (Suprapto 1995: 70). This made Indonesia the largest rice-importing country in the world. The fact that Indonesia achieved self-sufficiency in rice in the mid-1980s explains the steep drop in imports of consumer goods. This decline, however, was offset by an increase in the share of raw material goods and capital goods. The share of raw materials and capital goods amounted to about three-quarters of total import value in 1970 and increased to 96 per cent in 1990. Raw material imports consist mainly of chemicals, spare parts, fuel and lubricants. The major components of capital goods imports include transport equipment, passenger cars, and other machinery. Imports of these goods fluctuated from year to year but showed a tendency to increase. During the 1970s and the early 1980s, the value of raw materials and capital goods imports grew consistently. A massive increase in import-substitution industrialisation of final consumer goods was responsible for this surge in imports. Between 1980 and 1985, especially after the collapse of the oil prices, the value of imports declined. During this period the government issued austerity programs under which a large number of import-intensive projects were postponed and rephased. It was only after 1986, when the oil price declined sharply, that rapid growth in investment and production occurred. This resulted in a rapid growth in imports of raw materials and capital goods between 1985 and 1995. The Asian crisis pushed down imports of both raw materials and auxiliary and capital goods, while imports of consumer goods grew slightly. This decline in imports of productive goods had negative effects on Indonesia’s productive capacity (Ishihara and Marks 2005).
5.2.2
Changes in the direction of trade: regionalisation of trade Significant changes have occurred in the direction of foreign trade during the twentieth century. Whereas around 1900 38.1 per cent of all exports from the NetherlandsIndies were shipped to the Netherlands and 35.5 per cent of all imports originated there, by 1939 these figures had dropped to 14.6 per cent and 20.8 per cent respectively. In this period Europe as a whole lost ground as trading partner, especially to the United States. Booth attributes this increase in the American share of Indonesian imports partly to improved trans-Pacific shipping routes, but also to the fact that income growth and industrial development in Indonesia created a growing demand for both capital and consumer goods produced in the usa (Booth 1998: 209). In Asia initially Singapore and the Malay peninsula were by far the most important markets for Indonesia’s exports and source of imports. After 1920 on the import side this role was taken over by Japan. By 1939 Japan’s share of Indonesian imports accounted for 17.8 per cent of the total and more than 50 per cent of the imports from Asian countries as a whole. This was mainly due to the fact that Japan could manufacture relatively cheaply a range of consumer goods such as cotton cloth,
137
| Involution and Growth
household utensils and bicycles which were demanded by those benefiting from the growing economy. Moreover, Japanese imports into the Netherlands-Indies profited from a cheap yen due to depreciation of the yen and the adherence of the guilder to the gold standard. Table 5.2
Exports from the Netherlands-Indies by destination, 1900-1939 1900
1910
1920
1930
1939
35.3%
46.4%
38.8%
49.3%
34.8%
- China, Hong Kong, Macao
7.8%
8.4%
7.4%
8.2%
3.1%
- India (incl. Ceylon)
0.4%
13.1%
9.6%
11.5%
4.2%
- Japan (incl. Formosa)
1.9%
3.8%
6.2%
4.0%
3.4%
- Singapore & Peninsula
25.0%
20.7%
14.8%
23.1%
19.8%
0.2%
0.4%
0.9%
2.6%
4.3%
Asia
- Other Africa
2.9%
4.9%
12.3%
0.7%
4.6%
10.8%
4.6%
13.4%
12.4%
20.9%
2.7%
1.6%
4.5%
2.5%
5.6%
48.2%
39.5%
30.3%
32.7%
27.8%
- uk
4.9%
2.9%
6.4%
8.3%
4.6%
- Netherlands
38.1%
26.9%
15.8%
15.3%
14.6%
5.2%
9.7%
8.1%
9.0%
8.6%
usa Australia Europe
- Rest of Europe Source: cei xiia 1991: 101-103.
Table 5.3
Imports into the Netherlands-Indies by origin, 1900-1939 1900
1910
1920
1930
1939
45.3%
45.2%
34.4%
38.6%
34.3%
- China, Hong Kong, Macao
2.8%
3.8%
3.2%
3.2%
3.5%
- India (incl. Ceylon)
0.6%
11.1%
2.9%
7.1%
3.1%
- Japan (incl. Formosa)
0.2%
1.0%
11.0%
11.3%
17.8%
- Singapore & Peninsula
38.8%
22.6%
11.7%
11.9%
7.8%
- Other
2.9%
6.7%
5.5%
5.0%
2.1%
Africa
0.0%
0.0%
0.1%
0.6%
1.4%
usa
1.5%
1.6%
15.0%
10.6%
14.2%
Australia
1.4%
1.7%
3.5%
2.9%
3.2%
Europe
51.8%
51.5%
46.8%
44.4%
45.4%
- uk
12.7%
12.5%
17.0%
9.9%
7.0%
- Netherlands
35.5%
32.3%
23.9%
18.4%
20.8%
- Rest of Europe
3.6%
6.7%
5.9%
16.1%
17.7%
Asia
Source: cei xiia 1991: 88-90.
138
| Accounting for Services
Table 5.4
Exports from Indonesia by destination, 1952-2000 1952
1958
1965
1970
1980
1990
2000
33.5%
48.6%
37.2%
65.0%
66.2%
70.5%
64.7%
- Malaysia
2.7%
4.3%
na
na
0.3%
1.0%
3.2%
- Thailand
na
na
0.5%
0.0%
0.2%
0.7%
1.7%
- Philippines
na
na
2.5%
2.3%
0.8%
0.6%
1.3%
24.7%
26.3%
0.8%
15.5%
11.3%
7.4%
10.6%
na
3.5%
1.2%
1.0%
0.7%
2.4%
2.5%
- Japan
2.7%
1.7%
17.1%
40.8%
49.3%
42.5%
23.2%
- Other (incl. China)
3.5%
12.8%
15.1%
5.4%
3.7%
15.8%
22.3%
Africa
1.0%
0.3%
0.4%
0.1%
0.3%
0.8%
1.8%
25.3%
16.2%
21.3%
13.0%
19.6%
13.1%
13.6%
3.0%
6.4%
7.8%
3.3%
1.5%
1.6%
2.4%
32.8%
25.9%
27.6%
15.7%
7.0%
12.5%
14.8%
2.7%
12.2%
0.8%
1.3%
0.6%
2.0%
2.4%
21.4%
4.0%
12.8%
5.7%
1.9%
2.8%
3.0%
8.7%
9.6%
13.9%
8.7%
4.5%
7.7%
9.4%
Asia
- Singapore - Hong Kong
usa Australia Europe - uk - Netherlands - Rest of Europe
Source: bps, Statistik Indonesia, various issues.
Table 5.5
Imports to Indonesia by origin, 1952-2000 1952
1958
1965
1970
1980
1990
2000
40.4%
46.2%
55.7%
50.2%
63.6%
55.1%
63.9%
- Malaysia
0.2%
0.2%
na
na
0.3%
1.5%
3.4%
- Thailand
na
na
7.5%
1.1%
1.3%
0.8%
3.3%
- Philippines
na
na
na
na
0.8%
0.3%
0.3%
1.8%
1.9%
0.0%
5.7%
8.6%
5.8%
11.3%
na
na
2.0%
2.2%
1.3%
1.3%
1.0%
- Japan
13.5%
12.9%
22.9%
29.4%
31.5%
24.3%
16.1%
- Others (incl. China)
25.0%
31.2%
23.3%
11.8%
19.8%
21.2%
28.5%
1.4%
4.1%
1.0%
2.9%
1.2%
0.8%
2.5%
17.1%
16.2%
9.4%
17.8%
13.0%
11.5%
10.1%
Asia
- Singapore - Hong Kong
Africa usa Australia
1.4%
1.3%
0.5%
2.8%
3.5%
5.4%
5.1%
35.9%
32.1%
31.0%
25.4%
15.9%
22.1%
12.5%
- uk
7.2%
5.1%
3.9%
3.5%
2.4%
2.0%
1.7%
- Netherlands
13.1%
6.2%
3.3%
5.0%
1.1%
2.5%
1.3%
- Rest of Europe
15.6%
20.8%
23.8%
16.9%
12.4%
17.6%
9.6%
Europe
Source: bps, Statistik Indonesia, various issues.
139
| Involution and Growth
The decades after independence are characterised by a continuous decline in Europe’s share in Indonesia’s export and import trade, in favour of Asia in particular. In 1990 more than 70 per cent of Indonesian exports went to other parts of Asia, of which Japan alone accounted for over 40 per cent. Booth notes that ‘in 1980 Japan was absorbing a slightly higher proportion of Indonesian exports than had the Netherlands a century earlier’ (Booth 1998: 210). Since the last decade of the twentieth century China gained importance as trading partner for Indonesia. Although China is not separately classified in the statistical yearbooks, the category other Asian countries increased significantly both for imports and for exports. Other important Asian trading partners are South Korea and Taiwan. Economist and Indonesia expert Hal Hill (2000: 85) argues that this re-orientation has not been the result of a conscious commercial strategy, but is due instead to fundamental economic forces. In this respect he lists three factors: 1) the rapid growth of the East Asian region; 2) stronger economic complementarities between low-wage, but resource-rich Indonesia and the resource-poor, high-wage economies of Japan and the Newly Industrialising Economies (nies); and 3) political-institutional changes which have gradually weakened old ties in favour of growing networks based on asean and other regional initiatives.
5.2.3
Trade policy Trade policy and protection are not recent phenomena. The voc imposed import and export duties almost immediately upon arrival in the Netherlands-Indies in the early seventeenth century (cei xiia 1991: 28). During the early decades of the twentieth century duties were in general quite low since the authorities did not want to impose too heavy a burden on the indigenous population. This Liberal Policy, which had its origins in the 1870s, was the result of growing influence of political and economic liberalism in the Netherlands since the 1850s (Fasseur 1978: 157). After the end of the First World War the government was of the opinion that rising costs necessitated an increase in the tax burden. This resulted in a rise of import duties on a number of products, and various hitherto tax-exempted products became dutiable. Protectionist arguments were not yet a real factor and the Netherlands-Indies were considered an open and unprotected economy (cei xiia 1991: 29; Booth 1998: 216). The Depression of the 1930s changed the situation. Now trade policy considerations became more and more important. Protection introduced in 1933 was especially aimed at limiting the influx of cheap Japanese goods, which threatened to displace imports from the Netherlands (Boediono and Pangestu 1986: 2; Booth 1998: 218-222). The main policy instruments at this time were discriminatory tariffs, import quotas and licences, rather than ad valorem tariffs. The policies were effective in raising the share of imports from the West at the expense of Japanese imports.
140
| Accounting for Services
As figure 5.3 shows, after independence trade policy became even more important, especially in increasing tax revenues and allocating scarce foreign resources. The importance of this kind of taxation is illustrated by the fact that government revenue from taxes on trade fluctuated between 32 and 66 per cent of total tax revenue between 1951 and 1957 (Boediono and Pangestu 1986: 3). Following the take-over of Dutch enterprises in 1957, and the subsequent period of ‘Guided Democracy’, trade policies only intensified, with an emphasis on indigenous Indonesian control over all aspects of economic activity. In April 1959 government trading houses obtained monopoly rights to import nine categories of goods which comprised 75 per cent of all imports (Boediono and Pangestu 1986: 5). Private importers could import only non-essential goods and the number of importers was restricted to 400 (Paauw 1963: 212). Moreover, government intervention in the retail trade, which was traditionally handled by Chinese and Indian traders, resulted in disruption in the distribution of goods and a scarcity of most consumer goods. The impact of government intervention in the trade sector is further reflected by the fact that in 1963 and 1964 about 70 per cent of government revenue came from foreign trade taxes (Boediono and Pangestu 1986: 6). This also shows the extreme dependence of government finance on trade taxes.
Figure 5.3 Foreign trade taxes as percentage of total government revenue
60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 1900
1910
1920
1930
1940
1950
1960
1970/71 1980/81 1990/91
Source: 1900-1939: cei ii 1990; 1950-2000: Statistik Indonesia, various issues.
141
| Involution and Growth
Thus we can see that during the early 1960s barriers to international trade were extensive. However, as a result of a series of packages introduced by the New Order government, by 1970 many of these barriers had been removed. Most export taxes were reduced, tariffs became the primary instrument of import protection and the tariff structure was simplified (Hill 2000: 114). This leads Hill (2000: 115) to conclude that ‘the late 1960s ushered in a period of economic liberalism in Indonesia’. During the 1970s sentiment changed. Import bans began to re-appear and regulation intensified after the oil boom, mainly to protect non-oil tradable activities. The second oil boom led to further trade restrictions with outright prohibitions and an ‘authorized importer system’ (Tata Niaga Impor). However, the revenue motive of foreign trade regulations was no longer important. The contribution of taxes on trade to total revenue declined from 38.2 per cent in 1968 to only 7.3 per cent in 1982. This fall was mainly due to a significant rise of taxes on oil companies, which provided more than 70 per cent of domestic revenue in 1982 (Boediono and Pangestu 1986: 8). In the mid-1980s trade was still highly regulated. There were extensive restrictions on foreign trade including high tariffs and a multitude of non-tariff import barriers (Bird and Manning 2003: 77). Moreover, import quotas increased mainly to the benefit of cronies close to the ‘first family’ who sought to capture monopoly profits (Basri 2001). When world oil prices fell and slower world economic growth depressed commodity prices in the early 1980s, this also heavily affected Indonesia. Growth slowed, trade and investment fell, debt increased and the government faced a major fiscal challenge because of falling oil revenues. These developments provoked discussion about the ‘high-cost’ economy and the uncompetitive nature of many Indonesian industries. Economists at the University of Indonesia urged extensive deregulation to get the Indonesian economy back on its growth path (Hill 2000: 116). Between 1986 and 2000 a number of policy reforms were implemented. Bird and Manning (2003: 78) divide this period into three phases. Firstly, there was a period of substantial trade and investment liberalisation from 1986 to 1991, followed by increasing signs of reform fatigue and government involvement in costly capitaland technology-intensive projects from 1991 to 1997. The third phase was the period of comprehensive reforms under the imf programme from 1998 onwards. The most important measures taken during this first phase were the devaluation of the rupiah in September 1986, discussed earlier, and a series of trade and investment deregulation packages, which substantially reduced tariff rates and eliminated most quantitative import restrictions (although these were replaced by tariffs). Average tariff rates fell from 27 per cent in 1986 to 20 per cent in 1991, 15 per cent in 1995 and only 7.3 per cent in 2001 (Bird and Manning 2003: 78). Furthermore, Fane and Condon (1996) found that the average Effective Rate of Protection (erp) for the non-oil manufacturing sector declined from 59 per cent in 1987 to 16 per cent in the early 1990s.
142
| Accounting for Services
Hill argues about this period: ‘There can be little doubt that the packages transformed Indonesian industry from a protected, inward-looking sector to one which is increasingly outwardlooking and internationally competitive. […] The reorientation of thinking over this period within the Department of Industry, extending up to the Minister, from protection and control to promotion and export, was clearly evident’ (Hill 2000: 117). This period of far-reaching trade reforms during the late 1980s slowed down in the early 1990s. A number of policy measures taken in the preceding years were reversed and crony capitalism became more widespread again. Moreover, many government monopolies and cartel arrangements remained relatively untouched. For example, a clove monopoly was granted to a private-state joint venture in 1991, tariff protection was granted to a large petrochemical plant in February 1995, and tax exemptions were granted to an automotive company in 1996 (Bird and Manning 2003: 79). Not surprisingly, all three companies were partly owned by then President Suharto’s children. The third phase was triggered by the Asian crisis in 1997/1998. The conditional help by the imf and major donors forced Indonesia to implement comprehensive policy reforms in many sectors and institutions. For international trade these reforms included reducing most tariff rates below 10 per cent, and eliminating most of the remaining Non-Tariff Barriers (ntbs). On the domestic trade side, reforms included removing several monopolies and cartels, including the agricultural monopolies of the State Logistics Agency (Badan Urusan Logistik, bulog). Additionally, many of the investment restrictions on domestic distribution were removed, including opening up wholesale and retail sectors to foreign investment. With respect to trade policy and regional economic development, it is worth mentioning a study by Garcia Garcia (2000). Looking at net rates of protection at a regional level he finds that Indonesia’s trade and price interventions since 1986 have been pro-Java and pro-urban. This has occurred because provinces that have different factor endowments, and productive activities have enjoyed different rates of protection. Garcia Garcia argues that Java, having a high labour/land ratio and produce most of Indonesia’s manufacturing output, has benefited more from trade policies than the Outer Islands which have a low labour/land ratio and a large endowment of natural resources (land, forest, fisheries, mining, oil and gas) and which produce most of the country’s output from natural resources. According to Garcia Garcia, interventions have protected manufacturing ten times as much as they have protected agriculture and forestry. In addition, the oil, gas and mining sectors have been taxed in such as a way as to incur a heavier burden on the Outer Islands compared to Java.
143
| Involution and Growth
5.2.4
Foreign trade as engine of growth The preceding sections have discussed the developments in Indonesia’s foreign trade and the way the government steered these through trade policy. The question remains, however, to what extent foreign trade has actually functioned as an engine of growth.
Figure 5.4
Openness and growth, 1900-1997
7%
1970-1980
1990-1997
6% y = 0,0679x + 0,0238 R² = 0,6336
------> GDP growth
5%
4%
1980-1990
1950-1960 1960-1970 1920-1930
3% 1900-1910
2%
1910-1920 1930-1940
y = 0,0841x - 0,0026 R² = 0,7573
1%
0% 0
0.1
0.2 1900-1940
0.3
0.4 1950-1997
0.,5
0.6 -------> Openess
Note: Decadal averages for growth and openness. Openness is measured as imports and exports divided by gdp. Sources: See figure 5.2.
Figure 5.4 gives some direction in this matter. This scatter diagram clearly shows that a greater openness of the economy, as measured by the ratio of total trade and gdp, is associated with higher growth rates. This suggests that foreign trade has indeed played an important role in Indonesia. Furthermore it is interesting to see that similar levels of openness were associated with higher growth rates in the postindependence period compared to the colonial period. Hanson (1980: 51; see also Booth 1998: 227) elaborates on the relation between trade and growth, He lists three conditions which need to be fulfilled in order for trade to contribute significantly to a country’s economic development:
144
| Accounting for Services
1) A large export sector, 2) Rapid export growth, especially in per capita terms, and 3) A comparative advantage in products with growth-promoting or at least nongrowth-retarding production functions. Table 5.6 summarises these conditions for Indonesia for different periods. It shows that in the period 1900-1929 the export sector accounted for a growing proportion of gdp (see also figure 5.2). Moreover, export volume growth per capita accelerated after 1900, and the direct contribution of exports to gdp growth was high. Booth, however, argues that the third factor was not met in this period. Indonesian export staples – sugar, tobacco, tin, rubber and palm oil – lacked ‘growth-promoting production functions’ (Booth 1998: 228), so that international trade failed to generate a broadly based development. Table 5.6
Trade and economic growth in Indonesia, 1900-1997
Growth volume of exports Average ratio of exports/gdp Direct contribution of exports to gdp growtha
1900-1929
1934-1941
1929-1967
1949-1961
1967-1997
5.6
2.2
3.0
2.3
5.6
0.195
0.163
0.094
0.078
0.207
42%
8%
2%
5%
19%
Note: a: Calculated as (average ratio exports/gdp) x (volume of exports growth/real gdp growth). Source: Van der Eng 2002: 155.
This changed, however, in the period 1967-1997. During this period growth in the volume of exports and the contribution of exports to gdp were both high. What is more important, though, is that the composition of export products also changed. Whereas in the colonial period agricultural products dominated exports, from independence until the early 1980s oil was the most important export product. Since then the role of oil has been overtaken by manufactured exports (Van der Eng 2002: 155; Hill 2000: 82). Through their backward linkages, these products have had a much greater impact on economic development in Indonesia (Athukorala and Santosa 1997: 89).
5.3
Domestic dynamics in the trade sector: involutionary growth?
5.3.1
Employment and labour productivity So far we have discussed developments in international trade. It was shown that periods in which Indonesia was open to trade were associated with higher growth rates. This underlines the importance of the trade sector as an engine of growth.
145
| Involution and Growth
However, domestic dynamics in the trade sector bring to light that the role of this sector in the process of economic development has been ambiguous. In this section I first turn attention to changes in employment in the trade sector. Table 5.7 shows the first stylised fact. Throughout the twentieth century the trade sector has become increasingly important as an employer. Especially in the 1960s and 1990s the growth of number of people working in trade was significantly higher than in other sectors. Table 5.8 shows the effect these changes in the number of people employed in the trade sector had on labour productivity. In the 1930s labour productivity in trading was high: almost four times as high as labour productivity in agriculture and considerably higher than that in industry. However, whereas labour productivity in those other sectors increased, productivity in trade fell dramatically up to 1971. During the 1970s the trade sector clearly benefited from the profitable exports of oil. During the 1980s productivity growth slowed down and even fell in the 1990s. Strikingly, only in 1990 was productivity in trading higher than it was in the 1930s. These developments in labour productivity in trading reflect how the Indonesian trade sector has transformed from one dominated by merchants to one in which peddlers are predominant. This is a process that I would term ‘involution’ in the trade sector. The concept of involution is usually associated with the anthropologist Clifford Geertz (1963). However, it was initially an American anthropologist, Alexander Goldenweiser, who devised it in the 1930s ‘to describe those culture patterns which, after having reached what would seem to be a definitive form, nonetheless fail either to stabilize or transform themselves into a new pattern but rather continue to develop by becoming internally more complicated’ (Geertz 1963: 80-81). This is exactly what, in my opinion, occurs in the trade sector. To see how, it is necessary to discuss how the trade sector was organised during the colonial era and thereafter.
Table 5.7 Occupational structure, 1905-2000 Agriculture
146
Manufacturing
Trade
Other sectors
1905
67.9%
5.6%
5.1%
21.4%
1930
68.4%
10.6%
6.2%
14.8%
1961
71.9%
5.7%
6.7%
15.7%
1971
64.2%
6.5%
10.3%
19.0%
1980
56.4%
9.0%
13.0%
21.6%
1990
55.9%
10.1%
14.6%
19.4%
2000
45.3%
13.0%
20.6%
21.2%
Source: Population censuses.
| Accounting for Services
Table 5.8
Labour productivity in Indonesia’s service sector, 1905-2000 (in 1993 Rp per labourer) Agriculture
Industry (excl. oil and gas)
Trade
Transport & Total service sector communications
1905
825.6
4,102.9
2,878.8
1,548.1
2,122.7
1930
978.0
3,288.9
3,894.5
2,924.9
3,612.9
1961
830.2
3,766.7
2,458.9
3,278.6
1,727.8
1971
972.2
4,406.8
2,001.8
3,212.3
1,480.8
1980
1,322.6
5,289.1
3,425.8
5,101.4
2,623.7
1990
1,277.8
8,078.5
4,202.4
7,077.7
4,171.4
2000
1,677.3
10,830.9
3,115.8
6,964.6
4,252.6
Sources: Employment figures: Population censuses; gdp estimates: for Agriculture and Industry: Van der Eng 2002; other sectors: Author’s estimates.
Table 5.9
Average annual labour productivity growth (in percentages), 1930-2000 Trade
Transport & communications
Total service sector
Total labour productivity
Agriculture
Industry (excl. oil and gas)
1905-1930
0.68
-0.88
1.22
2.58
2.15
-1.18
1930-1961
-0.53
0.44
-1.47
0.37
-2.35
-0.53
1961-1971
1.59
1.58
-2.04
-0.20
-1.53
0.99
1971-1980
3.48
2.05
6.15
5.27
6.56
5.92
1980-1990
-0.34
4.33
2.06
3.33
4.75
3.25
1990-2000
2.76
2.98
-2.95
-0.16
0.19
3.06
Source: Based on table 5.7.
5.3.2
Changes in the organisation of distribution Initially economic activities in Indonesia were organised with the objective of as much benefit as possible for the Netherlands (Gonggrijp 1948; Rutgers 1947). Panglaykim and Palmer (1969) argue that, due to a lack of restraints on Dutch businesses, small firms gradually developed into powerful groups, thereby extending their control over various important links in the marketing channels. These firms, which in many respects resemble existing conglomerates, were very influential in the economy of Indonesia. The most influential commercial companies, known as the ‘Big Ten’, were Internatio, Borsumij, Jacobson van den Berg, Geo Wehry, Lindeteves, Maclaine Watson (British), Moluksche Handelsvereeniging, Tels & Co., Deli Atjeh, and Mirandolle & Voute (Panglaykim 1968: 37; Panglaykim and Palmer 1969: 2). The Dutch controlled both most imports from abroad and the outlets for commercial crops to the world market, exercising their control through the credit system. Panglaykim and Palmer (1969: 4) give a detailed illustration of how this marketing structure functioned: consumer goods were imported from overseas by Dutch commercial houses. These goods were subsequently distributed to Chinese middlemen (wholesalers) who then divided them amongst the smaller middlemen (retailers)
147
| Involution and Growth
living in the remote areas. Periodically, these small middlemen went to the various collecting points of the main traffic arteries trading consumer goods, raw materials, equipment and some cash with the farmers in return for their commercial crops. The crops collected this way were then taken to the small towns where the small middlemen lived; there they were sorted and then transported to the cities at regular intervals. All these activities were carried out regularly and continuously. The smaller middlemen who had done the collecting periodically settled accounts with the Chinese wholesale middlemen, taking back with them the finished goods they needed for their next trip to the collecting points. Similarly, in the cities, the Chinese wholesale middlemen carried out the final sorting and grading. They then delivered the agricultural or forest products, ready for export, to the Dutch commercial houses, with whom they settled accounts so that they in turn were able to purchase fresh supplies for the collectors. This structure is illustrated in figure 5.5.
Figure 5.5 Marketing structure Indonesia, ca. 1900-1940
D utch trading house
Settles accounts
Provides working capital
Chinese middlemen (wholesaler)
Provides working capital
Settles accounts
C hinese middlemen (retailer)
Trades consumer goods, equipment, raw materials
For commercial goods
Farmers
The Chinese traders thus served as the link between the unorganised sector, consisting of millions of farmers, and the organised sector of Dutch import and export firms. The under-development of the infrastructure (transportation and communications facilities, finance, etc.) strengthened the position of the various middlemen in the chain making them virtually the only outlet for the farmers’ products. Panglaykim and Palmer therefore conclude that ‘In most cases the near-monopolistic position of the middlemen financed by the big firms left the farmers generally little choice but to accept the traders’ terms’ (1969: 5).
148
| Accounting for Services
Now, how can these findings explain the relatively high labour productivity in 1930? Firstly, the organisation of the trade sector made it highly profitable. These high levels of labour productivity do not so much reflect efficiency in the trade sector; it would be more accurate to say they mirror the profits made, although Jonker and Sluyterman (2000: 211, 251) argue that dividends paid by the large trading houses were never impressive. A second point has to be added here. During the colonial era Indonesia was still very much an agrarian economy. Although some industrialisation took place, especially in Java, the majority of the population still lived as peasants, providing for their own needs. Therefore the less productive retail sector was relatively underdeveloped. Goods were usually traded from farmers to Chinese to Dutch trading houses and then on the world market. This point is strengthened if we look at how margins in wholesaling and retailing differ. In an interesting study on trading in rural Java, anthropologist Jennifer Alexander (1987) describes the following marketing structure. The producer usually sells his goods through an agent to a depot. From this depot the goods are further distributed. Either through regional markets, town markets or village markets (or a combination of them) goods are distributed to the consumers. The left hand-side of figure 5.6 corresponds more or less with figure 5.5. Figure 5.6 Marketing structure in rural Java, 1982
W holesale trading
R etail trading R egional M arket (B akul)
A gent
V illage M arket (B akul) D epot (Juragan)
P roducer
R egional M arket (Juragan )
T ow n M arket (Juragan )
T ow n M arket (B akul)
C onsum er
V illage W arung
Source: Alexander 1987: 58.
As table 5.10 shows the largest gain is made by the agent who buys from the producer and sells to the depot, an action categorised as wholesaling. The smaller gains are made in the distribution through village markets and village warung, i.e. in retailing.
149
| Involution and Growth
Table 5.10 Trade margins in rural Java, 1982 Market level
Sale price per kg (in Rp)
Producer
25
Agent
28
Depot
60
Regional market
65
District market
75
Village market
90-110
Village warung
95-115
Source: Alexander 1987: 59.
Table 5.11 Employment in trade sector: 1905-2000 Population (x1,000) 1905 1930 1961 1971 1980 1990 2000
29,716 40,891 62,993 76,102 91,217 107,526 na
Population (x1,000) 1905 1930 1961 1971 1980 1990 2000
7,305 18,247 34,026 42,357 55,560 71,722 na
Population (x1,000)
150
1905 1930 1961 1971 1980 1990
37,020 59,138 97,019 118,460 146,776 179,248
2000
205,843
Sources: See table 5.7.
| Accounting for Services
Java & Madura Employed in trade sector (x1,000) Men Women 275 358 325 584 1,666 1,756 1,521 2,507 2,519 3,914 3,733 na na Outer Islands Employed in trade sector (x1,000) Men Women na na 124 58 528 575 262 971 683 1,547 1,346 na na Indonesia Employed in trade sector (x1,000) Men Women 275 358 449 642 2,194 2,331 1,783 3,478 3,201 5,461 5,079 9,686
8,813
Number per 1,000 21 22 26 43 55 71 na
Number per 1,000 na 10 16 20 30 40 na
Number per 1,000 17 18 23 35 46 59 90
The major difference between the distribution chain in the colonial period and the period since independence is that the emphasis has shifted from profitable wholesale trading (i.e. mainly the depot function), which was dominated by the Dutch and to a lesser extent by the Chinese middlemen, to low-value added retailing. When the big business houses were dissolved following nationalisation in 1959, a void was left behind. The newly established state trading corporation ‘lacked the linkages – backward through the chain of middlemen to the villages and forward through their own contacts and ancillary services with world markets – which had constituted much of the secret of the success of the Dutch commercial houses’ (Panglaykim 1968: 57). An increasing number of people have taken the opportunity since then to fill this void. In other words, the trade sector has developed into a sector in which more and more people share the crumbs. Or in Goldenweiser’s definition of involution, the result was ‘progressive complication, variety within uniformity’ (1936: 103).
5.3.3
Involutionary growth Retailing existed already in the colonial period. Alexander and Alexander (1990: 38) note that in 1905 there were 2,800 official marketplaces (pasar) in Java and at least 28,000 village stores (warung) (see also omw, via 1909: App. 7). What has changed, however, is the scale of this retail trade. This is supported by population censuses throughout the twentieth century as well as by an indirect estimate of the size of the informal sector from 1960 onwards. The census of 1930 showed that in Java and Madura one million natives made their living by trading in foodstuffs or preparing food, while another 100,000 lived by trading in miscellaneous goods. A further examination of the census figures reveals that the retail trade was of more importance in Java and Madura than in the Outer Islands. And, within Java, trade was a more common profession in Central and East Java than in West Java. De Vries and Cohen relate this difference to a more differentiated diet. ‘This means a mixed diet that involves a great variety of side-dishes [;...] consequently many people are able to make a living as small traders where such a diet prevails’ (De Vries and Cohen 1937: 268). The ultimate source of this mixed diet was of course rising income, which is also acknowledged by De Vries and Cohen. They rightly argue that the need for petty trade grows in proportion to the increase in the number of native businesses and small industries, such as for example that of sugar, change the society from subsistence farming to a more market-oriented one in which income can be augmented. At the same time, only 6.2 per cent of the population were employed in the trade sector in 1930 (see table 5.11). This share did not change much until the 1960s when it increased from 6.7 per cent in 1961 to more than 10 per cent in 1971. Between 1971 and 2000 the trade sector became the most important non-agricultural employer with 1 out of 5 workers having a job in the trade sector in 2000. Another point that draws the attention is the role of women in the trade sector. It was not only the case that the majority of women were employed in this sector, but
151
| Involution and Growth
in Java and Madura women also outnumbered men by a factor of 1.8 in 1930. This was not new either. As early as 1683 voc officials were already noting: ‘Women who, instead of taking up some honest business by which to earn a living decently, seek to make a little money by sitting all day by the road-side selling a few vegetables and other little things of small value, and do this in such multitudes that they jostle each other and create great disorder in the market place, beside depriving one another of profit and the possibility of obtaining a sufficient living from this trafficking.’ (De Vries and Cohen 1937: 264) Manning notes, in this respect, that the trade sector accounted for many more new jobs for women than either manufacturing or services in the period 1971-1990, both in Java and the Outer Islands (Manning 1998: 251). In the Outer Islands Manning attributes this to the expansion of roads and the subsequent beginning of more intensive rural-urban trade links. Trade in Java remained mainly a rural occupation, mostly small-scale. Contrary to the common view, Alexander and Booth (1992: 297-299) found that in the early 1980s most of this petty trade was on a full-time basis, non-seasonal in nature, and in operation for some years. However, because of declining cottage industries, more women crowded into trade, which eroded this privileged position. There are many studies that describe how women, who found it hard to make ends meet in rural Java, in both agriculture and traditional industries, moved into petty trade in the growing cities (see for example Lehrman 1983; and Hetler 1989). But it was not only women who increasingly found employment in petty trade. Since independence the number of men working in trade has been catching up. This is especially due to the ‘informalisation of the urban economy’ (Manning 1998: 103), in which non-waged jobs in petty trade and other services – such as household servants, barbers, service repair shops and tailors – in particular grew rapidly. Anthropologist Benjamin White (1991: 47) came to similar conclusions for early twentieth century Java. He argues that the shift to labour into non-farm activities was due more to ‘push’ than to ‘pull’ factors. The lack of agricultural opportunities to make an adequate living pushed labourers into activities that were easily accessible and had low capital requirements, of which retail trade is a perfect example. This pattern is supported by an indirect estimate of the size of the informal sector which can be arrived at by using an estimation method devised by the International Labour Organization (ilo) (see also Frankema 2008: 171-172). This is a crude but conceptually consistent method of arriving at a proximate estimate of the size of the urban informal sector on the basis of labour force data derived from household surveys, labour force sample surveys and population censuses. The method basically involves a decomposition of the economically active population by employment status. Firstly, the labour force is split up into the categories of own-account workers (self-employed workers and employers), wage earners (including salaried
152
| Accounting for Services
employees) and unpaid family workers. Then the category of own-account workers is further subdivided into self-employed working in agriculture (farmers), professional and technical self-employed (i.e. lawyers, technicians, supervisors etc.) and other self-employed. The combined share of the non-agricultural self-employed and unpaid family workers in the total economically active population, corrected for the share of professionals, technicians and employers, is taken as a proxy for the size of the urban informal sector (prealc 1982; ilo 1993). For Indonesia these figures can be retrieved from annual issues of bps, Statistik Indonesia and the ilo, Yearbook of Labour Statistics. The limitations of this method relate to the general lack of possibility to further decompose the heterogeneous category of urban own-account workers. Thus, it may tend to over-estimate the size of the urban informal sector by including people working in micro-enterprises in the formal urban economy, such as one-man retail businesses. On the other hand, this effect is countervailed by workers with a first job in the formal sector and a second job in the informal sector to complement their incomes. The main advantage of this method, however, is that it is based on a uniform concept of employment status, which is relatively comparable over time and across countries. The specific advantage for the case of Indonesia is that the data required to compute this indicator are available for a relatively large amount of benchmark years. The time series for the years 1965-2003 are displayed in figure 5.7. For those years for which detailed information on the professional own-account workers is missing, a linear interpolation technique is used to estimate its share. It should be noted that this group usually constitutes a tiny share of the total labour force in developing countries. In Indonesia in 1976 its share of the total economically active population was 1.9 per cent; it was 3.4 per cent in 1985 and 3.5 percent in 1992. In other words, the interpolation exercise is not likely to cause major errors in the estimation procedure. Nevertheless, for transparency both a crude estimate (without a correction for the professional own-account workers) and a refined estimate is given. It should be noted that the correlation coefficient of both time-series is 0.97, where the absolute levels of the refined estimate tend to be somewhat higher because of the inclusion of the category of unpaid family workers. Figure 5.7 shows that the share of urban informal sector workers in the total labour force almost doubled from 13.8 per cent in 1965 to a maximum of 25.0 per cent in 1999, in the wake of the Asian crises. Since 1999 the share has declined to 22.0 per cent. If we look at this long-term trend in more detail it appears that it was particularly in the economically difficult years of the early 1980s and the final years of Suharto’s presidency before the Asian crisis that the urban informal sector expanded most rapidly. It is also noteworthy that from the 1980s until the early 1990s the trend line appears to be more or less horizontal, fluctuating around 20 per cent. In this same period the share of the trade sector in total employment did not change much either (see table 5.7).
153
| Involution and Growth
Figure 5.7
Share of urban self-employed in the total labour force, 1965-2003
Sources: bps, Statistical Yearbook of Indonesia (Statistik Indonesia), various issues 1975-2003; and ilo, Yearbook of Labour Statistics, various issues 1966-1995.
In table 5.12 these levels are compared with those of a selection of the world’s economically most advanced countries. It turns out that in those countries the share of self-employed has declined significantly since the 1930s, typically to a level between 7 and 10 per cent of the total labour force, indicating that the size as well as the direction of the trend of the urban informal sector in Indonesia is markedly different from more advanced countries. Table 5.12
1930/31
Share of urban self-employed in total labour force in a selection of economically advanced countries,1930-1999 usa
Canada
0.08
0.09
0.11
uk
France
Netherlands
Denmark
Sweden
Japan
0.16
0.14
0.17
0.18
0.15
1960/71
0.07
0.08
0.07
0.11
0.11
0.11
0.06
0.13
1993/99
0.07
0.08
0.10
0.08
0.09
0.07
0.08
0.07
Source: Frankema 2008: 172.
The overall trend for Indonesia is very much in line with the literature that states that the urban informal sector has expanded considerably since the 1960s (Thorbecke 1991: 1596; Manning 1998: 103; Booth 2000: 81; Butzer et al. 2003). In my opinion, this exactly reflects the type of involutionary growth in the trade sector as defined
154
| Accounting for Services
by Goldenweiser. The trade sector has transformed into an internally more complicated organisation, in which an increasing number of people share the crumbs. This development is also reflected in the relative decline in labour productivity in the trade sector, similar to what has happened in Latin American countries. For instance, in a study by Mulder (1999) of the development of service industries in Brazil and Mexico, it is argued that the rise in the urban informal sector coincided with a marked decline in the relative productivity performance of the trade and commerce sector. After a gradual increase, the ratio of relative productivity levels in Brazilian trade versus that in the usa dropped sharply, from a peak of 34 per cent in 1975 to 13 per cent in 1995 (the end year of Mulder’s analysis). The Mexico-us ratio dropped after a peak of 25 per cent in 1982 to 12 per cent in 1995 (Mulder 1999: 152). Mulder attributes the sharp turn in the mid-1970s (Brazil) and early 1980s (Mexico) to the swelling numbers of petty traders in the urban areas. This explanation is supported by ilo labour survey data (ilo, Yearbook of Labour Statistics 19931995) showing that the lion-share of the urban self-employed in Latin American Countries (lacs) is registered in the trade and commerce sector. In the majority of lacs the share of self-employed (including unpaid family workers) consists of more than half of total employment in the trade sector in the early 1990s. By comparison, in Canada and the usa this share does not exceed 10 per cent. Indeed, the Latin American trade sector functioned as an important safety net for growing surpluses of low-skilled urban labour. These labourers did not benefit from the social benefits and wage increases demanded by labour unions representing formal sector workers (Frankema 2008: 175-180). In the case of Indonesia, Manning (1998: 96) also argues that employment growth of non-wage earners was especially rapid in petty trade. In an extensive study on the informal sector in Indonesia conducted in 1977, Hidayat (1978) estimated that of those employed in the informal sector 50 per cent were working in trade. The literature thus suggests that there have been similar processes of structural change in Latin America and Indonesia (see also Portes and Benton 1984; Tokman 1984). This would imply that relative levels of productivity in the Indonesian trade sector, as opposed to other service sectors, will show a tendency in future to decline as well. Figure 5.8 presents estimates of average labour productivity in various service sectors, while total service sector labour productivity is held constant (set at 1.00). The figure shows that in the usa productivity levels in the trade sector gradually increased in comparison to other service industries, such as transport and communication, financial services, personal and social services, and government services. In Brazil, Mexico and Indonesia a notable decline can be observed. Hence, the development of the urban informal sector in Indonesia displays some remarkable similarities with that in Brazil, Mexico and Chile during the period 1950-2005.
155
| Involution and Growth
Figure 5.8
Relative levels of labour productivity, trade sector versus other service sectors, usa, Brazil, Mexico and Indonesia USA ( 1950-1997)
002
002
001
001
001
Mexico (1950-2003)
001
1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 Trade sector
1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 Trade sector
Other service sectors
Indonesia (1961-2005)
Brazil (1950-2003) 002
002
001
001
001
Other service sectors
001
1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 Trade sector
1961 1966 1971 1976 1981 1986 1991 1996 2001
Other service sectors
Trade sector
Other service sectors
Source: Author’s calculations from Timmer and de Vries 2007.
5.4
Concluding remarks The role of trade in economic development has been an on-going debate. The neoclassical theory suggests that exports lead to increasing specialisation, greater economies of scale due to an enlargement of the market size, and more rapid technological change. At the same time, the trade sector in many developing countries also functions as an employer of last resort. Because of its flexibility, low-skilled jobs, limited capital requirements and low entry barriers, this sector absorbs those workers pushed out of the agricultural sector and unable to find work in manufacturing. This chapter has highlighted the developments in Indonesia both in foreign trade and in organisation of the trade sector between 1900 and 2000. The main conclusion is that the Indonesian trade sector fulfilled an ambiguous function. On the one hand it did indeed function as an engine of growth. Both
156
| Accounting for Services
during the colonial period and after independence sensible trade policies resulted in periods of strong growth fuelled by economies of scale and technological change. At the same time, the lack of openness to trade may partially explain the stagnation in the 1950s. In sum, there has been a positive association between openness to trade and gdp growth. The domestic dynamics in the trade sector have been rather different, though. It has been shown that in this respect the trade sector has functioned as a safety net for those unable to find (enough) work in agriculture or manufacturing. In the colonial period the trade sector was dominated by the large Dutch trading houses in collaboration with Chinese middlemen. Clearly, retail trade did already exist, possibly even to a larger extent than the official statistics suggest because of by-employment. But it was not yet the sector of last resort. Most people were still working in the agricultural sector, with an increasing number finding employment in the rising manufacturing sector. In the past few decades this has changed. Since the late 1960s especially both the absolute and the relative numbers of people working in the trade sector have increased rapidly, whereas labour productivity is still below levels reached in the 1930s. Moreover, in relative terms labour productivity in the trade sector has declined markedly. A transformation has taken place of a sector dominated by highly profitable wholesale trade in the colonial period into one in which an almost endless chain of traders is involved in the distribution process created an ‘internally complicated organisation’. This process is, in my opinion, well conveyed by the term ‘involution’.
157
| Involution and Growth
158
| Accounting for Services
6
Unity or diversity?
Market integration through trade and transport
6.1
Introduction The motto of Indonesia is Bhinneka Tunggal Ika, which is Old Javanese and is often loosely translated as ‘Unity in Diversity’. Literally it means ‘(Although) in pieces, yet One’. Whether this slogan can be applied to Indonesia’s economy is debatable. It is clear that in Indonesia the emergence of an integrated national economy has been a slow and on-going evolutionary process. Dick et al. (2002: 10) argue that the structure of a national economy came into being only during the presidency of Suharto. They base this finding mainly on the fact that inter-island trade has only risen significantly since the late 1960s (Dick et al. 2002: 24-32). But an increase in inter-island trade is only suggestive evidence of the creation of a ‘national economy’. This chapter aims to give a more satisfactory answer to this question by assessing the process of market integration in Indonesia during the twentieth century using rice price series for a number of cities across the archipelago. In this way it is possible to evaluate whether developments in the two largest service sectors, i.e. trade and transport as discussed in the preceding two chapters, have enhanced economic development. The reasoning behind this is that increased efficiency in these sectors is a necessary, but not sufficient condition for economic development. Only when efficient and affordable transport and trade networks result in integrated and efficient markets can an economy develop to its full potential. Therefore this chapter assesses to what extent the developments in the transport and trade sectors indeed resulted in integrated and efficient markets in Indonesia in the twentieth century. As an instrument to measure market efficiency and market integration I will make use of rice price series, not only because these are relatively abundant for a number of cities across the archipelago and covering more or less the whole twentieth century, but also because rice plays a central role in Indonesia’s economy. Therefore stable rice prices through an integrated market, which is facilitated by efficient transport and trade networks, can be considered of crucial importance for economic development in Indonesia. Rice production accounted for about 50 per cent of total value added in agriculture throughout the twentieth century (Van der Eng 1996b: 259-263). And despite the fact that agriculture as a percentage of total gdp has been declining steadily,
159
| Unity or diversity?
especially since the 1970s, almost 10 per cent of gdp is still earned in rice production today. But it is not only as a source of income that rice plays a significant role in the Indonesian economy: on the consumption side, as well, is rice the most important product. In 2001 on average 14 per cent of a family’s budget was spent on rice, varying from close to 30 per cent for the poor to only 2.5 per cent for the very rich (bps, Statistical Yearbook 2001). Since Engel’s Law seems to hold for rice consumption, in earlier stages of development rice was probably even a more important expenditure item than it is today. Considering the importance of rice in the Indonesian economy, it can be argued that a well-functioning rice market is a precondition for economic development. This is in line with the neo-institutional approach developed by North (1981, 1990). According to this school of economics, well-protected property rights and low transaction costs are necessary for efficient markets, which in turn make processes of commercialisation and specialisation possible. Van Zanden (2004) showed that institutional failures resulted in extreme fluctuations in rice prices in Java during the first half of the nineteenth century. In combination with the poor integration of the rice market, this meant that peasants had weak incentives to increase production for the market. This is arguably one of the reasons behind the slow economic development of Java during the nineteenth century. Twentieth-century Indonesia forms an excellent laboratory in which to further analyse the relation between efficient markets and economic growth. Data on rice prices are relatively abundant. Moreover, economic development in Indonesia during the twentieth century can safely be characterised as erratic. Periods of growth alternated with recessions. Taking a long-term perspective enables us to draw conclusions about the role that efficient markets have played in the economic development of Indonesia. Studies empirically testing market efficiency in Indonesia are scarce. Several descriptive studies evaluating rice market performance are available (Timmer 1974; World Bank 1987; Food and Agriculture Organization 1991; Pearsson et al. 1991; Tabor 1992). Prior to the Green Revolution, Mears (1961) conducted a study and concluded that rice markets in Indonesia did not function efficiently. Squires and Tabor (1987) econometrically tested for rice market integration in Java using Granger (1981) causality tests, finding the Javanese rice market to be integrated. Alexander and Wyeth (1994) introduced cointegration tests to study rice market integration in Indonesia between 1979 and 1990. They concluded that markets were integrated during this period. Ismet et al. (1998) tested for market integration for the period 1982-1993 and found that relative to the pre-self-sufficiency period (1982-1984), the post-self-sufficiency period (1985-1993) had a smaller degree of market integration. This chapter adds to the current debate in one important aspect. Whereas prior studies cover only short periods, I analyse the functioning of the rice market in Indonesia from a long-term perspective. Looking at both price stability and market inte-
160
| Accounting for Services
gration under the different regimes (i.e. colonial administration, Sukarno, Suharto and post-Suharto) and relating this to economic growth will, I hope, enhance our understanding of Indonesia’s long-term economic development. The underlying hypothesis is that more stable prices and better-integrated markets are conditioned by efficient trade networks and an adequate physical infrastructure. The remainder of the chapter will be organised as follows. Section 6.2 deals with the theoretical relation between stable food prices, market integration and economic development. In section 6.3 inter-temporal price variations in Indonesia’s rice market are discussed. In section 6.4 we shift attention to spatial market integration. Section 6.5 concludes.
6.2
Stable food prices, market integration and economic development The positive relationship between market integration and economic development is widely accepted in economic theory. The neo-classical argument is that expansion and integration of markets lead to improvements in productivity through the spreading of fixed costs, economies of scale and an increasing division of labour. But there is another argument as to why better-integrated markets enhance economic development: through price stabilisation. American economist and expert on the Indonesian rice market C. Peter Timmer (1996) states that ‘where food prices have not been stabilized successfully and food security remains questionable, political stability and economic growth [have] been threatened (1996: 46).’ Timmer (1989a, 1996) discusses a number of reasons why price stabilisation is economically beneficial (see also Dawe 1997). Firstly, unstable prices result in displaced investments in physical capital. Price instability means that investments become riskier. This leads to investments that are lower than would be optimal for the society as a whole. For example, society would benefit from investments in irrigation because it will enhance technological development. With unexpectedly fluctuating prices, such an investment is too risky for an individual farmer, because whether he will profit from it depends on the (uncertain) future price. Secondly, price instability leads to substitution of savings and work for consumption and leisure. Of course this increases the welfare of the farm family, but the shift in allocation of time and resources is not optimal for economic growth. Thirdly, unstable prices cause transaction costs for consumers in re-allocating their budgets when prices change. Compared to rich consumers, poor consumers are likely to value this aspect more. For example, if a food crop constitutes 20-30 per cent of a consumer’s expenditure, then a doubling of prices may require a re-allocation of a quarter of total expenditure. A fourth reason why unstable food prices can influence economic growth is the inter-linkage with macro-economic factors. For example, at the beginning of the
161
| Unity or diversity?
modern economic growth process in Indonesia in the late 1960s, rice accounted for one-quarter of gdp and one-third of employment. Hence, instability in rice prices causes macro-economic instability which in turn lowers economic growth. Fifthly, price instability affects the industrial sector. Stability in money wages can be achieved only if food prices are stable. When this is the case, it is likely to induce investments in labour-intensive machinery, improving the efficiency of technology choice in low-wage economies. Besides, if stable food prices contribute to a stable political environment in which investors can form secure long-term expectations, the overall level of investment is likely to be stimulated. The above factors lead Timmer to conclude that ‘food security and economic growth interact with each other in a mutually reinforcing process over the course of development’ (Timmer 2004: 2). An instrument to safeguard stability in food prices is market integration. Given the price inelasticity in demand for rice, deviations from a normal price normally reflect uncontrollable supply shocks (Persson 1999: 7-8). An integrated market can mitigate the effect of such price shocks because it induces trade between surplus and deficit areas. If a market is integrated and a harvest failure drives up prices in market A, arbitrage opportunities arise. Traders from other markets will be attracted by the high prices in market A and start selling their goods there. This will lower prices in market A and increase prices in the other markets until an equilibrium is reached. In other words, there is a ‘spatial cancelling out of harvest disturbances’ (Persson 1999: 9). In conclusion, expansion and integration of markets lead, on the one hand, to improvements in productivity through economies of scale, the spreading of fixed costs and an increasing division of labour. On the other hand, market integration can have a positive effect on economic growth because it enhances price stabilisation. Now let us turn attention to the empirical examination of how prices in the rice market have fluctuated over time in Indonesia.
6.3
Intertemporal rice price stabilisation in Indonesia: government intervention Figure 6.1 shows the monthly fluctuations in the rice prices in Indonesia between 1920 and 2006. Due to data availability the period 1920-1940 only covers Java. It is based on the average price of rice on 120 native markets. From 1949 onwards prices refer to Indonesia as a whole. It is likely that the average levels off the fluctuations For the relation between macro-economic instability and economic growth, see for example Dawe 1996, Barro and Sala-I-Martin 1995. For examples of studies of areas where a lack of market integration resulted in famines, see Sen 1981; Ravallion 1987; Von Braun, Teklu and Webb 1999.
162
| Accounting for Services
in the individual markets. If a farmer has access only to one or two markets the average price fluctuation will underestimate the true risk faced by a farmer. This is confirmed by the dashed line which represents the Jakarta market for rice. However, although fluctuations in the Jakarta market alone are higher, the trend is the same.
Figure 6.1 Rice price fluctuations, 1920-2006 1 0,8 0,6 0,4 0,2 0 -0,2 -0,4 -0,6 1920
1930
1940
1950 Jakarta
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
Indonesia average
Note: Fluctuations are expressed as monthly deviations from a 13-month moving average. The period 1920-1940 refers to Java only. Sources: 1920-1939: cks (1938); Statistisch Jaaroverzicht; Korte Berichten voor landbouw, nijverheid en handel (Appendix: Maandstatistieken van het Centraal Kantoor voor de Statistiek. Prijzen en indexcijfers in ni); Maandcijfers betreffende den economischen toestand der inheemsche bevolking op Java en Madoera, deel A; 1949-1956: Mears (1961); 1957-1968: Warta bps; 1969-1984: Statistik Bulog; 1985-2000: Laporan Mingguan Bank Indonesia; 2000-2006: Statistik Ekonomi Moneter Indonesia.
From figure 6.1 we can conclude that price developments of rice have been rather erratic during the twentieth century. It is striking to see fluctuations of only ±10 per cent in the 1920s, decreasing even further in the 1930s. This can be partly attributed to increasing rice imports during the dry season, as between 1900 and 1929 about 9 per cent of Indonesia’s domestic rice supply was imported (see table 6.1). This share was high enough to have an impact on domestic price formation (Van der Eng 1996b: 184; cei iv 1978: 19).
163
| Unity or diversity?
Table 6.1
Net rice imports as percentage of domestic supply, 1900-2000 Java
Outer Islands
Total
1900-1909
4.2
9.5
6.1
1910-1919
8.1
11.1
9.2
1920-1929
6.9
11.2
8.6
1930-1939
2.3
9.7
5.2
1950-1959
6.2
1960-1969
7.6
1970-1979
8.2
1980-1989
1.7
1990-1999
1.9
Sources: 1900-1989: Van der Eng 1996b: 183; 1990-1999: faostat.
But the rather small fluctuations also suggest that the distribution system in colonial Java was well enough developed to guarantee a stable spread of the supply of the marketed rice over the entire island (Van der Eng 1996b: 191; see also cei iv 1978: 16). However, price stabilisation did not come as ‘manna from heaven’. Intervention by the colonial government significantly contributed to price stability; as early as 1911 the government intervened in the rice market in reaction to extreme shortages (Creutzberg 1974: 171). But the rice market was in general left to its own devices until the effects of the international crisis after 1929 led the colonial government to introduce measures to protect the domestic rice economy (cei iv 1978: 21; Timmer 1991: 235). The colonial government not only intervened indirectly through trade restrictions and tax policy, it also intervened directly by purchasing rice in surplus areas, in order to avoid rice hoarding for speculation and to guarantee the supply of rice at affordable prices in deficit areas (Van der Eng 1996b: 186; Creutzberg 1974: 119120). The purchased paddy was subsequently sold to government institutes, such as the army, navy, police, prisons, hospitals and government enterprises and to large private companies in the Outer Islands. These measures were backed by the promotion of inter-urban and inter-island transport from surplus areas. For example, rice imports into some parts of the Outer Islands were forbidden to further the shipment from Java to these islands. Moreover, revenues from the rice import tax were used to subsidise the freight rates for food crops (Van der Eng 1996b: 185). In 1939 the government founded the semi-private Food Supply Board (Voedingsmiddelenfonds, vmf), which co-ordinated the stabilisation of rice prices. vmf had a monopoly on rice imports, and it controlled the inter-island shipments of rice through licences. As a result of these policies, net imports dwindled and Java became a net exporter of rice in 1940, whereas Indonesia as a whole became selfsufficient in rice in 1941.
164
| Accounting for Services
Figure 6.1 suggests that this re-arrangement of rice trade from dependence on imported rice to domestically produced rice did not have a negative effect on the goal of price stabilisation, with fluctuations in the 1930s being lower than in the 1920s.
Figure 6.2 Price fluctuations, Java vs Outer Islands, 1949-2006 0,8 0,6 0,4 0,2 0 -0,2 -0,4 -0,6 1949
1954
1959
1964
1969
1974
Java
Note: Deviation from 13-month moving average.
Sources: As for figure 6.1.
1979
1984
1989
1994
1999
2004
Outer Islands
During the 1950s and 1960s price fluctuations increased. This could be just a statistical artefact due to the inclusion of markets in the Outer Islands. However, as can be seen in figure 6.2 that is not the case. The difference in monthly deviations from a 13-month centred moving average between Java and the Outer Islands is negligible. And the small difference that appears suggests that prices in Java fluctuate more than in the Outer Islands. Apparently the successors to the vmf did not succeed in stabilising rice prices. This can be attributed both to inefficient organisation and to inefficient policy goals. After independence food logistics management was in the hands of two different institutions. Rice marketing was the responsibility of the Yayasan Urusan Bahan Makanan (yubm), while paddy purchasing activities were done under the authority of the Yayasan Badan Pembelian Padi (ybpp). Under Presidential Decree No. 3/1964 yubm and ybpp were merged into Badan Pelaksanan Urusan Pangan (bpup) with the objective of managing, transporting, processing, storing and distributing food commodities.
165
| Unity or diversity?
Besides improving the inefficient organisational structures, the policy goal of the different agencies was no longer to ‘steer’ the rice market, but rather to control the production of milled rice. Rice mills were obliged to work only for the food logistics agencies and unauthorised trade of large quantities of rice was forbidden (Van der Eng 1996b: 187). But the inability of the agencies to meet purchase targets led to shortages in milled rice which were required to stabilise prices. According to Van der Eng this failure to fulfil purchase targets was partly caused by logistical difficulties of transport and distribution (Van der Eng 1996b: 187). As discussed in chapter 4, the Japanese occupation and the subsequent Indonesian struggle for independence had done great damage to Indonesia’s physical infrastructure. Rehabilitation and extension of the infrastructure only really took place from the late 1960s onwards. Moreover, given the fact that unlicensed private trade of large quantities of rice was forbidden, the food logistics agencies were supposed to intervene in the rice market. In practice, however, they distributed mainly to civil servants and military rather than working towards actual price control (Van der Eng 1996b: 188). In the New Order the control of rice was carried out by Komando Logistik Nasional (Kolognas), although 10 May 1967 Kolognas was dissolved and replaced by Badan Urusan Logistik (Bulog). Initially the mission of Bulog was to function as a buffer stockholder and a rice supplier to government employees. It was from November 1978 onwards that Bulog’s main task was broadened to include controlling and stabilising the price of rice, paddy, wheat and other staple foods at both producer and consumer levels. So almost forty years later policies of intervention in the rice market resembled those of the 1930s, when the Dutch intervened massively into domestic rice marketing and price formation (Timmer 1991: 235). This is clearly visible in figure 6.1, where we see that after 1974 rice prices stabilise with fluctuations comparable to those in the 1930s. Since intervention by Bulog in the rice market was limited in this period, Van der Eng attributes this decline in fluctuations to the rehabilitation of communications and the liberalisation of domestic rice trade (Van der Eng 1996b: 192). The beginning of the twenty-first century is again characterised by greater fluctuations in rice prices. This is partly due to the aftermath of the Asian crisis. Furthermore, Bulog was re-organised into a public corporation. As a result of on-going studies into its functioning and under pressure from the imf, measures were undertaken to reform Bulog. Consequently its role of supplying rice to civil officials was ended by law and its role as an agency that stabilised producer and consumer prices was reduced to that of overseeing the floor price for dried paddy. In this respect, Yonekura (2005: 133) lists 4 explicit reforms that were undertaken: The fluctuations in 1973-1974 were caused by a world food crisis. The shortage of rice in world markets made it impossible for Indonesia, despite abundant foreign exchange from oil revenues, to purchase enough rice to maintain internal price stability (Timmer 1989b: 24).
166
| Accounting for Services
1) Limiting Bulog’s activities and duties financed by government funds; 2) Seeking to minimise protection for farmers and minimising Bulog’s financial burden. This has been attained by ending year-round domestic procuring and concentrating it in the harvest seasons. Moreover, procurement prices should be set near import prices; 3) Deregulating and reinforcing market transactions. This means liberalising rice imports by allowing private importers to trade in rice. Additionally, Bulog should import rice on a competitive basis, and its special advantages, support, rights and prerogatives have been abandoned; and 4) Improving governance. In short, the reforms implied an enhanced role for market forces and a limitation of Bulog’s monopoly in the import sector. This resulted in somewhat higher fluctuations in the rice prices (McCulloch and Timmer 2008). Because of the high costs of national price stabilisation schemes many economists are sceptical as to whether food price stability is financially feasible (Newbery and Stiglitz 1979, 1981; Behrman 1984; Williams and Wright 1991). Anderson and Roumasset even state: ‘Government efforts to nationalize grain markets and to regulate prices across both space and time have the effect of eliminating the private marketing and storage sector. Rather than replacing private marketing, government efforts should be aimed at enhancing private markets through improving transportation, enforcing standards and measures in grain transactions, and implementing small-scale storage technology.’ (Anderson and Raoumasset 1996: 62) However, for Indonesia Timmer rejects this condemnation. He argues that in Indonesia the stabilisation of domestic rice prices was made possible by the expanding role of the private marketing sector (Timmer 2004: 5). Figure 6.3, which represents the marketing structure of rice in Indonesia, and figure 6.4, which illustrates the functioning of Bulog, support this. They show that Bulog did not replace the private traders, but rather dictates the ‘rules’ by which or the boundaries within which private traders operate by setting floor and ceiling prices (see figure 6.4). The marketing margin between the floor price (B in figure 6.4) and the ceiling price (A in figure 6.4) affects private traders. A decision to squeeze the margin is also a decision to squeeze the private sector. Rather than acting as a monopolist in rice markets, Bulog is intended to serve as a buyer and seller of last resort (Timmer 1991: 239). Bulog procures quite a small proportion of the marketed crop only, i.e. 3-5 per cent during the 1970s, 8-9 per cent during the 1980s and 4-5 per cent between 1990 and 1997 (Ellis 1993: 429; Piggot et al. 1993: 90; Saifullah 2001: 98). This means that the private market is responsible for moving the bulk of the marketed crop.
167
| Unity or diversity?
Figure 6.3 Marketing structure of rice Farmers Padi Padi
Wholesale buyer
Koperasi Unit Desa (KUD)
Small trader Padi
Beras
Rice miller
Dolog/Bulog Beras
Beras
Large traders
Main market
Beras Beras
Beras
Retailers/warung holders
Consumers
Note: Dolog is an acronym for Depot Logistik and refers to the regional offices of Bulog.
Source: Natawidjaja 2001: 75.
It is therefore necessary to assess the role of transport and trade in the integration of the rice market in Indonesia. Spatially integrated rice markets can be achieved only if private traders react to arbitrage opportunities and if transportation is not a major obstacle. Or to quote Timmer: ‘Nearly all price interventions have been attempted through use of the market rather than displacement of it, and this no doubt accounts for much of the success in defending the desired price levels. As a consequence, the private food marketing sector has had a relatively large role, and the structure, conduct,
168
| Accounting for Services
and performance of this sector [ form] a crucial factor in the design and implementation of price policy in Indonesia.’ (Timmer 1989b: 39) Figure 6.4 Functioning of Bulog Intervention Bulog
C EILIN G PR IC E
A
Arbitrage opportunities traders C
Efficient bandwith between two cities
C
Arbitrage opportunities traders
B
Intervention Bulog
6.4
Spatial price differences in Indonesia
6.4.1
A simple approach
FLO O R PR IC E
An underlying goal of efforts at price stabilisation is to integrate Indonesia’s rice markets, since integrated markets can contribute in an important way to stable prices (Timmer 1991: 239). A harvest failure in market A would in case of autarky cause an extreme supply shock and a sharp increase in price there. If markets are spatially integrated, however, this effect will be mitigated by an influx of rice from market B. But spatially integrated markets also enhance productivity growth because of economies of scale and division of labour. It is therefore informative to see how prices fluctuate between markets. In figure 6.5 price fluctuations between markets are illustrated by the so-called coefficient of variation (cv). This coefficient is obtained by dividing the standard deviation of the different market prices by the mean of these market prices. The
169
| Unity or diversity?
rationale behind this variable is that in perfectly integrated markets the Law of One Price holds. Thus, in this case the price of rice would be the same in all markets resulting in a standard deviation of 0. In figure 6.5 a cv is computed for 11 cities (Jakarta, Bandung, Semarang, Surabaya, Palembang, Padang, Medan, Pontianak, Makassar, Manado and Banjarmasin). To avoid a bias in the results a mean and standard deviation were only calculated if there were observations for all cities. Since for Padang, Manado and Banjarmasin a relatively large number of observations are missing, I also calculate a cv for 8 cities only (excluding Padang, Manado and Banjarmasin). As can be seen, this does not significantly change the results. For the colonial period the cv for 11 cities covers the period 1927-1931, only. As an extension of these findings for a longer period, a cv for 7 cities is also calculated. These cities are Weltevreden (Jakarta), Bandung, Semarang, Surabaya, Yogyakarta, Surakarta (Solo) and Malang. One has to be careful with this comparison since not all of these cities are included in the cv for 11 cities. More importantly these 7 cities are all in Java, while the cv8 and cv11 cover Indonesia as a whole. However the correlation between the cv11 and cv7 is striking, so it is believed that the cv7 is a good proxy for changes in fluctuations between markets in the colonial period. Keeping this in mind, figure 6.5 to a large extent supports the findings so far. Fluctuations between markets are low in Java, and probably Indonesia as a whole, in the 1920s and 1930s. This notion is in line with a study by Uemura (2002), who concluded that already in the early twentieth century the inter-regional trade of rice and paddy was much developed in Java. This integration is driven by the developments in transport infrastructure, as discussed in chapter 4. Whereas in the late nineteenth century transport of rice relied upon shipment by prahu and carts, the gradually opening of the railway in the early twentieth century and subsequently the improvements in road transport made transport more efficient (Uemura 2002). In the years following independence spatial price differences are extremely large and, although they fell around 1953, they remain variable and in general rather large. After Suharto came to power repair of the infrastructure and a more efficient distribution system resulted in more stable prices. The oil boom caused another disruption in 1973, but afterwards price fluctuations between markets returned to levels comparable to the ones in Java in the 1920s. Alongside a stabilisation of rice prices, as suggested by figure 6.1, these observations indicate that price fluctuations between markets are reduced. It is tempting to interpret this result as a sign of increasing market integration. However, as Ravallion (1987) has shown, if prices at different markets are generated by identical but independent processes, nothing can be inferred about the interlinkage of markets from these kind of results. Thus to see whether rice markets have indeed become better integrated, as this simple approach to market integration suggests, we have to adopt a more advanced method.
170
| Accounting for Services
Figure 6.5 Fluctuations between markets, 1925-2006 70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0% 1925
1935
1945
1955
cv 7 Java
6.4.2
1965
1975
cv 11
1985
1995
2005
cv 8
Note: Fluctuations measured by coefficients of variation. cv7 Java: Weltevreden (Jakarta), Bandung, Semarang, Surabaya, Yogyakarta, Surakarta (Solo) and Malang. cv8: Jakarta, Bandung, Semarang, Surabaya, Palembang, Medan, Pontianak and Makassar. cv11: Jakarta, Bandung, Semarang, Surabaya, Palembang, Padang, Medan, Pontianak, Makassar, Manado and Banjarmasin. Sources: As for figure 6.1.
Advanced testing for market integration: method Two product markets are said to be integrated if the price in the importing market equals the price in the exporting market plus the transportation and other transfer costs of moving the product between the two markets (Baulch 1997: 514). Put differently, if we have two markets trading in a commodity in period t, these markets are integrated if the price in one market, P1t, equals the simultaneous price in the other, P2t, plus transfer costs Kt: P1t = P2t + Kt If (1) holds, there is no incentive to trade. Arbitrage will occur when
171
| Unity or diversity?
.
(1)
Several methods have been used to measure market integration. Advocated by Granger and Elliot (1967) simple bivariate correlation coefficients, also called the Law of One Price (lop), was long the most common measure used. Later this method was strongly criticised, most notably by Harriss (1979) and Ravallion (1986). Advances in time-series econometrics led to the development of models that address some of the perceived weaknesses in the correlation coefficient approach. In this respect, Ravallion (1986) proposed a dynamic model of spatial price differentials incorporating time lags. One major drawback remained, however. Both the lop and Ravallion models test whether price changes in one market will be translated on a one-for-one basis to the other market, either instantaneously (lop) or with lags (Ravallion). But prices in different markets will move on a one-for-one basis only if the inter-market price differential is equal to transfer costs. Thus price movements inside the bandwidth set by the transfer costs do not undermine the hypothesis of market integration, whereas these models possibly force us to reject the hypothesis of an integrated market. Palaskas and Harris-White (1993) and Alexander and Wyeth (1994) therefore extended Ravallion’s model using cointegration and Granger causality ordinary least squares (ols) techniques. This allowed testing for more general notions between markets and measures whether prices in two markets vary within a fixed range (Baulch 1997: 518). A limitation of these models, however, is that all models are in fact ‘static’. Markets are either integrated or not. This requires the assumption of a constant market structure throughout the entire sample period. It implies that when observations for different sub-periods are limited, market integration analysis is not feasible (Dercon 1995). Presently the most common approach to test for market integration is using a Vector Error Correction Model applied among others by Persson (1999), Dawson and Dey (2002) and Baten and Wallusch (2003). This model is applied here. It contains the following steps. 1) Test for stationarity (Augmented Dickey-Fuller, adf) As suggested by Engle and Granger (1987), before applying the cointegration tests one must test for a unit root in the individual price series. The standard procedure to test for this unit root is the Augmented Dickey-Fuller test. If the test statistic is below the critical value we cannot reject the null hypothesis of a unit root. An adf is conducted first on the (log)level of the series and subsequently on the first difference. The lag length is determined by minimizing of the Schwarz Criterion.
See for example Gilbert 1969; Illori 1968; Cummings 1967; Lele 1967, 1971 and Jones 1972.
172
| Accounting for Services
Often price series turn out to be integrated of order 1, I(1), which means that the level of the prices is a non-stationary process, while the first difference is a stationary process (Persson 1999: 116). If the results show that each individual time series is I(1) it allows the researcher to apply the Johansen and Juselius (1990) cointegration tests. 2) Cointegration test/Rank test A linear combination of two or more non-stationary series may be stationary. If such a stationary, or I(0), linear combination exists, the non-stationary (with a unit root) time series are cointegrated. The stationary linear combination is called the cointegrating equation and may be interpreted as a long-term equilibrium between the variables. After ensuring that the individual series are non-stationary we are now interested whether the series are cointegrated and, if they are, in identifying the long-term relationship. Testing for cointegration is done following the methodology developed by Johansen (1991, 1995). Johansen’s method is to test the restrictions imposed by cointegration on the unrestricted var. It estimates a matrix π in an unrestricted form, and then tests whether the restrictions implied by the reduced rank of π can be rejected. If π has full rank it means there are as many stationary relations as there are variables. If π has rank 1, it means that there exists one stationary relation among the variables. If π has rank 0, it means that a stationary relation does not exist. Two test statistics are given by Johansen and Juselius to test for this number of cointegrating vectors: the trace test and the maximal eigenvalue test. The rank of π is estimated sequentially from r=0 to r=k-1 until we fail to reject. If both test statistics are greater than the critical values as given in Osterwald-Lenum (1992: 467), the null hypothesis is rejected. But before actually applying the test described above we first have to decide which kind of model to choose. There are five possibilities: (i) without any deterministic variable in both cointegrating equation and in var, (ii) with intercept in cointegrating equation, (iii) intercept both in cointegrating equation and in var, (iv) intercept and linear trend in cointegrating equation and intercept in var, and (v) intercept and linear trend both in cointegrating equation and in var. Since there is no economic explanation for a linear trend assuming long-term equilibrium conditions, we would expect model iii to generate the best outcome. Moreover we would expect π to have rank one. Consider the case that there would be more than one cointegrating relationship, for example two. This would mean that some prices could be generated by the first, some by the second and some by a combination of the first and second. In that case we would not call these markets integrated (Gonzales-Rivera and Helfand 2001). So if we find a rank different from 1 we conclude that markets are not integrated.
173
| Unity or diversity?
3) A Vector Error Correction Model If two series are cointegrated we can test for a long-term equilibrium. The procedure is based on maximum likelihood estimation of the vector error correction model (vecm):
(2)
where xt = [P1t, P2t]’, which are I(1), Δxt = xt-xt-1, μ is a (2 x 1) vector of parameters, Γ1,…,Γk+1 and π are (2 x 2) matrices of parameters, D are 11 centred monthly dummies, Ψ is a (2 x 11) matrix of parameters, and εt is a (2 x 1) vector of white noise errors. When π is of reduced rank, that is r 2).
1987-2006
1
Banjarmasin-Surabaya Banjarmasin-Jakarta Banjarmasin-Medan Banjarmasin-Palembang Banjarmasin-Pontianak Banjarmasin-Manado Banjarmasin-Makassar Banjarmasin-Semarang Banjarmasin-Surabaya Banjarmasin-Jakarta Banjarmasin-Medan Banjarmasin-Palembang Banjarmasin-Pontianak Banjarmasin-Manado Banjarmasin-Makassar Banjarmasin-Semarang Banjarmasin-Surabaya Banjarmasin-Jakarta Banjarmasin-Medan Banjarmasin-Palembang Banjarmasin-Pontianak Banjarmasin-Manado Banjarmasin-Makassar
1969-1986
2 4 1 2 2 1 1 2 1 1 1 3 2 3 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1
Banjarmasin-Semarang
1949-1964
Lag length
Cities
Period
1.470 1.894 3.493 4.169 3.118 2.921 3.709 3.994 3.790 4.154
1.153 0.064 1.072 2.193
1.876
1.999
t-value 1.791
0.201 0.243 0.150 0.186 0.154 0.123 0.152 0.200 0.104 0.122
0.242 0.189 0.197 0.285
0.162
0.129
0.148
Gamma
Banjarmasin also presents an interesting case. In the period after independence it was cointegrated only with Semarang and Medan. This changed in the subsequent period, in which it is cointegrated with all other cities in the sample, although it has to be noted that for Semarang and Pontianak the null hypothesis of heterogeneity was rejected. Just as was the case with Medan the coefficients of adjustment in this period were quite high. The period 1987-2006 again shows strong cointegration with all other markets in Indonesia, but significantly lower coefficients of adjustment compared to the preceding period. The findings of this statistical analysis largely support the earlier conclusions regarding market efficiency. In the first years after independence it was difficult to speak of a ‘national’ economy in Indonesia, in which the different regions in Indonesia formed an integrated market. Market integration was in most cases limited to cities in close proximity or those with close trade relations. For many city pairs, however, the hypothesis of cointegration was rejected. This confirms Mears’ statement about the 1950s that ‘there is still no Indonesian common market, with prices in the separate areas differing by only the cost of transport’ (Mears 1961: 11). In the subsequent period a shift took place, not only to more market integration in the long run (thus being cointegrated), but also in the short run. Coefficients of adjustment are high in the years between 1969 and 1987. Apparently the improved infrastructure combined with efficient procurement by Bulog and efficient networks of private traders resulted not only in lower variance in rice prices over time; there was also a quite rapid adjustment when price differentials existed in markets. This efficient functioning of markets is significantly lower in the period 19872006. Although most markets still have a long-term equilibrium, the speed of adjustment is lower. It is probable that the monopoly that Bulog has held since its establishment in 1969 seriously harmed (private) market incentives. Another possibility is that the increased complexity of the distribution networks, as discussed in chapter 5, has made it more difficult to swiftly react to price signals.
6.5
Concluding remarks The economic literature offers theoretical foundations as to why stable prices and market integration lead to economic growth. This chapter has shown how across time and across space market efficiency and market integration changed in Indonesia using rice price series for different cities in Indonesia. It was suggested that under the colonial administration markets were functioning relatively well. Rice price fluctuations were limited and evidence suggests that markets, at least in Java, were integrated. Immediately after independence increased uncertainty, a devastated infrastructure and a lack of political power to tackle these problems affected both price stability and market integration. Not surprisingly this resulted in a stagnating economy.
181
| Unity or diversity?
After Suharto came to power, economic policy became one of the priorities of the new government. The two oil booms during the 1970s provided the government with the financial means to get the economy on an unprecedented growth path. Large investments were made in infrastructure, and measures were taken to regulate rice prices. Particularly after the establishment of Bulog in 1969 the government started to heavily regulate rice markets. This resulted in a high degree of price stability and increased market integration, which in turn translated into high growth rates. Since 1987 the goal of stabilisation of rice prices has still been attained, despite a small increase in fluctuations since the beginning of the twenty-first century, caused by the reforms taken to limit the monopoly power of Bulog and give market forces a greater role. This change is also reflected in the market integration analysis. In this last period under study Indonesia’s rice market was clearly integrated. The speed of adjustment coefficients, however, were lower than before, signalling new inefficiencies in the rice market.
182
| Accounting for Services
7
Conclusions
7.1
Accounting for services Economic development in Indonesia during the twentieth century was highly erratic. Periods of unprecedented economic growth alternated with dramatic crises. Exportled expansion in the beginning of the twentieth century was followed by stagnation as a result of the worldwide economic depression. The revival that seemed to occur in the second half of the 1930s did not materialise due to the outbreak of the Second World War and the subsequent struggle for independence. The (at best) modest recovery that took place during the 1950s was swept away by the economic turmoil in the mid-1960s. Finally the New Order government of Suharto succeeded in setting Indonesia on a formidable growth path, which was, however, abruptly ended by the Asian crisis in 1997/98. These broad observations are often repeated in the historiography on Indonesian economic development. But until the 1990s an extensive and consistent basis to quantitatively support these developments was missing. A first attempt to overcome this problem was undertaken by Van der Eng (1992) who adopted the system of Historical National Accounts for the study of long-term economic development in Indonesia. An updated version of this path-breaking work was published in 2002 (Van der Eng 2002). This offered the first consistent quantitative estimates of economic growth in Indonesia during the twentieth century. However, whereas Van der Eng’s estimates for the agricultural sector were the result of very detailed work undertaken during his PhD research (Van der Eng 1996b), the estimates for the manufacturing sector and especially the service sector were based on more indirect measures and sometimes bold assumptions. Moreover, his service sector estimates consisted only of constant price series. Therefore it was believed that a careful reconstruction of the service sector within the framework of Historical National Accounts during the late colonial period and since independence could be an important contribution to the study of Indonesian economic development. In turn, the results would enable a systematic analysis of the long-term development of Indonesia during the twentieth century in general, and the service sector in particular. With these aims in mind the argument in this book was logically unfolded as follows: 1) a careful reconstruction of the service sector in Indonesia within a National Accounting framework (chapter 2 and appendices 1-7), which subsequently formed
183
| Conclusions
the basis for 2) an analysis of the role of the service sector in the process of economic development in Indonesia (chapters 3-6). In the latter part of the book the emphasis was on the two most important trade sectors: transportation and trade.
7.2
The economic development of the indonesian service sector, ca. 1900-2000 Within the System of National Accounts the service sector is defined as economic activities related to transportation and communications, trade, government, financial services, housing and other services. In estimating these sectors, the methods as prescribed by the sna were adopted as closely as possible. In most cases this resulted in reliable estimates. But due to data limitations rather rough approaches had to be taken in a few cases, notably for the categories ‘other services’ and ‘road transport’. Clearly, these estimates therefore have a larger margin of error, but the consistency in the method of estimation ensures that it does give a good picture of developments in those sectors. Overall the margin of error fluctuates between 15 and 25 per cent, which seems to be acceptable. Horlings (1995), for example, estimated the reliability of his service sector estimates for the Netherlands, 1800-1850, to be between 15 to 30 per cent, whereas Smits (1995) for the period 1850-1913 came to a margin of error between 10 to 15 per cent. The results of these meticulous exercises offer a number of interesting insights. At the beginning of the twentieth century, trade was the most important service sector, followed by housing. This reflected two characteristics of the Indonesian economy. Firstly, a rather low level of income resulted in a relatively large share spent on a necessity good as housing. Secondly, the relatively large trade sector was a consequence of its role as win-gewest for the coloniser, the Netherlands. After independence, housing lost importance, and the trade sector contributed less to total service sector gdp, resulting in a more diversified structure. Nevertheless, trade remained the most important service sector in the twentieth century. Average annual growth in the service sector during the twentieth century was 3.8 per cent, compared to 2.1 and 3.9 per cent in agriculture and industry respectively. Within the service sector, growth was most significant in the transport and communications sector. This is not surprising given the technological innovations in this sector. If we look at occupational structure, the agricultural sector was by far the most important employer during the colonial period, with almost 70 per cent of the labour force working in that sector. Its share actually rose between 1930 and 1961 due to the economic turmoil caused by the Second World War, the subsequent struggle for independence and the first decade under President Sukarno. From 1961 onwards, we see a slow but steady decrease in the share of agricultural employment, to approximately 45 per cent in 2000. Another striking feature is that the share of industry in total employment increased only slowly, from 7.9 per cent in 1961 to 13.7 per cent in
184
| Accounting for Services
1990 and 16.9 per cent in 2000. Most labourers who were pushed out of the agricultural sector apparently failed to find employment in the industrial sector. Because of its relatively low entry barriers many of them ended up in the low-productivity service sectors. This is reflected in the fact that growth in employment within the service sector was especially geared to the trade sector. The value added estimates can be combined with employment figures to draw some conclusions about labour productivity. The main conclusion in this respect is that labour productivity in Indonesia’s service sectors, except for the financial sector, has not been very impressive. Productivity in the service sector is both higher in level and growing more rapidly than agricultural productivity, but is outpaced by developments in the industrial sector. It seems that Indonesia’s major service sectors are still the traditional sectors with relatively low value added. Looking at these three measures, i.e. economic structure, occupational structure and labour productivity, we see a profound transformation of the economy during the twentieth century, especially during the 1970s. Nevertheless, Indonesia is still in transition. Agriculture is still the largest sector, both in employment and income. Moreover, within the service sector most employment and most income are still in the more traditional service sectors such as transportation and trade, which were already quite important in the colonial period. Therefore I conclude that a decisive transition to a modern economy with sweeping structural changes has not yet taken place.
7.3
Transport, trade and integrating markets Transportation is considered a necessary but not sufficient condition for economic growth. Without any form of transportation autarky is the only possible outcome. It therefore is often termed indispensable for economic growth. Theory shows that efficient transportation systems have significant effects on economic welfare and economic growth, because cheap and reliable transportation enable local specialisation, higher producer prices, lower producer costs and higher productivity or, in Fogel’s terms, social savings. Looking at developments in the transportation sector in Indonesia during the twentieth century three phases can be distinguished. The first phase was the colonial period. During this period the Dutch laid down a relatively efficient transportation network. Railways played especially an important role during the first two decades of the century, although these were largely confined to Java. Being a large archipelago, water transport was essential not only for economic, but also for political reasons. The Royal Packet Company (kpm) was the leading shipping company being granted all scheduled traffic service by the Dutch government, resulting in a near-monopoly. kpm succeeded in offering reliable and safe transport over water. From a welfare perspective it can be argued that kpm’s monopoly was not optimal, because it resulted in high prices, but at the same time the higher profits made on trunk lines enabled kpm to cross-subsidise less profitable routes, thus creating both
185
| Conclusions
a politically and economically integrated country. Besides the large ships operated by kpm an extensive fleet of indigenous rigged ships, called prahu, were active in Indonesian waters, sometimes in the role of competitors to the kpm, but usually as feeder ships. Road transport gained significance due to the technological innovation of the automobile from the 1920s onwards. The introduction of cars, trucks and buses made it possible to ship passengers and goods without additional feeder services. These developments affected rail transport especially negatively, leading to stagnating growth. The railway sector did not really recover from this until the late 1980s. In 1928 the first airline was established in Indonesia, but its contribution remained marginal during the colonial period. The second phase, from the Japanese invasion in 1942 until the fall of Sukarno in 1966, was characterised by enormous infrastructural and institutional damage. Railways and roads were severely neglected, while continuous competition and struggle between kpm and the state-owned shipping company pelni, escalated into the expulsion of kpm in 1957. Despite the fact that problems of capacity were rapidly solved, organisational problems damaged the water transport sector. Over-capacity, unreliable schedules and other inefficiencies negatively affected not only growth in this sector, but also the economy as a whole. Only developments in air transport were satisfactory. The third phase is the extended New Order period from 1966 until 2000. Major investments in roads, re-organisation and deregulation of the water transport sector, and rehabilitation of the railways combined with continuing growth in air transport caused what Dick and Forbes (1992) call ‘a quiet revolution’. During the twentieth century transportation costs decreased significantly. This means that important social savings have been made (Fogel), consumer and producer surpluses have increased (Spatial Price Equilibrium model) and that lower producer costs and higher producer prices combined with economies of scale have led to higher productivity. In conclusion, the Dutch laid down a relatively efficient transportation network, but the Second World War and the struggle for independence resulted in a physical infrastructure that was in an appalling state. These problems were not solved until the early 1970s. Since then the repair of the existing infrastructure and the construction of new infrastructure spurred growth in the transport sector, which translated into high economic growth. Nevertheless, there is still potential for further growth in the transportation sector and consequently in the Indonesian economy as a whole. Most developments have been biased towards Java and, to a lesser extent, towards Bali and Sumatra. Especially in the Outer Islands, but also in Java and Madura, transportation networks are still considerably less efficient than in Western countries. Moreover, other problems have risen, such as severe congestion in Java. These problems need to be overcome in future in order for the transport sector to remain a catalyst of economic growth. The trade sector has been the largest service sector throughout the twentieth century. But the exact relation between trade and economic growth is a matter of
186
| Accounting for Services
debate. Neo-classical economic theory suggests that exports lead to increasing specialisation, greater economies of scale due to an enlargement of the market size, and more rapid technological change. Anti-globalists, on the other hand, argue that trade favours the rich at the expense of the poor. Moreover, the trade sector in many developing countries functions as an employer of last resort. Because of its flexibility, low-skilled jobs, limited capital requirements and low entry barriers, this sector absorbs those workers pushed out of the agricultural sector and unable to find work in manufacturing. The main conclusion is that the Indonesian trade sector fulfilled an ambiguous function. On the one hand it did indeed function as an engine of growth. Both during the colonial period and after independence careful trade policies resulted in periods of strong growth fuelled by economies of scale and technological change. In sum, there has been a strong positive association between openness to trade and gdp growth. The domestic dynamics in the trade sector have been rather different, however. It was shown that in this respect the trade sector has functioned as a safety net for those unable to find (enough) work in agriculture or manufacturing. In the 1930s the trade sector was dominated by the large Dutch trading houses in collaboration with Chinese middlemen. Clearly, retail trade already existed at this time, perhaps even on a larger scale than the official statistics suggest because of by-employment. But it was not yet the sector of last resort. Most people were still working in the agricultural sector, with an increasing number finding employment in the rising manufacturing sector. This has changed in the last few decades. Since the late 1960s in particular, both the absolute and the relative number of people working in the trade sector has increased rapidly, whereas labour productivity is still below levels reached in the 1930s. This can be attributed to the capital-intensive industrialisation that occurred, which resulted in failure of the manufacturing sector to absorb the labour surplus. Moreover, in relative terms, labour productivity in the trade sector has declined markedly. A transformation has taken place from a sector dominated by the highly profitable wholesale trade in the colonial period to one in which an almost endless chain of traders is involved in the distribution process creating an ‘internally complicated organization’. This process is, in my opinion, very well captured by the term ‘involution’. That transport and trade enhance specialisation, economies of scale and division of labour is often taken as an axiom. The implicit assumption behind this is that efficient transportation and trade networks lead to increased market integration. Therefore the key to assess the contribution of the service sector to economic development is to test whether markets have become integrated in Indonesia. Using rice price series for different cities across Indonesia it was possible to test this hypothesis. Statistical analysis suggests that under the colonial administration markets were functioning relatively well. Rice price fluctuations were limited and markets, at least in Java, were integrated. After independence uncertainty increased, and a devastated infrastructure and lack of political power affected both price stability and market integration. Not surprisingly this resulted in a stagnating economy.
187
| Conclusions
When Suharto came to power in 1966, economic policy became one of the priorities of the new government. One of the economic measures taken was to make large investments in infrastructure. Furthermore the government started to regulate rice markets heavily. Towards this goal it established Bulog in 1969. The measures taken resulted in increased market integration and hence high price stability, which in turn were translated in high growth rates. The goal of stabilisation of rice prices has more or less been attained since the 1970s, despite a small increase in fluctuations since the beginning of the twentyfirst century. These were caused by the reforms taken to limit the monopoly power of Bulog and give market forces a greater role. Markets are still clearly integrated, although the speed-of-adjustment coefficients are lower than before, signalling inefficiencies in the rice market. Altogether the evidence suggests that the Indonesian economy has gradually become more integrated, so that Java and the Outer Islands can be considered a single economic unit. Therefore the conclusion can be drawn that developments in the transport and trade sectors have indeed resulted in more integrated markets and thus that the service sector has played a significant role in the economic development of Indonesia.
7.4
the service sector: tertiary? The role of the service sector in the process of economic development has been a neglected field of research. The emphasis in development economics has for a long time been on the agricultural sector and industrialisation, possibly because in the ‘role model of Western economic development’, Great Britain, developments in these sectors spurred economic growth. However, in general the service sector is at the heart of all economic growth. By stimulating and facilitating production for the market rather than simply for self-sufficiency it enables greater specialisation, division of labour and economies of scale (Eswaran and Kotwal 2002: 403). In this respect it contradicts the linear stage theories of economic development, which argue that service sector development is preceded by manufacturing development. Very few countries have followed this linear developmental mode implied by terms such as ‘tertiary’ and ‘post-industrial’ (see also Szirmai 2005: 109-112, 271272). In my opinion, models based on the assumption of a unidirectional flow of economic activity from agriculture to manufacturing to services are simplistic and inaccurate. Far from being derivative or parasitical, the service sector is a vital force in stimulating and facilitating economic growth. The traditional view of the service sector as a ‘residual’ or ‘tertiary’ sector has been falsified for Indonesia in this book. Similar conclusions were drawn by Horlings (1995) and Smits (1995) for the Netherlands between 1800 and 1913. Apparently the linear stage theories of economic development, which remain persistent in both economic literature and economic policy making, need some adaptation.
188
| Accounting for Services
I would argue that structural change should be redefined as a decreasing share of agricultural employment and income instead of a shift from agriculture to industry to services as implied by the linear stage theories. The relative ‘devaluation’ of the agricultural sector triggers a dynamic process in which the respective shares of industrial and service employment and income start to change. This can result in 1) an equal increase in both sectors; 2) one biased towards industry; or 3) one biased towards services. The outcome of the process is country-specific. In Great Britain, for example, structural change took place in the form of a significant increase in the industrial sector both in employment and in income, followed only later by an expansion of the service sector. But in the Netherlands structural change was the result of an expanding transport and trade sector, while developments in the industrial sector lagged behind. For Indonesia structural change was, as in the Netherlands, biased towards services, but the story is quite different from the Dutch case. A number of factors can explain this. To begin with, its transport sector and its trade sector were already relatively well developed before industrialisation to serve the needs of its coloniser. This meant that in the initial stages of development the service sector was relatively large. Furthermore, Indonesia has a distinct geographical setting, being a large archipelago. This makes it almost impossible to refrain from involvement in the world economy through trade. But it also explains the extensive inter-island trade that takes place. Figure 7.1
From parasite to catalyst Static: Agriculture
Industry
Services (Clark, Fisher, etc.)
Industry
Services
Dynamic: Agriculture
A third explanation for the ‘service bias’ in Indonesia’s economic development lies in a process that is common for developing countries and what in this study is termed ‘involution of the trade sector’. When people were pushed out the agricultural sector from the late 1960s onwards the manufacturing sector failed to absorb the labour surplus. Due to the trade sector’s low entry barriers, many of those labourers found work in that sector. Similar processes can be observed in Latin American countries, such as Brazil and Mexico.
189
| Conclusions Figure 7-1.indd 1
Recently the importance of the service sector in the economic development of developed countries has been acknowledged by several researchers (Horlings 1995; Smits 1995; Broadberry 2007). However, in the economic development literature, studies focusing on service-related economic growth are still rare. A notable exception is a study by Gani and Clemes (2002). For countries forming the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (asean), they found that service sector growth had a significant impact on raising productivity in other sectors and on enhancing the efficiency of resource allocation. I also believe that economic development strategies should place more emphasis on service sector development. Notwithstanding the fact that all sectors of an economy are important, service development is crucial, since resource allocation to the agricultural or industrial sector is premature unless physical infrastructure and financial and social services are already well developed. In other words, services need to be accounted for in the process of economic development. That is the main conclusion of this book.
190
| Accounting for Services
appendix 1
National Accounting for Transport and Communications
According to the System of National Accounts, the output of transportation is measured by the value of the amounts receivable for transporting goods or persons. In economics a good in one location is recognised as having a different quality from the same good in another location, so that transporting from one location to another is a process of production in which an economically significant transformation takes place even if the good remains otherwise unchanged. The transport and communications sector consists of the following sub-sectors: 1) rail transport; 2) road transport; 3) water transport; 4) air transport; and 5) communications. In this appendix the data sources and raw statistical data are given for these sub-sectors, which are subsequently used to estimate time-series in value added.
A1.1
Rail transport The prime source for the reconstruction of railway transport in the framework of the national accounts is Statistiek van het vervoer op de spoorwegen en tramwegen met machinale beweegkracht in Nederlandsch-Indië, Batavia, 1900-1914, and Verslag betreffende het spoor- en tramwegwezen in Nederlandsch-Indië, Batavia, 1915-1930. These are combined with: • Jaarcijfers voor het Koninkrijk der Nederlanden. Koloniën. The Hague, 1897-1921; • Statistisch Jaaroverzicht van Nederlandsch-Indië. Batavia, 1922-1940; • Koloniaal Verslag, The Hague, 1849-1930; • Indisch Verslag, The Hague, 1931-1940. Information on number of passengers, goods transported, total revenues and net profits was obtained from the above listed sources. Estimates on the cost structure are obtained from annual reports of railway enterprises mentioned in the text (i.e. ss, dsm, and nism): • Jaarverslag der n.v. Deli Spoorweg Maatschappij, Amsterdam, 1883-1940; • Verslag over den aanleg en de exploitatie van de Staatsspoorwegen in NederlandschIndië, Batavia, 1887-1915; • Verslag der Staatsspoor- en tramwegen in Nederlandsch-Indië, Batavia, 1915-1941; • Verslag van den raad van beheer der Nederlandsch-Indische Spoorweg Maatschappij aan de algemeene vergadering van aandeelhouders, The Hague, 1869-1929;
191
| Appendix 1
• Verslag n.v. Nederlandsch-Indische Spoorweg Maatschappij, The Hague, 1930-1940. • ara, inv. 2.20.11, Deli Spoorweg Maatschappij, 1883-1970; • ara, inv. 2.20.10, Nederlandsch-Indische Spoorweg-Maatschappij, 1863-1973. The sources above provide the necessary information to estimate value added in rail transport. I arrived at these estimates by adding net profit, salaries and wages, interest and depreciation. Net profit for rail transport is taken directly from the sources; the other elements needed to estimate value added are obtained in an indirect way, by taking the ratio of wages and salaries, interest and depreciation on the one hand and total operating costs on the other hand for the Deli Spoorweg Maatschappij (Deli Railway Company, dsm), since this ratio can be calculated from the sources on an annual basis. Constant price estimates are obtained by dividing value added in current prices by a weighted volume index of passenger transport and goods transport.
Notes for table A1.1 (1) = Revenue from passenger transport in guilders (2) = Revenue from luggage transport in guilders (3) = Revenue from goods transport in guilders (4) = Other profits in guilders (5) = (1) + (2) + (3) + (4) = Total revenue in guilders (6) = Operating costs in guilders (7) = (6) – (5) = Net profit in guilders (8) = Volume of passenger transport (9) = Volume of goods transport, tons (10) = Value added/operating expenses of Deli Spoorweg Maatschappij (dsm) In the annual reports of dsm operation costs are divided into salaries and wages, interest, depreciation and other operating expenses. This makes it possible to construct value added/output ratios for every year. (11) = Value added/output ratio Staatsspoorwegen (ss) For benchmark years a value added/output ratio was estimated for the years 1926 and 1930. These estimates are very robust, due to the lack of disaggrega tion of the data. (12) = Value added in current prices (in millions of guilders) = (6) * (10) + (7) Since the value added/output ratio of the Staatsspoorwegen is very rough I have chosen to use the one of dsm. The decrease of the ratio is mainly caused by a lower share of wages and salaries paid. (13) = Volume-index (1939=100) passenger transport (14) = Volume-index (1939=100) goods transport (15) = Weighted volume-index (1939=100) = (1)/((1)+(3))*(13) + (3)/((1)+(3))*(14) (16) = (12)/(15) * 100 = Value added in constant (1939=100) prices (in millions of guilders)
192
| Accounting for Services
193
| Appendix 1
22,560,945
23,237,234
15,511,545
1910
1914
14,549,522
1909
1913
13,836,537
1908
17,430,816
12,919,877
1907
20,149,727
11,457,549
1906
1912
10,295,801
1905
1911
9,136,572
9,481,241
1904
1902
1903
8,142,549
8,619,960
1901
7,153,142
7,887,674
1900
1898
1899
5,752,183
6,341,490
1897
5,085,552
4,912,250
1894
5,367,082
4,792,390
1893
1896
4,574,474
1895
4,509,124
1892
4,104,497
(1)
134,398
120,591
117,089
101,216
90,589
78,745
70,399
62,680
59,962
48,160
39,605
33,726
27,734
22,595
21,605
17,152
9,611
7,323
5,041
4,836
4,720
4,171
3,769
3,285
3,039
(2)
32,858,975
32,105,576
29,920,837
27,291,329
24,774,581
21,957,697
21,349,767
19,670,112
18,039,506
17,347,037
15,779,089
14,572,639
14,382,937
14,586,046
13,811,086
12,842,971
11,085,379
10,673,211
9,474,060
9,252,673
9,253,929
7,899,420
7,870,519
7,490,136
6,425,671
(3)
Estimation of value added in rail transport, 1890-1939
1891
1890
Table A1.1 (4)
2,767,194
2,387,791
2,185,088
1,981,408
1,542,860
1,512,095
1,509,533
1,346,956
1,288,179
1,170,810
1,138,940
1,312,643
1,081,848
1,042,585
1,005,738
874,638
871,260
763,956
699,420
611,551
449,884
532,527
514,644
484,282
474,528
(5)
58,997,801
57,174,903
52,372,741
46,804,769
41,919,575
38,098,059
36,766,236
33,999,625
30,845,196
28,861,808
26,438,875
25,055,580
24,112,479
23,793,775
22,726,103
20,887,903
18,307,740
17,196,673
15,545,603
14,954,612
14,620,783
13,228,508
12,963,406
12,486,827
11,007,735
(6)
32,247,172
29,333,226
26,488,515
23,018,083
21,558,456
20,571,779
19,357,870
18,307,116
17,087,154
15,343,512
14,606,568
14,068,333
13,652,558
12,887,250
11,543,027
10,441,842
9,559,072
8,591,344
7,753,243
6,691,121
6,591,920
6,339,248
6,218,241
5,528,158
5,478,026
(7)
26.750.629
27.841.677
25.884.226
23.786.686
20.361.119
17.526.280
17.408.366
15.692.509
13.758.042
13.518.296
11.832.307
10.987.247
10.459.921
10.906.525
11.183.076
10.446.061
8.748.668
8.605.329
7.792.360
8.263.491
8.028.863
6.889.260
6.745.165
6.958.669
5.529.709
(8)
108.080.420
106.130.815
93.501.912
81.349.772
72.106.134
67.961.792
63.392.277
58.492.861
51.788.604
48.182.279
44.280.256
42.546.070
39.936.638
38.624.387
37.103.918
30.464.281
24.871.059
21.177.246
19.627.205
19.130.397
18.605.753
18.268.587
17.388.300
17.034.265
15.026.445
194
| Accounting for Services
(1)
14,150,000
14,697,000
15,296,000
1939
11,249,000
1936
1938
11,706,000
1935
1937
14,805,000
12,940,000
1934
1932
1933
23,427,000
18,027,000
1931
29,282,000
1930
(2)
228,580
228,326
231,122
222,535
223,776
240,587
285,564
301,431
246,622
206,323
179,891
178,276
166,157
145,978
318,000
312,000
297,000
259,300
258,300
309,900
355,200
393,900
505,000
644,800
34,472,000
36,455,527
1928
1929
38,511,736
38,620,168
1927
1925
1926
38,249,245
38,954,946
1924
47,515,274
40,765,628
54,392,687
1921
1923
47,244,109
1920
1922
30,512,179
35,947,627
1919
1917
1918
25,510,979
28,827,895
1916
24,870,914
1915
(3)
39,228,000
35,121,000
35,873,000
29,755,100
29,236,600
31,547,200
35,941,100
48,625,100
59,697,600
75,346,000
92,653,000
88,218,632
80,639,449
70,509,312
75,648,575
68,581,668
58,443,496
59,412,986
66,465,368
57,545,946
49,590,649
44,051,755
40,486,427
38,371,385
34,198,789
(4)
4,176,000
3,234,000
3,136,000
2,907,000
3,734,000
3,039,000
3,007,000
3,688,000
4,061,000
4,247,000
4,397,000
8,178,948
7,879,212
9,048,851
5,143,436
5,866,702
11,161,676
11,805,359
13,481,833
7,062,783
5,465,402
4,696,261
3,703,074
3,744,726
3,275,286
(5)
59,018,000
53,364,000
53,456,000
44,170,400
44,934,900
47,836,100
54,108,300
70,734,000
87,690,600
109,519,800
131,522,000
133,081,687
127,367,155
118,301,021
119,969,492
112,921,391
110,611,387
119,019,183
134,641,319
112,099,460
91,210,001
79,440,086
73,195,672
67,793,247
62,490,967
(6)
39,807,000
38,763,000
35,270,000
34,110,000
36,702,000
39,609,000
44,945,000
58,181,000
67,209,000
76,237,000
77,902,000
79,098,899
76,314,046
73,424,991
74,596,870
72,986,608
79,903,644
96,281,330
101,192,190
86,080,880
57,310,403
47,570,418
38,441,216
33,576,620
31,957,599
(7)
19.211.000
14.601.000
18.186.000
10.060.400
8.232.900
8.227.100
9.163.300
12.553.000
20.481.600
33.282.800
53.620.000
53.982.788
51.053.109
44.876.030
45.372.622
39.934.783
30.707.743
22.737.853
33.449.129
26.018.580
33.899.598
31.869.668
34.754.456
34.216.627
30.533.368
(8)
87.978.000
84.214.000
83.333.000
68.561.000
66.845.000
74.169.000
81.679.000
87.022.000
110.479.000
135.024.000
146.696.000
142.724.346
139.910.600
136.068.219
133.534.004
127.750.526
133.918.581
157.194.014
177.445.578
173.236.234
149.932.194
131.007.306
129.066.888
116.748.946
106.763.606
195
| Appendix 1
2.494.621
2.743.208
3.049.640
1897
1898
1899
7.583.821
8.636.831
9.339.439
9.887.736
10.223.288
1912
1913
1914
6.658.367
1910
72%
6.638.384
1908
1909
1911
73%
5.453.317
6.130.907
1906
1907
73%
67%
71%
72%
71%
72%
72%
70%
70%
4.615.770
5.020.730
1904
73%
74%
74%
78%
79%
78%
1905
3.968.061
4.116.090
1902
1903
3.451.030
2.168.221
3.766.739
77%
2.149.407
1895
1896
1900
75% 76%
1.879.623
2.005.084
1893
1894
1901
78% 76%
1.552.859
75% 79%
1.426.459
1891
1892
79%
(10)
1.308.897
(9)
Continued
1890
Table A1.1 (11)
(12)
39.69
40.73
37.45
33.43
30.13
27.36
26.65
24.76
21.72
20.33
19.18
18.25
17.95
17.69
17.81
16.45
14.22
13.19
11.79
11.29
11.04
10.27
10.20
9.37
8.75
123
121
106
92
82
77
72
66
59
55
50
48
45
44
42
35
28
24
22
22
21
21
20
19
17
(13)
94
91
86
80
70
61
61
57
50
46
43
38
37
35
32
28
25
23
20
20
19
17
14
13
12
(14)
106
103
94
85
75
68
66
61
54
49
46
42
40
38
36
30
26
23
21
21
19
19
16
15
14
(15)
(16)
42.15
42.12
35.32
28.32
22.48
18.54
17.46
14.99
11.66
10.06
8.73
7.67
7.17
6.73
6.34
5.01
3.75
3.09
2.46
2.32
2.15
1.92
1.67
1.45
1.23
196
| Accounting for Services 61% 53% 49% 55% 54% 57% 62% 65%
18.668.310
19.066.396
15.817.032
15.258.800
15.745.600
8.261.900
7.655.700
7.211.000
7.640.000
10.083.400
9.750.400
10.828.300
1928
1929
1930
1931
1932
1933
1934
1935
1936
1937
1938
1939
66%
64%
64%
65%
66%
66%
15.735.678
17.116.242
1926
66%
62%
59%
59%
64%
64%
66%
1927
14.510.358
13.343.874
15.668.386
14.036.364
1922
1923
1924
16.150.092
1925
14.599.897
1920
1921
68%
13.104.118
13.937.480
1918
1919
71% 71%
12.133.113
12.656.957
1916
(10) 69%
1917
(9)
10.508.007
1915
60%
50%
(11)
(12)
37.87
33.92
34.50
27.49
25.77
26.07
29.79
34.71
46.79
66.31
85.23
87.98
84.68
78.16
79.21
70.25
64.95
70.17
86.01
71.75
60.44
53.82
52.26
48.46
43.26
100
96
95
78
76
84
93
99
126
153
167
162
159
155
152
145
152
179
202
197
170
149
147
133
121
(13)
100
90
93
71
67
71
76
145
141
146
176
172
158
145
145
134
123
130
149
135
129
121
117
112
97
(14)
100
92
94
73
69
75
81
133
137
148
174
169
158
149
147
138
135
151
173
163
146
132
129
120
107
(15)
(16)
37.87
31.11
32.28
19.95
17.85
19.46
24.17
46.10
63.91
98.24
147.92
149.06
134.11
116.16
116.52
96.95
87.77
106.25
148.62
116.83
88.39
71.27
67.57
58.29
46.41
In Indonesia’s official national accounts railway transport is estimated first in current prices using the state railway enterprise annual reports. Gross value added at constant prices is then obtained by extrapolation, using a passenger and ton-kilometre weighted composite indices as the extrapolator. Some key indicators for railway transport between 1950 and 2000 are presented in table A1.2. The sources used are: • bps, Statistical Yearbook of Indonesia, several volumes; • bps, Seri Statistik pengangkutan kereta api, 1961-1972; • bps, Statistik angkutan kereta api 1990; • bps, Statistik perhubungan, 1999.
Notes for table A1.2 (1 = (2) = (3) = (4) = (5) = (6) = (7) = (8) = (9) =
Number of passengers transported (x 1,000) Tons of goods transported (x 1,000) Passenger-kilometres (millions) Ton-kilometres (millions) Average haul freight (km) Average distance travelled per passenger (km) Length of railway Number of locomotives Tons of baggage
The name of the state railway enterprise has changed several times throughout the second half of the twentieth century. In chronological order the name was: dka (Djwatan Kereta Api), pnka (Perusahaan Nasional Kereta Api), pjka (Perusahaan Jasa Kerata Api), Perumka (Perusahaan Umum Kereta Api) and pt Kereta Api.
197
| Appendix 1
198
| Accounting for Services 5,391 5,881
106,963
103,323
97,235
111,144
125,712
151,316
1950
1951
1952
1953
1954
1955
3,510
54,000
50,000
49,000
39,000
27,000
1970
1971
1972
1973
1968
1969
75,000
68,000
1967
92,000
123,000
1963
1966
130,000
1962
117,000
144,000
1961
125,000
158,000
1964
6,000
146,000
1959
1960
1965
5,836
124,000
1958
4,971
4,562
4,202
3,958
4,025
3,307
2,939
3,860
4,397
4,841
5,127
5,599
6,494
6,564
6,158
6,548
136,253
140,357
1956
1957
6,822
6,304
6,042
5,464
4,976
51,084
65,014
1948
1949
(2)
(1)
3,344
3,545
3,378
3,407
4,028
4,971
6,003
7,322
6,329
6,548
7,057
7,201
5,056
4,016
3,437
3,003
3,482
3,785
1,532
(3)
Table A1.2 Key indicators for railway transport, 1948-2000
1,039
949
855
860
739
665
881
973
1,045
1,072
1,157
1,245
1,159
1,046
1,069
1,044
1,053
976
902
789
827
723
434
(4)
228
226
216
214
223
226
232
220
220
210
207
192
(5)
86
72
68
63
59
66
65
59
54
53
54
50
(6)
6,637
6,637
6,637
6,640
6,640
6,640
6,640
6,640
6,640
6,640
6,640
6,640
6,640
6,640
6,640
6,640
6,640
6,640
6,640
6,640
6,640
6,640
6,616
6,925
5,103
3,617
(7)
879
934
970
1,004
1,100
1,164
1,189
1,236
1,254
1,251
1,209
1,218
1,132
1,141
1,165
1,150
1,118
1,065
1,063
1,045
1,004
940
865
737
584
(8)
92,658
108,681
104,384
105,493
154,775
167,000
403,000
481,000
324,000
333,000
359,000
409,000
123,890
115,360
92,179
(9)
199
| Appendix 1
160,300
191,600
1999
2000
19,186
158,600
169,800
1997
1998
18,421
153,700
1996
16,368
19,544
19,286
18,217
16,868
115,866
15,690
144,500
98,200
1993
13,726 14,988
1995
73,057
1992
12,537
8,577
7,589
1994
62,228
1991
11,768
55,542
58,212
52,251
1988
1989
48,565
1990
10,317
48,659
6,752
6,423
5,066
1986
1983
4,971 4,700
1987
46,261
1982
46,742
43,697
1981
4,859
46,693
43,264
1980
5,174
4,500
3,819
3,449
4,064
1985
41,754
1979
(2) 4,728
1984
31,445
40,469
1978
22,277
23,039
1976
1977
22,521
1975
(1)
28,292
1974
(3)
19,228
17,829
16,196
15,518
15,223
15,500
13,610
12,377
10,459
9,767
9,290
8,426
7,863
7,515
7,545
6,774
6,379
6,106
6,294
6,166
6,089
5,758
4,759
3,809
3,522
3,409
3,468
(4)
5,009
5,035
4,963
5,030
4,700
4,172
3,854
3,955
3,778
3,470
3,190
2,921
2,360
1,758
1,464
1,333
1,173
916
885
970
961
1,021
1,015
853
703
916
1,118
256
261
272
262
254
247
235
252
252
253
(5)
(6)
100
111
95
98
99
113
160
152
150
153
148
144
135
132
144
143
146
142
151
131
158
151
123
(7)
6,370
6,370
6,708
6,708
6,708
6,701
6,699
6,699
6,699
6,699
6,699
6,699
6,699
6,637
6,637
6,637
6,637
(8)
805
812
835
835
790
790
798
760
692
667
679
677
622
600
469
527
787
(9)
160,000
152,000
150,000
153,000
148,000
144,000
135,000
132,000
144,000
143,000
146,000
142,000
151,000
131,000
158,000
151,000
123,000
Table A1.3 Railway transport according to i-o tables (in millions rupiah) Value added
1975
6,138
1980 1985
Revenue
Value added/ Operating surplus output ratio (%)
Wages & salaries
Depreciation
338
Indirect taxes
18,710
32.8
-1,238
7,036
1
21,874
51,299
42.6
-16,317
31,968
6,219
4
52,721
111,756
47.2
-9,812
46,517
16,016
0
1990
105,788
233,692
45.3
4,565
83,901
17,322
0
1995
263,609
567,239
46.5
20,775
192,620
50,214
0
2000
743,740
2,258,074
32.9
188,610
433,923
86,047
35,161
In table A1.4 the data above are used to calculate time-series for value added in rail transport between 1900 and 2000. Value added for the colonial period is taken from table A1.1. For the period after 1950 I rely on the Input-Output tables and extrapolate the missing years based on a volume index and subsequently correcting for inflation using a cpi index. For the colonial period it was only possible to construct a volume index based on the number of passengers and goods transported without taking into account the average distance travelled. Since independence data are available on passengerkilometres and ton-kilometres. Constant price estimates are arrived at by taking an unweighted average index of the two volume indices.
Notes for table A1.4 (1) = (2) = (3) = (4) = (5) = (6) = (7) = (8) = (9) = (11) =
200
Value added in current prices (million guilders/rupiah) For the period until 1940 value added estimates in current prices are taken from table A1.1. Bold indicates the numbers taken from the input-output tables (table A1.3). Other years are calculated by extrapolation based on the volume index (8) and corrected for inflation using the cpi index (11) by van Leeuwen (2007) Number of passengers (x 1,000) Freight (ton x 1,000) Unweighted volume index (1993=100) of (2) and (3) Passenger-kilometres (in millions) Ton-kilometres (in millions) Unweighted volume index (1993=100) of (5) and (6) Average unweighted index (1993=100) = ((4) + (7))/2 Value added in constant prices (1993=100) (millions fl/Rp) cpi (Van Leeuwen 2007), 1993=100 The sharp decrease after 1966 is because in that year 1000 rupiah was converted into 1 new rupiah as a consequence of the hyperinflation from which Indonesia suffered during that time. This leads to sharp fluctuations in both current price value added estimates as the cpi index.
| Accounting for Services
201
| Appendix 1
11.29
11.79
13.19
14.22
16.45
17.81
17.69
17.95
18.25
1894
1895
1896
1897
1898
1899
1900
1901
1902
1903
21.72
24.76
26.65
27.36
30.13
33.43
37.45
40.73
39.69
43.26
48.46
1906
1907
1908
1909
1910
1911
1912
1913
1914
1915
1916
19.18
11.04
1893
20.33
10.27
1892
1905
10.20
1891
1904
8.75
9.37
1890
(1)
116,749
106,764
108,080
106,131
93,502
81,350
72,106
67,962
63,392
58,493
51,789
48,182
44,280
42,546
39,937
38,624
37,104
30,464
24,871
21,177
19,627
19,130
18,606
18,269
17,388
17,034
15,026
(2)
12,133
10,508
10,223
9,888
9,339
8,637
7,584
6,658
6,638
6,131
5,453
5,021
4,616
4,116
3,968
3,767
3,451
3,050
2,743
2,495
2,168
2,149
2,005
1,880
1,553
1,426
1,309
(3)
Table A1.4 Value added of railway transport, 1890-2000
122.7
109.3
108.5
105.7
96.5
86.6
76.4
69.5
67.1
61.9
55.0
50.9
46.8
43.3
41.2
39.5
37.0
31.6
27.1
23.9
21.4
21.1
20.1
19.3
17.1
16.2
14.6
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
219,807
195,686
194,242
189,302
172,791
155,063
136,800
124,522
120,149
110,914
98,428
91,097
83,735
77,563
73,789
70,705
66,350
56,555
48,522
42,720
38,362
37,710
35,927
34,478
30,650
29,091
26,177
(9)
0.014
0.013
0.013
0.014
0.015
0.013
0.012
0.012
0.013
0.012
0.011
0.010
0.010
0.012
0.011
0.012
0.010
0.010
0.010
0.013
0.009
0.009
0.010
0.011
0.012
0.011
0.011
(10)
202
| Accounting for Services
(1)
152.7
(9)
(10)
0.016
0.013
0.010
0.010
0.009
0.010
0.010
0.011
0.012
0.015
0.017
0.017
0.017
0.018
0.018
0.018
0.019
0.021
0.023
0.027
0.032
0.019
0.019
0.015
0.024
168,848
156,832
158,690
125,398
120,308
130,609
142,392
211,540
236,780
267,414
306,440
299,093
283,711
268,374
265,301
249,751
245,742
273,474
311,681
293,026
266,669
241,867
235,949
1944
(8)
1943
94.3
87.6
88.6
70.0
67.2
72.9
79.5
118.1
132.2
149.3
171.1
167.0
158.4
149.8
148.1
139.4
137.2
(7)
0.017
10,828
9,750
10,083
7,640
7,211
7,656
8,262
15,746
15,259
15,817
19,066
18,668
17,116
15,736
15,668
14,510
13,344
14,036
163.6 174.0
(6)
1942
87,978
84,214
83,333
68,561
66,845
74,169
81,679
87,022
110,479
135,024
146,696
142,724
139,911
136,068
133,534
127,751
133,919
157,194
16,150
14,600
135.0 148.9
(5)
0.011
37.87
1939
173,236
177,446
13,937
13,104
(4) 131.7
0.012
33.92
1938
131,007
149,932
(3) 12,657
1941
34.50
(2)
129,067
1940
27.49
1937
1931
1936
46.79
1930
25.77
66.31
1929
1935
85.23
1928
26.07
87.98
1927
1934
84.68
1926
34.71
78.16
1925
29.79
79.21
1924
1932
70.25
1923
1933
70.17
64.95
1922
71.75
86.01
1921
1919
1920
53.82
60.44
1918
52.26
1917
203
| Appendix 1
323
373
452
1953
1954
1955
1,321
1,543
1,864
4,824
10,222
21,283
68,973
636
1,692
3,652
4,069
4,684
4,466
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1959
1960
628
1,004
1958
556
273
1952
626
175
1951
1957
146
1950
1956
52
91
1948
1949
39,000
49,000
50,000
54,000
68,000
75,000
92,000
125,000
117,000
123,000
130,000
144,000
158,000
146,000
124,000
140,357
136,253
151,316
125,712
111,144
97,235
103,323
106,963
65,014
51,084
4,562
4,202
3,958
4,025
3,307
2,939
3,860
4,397
4,841
5,127
5,599
6,494
6,564
6,000
5,836
6,158
6,548
6,822
6,304
6,042
5,464
5,881
5,391
4,976
3,510
36.0
39.2
38.4
40.3
41.9
41.7
53.0
66.2
67.4
71.2
76.5
86.7
91.4
84.0
76.5
83.7
85.1
91.6
80.3
74.0
65.9
70.4
68.7
52.6
39.2
3,344
3,545
3,378
3,407
4,028
4,971
6,003
7,322
6,329
6,548
7,057
7,201
5,056
4,016
3,437
3,003
3,482
3,785
1,532
1,039
949
855
860
739
665
881
973
1,045
1,072
1,157
1,245
1,159
1,046
1,069
1,044
1,053
976
902
789
827
723
434
(6)
33.0 32.0 33.4 32.0
25.6 27.6 27.9
34.1
34.9
44.3
53.7
53.7
56.2
60.4
66.6
67.4
61.6
58.2
61.4
62.0
63.8
55.7
50.8
45.0
48.5
47.4
32.9
(8)
25.7
26.3
28.0
35.5
41.3
40.0
41.2
44.4
46.6
43.4
39.1
40.0
39.1
36.0
31.0
27.6
24.1
26.6
26.1
13.1
(7)
57,244
59,771
57,306
59,139
61,077
62,498
79,277
96,249
96,207
100,622
108,265
119,345
120,656
110,247
104,324
109,895
111,042
114,284
99,732
91,012
80,584
86,925
84,946
58,868
70,248
(9)
(10)
8.13
7.62
7.34
6.50
5.56
2.48
0.93
79.84
19.73
9.30
4.16
1.50
1.09
0.887
0.734
0.504
0.459
0.401
0.303
0.285
0.268
0.254
0.152
0.130
0.106
0.058
(5)
0.082
(4)
1947
(3)
1946
(2) 0.033
(1)
1945
204
| Accounting for Services
307,900
504,000
622,300
743,740
1998
1999
2000
287,400
1997
263,609
1996
152,145
1992
1995
125,080
1991
179,100
105,788
1990
219,300
100,475
1989
1994
85,788
1988
1993
60,371
52,721
1985
69,892
38,247
1984
1987
30,793
1983
1986
26,031
1982
1979
21,874
15,939
1978
24,468
10,900
1977
1981
7,975
1976
1980
6,138
6,723
1975
5,274
1974
(1)
4,037
1973
(2)
191,600
160,300
169,800
158,600
153,700
144,500
115,866
98,200
73,057
62,228
58,212
55,542
52,251
48,565
48,659
46,693
46,742
46,261
43,697
43,264
41,754
40,469
31,445
23,039
22,277
22,521
28,292
27,000
(3)
19,544
19,286
18,217
19,186
18,421
16,868
16,368
15,690
14,988
13,726
12,537
11,768
10,317
8,577
7,589
6,752
6,423
5,066
4,700
4,971
4,859
5,174
4,500
3,819
3,449
4,064
4,728
4,971
(4)
158.0
143.1
142.9
141.5
136.4
126.6
111.2
100
85.0
75.1
69.4
65.7
59.7
52.6
49.6
45.8
44.8
39.8
37.3
38.1
37.0
37.7
31.0
24.5
22.9
25.1
30.4
30.5
19,228
17,829
16,196
15,518
15,223
15,500
13,610
12,377
10,459
9,767
9,290
8,426
7,863
7,515
7,545
6,774
6,379
6,106
6,294
6,166
6,089
5,758
4,759
3,809
3,522
3,409
3,468
(5)
5,009
5,035
4,963
5,030
4,700
4,172
3,854
3,955
3,778
3,470
3,190
2,921
2,360
1,758
1,464
1,333
1,173
916
885
970
961
1,021
1,015
853
703
916
1,118
(6)
134.2 135.8 139.7 149.6
128.8 136.2 141.2
128.9
120.9
107.4
100.0
87.5
79.2
73.7
68.4
60.8
52.6
48.9
44.8
42.3
37.2
35.9
37.0
36.2
36.6
31.7
25.6
23.1
25.7
29.9
267,957
250,121
243,294
240,295
230,938
216,506
192,407
179,100
156,688
141,897
131,979
122,456
108,851
94,166
87,657
80,166
75,700
66,595
64,273
66,240
64,910
65,603
56,785
45,761
41,345
46,106
53,633
(9) 54,555
(8) 30.5
126.9
121.4
115.2
103.7
100.0
90.0
83.4
78.0
71.1
61.9
52.6
48.3
43.7
39.8
34.6
34.5
35.8
35.4
35.6
32.4
26.6
23.2
26.4
29.5
(7)
(10)
269.38
259.77
215.58
136.59
128.06
118.76
108.45
100
91.09
84.73
77.52
71.86
67.52
62.48
57.21
54.03
51.63
46.74
42.21
38.75
35.67
30.90
25.66
23.75
21.41
17.86
15.00
10.66
A1.2
Road transport Road transport is more difficult to estimate than, for example, rail transport since no annual reports are available to rely on. Hence more indirect methods are used to obtain value added in this sector. Sources make it possible to estimate value added in road transport for the year 1930. Firstly, I tried to find out how many cars there were in Indonesia. Based on the number of cars imported, the number of cars registered and average revenue statistics, current price estimates can be derived. These estimates will probably be rather robust since figures, at least until 1935 when the registration system improved, are quite inaccurate. Therefore I derived the number of cars in operation by the following formula: Cars in operation (t) = Imports of cars (t) + Cars in operation (t-1) – 0.10 * Cars in operation (t-1). This method has the advantage of it relying on import statistics, which are in general quite accurate. And since Indonesia did not have its own automobile industry during the colonial period, all cars had to be imported. Statistics on motor vehicles for road traffic and import of cars are presented in table A1.5. Estimates of the cars in operation in Indonesia are given in table A1.6.
205
| Appendix 1
Table A1.5
Motor vehicles, 1910-1940 Motor vehicles for road traffic Cars
Trucks
Motorcycles
Imports of motor vehicles for road traffic Busses
Cars
Trucks
Motorcycles
1910 1911 1912 1913
1,330
x
x
1914
1,180
x
x
1915
777
x
287
1916
2,608
x
500
1917
2,768
1918
1,763
197
587
1919
2,857
669
710
1920
4,999
1,555
1,149
1921
4,740
1,931
1,327
1922
949
1,865
215
590
1923
x
x
x
x
3,169
61
491
1924
x
x
x
x
3,487
289
621
1925
38,709
4,676
7,215
224
7,537
859
991
1926
46,569
6,253
9,306
1,698
10,236
2,146
1,522
1927
54,889
8,040
11,106
3,043
9,694
3,033
2,531
1928
60,056
10,749
13,420
5,200
11,895
4,404
2,696
1929
67,863
16,077
14,788
5,590
12,321
5,902
2,700
1930
57,749
14,100
10,595
5,403
6,025
3,191
2,098
1931
59,495
14,876
11,275
6,318
3,903
1,796
1,040
1932
x
x
x
x
1,808
721
414
1933
60,065
12,007
16,172
7,341
1,950
1,221
551
1934
36,690
7,507
10,305
5,531
1,959
1,564
344
1935
43,446
9,602
11,781
6,639
3,842
1,201
476
1936
46,720
10,298
11,804
7,114
4,426
1,539
559
1937
49,437
11,524
12,517
8,889
5,947
3,379
1,140
1938
54,720
9,655
13,239
7,216
6,617
3,089
1,640
1939
56,067
10,164
13,959
6,826
5,470
1,820
1,367
1940
56,352
10,922
14,544
6,459
4,415
3,796
1,044
Source: cei ix 1989.
206
| Accounting for Services
Table A1.6 Cars in operation in Indonesia, 1913-1940 Number of cars in operation
Imports of cars
Index (1930=100)
1913
1,330
1,330
2.4
1914
2,377
1,180
4.2
1915
2,916
777
5.2
1916
5,233
2,608
9.3
1917
7,477
2,768
13.3
1918
8,493
1,763
15.2
1919
10,500
2,857
18.7
1920
14,449
4,999
25.8
1921
17,744
4,740
31.7
1922
17,835
1,865
31.8
1923
19,220
3,169
34.3
1924
20,785
3,487
37.1
1925
26,244
7,537
46.8
1926
33,856
10,236
60.4
1927
40,164
9,694
71.7
1928
48,043
11,895
85.7
1929
55,559
12,321
99.2
1930
56,028
6,025
100
1931
54,329
3,903
97.0
1932
50,704
1,808
90.5
1933
47,583
1,950
84.9
1934
44,784
1,959
79.9
1935
44,148
3,842
78.8
1936
46,720
4,426
83.4
1937
49,437
5,947
88.2
1938
54,720
6,617
97.7
1939
56,067
5,470
100.1
1940
56,352
4,415
100.6
Note: Number of cars in operation derived by the following formula: Cars in operation (t) = Imports of cars (t) + Cars in operation (t-1) – 0.10 * Cars in operation (t-1). Imports of cars taken from cei ix 1989.
207
| Appendix 1
The next step is to come up with an estimate of value added per car, truck and bus. For this I used the source Statistiek van het Taxi-verkeer in de Stad Soerabaja (Statistics on Taxi-Traffic in the City of Surabaya), which gives information about the revenues earned by taxis. From this source I calculated average value added per taxi per year to be around 2,700 guilders. Assuming, on average, a constant ratio between number of cars and taxis across Indonesia, and a similar cost structure, value added for transport by car comes to roughly 37.2 million guilders in 1929 (see table A1.7). Table A1.7 Value added by taxis in Indonesia, 1929 Number of cars
Taxis
Value added per taxi
Value added total
Surabaya
4,166
843 (=20.24 %)
2,710.15
2,284,635
Indonesia
67,863
13,735 (=20.24 %)
2,710.15
37,223,910
For value added by trucks and buses I had to rely on the same source, since no information is available about revenue and operating expenses of trucks and buses. Therefore I assumed that, because more people are needed (for among others loading/unloading, administration, etc.) to operate a bus or truck, the value added of these means of transportation is twice as high as that of a taxi. This is exactly in line with the assumptions made by Neumark (1954: 377) and Muljatno (1960: 176) who both had access to information from the Ministry of Communications and Ikatan Motor Indonesia (Indonesian Motor Union). The following calculation then gives us the value added of trucks and buses in 1930: Number of trucks * value added per truck (= 2 * value added by a taxi) + Number of buses * value added per bus (= 2 * value added by a taxi) = 16,077 * 5,420 guilders + 5.590 * 5,420 guilders = 116,513,740 guilders Now we only need an estimate for value added in traditional road transport. For this I relied on the 1930 population census. According to this census 166,521 persons were working in the sub-sector road transport. Based on the number of cars, bus and trucks in operation in 1930 (see above) I assumed that 15,000 of them worked as taxi drivers, and 65,000 for bus and truck companies (3 per bus/truck). This means that approximately 95,000 people were working as drivers of traditional means of transportation. It is unlikely that they earned significantly more than an unskilled labourer. Therefore it is assumed that on average someone working in this sector earns a wage close to that of an unskilled labourer (cei xiii 1992: 120). This means that the contribution of traditional road transport to gdp was 95.000 * 0.50 guilders per day * 320 days = 15.2 million guilders in 1930. Adding up value added by cars, trucks, buses and traditional modes of transport I arrived at a total value added in current prices in road transport of nearly 170 million in 1930 (see table A1.8).
208
| Accounting for Services
Table A1.8 Value added by road transport, 1930
1930 Source: See text
Traditional road transport 15,200
Taxis/cars
Trucks/buses
Total road transport
37,224
116,514
168,938
To arrive at value added constant price estimates the following procedure is used. • Traditional road transport is extrapolated based on an urbanisation index. The underlying reasoning for this is not that in urban areas the demand for traditional forms of road transport is higher than in rural areas, but that urbanisation functions as a proxy for the level of market activity. In a subsistence economy all people live in rural areas and there is no need to market their products and hence demand for (traditional forms of) transport is limited. • Taxis, cars, buses and trucks are extrapolated based on the number of cars in Indonesia. From these constant price series I obtained value added in current prices by assuming that value added in this sector followed the development of the cost-of-living index. This index is taken from Van Leeuwen (2007). The constant price series is inflated by this index. The results of these exercises are summarised in appendix table A1.9. The estimation of gross value added at current prices in Indonesia’s post-independence national accounts was rather intransparant. The available information does show that estimation methods were essentially the same as used for the colonial period, so that a more or less consistent series is obtained. In nearly all cases, however, the underlying data are not available, so that I have to rely on the aggregated estimates. Due to this very limited data availability some crude procedures have to be followed, which particularly build on the Input-Output tables. The years for which i-o tables were published are used as benchmark years from which estimates for other years are obtained by extrapolation, based on a volume index of number of motor vehicles and inflated for the years within. The various key indicators for this procedure are given in appendix tables A1.10 and A1.11. The complete time-series for value added in road transport are presented in table A1.12.
209
| Appendix 1
210
| Accounting for Services
11,932
12,008
12,084
12,160
12,464
1918
1919
1920
1921
11,856
1916
1917
11,780
11,476
1911
11,704
11,400
1910
1915
11,324
1909
1914
11,248
1908
11,552
11,172
1907
11,628
11,096
1906
1913
11,020
1905
1912
10,868
10,944
1904
1902
1903
10,716
10,792
1901
10,640
1900
Traditional road transport
11,789
9,600
6,976
5,642
4,968
3,476
1,938
1,579
884
Taxis
Constant prices (1930=100) (in thousands of guilders)
Table A1.9 Value added by road transport, 1900-1940
36,900
30,048
21,836
17,661
15,550
10,882
6,065
4,943
2,766
Trucks/buses
61,153
51,808
40,896
35,311
32,449
26,214
19,782
18,226
15,277
11,552
11,476
11,400
11,324
11,248
11,172
11,096
11,020
10,944
10,868
10,792
10,716
10,640
Total
0.027
0.032
0.019
0.019
0.015
0.014
0.013
0.013
0.014
0.015
0.013
0.012
0.012
0.013
0.012
0.011
0.010
0.010
0.012
0.011
0.012
0.010
cpi(1930=100) (Van Leeuwen 2007)
113,145
119,884
64,394
56,166
38,066
29,594
21,843
17,367
12,710
13,584
11,505
10,189
9,933
10,319
9,531
8,198
7,517
7,571
8,201
7,601
7,947
6,199
Current prices (in thousands of guilders)
211
| Appendix 1
14,592
14,896
15,200
15,504
15,808
16,112
1928
1929
1930
1931
1932
1933
17,328
17,632
17,936
18,240
1937
1938
1939
1940
17,024
14,288
1927
1936
13,984
1926
16,416
13,680
1925
16,720
13,376
1924
1935
13,072
1923
1934
12,768
1922
Traditional road transport
37,439
37,250
36,355
32,845
31,040
29,331
29,753
31,613
33,686
36,095
37,224
36,912
31,918
26,684
22,493
17,436
13,809
12,770
11,849
Taxis
Constant prices (1930=100) (in thousands of guilders)
119,195
117,336
96,297
136,595
124,915
145,138
78,515
106,366
116,000
126,616
116,514
129,442
85,766
80,966
83,588
71,805
43,224
39,970
37,089
Trucks/buses
174,874
172,521
150,284
186,768
172,979
191,188
124,685
154,091
165,494
178,215
168,938
181,250
132,276
121,938
120,065
102,920
70,410
65,812
61,706
Total
0.011
0.013
0.010
0.010
0.009
0.010
0.010
0.011
0.012
0.015
0.017
0.017
0.017
0.018
0.018
0.018
0.019
0.021
0.023
cpi(1930=100) (Van Leeuwen 2007)
108,459
133,014
88,702
109,031
94,350
108,409
72,632
98,220
119,383
153,628
162,447
150,205
130,621
123,198
126,230
108,838
103,803
104,131
106,902
Current prices (in thousands of guilders)
Table A1.10 Key indicators for road transport, 1949-2000 Roads Asphalted
Non-asphalted
14,357
35,073
Unspecified
Total
1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954
49,430
1955 1956 1957 1958 1959
13,583
37,251
28,474
79,308
1960
13,583
37,251
28,474
79,308
1961
14,538
36,484
28,239
79,261
1962
14,566
36,585
28,138
79,289
1963
19,658
34,297
25,462
79,417
1964
20,017
41,992
20,116
82,125
1965
20,877
42,273
20,116
83,266
1966
20,444
43,320
20,533
84,297
1967
20,444
43,320
20,533
84,297
1968
20,444
43,320
20,533
84,297
1969
20,444
43,320
20,533
84,297
1970
20,444
43,320
20,533
84,297
1971
23,347
39,497
26,534
89,378
1972
26,712
43,037
25,714
95,463
1973
29,089
42,912
25,995
97,996
1974
29,583
43,937
27,738
101,258
1975
33,051
44,856
26,774
104,681
1976
48,369
65,619
7,811
121,799 122,794
1977
49,319
65,017
8,458
1978
59,029
62,086
7,600
128,715
1979
57,746
62,889
8,427
129,062 146,498
1980
59,622
75,316
11,560
1981
65,827
79,860
11,580
157,267
1982
69,488
88,272
10,547
168,307 188,079
1983
75,999
98,266
13,814
1984
81,336
103,062
14,057
198,455
1985
84,363
111,016
11,984
207,363
1986
90,787
121,568
11,856
224,211
1987
99,467
117,048
10,829
227,344
212
| Accounting for Services
Number of motor vehicles 1949
Passenger cars
Trucks
Buses
Motorcycles
Total
17,626
15,949
2,756
4,584
40,915
1950
22,164
17,629
5,870
5,546
51,209
1951
31,046
21,649
7,643
7,663
68,001
1952
39,435
27,085
8,474
16,468
91,462
1953
41,026
27,767
8,644
21,082
98,519
1954
59,606
41,751
9,415
58,504
169,276
1955
61,104
43,128
9,620
67,194
181,046
1956
63,583
44,901
10,280
76,656
195,420
1957
73,219
51,410
11,498
99,079
235,206
1958
73,533
44,843
9,090
105,101
232,567 244,592
1959
74,819
46,552
9,882
113,339
1960
103,254
75,488
17,885
133,444
330,071
1961
129,262
69,837
17,852
152,228
369,179
1962
136,328
72,738
18,785
173,417
401,268
1963
143,189
77,264
23,146
196,223
439,822
1964
157,474
83,571
19,541
220,953
481,539 501,693
1965
165,955
83,798
18,021
233,919
1966
179,494
92,891
19,584
281,779
573,748
1967
184,954
94,892
18,840
287,522
586,208
1968
201,743
93,417
19,612
308,404
623,176
1969
218,866
94,065
19,367
368,724
701,022
1970
238,918
102,365
23,541
440,365
805,189
1971
259,282
115,082
22,797
516,949
914,110
1972
277,210
209,593
26,488
615,220
1,128,511
1973
307,739
144,060
30,368
720,011
1,202,178
1974
336,018
165,719
31,175
908,247
1,441,159
1975
337,911
196,416
35,133
1,192,051
1,761,511
1976
420,488
222,250
39,790
1,417,801
2,100,329
1977
479,155
278,979
60,769
1,717,807
2,536,710
1978
536,569
333,353
58,583
1,998,051
2,926,556
1979
581,531
393,109
69,770
2,307,215
3,351,625
1980
639,464
473,831
86,284
2,671,978
3,871,557
1981
719,336
589,439
113,509
3,207,499
4,629,783
1982
791,019
657,104
135,151
3,764,442
5,347,716
1983
685,940
717,873
160,260
4,135,677
5,879,750
1984
926,994
790,881
191,654
4,556,095
6,465,624
1985
990,651
845,338
227,304
4,794,517
6,857,810
1986
1,063,959
882,331
256,574
5,118,907
7,321,771
1987
1,170,103
953,694
303,378
5,554,305
7,981,480
213
| Appendix 1
Table A1.10 Continued Roads Asphalted
Non-asphalted
Unspecified
Total 254,934
1988
111,649
128,929
14,356
1989
121,313
133,522
16,340
271,175
1990
130,262
138,863
19,602
288,727 319,370
1991
142,053
146,157
31,160
1992
150,930
146,239
28,272
325,441
1993
159,329
155,119
30,444
344,892
1994
164,866
159,220
32,792
356,878
1995
171,508
135,505
20,214
327,227
1996
180,614
139,233
16,530
336,377
1997
192,668
132,237
16,562
341,467
1998
168,072
155,390
31,901
355,363
1999
203,374
136,210
16,367
355,951
2000
203,214
136,590
16,147
355,951
Table A1.11 Road transport according to i-o tables (in million of rupiah)
Value added
Revenue
Value added/ output ratio (%)
Operating surplus
Wages & salaries
Depreciation Indirect taxes
1975
419,663
628,452
66.8
289,414
80,300
41,205
8,744
1980
1,269,735
2,058,973
61.7
680,842
345,177
217,397
26,320
1985
3,169,333
5,569,754
56.9
1,667,171
801,474
633,557
67,131
1990
6,740,710
10,964,070
61.5
3,501,815
1,751,845
1,306,503
180,547
1995
16,210,519
24,896,045
65.1
9,719,649
3,592,806
2,636,997
261,067
2000
21,768,975
48,398,100
45.0
7,631,520
5,651,838
7,768,813
716,804
The information on the length of roads and number of motor vehicles is taken from: • bps, Statistical Yearbook of Indonesia, several volumes; • bps, Statistik perhubungan, 1999; • bps, Statistik Dalam 50 Tahun Indonesia Merdeka, 1995. In table A1.12 the statistics discussed before are used to calculate time-series estimates of value added in road transport.
214
| Accounting for Services
Number of motor vehicles Passenger cars
Trucks
Buses
Motorcycles
Total 7,770,949
1988
1,073,106
892,581
385,731
5,419,531
1989
1,182,253
952,461
434,903
5,722,291
8,291,908
1990
1,313,210
1,024,296
468,550
6,082,966
8,889,022
1991
1,494,607
1,087,940
504,720
6,494,871
9,582,138
1992
1,590,750
1,126,262
539,943
6,941,000
10,197,955
1993
1,700,454
1,160,539
568,490
7,355,114
10,784,597
1994
1,890,340
1,251,986
651,608
8,134,903
11,928,837
1995
2,107,299
1,336,177
688,525
9,076,831
13,208,832
1996
2,410,526
1,454,585
724,914
10,296,077
14,886,102
1997
2,639,523
1,548,397
611,402
11,735,797
16,535,119
1998
2,772,531
1,592,572
627,969
12,651,813
17,644,885
1999
2,897,803
1,628,531
644,667
13,053,148
18,224,149
2000
3,038,913
1,707,134
666,280
13,563,017
18,975,344
Notes for table A1.12 (1) = (2) = (3) = (4) = (5) = (6) = (7) = (8) =
215
Value added in current prices (million guilders/rupiah) Value added for the colonial period is taken from table A1.9. Bold indicates the numbers taken from the i-o tables. Other years are calculated by by extrapolation based on the volume index (8) and corrected for inflation using the cpi index (11) by Van Leeuwen (2007). Number of motor vehicles Volume index of number of motor vehicles (1993=100) Value added in constant (1930=100) prices Value added index (1930=100) Value added in constant (1993=100) prices Value added in constant prices corrected for decreasing weight of traditional transport (million fl/Rp) Constant price estimates are obtained by extrapolation using the volume index of motor vehicles. In the period 1900-1930 this method would severely under-estimate traditional road transport, since road transport by motor vehicle was still only marginal. A correction has been made for this by extrapolating the constant (1993=100) price estimate for 1993 by the value added index (5). cpi (Van Leeuwen 2007)
| Appendix 1
Table A1.12 Value added by road transport, 1900-2000 (1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
1900
7.2
10.6
6.3
18,501
0.010
1901
8.6
10.7
6.3
18,633
0.012
1902
8.1
10.8
6.4
18,765
0.011
1903
8.5
10.9
6.4
18,897
0.012
1904
8.1
10.9
6.5
19,029
0.010
1905
7.9
11.0
6.5
19,162
0.010
1906
8.4
11.1
6.6
19,294
0.011
1907
9.5
11.2
6.6
19,426
0.012
1908
10.1
11.2
6.7
19,558
0.013
1909
9.3
11.3
6.7
19,690
0.012
1910
9.4
11.4
6.7
19,822
0.012
1911
10.3
11.5
6.8
19,955
0.013
1912
11.6
11.6
6.8
20,087
0.015
1913
14.2
1,330
0.0
15.3
9.0
4,536
23,297
0.014
1914
16.5
2,377
0.1
21.8
12.9
8,107
33,246
0.013
1915
17.7
2,916
0.1
28.0
16.6
9,947
42,682
0.013
1916
25.9
5,233
0.2
35.4
20.9
17,847
53,917
0.014
1917
37.6
7,477
0.2
42.7
25.3
25,503
65,081
0.015
1918
52.2
8,493
0.2
49.2
29.1
28,966
74,998
0.019
1919
64.7
10,500
0.3
56.3
33.4
35,814
85,921
0.019
1920
124.9
14,449
0.4
64.8
38.4
49,282
98,811
0.032
1921
111.1
17,744
0.5
73.0
43.2
60,521
111,386
0.027
1922
85.5
17,835
0.5
79.2
46.9
60,830
120,714
0.023
1923
87.9
86.1
51.0
131,355
0.021
1924
103.3
93.2
55.2
142,177
0.019
1925
147.6
31,144
0.9
102.9
60.9
106,222
156,944
0.018
1926
172.5
41,807
1.2
120.1
71.1
142,589
183,087
0.018
1927
162.3
51,247
1.5
121.9
72.2
174,787
185,943
0.018
1928
172.9
63,992
1.9
132.3
78.3
218,255
201,708
0.017
1929
248.5
77,226
2.3
152.9
90.5
263,395
233,231
0.017
1930
224.5
75,531
2.2
168.9
100
257,614
257,614
0.017
1931
155.4
75,523
2.2
178.2
1932
117.8
1933
88.8
66,931
2.0
216
| Accounting for Services
257,584
0.015
165.5
239,198
0.012
154.1
228,282
0.011
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
1934
69.7
57,822
1.7
124.7
197,213
0.010
1935
106.5
60,389
1.8
191.2
205,967
0.010
1936
90.8
64,132
1.9
173.0
218,734
0.009
1937
122.1
69,850
2.0
186.8
238,237
0.010
1938
99.9
71,591
2.1
150.3
244,175
0.010
1939
109.6
73,057
2.1
172.5
249,175
0.013
1940
115.9
73,733
2.1
174.9
251,480
0.011
1941
0.012
1942
0.017
1943
0.016
1944
0.024
1945
0.033
1946
0.058
1947
0.082
1948
0.106
1949
189
36,331
1.1
123,914
0.130
1950
292
45,663
1.3
155,742
0.152
1951
452
60,338
1.8
205,794
0.254
1952
936
74,994
2.2
255,781
0.268
1953
1,020
77,437
2.3
264,114
0.285
1954
1,550
110,772
3.2
377,809
0.303
1955
1,693
113,852
3.3
388,314
0.401
1956
2,339
118,764
3.5
405,067
0.459
1957
3,070
136,127
4.0
464,287
0.504
1958
3,155
127,466
3.7
434,747
0.734
1959
4,730
131,253
3.8
447,663
0.887
1960
8,567
196,627
5.7
670,634
1.09
1961
11,643
216,951
6.3
739,952
1.50
1962
16,739
227,851
6.6
777,129
4.16
1963
49,773
243,599
7.1
830,840
9.30
1964
119,052
260,586
7.6
888,778
19.73
1965
259,426
267,774
7.8
913,294
79.84
1966
1,144,871
291,969
8.5
995,815
0.93
1967
13,714
298,686
8.7
1,018,725
2.48
1968
38,300
314,772
9.2
1,073,589
5.56
217
| Appendix 1
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
1969
90,783
332,298
9.7
1,133,365
6.50
1970
116,421
364,824
10.6
1,244,301
7.34
1971
143,152
397,161
11.6
1,354,593
7.62
1972
192,080
513,291
15.0
1,750,676
8.13
1973
192,610
482,167
14.1
1,644,522
10.66
1974
278,947
532,912
15.5
1,817,597
15.00
1975
419,663
569,460
16.6
1,942,251
17.86
1976
603,059
682,528
19.9
2,327,891
21.41
1977
802,546
818,903
23.9
2,793,023
23.75
1978
983,400
928,505
27.1
3,166,842
25.66
1979
1,331,822 1,044,410
30.5
3,562,158
30.90
1980
1,269,735
35.0
4,091,391
35.67
1,199,579
1981
1,635,688 1,422,284
41.5
4,850,968
38.75
1982
1,983,369
1,583,274
46.2
5,400,055
42.21
1983
2,169,785
1,564,073
45.6
5,334,567
46.74
1984
2,925,787 1,909,529
55.7
6,512,810
51.63
1985
3,169,333 2,063,293
60.2
7,037,251
54.03
1986
3,582,764 2,202,864
64.2
7,513,284
57.21
1987
4,311,321
2,427,175
70.8
8,278,339
62.48
1988
4,513,591
2,351,418
68.6
8,019,956
67.52
1989
5,249,553 2,569,617
74.9
8,764,164
71.86
1990
6,740,710 2,806,056
81.8
9,570,584
77.52
1991
8,105,945 3,087,267
90.0
10,529,708
84.73
1992
9,193,035
95.0
11,108,461
91.09
3,256,955
1993
11,696,900 3,429,483
100
11,696,900
100
1994
13,439,300
3,793,934
110.6
12,939,929
108.45
1995
16,210,519
4,132,001
120.5
14,092,970
118.76
1996
16,631,700 4,590,025
133.8
15,655,148
128.06
1997
18,240,400 4,799,322
139.9
16,368,995
136.59
1998
22,461,500 4,993,072
145.6
17,029,816
215.58
1999
20,594,800
5,171,001
150.8
17,636,676
259.77
2000
21,768,975
5,412,327
157.8
18,459,764
269.38
218
| Accounting for Services
A1.3
Water transport During the colonial period the most important player in shipping transport was the Koninklijke Paketvaart Maatschappij (kpm). In 1930 it was estimated that kpm covered 42.9 per cent of total intra-island shipping traffic or almost 80 per cent of intra-island shipping under the flag of the Netherlands-Indies (Statistiek van de Scheepvaart over het jaar 1930). Since the profit and loss accounts of this company are available it is possible to estimate its value added. The main sources for estimating water transport between 1900 and 1940 are the following: • • • • • • •
• •
Jaarcijfers voor het Koninkrijk der Nederlanden. Koloniën, The Hague, 1897-1921; Statistisch Jaaroverzicht van Nederlandsch-Indië, Batavia, 1922-1940; Koloniaal Verslag, The Hague, 1849-1930; Indisch Verslag, The Hague, 1931-1940; ara-ii, Archive of Koninklijke Paketvaart Maatschappij, uncoded items, 18921973 (2.20.58.01); ara-ii, Archive of Koninklijke Paketvaart Maatschappij and Koninklijke Java China Paketvaart Lijnen (kpm/kjcpl), balances and annual reports (2.20.59); Knaap, G.J. (1989), Changing Economy in Indonesia. A selection of statistical sources material from the early 19th century up to 1940. Volume 9: Transport 1819-1940, Edited by P. Boomgaard, Amsterdam: Royal Tropical Institute; á Campo, J.N.F.M. (1992), Koninklijke Paketvaart Maatschappij. Stoomvaart en staatsvorming in de Indonesische archipel, 1888-1914, Hilversum: Verloren; Departement der Marine, Statistiek van de scheepvaart, Batavia, 1910-1939.
Notes for table A1.13 (1) = (2) = (3) = (4) = (5) = (6) = (7) = (8) = (9) = (10)=
219
Number of steamers and motor vessels Burden of steamers and motor vessels (1,000 m3) Number of sailing vessels, European rigging Burden of sailing vessels, European rigging (1,000 m3) Number of sailing vessels, indigenous rigging Burden of sailing vessels, indigenous rigging (1,000 m3) Total number of sailing vessels Total burden of sailing vessels (1,000 m3) Total number of vessels Total burden of vessels (1,000 m3)
| Appendix 1
Table A1.13 General water transport statistics, 1891-1940 (1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
1891
77
70
192
87
1,605
76
1892
82
81
185
81
1,572
76
1893
82
77
181
79
1,627
78
1894
80
81
185
77
1,668
79
1895
81
82
201
81
1,720
81
1896
84
87
200
74
1,838
87
1897
81
90
183
65
1,826
94
1898
85
94
174
58
1,859
95
1899
104
110
176
63
1,951
107
1900
116
113
177
57
2,104
119
1901
145
141
179
58
2,269
132
1902
157
145
165
51
2,272
129
1903
176
157
145
50
2,308
134
1904
181
185
129
40
1,867
115
1905
183
194
137
43
2,316
145
1906
190
217
133
46
2,171
129
1907
190
247
278
63
2,327
144
1908
255
283
446
60
11,773
290
1909
255
268
234
57
10,068
249
1910
274
265
610
63
11,785
293
1911
314
303
408
54
8,888
235
1912
204
329
121
23
4,873
118
1913
152
225
54
22
4,756
157
1914
196
389
51
26
3,780
112
1915
216
395
44
24
5,508
143
1916
233
436
45
26
5,162
123
1917
235
442
41
15
5,040
119
1918
210
366
49
17
5,714
123
1919
220
430
44
27
5,833
131
1920
224
470
38
13
5,534
123
1921
224
479
33
10
5,491
125
1922
225
479
x
x
x
x
1923
226
507
x
x
x
x
1924
230
516
x
x
x
x
1925
250
515
x
x
x
x
1926
249
542
x
x
x
x
1927
309
583
x
x
x
x
1928
317
626
x
x
x
x
1929
323
684
x
x
x
x
1930
327
696
x
x
x
x
220
| Accounting for Services
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
1931
347
733
x
x
x
x
1932
311
714
x
x
x
x
1933
297
683
x
x
x
x
1934
309
676
x
x
x
x
1935
308
674
x
x
x
x
1936
x
x
x
x
x
x
1937
315
663
x
x
x
x
1938
347
726
x
x
x
x
1939
378
702
x
x
x
x
1940
475
1,859
x
x
x
x
(7)
(8)
(9)
(10)
1891
1,797
163
1,874
233
1892
1,757
157
1,839
238
1893
1,808
157
1,890
234
1894
1,853
156
1,933
237
1895
1,921
162
2,002
244
1896
2,038
161
2,122
248
1897
2,009
159
2,090
249
1898
2,033
153
2,118
247
1899
2,127
170
2,231
280
1900
2,281
176
2,397
289
1901
2,448
190
2,593
331
1902
2,437
180
2,594
325
1903
2,453
184
2,629
341
1904
1,996
155
2,177
340
1905
2,453
188
2,636
382
1906
2,304
175
2,494
392
1907
2,605
207
2,795
454
1908
12,219
350
12,474
633
1909
10,302
306
10,557
574
1910
12,395
356
12,669
621
1911
9,296
289
9,610
592
1912
4,994
141
5,198
470
1913
4,810
179
4,962
404
1914
3,831
138
4,027
527
1915
5,552
167
5,768
562
1916
5,207
149
5,440
585
1917
5,081
134
5,316
576
1918
5,763
140
5,973
506
221
| Appendix 1
(7)
(8)
(9)
(10)
1919
5,877
158
6,097
588
1920
5,572
136
5,796
606
1921
5,524
135
5,748
614
1922
5,399
129
5,624
608
1923
5,396
122
5,622
629
1924
5,231
123
5,461
639
1925
4,833
113
5,083
628
1926
5,387
126
5,636
668
1927
5,021
118
5,330
701
1928
5,430
132
5,747
758
1929
5,693
139
6,016
823
1930
5,926
143
6,253
839
1931
5,837
145
6,184
878
1932
5,725
145
6,036
859
1933
5,716
148
6,013
831
1934
5,669
149
5,978
825
1935
5,024
137
5,332
811
1936
x
x
x
x
1937
3,069
140
3,384
803
1938
3,635
155
3,982
881
1939
3,926
184
4,304
886
1940
4,292
205
4,767
2,064
Notes for table A1.14 (1) = (2) = (3) = (4) = (5) = (6) = (7) = (8) = (9) = (10)= (11)= (12)= (13)= (14)= (15)= (16)= (17)=
222
Number of kpm motor vessels Number of kpm steamers Burden of kpm vessels (1,000 m3 gross) Number of passengers transported by kpm kpm sea miles Depreciation on fleet Depreciation on buildings Revenue from government freight Revenue from government passages Revenue from private freight Revenue from private passages Total income from shipping services Total income kpm Operating expenses on shipping Value added/total cost ratio Value added/output ratio (13) * (16) = Value added kpm, current prices in thousands of guilders
| Accounting for Services
Table A1.14 Statistics on kpm, 1891-1940 (1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
1891
-
28
82
122
752
217,460
1892
-
30
87
150
808
388,825
1893
-
31
93
175
880
652,807
1894
-
31
93
179
963
762,691
1895
-
32
101
180
968
635,000
1896
-
31
102
213
1,026
820,556
1897
-
34
114
190
1,044
767,454
1898
-
34
122
193
1,137
765,719
1899
-
33
120
179
1,144
637,129
1900
-
36
134
197
1,164
748,431
1901
-
38
138
208
1,158
705,784
1902
-
45
169
240
1,244
720,812
1903
-
46
177
259
1,426
859,537
1904
-
45
176
294
1,429
977,281
1905
-
46
179
289
1,486
956,229
1906
-
47
187
366
1,540
983,554
1907
-
52
203
408
1,615
1,001,711
1908
-
60
241
449
1,731
1,098,654
1909
-
66
277
497
1,927
1,278,214
1910
-
68
278
565
2,045
1,390,750
1911
2
71
299
644
2,133
1,344,374
1912
2
78
362
680
2,265
1,455,267
1913
2
85
390
663
2,375
1,744,704
1914
4
86
425
680
2,405
1,961,193
1915
7
88
466
617
2,631
2,156,315
1916
7
86
456
689
2,899
2,178,873
1917
7
86
456
774
3,183
2,180,566
1918
7
85
442
667
2,713
2,104,997 1,997,750
1919
7
88
464
887
2,843
1920
7
91
483
991
2,837
2,386,853
1921
7
98
509
884
2,880
2,575,884
1922
7
100
539
736
2,916
2,896,306
1923
6
100
560
680
3,038
3,604,545
1924
6
100
551
742
3,248
3,800,070
1925
6
100
551
946
3,331
3,927,700
1926
8
107
592
1,167
3,586
3,927,700
1927
8
115
640
1,010
3,840
4,080,781
1928
10
125
739
1,075
4,138
6,536,228
1929
17
120
766
1,203
4,495
6,997,747
1930
32
113
808
1,024
4,436
7,381,862
1931
32
112
817
684
3,994
5,706,394
223
| Appendix 1
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
1932
34
110
816
528
3,589
5,678,451
1933
33
105
806
444
3,554
5,470,500
1934
33
98
780
421
3,567
5,393,175
1935
35
94
784
445
3,663
5,329,819
1936
35
93
762
418
3,679
5,586,200
1937
38
93
779
605
4,052
5,955,033 6,543,706
1938
42
89
872
527
3,931
1939
49
85
907
516
4,111
5,567,717
1940
53
85
914
501
4,216
5,552,969
(7)
(8)
(9)
(10)
(11)
(12)
1891
189,355
1,305,546
1,414,484
795,866
3,705,252
1892
200,294
1,339,761
1,526,459
880,057
3,946,571
1893
229,605
1,501,048
1,984,469
1,075,553
4,790,676
1894
247,400
1,452,828
2,185,012
1,068,886
4,954,126
1895
281,287
1,489,334
2,153,749
1,000,612
4,924,983
1896
271,981
1,866,395
2,139,056
1,049,937
5,327,368
1897
241,948
1,436,583
2,415,712
1,157,639
5,251,882
1898
339,124
1,545,448
2,504,261
1,352,854
5,741,687
1899
303,024
1,175,181
3,170,760
1,320,205
5,969,170
1900
299,765
1,095,922
3,463,100
1,494,394
6,353,180
1901
389,482
1,259,301
3,750,336
1,589,798
6,988,917
1902
385,309
1,494,815
3,952,052
1,606,462
7,438,637
1903
375,574
1,450,456
4,009,465
1,630,795
7,466,289
1904
417,060
1,348,348
4,105,594
1,678,244
7,549,247
1905
344,545
1,265,623
4,210,888
1,736,567
7,557,624
1906
337,212
1,354,125
4,643,040
1,883,786
8,218,163
1907
343,785
1,234,460
4,021,228
2,164,757
7,764,230
1908
318,851
1,465,894
5,301,207
2,259,121
9,345,074
1909
401,509
1,362,523
5,876,994
2,489,247
10,130,272
1910
564,530
1,442,571
7,456,094
3,133,826
12,597,021
1911
66,015
601,582
1,412,909
7,971,268
3,706,359
13,692,118
1912
105,924
599,682
1,446,622
8,917,185
3,965,959
14,929,448
1913
117,737
704,398
1,536,449
10,272,910
4,262,923
16,776,680
1914
193,796
809,000
1,817,000
11,842,000
4,243,000
18,711,000
1915
313,872
1,176,058
1,622,883
15,182,677
4,174,154
22,155,772
1916
334,817
2,239,000
1,746,000
19,318,000
4,724,000
28,027,000
1917
385,321
3,121,000
1,804,000
25,247,000
5,460,000
35,632,000
1918
502,015
1919
599,285
4,002,286
2,048,062
35,542,516
7,987,968
49,580,832
1920
822,829
5,053,138
2,400,661
31,537,587
9,771,903
50,299,163
1921
1,055,871
6,338,339
2,709,698
32,025,543
10,908,710
51,982,291
224
| Accounting for Services
(7)
(8)
(9)
(10)
(11)
(12)
4,624,794
2,299,738
30,991,878
9,575,835
47,492,245
1,297,110
4,392,117
2,030,782
31,061,559
9,025,515
46,509,973
1,387,415
4,381,299
2,055,695
32,307,367
9,779,409
48,523,770
1925
1,679,071
4,088,384
2,096,960
35,205,190
11,606,713
54,756,492
1926
1,679,071
3,904,765
2,787,175
37,253,059
14,041,663
57,986,662
1927
2,648,304
4,391,500
3,108,760
39,588,824
15,136,398
62,225,483
1928
2,397,605
4,474,503
3,040,447
42,333,620
15,746,711
65,595,281
1929
2,856,856
4,565,211
3,209,750
46,233,878
17,796,062
71,804,901
1930
962,333
4,802,763
3,173,193
39,670,366
14,864,853
62,511,175
1931
276,282
3,585,348
2,518,051
30,274,412
10,370,360
46,748,170
1932
193,984
2,327,177
1,900,431
24,790,511
8,150,459
37,168,576
1933
197,611
2,473,773
2,038,919
26,353,775
6,700,006
37,566,473
1922
1,847,183
1923 1924
1934
197,365
2,391,355
2,133,935
25,342,059
6,447,971
36,315,320
1935
229,647
2,475,049
1,892,303
25,624,318
6,406,359
36,398,029
1936
341,888
2,527,767
1,749,088
24,988,731
6,251,467
35,517,052
1937
1,927,240
3,104,249
1,800,006
34,821,814
9,316,171
49,042,239
1938
642,476
3,654,020
1,749,185
34,267,547
8,391,457
48,062,209
1939
16,625
4,655,064
1,790,065
38,806,177
8,402,428
53,653,735
1940
123,020
5,531,174
1,949,004
45,659,603
7,201,612
60,341,393
(15)
(16)
(17)
(13)
(14)
1891
4,754,992
1892
4,968,863
3,804 3,975
1893
5,827,842
4,662
1894
6,625,076
5,300
1895
6,137,533
4,910
1896
6,718,108
5,374
1897
6,619,349
5,295
1898
7,174,197
5,739
1899
7,110,442
5,688
1900
7,753,525
6,203
1901
8,205,544
6,564
1902
8,260,978
6,609 6,970
1903
8,712,135
1904
8,984,223
7,187
1905
9,294,163
7,435
1906
9,593,581
7,675
1907
10,055,842
8,045
1908
10,756,401
8,605
1909
11,405,565
9,124
1910
14,023,505
11,219
1911
15,442,000
12,354
225
| Appendix 1
(13)
(14)
(15)
(16)
(17)
1912
17,559,000
14,047
1913
20,051,000
16,041
1914
21,285,000
17,028
1915
24,497,000
19,598
1916
35,911,000
19,707,893
28,729
1917
52,767,000
24,064,247
42,214
1918
50,386,798
26,114,875
40,309
1919
52,413,850
33,274,714
41,931
1920
52,388,080
45,563,231
41,910
1921
55,963,124
47,552,561
44,770
1922
32,025,543
1923
40,144,045
1924
37,994 79.6%
37,208
40,959,894
81.3%
38,819
1925
53,406,993
41,867,137
83.2%
42,726
1926
58,571,854
44,787,854
46.8%
85.3%
46,857
1927
61,989,663
47,360,963
47.7%
87.7%
49,592
1928
66,110,880
51,602,850
46.6%
89.3%
52,889
1929
70,223,854
57,114,910
88.6%
56,179
1930
61,398,851
56,306,932
84.6%
49,119
1931
47,304,652
51,090,210
47.6%
81.0%
37,844
1932
37,693,727
42,626,301
47.1%
85.6%
1933
33,481,474
39,224,451
1934
32,745,630
36,164,337
26,197
1935
33,023,884
35,336,287
26,419
1936
23,763,013
30,155 26,785
47.3%
28,414
1937
58,760,247
28,829,962
46.1%
71.1%
47,008
1938
57,056,917
31,187,765
46.3%
65.9%
45,646
1939
63,674,116
31,421,947
46.4%
66.8%
50,939
1940
69,693,883
35,218,859
42.0%
64.2%
55,755
Notes for table A.15 (1) = (2) = (3) =
226
Value added kpm, current prices/80% = Value added water transport, current prices in thousands of guilders Volume index (burden 1,000 m3), 1939 =100 (1)/(2) * 100 = Value added water transport, constant prices (1939 = 100) in thousands of guilders
| Accounting for Services
227
Table A1.15 Value added by water transport, 1891-1940 (1)
(2)
(3)
1891
4,755
26.3
18,081
1892
4,969
26.9
18,498
1893
5,828
26.4
22,066
1894
6,625
26.7
24,767
1895
6,138
27.5
22,286
1896
6,718
28.0
24,001
1897
6,619
28.1
23,553
1898
7,174
27.9
25,734 22,499
1899
7,110
31.6
1900
7,754
32.6
23,770
1901
8,206
37.4
21,964
1902
8,261
36.7
22,521
1903
8,712
38.5
22,636
1904
8,984
38.4
23,412
1905
9,294
43.1
21,557
1906
9,594
44.2
21,683
1907
10,056
51.2
19,624
1908
10,756
71.4
15,056
1909
11,406
64.8
17,605
1910
14,024
70.1
20,008
1911
15,442
66.8
23,111
1912
17,559
53.0
33,101
1913
20,051
45.6
43,973
1914
21,285
59.5
35,785
1915
24,497
63.4
38,620
1916
35,911
66.0
54,388
1917
52,767
65.0
81,166
1918
50,387
57.1
88,227
1919
52,414
66.4
78,977
1920
52,388
68.4
76,594
1921
55,963
69.3
80,755
1922
47,492
68.6
69,207
1923
46,510
71.0
65,513
1924
48,524
72.1
67,280
1925
53,407
70.9
75,348
1926
58,572
75.4
77,687
1927
61,990
79.1
78,349
1928
66,111
85.6
77,275
1929
70,224
92.9
75,599
1930
61,399
94.7
64,838
| Appendix 1
(1)
(2)
(3)
1931
47,305
99.1
47,736
1932
37,694
97.0
38,879
1933
33,481
93.8
35,697
1934
32,746
93.1
35,167
1935 1936
33,024 35,517
91.5 x
36,078 39,030
1937
58,760
90.6
64,834
1938
57,057
99.4
57,381
1939
63,674
100
63,674
1940
69,694
In the 1960s estimates were based on Bank Indonesia’s statistics of Indonesianowned and chartered tonnage in inter-insular and ocean trade. Gross value added at constant prices was obtained by deflating current price estimates by the cost of living index. From the 1980s onwards output and current prices were estimated by multiplying the number of cargoes and passengers transported by tariff per unit of cargo and passenger, respectively. Average output data were derived from shipping enterprise reports, while data on cost structure were based on Input-Output tables. Cargo and passenger data were provided by the National Shipowner Association (insa), bps and other sources. Gross value added at constant prices was calculated by extrapolation using weighted composite indices of cargoes and passengers transported. Just as with the other sub-sectors, these underlying reports and surveys have never been published. It is also remarkable that, besides loading and unloading statistics, other data on cargo and passengers or systematic data on the number of ships sailing under the Indonesian flag have never been published by bps. So, again, for the period 1950-2000 the i-o tables serve as starting point from which estimates for the other years are arrived at by extrapolation (tables A1.18-A1.20). Other informative, available statistics (tables A1.16 and A1.17) on shipping in Indonesia from 1950 until 2000 are taken from: • bps, Statistical Yearbook of Indonesia, several volumes; • bps, Statistik perhubungan, 1999; • bps, Statistik Dalam 50 Tahun Indonesia Merdeka, 1995.
228
| Accounting for Services
Table A1.16 Loading and unloading (x1,000 tons) in Indonesian harbours, 1952-2002 Loading 1952
Unloading
Inter-island
International
Total
Inter-island
International
Total
3,417
2,870
6,287
3,417
2,537
5,954
5,200
2,500
7,700
5,200
3,100
8,300
1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958
4,881
2,142
7,023
4,881
2,311
7,192
1959
5,267
2,220
7,487
5,267
2,513
7,780
1960
5,740
2,137
7,877
5,740
2,777
8,517
1961
5,813
2,407
8,220
5,813
3,349
9,162
1962
5,496
2,081
7,577
5,496
2,496
7,992
1963
5,674
2,365
8,039
5,777
1,859
7,636
1964
5,858
2,250
8,108
6,073
22,345
28,418
1965
6,048
2,346
8,394
6,384
2,165
8,549
1966
8,200
2,452
10,652
6,630
2,628
9,258
1967
8,868
2,581
11,449
6,948
2,669
9,617
1968
8,975
2,910
11,885
7,877
2,556
10,433
1969
11,067
28,335
39,402
8,473
3,861
12,334
1970
13,207
33,208
46,415
9,694
4,666
14,360
1971
14,166
42,425
56,591
12,078
5,406
17,484
1972
14,632
60,077
74,709
12,980
6,234
19,214
1973
17,483
70,977
88,460
16,839
8,940
25,779
1974
14,973
57,776
72,749
10,734
10,328
21,062
1975
13,042
53,166
66,208
13,480
9,209
22,689
1976
15,770
67,152
82,922
16,913
9,654
26,567
1977
18,424
65,763
84,187
18,827
11,968
30,795
1978
16,129
60,845
76,974
26,576
10,841
37,417
1979
20,292
60,295
80,587
28,655
10,981
39,636
1980
22,298
61,166
83,464
32,764
13,354
46,118
1981
24,593
59,463
84,056
35,356
13,758
49,114
1982
25,465
57,372
82,837
39,284
16,296
55,580
1983
26,285
62,402
88,687
40,075
16,868
56,943
1984
30,930
66,801
97,731
47,670
12,427
60,097
1985
36,967
54,814
91,781
47,531
15,886
63,417
1986
45,816
63,589
109,405
56,290
20,302
76,592
1987
49,227
74,946
124,173
63,235
20,408
83,643
229
| Appendix 1
Table A1.16 Continued Loading Inter-island
Unloading
International
Total
Inter-island
International
Total
135,433
62,925
21,601
84,526
139,725
72,444
22,798
95,242
178,822
88,009
26,105
114,114
189,054
94,504
34,903
129,407
215,678
111,664
38,178
149,842
140,861
234,861
112,462
41,973
154,435
111,131
155,869
267,000
123,332
48,857
172,189
178,554
131,692
310,246
136,068
72,803
208,871
160,953
132,693
293,646
141,150
74,178
215,328
147,769
131,289
279,058
148,055
67,196
215,251
113,487
133,700
247,187
119,792
47,138
166,930
1999
113,633
139,340
252,973
122,368
43,477
165,845
2000
127,740
141,528
269,268
137,512
45,040
182,552
1988
53,308
82,125
1989
56,879
82,846
1990
69,332
109,490
1991
75,674
113,380
1992
87,107
128,571
1993
94,000
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998
2001
135,298
154,435
289,733
156,042
51,660
207,702
2002
137,949
163,340
301,289
170,201
53,660
223,861
Table A1.17 Arrival of ships and vessels in selected harbours, 1938-1959 Djakarta No.
Semarang m3
Surabaja
Belawan
No.
m3
No.
m3
No.
m3
1938
5,917
16,904
4,130
13,856
19,436
15,005
3,318
9,994
1939
6,456
17,298
6,650
13,827
22,021
15,789
3,274
10,083
1940
7,002
15,444
5,934
10,844
18,016
13,574
3,299
7,022
1950
3,423
14,635
3,098
6,272
4,762
10,163
1,993
5,982
1951
4,040
13,315
2,072
6,479
5,134
10,349
2,873
6,529
1952
4,785
15,325
2,224
7,261
5,238
10,526
3,255
7,492
1953
4,716
16,400
2,081
8,030
4,641
11,405
2,355
5,952
1954
4,628
15,618
1,785
8,591
4,788
12,631
1,941
5,290
1955
4,989
15,773
1,821
7,432
5,015
12,641
3,559
9,658
1956
5,128
15,337
1,703
6,998
6,445
13,602
3,349
9,264
1957
5,329
16,062
1,736
7,517
6,737
12,416
2,537
7,333
1958
5,301
12,559
1,567
4,656
7,008
8,190
1959
7,524
11,934
1,769
5,039
7,850
9,495
230
| Accounting for Services
Table A1.17 Continued Palembang No. 1938
1,967
Pontianak
Balikpapan
Makassar
m3
No.
m3
No.
m3
No.
m3
7,089
3,299
581
2,348
5,348
9,317
6,863
1939
1,955
7,558
4,483
624
2,897
5,885
8,393
6,751
1940
2,132
7,897
3,738
549
2,641
6,961
9,217
5,425
1950
3,337
14,009
2,357
656
2,016
3,066
3,551
5,394
1951
3,220
12,388
2,677
696
2,081
4,990
4,873
5,565
1952
3,991
13,005
2,883
648
2,045
6,146
3,964
6,342
1953
4,417
13,283
3,245
564
3,724
8,272
3,315
6,326
1954
4,187
13,338
3,313
706
2,875
8,190
3,089
5,849
1955
2,823
8,167
3,515
707
2,506
8,240
2,926
5,492
1956
3,658
10,476
3,312
628
192
708
2,198
4,430
1957
4,925
14,608
2,939
632
946
3,291
2,444
4,384
1958
4,774
14,509
3,448
495
2,868
5,440
2,311
2,064
1959
3,917
9,881
1,762
484
2,435
5,797
2,331
2,935
Manado 1938
Other
Total
No.
m3
No.
m3
No.
m3
1,152
1,607
57,181
66,724
108,065
143,971
1939
1,188
1,886
58,865
66,693
116,182
146,394
1940
1,209
1,906
57,667
53,030
110,855
122,652
1950
1,162
1,427
80,741
39,325
106,440
100,929
1951
1,685
1,446
116,226
45,083
144,881
106,840
1952
1,535
1,014
114,730
47,464
144,650
115,223
1953
1,929
1,205
133,965
59,896
164,388
131,333
1954
1,784
1,141
73,380
39,176
101,770
110,530
1955
1,564
1,095
135,693
55,726
164,411
124,931
1956
1,769
1,090
140,579
48,667
168,333
111,200
1957
1,753
1,615
144,901
44,507
174,247
112,365
1958
746
202
143,194
39,437
171,217
87,552
1959
1,468
598
133,251
42,697
162,307
88,860
231
| Appendix 1
Notes for tables A1.18-A1.20 (1) = (2) = (3) = (4) = (5) =
Value added Revenue Value added/output ratio (%) Operating surplus Wages and salaries
(6) = Depreciation (7) = Indirect taxes Table A1.18 Value added by sea transport according to i-o tables (in million rupiah) (1) 1975
30,044
(2)
(3)
(4)
124,448
24.1
2,970
(5) 17,470
(6) 9,576
(7) 28
1980
155,090
373,178
41.6
51,444
70,634
29,616
3,396
1985
459,891
988,548
46.5
160,695
191,041
103,075
5,080
1990
1,363,576
2,730,419
49.9
739,662
183,968
417,280
22,666
1995
2,992,684
5,435,042
55.1
1,272,425
943,738
651,200
125,321
2000
6,914,009
26,596,337
26.0
3,242,053
1,459,412
1,780,221
432,325
Table A1.19 Value added by inland water transport according to i-o tables (in million rupiah) (1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
1975
131,704
170,158
77.4
82,893
34,281
13,137
1,394
1980
161,978
260,720
62.1
50,380
87,201
23,080
1,317
1985
321,993
512,018
62.9
110,573
162,778
45,737
2,905
1990
711,684
1,076,469
66.1
378,460
199,433
115,608
18,183
1995
1,139,906
1,681,200
67.8
618,885
313,522
164,262
43,238
2000
1,927,582
4,589,625
42.0
375,854
736,168
797,194
18,366
Table A1.20 Value added by sea transport and inland water transport according to i-o tables (in million rupiah) (1)
(2)
(3)
1975
161,748
294,605
54.9
(4)
(5)
(6)
85,863
51,751
22,712
(7)
1980
317,068
633,898
50.0
101,824
157,835
52,696
4,713
1985
781,884
1,500,566
52.1
271,268
353,819
148,812
7,985
1990
2,075,260
3,806,888
54.5
1,118,122
383,401
532,888
40,849
1995
4,132,590
7,116,242
58.1
1,891,310
1,257,260
815,462
168,559
2000
8,841,592
31,185,962
28.4
3,617,907
2,195,580
2,577,415
450,691
1,421
In table A1.21 the statistics discussed before are used to estimate value added in water transport for the period 1900-2000.
232
| Accounting for Services
Notes for table A1.21 (1) = (2) = (3) = (4) = (5) = (6) = (7) = (8) =
Value added in current prices (million guilders/rupiah) For the colonial period value added is taken from table A1.15. Bold indicates the numbers taken from the Input-Output tables. Other years are calculated by extrapolation based on the volume index (6) and corrected for inflation using the cpi index (11) by Van Leeuwen (2007). Volume index loading (1993=100) (calculated from table A1.16) Volume index unloading (1993=100) (calculated from table A1.16) Volume index burden 1,000m3 (1939=100) Volume index number of ships arriving in Indonesian ports (1939=100) ‘Chained’ volume index using (2), (3), (4), (5) For the years 1957-2000 an average of (2) and (3) is used. This is linked to the index (5) for the period 1938-1957. Then this index is again chained with index (4). Value added in constant 1993 prices (million guilders/rupiah) cpi (Van Leeuwen 2007)
Table A1.21 Value added by water transport, 1891-2000 (1) 1891 1892 1893 1894 1895 1896 1897 1898 1899 1900 1901 1902 1903 1904 1905 1906 1907 1908 1909 1910 1911 1912 1913 1914
233
(2)
4.75 4.97 5.83 6.63 6.14 6.72 6.62 7.17 7.11 7.75 8.21 8.26 8.71 8.98 9.29 9.59 10.06 10.76 11.41 14.02 15.44 17.56 20.05 21.29
| Appendix 1
(3)
(4) 26.3 26.9 26.4 26.7 27.5 28.0 28.1 27.9 31.6 32.6 37.4 36.7 38.5 38.4 43.1 44.2 51.2 71.4 64.8 70.1 66.8 53.0 45.6 59.5
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
0.7 0.7 0.7 0.7 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.9 0.9 1.0 1.0 1.1 1.1 1.2 1.2 1.4 2.0 1.8 1.9 1.8 1.5 1.3 1.6
25,185 25,726 25,294 25,618 26,375 26,807 26,915 26,699 30,266 31,239 35,779 35,130 36,859 36,751 41,291 42,372 49,074 68,422 62,045 67,125 63,991 50,803 43,669 56,965
0.011 0.012 0.011 0.010 0.009 0.009 0.013 0.010 0.010 0.010 0.012 0.011 0.012 0.010 0.010 0.011 0.012 0.013 0.012 0.012 0.013 0.015 0.014 0.013
1915 1916 1917 1918 1919 1920 1921 1922 1923 1924 1925 1926 1927 1928 1929 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957
234
(1) 24.50 35.91 52.77 50.39 52.41 52.39 55.96 47.49 46.51 48.52 53.41 58.57 61.99 66.11 70.22 61.40 47.30 37.69 33.48 32.75 33.02 35.52 58.76 57.06 63.67 69.69
142.9 324.4 341.8 412.7 271.5 580.9 681.1 774
(2)
(3)
2.7
3.9
3.3
5.4
| Accounting for Services
(4) 63.4 66.0 65.0 57.1 66.4 68.4 69.3 68.6 71.0 72.1 70.9 75.4 79.1 85.6 92.9 94.7 99.1 97.0 93.8 93.1 91.5 91.0 90.6 99.4 100
(5)
93.0 100 95.4
(6) 1.7 1.8 1.8 1.6 1.8 1.9 1.9 1.9 1.9 2.0 1.9 2.1 2.2 2.3 2.6 2.6 2.7 2.7 2.6 2.6 2.5 2.5 2.5 2.7 2.9 2.8
(7) 60,748 63,234 62,261 54,695 63,558 65,504 66,369 65,720 67,990 69,071 67,882 72,206 75,773 81,934 88,960 90,689 94,905 92,851 89,825 89,176 87,663 87,150 86,798 95,229 102.382 97.688
91.6 124.7 124.5 141.5 87.6 141.5 144.9 150.0
2.7 3.7 3.7 4.2 2.6 4.2 4.3 4.4
93,797 127,672 127,469 144,862 89,682 144,883 148,339 153,550
(8) 0.013 0.014 0.015 0.019 0.019 0.032 0.027 0.023 0.021 0.019 0.018 0.018 0.018 0.017 0.017 0.017 0.015 0.012 0.011 0.010 0.010 0.009 0.010 0.010 0.013 0.011 0.012 0.017 0.016 0.024 0.033 0.058 0.082 0.106 0.130 0.152 0.254 0.268 0.285 0.303 0.401 0.459 0.504
1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996
(1) 1,107 1,269 1,690 2,461 6,096 13,576 75,192 126,861 1,717 4,797 11,464 28,065 37,201 47,069 62,779 101,048 116,764 161,748 196,083 231,060 255,155 323,242 317,068 456,864 524,650 608,512 725,156 781,884 959,733 1,166,449 1,323,714 1,518,700 2,075,260 2,428,008 3,000,493 3,488,500 4,088,700 4,132,590 5,030,900
(2) 3.0 3.2 3.4 3.5 3.2 3.4 3.5 3.6 4.5 4.9 5.1 16.8 19.8 24.1 31.8 37.7 31.0 28.2 35.3 35.8 32.8 34.3 35.5 35.8 35.3 37.8 41.6 39.1 46.6 52.9 57.7 59.5 76.1 80.5 91.8 100 113.7 132.1 125.0
(3) 4.7 5.0 5.5 5.9 5.2 4.9 18.4 5.5 6.0 6.2 6.8 8.0 9.3 11.3 12.4 16.7 13.6 14.7 17.2 19.9 24.2 25.7 29.9 31.8 36.0 36.9 38.9 41.1 49.6 54.2 54.7 61.7 73.9 83.8 97.0 100 111.5 135.2 139.4
(4)
(5) 147.4 139.7
(6) 4.3 4.1 4.4 4.7 4.2 4.2 10.9 4.6 5.3 5.6 5.9 12.4 14.5 17.7 22.1 27.2 22.3 21.4 26.3 27.9 28.5 30.0 32.7 33.8 35.6 37.3 40.3 40.1 48.1 53.5 56.2 60.6 75.0 82.1 94.4 100 112.6 133.7 132.2
(7) 150,880 143,029 154,695 164,527 146,537 145,948 381,180 158,896 183,673 193,647 206,101 431,933 506,899 617,757 771,854 948,127 778,170 747,968 915,898 973,045 994,268 1,046,163 1,140,740 1,178,974 1,242,951 1,301,791 1,404,581 1,397,890 1,677,582 1,866,897 1,960,495 2,113,401 2,616,912 2,865,627 3,294,158 3,488,500 3,927,708 4,663,186 4,612,830
(8) 0.734 0.887 1.09 1.50 4.16 9.30 19.73 79.84 0.93 2.48 5.56 6.50 7.34 7.62 8.13 10.66 15.00 17.86 21.41 23.75 25.66 30.90 35.67 38.75 42.21 46.74 51.63 54.03 57.21 62.48 67.52 71.86 77.52 84.73 91.09 100 108.45 118.76 128.06 136.59
1997
5,003,900
118.8
139.4
129.1
4,503,619
1998
6,881,500
105.2
108.1
106.7
3,721,165
215.58
1999 2000
8,073,200 8,841,592
107.7 114.6
107.4 118.2
107.6 116.4
3,751,882 4,061,596
259.77 269.38
235
| Appendix 1
A1.4
Air transport The value added of air transport can also be estimated with the production approach. In 1928 the Dutch Netherlands-Indies Airlines (Koninklijke Nederlandsch-Indische Luchtvaartmaatschappij, knilm) started its operation. Based on its annual reports value added of air transport could be estimated for the period 1928-1940. The annual reports were found in the National Archive: • knilm, annual reports, ara, Ministerie van Koloniën, Regeringscommissarissen, Nummer toegang: 2.10.46.01, inv. nr. 121-124. Other sources used for estimation of this sector were the following information: • Statistisch Jaaroverzicht van Nederlandsch-Indië, Batavia, 1922-1940; • Koloniaal Verslag, The Hague, 1849-1930; • Indisch Verslag, The Hague, 1931-1940; • Nederlandsch-Indische luchtreisgids, Weltevreden, 1929-1934.
Notes for table A1.22 (1) = Passenger kilometres available (2) = Passenger kilometres transported (3) = Ton kilometers available (4) = Ton kilometers transported (5) = Freight capacity used = (3)/(4) * 100 % (6) = Passenger capacity used = (1)/(2) * 100 % (7) = Number of flights (8) = Hours flown (9) = Distance flown (10)= Total costs (11)= Income from passenger transport (12)= Income from freight transport (13)= Income from other sources (14)= Total income (15)= (14) – (10) = Profit For three years it was possible to estimate a value added/total cost ratio. For the years 1932, 1933 and 1934 this ratio was respectively 47.4%, 39.9% and 38.5%. Therefore for the period 1929-1940 and average value added/total cost ratio of 40% was assumed. This leads to the value added estimates in current and constant prices in table A1.21. (16)= Value added in current price = (14) – 0.6 * (10) (17)= Weighted volume index (1939=100) (18)= Value added in constant (1939) prices
236
| Accounting for Services
Table A1.22 Indicators for air transport and value added, 1928-1940 (1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
1930
6,003,426
3,172,577
550,005
222,786
40.5
882,816
379,132
42.9
1931
7,767,456
3,483,080
1,030,559
399,845
38.8
1929
(5)
1932
7,333,760
2,612,051
961,057
319,714
33.3
1933
7,073,696
2,703,824
916,741
331,296
36.1
1934
7,424,128
3,243,674
1,008,948
401,926
39.8
1935
8,540,594
3,239,296
1,157,287
363,369
31.4
1936
11,938,468
4,133,092
1937
14,623,052
4,861,863
1,675,862
485,825
29.0
1938
16,968,656
5,302,272
1,941,002
556,547
28.7
1939
16,490,000
6,416,528
1,914,688
663,323
34.6
(6)
(7)
(8)
(9)
(10)
2,366
3,063
488,850
1,084,486
1930
52.8
2,704
5,011
801,760
1,585,929
1931
44.8
2,755
5,678
919,794
1,590,674
1932
35.6
2,931
5,284
858,358
1,445,896
1933
38.2
2,471
5,171
863,698
1,458,079
1934
43.7
3,018
5,646
956,466
1,037,775
1935
37.9
2,780
5,587
986,894
1,044,918
1936
34.6
2,871
5,669
1937
33.2
2,905
5,677
1938
31.2
3,182
8,655
2,224,427
1939
38.9
3,178
10,174
2,783,004
1940
1929
1,203,504 1,537,516
1,650,826
1940 (11)
(12)
1929
280,672
10,933
792,881
(13)
1,084,486
(14)
(15) 0
1930
499,084
34,677
1,057,739
1,591,500
5,571
1931
498,212
33,762
1,199,252
1,731,226
140,552
1932
355,291
24,021
1,210,160
1,589,473
143,576
1933
346,899
24,191
1,246,989
1,618,079
160,000
1934
365,351
23,973
648,450
1,037,775
0
1935
286,616
17,390
624,192
928,198
-116,720
1936
345,646
17,883
769,127
1,132,655
-70,848
1937
482,317
19,122
1,063,472
1,564,911
-85,915
1938
607,426
37,753
1,200,139
1,845,318
-379,109
1939
823,060
52,798
1,882,473
2,758,331
-24,673
1940
237
| Appendix 1
Table A1.22 Continued (16)
(17)
(18)
1929
433,794
34.0
147,423
1930
639,943
49.9
319,619
1931
776,821
54.7
424,638
1932
721,935
41.2
297,311
1933
743,231
42.6
316,968
1934
415,110
51.2
212,412
1935
301,248
50.7
152,821
1936
410,553
64.4
264,367
1937
574,415
75.7
434,686
1938
510,662
82.7
422,363
1939
1,088,529
100
1,088,529
Table A1.23 Ticket prices, knilm, 1929-1933 Price
Distance
Price per km
Batavia – Bandoeng
f. 17.50
110 km
15.9 cents
Batavia – Semarang
f. 70,-
400 km
17.5 cents
Batavia – Soerabaja
f. 115,-
670 km
17.2 cents
Batavia – Palembang
f. 93.50
585 km
16.0 cents
Price per kg
Distance
Price per km
Batavia – Bandoeng
f. 0.20
110 km
0.02 cents
Batavia – Semarang
f. 0.75
400 km
0.02 cents
Batavia Soerabaja
f. 1.20
670 km
0.02 cents
Batavia – Palembang
f. 1,-
585 km
0.02 cents
Table A1.24 Prices for freight, knilm, 1929-1933
For the period after independence the same estimation method has been used. Gross value added was estimated by the production approach, based on output and cost structure data that were obtained through airline enterprises survey by bps. Gross value added at constant prices was computed by using a weighted composite production index of passenger-kilometre and ton-kilometre of cargo transported. It will be no surprise that these surveys have not been published either. I have not been able to find annual reports of any of the airlines, although it is questionable whether this would lead to more reliable estimates than the ones made by bps. The i-o tables again are the most valuable source for estimation for the period since independence. The key indicators presented in table A1.25 through A1.27 were taken from the following sources:
238
| Accounting for Services
• • • •
bps, Statistical Yearbook of Indonesia, several volumes; bps, Statistik perhubungan, 1999; bps, Statistik Dalam 50 Tahun Indonesia Merdeka, 1995; Statistik Perhubungan Udara tahun 1964-1969.
Table A1.25 Indicators for air traffic, 1948-1973 Number of km flown (x1,000)
1948
7,689
Passengers
Freight and excess baggage
Pax-km
(x 1,000)
(x 1,000 m. ton-km)
(x1,000)
6,587
mail in kg
Goods and luggage in tons
111,905
1,122
3,542
1949
9,133
7,911
125,325
1,584
4,608
1950
9,371
9,009
148,216
1,343
5,065
1951
9,180
9,584
5,625
159,535
1,516
5,625
1952
9,585
9,630
5,382
159,372
1,756
5,382
1953
10,430
10,369
5,935
168,400
1,477
5,935
1954
12,393
11,387
5,679
180,088
1,545
5,679
1955
13,335
14,960
5,867
236,275
1,677
5,867
1956
13,715
16,815
6,447
269,000
1,785
6,447
1957
14,469
17,585
6,557
280,000
1,916
6,557
1958
7,610
11,546
4,036
194,000
1,402
4,036
1959
8,950
14,726
4,349
257,000
1,351
4,349
1960
9,414
15,452
4,255
259,000
1,195
4,255
1961
272,000
1962
303,000
1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968
451,455
1969
540,413
1970
827,449
1971
1,039,339
1972
1,284,553
1973
1,775,181
239
| Appendix 1
Table A1.26 Government airlines services (domestic and international), 1964-2000 Aircraft-km
Aircraft departures
in 000
number
Aircraft hours flown
Pax carried
Pax-km
Available seats-km
number
in 000
in 000
1964
13,823
37,402
483,639
471,140
678,798
1965
13,699
37,019
433,197
537,045
848,575
1966
12,522
32,364
372,614
494,413
817,223
1967
14,930
40,154
410,829
528,258
978,637
1968
16,497
47,511
451,455
510,455
1,034,317
1969
16,572
19,421
48,365
540,413
533,429
1970
20,255
22,295
51,367
827,449
872,542
1971
24,436
24,743
60,092
1,039,339
1,103,488
1972
32,475
32,983
76,485
1,284,553
1,314,286
1973
39,066
42,202
87,348
1,775,181
1,762,052
2,426,554 3,228,377
1974
47,249
64,729
104,181
2,217,464
2,214,600
4,198,993
1975
50,498
72,739
112,504
2,488,688
2,116,710
3,875,870
1976
65,553
91,563
142,184
3,103,019
3,108,036
5,992,324
1977
72,594
105,704
157,182
3,787,865
3,915,360
7,159,394
1978
78,101
115,204
169,103
4,433,028
4,246,510
7,915,172
1979
77,942
110,668
170,213
4,294,434
4,543,427
8,286,446
1980
88,542
124,818
193,292
5,060,936
6,006,964
11,309,083
1981
117,604
144,018
207,315
6,072,901
7,817,946
14,320,063
1982
126,559
144,300
215,360
5,917,730
7,976,342
16,024,098
1983
114,989
142,963
214,609
5,560,987
7,867,350
14,997,489
1984
122,886
146,223
216,052
5,530,678
8,687,000
16,749,674
1985
98,523
142,423
218,844
5,502,026
8,871,713
16,902,170
1986
104,683
150,647
229,878
6,047,518
10,509,807
19,896,247
1987
117,104
155,059
247,215
6,697,554
10,923,744
19,899,893
1988
123,500
163,455
241,244
7,474,163
13,297,710
22,500,923
1989
126,275
169,143
266,321
7,920,092
12,807,198
21,794,730
1990
131,504
166,444
251,157
8,435,042
13,934,333
23,632,281
1991
138,994
176,717
240,089
9,177,307
14,940,805
23,894,521
1992
160,123
190,565
287,714
9,403,308
17,230,319
30,388,942
1993
172,273
161,791
287,667
9,287,088
17,517,586
31,861,947
1994
171,436
157,271
287,342
9,985,481
19,372,695
33,511,782
1995
179,231
167,403
286,675
10,934,883
20,353,278
35,620,740
1996
189,718
205,683
307,070
11,570,793
20,550,975
37,143,069
1997
192,871
204,116
316,683
11,634,993
21,190,349
37,784,291
1998
126,526
130,878
204,153
7,336,876
14,175,025
24,373,363
1999
106,569
106,052
176,371
6,769,091
13,465,780
20,323,022
2000
111,298
113,437
183,052
7,671,045
15,087,597
21,419,129
240
| Accounting for Services
Per load factor
Freight
Performed ton-km
Available ton-km
%
ton
Weight load factor
in 000
in 000
%
1964
69.4
48,922
84,939
57.6
1965
63.3
57,981
105,210
55.1
1966
60.5
52,090
102,147
51.0
1967
54.0
56,821
117,042
48.5
1968
49.4
56,399
136,399
41.3 49.0
1969
66,351
135,394
1970
93,786
169,268
55.4
115,562
211,167
54.7
1971
8,028
1972
54.2
22,595
137,277
278,754
49.2
1973
54.6
18,251
178,633
358,127
49.9
1974
52.7
23,745
228,218
463,456
49.2
1975
54.6
25,879
203,411
423,469
48.0
1976
51.9
33,772
304,743
687,580
44.3
1977
54.7
38,807
383,110
788,232
48.6
1978
53.7
43,958
442,156
926,930
47.7
1979
54.8
42,669
467,996
990,737
47.2
1980
53.1
59,336
624,408
1,256,440
49.7
1981
54.6
65,971
854,547
1,821,892
46.9
1982
49.8
73,814
878,563
2,066,771
42.5
1983
52.5
72,432
860,400
1,872,440
46.0
1984
51.9
74,745
922,658
2,114,926
43.6
1985
52.5
73,656
918,921
2,178,345
42.2
1986
52.8
78,886
1,114,448
2,486,499
44.8
1987
54.9
105,422
1,297,892
2,802,627
46.3
1988
59.1
114,316
1,609,897
3,052,175
52.7
1989
58.8
115,425
1,561,641
2,987,062
52.3 52.7
1990
59.0
141,296
1,709,740
3,241,809
1991
62.5
171,624
1,819,802
3,298,254
55.2
1992
56.7
164,241
2,076,586
4,177,301
49.7
1993
55.0
168,993
2,201,103
4,606,613
47.8
1994
57.8
193,025
2,644,842
4,927,192
53.7
1995
57.1
201,882
2,558,654
4,959,793
51.6
1996
55.3
208,093
2,552,234
5,093,567
50.1
1997
56.1
207,867
2,596,251
5,159,277
50.3
1998
58.2
133,747
1,643,509
3,242,137
50.7
1999
66.3
121,277
1,455,066
2,559,774
56.8
2000
70.4
143,465
1,690,026
2,751,596
61.4
241
| Appendix 1
Table A1.27 Private airlines services (domestic), 1964-2000 Aircraft-km
Aircraft departures
Aircraft hours flown
Pax carried
Pax-km
Available seats-km
in 000
number
hours
number
in 000
in 000
1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969
975
4,891
44,581
1970
3,107
5,260
13,532
123,865
1971
4,155
7,799
13,946
161,392
118,265
1972
4,429
8,652
13,561
160,840
128,022
187,750
1973
4,403
8,133
13,478
172,076
138,536
195,338
1974
5,912
12,437
13,561
226,065
159,467
243,228
1975
5,630
11,436
13,478
190,288
146,546
228,787
1976
5,046
11,343
17,696
190,642
154,340
216,417
1977
6,214
14,516
21,195
231,312
136,736
208,786
1978
7,151
19,262
25,625
273,862
171,721
256,236
1979
8,891
21,013
30,769
374,061
212,700
313,445
1980
7,153
15,370
24,460
311,337
224,145
309,157
1982
15,128
24,949
41,372
596,644
472,376
686,637
1983
14,674
29,833
41,261
644,270
552,094
789,948
1984
19,155
36,784
53,360
1,162,917
715,030
1,090,522
1985
21,691
34,308
52,756
782,540
657,655
984,830
1986
20,237
33,054
47,369
716,834
625,694
897,237
1987
17,978
33,123
52,356
710,614
615,692
915,488
1988
18,883
35,265
54,289
766,637
648,914
925,137
1989
16,934
26,735
46,425
679,825
637,434
902,978
1990
15,714
30,953
49,167
588,789
512,492
800,805
1991
26,391
39,059
66,681
1,215,020
1,070,569
1,826,986
1992
33,264
57,863
86,676
1,683,718
1,446,247
2,246,470
1993
48,091
75,371
100,024
2,687,723
2,158,381
4,031,152
1994
51,203
81,095
112,854
3,527,121
2,930,451
4,968,313
61,667
1981
1995
60,756
95,975
125,892
4,610,816
3,675,888
5,674,915
1996
102,134
99,436
131,945
5,150,889
3,967,855
5,798,977
1997
98,883
92,633
120,862
4,809,408
3,744,643
5,545,655
1998
28,072
46,938
60,057
2,258,403
1,794,105
2,672,832
1999
17,879
34,305
39,161
1,534,470
1,277,084
1,714,727
2000
23,946
41,710
56,263
1,994,254
1,693,067
2,517,672
242
| Accounting for Services
Per load factor
Freight
Performed ton-km
Available ton-km
Weight load factor
%
ton
in 000
in 000
%
1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969
426
1,568
2,256
69.5
1970
1,051
5,649
9,064
62.3
1971
1,299
9,813
14,736
66.6
1972
68.2
1,746
11,118
15,844
70.2
1973
70.9
1,526
12,431
15,995
77.7
1974
65.6
2,606
14,389
22,641
63.6
1975
64.1
1,947
13,172
21,048
62.6
1976
71.3
1,805
15,557
30,948
50.3
1977
65.5
2,115
13,151
22,543
58.3
1978
67.0
1,710
14,909
21,920
68.0
1979
67.9
3,079
20,875
31,401
66.5
1980
72.5
2,940
18,166
27,277
66.6
1982
68.8
5,552
40,694
64,918
62.7
1983
69.9
5,174
49,004
74,114
66.1
1984
65.6
5,521
62,836
95,818
65.6
1985
66.8
4,782
54,062
97,966
55.2
1986
69.7
4,769
50,121
87,512
57.3
1987
67.3
4,803
50,962
83,989
60.7
1988
70.1
5,062
52,914
82,619
64.0
1981
1989
70.6
5,902
53,229
80,432
66.2
1990
64.0
6,611
44,860
71,554
62.7
1991
58.6
9,655
93,334
170,813
54.6
1992
64.4
9,205
123,846
210,325
58.9
1993
53.5
17,578
212,518
426,556
49.8
1994
59.0
24,612
269,920
550,948
49.0
1995
64.8
44,560
373,960
648,313
57.7
1996
68.4
50,703
392,269
709,038
55.3
1997
67.5
49,435
376,479
620,749
60.6
1998
67.1
33,753
181,975
303,277
60.0
1999
74.5
30,988
139,493
202,700
68.8
2000
67.2
26,977
173,041
306,564
56.4
243
| Appendix 1
The data from the Input-Output tables are presented in table A1.28.
Notes for table A1.28 (1) = (2) = (3) = (4) = (5) = (6) = (7) =
Value added Revenue Value added/output ratio (%) Operating surplus Wages and salaries Depreciation Indirect taxes
Table A1.28 Value added by air transport according to i-o tables (million Rp) (1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
1975
56,609
114,911
49.3
31,444
9,339
15,781
45
1980
151,109
438,552
34.5
82,298
24,449
44,215
147
1985
225,700
799,975
28.2
31,395
51,632
141,065
1,608
1990
1,073,639
3,035,319
35.4
234,452
253,909
575,429
9,849
1995
2,811,539
8,155,203
34.5
548,485
695,453
1,538,871
28,730
2000
4,429,709
25,296,986
17.5
783,194
1,377,522
1,918,923
350,071
The statistics presented above are transformed in time-series estimates of value added in air transport. These figures are presented in table A1.29 below.
Notes for table A1.29 (1) = (2) = (3) = (4) = (5) = (6) = (7) = (8) =
244
Value added in current prices (million guilders/rupiah) Bold indicates the numbers taken from the Input-Output tables. Other years are calculated by extrapolation based on the volume index and corrected for inflation using the cpi index (11) by Van Leeuwen (2007). For the years 1975, 1985 and 1990 this results in estimates that diverge a little from the trend. This is probably a consequence of using a cpi index to inflate the estimates. For the long-term trend it does not seem have a large impact. Passenger kilometres (x1,000) Ton kilometres (x1,000) Volume index pax-km (1993=100) Volume index ton-km (1993=100) Average volume index (1993=100) Value added in constant 1993 prices (million fl/Rp) cpi (Van Leeuwen 2007)
| Accounting for Services
Table A1.29 Value added by air transport, 1928-2000 (1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
1928
(8) 0.017
1929
0.43
0.009
0.009
122
0.017
1930
0.64
3,173
379
223 0.016
0.016
0.016
210
0.017
1931
0.78
3,483
400
0.018
0.017
0.017
226
0.015
1932
0.72
2,612
320
0.013
0.013
0.013
175
0.012
1933
0.74
2,704
331
0.014
0.014
0.014
182
0.011
1934
0.42
3,244
402
0.016
0.017
0.017
219
0.010
1935
0.30
3,239
363
0.016
0.015
0.016
208
0.010
1936
0.41
4,133
0.021
278
0.009
1937
0.57
4,862
486
0.025
0.020
0.022
296
0.010
1938
0.51
6,996
557
0.036
0.023
0.029
387
0.010
1939
1.09
10,037
663
0.051
0.027
0.039
519
0.013
0.079
1,049
0.011
1940
0.021
15,609
0.079
1941
0.012
1942
0.017
1943
0.016
1944
0.024
1945
0.033
1946
0.058
1947
0.082
1948
8
111,905
0.6
0.6
7,518
0.106
1949
11
125,325
0.6
0.6
8,419
0.130
1950
15
148,216
0.8
0.8
9,957
0.152
1951
27
159,535
0.8
0.8
10,717
0.254
1952
29
159,372
0.8
0.8
10,706
0.268
1953
32
168,400
0.9
0.9
11,313
0.285
1954
37
180,088
0.9
0.9
12,098
0.303
1955
64
236,275
1.2
1.2
15,873
0.401
1956
83
269,000
1.4
1.4
18,071
0.459
1957
95
280,000
1.4
1.4
18,810
0.504
1958
96
194,000
1.0
1.0
13,033
0.734
1959
153
257,000
1.3
1.3
17,265
0.887
1960
190
259,000
1.3
1.3
17,399
1.09
1961
273
272,000
1.4
1.4
18,273
1.50
1962
847
303,000
1.5
1.5
20,355
1963 1964
245
4.16 9.30
5,764
471,140
| Appendix 1
48,922
2.4
2.0
2.2
29,221
19.73
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
1965
27,078
537,045
57,981
2.7
2.4
2.6
33,915
79.84
1966
289
494,413
52,090
2.5
2.2
2.3
30,870
0.93
1967
825
528,258
56,821
2.7
2.4
2.5
33,303
2.48
1968
1,813
510,455
56,399
2.6
2.3
2.5
32,589
5.56
1969
2,373
533,429
67,919
2.7
2.8
2.8
36,515
6.50
1970
4,301
934,209
99,435
4.7
4.1
4.4
58,607
7.34
1971
5,743
1,221,753
125,375
6.2
5.2
5.7
75,368
7.62
1972
7,245
1,442,308
148,395
7.3
6.1
6.7
89,080
8.13
1973
12,380
1,900,588
191,064
9.7
7.9
8.8
116,157
10.66
1974
21,933
2,374,067
242,607
12.1
10.1
11.1
146,174
15.00
1975
56,609
2,263,256
216,583
11.5
9.0
10.2
135,326
17.86
1976
42,237
3,262,376
320,300
16.6
13.3
14.9
197,285
21.41
1977
58,085
4,052,096
396,261
20.6
16.4
18.5
244,611
23.75
1978
70,202
4,418,231
457,065
22.5
18.9
20.7
273,559
25.66
1979
90,722
4,756,127
488,871
24.2
20.3
22.2
293,618
30.90
1980
151,109
6,231,109
642,574
31.7
26.6
29.1
385,248
35.67
1981
192,434
7,817,946
854,547
39.7
35.4
37.6
496,591
38.75
1982
226,033
8,448,718
919,257
42.9
38.1
40.5
535,498
42.21
1983
248,593
8,419,444
909,404
42.8
37.7
40.2
531,816
46.74
1984
302,362
9,402,030
985,494
47.8
40.8
44.3
585,656
51.63
1985
225,700
9,529,368
972,983
48.4
40.3
44.4
586,507
54.03
1986
396,412
11,135,501
1,164,569
56.6
48.2
52.4
692,916
57.21
1987
472,944
11,539,436
1,348,854
58.6
55.9
57.3
756,945
62.48
1988
623,723 13,946,624
1,662,811
70.9
68.9
69.9
923,768
67.52
1989
642,274 13,444,632 1,614,870
68.3
66.9
67.6
893,780
71.86
1990
1,073,639 14,446,825 1,754,600
1991 1992 1993
73.4
72.7
73.1
965,704
77.52
1,913,136
81.4
79.3
80.3
1,061,666
84.73
1,120,217 18,676,566 2,200,432
94.9
91.2
93.0
1,229,855
91.09
899,536
16,011,374
2,413,621
100
100
100
1,321,800
100
1,602,000 22,303,146 2,914,762
113
121
117.1
1,547,268
108.45
1995
1,811,539 24,029,166 2,932,614
122
122
121.8
1,610,132
118.76
1996
2,277,100 24,518,830 2,944,503
125
122
123.3
1,629,835
128.06
1997
2,543,400 24,934,992 2,972,730
127
123
124.9
1,651,542
136.59
1998
3,664,100 15,969,130
1,825,484
81
76
78.4
1,036,246
215.58
1999
3,672,900 14,742,864
1,594,559
75
66
70.5
931,825
259.77
2000
4,429,709 16,780,664 1,863,067
85
77
81.2
1,073,796
269.38
246
| Accounting for Services
1994
1,321,800 19,675,967
A1.5
Communications During the colonial period the communications sector was in hands of the stateowned enterprise ptt (Staatsbedrijf der Posterijen, Telegrafie en Telefonie). The data available for this sector are, like those for rail and air transport, quite comprehensive and are taken from the annual reports of the ptt: • Verslag omtrent den Post- en Telegraafdienst in Nederlandsch-Indië, Batavia, 18761907; • Verslag omtrent den Post-, Telegraaf- en Telefoondienst in Nederlandsch-Indië, Batavia, 1908-1941. Based on these profit and loss accounts it is possible to come up with an estimate of the value added of this sub-sector.
Notes for table A1.30 (1) = Revenues from mail, in thousands of guilders (2) = Revenue from telephone & telegraph, in thousands of guilders (3) = Other revenues, in thousands of guilders (4) = (1) + (2) + (3) = Total revenue (5) = Operating expenses (6) = (4) – (5) = Net profit (7) = Value added/operating costs ratio The value added/operating costs ratio could be calculated for the period 1924 1938, because information on the expenditure structure was given in the Ver slag omtrent den Post-, Telegraaf- en Telefoondienst in Nederlandsch-Indië in 1938, p. 72. (8) = (6) + (5)*average (7) = Value added, current prices in thousands of guilders (9) = Volume-index number telegrams (10) = Volume-index number pieces of mail (11) = Weighted volume-index (12) = (8)*(12)/100 = Value added in constant prices in thousand of guilders
247
| Appendix 1
Table A1.30 Estimation of value added by communications, 1901-1940 (1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6) (000)
(000)
(000)
(000)
(000)
(000)
1901
2,130
1,043
2
3,175
3,101
74
1902
2,014
1,100
3
3,117
2,501
616
1903
2,051
1,020
2
3,073
4,867
-1,794
1904
2,153
1,152
3
3,308
2,710
598
1905
2,268
1,221
2
3,491
4,099
-608
1906
2,401
1,453
2
3,856
3,748
108
1907
2,429
1,932
8
4,369
4,234
135
1908
2,377
2,073
2
4,452
4,497
-45
1909
2,588
2,280
3
4,871
5,079
-208
1910
2,728
2,750
2
5,480
6,235
-755
1911
3,176
3,277
9
6,462
7,982
-1,520
1912
2,819
3,404
12
6,235
8,339
-2,104 -5,970
1913
3,208
3,669
11
6,888
12,858
1914
3,974
4,804
116
8,894
10,310
-1,416
1915
4,161
5,283
85
9,529
13,025
-3,496
1916
4,682
6,064
142
10,888
13,109
-2,221
1917
4,935
6,726
148
11,809
14,757
-2,948
1918
5,287
8,749
169
14,205
16,640
-2,435
1919
6,462
11,530
128
18,120
20,040
-1,920
1920
7,357
15,784
203
23,344
27,671
-4,327
1921
9,716
17,401
344
27,461
35,833
-8,372
1922
10,459
15,281
587
26,327
32,800
-6,473
1923
11,695
15,109
712
27,516
32,790
-5,274
1924
12,874
15,334
833
29,041
29,853
-812
1925
13,254
16,260
676
30,190
29,562
628
1926
13,836
16,478
995
31,309
30,707
602
1927
14,410
17,267
1,080
32,757
32,055
702
1928
15,245
18,470
1,180
34,895
34,352
543
1929
15,823
20,407
36,230
35,725
505
1930
15,819
20,064
35,883
36,098
-215
1931
15,240
18,238
33,478
35,037
-1,559
1932
14,345
15,892
30,237
31,848
-1,611
1933
13,431
14,023
27,454
28,286
-832
1934
13,102
12,818
25,920
25,055
865
1935
12,651
11,969
24,620
22,270
2,350
1936
12,866
11,383
24,249
21,663
2,586
1937
13,458
12,378
25,836
21,305
4,531
1938
13,226
12,174
25,400
22,574
2,826
1939
13,584
13,960
27,544
23,005
4,539
1940
12,995
16,910
29,905
23,772
6,133
248
| Accounting for Services
(7)
(8)
(9)
(10)
(000)
(1939=100)
1901
2,545
35.9
(1940=100) 30.4
(1939=100) 18.7
(1940=100) 17.8
1902
2,609
32.9
27.8
20.3
19.2
1903
2,085
28.7
24.3
21.4
20.3
1904
2,758
31.4
26.6
22.7
21.6
1905
2,659
32.9
27.9
24.3
23.0
1906
3,095
38.9
32.9
25.8
24.5
1907
3,510
44.7
37.8
27.0
25.6
1908
3,540
47.9
40.6
31.6
30.0
1909
3,840
53.1
44.9
31.7
30.1
1910
4,214
61.5
52.1
32.8
31.1
1911
4,841
70.9
60.0
33.4
31.7
1912
4,542
80.4
68.1
39.5
37.5
1913
4,278
83.8
70.9
40.2
38.1
1914
6,801
86.8
73.5
41.9
39.7
1915
6,885
88.4
74.8
43.1
40.9
1916
8,227
101.0
85.5
44.9
42.6
1917
8,813
113.3
96.0
47.6
45.1
1918
10,828
138.9
117.6
51.9
49.2
1919
14,052
145.0
123.5
55.7
52.8
1920
17,727
163.2
138.2
62.3
59.1
1921
20,187
139.1
117.8
62.0
58.8
1922
19,669
115.5
97.8
61.8
58.6
20,859
111.8
94.7
60.8
57.7
1924
1923 81.5
22,981
118.0
99.9
59.7
56.6
1925
79.7
24,189
129.7
109.8
64.3
61.0
1926
78.6
25,075
134.6
114.0
65.2
61.8
1927
77.3
26,250
134.8
114.1
70.5
66.8
1928
77.8
27,922
134.8
114.1
74.2
70.3
1929
78.5
28,977
136.4
115.5
81.1
76.9
1930
78.6
28,555
125.1
105.9
87.6
83.1
1931
80.9
26,366
107.4
91.0
84.7
80.3
1932
81.2
23,772
93.0
78.7
86.1
81.6
1933
80.7
21,712
87.2
73.8
75.8
71.9
1934
81.6
20,833
83.5
70.7
76.3
72.3
1935
81.8
20,099
78.5
66.5
70.0
66.4 70.7
1936
78.1
19,852
78.4
66.4
74.5
1937
79.8
21,511
91.2
77.2
81.9
77.7
1938
79.7
20,818
89.0
75.4
93.5
88.6
1939
22,874
100
84.7
100.0
94.8
1940
25,079
118.12
100
105.5
100
249
| Appendix 1
(11)
(12)
1939=100
1940=100
1901
24.4
21.9
1939=100 (000)
1940=100 (000)
1902
24.7
22.3
620.0
1903
23.8
21.6
645.3
557.4 581.2
1904
25.8
23.3
496.7
450.7
1905
27.3
24.7
710.5
643.0
1906
30.7
27.7
725.9
657.1
1907
34.8
31.0
951.3
856.0
1908
39.2
34.9
1,221.2
1,087.3
1909
41.7
37.0
1,387.4
1,235.4
1910
47.2
41.6
1,602.6
1,422.7
1911
52.4
46.1
1,989.4
1,754.3 2,229.6
1912
61.9
54.2
2,537.8
1913
63.5
55.6
2,812.1
2,463.3
1914
66.5
58.2
2,714.6
2,379.9
1915
68.4
59.9
4,521.7
3,959.1
1916
76.6
66.8
4,712.2
4,122.7 5,495.7
1917
85.5
74.4
6,298.8
1918
106.1
91.8
7,535.2
6,559.1
1919
112.9
98.1
11,486.0
9,938.8
1920
131.1
113.0
15,869.5
13,787.6
1921
111.5
96.7
23,243.7
20,034.7
1922
93.7
81.9
22,508.7
19,511.5
1923
89.6
78.5
18,427.7
16,104.0 16,382.3
1924
91.4
80.1
18,686.4
1925
100.3
87.9
21,004.6
18,418.3
1926
102.9
90.2
24,262.7
21,250.4
1927
105.5
92.6
25,813.8
22,612.2
1928
107.4
94.3
27,698.2
24,304.7
1929
112.3
98.6
29,978.9
26,331.1
1930
108.6
95.9
32,529.2
28,581.4
1931
97.1
86.1
31,007.0
27,371.4
1932
89.7
80.1
25,599.2
22,704.1 19,040.7
1933
81.6
72.9
21,326.5
1934
79.8
71.5
17,717.2
15,817.0
1935
74.2
66.4
16,631.4
14,895.7
1936
76.4
68.7
14,904.9
13,352.6
1937
86.3
77.4
15,157.1
13,628.4 16,657.0
1938
91.4
82.3
18,574.0
1939
100
89.7
19,017.7
17,128.9
1940
112.6
100
22,874.2
20,510.3
250
| Accounting for Services
The method of estimation throughout the second half of the twentieth century was also the production approach. Output at current prices was gathered from financial reports of these companies. Value added was also from the financial report in the form of summing wages and salaries, profit or loss, depreciation and other components of the value added. Value added and output at constant prices were estimated by extrapolation. Table A1.31 Income of ptt, 1938-1955
1938 1939 1940
Post 13,226 13,584 12,995
Telegraph 4,311 5,544 7,884
Telephone 7,863 8,416 9,026
Indonesia 25,400 27,544 29,905
1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955
22,804 27,392 38,217 65,877 95,207 138,872 155,217 166,215
11,319 13,981 27,439 41,650 47,660 48,017 49,419 79,658
13,103 20,163 32,829 63,723 85,453 103,537 114,951 126,733
47,226 61,536 98,485 171,250 228,320 290,426 319,587 372,606
Total Java and Madura
33,733 44,423 71,138 122,683 169,193 217,538 241,302 276,887
Note: Until 1940 guilders, from 1948 onwards Rupiah (x 1,000)
Notes for table A1.32 (1) = (2) = (3) = (4) = (5) = (6) = (7) =
Value added Revenue Value added/output ratio Operating surplus (%) Wages and salaries Depreciation Indirect taxes
Table A1.32 Value added by communications according to i-o tables (million rupiah) (1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7) 486
1975
33,538
53,963
62.1
9,097
18,368
5,586
1980
150,328
265,193
56.7
19,285
56,602
73,637
805
1985
561,841
835,448
67.3
270,956
180,609
108,196
2,080
1990
1,541,568
2,124,786
72.6
729,047
363,181
425,912
23,428
1995
5,740,649
8,020,618
71.6
2,506,591
1,537,261
1,616,398
80,399
2000
18,260,265
24,378,623
74.9
10,196,767
3,557,469
4,129,613
376,416
251
| Appendix 1
Table A1.33 Key indicators for communications, 1956-2000 Letters sent ( x1,000) Domestic
International
Telephone calls Connections
(x 1,000 minutes)
Telex production Domestic International (x 1,000 pulses) (minutes)
1956 1957
24,797
1958
26,590
1959
33,061
1960
221,831
5,335
37,771
1961
208,364
6,292
45,126
1962
219,749
6,440
45,049
1963
207,545
7,375
46,055
1964
194,029
6,483
55,104
1965
200,370
8,551
153,131
77,510
2,532
2,892
1966
154,175
6,754
158,043
50,690
3,375
30,547
1967
123,548
5,408
169,605
35,832
4,171
129,735
1968
123,198
4,762
170,808
26,873
5,086
187,949
1969
133,407
4,755
139,206
26,591
6,202
256,773
1970
141,689
6,505
144,981
31,636
7,666
404,957
1971
158,824
8,204
152,146
40,354
9,235
647,518
1972
172,059
8,648
168,208
40,699
11,262
924,060
1973
155,534
9,416
178,029
52,808
14,078
1,408,893
1974
152,749
12,172
193,428
56,730
17,401
1,872,659
1975
163,866
11,521
208,954
57,626
22,628
2,592,205
1976
176,829
10,445
189,427
58,862
28,284
2,928,455
1977
193,998
12,005
193,383
59,858
30,773
3,884,996
1978
212,295
11,888
220,990
61,048
35,894
4,510,950
1979
204,646
16,459
202,141
61,877
43,270
5,507,959
1980
234,840
15,669
369,843
72,024
56,904
6,946,184
1981
231,760
17,723
427,185
77,199
82,279
8,837,634
1982
257,001
14,033
475,459
84,528
271,864
10,132,802
1983
286,966
22,101
503,253
72,345
336,400
11,013,554
1984
330,333
27,124
536,102
77,929
378,443
12,446,469
1985
357,152
24,757
602,356
80,381
421,185
12,643,377
1986
382,311
29,393
658,341
91,935
435,364
12,732,283
1987
402,215
29,169
737,588
106,513
471,890
11,180,447
1988
429,497
30,106
803,287
117,453
518,409
9,922,001
1989
456,221
30,353
893,145
130,133
559,626
8,838,313
1990
436,782
31,372
1,043,919
82,871
587,471
12,581,541
1991
493,542
34,709
1,276,593
73,407
694,192
7,667,594
1992
555,340
34,709
1,541,987
62,591
625,798
5,873,214
252
| Accounting for Services
Telegram production Number of telegrams (x 1,000) Domestic
Number of words (x 1,000)
International
Interlocal
International
1956 1957
3069
1224
57,369
41,991
1958
3198
1082
63,132
37,464
1959
3857
1084
78,409
35,646
1960
3,860
1,078
85,724
35,523
1961
3,921
1,061
91,822
34,798
1962
4,210
984
92,995
32,255
1963
2,732
997
101,516
34,970
1964
1,735
813
38,643
27,599
1965
2,860
504
154,475
24,075
1966
2,857
453
156,656
27,390
1967
1,772
422
119,880
26,220 26,460
1968
2,337
418
154,140
1969
2,081
473
55,832
30,270
1970
2,133
474
57,201
30,690 29,730
1971
2,390
461
61,512
1972
2,753
470
80,695
30,510
1973
3,410
347
105,166
23,839
1974
3,756
503
112,054
15,203
1975
3,642
475
107,567
14,694
1976
4,048
400
123,744
13,240
1977
4,404
351
134,402
11,529
1978
4,905
304
150,103
9,682
1979
5,503
268
167,885
7,930
1980
6,455
232
190,901
6,790
1981
6,924
181
205,372
5,698 4,548
1982
7,142
141
214,669
1983
7,859
105
240,074
3,328
1984
8,419
81
265,683
2,504
1985
9,087
68
285,490
2,182
1986
10,377
60
320,988
1,972
1987
11,090
57
320,891
1,828
1988
11,668
63
371,268
1,765
1989
12,825
61
410,038
1,588
1990
14,087
59
443,601
1,440
1991
13,582
41
400,310
968
1992
11,327
30
357,499
688
253
| Appendix 1
Table A1.33 Continued Letters sent ( x1,000)
Telephone calls Connections
(x 1,000 minutes)
Telex production
Domestic
International
Domestic International (x 1,000 pulses) (minutes)
1993
638,483
87,749
1,848,678
92,419
574,441
3,734,337
1994
678,830
92,137
2,439,670
238,834
502,176
4,273,243
1998
588,133
34,462
1999
465,949
29,871
2000
413,625
25,249
1995 1996 1997
The statistics above are transformed in estimates of value added in communications in table A1.34.
Notes for table A1.34 (1) = (2) = (3) = (4) = (5) =
254
Value added in current prices (guilders/rupiah) For the colonial period value added is taken from table A1.30. Bold indicates the numbers taken from the Input-Output tables. Other years are calculated by extrapolation based on the volume index (2) and corrected for inflation using the cpi index (5) by Van Leeuwen (2007). Volume index (1993=100) Value added in constant 1930 prices Value added in constant 1993 prices For the colonial period value added in constant prices is taken from table A1.30 and recalculated with 1993 as base year. For the years after independence estimates are obtained through extrapolation based on the volume index (2). cpi (Van Leeuwen 2007)
| Accounting for Services
Telegram production Number of telegrams (x 1,000)
Number of words (x 1,000)
Domestic
International
Interlocal
International
1993
10,066
44
298,704
1,167
1994
10,158
38
280,387
1,051
1995
5,278
36
165,221
1,045
1996
5,919
31
143,341
940
1997
2,989
28
98,739
792
1998
86,333
779
1999
56,830
554
2000
35,621
440
Table A1.34 Value added by communications, 1901-2000 (1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
620
5,767
0.012
1901
2.5
1902
2.6
645
6,003
0.011
1903
2.1
497
4,620
0.012
1904
2.8
711
6,609
0.010
1905
2.7
726
6,752
0.010
1906
3.1
951
8,848
0.011
1907
3.5
1,221
11,359
0.012
1908
3.5
1,387
12,905
0.013
1909
3.8
1,603
14,906
0.012
1910
4.2
1,989
18,505
0.012
1911
4.8
2,538
23,605
0.013
1912
4.5
2,812
26,156
0.015
1913
4.3
2,715
25,250
0.014
1914
6.8
4,522
42,058
0.013
1915
6.9
4,712
43,830
0.013
1916
8.2
6,299
58,588
0.014
1917
8.8
7,535
70,088
0.015
1918
10.8
11,486
106,837
0.019
1919
14.1
15,870
147,609
0.019
1920
17.7
23,244
216,200
0.032
1921
20.2
22,509
209,364
0.027
1922
19.7
18,428
171,404
0.023
1923
20.9
18,686
173,811
0.021
1924
23.0
21,005
195,373
0.019
255
| Appendix 1
(1) 1925
(2)
24.2
(3)
(4)
(5)
24,263
225,678
0.018
1926
25.1
25,814
240,105
0.018
1927
26.2
27,698
257,633
0.018
1928
27.9
29,979
278,847
0.017
1929
29.0
32,529
302,568
0.017
1930
28.6
31,007
288,410
0.017
1931
26.4
25,599
238,110
0.015
1932
23.8
21,326
198,367
0.012
1933
21.7
17,717
164,796
0.011
1934
20.8
16,631
154,696
0.010
1935
20.1
14,905
138,637
0.010
1936
19.9
15,157
140,983
0.009
1937
21.5
18,574
172,765
0.010
1938
20.8
19,018
176,892
0.010
1939
22.9
22,874
212,763
0.013
1940
25.1
28,245
262,718
1941
0.011 0.012
1942
0.017
1943
0.016
1944
0.024
1945
0.033
1946
0.058
1947
0.082
1948
38
0.106
1949
49
0.130
1950
79
620,000
0.152
1951
137
665,000
0.254
1952
183
700,000
0.268
1953
232
740,000
0.285
1954
256
780,000
0.303
1955
298
828,000
0.401
1956
862
910,545
0.459
1957
947
28.9
926,089
0.504
1958
1,378
29.4
928,596
0.734
1959
1,666
29.5
1,113,891
0.887
1960
2,052
35.4
1,189,347
1.09
1961
2,809
37.8
1,223,419
1.50
1962
7,814
38.9
1,305,021
4.16
256
| Accounting for Services
(1) 1963
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
17,471
41.5
1,162,910
9.30
1964
37,050
36.9
1,136,924
19.73
1965
149,954
36.1
1,505,152
79.84
1966
1,756
47.8
1,124,115
0.93
1967
4,653
35.7
777,817
2.48
1968
10,448
24.7
733,559
5.56
1969
12,204
23.3
718,413
6.50
1970
13,784
22.8
795,603
7.34
1971
14,311
30.1
948,578
7.62
1972
15,276
32.1
1,010,095
8.13
1973
20,017
37.9
1,193,286
10.66
1974
28,182
40.5
1,273,836
15.00
1975
33,538
40.9
1,287,246
17.86
1976
58,000
43.2
1,360,772
21.41
1977
73,000
45.6
1,436,246
23.75
1978
98,000
48.6
1,528,244
25.66
1979
123,000
50.7
1,595,542
30.90
1980
150,328
58.9
1,852,454
35.67
1981
225,000
62.2
1,958,610
38.75
1982
350,000
66.6
2,095,676
42.21
1983
404,400
66.3
2,087,048
46.74
1984
439,500
72.4
2,278,727
51.63
1985
561,841
76.6
2,411,521
54.03
1986
637,200
86.4
2,720,204
57.21
1987
803,800
94.9
2,988,461
62.48
1988
912,500
102.1
3,213,680
67.52
1989
1,025,400
111.7
3,517,204
71.86
1990
1,541,568
98.0
3,085,570
77.52
1991
1,580,600
95.7
3,012,313
84.73
1992
1,966,100
87.2
2,743,751
91.09
1993
3,147,700
100
3,147,700
100
1994
4,161,600
3,788,400
108.45
1995
5,740,649
4,397,100
118.76
1996
5,679,900
5,256,500
128.06
1997
7,033,300
6,173,400
136.59
1998
10,100,000
6,471,300
215.58
1999
12,453,900
7,034,500
259.77
2000
18,260,265
7,853,500
269.38
257
| Appendix 1
258
| Accounting for Services
Appendix 2
National Accounting for Trade
Activities included in this sub-sector are the ones concerned with buying and selling products, either new or used goods, for distribution without changing the characteristics of the products. According to the 1993 System of National Accounts traders are treated as supplying services rather than goods to their customers by storing and displaying a selection of goods in convenient locations and making them easily available for customers to buy. Their output is measured by the total value of the trade margins realised on the goods they purchase for resale. A trade margin is defined as the difference between the actual or imputed price realised on a good purchased for resale and the price that would have to be paid by the distributor to replace the good at the time it is sold or otherwise disposed of. The margins realised on some goods may be negative if their prices have to be marked down. They must be negative on goods that are never sold. The key is therefore to assess the trade margins on different kind of goods over time. Table A2.1 gives aggregated trade margins from two trading houses in the period 1914-1939. Table A2.2 shows trade margins derived from the Input-Output tables. Table A2.1 Profit margins, Hagemeijer and Internatio, 1914-1939 Trade ( in millions) Total export
Total import
Turnover (x1,000)
Purchases (x1,000)
Hagemeijer
Internatio
Hagemeijer
Internatio
1914 1915 1916 1917
674 770 865 778
412 390 419 485
1.934 1.988 2.921 1.957
46.034 67.451 89.098 100.022
1.664 1.662 2.093 1.177
43.419 64.530 84.858 94.560
1918 1919 1920 1921 1922 1923 1924 1925 1926 1927
676 2.152 2.228 1.191 1.142 1.378 1.543 1.802 1.585 1.645
557 740 1.225 1.193 756 644 698 840 895 903
2.362 2.990 6.510 4.624 4.084 3.290 3.690 4.759 4.320 4.833
90.969 119.848 146.216 123.937 82.294 84.337 104.617 120.650 118.972 131.413
1.950 2.369 5.810 4.537 3.846 2.544 2.907 3.830 3.584 4.151
84.678 112.527 141.737 120.178 78.071 80.642 100.237 115.501 113.285 125.591
259
| Appendix 2
1928 1929 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939
Trade ( in millions) Total export Total import 1.580 1.003 1.446 1.108 1.161 888 750 592 544 384 471 330 490 291 450 277 540 287 953 498 660 490 748 478
Turnover (x1,000) Hagemeijer Internatio 5.821 136.522 5.035 134.148 3.806 87.035 3.395 66.941 3.072 50.397 3.063 45.854 3.997 50.402 3.499 50.242 4.135 64.524 104.823 106.650 6.752 130.155
Gross margin (x1,000) Hagemeijer Internatio 1914 1915 1916 1917 1918 1919 1920 1921 1922 1923 1924 1925 1926 1927 1928 1929 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939
320 326 828 780 412 621 700 87 238 746 783 929 736 682 1.058 919 612 539 541 453 565 507 708 908 1.151 1.544
2.615 2.921 4.240 5.462 6.291 7.321 4.479 3.759 4.223 3.695 4.380 5.149 5.687 5.822 6.220 5.388 3.735 2.957 1.811 512 377 2.632 3.549 5.485 5.259 7.779
Source: De Jong 1995
260
| Accounting for Services
Purchases (x1,000) Hagemeijer Internatio 4.763 130.302 4.116 128.760 3.194 83.300 2.856 63.984 2.531 48.586 2.610 45.342 3.432 50.025 2.992 47.610 3.427 60.975 99.338 101.391 5.208 122.376
Gross profit margin Hagemeijer Internatio 16,5% 16,4% 28,3% 39,9% 17,4% 20,8% 10,8% 1,9% 5,8% 22,7% 21,2% 19,5% 17,0% 14,1% 18,2% 18,3% 16,1% 15,9% 17,6% 14,8% 14,1% 14,5% 17,1%
22,9%
5,7% 4,3% 4,8% 5,5% 6,9% 6,1% 3,1% 3,0% 5,1% 4,4% 4,2% 4,3% 4,8% 4,4% 4,6% 4,0% 4,3% 4,4% 3,6% 1,1% 0,7% 5,2% 5,5% 5,2% 4,9% 6,0%
261
| Appendix 2
1-07 1-08 1-09 1-10 1-11 1-12 1-13 1-14 1-15 1-16 1-17 1-18 1-19 1-20 1-21
1-06
1-01 1-02 1-03 1-04 1-05
1975 i-o Code
Paddy Handpounded rice Maize Root crops Fruit & Vegetables Fruit Vegetables Beans Groundnut Soybeans Rubber Sugar Coconut Palm oil & vegetable oil Tobacco Coffee Tea Clove Nutmeg other spices Other crops Livestock Slaughtering Poultry and its products Wood/Logging
Commodity
1.8% 7.5% 1.3% 6.1% 26.1% 17.5% 32.6% 5.1% 5.5% 4.4% 10.5% 7.6% 16.1% 3.9% 14.8% 12.9% 16.4% 49.3% 12.2% 9.2% 76.0% 9.8% 5.6% 5.1% 30.8%
Wholesale trade
0.0% 7.0% 1.1% 4.6% 24.1% 15.4% 30.6% 2.4% 4.3% 0.6% 0.0% 2.2% 4.2% 2.8% 7.6% 2.4% 3.8% 0.1% 5.0% 0.9% 4.8% 0.2% 4.6% 2.8% 4.7%
Retail trade
1971
million of Rp 463,796 379,801 37,229 107,805 165,054 70,900 94,154 41,757 15,712 22,719 143,716 39,524 59,848 68,751 63,813 45,097 29,055 16,145 2,543 11,677 11,964 49,916 64,140 49,942 149,117
Output
Table A2.2 Trade margins based on i-o tables, 1975-2000 (1975 i-o classification code)
11.3% 9.2% 0.9% 2.6% 4.0% 1.7% 2.3% 1.0% 0.4% 0.6% 3.5% 1.0% 1.5% 1.7% 1.6% 1.1% 0.7% 0.4% 0.1% 0.3% 0.3% 1.2% 1.6% 1.2% 3.6%
2.6% 0.0% 6.6% 5.7% 16.7% 20.5% 13.8% 18.1% 4.5% 4.8% 6.5% 11.7% 8.9% 5.5% 21.0% 40.2% 18.8% 44.3% 15.7% 13.1% 30.1% 9.0% 5.3% 13.6% 30.0%
Output as Wholesale % of total trade
0.0% 8.5% 7.0% 4.8% 16.7% 20.5% 13.7% 7.5% 3.1% 0.4% 0.0% 4.6% 4.0% 1.9% 3.2% 19.5% 4.4% 0.1% 6.2% 3.2% 3.2% 1.0% 4.6% 9.2% 2.8%
Retail trade million of Rp 1,364,487 616,536 169,415 408,960 567,137 247,672 319,465 178,315 82,286 78,244 255,646 83,856 158,651 118,712 122,080 88,848 56,148 41,931 10,254 16,663 28,411 111,708 207,056 127,708 317,759
Output
1975
10.5% 4.7% 1.3% 3.1% 4.4% 1.9% 2.5% 1.4% 0.6% 0.6% 2.0% 0.6% 1.2% 0.9% 0.9% 0.7% 0.4% 0.3% 0.1% 0.1% 0.2% 0.9% 1.6% 1.0% 2.4%
Output as % of total
262
| Accounting for Services
3-37 3-38
2-26 3-27 3-28 3-29 3-30 3-31 3-32 3-33 3-34 3-35 3-36
Other mining Processing and preserving food Vegetable oil Milling and polishing of rice Other cereal milling Sugar industry Manufacture of other food products Manufacture of beverages Manufacture of cigarettes Spinning industry Manufacture of textile, leather and clothing Manufacture of made up textile goods except wearing apparel Wearing apparel Manufacture of footwear and leather products Manufacture of wood and wooden products Manufacture of paper and printing Manufacture of paper and cardboard Manufacture of paper and cardboard products Printing and publishing
Other forest products Fishing Sea fishing Inland water fishing Drying and salting of fish Coal mining and metal ore mining Crude oil and gas mining
1-22 1-23
2-24 2-25
Commodity
1975 i-o Code
1971
8.6% 20.7% 2.4% 1.5% 10.3% 4.9% 8.8% 7.5% 7.1% 1.4% 7.4% 4.1% 3.6% 20.5% 2.8% 6.1% 1.3% 0.0% 7.4%
4.9% 3.7% 24.7% 17.3% 41.9% 143.7% 18.0% 27.5%
4.0% 13.9% 5.9% 7.7% 27.2% 0.0% 0.0%
Retail trade
58.8% 26.6% 5.8% 7.5% 18.9% 5.6% 12.1% 22.0% 7.8% 25.4% 12.2%
16.7% 18.7% 13.7% 9.1% 30.5% 0.0% 14.2%
Wholesale trade
12,153 77,203 17,366 34,819 40,241 5,229 3,032 31,980
31,095 9,777 68,372 213,015 17,855 64,642 82,053 18,999 85,376 25,965 235,106
21,826 222,786 94,719 48,836 79,230 308,399 495
Output
0.3% 1.9% 0.4% 0.8% 1.0% 0.1% 0.1% 0.8%
0.8% 0.2% 1.7% 5.2% 0.4% 1.6% 2.0% 0.5% 2.1% 0.6% 5.7%
0.5% 5.4% 2.3% 1.2% 1.9% 7.5% 0.0%
11.9% 3.9% 10.2% 22.9% 24.7% 67.3% 9.0% 17.3%
39.9% 27.7% 6.2% 2.2% 12.0% 9.3% 9.1% 15.3% 6.1% 3.3% 7.7%
29.8% 21.6% 35.3% 5.6% 16.0% 0.2% 0.0%
Output as Wholesale % of total trade
8.9% 3.7% 7.3% 0.8% 6.1% 0.7% 0.5% 7.9%
5.1% 22.5% 3.9% 2.1% 5.8% 7.0% 7.9% 9.6% 6.0% 0.2% 4.8%
0.7% 13.0% 15.6% 4.7% 15.4% 0.0% 0.0%
Retail trade
14,404 158,419 46,037 115,452 121,230 19,637 10,354 91,240
96,766 62,024 67,450 1,145,061 166,202 136,902 253,957 33,021 315,635 95,184 509,459
42,087 398,014 166,308 92,366 139,340 97,598 2,464,583
Output
1975
0.1% 1.2% 0.4% 0.9% 0.9% 0.2% 0.1% 0.7%
0.7% 0.5% 0.5% 8.8% 1.3% 1.1% 1.9% 0.3% 2.4% 0.7% 3.9%
0.3% 3.1% 1.3% 0.7% 1.1% 0.7% 18.9%
Output as % of total
263
| Appendix 2 12.3% 75.7%
Manufacture of transport equipment Other manufactures
3-49 3-50
3-41 3-42 3-43 3-44 3-45 3-46 3-47 3-48
11.4% 20.5% 15.5%
All agricultural products
All manufacturing products
Total
149.6% 31.4% 41.7% 34.8% 43.2% 12.2% 59.1% 55.5% 5.5% 284.8% 15.5% 39.5% 354.4%
Manufacture of fertilizers Chemical industry Manufacture of drugs and medicine Manufacture of cosmetics Manufacture of plastic goods Manufacture of petroleum Manufacture of rubber products Manufacture of ceramic and earthenware Cement industry Manufacture of basic iron and steel Manufacture of non ferrous basic metal Manufacture of metal products Manufacture of machinery and equipment
3-39 3-40
Wholesale trade
Commodity
1975 i-o Code
1971
5.6%
5.4%
5.8%
1.8% 20.1%
0.1% 11.3% 33.2% 29.9% 12.7% 5.0% 4.3% 3.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 2.7% 61.1%
Retail trade
4,107,310
1,862,008
2,240,940
194,169 14,839
3,232 254,050 8,157 9,374 4,763 1,999 12,123 42,725 6,425 5,230 17,729 55,314 17,965
Output
100%
45.3%
54.6%
4.7% 0.4%
0.1% 6.2% 0.2% 0.2% 0.1% 0.0% 0.3% 1.0% 0.2% 0.1% 0.4% 1.3% 0.4%
11.5%
12.1%
10.6%
9.0% 82.3%
0.0% 34.7% 15.9% 24.2% 38.2% 12.7% 39.7% 56.1% 66.3% 330.1% 48.0% 38.6% 173.8%
Output as Wholesale % of total trade
4.5%
3.6%
5.7%
3.9% 34.9%
0.0% 12.8% 15.9% 24.7% 7.4% 4.8% 6.7% 2.8% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 1.3% 30.8%
Retail trade
13,037,230
7,546,850
5,490,380
717,409 37,303
34,972 208,393 32,448 30,549 29,201 340,137 43,474 95,802 34,441 15,309 48,791 171,964 118,331
Output
1975
100%
57.9%
42.1%
5.5% 0.3%
0.3% 1.6% 0.2% 0.2% 0.2% 2.6% 0.3% 0.7% 0.3% 0.1% 0.4% 1.3% 0.9%
Output as % of total
264
| Accounting for Services 21.8% 14.0%
Root crops
Fruit & Vegetables
Fruit
Vegetables
1-04
1-05
Sugar
Coconut
Palm oil & vegetable oil
Tobacco
Coffee
Tea
Clove
Nutmeg
Other spices
Other crops
Livestock
Slaughtering
1-08
1-09
1-10
1-11
1-12
1-13
1-14
1-15
1-16
1-17
1-18
1-19
5.5%
Soybeans
6.7%
9.5%
13.2%
14.2%
15.7%
21.1%
16.8%
34.3%
17.9%
5.8%
10.0%
13.2%
13.0%
5.2%
Groundnut
Rubber
6.8%
6.7%
7.2%
Beans
1-07
1-06
17.6%
Maize
1-03
0.3%
Handpounded rice
1-02
2.6%
Paddy
Wholesale trade
1-01
1975 i-o Code Commodity
Table A2.2 Continued, 1980-1985 1980
5.0%
0.4%
2.9%
4.1%
6.2%
0.1%
2.7%
4.5%
1.2%
1.8%
3.3%
4.0%
0.0%
0.4%
3.5%
7.9%
13.8%
20.5%
16.9%
5.4%
6.9%
7.6%
0.0%
Retail trade
746,300
597,149
121,904
18,404
25,294
290,118
194,556
527,021
235,068
335,142
412,592
339,869
958,076
174,970
226,994
446,957
749,193
648,457
1,397,650
714,215
382,654
1,373,920
3,436,221
million of Rp
Output
1.6%
1.3%
0.3%
0.0%
0.1%
0.6%
0.4%
1.1%
0.5%
0.7%
0.9%
0.7%
2.1%
0.4%
0.5%
1.0%
1.6%
1.4%
3.0%
1.5%
0.8%
2.9%
7.4%
6.5%
9.5%
12.7%
15.7%
17.6%
16.6%
39.4%
14.2%
7.3%
10.1%
12.3%
13.0%
4.9%
5.0%
6.3%
13.5%
21.2%
18.0%
6.1%
6.9%
1.5%
2.6%
Output as Wholesale % of total trade
4.8%
0.8%
2.2%
6.2%
0.3%
2.7%
0.4%
0.1%
0.9%
3.3%
3.1%
0.0%
0.4%
3.5%
7.6%
13.7%
20.0%
17.4%
5.6%
5.6%
6.1%
0.0%
Retail trade million of Rp
Output
2,203,565
1,290,105
568,322
33,387
446,994
220,389
651,481
533,302
843,934
829,798
905,254
293,282
426,630
521,524
1,052,752
1,479,885
2,102,367
3,582,252
1,798,023
855,554
172,090
7,140,749
1985
2.4%
1.4%
0.6%
0.0%
0.5%
0.2%
0.7%
0.6%
0.9%
0.9%
1.0%
0.3%
0.5%
0.6%
1.1%
1.6%
2.3%
3.8%
1.9%
0.9%
0.2%
7.7%
Output as % of total
265
| Appendix 2 38.3%
Other forest products
Fishing
Sea fishing
1-22
1-23
8.5% 15.5% 7.0% 14.2%
Other mining
Processing and preserving food
Vegetable oil
Milling and polishing of rice
Other cereal milling
Sugar industry
Manufacture of other food products
Manufacture of beverages
Manufacture of cigarettes
Spinning industry
Manufacture of textile, leather and clothing
Manufacture of made up textile goods except wearing apparel
Wearing apparel
Manufacture of footwear and leather products
2-26
3-27
3-28
3-29
3-30
3-31
3-32
3-33
3-34
3-35
3-36
2.5%
5.8%
22.1%
12.6%
4.6%
10.9%
0.4%
10.6%
13.0%
3.5%
0.0%
Crude oil and gas mining
2-25
0.1%
Coal mining and metal ore mining
27.8%
7.3%
40.4%
2-24
Drying and salting of fish
Inland water fishing
27.0%
Wood/Logging
33.7%
Poultry and its products
1-21
13.0%
Wholesale trade
1-20
1975 i-o Code Commodity
9.3%
6.4%
7.9%
5.7%
0.1%
6.2%
16.3%
9.3%
9.0%
5.9%
0.5%
5.5%
5.4%
17.7%
0.0%
0.0%
26.9%
5.8%
17.7%
17.1%
0.1%
0.4%
8.7%
Retail trade
1980
162,603
52,709
52,092
1,332,169
385,981
1,222,091
109,842
1,044,158
331,423
244,685
3,010,180
235,967
223,408
371,851
13,238,896
430,759
285,104
273,254
452,748
1,011,106
53,630
1,571,682
577,475
million of Rp
Output
0.3%
0.1%
0.1%
2.9%
0.8%
2.6%
0.2%
2.2%
0.7%
0.5%
6.5%
0.5%
0.5%
0.8%
28.4%
0.9%
0.6%
0.6%
1.0%
2.2%
0.1%
3.4%
1.2%
13.1%
5.1%
12.2%
7.5%
1.8%
6.9%
20.6%
12.6%
5.4%
11.2%
2.9%
9.6%
17.4%
62.3%
0.0%
1.0%
28.5%
7.6%
38.2%
26.4%
26.7%
31.0%
13.0%
Output as Wholesale % of total trade
1985
8.1%
5.5%
5.8%
5.2%
0.7%
5.2%
13.7%
9.0%
7.2%
6.0%
0.8%
5.4%
10.9%
0.1%
0.0%
0.0%
27.9%
5.1%
17.7%
17.2%
2.0%
3.1%
8.7%
Retail trade
188,143
631,910
95,656
2,519,123
916,469
3,413,506
258,759
2,006,750
815,481
585,181
7,840,130
1,003,460
591,101
858,846
15,477,361
390,998
660,412
615,389
857,141
2,132,942
129,902
1,482,206
1,379,855
million of Rp
Output
0.2%
0.7%
0.1%
2.7%
1.0%
3.7%
0.3%
2.2%
0.9%
0.6%
8.4%
1.1%
0.6%
0.9%
16.6%
0.4%
0.7%
0.7%
0.9%
2.3%
0.1%
1.6%
1.5%
Output as % of total
266
| Accounting for Services 71.3% 12.8% 8.8% 10.2%
Cement industry
Manufacture of basic iron and steel
Manufacture of non ferrous basic metal
Manufacture of metal products
Manufacture of machinery and equipment
Manufacture of transport equipment
Other manufactures
All agricultural products
All manufacturing products
Total
3-44
3-45
3-46
3-47
3-48
3-49
3-50
9.7%
42.8%
37.2%
34.8%
52.5%
38.4%
21.3%
Manufacture of rubber products
3-42
8.8%
Manufacture of plastic goods
Manufacture of petroleum
18.7% 16.3%
Manufacture of cosmetics
3-41
31.2%
Manufacture of drugs and medicine
1.6% 27.4%
Printing and publishing
Chemical industry
23.4%
Manufacture of paper and cardboard products
Manufacture of fertilizers
20.1%
Manufacture of paper and cardboard
3-40
85.6%
Manufacture of paper and printing
3-38
3-39
38.9%
Manufacture of wood and wooden products
24.9%
Wholesale trade
3-37
1975 i-o Code Commodity
1980
3.4%
2.6%
5.0%
19.3%
2.7%
4.9%
1.0%
0.0%
0.0%
0.0%
5.4%
9.1%
3.4%
13.0%
16.4%
8.5%
0.0%
11.8%
0.2%
0.3%
7.5%
0.3%
Retail trade
46,583,485
30,816,484
15,767,001
203,393
1,440,869
1,163,067
495,562
379,978
363,702
215,569
130,481
1,623,112
262,608
227,511
137,804
970,037
319,784
231,911
42,963
93,611
368,485
671,373
million of Rp
Output
100%
66.2%
33.8%
0.4%
3.1%
2.5%
1.1%
0.8%
0.8%
0.5%
0.3%
3.5%
0.6%
0.5%
0.3%
2.1%
0.7%
0.5%
0.1%
0.2%
0.8%
1.4%
9.5%
8.5%
11.9%
14.9%
3.0%
14.0%
24.2%
19.7%
30.6%
34.1%
8.0%
5.7%
20.0%
18.4%
25.5%
19.1%
0.4%
15.5%
23.6%
32.1%
22.6%
28.1%
Output as Wholesale % of total trade
3.2%
2.2%
5.6%
5.3%
1.8%
2.0%
0.9%
0.0%
0.0%
0.0%
0.2%
2.2%
4.5%
12.9%
13.9%
6.8%
0.3%
8.0%
0.3%
0.2%
3.9%
0.8%
Retail trade
Output
30.6%
0.5%
2.2%
2.3%
1.3%
0.9%
0.9%
0.7%
1.4%
11.5%
0.7%
0.3%
0.6%
2.5%
1.3%
0.5%
0.2%
0.3%
1.0%
2.8%
Output as % of total
93,166,433
100%
64,620,295 69.4%
28,546,138
466,266
2,024,504
2,115,895
1,166,481
866,517
854,943
678,970
1,314,322
10,685,012
680,983
286,122
543,333
2,291,166
1,198,114
434,410
167,500
302,266
904,176
2,563,007
million of Rp
1985
267
| Appendix 2 12.0% 6.5%
Root crops
Fruit & Vegetables
Fruit
Vegetables
1-04
1-05
Sugar
Coconut
Palm oil & vegetable oil
Tobacco
Coffee
Tea
Clove
Nutmeg
other spices
Other crops
Livestock
Slaughtering
1-08
1-09
1-10
1-11
1-12
1-13
1-14
1-15
1-16
1-17
1-18
1-19
2.4%
Soybeans
6.1%
3.3%
7.2%
8.9%
7.5%
20.5%
4.1%
2.4%
5.0%
5.2%
4.3%
3.0%
Groundnut
Rubber
3.8%
7.0%
Beans
1-07
1-06
9.4%
Maize
1-03
3.8%
Handpounded rice
1-02
0.8%
Paddy
Wholesale trade
1-01
1975 i-o Code Commodity
Table A2.2 Continued, 1990-1995
7.5%
0.7%
4.4%
0.2%
1.8%
0.3%
0.2%
0.0%
2.4%
0.0%
0.0%
0.3%
2.8%
7.8%
10.5%
17.5%
14.2%
4.8%
4.5%
0.0%
1990 Retail trade
3,414,980
2,248,388
1,376,288
594,700
184,897
728,692
418,220
1,062,708
1,193,046
924,878
932,278
1,151,707
1,044,854
2,524,774
3,736,004
4,037,691
7,773,695
2,656,676
1,600,424
14,081,838
million of Rp
Output
1.7%
1.1%
0.7%
0.3%
0.1%
0.4%
0.2%
0.5%
0.6%
0.5%
0.5%
0.6%
0.5%
1.2%
1.8%
2.0%
3.8%
1.3%
0.8%
6.9%
7.0%
10.8%
7.0%
3.3%
11.0%
30.7%
6.7%
1.7%
5.4%
13.3%
3.3%
3.2%
2.8%
3.9%
5.9%
11.9%
9.1%
6.5%
3.8%
1.4%
Output as Wholesale % of total trade
8.3%
1.9%
2.9%
0.1%
3.2%
0.3%
0.1%
0.0%
2.6%
0.0%
0.0%
0.9%
2.8%
6.1%
8.9%
13.1%
11.1%
4.4%
4.6%
0.0%
Retail trade
Output
12,573,324
5,626,265
2,550,513
590,038
514,872
1,409,436
1,235,161
2,780,401
3,044,150
3,783,402
3,768,286
1,799,522
1,430,150
3,673,195
7,567,590
8,546,637
16,114,227
4,423,516
3,276,902
23,514,310
million of Rp
1995
2.4%
1.1%
0.5%
0.1%
0.1%
0.3%
0.2%
0.5%
0.6%
0.7%
0.7%
0.3%
0.3%
0.7%
1.4%
1.6%
3.1%
0.8%
0.6%
4.5%
Output as % of total
268
| Accounting for Services 28.9%
Other forest products
Fishing
Sea fishing
1-22
1-23
5.0% 10.7%
Vegetable oil
Milling and polishing of rice
Other cereal milling
Sugar industry
Manufacture of other food products
Manufacture of beverages
Manufacture of cigarettes
Spinning industry
Manufacture of textile, leather and clothing
Manufacture of made up textile goods except wearing apparel
Wearing apparel
Manufacture of footwear and leather products
3-28
3-29
3-30
3-31
3-32
3-33
3-34
3-35
3-36
Manufacture of wood and wooden products
9.3%
Processing and preserving food
3-27
3-37
5.6%
Other mining
2-26
21.2%
0.9%
4.4%
14.0%
12.4%
5.3%
12.1%
3.0%
12.0%
25.1%
23.7%
0.0%
Crude oil and gas mining
2-25
1.4%
Coal mining and metal ore mining
20.3%
7.1%
14.0%
2-24
Drying and salting of fish
Inland water fishing
20.4%
Wood/Logging
1-21
17.8%
Poultry and its products
4.9%
Wholesale trade
1-20
1975 i-o Code Commodity
0.6%
8.5%
5.8%
4.7%
5.5%
0.7%
5.4%
15.0%
9.0%
8.1%
7.5%
1.0%
3.5%
12.0%
0.0%
0.0%
0.0%
29.6%
5.1%
19.1%
18.2%
1.4%
1.6%
5.0%
1990 Retail trade
8,907,254
956,383
3,245,514
573,429
10,971,070
3,204,806
7,020,399
554,147
6,447,790
1,937,550
1,388,726
15,590,172
2,808,780
2,514,694
3,123,989
22,945,458
2,550,556
1,329,052
1,301,116
2,083,365
4,713,533
342,145
3,167,509
3,246,238
million of Rp
Output
4.3%
0.5%
1.6%
0.3%
5.4%
1.6%
3.4%
0.3%
3.1%
0.9%
0.7%
7.6%
1.4%
1.2%
1.5%
11.2%
1.2%
0.6%
0.6%
1.0%
2.3%
0.2%
1.5%
1.6%
13.5%
11.2%
4.0%
4.5%
5.2%
1.8%
2.6%
12.3%
10.7%
4.9%
15.5%
2.3%
13.2%
21.2%
23.1%
0.0%
1.0%
23.8%
3.0%
22.3%
16.3%
2.0%
14.0%
5.1%
Output as Wholesale % of total trade
17.5%
8.4%
4.5%
2.2%
4.5%
0.3%
2.7%
10.6%
7.7%
7.2%
9.6%
0.7%
3.7%
13.3%
0.0%
0.0%
0.0%
15.2%
2.1%
14.3%
10.5%
6.3%
1.2%
1.9%
Retail trade
Output
22,608,605
5,028,319
10,612,323
1,264,633
33,676,663
11,055,347
17,710,696
2,782,640
27,770,392
9,551,683
5,284,685
28,680,691
8,794,176
17,340,164
9,918,888
28,095,680
9,550,051
1,958,002
3,843,541
6,098,895
11,900,438
2,380,332
8,976,488
9,571,347
million of Rp
1995
4.3%
1.0%
2.0%
0.2%
6.4%
2.1%
3.4%
0.5%
5.3%
1.8%
1.0%
5.5%
1.7%
3.3%
1.9%
5.4%
1.8%
0.4%
0.7%
1.2%
2.3%
0.5%
1.7%
1.8%
Output as % of total
269
| Appendix 2 14.4% 7.0% 8.5% 8.1%
Manufacture of ceramic and earthenware
Cement industry
Manufacture of basic iron and steel
Manufacture of non ferrous basic metal
Manufacture of metal products
Manufacture of machinery and equipment
Manufacture of transport equipment
Other manufactures
All agricultural products
All manufacturing products
Total
3-43
3-44
3-45
3-46
3-47
3-48
3-49
3-50
3.0%
20.4%
29.9%
15.3%
9.7%
25.9%
20.1%
10.2%
Manufacture of rubber products
3-42
12.5%
Manufacture of plastic goods 5.6%
34.7%
Manufacture of cosmetics
Manufacture of petroleum
11.6%
Manufacture of drugs and medicine
3-41
12.8%
Chemical industry
Printing and publishing
3-40
7.9% 8.0%
Manufacture of paper and cardboard products 0.5%
5.2%
Manufacture of paper and cardboard
Manufacture of fertilizers
6.5%
Manufacture of paper and printing
Wholesale trade
3-39
3-38
1975 i-o Code Commodity
3.7%
3.0%
5.5%
13.1%
3.4%
3.4%
1.3%
0.0%
0.0%
0.0%
1.5%
2.2%
3.4%
4.6%
24.3%
8.8%
7.1%
0.4%
6.6%
0.1%
0.1%
2.2%
1990 Retail trade
0.6%
2.9%
3.5%
1.6%
0.9%
1.6%
0.5%
0.8%
1.6%
9.3%
0.8%
0.1%
0.7%
3.6%
1.1%
0.7%
0.3%
1.1%
2.1%
204,854,695
100%
151,668,788 74.0%
8.5%
8.8%
7.6%
9.9%
2.8%
19.8%
22.2%
6.9%
9.6%
27.3%
12.8%
5.7%
6.4%
14.0%
15.1%
6.9%
13.0%
0.1%
4.7%
6.8%
5.6%
5.5%
Output as Wholesale % of total trade
53,185,907 26.0%
1,220,286
6,005,865
7,075,613
3,196,928
1,903,732
3,370,672
1,089,005
1,638,342
3,203,479
19,051,251
1,692,206
285,908
1,521,450
7,325,117
2,299,640
1,365,030
711,669
2,246,768
4,323,467
million of Rp
Output
3.4%
3.1%
4.3%
5.7%
1.0%
2.7%
1.4%
0.0%
0.0%
0.0%
0.8%
1.1%
3.8%
4.3%
10.2%
4.7%
3.9%
0.1%
2.3%
0.3%
0.1%
0.8%
Retail trade
Output
524,417,643
402,711,040
121,706,603
6,140,095
19,753,331
23,539,136
7,599,829
4,242,259
9,449,836
2,499,886
5,964,397
11,367,831
26,059,038
10,834,478
1,539,221
3,891,757
33,353,035
5,170,538
4,457,789
2,667,154
7,626,528
14,751,470
million of Rp
1995
100%
76.8%
23.2%
1.2%
3.8%
4.5%
1.4%
0.8%
1.8%
0.5%
1.1%
2.2%
5.0%
2.1%
0.3%
0.7%
6.4%
1.0%
0.9%
0.5%
1.5%
2.8%
Output as % of total
Table A2.2 Continued, 2000 2000 1975 i-o Code
Commodity
Wholesale Retail trade trade
Output
Output as % of total
million of Rp 1-01
Paddy
1-02
Handpounded rice
1-03
Maize
1-04
Root crops
1-05
Fruit & Vegetables
1-06
2.2%
0.0%
56,850,086
3.7%
12.7%
11.8%
10,700,060
0.7%
9.5%
14.9%
14,682,509
0.9%
16.2%
15.5%
36,730,962
2.4%
Fruit
17.5%
16.1%
13,943,195
0.9%
Vegetables
15.4%
15.1%
22,787,767
1.5%
Beans
7.2%
5.0%
7,035,499
0.5%
Groundnut
5.3%
5.3%
3,553,623
0.2%
Soybeans
9.0%
1.0%
2,397,887
0.2%
1-07
Rubber
4.3%
0.0%
11,972,081
0.8%
1-08
Sugar
9.7%
0.2%
5,190,566
0.3%
1-09
Coconut
8.4%
8.7%
6,911,272
0.4%
1-10
Palm oil & vegetable oil
1.0%
0.2%
5,298,764
0.3%
1-11
Tobacco
4.2%
1.8%
970,166
0.1%
1-12
Coffee
17.9%
0.6%
1,943,888
0.1%
1-13
Tea
11.0%
9.6%
600,524
0.0%
1-14
Clove
5.0%
5.3%
1,553,382
0.1%
1-15
Nutmeg
1-16
other spices 16.7%
6.6%
8,628,666
0.6%
9.4%
2.6%
10,813,696
0.7%
1-17
Other crops
1-18
Livestock
1-19
Slaughtering
10.9%
9.1%
26,724,474
1.7%
1-20
Poultry and its products
11.1%
4.9%
35,732,657
2.3%
1-21
Wood/Logging
14.3%
1.4%
17,340,028
1.1%
1-22
Other forest products
3.6%
0.3%
8,875,750
0.6%
1-23
Fishing
19.0%
13.0%
38,880,989
2.5%
Sea fishing
22.0%
14.0%
22,138,438
1.4%
Inland water fishing Drying and salting of fish
5.3%
3.1%
5,648,732
0.4%
19.8%
15.9%
11,093,820
0.7%
2-24
Coal mining and metal ore mining
2.0%
0.0%
51,377,070
3.3%
2-25
Crude oil and gas mining
0.0%
0.0%
129,638,467
8.3%
2-26
Other mining
16.1%
0.2%
15,799,613
1.0%
3-27
Processing and preserving food
19.2%
11.2%
41,969,313
2.7%
3-28
Vegetable oil
12.8%
3.6%
48,416,945
3.1%
270
| Accounting for Services
2000 1975 i-o Code
Commodity
Wholesale Retail trade trade
3-29
Milling and polishing of rice
11.7%
3-30
Other cereal milling
3-31
Sugar industry
3-32
Manufacture of other food products
3-33 3-34 3-35 3-36
Output
Output as % of total
million of Rp 3.5%
65,671,746
4.2%
14.4%
8.3%
11,776,009
0.8%
7.6%
6.5%
7,388,986
0.5%
7.8%
9.1%
83,972,019
5.4%
Manufacture of beverages
10.6%
14.7%
7,568,598
0.5%
Manufacture of cigarettes
10.5%
4.0%
35,837,164
2.3%
Spinning industry
3.6%
2.4%
29,500,124
1.9%
Manufacture of textile, leather and clothing
7.8%
5.9%
101,911,975
6.5%
Manufacture of made up textile goods except wearing apparel
2.9%
2.9%
3,232,462
0.2%
Wearing apparel
9.6%
6.5%
29,707,788
1.9%
Manufacture of footwear and leather products
11.9%
10.1%
15,640,346
1.0%
3-37
Manufacture of wood and wooden products
12.9%
5.9%
56,413,812
3.6%
3-38
Manufacture of paper and printing
7.0%
2.7%
55,989,500
3.6%
Manufacture of paper and cardboard
6.1%
1.3%
33,511,472
2.2%
Manufacture of paper and cardboard products
7.7%
6.3%
8,850,620
0.6% 0.9%
Printing and publishing
8.7%
3.6%
13,627,408
3-39
Manufacture of fertilizers
3.1%
3.5%
7,141,254
0.5%
3-40
Chemical industry
6.6%
4.2%
99,724,451
6.4%
Manufacture of drugs and medicine
1.1%
4.4%
9,816,743
0.6%
Manufacture of cosmetics
11.8%
15.5%
3,999,697
0.3%
Manufacture of plastic goods
6.8%
4.0%
31,041,928
2.0%
3-41
Manufacture of petroleum
2.6%
1.1%
110,549,652
7.1%
3-42
Manufacture of rubber products
6.5%
3.6%
26,390,348
1.7%
3-43
Manufacture of ceramic and earthenware
6.8%
5.8%
16,057,561
1.0%
3-44
Cement industry
20.6%
39.3%
7,763,818
0.5%
3-45
Manufacture of basic iron and steel
3.6%
0.0%
20,117,948
1.3%
3-46
Manufacture of non ferrous basic metal
6.7%
0.0%
13,611,665
0.9%
3-47
Manufacture of metal products
4.7%
2.0%
27,529,413
1.8%
3-48
Manufacture of machinery and equipment
9.6%
5.1%
94,102,803
6.0%
3-49
Manufacture of transport equipment
16.4%
1.2%
59,205,120
3.8%
3-50
Other manufactures
13.7%
10.4%
23,841,034
1.5%
All agricultural products
10.5%
6.7%
307,436,021
19.7%
All manufacturing products
7.8%
4.1%
1,249,266,409
80.3%
Total
8.4%
4.6%
1,556,702,430
100%
271
| Appendix 2
The conclusion is that over time trade margins do not seem to fluctuate too much. Therefore I have chosen to use fixed margins of 12.5 per cent for agricultural goods, 11.5 per cent for manufactured goods, 20 per cent for imports and 15 per cent for exports. These percentages are mainly based on estimates from the i-o tables, and seem in line with other sources. Furthermore, I assume that in 1900 50 per cent of total agricultural output is for own consumption falling to 10 per cent in 2000. For estimates of agricultural and industrial value added I relied on the estimates by Van der Eng (2002). These estimates, however, are in constant prices and therefore were first transformed in current price estimates using a cpi. Then from these value added estimates output was calculated by dividing value added by a value added-output ratio for which the average ratio of the i-o tables from 1975-2000 was taken.
Notes for table A2.3: (1) = Agricultural value added in constant 1983 prices (billion fl/Rp) (Van der Eng 2002) (2) = Industrial value added in constant 1983 prices (billion fl/Rp) (Van der Eng 2002) (3) = Agricultural value added in current prices (million fl/Rp) = ((1) * (10))/100 (4) = Industrial value added in current prices (million fl/Rp) = ((2) * (10))/100 (5) = Output in agriculture in current prices = (3) / Value added-output ratio = (3) * 0.77 0.77 is the average value added output ratio in the i-o tables from 1975 to 2000. (6) = Output in industry in current prices = (4) / Value added-output ratio = (3) * 0.48 0.48 is the average value added output ratio in the i-o tables from 1975 to 2000 (7) = Import (in million fl/Rp) (8) = Export (in million fl/Rp) (9) = cpi (1993 = 100) (10) = cpi (1983=100) (11) = Value added in current prices (million fl/Rp) = (5) * 12.5% * # + (6) * 11.5% + (7) * 20% + (8) * 15 % (#: assumption that in 1900 50 per cent of agricul tural output is for self consumption falling to 10 per cent in 2000). (12) = Value added in constant 1993 prices (million fl/Rp) = (11) / (9)* 100
272
| Accounting for Services
Table A2.3 Value added in trade sector, 1900-2000 (1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
1900
3,715
1,392
773
290
1,004
(6) 603
1901
3,686
1,314
951
339
1,235
706
1902
3,564
1,296
852
310
1,106
645
1903
3,769
1,385
942
346
1,224
721
1904
3,839
1,324
860
297
1,117
618
1905
3,881
1,269
838
274
1,089
571
1906
4,060
1,281
930
293
1,207
611
1907
4,113
1,348
1,065
349
1,383
727
1908
4,037
1,372
1,102
375
1,431
780
1909
4,283
1,373
1,096
351
1,424
732
1910
4,523
1,498
1,158
383
1,504
799
1911
4,701
1,656
1,326
467
1,722
973
1912
4,697
1,746
1,527
567
1,983
1,182
1913
4,807
1,898
1,428
564
1,854
1,174
1914
4,889
1,752
1,408
505
1,829
1,051
1915
4,995
1,709
1,409
482
1,829
1,004
1916
4,931
1,860
1,499
565
1,947
1,178
1917
5,070
1,719
1,648
559
2,140
1,164
1918
5,283
1,720
2,198
716
2,854
1,491
1919
5,442
1,849
2,269
771
2,947
1,606
1920
5,137
1,897
3,483
1,286
4,523
2,680
1921
4,969
1,892
2,827
1,077
3,672
2,243
1922
5,347
1,931
2,647
956
3,437
1,991
1923
5,394
2,034
2,390
901
3,103
1,877
1924
5,698
2,084
2,325
850
3,019
1,771
1925
5,761
2,131
2,241
829
2,910
1,727
1926
6,064
2,342
2,353
909
3,056
1,893
1927
6,418
2,440
2,407
915
3,126
1,906
1928
6,520
2,557
2,399
941
3,116
1,960
1929
6,294
2,774
2,304
1,015
2,992
2,115
1930
6,528
2,821
2,330
1,007
3,027
2,098
1931
6,396
2,361
2,040
753
2,650
1,569
1932
6,419
2,231
1,714
596
2,226
1,241
1933
6,309
2,256
1,489
532
1,934
1,109
1934
6,025
2,551
1,307
554
1,698
1,153
1935
6,345
2,850
1,320
593
1,714
1,235
1936
6,655
3,284
1,338
660
1,737
1,375
1937
7,099
3,669
1,519
785
1,973
1,636
1938
7,101
3,795
1,562
835
2,029
1,739
1939
7,247
3,985
2,073
1,140
2,692
2,374
1940
7,563
4,478
1,739
1,030
2,259
2,146
273
| Appendix 2
(1)
(2)
(3)
7,869
4,732
1,999
(4)
(5)
(6)
1,202
2,596
2,504
1949
6,272
2,873
1950
6,410
2,953
17,449
7,993
22,661
16,651
20,897
9,627
27,138
20,056
1951
6,858
3,406
37,280
18,515
48,416
38,573
1952
6,901
3,328
39,584
19,089
51,408
39,770
1953 1954
7,054
3,428
42,994
20,894
55,837
43,528
7,724
3,607
50,028
23,363
64,972
48,672
1955
7,473
4,144
64,096
35,543
83,241
74,048
1956
7,549
3,883
74,146
38,139
96,294
79,456
1957
7,558
4,469
81,483
48,180
105,822
100,376
1958
7,835
3,412
122,986
53,558
159,722
111,580
1959
8,222
3,315
156,037
62,912
202,646
131,067
1960
8,406
3,294
196,499
77,001
255,193
160,418
1961
8,523
3,679
272,736
117,728
354,203
245,267
1962
9,097
3,538
809,633
314,882
1,051,471
656,004
1963
8,474
3,274
1,686,326
651,526
2,190,034
1,357,346
1964
9,046
3,270
3,817,412
1,379,940
4,957,678
2,874,875
1965
9,029
3,322
15,421,532
5,673,976
20,027,964
11,820,783
1966
9,448
3,407
188,960
68,140
245,403
141,958
1967
8,811
3,409
466,983
180,677
606,471
376,410
1968
9,589
3,830
1,141,091
455,770
1,481,936
949,521
1969
9,921
4,549
1,379,019
632,311
1,790,934
1,317,315
1970
10,728
5,133
1,684,296
805,881
2,187,397
1,678,919
1971
10,767
5,868
1,755,021
956,484
2,279,248
1,992,675
1972
11,015
6,639
1,916,610
1,155,186
2,489,104
2,406,638
1973
12,201
7,333
2,781,828
1,671,924
3,612,764
3,483,175
1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948
1974
12,354
8,256
3,965,634
2,650,176
5,150,174
5,521,200
1975
12,273
8,670
4,688,286
3,311,940
6,088,683
6,899,875
1976
12,971
9,104
5,940,718
4,169,632
7,715,218
8,686,733
1977
13,213
10,149
6,712,204
5,155,692
8,717,148
10,741,025
1978
14,301
10,853
7,851,249
5,958,297
10,196,427
12,413,119
1979
14,669
12,024
9,696,209
7,947,864
12,592,479
16,558,050
1980
15,877
13,722
12,114,151
10,469,886
15,732,664
21,812,263
274
| Accounting for Services
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
1981
16,803
15,094
13,929,687
12,512,926
18,090,503
26,068,596
1982
16,629
15,593
15,015,987
14,080,479
19,501,282
29,334,331
1983
17,696
15,812
17,696,000
15,812,000
22,981,818
32,941,667
1984
18,513
17,730
20,447,194
19,582,388
26,554,797
40,796,641
1985
19,300
19,267
22,308,623
22,270,479
28,972,238
46,396,831
1986
19,799
20,789
24,231,612
25,443,254
31,469,626
53,006,778
1987
20,224
22,679
27,032,411
30,313,887
35,107,027
63,153,931
1988
21,167
25,192
30,574,555
36,388,444
39,707,215
75,809,258
1989
22,267
28,227
34,231,358
43,393,746
44,456,309
90,403,637
1990
23,028
32,062
38,189,054
53,170,812
49,596,174
110,772,525
1991
23,756
35,983
43,060,212
65,222,917
55,922,353
135,881,076
1992
25,331
40,064
49,359,743
78,068,325
64,103,562
162,642,343
1993
25,792
44,963
55,176,915
96,189,501
71,658,331
200,394,794
1994
25,968
50,825
60,247,482
117,917,371
78,243,483
245,661,189
1995
27,184
57,074
69,064,490
145,003,926
89,694,143
302,091,512
1996
28,062
64,058
76,879,641
175,495,547
99,843,690
365,615,723
1997
28,149
67,921
82,252,964
198,468,990
106,822,032
413,477,063
1998
28,130
56,756
129,733,879
261,755,281
168,485,557
545,323,502
1999 2000 (7)
(8)
(9)
(10)
(11)
1900
195.9
255.2
0.010
0.208
209.55
2,155,346
(12)
1901
229.2
265.5
0.012
0.258
244.69
2,028,947
1902
203.0
274.4
0.011
0.239
226.22
2,024,899
1903
187.1
295.6
0.012
0.250
243.03
2,079,561
1904
207.8
309.1
0.010
0.224
231.01
2,206,309
1905
218.8
330.9
0.010
0.216
229.83
2,276,203
1906
234.9
330.9
0.011
0.229
245.98
2,298,105
1907
247.3
364.6
0.012
0.259
279.10
2,305,244
1908
280.6
470.7
0.013
0.273
311.64
2,442,106
1909
281.6
455.1
0.012
0.256
304.20
2,541,963
1910
345.3
452.6
0.012
0.256
330.33
2,760,307
1911
400.5
521.6
0.013
0.282
387.30
2,938,088
1912
434.8
596.7
0.015
0.325
448.22
2,950,317
1913
493.3
683.9
0.014
0.297
464.23
3,343,900
1914
429.5
684.7
0.013
0.288
436.58
3,242,978
1915
399.4
770.9
0.013
0.282
439.03
3,330,566 3,463,549
1916
446.3
868.1
0.014
0.304
492.19
1917
496.7
793.2
0.015
0.325
504.10
3,318,182
1918
567.5
679.8
0.019
0.416
590.97
3,039,046
1919
793.2
2,167.5
0.019
0.417
880.69
4,518,253
275
| Appendix 2
(7)
(8)
(9)
(10)
1920
1,310.8
2,238.9
0.032
0.678
1921
1,244.4
1,195.9
0.027
1922
842.3
1,153.0
0.023
1923
651.4
1,380.5
1924
706.5
1,557.3
1925
862.6
1926
924.1
1927
927.1
1928
1,030.2
1929 1930
(11)
(12)
1,234.07
3,893,937
0.569
954.24
3,587,747
0.495
823.06
3,557,052
0.021
0.443
782.88
3,780,577
0.019
0.408
803.54
4,213,370
1,813.4
0.018
0.389
861.42
4,737,228
1,600.5
0.018
0.388
873.30
4,815,095
1,656.2
0.018
0.375
890.62
5,080,912
1,589.9
0.017
0.368
908.35
5,280,323
1,166.0
1,487.8
0.017
0.366
929.98
5,435,894
922.3
1,200.0
0.017
0.357
840.31
5,035,577
1931
609.9
822.1
0.015
0.319
632.42
4,241,094
1932
409.9
615.1
0.012
0.267
491.69
3,939,522
1933
331.4
527.0
0.011
0.236
425.65
3,858,493
1934
291.6
564.5
0.010
0.217
410.61
4,048,214
1935
277.9
505.3
0.010
0.208
410.52
4,222,444
1936
287.3
630.7
0.009
0.201
450.06
4,789,851
1937
516.0
1,012.3
0.010
0.214
602.97
5,999,731
1938
497.4
714.4
0.010
0.220
572.02
5,562,689
1939
529.9
787.1
0.013
0.286
717.82
5,369,172
1940
437.6
940.3
0.011
0.230
661.70
6,154,726
1941
475.6
1,086.7
0.012
0.254
761.53
6,414,127
1942
0.017
1943
0.016
1944
0.024
1945
0.033
1946
0.058
1947
0.082
1948
0.106
1949
0.130
2.782
3,886
2,988,560
1950
1,728
3,047
0.152
3.260
5,484
3,598,548
1951
3,383
4,918
0.254
5.436
10,111
3,979,070
1952
10,855
10,664
0.268
5.736
12,894
4,808,864
1953
8,739
9,610
0.285
6.095
13,165
4,620,655
1954
7,216
9,928
0.303
6.477
14,345
4,737,922
1955
6,888
10,618
0.401
8.577
18,978
4,733,429
1956
9,807
10,209
0.459
9.822
21,345
4,649,049
1957
9,160
11,052
0.504
10.781
24,663
4,893,898
1958
5,851
8,612
0.734
15.697
29,908
4,076,109
1959
5,227
9,944
0.887
18.978
36,253
4,086,644
276
| Accounting for Services
(7)
(8)
(9)
(10)
1960
49,000
52,000
1.09
23.376
1961
64,000
45,000
1.50
1962
72,000
69,000
4.16
1963
300,000
291,000
9.30
1964
932,000
874,000
1965
1,360,000
1966
69,800
(11)
(12)
59,653
5,459,304
32
80,697
5,394,823
89
198,503
4,771,441
199
465,608
5,005,410
19.73
422
1,116,611
5,660,593
1,251,000
79.84
1,708
3,721,697
4,661,498
40,300
0.93
20
59,766
6,392,894
1967
143,000
74,400
2.48
53
141,268
5,702,190
1968
326,600
227,900
5.56
119
351,707
6,322,752
1969
402,600
245,200
6.50
139
442,512
6,810,553
1970
529,000
428,800
7.34
157
576,467
7,855,017
1971
607,000
507,000
7.62
163
649,974
8,530,623
1972
766,000
729,000
8.13
174
784,490
9,645,185
1973
1,315,600
1,189,000
10.66
228
1,199,699
11,256,665
1974
2,293,700
3,105,100
15.00
321
2,071,885
13,808,073
1975
2,778,000
2,850,600
17.86
382
2,385,544
13,359,692
1976
3,222,100
3,429,600
21.41
458
2,933,214
13,700,949
1977
3,817,200
4,465,800
23.75
508
3,548,960
14,945,477
1978
4,558,800
4,787,800
25.66
549
4,092,376
15,946,875
1979
7,554,700
9,628,700
30.90
661
6,143,854
19,884,368
1980
10,079,800
13,849,200
35.67
763
8,214,348
23,031,433
1981
13,802,200
14,927,900
38.75
829
9,860,835
25,446,706
1982
15,681,700
13,345,200
42.21
903
10,529,951
24,946,579
1983
19,625,900
19,847,000
46.74
1,000
13,080,631
27,983,439
1984
19,844,700
22,999,300
51.63
1,104
14,885,425
28,832,130
1985
19,835,200
21,533,900
54.03
1,156
15,574,846
28,825,754
1986
21,036,210
20,009,900
57.21
1,224
16,624,552
29,059,176
1987
27,955,800
29,874,300
62.48
1,337
21,056,352
33,700,613
1988
31,171,400
34,665,600
67.52
1,444
24,381,003
36,109,637
1989
38,601,000
42,505,000
71.86
1,537
29,249,193
40,702,761
1990
50,945,700
51,953,100
77.52
1,658
36,052,534
46,507,769
1991
61,375,700
62,263,800
84.73
1,813
43,280,648
51,081,460
1992
70,336,600
76,384,400
91.09
1,949
51,184,086
56,193,592
1993
78,383,000
85,296,200
100
2,139
59,327,189
59,327,189
1994
89,780,000
94,537,400
108.45
2,320
68,955,308
63,582,807
1995
125,656,902
119,592,500
118.76
2,541
87,677,135
73,827,352
1996
140,811,996
137,533,300
128.06
2,740
101,870,930
79,548,123
1997
176,599,794
174,871,305
136.59
2,922
120,957,762
88,555,909
1998
413,058,111
506,244,809
215.58
4,612
116,688,500
54,127,352
1999
301,654,008
390,560,100
259.77
5,557
140,588,700
54,120,986
2000
423,317,900
542,992,400
269.38
5,763
155,184,400
57,608,022
277
| Appendix 2
278
| Accounting for Services
Appendix 3
National Accounting for Government Services
The conventional practice in national income estimation is to evaluate government services – other than those of government enterprises – in terms of expenditures made for them. Government activities can best be split into administrative and commercial activities. The former are valued at the cost of these services, that is, as equivalent to the wages and salaries paid by government administrative departments and the latter on the same basis as other productive enterprises. The government sector includes public administration under government services. Railways, post and telegraph, opium production, salt production, etc. are included under commercial activities. These major commercial activities are treated separately.
A3.1
Government administration in Indonesia’s National Accounts since independence Figures about wages and salaries were taken directly from the different ministries in the period 1951-1954. These are given in table A3.1.
Table A3.1
Government administration and defence, 1951-1954 (x1,000 rupiah) 1951
Central government and defence
1952
1953
1954
3,110,698
4,054,956
3,711,056
4,382,004
Local government
828,100
1,249,800
2,181,451
2,687,272
Government income from property excluding estates
246,100
581,300
368,971
418,667
Source: Muljatno 1960: 192-193.
In the national accounts estimates of the 1960s production accounts for the central government were derived from actual routine budget expenditure statements of the Budget Directorate of the Department of Finance. Fixed capital consumption was calculated as 5 per cent of net value added, i.e. compensation of employees. For local government, compensation of employees was calculated as the product of average annual income per employee and employment figures. Employment estimates were based on information from the Department of Interior and on the Census of Civil Servants.
279
| Appendix 3
For the 1980s and 1990s the contribution of this sector to gross domestic product consisted of routine wages and salaries of central and local government employees, the wage component of the development budget, and 5 per cent depreciation. The estimation was based on realised government expenditure gathered from the Ministry of Finance and bps. Van der Eng (1996, 2002) used gross public expenditure, deflated with the index of retail prices as an indicator. He argued that using employment in this sector as an indicator, assuming that productivity remained unchanged, may be a better option. But, apart from the fact that there are no consistent data on employment in the public sector, the impression exists that during the 1950s and 1960s the payroll of the public service expanded significantly, although many civil servants spent part of their ‘official’ working hours in second jobs in order to augment their ‘official’ income. Official estimates of the contribution of government administration and defence to total gpd are given in table A3.2. Table A3.3 presents the estimates from the Input-Output tables. Comparing tables A32 and A3.3, we see rather large differences between the national account estimates on the one hand and the ones based on i-o tables on the other. This is caused by the fact that in the national account estimates health and educational services by the government are included under government administration and defence, whereas in the i-o tables these are classified as educational and health services. Table A3.4 and A3.5 show the government budget between 1969 and 2000. For the period 1950-1968 only aggregated information on the government budget was found. Using the rather stable ratio of personnel expenditures as percentage of total routine expenditures, which averages 39.3 per cent with a standard deviation of 6.4 per cent between 1969 and 2000 (table A3.5, column (7)), it is possible to make a rough estimate for the contribution of the government sector in this earlier period.
280
| Accounting for Services
Table A3.2 Government administration and defence in Indonesia’s National Accounts, 1958-2000
Year
Billion Rp
1958
15.1
Year
Billion Rp
1980
3,142.3
1959
15.1
1981
3,904.7
1960
17.6
1982
4,428.7
1961
26.4
1983
5,711.5
1962
33.8
1984
6,469.9
1963
120.5
1985
7,925.1
1964
195.6
1986
8,307.3
1965
845.5
1987
8,911.8
1966
16.2
1988
9,446.2
1967
40.6
1989
11,174.2
1968
88.0
1990
12,801.4
1969
136.0
1991
14,621.6
1970
183.0
1992
17,309.4
1971
214.0
1993
22,458.0
1972
290.0
1994
22,754.9
1973
405.0
1995
26,555.2
1974
585.0
1996
29,752.9
1975
864.3
1997
32,127.9
1976
1,074.3
1998
40,641.0
1977
1,394.2
1999
56,745.0
1978
1,685.4
2000
69,460.2
1979
2,199.6
Source: Pendapatan Nasional Indonesia, various issues.
Table A3.3 Government administration and defense according to Indonesia’s i-o tables (in millions Rp) 1971 Salaries and wages (1) Depreciation (2) Value added (3) (2)/(1) * 100%
1975
1985
177,003
669,779
2,344,690
6,071,428
8,850
35,252
123,405
303,571
185,853
705,030
2,468,094
5.0%
5.3%
5.3%
Source: Input-output tables, various issues.
281
1980
| Appendix 3
1990
9,690,485 18,829,796 484,524
6,374,999 10,175,009 5.0%
1995
5.0%
954,595
2000 42,351,925 2,147,072
19,784,391 44,498,997 5.1%
5.1%
Table A3.4 Government budget: personnel expenditures, 1969/1970-1999/2000 (in billion Rp) Personnel expenditures Rice allowances Salaries and pensions
Food allowances
Other domestic personnel expenditures
Overseas personnel expenditure
1969/1970
Total
103.84
1970/1971
131.43
1971/1972
163.34
1972/1973
200.38
1973/1974
268.86
1974/1975 1975/1976 1976/1977
114.9
424.8
45.7
36.9
14.3
636.6
1977/1978
126.2
672.9
47.8
31.5
14.8
893.2
1978/1979
132.8
760.3
51.3
33.6
23.6
1,001.6
1979/1980
179.9
1,053.9
109.9
47.1
29.1
1,419.9
1980/1981
252.0
1,482.9
193.2
61.2
34.0
2,023.3
1981/1982
253.3
1,660.4
240.5
79.5
43.4
2,277.1
1982/1983
289.9
1,749.0
254.9
78.6
45.7
2,418.1
1983/1984
346.1
1,996.0
261.3
87.6
66.0
2,757.0
1984/1985
407.0
2,206.6
271.4
89.7
72.1
3,046.8
1985/1986
402.0
3,072.6
300.4
161.1
82.2
4,018.3
1986/1987
406
3,330
288
177
110
4,311
1987/1988
451
3,561
299
176
130
4,617
1988/1989
518
3,833
327
185
135
4,998
1989/1990
588
4,826
373
243
171
6,201
1990/1991
640
5,570
382
263
198
7,053
1991/1992
922
6,299
393
279
209
8,102
1992/1993
891
7,595
479
315
274
9,554
1993/1994
834
9,145
493
418
255
11,145
1994/1995
1,038
10,490
801
396
344
13,069
1995/1996
734
11,047
560
370
290
13,001
1996/1997
768
13,002
101
480
103
14,454
1997/1998
788
13,698
1,174
671
938
17,269
1998/1999
1,606
19,089
1,687
1,161
937
24,480
1999/2000
2,004
26,881
2,289
1,438
1,011
33,623
Source: Statistik Indonesia, various issues.
Notes for table A3.5 (1) = (2) = (3) =
282
Total material expenditures Subsidies to autonomous regions a. Personnel expenditures; b. Non-personnel expenditures; c. Total Total interest and debt repayments
| Accounting for Services
(4) = (5) = (6) = (7) = Table A3.5
Others Total routine expenditures Development expenditures Personnel expenditures as percentage of total routine expenditures
Government budget: other expenditures, 1969/1970-1999/2000 (in billion Rp) (1)
1969/1970
50.29
1970/1971
62.57
1971/1972
67.12
1972/1973
95.42
1973/1974
110.14
(2)a
(2)b
(2)c
(3)
(5)
(6)
(7)
44.12
14.44
(4) 3.85
216.5
334.67
48.0%
56.16
25.60
12.41
288.2
457.93
45.6%
66.80
46.60
5.23
349.1
544.99
46.8%
83.90
53.40
5.00
438.1
736.32
45.7%
108.60
70.70
155.00
713.3
1,164.2
37.7%
1974/1975 1975/1976 1976/1977
339.7
313.0
189.5
150.9
1,629.7
2,054.5
39.1%
1977/1978
376.8
478.4
228.3
172.2
2,148.9
2,156.8
41.6%
1978/1979
419.5
522.3
534.5
265.8
2,743.7
2,555.6
36.5%
1979/1980
569.0
669.9
684.1
718.9
4,061.8
4,014.2
35.0%
1980/1981
670.6
976.1
784.8
1,345.2
5,800.0
5,916.1
34.9%
1981/1982
922.7
1,209.1
931.1
1.637,6
6,977.6
6,940.1
32.6%
1982/1983
1,041.2
1,315.4
1,224.5
997.1
6,996.3
7,359.6
34.6%
1983/1984
1,057.1
1,547.0
2,102.6
948.1
8,411.8
9,899.2
32.8%
1984/1985
1,182.8
1,888.3
2,776.5
539.5
9,433.9
9,951.9
1985/1986
1,367.1
2.247,6
241,4
2.489,0
3,323.1
754.0
11,952
1986/1987
1,367
2,410
239
2,649
5,058
174
13,559
32.3% 52.4%
8,332
49.6% 41.2%
1987/1988
1,329
2,592
224
2,816
8,205
515
17,482
9,477
1988/1989
1,492
2,779
259
3,038
10,940
271
20,739
12,251
37.5%
1989/1990
1,702
3,338
228
3,566
11,939
923
24,331
13,834
39.2%
1990/1991
1,830
3,961
276
4,237
13,395
3,483
29,998
16,656
36.7%
1991/1992
2,373
4,520
314
4,834
13,434
1,484
30,227
21,765
41.8%
1992/1993
2,928
4,996
387
5,383
14,524
1,216
33,605
26,906
43.3%
1993/1994
3,032
6,575
334
6,909
17,163
2,041
40,290
28,428
44.0%
1994/1995
4,296
6,756
432
7,188
18,422
204
43,179
29,164
45.9%
1995/1996
5,175
7,807
420
8,227
22,109
1,923
50,435
28,781
41.3%
1996/1997
8,109
8,874
484
9,358
27,491
3,149
62,561
35,952
37.3%
1997/1998
8,999
10,520
541
11,061
31,112
21,169
89,610
38,359
31.0%
1998/1999
11,058
13,512
682
14,194
55,798
42,187
147,717
67,869
25.7%
1999/2000
10,862
18,379
791
19,170
39,994
63,232
166,881
78,311
31.2%
Source: Statistik Indonesia, various issues.
283
| Appendix 3
Table A3.6 Government budget, 1950-1968 (in million of Rp)
Receipts
A3.2
Expenditures
Balance
1950
6,990.2
8,726.3
-1,736.1
1951
11,810.9
10,625.1
1,185.8
1952
12,246.8
5,025.4
7,221.4
1953
13,590.5
15,658.5
-2,068.0
1954
11,788.7
13,390.7
-1,602.0
1955
14,226.5
16,316.5
-2,090.0
1956
18,451.5
20,015.0
-1,563.5
1957
20,570.7
25,610.2
-5,039.5
1958
23,272.7
35,313.0
-12,040.3
1959
30,570.9
44,350.4
-13,779.5
1960
53,648
60,544
-6,896
1961
62,218
88,522
-26,304
1962
74,020
122,078
-48,058
1963
162,130
329,800
-167,670
1964
283,386
681,330
-397,944
1965
960,766
2,526,320
-1.565,554
1966
13,142
29,433
-16,291
1967
84,900
87,555
-2,655
1968
185,283
185,283
0
From 1966 on calculated in million of new Rp. (1000 Rp old = 1 Rp new). Source: Statistical Pocketbook of Indonesia, 1967.
Government administration in the colonial period For the colonial period a few useful sources for the estimation of the government sector are available. To begin with the number of people employed by the government is known for 1930 from the census. These results can be found in table A3.7. Moreover the Colonial Reports give the number of government employees as of 1 March 1932. A direct estimate of the payroll paid by the government can be made for one single year, namely 1926. For that year the total wages and salaries paid to all employees have been published (Indisch Verslag 1929: 430). Unfortunately this has not been published for other years. Additionally, this figure seems to under-estimate the total number of persons employed, because it is unlikely that the number of civil servants increased from 149,783 in 1926 to 516,176 in 1930. Probably, people working in the desa are not accounted for in the figures published in the Colonial Report.
284
| Accounting for Services
Table A3.7 Number of civil servants, 1930 Natives Desa Local government
Europeans
Chinese
Others
Total
274,802
14
53
22
274,891
44,665
1,833
360
174
47,032
Autonomous regions
23,141
175
111
48
23,475
Central Government
69,939
8,235
2,360
200
80,734
Police
34,340
1,510
92
41
35,983
Army
37,704
8,015
21
5
45,745
7,320
949
42
5
8,316
491,911
20,731
3,039
495
516,176
Marine Total government Source: Volkstelling 1930.
Table A3.8 Government payroll, 1926 Number of civil servants 1
Council of the Netherlands-Indies
2
Council of the chief of departments
Salaries per year (x fl 1,000)
30
45.1
2
24.6
2a
Gov. Delegate for general affairs
1
18.0
3
General Secretariat
209
484.0
4
General Audit Office
361
687.0
5
Salary Office
19
75.6
6
Department of Justice
6,602
10,609.6
7
Department of Finance
14,741
16,190.0
8
Department of Civil Service
38,938
34,831.6
9
Department of Education and Culture
15,310
32,494.1
10
Department of Agriculture, Industries and Commerce
3,809
7,542.5
11
Department of Public Works
7,568
8,236.6
12
Department of State Enterprises
57,737
42,816.1
13
Department of War
973
1,900.4
14
Department of Navy
3,469
3,644.1
15
Local and self-government Total
Source: Indisch Verslag 1929: 430.
285
| Appendix 3
14
201.6
149,783
159,800.9
Table A3.9 Government finance, 1867-1939 Receipts Ordinary 1867
Extraordinary
137,538
Expenditures Total
Ordinary
137,538
95,555
Extraordinary
Total 110,411
1870
123,525
123,525
105,296
1880
146,838
146,838
135,103
11,833
146,936
115,765
1890
136,287
136,287
119,854
7,883
127,737
1900
151,809
151,809
137,433
8,682
146,115
155,646
155,646
157,308
8,915
166,223
221,516
221,516
213,670
17,757
231,427
1912
270,550
270,550
247,795
21,230
269,025
1913
311,354
311,354
287,835
39,236
327,071 343,943
1901 1902 1903 1904 1905 1906 1907 1908 1909 1910 1911
1914
281,726
281,726
295,323
48,620
1915
309,734
309,734
306,335
41,552
347,887
1916
343,127
343,127
331,575
41,474
373,049 420,403
1917
360,139
360,139
371,473
48,930
1918
398,872
852
399,724
442,287
70,286
512,573
1919
535,563
7,534
543,097
623,613
97,573
721,186
1920
756,101
261
756,362
921,740
138,695
1,060,435
1921
791,267
496
791,763
866,086
189,930
1,056,016
1922
751,930
648
752,578
759,230
92,028
851,258
1923
650,052
396
650,448
645,978
64,815
710,793
1924
710,355
7,584
717,939
617,644
48,494
666,138
1925
752,095
1,754
753,849
643,592
39,262
682,854 751,069
1926
805,220
2,633
807,853
704,993
46,076
1927
768,709
10,343
779,052
722,820
53,038
775,858
1928
826,158
9,759
835,917
784,848
60,917
845,765
1929
840,904
7,625
848,529
832,548
72,045
904,593
1930
740,393
15,159
755,552
825,388
68,152
893,540
1931
634,369
17,640
652,009
736,285
30,777
767,062
1932
465,361
35,768
501,129
606,989
24,151
631,140
1933
404,796
55,840
460,636
526,236
27,826
554,062
286
| Accounting for Services
Receipts
Expenditures
Ordinary
Extraordinary
Total
Ordinary
Extraordinary
Total
1934
406,320
48,047
454,367
488,906
19,550
508,456
1935
432,184
34,667
466,851
465,663
14,769
480,432
1936
469,006
66,155
535,161
490,490
20,490
510,980
1937
471,392
54,270
525,662
470,896
71,682
542,578
1938
511,445
39,388
550,833
510,960
59,986
570,946
vi
1939 Source: Indisch Verslag, various issues, cks (1939).
Table A3.10 Government budget, 1900-1907 i
ii
iii
iv
v
1900
1,107,680
5,330,193
12,823,727
29,558,353
16,625,491
1901
1,107,420
5,362,231
10,297,405
30,281,315
17,278,249
1902
1,123,890
5,541,384
11,649,090
30,068,058
18,003,540
1903
1,124,140
5,630,611
13,009,546
30,772,778
19,810,608
1904
1,123,490
5,955,601
13,435,890
30,101,519
20,152,240
1905
1,122,440
5,983,198
13,270,492
22,292,955
20,795,790
6,992,358
1906
1,104,300
5,838,221
15,410,604
23,045,786
19,601,294
6,381,702
1907
1,111,240
5,872,796
16,336,649
23,433,286
23,027,364
7,187,541
vii
viii
ix
x
Total
1900
21,889,118
25,253,903
4,574,458
117,162,923
1901
22,669,461
27,268,621
4,785,753
119,050,455
1902
25,723,182
27,994,626
5,134,330
125,238,100
1903
26,721,799
28,150,426
5,220,117
130,440,025
1904
28,216,572
28,287,344
5,076,679
132,349,335
1905
25,569,655
28,025,980
5,152,044
1906
26,192,727
26,273,912
4,834,830
1,138,710
129,822,086
1907
27,170,840
26,606,911
4,970,851
1,292,230
137,009,708
i = Government and High Colleges ii = Department of Justice iii = Department of Finance iv = Department of Civil Services v = Department of Education, Cults and Industry
287
| Appendix 3
129,204,912
vi = Department of Agriculture vii = Department of Civil Public Works viii = Department of War ix = Navy Department x = Local government
Table A3.11 Government budget, 1908-1940 ii
iii
iv
v
vi
1908
1,110,980
i
6,002,615
17,730,065
24,091,032
10,716,134
6,645,104
1909
1,148,840
6,102,626
21,188,674
24,528,562
11,756,634
7,067,076
1910
1,166,920
6,505,504
23,992,872
24,897,460
12,890,728
7,391,301
1911
1,444,480
7,046,986
30,076,777
26,555,959
13,921,006
7,991,465
1912
1,307,640
7,682,807
29,844,653
28,590,155
16,260,293
8,644,705
1913
1,371,170
8,062,705
29,585,420
32,091,121
16,981,653
10,458,668
1914
1,324,930
9,084,711
31,286,037
35,550,097
18,924,656
11,684,330
1915
1,319,029
9,522,594
29,698,700
40,001,850
20,917,487
12,905,184
1916
1,320,804
9,854,301
30,760,807
37,182,005
27,603,334
14,291,610
1917
1,403,074
11,007,972
32,185,233
41,546,031
29,252,121
14,749,292
1918
1,708,379
11,537,739
33,190,046
41,759,959
32,053,540
16,395,573
1919
1,644,521
12,774,770
34,654,777
47,007,875
34,933,974
19,771,855
1920
1,835,152
13,490,692
43,737,311
55,677,457
39,502,101
20,335,434
1921
2,089,376
15,498,421
52,774,383
74,677,840
47,830,680
24,588,399
1922
2,187,669
17,020,922
109,763,587
77,407,440
52,161,488
28,226,385
1923
2,124,638
15,357,588
101,729,730
57,450,394
59,008,667
20,667,580
1924
2,246,150
17,040,799
89,549,092
58,179,240
56,278,470
17,869,507 18,777,201
1925
2,276,809
17,165,583
83,476,261
72,313,883
58,712,035
1926
2,689,903
20,535,396
80,460,180
77,989,793
65,698,280
21,215,120
1927
3,172,531
21,454,875
84,333,030
89,399,212
69,900,855
24,124,971
1928
3,494,882
24,576,825
64,429,167
96,778,378
75,196,520
25,979,347
1929
2,947,114
25,375,631
90,322,996
102,900,983
75,824,400
28,984,169
1930
3,694,968
25,038,884
99,341,279
115,943,331
81,561,057
32,601,911
1931
3,480,392
25,416,877
81,362,155
116,786,211
87,211,800
31,386,820
1932
3,469,923
13,794,785
68,274,423
78,113,389
37,031,250
1933
2,956,898
19,990,021
75,215,410
63,964,792
33,255,511 18,711,352
1934
2,712,205
16,068,881
74,446,396
75,819,036
62,575,730
17,506,355
1935
2,060,278
14,109,488
69,213,656
70,104,200
47,824,881
21,536,390
1936
1,948,797
13,694,671
35,774,065
57,659,855
45,320,355
14,152,312
1937
1,898,562
13,951,856
35,502,467
47,428,295
43,773,198
13,702,543
1938
1,956,724
15,480,197
55,120,563
77,229,740
38,721,185
14,789,826
1939
2,247,183
17,783,231
43,900,360
93,630,518
45,716,005
16,017,640
2,462,478
17,976,241
41,853,060
121,283,535
49,647,270
20,556,275
1940 Source:
Begroting Nederlandsch-Indië. Appendix to the Handelingen van de Tweede Kamer der Staten Generaal, various issues. i = Government and High Colleges vii = Department of Civil Public Works ii = Department of Justice viii = Department of Government Industries iii = Department of Finance ix = Department of War iv = Department of Civil Services x = Navy Department v = Department of Education and Cults xi = Local government vi = Department of Agriculture, Industry and Commerce a: In 1935 the Department of Civil Public Works was merged with the Department of War.
288
| Accounting for Services
vii
viii
ix
x
xi
1908
25,977,160
19,340,691
26,963,362
4,961,027
4,235,723
1909
27,332,416
19,301,966
27,117,438
5,645,944
4,594,938
1910
16,932,266
37,720,184
27,957,789
6,289,702
4,478,162
1911
22,408,444
45,520,758
29,591,237
8,433,736
4,503,492
1912
30,158,736
54,027,587
29,949,228
11,389,950
5,454,673
1913
32,480,470
55,517,795
31,637,108
11,794,667
5,390,288
1914
37,678,122
64,045,690
32,836,752
13,784,494
5,687,453
1915
42,372,812
72,844,946
34,520,411
14,049,685
7,931,876
1916
39,946,040
70,202,545
32,949,199
15,045,005
10,130,974
1917
47,350,217
78,174,900
33,980,590
17,034,535
11,682,319
1918
51,580,499
85,756,608
37,699,322
18,678,715
12,672,019
1919
60,208,770
100,078,267
52,683,511
20,972,810
14,530,543
1920
70,425,032
117,025,985
55,787,807
22,792,540
16,608,333
1921
100,936,861
162,375,405
65,137,600
31,490,225
19,807,129
1922
106,784,668
181,589,276
73,015,337
30,414,780
22,257,467
1923
81,848,051
168,442,413
66,378,566
30,261,848
20,517,106
1924
60,703,570
151,501,122
61,697,201
28,599,545
18,031,205
1925
49,520,110
139,745,195
57,665,696
27,988,810
1926
45,712,984
138,296,611
63,098,623
30,019,084
1927
51,165,246
136,327,928
66,179,147
33,141,375
1928
58,628,291
137,780,502
71,674,165
34,370,140
1929
60,949,585
141,487,287
75,062,057
38,317,115
1930
60,500,965
143,870,930
76,936,995
39,709,476
1931
58,437,040
143,516,745
76,512,340
34,992,860
1932
49,619,836
73,805,350
77,499,100
40,166,845
1933
26,074,543
70,859,736
64,447,000
19,207,440
1934
17,486,520
50,363,924
58,530,800
23,007,050
1935
51,004,636a
47,823,600
22,032,240
1936
52,397,656
46,563,600
23,476,215 27,400,639
1937
42,773,057
48,333,200
1938
51,049,479
61,209,000
34,658,165
1939
57,504,122
75,467,100
40,874,655
1940
58,383,937
104,952,900
35,359,539
289
| Appendix 3
The available data allow for a consistent estimation of value added in government services. From the budgets the expenditure on personnel is taken and this is augmented with 5 per cent depreciation. The expenditure on personnel was estimated to be, on average, 34.5 per cent of the budget for the period 1900-1940 and 39.3 per cent on average for the period 1950-2000. The results are summarised in appendix table A3.12.
Notes for table A3.12 (1) = (2) = (3) = (4) = (5) =
Routine expenditures (million fl/Rp) Personnel expenditure as % of total routine expenditures Value added in current prices = ((1) * (2)) + ((1) * (2) * 5 % depreciation) cpi (1993 = 100) (Van Leeuwen 2007) Value added in constant prices (million fl/Rp) = (3)/(5) * 100
Table A3.12 Value added by government services, 1900-2000 (1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
1900
117
42.4
0.010
436,546
1901
119
43.1
0.012
357,590
1902
125
45.4
0.011
406,094
1903
130
47.3
0.012
404,321
1904
132
47.9
0.010
457,888 463,543
1905
129
46.8
0.010
1906
130
47.0
0.011
439,358
1907
137
49.6
0.012
409,930
1908
148
53.5
0.013
419,481
1909
156
56.4
0.012
471,567
1910
170
61.7
0.012
515,270
34.5%
1911
197
71.5
0.013
542,730
1912
223
80.9
0.015
532,472
1913
235
85.3
0.014
614,154
1914
262
94.9
0.013
704,695
1915
286
103.6
0.013
786,183
1916
289
104.8
0.014
737,433
1917
318
115.3
0.015
759,128
1918
343
124.3
0.019
639,020
1919
399
144.6
0.019
742,019
1920
457
165.6
0.032
522,612
1921
597
216.3
0.027
813,390
1922
701
29.5%
253.9
0.023
1,097,183
1923
624
33.3%
226.0
0.021
1,091,209
1924
562
35.6%
203.5
0.019
1,066,925
1925
528
36.6%
191.1
0.018
1,051,135
290
| Accounting for Services
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
1926
546
37.1%
197.7
0.018
1,089,971
1927
579
36.3%
209.8
0.018
1,196,979
1928
593
35.1%
214.8
0.017
1,248,549
1929
642
36.3%
232.6
0.017
1,359,749
1930
679
36.4%
246.0
0.017
1,474,407
1931
659
37.1%
238.8
0.015
1,601,154
1932
475
172.1
0.012
1,378,752
1933
361
130.9
0.011
1,186,852
1934
399
144.4
0.010
1,423,283
1935
346
125.2
0.010
1,288,105
1936
291
105.4
0.009
1,121,859
1937
275
99.5
0.010
990,388
1938
350
126.9
0.010
1,233,720
1939
393
142.4
0.013
1,065,237
1940
452
163.9
0.011
1,524,593
1941
0.012
1942
0.017
1943
0.016
1944
0.024
1945
0.033
1946
0.058
1947
0.082
1948
0.106
1949
0.130
1950
8,726
3,601
0.152
1951
10,625
4,384
0.254
2,363,023 1,725,474
1952
15,025
6,200
0.268
2,312,447
1953
15,659
6,461
0.285
2,267,934
1954
13,391
5,526
0.303
1,825,086
1955
16,317
6,733
0.401
1,679,367
1956
20,015
8,259
0.459
1,798,912
1957
25,610
10,568
0.504
2,097,045
1958
35,313
14,572
0.734
1,985,966
1959
44,350
18,301
0.887
2,063,010
1960
60,544
24,983
1.09
2,286,415
1961
88,522
36,529
1.50
2,442,055
1962
122,078
50,375
4.16
1,210,882
1963
329,800
136,092
9.30
1,463,025
1964
681,330
281,151
19.73
1,425,277
1965
2,526,320
1,042,486
79.84
1,305,734
291
| Appendix 3
(1) 1966
(2)
29,433
(3)
(4)
(5)
12,146
0.93
1,299,148
1967
87,555
36,130
2.48
1,458,342
1968
185,283
76,457
5.56
1,374,494 1,275,981
1969
82,906
6.50
1970
216,540
48.0%
89,355
7.34
1,217,567
1971
288,170
45.6%
118,913
7.62
1,560,686
1972
349,090
46.8%
144,052
8.13
1,771,097
1973
438,100
45.7%
180,782
10.66
1,696,261
1974
713,300
37.7%
1,961,650
294,343
15.00
1975
420,394
17.86
2,354,321
1976
546,445
21.41
2,552,427
1977
1,629,700
39.1%
672,496
23.75
2,832,032
1978
2,148,900
41.6%
886,744
25.66
3,455,398
1979
2,743,700
36.5%
1,132,188
30.90
3,664,286
1980
4,061,800
35.0%
1,676,102
35.67
4,699,463 6,176,290
1981
5,800,000
34.9%
2,393,370
38.75
1982
6,977,600
32.6%
2,879,307
42.21
6,821,385
1983
6,996,300
34.6%
2,887,023
46.74
6,176,219
1984
8,411,800
32.8%
3,471,129
51.63
6,723,359
1985
9,433,900
32.3%
3,892,899
54.03
7,204,935 8,620,602
1986
11,951,500
52.4%
4,931,786
57.21
1987
13,559,000
49.6%
5,595,121
62.48
8,954,971
1988
17,482,000
41.2%
7,213,947
67.52
10,684,262
1989
20,739,000
37.5%
8,557,948
71.86
11,909,119
1990
24,331,000
39.2%
10,040,187
77.52
12,951,841
1991
29,998,000
36.7%
12,378,675
84.73
14,609,781
1992
30,227,000
41.8%
12,473,172
91.09
13,693,950
1993
33,605,000
43.3%
13,867,103
100
13,867,103
1994
40,290,000
44.0%
16,625,669
108.45
15,330,316
1995
43,179,000
45.9%
17,817,814
118.76
15,003,251
1996
50,435,000
41.3%
20,812,003
128.06
16,251,503
1997
62,561,000
37.3%
25,815,797
136.59
18,900,328
1998
89,610,000
31.0%
36,977,567
215.58
17,152,485
1999
147,717,000
25.7%
60,955,420
259.77
23,465,381
2000
166,881,000
31.2%
68,863,445
269.38
25,563,696
292
| Accounting for Services
Appendix 4
National Accounting for Housing
In the sna the contribution of house property to national income is taken as equivalent to the net rental income of dwellings. No distinction is made between owneroccupied houses and rented houses. The rental value of shops and other industrial buildings is not counted as housing, but as part of the product of the respective industries. Data on the number of houses can be obtained from the population censuses. These give us the average size of a household. Combining these with population estimates gives a time-series of the number of houses. Unfortunately, we only have fragmentary information on rents, which makes it impossible to construct timeseries. A source that provides some information on housing rents is a survey by the Centraal Kantoor van de Statistiek (cks) in 1928 on 314 urban households. The relevant results are presented in table A4.1.
Table A4.1 Monthly expenditure on rent, August 1925 Income class
Number of families
Average expenditure
On rent
A (2400) Total Source: cks (1928).
In 1939 cks published a study on 95 labourer households in Jakarta. This survey revealed that rents for these labourers, which can be classified as largely unskilled labourers, varied between 0.50 and 5.00 guilders (cks 1939: 12).
293
| Appendix 4
Ibrahim and Weinreb (1957) conducted a study on living expenditures in Jakarta in 1953. In a sample of 250 urban households they found an average rent for civil servants of Rp 16.00, for a labourer of Rp 9.70 and for a trader Rp 1.40 (see table A4.3). Moreover in a recent paper by Colombijn and Barwegen (2005) give some detailed information on rents in Indonesian cities between 1930 and 1960. Their findings can be found in table A4.2. They found that cheap houses without brick walls, sometimes referred to as ‘indigenous houses’, had rents up to 20-30 guilders. Very cheap houses in Medan, Bandung, Semarang, Malang and Surabaya brought in between 1.00 and 6.00 guilders. Dwellings of 1.00 and 2.00 guilders were usually meant for single coolies. Rents for middle-class residents were in the range of 20-80 guilders. Upper-class houses were 80 or more guilders. Table A4.2 Monthly rents, 1930-1960 Monthly rent Dataset
n
0-10
10-30
30-50
50-80 80-120
Batavia, housing agency niva, 1934
127
-
7.1
29.9
40.2
Surabaya, housing agency Van Vloten, 1935
20.5
>120 2.4
908
0.3
13.4
31.9
32.6
16.3
5.4
Surabaya, Soerabaiasch Handelsblad, 1930-1940
91
-
3.3
9.9
16.5
17.6
52.7
Makassar, Makasaarsche Courant, 1930-1940
27
-
11.1
33.3
29.6
25.9
-
Medan, Deli Courant, 1930-1940
31
-
9.7
25.8
35.5
29.0
Medan, municipal houses, 1948
525
71.4
20.2
4.2
3.0
0.8
0.4
Bandung, settlement permits, 1946-1949
102
35.3
32.4
15.7
5.9
9.8
0.7
Bandung, settlement permits, 1950-1960
136
35.3
12.5
36.8
8.1
5.9
1.5
Note: Figures give percentages. Monthly rent is given in Netherlands-Indies guilders and Indonesian rupiahs. Source: Colombijn & Barwegen (2005).
Table A4.3 Monthly expenditure per family in Jakarta, 1953 Civil servant
Labourer
Rp.
% of total
Rp.
Food
353.35
69.75%
- Rice
128.30
25.33%
Trader
% of total
Rp.
% of total
324.62
75.68%
393.17
78.08%
148.67
34.66%
145.1
28.82%
- Meat
18.57
3.67%
18.15
4.23%
36.09
7.17%
- Fish
22.78
4.50%
18.98
4.42%
28.58
5.68%
- Dried fish
13.68
2.70%
14.22
3.31%
10.63
2.11%
- Eggs
6.02
1.19%
1.85
0.43%
3.01
0.60%
- Cassava
5.04
0.99%
3.29
0.77%
2.15
0.43%
- Wheat
18.50
3.65%
14.39
3.35%
16.37
3.25%
- Vegetables
23.79
4.70%
22.13
5.16%
22.09
4.39%
- Fruit
10.92
2.16%
4.03
0.94%
4.60
0.91%
- Spices
21.49
4.24%
19.96
4.65%
22.92
4.55%
294
| Accounting for Services
Civil servant
Labourer
Trader
Rp.
% of total
Rp.
% of total
Rp.
- Oil
14.87
2.94%
12.18
2.84%
25.25
5.01%
- Beverages
33.81
6.67%
17.03
3.97%
30.42
6.04%
- Sweets
35.58
7.02%
29.74
6.93%
45.96
9.13%
Heating, light and water
43.49
8.59%
34.03
7.93%
38.93
7.73%
- For the kitchen
39.10
7.72%
31.05
7.24%
33.14
6.58%
- Light and water
4.39
0.87%
2.98
0.69%
5.79
1.15%
23.46
4.63%
16.05
3.74%
22.34
4.44%
- For male
4.84
0.96%
2.19
0.51%
0.74
0.15%
- For female
1.62
0.32%
1.80
0.42%
1.00
0.20%
- For children
0.81
0.16%
1.69
0.39%
5.56
1.10%
Drugstore products
16.19
3.20%
10.37
2.42%
15.04
2.99%
Housing and furniture
18.65
3.68%
11.53
2.69%
3.23
0.64%
- Rent
0.28%
Clothing and drugstore products
% of total
16.00
3.16%
9.70
2.26%
1.40
- Furniture
1.52
0.30%
1.18
0.28%
0.68
0.14%
- Kitchenware
1.13
0.22%
0.65
0.15%
1.15
0.23%
Other expenditures
65.88
13.01%
40.16
9.36%
45.88
9.11%
- Health
7.34
1.45%
4.82
1.12%
2.68
0.53%
- Education
2.46
0.49%
2.50
0.58%
0.61
0.12%
- Car
6.53
1.29%
2.85
0.66%
11.52
2.29%
- Recreation/sports
1.82
0.36%
0.47
0.11%
2.88
0.57% 5.40%
- Leisure
42.55
8.40%
26.77
6.24%
27.21
- Taxes
5.18
1.02%
2.75
0.64%
0.98
0.19%
Durable goods
1.74
0.34%
2.57
0.60%
0
0.00%
506.57
100 %
428.96
100 %
503.55
100 %
Total
Source: Ibrahim and Weinreb, 1957: 779.
Because the information on rents is limited I chose to estimate value added in the housing sector for a base year, namely 1930. For the years 1975, 1980, 1985, 1990, 1995 and 2000 I relied on estimates from the i-o tables. Gross value added in constant prices is obtained by using the number of housing units as extrapolator, while gross value added at current prices was estimated by inflating the gross value added at constant prics using the housing component of the cpi as an inflator.
295
| Appendix 4
Notes for table A4.4 (1) = (2) = (3) = (4) = (5) = (6) = (7) = (8) = (9) =
Value added in current prices. Bold indicates estimate is taken from i-o table. The years in between are interpolated based on (4) and inflated by (6) for period 1950-2000, by (5) for period 1925-1940 and by (9) for period 19001924. Population (x 1,000) from Maddison (2003) Average household size from Population censuses. Number of dwellings = (2)/(3) Price index of rents (1930=100) calculated from cks (1935) and cks (1938) Price index of rents (1993 = 100) calculated from (7) Inflation of housing prices from bps (1995) and Statistik Indonesia, various issues. Value added in constant prices = (1)/(6) * 100 cpi (Van Leeuwen 2007)
Table A4.4 Value added by housing, 1900-2000 (1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
(9)
1900
159.58
42,746
9,185
1,641,395
0.010
1901
200.41
43,275
9,298
1,661,708
0.012
1902
187.94
43,810
9,413
1,682,251
0.011
1903
199.03
44,352
9,530
1,703,063
0.012
1904
180.53
44,901
9,648
1,724,144
0.010
1905
176.24
45,457
9,767
1,745,494
0.010
1906
189.04
45,993
9,882
1,766,076
0.011
1907
216.35
46,535
9,999
1,786,888
0.012
1908
230.72
47,085
10,117
1,808,007
0.013
1909
218.93
47,642
10,237
1,829,395
0.012
1910
221.52
48,206
10,358
1,851,052
0.012
1911
246.90
48,778
10,481
1,873,016
0.013
1912
287.94
49,358
10,605
1,895,288
0.015
1913
266.19
49,934
10,729
1,917,405
0.014
1914
261.14
50,517
10,854
1,939,792
0.013
1915
258.69
51,108
10,981
1,962,486
0.013
1916
282.14
51,705
11,109
1,985,410
0.014
1917
303.83
52,083
11,191
1,999,924
0.015
1918
390.78
52,334
11,245
2,009,563
0.019
1919
396.89
53,027
11,394
2,036,173
0.019
1920
653.78
53,723
11,543
2,062,899
0.032
1921
555.25
54,367
11,681
2,087,627
0.027
1922
488.85
55,020
11,822
2,112,702
0.023
1923
442.77
55,683
11,964
2,138,160
0.021
1924
412.68
56,354
12,108
2,163,926
0.019
296
| Accounting for Services
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
(9)
1925
398.25
57,036
12,255
104.66
2,190,114
0.018
1926
423.84
57,727
12,403
110.05
2,336,920
0.018
1927
431.86
58,429
12,554
110.78
2,463,745
0.018
1928
421.64
59,140
12,707
106.86
2,451,073
0.017
1929
402.45
59,863
12,862
100.77
2,352,413
0.017
1930
404.28
60,596
13,020
100.00
2,422,671
0.017
1931
396.96
61,496
13,213
96.75
2,662,085
0.015
1932
369.57
62,400
13,407
88.77
2,961,090
0.012
1933
332.12
63,314
13,604
78.62
3,010,679
0.011
1934
284.05
64,246
13,804
66.27
2,800,446
0.010
1935
314.30
65,192
14,007
72.26
3,232,802
0.010
1936
325.67
66,154
14,214
73.79
3,466,090
0.009
1937
356.45
67,136
14,425
79.58
3,546,745
0.010
1938
364.55
68,131
14,639
80.20
3,545,111
0.010
1939
377.43
69,145
14,857
81.82
2,823,078
0.013
1940
387.37
70,175
15,078
82.74
3,603,115
0.011
1941
71,316
1942
72,475
1943
73,314
1944
73,565
1945
73,332
1946
74,132
1947
75,146
1948
76,289
1949
4.7
77,654
1950
2,341
79,043
17,039
0.0007
1951
3,517
80,525
17,358
0.0007
11.48
1,282,492
1,258,889
1952
4,693
82,052
17,688
0.0007
0.00
1,306,812
1953
5,870
83,611
18,024
0.0007
2.94
1,331,642
1954
7,046
85,196
18,365
0.0008
5.71
1,356,885
1955
8,222
86,807
18,713
0.0008
-1.35
1,382,543
1956
9,398
88,456
19,068
0.0008
2.74
1,408,806
1957
10,575
90,124
19,428
0.0009
13.33
1,435,372
1958
11,751
91,821
19,793
0.0012
35.29
1,462,399
1959
12,927
93,565
20,169
0.0014
18.26
1,490,175
1960
14,103
95,254
20,533
0.0017
20.59
1,517,075 1,546,237
1961
15,280
97,085
20,928
0.0033
90.24
1962
16,456
99,028
21,255
0.0071
112.82
1,577,182
1963
17,632
101,009
21,586
0.0113
59.19
1,608,733
1964
18,808
103,031
21,924
0.03
143.61
1,640,937
1965
19,985
105,093
22,267
0.13
367.34
1,673,777
297
| Appendix 4
4.6
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
1966
21,161
107,197
22,616
1.24
866.34
1,707,287
1967
53,498
109,343
22,971
3.09
148.91
1,734,086
1968
92,153
111,532
23,332
5.23
69.59
1,761,338
1969
105,088
113,765
23,699
5.87
12.27
1,789,052
1970
158,773
116,044
24,073
8.74
48.74
1,817,255
1971
162,842
118,368
24,453
8.82
0.97
1,845,925
1972
169,040
121,282
25,021
8.95
1.45
1,888,796
1973
198,761
124,271
25,603
10.28
14.91
1,932,717
1974
249,681
127,338
26,199
12.62
22.76
1,977,730
1975
338,289
130,485
26,810
16.72
32.40
2,023,863
1976
548,067
133,713
27,436
20.64
23.50
2,654,972
1977
757,845
137,026
28,078
23.34
13.08
3,246,541
1978
967,624
140,425
28,735
24.00
2.80
4,032,308
1979
1,177,402
143,912
29,409
28.09
17.04
4,192,157
1980
1,387,180
147,490
30,100
33.22
18.28
4,175,749
1981
1,778,886
150,657
30,999
35.79
7.74
4,970,186
1982
2,170,591
153,894
31,928
40.92
14.33
5,304,475
1983
2,562,297
157,204
32,888
46.20
12.91
5,545,765
1984
2,954,002
160,588
33,879
52.12
12.80
5,668,051
1985
3,345,708
164,047
34,904
55.78
7.03
5,997,985
1986
3,929,018
166,976
35,832
58.34
4.58
6,735,234
1987
4,512,327
169,959
36,788
61.83
5.99
7,298,009
1988
5,095,637
172,999
37,773
64.46
4.25
7,905,443
1989
5,678,946
176,094
38,787
68.41
6.13
8,301,515
1990
6,262,256
179,248
39,833
76.91
12.43
8,142,133
1991
9,626,136
182,223
41,041
82.82
7.68
11,623,164
1992
12,990,017
185,259
42,297
86.60
4.56
15,000,871
1993
16,353,897
188,359
43,602
100
15.48
16,353,897
1994
19,717,777
191,524
44,959
109
9.09
18,074,780
1995
23,081,658
194,755
46,370
115
5.67
20,023,055
1996
24,839,707
198,025
47,832
121
4.72
20,576,911
1997
26,597,757
201,350
49,350
128
6.08
20,770,417
1998
28,355,806 204,390
50,843
189
47.47
15,015,456
1999
30,113,856 207,429
52,381
199
5.23
15,153,862
2000
31,871,905
54,071
219
10.10
14,567,253
298
210,875
4.8
4.9
4.5
3.9
| Accounting for Services
(9)
Appendix 5
National Accounting for Financial Services
According to sna 93, output of financial intermediation companies in banking, insurance services and pension fund services cannot be directly measured since such companies do not normally charge their customers for their services except for some minor incidental services. Banks earn their main source of income by the difference between the interest earned by providing loans and the interest paid on deposits. Pension funds and insurance companies accept contributions and invest them in order to pay their customers. Their output has to be measured indirectly. This has also been done in Indonesia. Firstly value added was estimated for the colonial period. The procedure adopted is the following. For the ‘big four’, namely the Java Bank, nhm, niem and nihb, the financial report of the Java Bank is taken as starting point. Their annual reports are actually available, but they have a number of short-comings: 1) they are often less detailed, 2) it is often hard to sub-divide income in the Netherlands from income in the Netherlands-Indies, and/or 3) it is hard to sub-divide income from banking and income from trade activities. Therefore I chose to use annual reports by the Java Bank, which give a very detailed statement of income and expenditures. Value added of the Java Bank is then divided by the share of credit extension of the Java Bank in total credit extension of the ‘big four’. For the other financial institutions, i.e. the Saving Banks, the Government Pawnshop service and the Government Credit banks, detailed financial accounts are available, which make it possible to estimate value added in a direct way. The data and results are summarised in appendix table A5.1.
299
| Appendix 5
300
| Accounting for Services
123.57
114.76
121.85
136.90
1907
1908
1909
1910
77.88 108.75 114.01 157.14
226.02
315.23
330.46
455.48
613.22
734.44
621.73
1915
1916
1917
1918
1919
1920
1921
75.45
199.64
270.63
209.43
86.77
189.31
204.39
1914
73.66
68.92
63.37
53.97
49.61
47.24
42.72
35.64
1913
163.10
118.84
1906
178.07
94.54
1905
1912
85.85
1904
1911
33.31
74.40
1903 32.90
31.59
27.26
67.65
65.48
1902
31.59
(2)
Credit extension by Java Bank
1901
69.01
(1)
Total credit extension
32.1%
36.8%
34.2%
34.5%
34.5%
34.5%
34.5%
42.5%
39.9%
41.4%
42.3%
46.3%
44.3%
43.2%
38.2%
35.9%
37.7%
38.3%
44.8%
48.2%
40.3%
45.8%
(3)= (2)/(1)
27.00 26.72
8.58
21.35
16.78
11.60
11.33
10.31
8.40
8.24
7.12
6.35
5.80
4.72
4.35
6.56
5.80
3.54
3.20
2.83
2.57
2.74
2.54
(5)= (4)/(3)
9.95
7.29
5.79
4.00
3.91
3.55
3.57
3.28
2.95
2.68
2.68
2.09
1.88
2.51
2.09
1.34
1.23
1.27
1.24
1.11
1.16
(4)
Credit extension of Value added of Java Value added big Bank four Java Bank as percentage of total
Value added by the financial sector, 1900-1940 (in millions of guilders)
1900
Table A5.1
0.28
142.53
136.52
114.78
116.90
99.62
83.97
75.90
66.85
51.68
40.28
28.85
20.78
19.78
12.98
13.29
6.76
2.96
2.11
9.27
7.54
12.22
13.32
11.22
9.23
7.10
5.78
4.22
3.00
2.34
1.79
1.44
1.05
0.74
0.65
0.39
0.35
0.31
0.30
1.81 1.69 1.86
(7) 0.28
(6)
Value added of government pawnshop
1.67
Loans by government pawnshop
301
| Appendix 5 80.47 132.35
441.16
1940
82.76
76.66
78.10
92.08
209.30
1935
74.55
73.70
306.95
215.54
1934
270.02
247.08
1933
98.87 185.35
1939
291.75
1932
1938
330.26
1931
161.33 119.76
261.35
387.05
1930
278.76
563.86
1929
144.88
153.34
126.78
133.75
142.45
158.63
1937
571.90
1928
(2) 167.25
1936
542.75
582.97
465.02
1925
1927
487.00
1924
1926
481.54
1923
(1)
477.36
1922
30.0%
30.0%
29.8%
29.7%
29.3%
37.3%
34.6%
29.8%
63.5%
29.9%
30.9%
28.6%
25.3%
26.3%
23.4%
28.8%
29.3%
32.9%
35.0%
(3)= (2)/(1)
(4)
3.28
4.08
3.10
3.72
3.40
3.06
2.81
3.26
3.01
2.72
5.51
8.10
7.93
7.03
8.11
11.68
7.68
8.60
7.21
10.92
13.59
10.39
12.54
11.60
8.19
8.14
10.92
4.73
9.08
17.81
28.32
31.29
26.74
34.72
40.62
26.26
26.10
20.59
(5)= (4)/(3)
(6)
88.19
86.80
85.31
75.30
65.41
67.52
69.58
78.12
109.77
153.12
194.14
207.02
181.46
173.89
169.89
166.25
151.04
150.52
151.91
(7)
7.94
7.81
9.30
6.72
6.03
7.44
6.57
6.95
10.02
13.63
19.11
20.36
16.91
18.80
19.18
18.57
15.47
11.83
11.41
302
| Accounting for Services
7.21
7.23
1906
1907
19.86
1922
13.94
1919
19.25
13.45
1918
19.95
12.38
1917
1921
11.37
1916
1920
9.53
10.71
1913
1915
10.30
1912
1914
9.18
9.62
1911
8.47
6.71
1905
1910
6.03
1904
7.21
4.87
7.80
4.00
1902
1903
1909
3.46
1908
2.89
1901
(8)
Loans by Post Office Savings Banks
Continued
1900
Table A5.1
0.48
0.46
0.29
0.22
0.19
0.15
0.12
0.13
0.12
0.10
0.09
0.06
0.07
0.05
0.05
0.07
0.07
0.06
0.05
0.04
0.03
0.03
0.02
(9)
Value added of Post Office Savings Bank
0.44 0.47 0.58
6.70 7.27 8.92
46.06
47.54
39.36
30.12
28.95
20.80
27.77
21.68
18.84
15.68
11.98
4.67
3.84
2.64
2.47
2.31
2.35
1.80
1.50
1.24
0.96
0.78
0.57
0.66
10.09
8.85
0.35 0.58
5.45 8.92
0.32
(11)
Value added of Government credit system
4.92
(10)
Loans by Government credit system
37.14
40.29
37.47
36.26
32.59
25.32
22.48
19.05
15.55
13.52
10.99
9.32
8.24
6.69
5.89
8.03
7.09
4.35
3.92
3.18
2.88
3.07
2.84
(12)= 5)+(7)+(9)+(11)
Total value added of financial sector
685.89
825.04
902.51
773.69
596.43
446.61
429.60
324.08
285.22
254.89
228.08
201.20
173.40
149.31
141.98
147.63
137.43
108.13
97.50
80.09
70.75
72.21
55.01
(13)= (1)+(6)+(8)+(10)
Total credit extension
303
| Appendix 5
42.88
52.93
54.41
50.61
1936
1937
1938
1939
1940
0.35
0.47
0.39
0.56
0.66
0.63
0.51
0.55
0.56
0.49
0.50
0.52
0.48
0.48
0.48
0.48
0.50
0.50
(9)
30.00
30.90
26.67
21.68
19.39
17.40
22.66 24.96 22.20
2.58 3.00
21.86
20.19
18.51
17.83
20.68
18.96
28.24
42.93
54.82
54.07
51.22
59.36
64.27
46.73
42.68
(12)= 5)+(7)+(9)+(11)
3.09
2.04
1.91
2.25
2.25 2.60
17.45
3.64
5.04
5.51
5.63
5.39
5.19
4.99
4.61
4.51
4.25
(11)
17.43
24.83
50.72
72.40
74.87
68.30
63.29
56.31
52.38
46.87
43.24
(10)
612.37
476.08
414.86
402.68
383.97
331.07
342.92
403.91
496.99
599.43
689.18
842.12
834.77
835.65
784.27
687.10
703.49
696.55
(13)= (1)+(6)+(8)+(10)
Sources: Total credit extension: cei vi 1980: table 5; Credit extension and value added of Java Bank: annual reports, various issues; Government Pawnshops: Verslag van den gouvernements-pandhuisdienst; Post Office savings bank: Verslag omtrent den dienst der Postspaarbank in Nederlandsch Indie; Government credit system: Verslag van het Volkscredietwezen. Note: In bold: interpolated and extrapolated values. For the period since independence we have to rely on the i-o tables (table A5.2). The intermediary years are extrapolated by weighting total credit extension and inflating by the consumer price index. These results of this exercise are presented in appendix table A5.3.
35.71
36.83
1935
31.84
34.79
1934
29.60
1932
1933
24.31
27.29
22.71
1929
1931
21.93
1928
1930
19.50
20.68
1925
1926
18.97
1924
1927
19.10
18.66
1923
(8)
Table A5.2 Financial sector in Indonesia’s i-o tables, 1971-2000 (in million Rp) Banking & other financial institutions
304
Insurance
Total financial sector
1971
33,935
5,962
39,897
1975
200,273
30,548
230,821
1980
683,726
81,426
765,152
1985
2,177,482
199,330
2,376,812
1990
7,774,956
632,622
8,407,578
1995
22,398,417
1,492,002
23,890,419
2000
58,183,452
6,130,327
64,313,779
Table A5.3 Value added of financial sector, 1900-2000 (in millions of fl/Rp) Total value added in current prices
Total credit extension
cpi, 1993=100
Value added in constant (1993) prices
1900
2.84
55.01
0.010
29,234.65
1901
3.07
72.21
0.012
25,481.42
1902
2.88
70.75
0.011
25,817.19
1903
3.18
80.09
0.012
27,174.80
1904
3.92
97.50
0.010
37,449.38
1905
4.35
108.13
0.010
43,050.96
1906
7.09
137.43
0.011
66,271.18
1907
8.03
147.63
0.012
66,293.18
1908
5.89
141.98
0.013
46,133.36
1909
6.69
149.31
0.012
55,866.98
1910
8.24
173.40
0.012
68,884.40
1911
9.32
201.20
0.013
70,690.88
1912
10.99
228.08
0.015
72,330.10
1913
13.52
254.89
0.014
97,401.59
1914
15.55
285.22
0.013
115,480.63
1915
19.05
324.08
0.013
144,511.78
1916
22.48
429.60
0.014
158,173.28
1917
25.32
446.61
0.015
166,687.35
1918
32.59
596.43
0.019
167,611.65
1919
36.26
773.69
0.019
186,021.93
1920
37.47
902.51
0.032
118,217.22
1921
40.29
825.04
0.027
151,473.99
1922
37.14
685.89
0.023
160,528.18
1923
42.68
696.55
0.021
206,097.05
1924
46.73
703.49
0.019
245,018.23
1925
64.27
687.10
0.018
353,438.64
| Accounting for Services
Total value added in current prices
Total credit extension
59.36
784.27
0.018
327,288.63
1926
cpi, 1993=100
Value added in constant (1993) prices
1927
51.22
835.65
0.018
292,201.05
1928
54.07
834.77
0.017
314,310.89
1929
54.82
842.12
0.017
320,454.79
1930
42.93
689.18
0.017
257,266.72
1931
28.24
599.43
0.015
189,371.38
1932
18.96
496.99
0.012
151,881.08
1933
20.68
403.91
0.011
187,419.90
1934
17.83
342.92
0.010
175,740.51
1935
18.51
331.07
0.010
190,363.42
1936
20.19
383.97
0.009
214,899.25
1937
21.86
402.68
0.010
217,468.93
1938
22.66
414.86
0.010
220,366.01
1939
24.96
476.08
0.013
186,719.82
1940
22.20
612.37
0.011
206,534.85
1951
173
2.152
0,254
68.210,72
1941 1942 ..... 1949 1950
305
1952
197
2.445
0,268
73.444,54
1953
193
2,394
0.285
67,676.70
1954
228
2,826
0.303
75,185.32
1955
324
4,017
0.401
80,702.64
1956
390
4,842
0.459
84,940.34
1957
364
4,521
0.504
72,254.37
1958
533
6,620
0.734
72,665.79
1959
913
11,334
0.887
102,896.98
1960
1,224
15,203
1.09
112,062.27
1961
2,313
28,716
1.50
154,619.07
1962
3,540
43,956
4.16
85,097.58
1963
6,750
83,814
9.30
72,569.23
1964
17,998
223,467
19.73
91,241.00
1965
80,326
997,327
79.84
100,609.45
1966
511
6,342
0.93
54,636.78
1967
2,513
31,196
2.48
101,417.30
| Appendix 5
Total value added in current prices 1968
Total credit extension
cpi, 1993=100
Value added in constant (1993) prices
10,209
126,755
5.56
183,530.06
1969
19,767
245,434
6.50
304,234.85
1970
29,184
362,352
7.34
397,667.51
1971
39,897
495,363
7.62
523,630.66
1972
52,971
657,692
8.13
651,271.95
1973
80,911
1,004,590
10.66
759,177.03
1974
111,948
1,389,954
15.00
746,078.39
1975
230,821
2,750,000
17.86
1,292,660.11
1976
299,312
3,566,000
21.41
1,398,076.36
1977
330,452
3,937,000
23.75
1,391,607.39
1978
452,745
5,394,000
25.66
1,764,223.61
1979
526,104
6,268,000
30.90
1,702,717.32
1980
765,152
7,880,000
35.67
2,145,337.24
1981
986,444
10,159,000
38.75
2,545,600.95
1982
1,264,443
13,022,000
42.21
2,995,600.15
1983
1,485,541
15,299,000
46.74
3,178,022.28
1984
1,826,752
18,813,000
51.63
3,538,303.15
1985
2,376,812
22,157,000
54.03
4,398,977.71
1986
2,832,179
26,402,000
57.21
4,950,556.78
1987
3,524,079
32,852,000
62.48
5,640,276.02
1988
4,720,048
44,001,000
67.52
6,990,656.69
1989
6,823,103
63,606,000
71.86
9,494,933.63
1990
8,407,578
97,696,000
77.52
10,845,775.60
1991
9,776,942
113,608,000
84.73
11,539,117.15
1992
10,644,498
123,689,000
91.09
11,686,300.27
1993
12,932,107
150,271,000
100
12,932,107.29
1994
16,254,743
188,880,000
108.45
14,988,290.04
1995
23,890,419
234,611,000
118.76
20,116,605.95
1996
29,828,122
292,921,000
128.06
23,291,935.01
1997
38,505,354
378,134,000
136.59
28,190,639.55
1998
49,634,550
487,426,000
215.58
23,023,577.52
1999
22,925,275
225,133,000
259.77
8,825,307.28
2000
27,392,248
269,000,000
269.38
23,874,755.34
Notes: in bold: estimate of Input-Output table. Intermediary years interpolated based on total credit extension.
306
| Accounting for Services
Appendix 6
National Accounting for Other Services
The category ‘other services’ are those for which income is difficult to measure on an annual basis due to lack of useful data. Those services are the catering services, the so-called social and community services, such as medical services, education, and entertainment, and the other services, such as domestic servants. A very crude estimation procedure for this is assuming that the category ‘other services’ makes up 20 per cent of total value added in services. This is based on information from the i-o tables, which shows that on average this category indeed was roughly 20 per cent of total value added in services (see table A6.1). Table A6.1 Other services in the i-o tables
1971
va other services (1) 282,432
Total va (2) 4,270,399
Total service va (3) 1,713,109
(1)/(2)
(1)/(3)
6.6%
16.5%
1975
894,419
13,694,242
4,816,366
6.5%
18.6%
1980
3,436,021
48,330,072
16,199,908
7.1%
21.2%
1985
8,287,882
97,645,877
38,824,139
8.5%
21.3%
1990
18,521,224
207,801,303
84,383,984
8.9%
21.9%
1995
50,377,773
535,564,814
232,727,515
9.4%
21.6%
2000 99,748,684 Source: i-o tables
1,366,500,301
511,411,697
7.3%
19.5%
A different procedure can be followed as well. From the different population censuses information was taken on the number of people working in 1) hotels and restaurants, 2) community services, and 3) other services. It is assumed that those working in sub-category 1) and 3) hardly earn more than a labourer and this wage is taken from Van Leeuwen (2007: 240-242). In sub-category 2) most people are probably rather well-educated since surgeons, teachers, etc. are part of this. Therefore it is assumed that those earn the wage of a craftsman, also taken from Van Leeuwen (2007: 240-242). This gives the benchmark estimates presented in table A6.2. These benchmark estimates are interpolated based on both government and private expenditure on education taken from Van Leeuwen (2007: 240-242). Constant price estimates are obtained by deflation using the cpi from Van Leeuwen (2007). The results of this are presented in appendix table A6.3.
307
| Appenix 6
308
| Accounting for Services 99.54
Yearly income (in million fl/Rp)
21,829
42.02
9.70
1,878,199
1975
219,034
406.13
87.81
2,455,954
877,188
1,282,011
1980
1,340,042
847.78
642.26
3,581,832
1,200,927
1,353,099
1985
3,293,699
1,517.83
1,323.24
4,125,191
2,875,664
354,753
1990 2,929,112
468,193
6,949,871
4,299.49
1,954.31
363,549
4,200,799
Note: Assuming 320 working days a year. Wage for a labourer in 2000 extrapolated by growth in wage of craftsman
0.41 0.88
Craftsman
1,608,285
Labourer
Current daily wage
Unspecified
990,473
Other services
1,803,413
169,520 394,865
Social and community services
1971 938,491
Hotels and restaurants
1930
Table A6.2 Value added by other services for benchmark years, 1930-2000 1995
17,782,329
7,869.97
4,961.50
253,018
5,526,795
3,102,347
752,435
2000
46,929,120
19,597.58
12,354.99
155,105
4,761,291
3,059,388
2,255,866
309
| Appenix 6
73.33
67.37
69.56
77.55
1923
1924
1925
79.08
1921
1922
55.20
63.06
1920
37.49
1918
1919
34.10
32.96
1915
36.62
28.19
1914
1917
24.92
1913
1916
20.98
1912
14.49
1909
17.27
11.85
1908
19.74
11.14
1907
1911
9.94
1906
1910
9.41
10.13
1905
8.28
1903
1904
7.82
8.66
1902
8.33
1901
1900
Value added in current prices
0.018
0.019
0.021
0.023
0.027
0.032
0.019
0.019
0.015
0.014
0.013
0.013
0.014
0.015
0.013
0.012
0.012
0.013
0.012
0.011
0.010
0.010
0.012
0.011
0.012
0.010
cpi
Table A6.3 Value added by other services, 1900-2000
426,455.9
364,736.5
325,344.1
316,916.2
297,336.8
198,981.7
283,190.9
192,811.1
241,020.2
239,980.4
250,034.8
209,431.5
179,511.8
138,115.4
149,740.0
144,273.7
121,082.2
92,874.7
91,983.0
92,880.2
100,294.2
89,898.0
70,834.7
77,515.8
64,840.6
85,730.1
Value added in constant (1993) prices
40.2
36.8
35.9
39.1
42.5
37.5
30.7
19.5
17.9
16.0
14.9
13.1
11.8
10.5
9.6
8.5
7.7
6.7
6.3
5.2
5.2
4.9
4.7
4.5
4.2
4.2
Government expenditure on education
21.3
18.5
17.6
19.1
20.3
12.6
13.1
10.3
11.2
11.1
11.3
9.3
8.0
6.1
6.1
5.3
3.8
2.7
2.6
2.6
2.9
2.5
1.9
2.4
2.1
2.4
Private expenditure on education
61.6
55.2
53.5
58.2
62.8
50.1
43.8
29.8
29.1
27.1
26.2
22.4
19.8
16.7
15.7
13.7
11.5
9.4
8.8
7.9
8.0
7.5
6.6
6.9
6.2
6.6
Total expenditure on education
310
| Accounting for Services
96.83
0.033 0.058 0.082 0.106 0.130 0.152 0.254
1947
1948
1949
1950
1951
1944
1946
0.024
1943
1945
0.017 0.016
1942
0.012
0.011
0.013
0.010
0.010
0.009
0.010
0.010
0.011
0.012
0.015
0.017
1941
51.20
1940
44.92
1937
45.51
51.62
1936
58.36
56.72
1935
1939
72.76
1934
1938
87.13
96.79
1931
80.76
99.54
1930
1933
0.017
101.99
1929
1932
0.017
97.33
1928
0.018
91.77
0.018
84.84
1927
cpi
1926
Value added in current prices
38,107.2
476,253.3
436,489.5
442,583.4
446,990.8
549,342.1
583,428.7
717,336.9
732,125.3
698,106.2
649,113.3
596,516.9
596,173.2
565,802.4
523,518.6
467,765.9
492
28.7
29.7
24.0
22.3
27.7
30.9
41.6
47.4
51.7
56.6
55.7
54.4
47.6
46.2
44.2
Value added in Government expenditure constant (1993) prices on education
82
12.0
16.6
12.1
13.3
13.3
14.1
16.1
16.8
17.5
20.2
23.4
26.6
29.7
26.7
23.2
Private expenditure on education
573.3
40.7
46.3
36.1
35.7
41.0
45.0
57.8
64.1
69.2
76.9
79.1
81.0
77.3
72.9
67.4
Total expenditure on education
311
| Appenix 6 7.34 7.62
15.00 17.86
14,354.60
18,379.27
21,829.17
29,903.09
47,688.69
81,368.42
219,034.58
304,024.65
361,407.81
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
23.75
21.41
10.66
8.13
6.50
5.56
2.48
3,432.14
0.93
8,727.66
1966
19.73 79.84
1968
1,217.56
1965
9.30
4.16
1.50
1.09
0.887
0.734
0.504
0.459
0.401
0.303
0.285
0.268
cpi
1967
22,303.62
82,509.28
1964
9,413.31
1963
911.66
1960
1,124.11
513.39
1959
3,660.01
351.86
1958
1962
256.36
1957
1961
155.13
207.93
1954
1956
149.79
1953
1955
157.67
148.27
1952
Value added in current prices
1,521,970.4
1,420,089.5
1,226,653.0
542,279.6
447,458.7
367,654.0
286,498.3
250,438.4
220,926.9
156,900.1
138,535.5
130,236.0
103,344.5
113,066.8
101,195.6
87,976.0
75,150.3
83,432.3
57,872.6
47,954.6
50,870.6
45,287.6
38,693.5
49,474.4
52,040.7
58,805.0
Value added in constant (1993) prices
806,943
690,466
511,693
370,684
218,197
137,996
102,139
85,822
62,722
34,724
12,799
4,306
288,482
76,345
29,641
10,377
2,965
2,418
1,952
1,617
1,308
1,057
905
795
796
847
Government expenditure on education
285,754
228,736
150,546
111,090
64,163
39,057
27,109
23,000
22,271
16,951
7,522
2,903
200,047
55,713
26,094
11,293
3,690
2,980
1,087
466
210
175
13
92
82
86
Private expenditure on education
1,092,696.6
919,201.8
662,239.0
481,774.1
282,359.8
177,053.2
129,248.3
108,821.8
84,992.1
51,675.6
20,321.3
7,209.0
488,529.0
132,057.4
55,735.2
21,670.5
6,655.7
5,397.8
3,039.8
2,083.4
1,517.9
1,231.1
918.5
886.9
877.9
933.6
Total expenditure on education
312
| Accounting for Services
25.66 30.90 35.67
449,086.92
633,947.68
1,340,041.82
1,626,902.11
1,734,532.27
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
Note: Bold indicates estimate is taken from i-o table.
269.38
46,929,119.67
2000
215.58 259.77
42,885,171.58
46,135,210.65
1999
136.59
128.06
100
91.09
1998
26,011,105.96
1997
118.76
12,765,892.05
1994
17,782,328.79
10,577,230.17
1993
21,265,507.22
8,768,662.20
1992
1995
108.45
7,698,264.75
1991
1996
77.52 84.73
71.86
5,493,398.90
6,949,870.56
67.52
1990
4,764,795.26
1988
57.21 62.48
1989
3,518,859.31
4,205,392.50
1986
54.03
3,293,699.26
1985
1987
51.63
1984
46.74
2,147,214.77
2,510,307.48
1983
42.21
38.75
cpi
Value added in current prices
17,421,169.6
17,760,197.4
19,892,798.0
19,043,318.1
16,605,632.1
14,973,370.7
11,771,265.6
10,577,230.2
9,626,871.6
9,085,783.6
8,965,333.0
7,644,535.7
7,056,929.8
6,730,715.1
6,150,851.6
6,095,942.6
4,862,307.3
4,593,544.0
4,109,292.3
4,198,356.2
3,757,216.4
2,051,749.6
1,749,969.5
Value added in constant (1993) prices
40,403,550
40,403,550
23,983,014
18,462,585
14,846,084
14,011,160
12,878,625
10,901,046
9,743,961
9,267,557
7,159,726
6,182,745
5,506,876
4,593,088
4,398,050
4,000,473
3,431,713
2,690,478
2,608,353
2,195,746
1,513,545
993,156
Government expenditure on education
24,597,999
25,767,897
21,106,386
13,324,554
12,038,400
10,659,000
7,756,574
5,157,117
4,050,820
3,382,719
2,583,000
2,081,918
1,833,156
1,567,932
1,326,753
1,143,000
1,004,522
849,356
767,794
635,328
476,000
403,161
364,634
Private expenditure on education
66,171,446.5
61,509,935.6
37,307,567.9
30,500,985.1
25,505,083.9
21,767,733.7
18,035,741.5
14,951,865.7
13,126,679.8
11,850,557.0
9,241,644.0
8,015,901.0
7,074,807.6
5,919,840.5
5,541,049.6
5,004,995.3
4,281,069.1
3,458,271.9
3,243,681.3
2,671,745.6
1,916,705.9
1,357,789.6
Total expenditure on education
Appendix 7
Employment and Population
As discussed in chapters 2 and 3, for Indonesia there are a number of sources on labour force statistics. However, due to differences in concepts, procedures and seasonal timing, they lack consistency. Therefore I follow the method employed by Timmer and De Vries (2007) and rely solely on population censuses. Timmer and De Vries use these censuses as benchmarks to which they apply trends from the labour force surveys. These population censuses, which have been held in 1930, 1961, 1971, 1980 and 1990 and 2000, are considered of reasonable quality. The 1905 data are based on a population count in that year. These data have to be treated with caution, since they are believed to be of poor quality in absolute terms resulting in an under-estimation of the number of people in most sectors. For this a correction had to be made. Therefore it was assumed that the labour force participation rate was equal to that in 1930 and 1961, namely 34 per cent, and that the 1905 population count does give a reliable picture of the relative distribution of the labour force across sectors. Or in formula: Labour force participation rate (=34 per cent) x population in 1905 x relative sectoral share of employment in 1905 population count. The resulting time-series of the occupational structure are presented in table A7.1. The size of the population is also given in table A7.1 and is taken from Van der Eng (2002).
An update of Van der Eng’s estimates is available from his website: http://ecocomm.anu. edu.au/people/info.asp?surname=van%20der%20Eng&Firstname=Pierre
313
| Appendix 7
Table A7.1 Number of people employed and population size (in thousands), 1905-2005 Sector:
1905
Agriculture, Mining and Forestry, and Quarrying Fishing
Manufacturing
Public Utilities
Construction
Transport, Wholesale and Retail Storage, and CommuTrade, nication Hotels and Restaurants
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
10,510
(c)
850
(c)
(c)
788
139
14,274
90
2,209
(c)
(c)
1,293
316
1906 1907 1908 1909 1910 1911 1912 1913 1914 1915 1916 1917 1918 1919 1920 1921 1922 1923 1924 1925 1926 1927 1928 1929 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 1940
314
| Accounting for Services
Finance, Insurance, and Real Estate
1905
Community, Social and Personal Services
Government Services
8
9
525
(d)
(d)
Activities not adequately defined
Sectoral Sum
2,643
15,455
1906
Population
45,457 45,993
1907
46,535
1908
47,085
1909
47,642
1910
48,206
1911
48,778
1912
49,358
1913
49,934
1914
50,517
1915
51,108
1916
51,705
1917
52,310
1918
52,334
1919
53,027
1920
53,723
1921
54,367
1922
55,020
1923
55,683
1924
56,354
1925
57,036
1926
57,727
1927
58,429
1928
59,140
1929
59,863
1930
685
(d)
(d)
2,003
20,870
60,596
1931
61,496
1932
62,400
1933
63,314
1934
64,246
1935
65,192
1936
66,154
1937
67,136
1938
68,131
1939
69,145
1940
70,175
315
| Appendix 7
Sector:
Agriculture, Mining and Forestry, and Quarrying Fishing
Transport, Wholesale and Retail Storage, and CommuTrade, nication Hotels and Restaurants
Manufacturing
Public Utilities
Construction
3
4
5
592
2,238
1
2
23,980
89
1,948
(c)
6
7
1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961
702
1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971
25,820
92
3,078
30
759
4,304
945
1972
25,557
123
3,234
30
928
4,657
962
1973
27,230
166
3,401
34
1,032
4,926
1,007
1974
27,529
188
3,605
40
1,187
5,245
1,053
1975
26,833
198
3,695
42
1,275
5,392
1,032
1976
27,386
249
3,698
46
1,265
5,475
1,090
316
| Accounting for Services
Finance, Insurance, and Real Estate
Community, Social and Personal Services
Government Services
Activities not adequately defined
Sectoral Sum
8
9
Population
1941
71,316
1942
72,475
1943
73,314
1944
73,565
1945
73,332
1946
74,132
1947
75,146
1948
76,289
1949
77,654
1950
79,043
1951
80,525
1952
82,052
1953
83,611
1954
85,196
1955
86,807
1956
88,456
1957
90,124
1958
91,821
1959
93,565
1960
95,254
1961
3,140
(d)
(d)
32,689
97,085
1962
99,028
1963
101,009
1964
103,031
1965
105,093
1966
107,197
1967
109,343
1968
111,532
1969
113,765
1970
116,044
1971
114
4,068
(a)
39,210
118,368
1972
138
4,437
(a)
40,066
121,239
1973
154
4,424
(a)
42,375
124,183
1974
174
4,564
(a)
43,584
127,201
1975
193
5,234
(a)
43,894
130,297
1976
204
5,307
(a)
44,720
133,470
317
| Appendix 7
Sector:
Agriculture, Mining and Forestry, and Quarrying Fishing
Manufacturing
Public Utilities
Construction
Transport, Wholesale and Retail Storage, and CommuTrade, nication Hotels and Restaurants
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
27,032
305
3,838
47
1,438
5,670
1,270
1978
27,703
327
4,092
52
1,544
5,868
1,425
1979
28,042
357
4,217
61
1,548
6,269
1,447
1980
28,752
386
4,702
66
1,656
6,717
1,470
1981
29,623
422
4,988
76
1,855
7,277
1,627
1982
29,706
392
4,863
88
1,942
7,555
1,716
1983
30,568
422
4,786
93
2,050
7,702
1,796
1984
31,263
474
5,626
95
1,949
7,731
1,940
1985
31,995
453
6,025
105
1,988
7,977
1,952
1986
32,383
505
6,341
124
2,022
8,475
2,024
1987
32,480
536
6,755
141
2,096
8,919
2,134
1988
33,456
550
7,286
154
2,282
9,555
2,244
1989
34,461
621
7,809
173
2,570
10,422
2,476 2,612
1977
1990
35,375
731
8,191
187
2,895
10,591
1991
34,396
782
8,460
209
3,425
10,939
2,817
1992
35,771
824
8,355
240
3,322
10,623
2,838
1993
33,449
904
9,352
238
3,951
11,970
3,311
1994
31,601
1,026
11,541
253
5,001
13,366
3,815
1995
31,544
1,049
11,505
240
5,169
14,388
4,135
1996
31,486
1,072
11,469
227
5,336
15,410
4,454
1997
29,924
1,242
11,940
323
5,904
16,480
4,675
1998
32,901
934
10,576
205
4,950
16,091
4,693
1999
32,036
1,005
12,260
261
4,800
16,776
4,752
2000
33,954
961
12,394
257
4,916
17,694
5,145
2001
33,176
917
12,867
252
5,394
16,718
5,025 5,279
2002
33,918
875
12,893
247
6,008
17,030
2003
35,929
1,014
12,239
210
5,700
16,508
5,580
2004
33,897
1,433
11,786
316
6,382
18,297
6,192
2005
34,904
1,120
12,406
259
6,209
18,085
6,273
Source: see text. Notes: (a): included in community services; (b): included in manufacturing; (c): included in finance.
318
| Accounting for Services
Finance, Insurance, and Real Estate
Community, Social and Personal Services
Government Services
Activities not adequately defined
Sectoral Sum
Population
8
9
1977
245
5,716
(a)
45,561
136,725 140,062
1978
267
6,022
(a)
47,300
1979
278
6,082
(a)
48,301
143,485
1980
302
7,142
(a)
51,193
146,995 150,134
1981
314
7,575
(a)
53,758
1982
324
7,634
(a)
54,221
153,343
1983
331
7,810
(a)
55,558
156,623
1984
351
7,970
(a)
57,399
159,975
1985
352
8,221
(a)
59,069
163,403
1986
372
8,459
(a)
60,704
166,312
1987
374
8,762
(a)
62,196
169,276
1988
369
9,114
(a)
65,011
172,294
1989
416
9,313
(a)
68,263
175,369
1990
502
9,524
(a)
70,608
178,500
1991
542
10,007
(a)
71,575
181,093
1992
590
10,472
(a)
73,034
183,724
1993
593
11,096
(a)
74,865
186,395
1994
655
11,293
(a)
78,552
189,107
1995
690
11,804
(a)
80,523
191,860
1996
724
12,315
(a)
82,494
194,655
1997
690
13,269
(a)
84,446
197,492
1998
649
13,014
(a)
84,012
200,372 203,296
1999
665
12,836
(a)
85,391
2000
927
10,053
(a)
86,301
206,265
2001
1,184
11,554
(a)
87,088
208,643 211,439
2002
1,041
10,878
(a)
88,169
2003
1,372
10,330
(a)
88,882
214,251
2004
1,181
11,042
(a)
90,525
217,077
2005
1,095
11,106
(a)
91,455
219,898
319
| Appendix 7
320
| Accounting for Services
References
Unpublished sources Algemeen Rijksarchief (ara), The Hague • Deli Spoorweg Maatschappij: ara, inv. 2.20.11 • Nederlandsch-Indische Spoorweg Maatschappij: ara, inv 2.20.10 • Koninklijke Paketvaart Maatschappij: º Uncoded items: ara, inv. 2.20.58.01 º Balances and annual reports: ara, inv. 2.20.59 • Koninklijke Nederlands-Indische Luchtvaart Maatschappij annual reports: º ara, Ministerie van Koloniën, 2.10.46.01, nr. 121-124
Series Bank Indonesia, Annual Report (1953-...). Bank Indonesia, Laporan Mingguan [Weekly Report] (1970-2001) continued as Statistik Ekonomi Moneter Indonesia [Economic and Monetary Statistics of Indonesia] (2001-...). bps, Pendapatan Nasional [National Accounts] (1970-...). bps, Statistical Pocketbook of Indonesia (1956-...). bps, Statistik Indonesia [Statistical Yearbook of Indonesia] (1976-...). bps, Seri Statistik Pengankutan Kereta Api [Railway Transport Statstics] (1961-1972). bps, Statistik Angkutan Kereta Api [Railway Transport Statistics] (1981-1990). bps, Statistik Perhubungan [Transportation and Communication Statistics] (1998-...) bps, Statistik Perhubungan Udara [Air Transport Statistics] (1964-1969). cks, Korte Berichten voor Landbouw, Nijverheid en Handel [Short Reports on Agriculture, Manufacturing and Trade] (1910-1932).
321
| References
cks, Maandcijfers betreffende den Economischen Toestand der Inheemsche Bevolking op Java en Madoera [Monthly Figures about the Economic Conditions of the Indigenous Population in Java and Madura] (1934-1939). cks, Mededeelingen van het Centraal Kantoor voor de Statistiek [Bulletin of the Central Bureau of Statistics], 1920-1940 (181 volumes). cks, Statistisch Zakboekje voor Nederlandsch-Indië [Statistical Pocketbook of the Netherlands Indies] (1934-1941). fao, faoStat. ilo, Yearbook of Labour Statistics (1935-...). Ichtisar Bulan Statistik (1949-1954) continued as Statistik Konjunktur (1954-1963), Warta bps (1966-1969), Indikator Ekonomi (1970-...). Indisch Verslag [Indian Report], (1931-1940). Jaarcijfers voor het Koninkrijk der Nederlanden – Koloniën [Statistical Abstract for the Kingdom of The Netherlands – Colonies] (1880-1921), continued as Statistisch Jaaroverzicht voor Nederlandsch-Indië [Statistical Abstract of the Netherlands Indies] (1922-1930). Jaarverslag der n.v. Deli Spoorweg Maatschappij [Annual Report Deli Spoorweg Maatschappij] (1883-1940). Koloniaal Verslag [Colonial Report] in Bijlagen bij de Handelingen van de Tweede Kamer der StatenGeneraal (1880-1930). Nederlandsch-Indische Luchtreisgids [Air Travel Guide Netherlands Indies] (1929-1934). Statistiek van de Scheepvaart in Nederlandsch-Indië [Shipping Statistics Netherlands Indies] (19101939). United Nations, Review of Maritime Transport (1968-...). Verslag Omtrent den Post- en Telegraafdienst in Nederlandsch-Indië (1876-1907) continued
as Verslag Omtrent den Post-, Telegraaf- en Telefoondienst in Nederlandsch-Indië (1908-1941). Verslag over den Aanleg en de Exploitatie van de Staatsspoorwegen in Nederlandsch-Indië (18871915) continued as Verslag der Staatsspoor- en Tramwegen in Nederlandsch-Indië (1915-1940) [Annual Report State Railways]. Verslag van den President van de Javasche Bank en van den Raad van Commissarissen (1854-1952) [Annual Report Java Bank] Verslag van den Raad van Beheer der NederlandschIndische Spoorweg Maatschappij aan de Algemeene Vergadering van de Aandeelhouders (1869-1929) continued as Verslag n.v. Nederlandsch-Indische Spoorweg Maatschappij (1930-1940) [Annual Report NederlandschIndische Spoorweg Maatschappij]. Verslag van de N.V. Koninklijke Paketvaart Maatschappij (1899-1940) [Annual Report Koninklijke Paketvaart Maatschappij]. Volkstelling 1930, Batavia: Landsdrukkerij, 1931-1936 (8 volumes).
Articles, Books and Papers Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson and J.A. Robinson (2001), ‘The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation’, American Economic Review, Vol. 91, No. 5, pp. 1369-1401. Ahmed, R. and M. Hossain (1990), Development Impact of Rural Infrastructure in Bangladesh, Washington dc: International Food Policy Research Institute. Alexander, C. and J. Wyeth (1994), ‘Cointegration and Market Integration: An Application to the Indonesian Rice Market’, Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 30, No. 2, pp. 303-328. Alexander, J. (1987), Trade, Traders and Trading in Rural Java, Singapore: Oxford University Press. Alexander, J. and A. Booth (1992), ‘The Service Sector’, in: A. Booth (ed.) The Oil Boom and After: Indonesian Economic Policy and Performance in the Soeharto Era, Singapore: Oxford University Press, pp. 283-319. Alexander, J. and P. Alexander (1990), ‘The Invisible Economy: Javanese Commerce in the Late Colonial State’, The Australian Journal of Anthropology, Vol. 1, No. 1, pp. 32-43.
322
| Accounting for Services
Alexander, P., P. Boomgaard and B. White (eds.) (1991), In the Shadow of Agriculture. Non-Farm Activities in the Javanese Economy, Past and Present, Amsterdam: Royal Tropical Institute. Ali, Shamsher (1966), ‘Interisland Shipping’, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. 2, No. 3, pp. 27-51. Anderson, J.R. and J.A. Roumasset (1996), ‘Food Insecurity and Stochastic Aspects of Poverty’, Asian Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 2, No. 1, pp. 53-66. Ark, B. van (1988), ‘The Volume and Price of Indonesian Exports, 1823 to 1940: The LongTerm Trend and its Measurement’, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. 24, No. 3, pp. 87-120. Ark, B. van (1996), ‘Sectoral Growth Accounting and Structural Change in Post-war Europe’, in: B. van Ark and N. Crafts (eds.) Quantitive Aspects of Post-war European Economic Growth, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 84-164. Arminius (H.G. Heyting) (1889), ‘Het Budget van een Javaanschen Landbouwer’ [The Budget of a Javanese Peasant], Indische Gids, Vol. 11, pp. 1685-1720, 1885-1917, 2149-2186. Arndt, H.W., and C. Ross (1970), ‘The New National Income Estimates’, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. 6, No. 3, pp. 33-60. Athukorala, P. and B. Santosa (1997), ‘Gains from Indonesian Export Growth: Do Linkages Matter?’, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. 33, No. 2, pp. 73-95. Baga, M. (1954), ‘Pendapatan Nasional’ [National Income], Buku Peringatan Dies Natalis ke-4, Fakultet Ekonomi, Universitas Indonesia, pp. 26-35. Bakker, C. (1954), ‘Some Remarks about Dr. Neumark’s Estimation of the National Income of Indonesia in 1951 and 1952’, Ekonomi dan Keuangan Indonesia, Vol. 7, pp. 597-602. Barro, R.J. and X. Sala-I-Martin (1995), Economic Growth, London: McGraw-Hill. Basri, M.C. (2001), The Political Economy of Manufacturing Protection in Indonesia 1975-1995, PhD dissertation, anu, Canberra. Baten, J. and J. Wallusch (2003), ‘Market Integration and Disintegration of Poland
and Germany in the 18th Century’, Tübingen Economics Department Working Paper No. 268. Baulch, B. (1997), ‘Transfer Costs, Spatial Arbitrage and Testing for Food Market Integration’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 79, No. 2, pp. 477-487. Baumol, W.J. (1967), ‘Macroeconomics of Unbalanced Growth: The Anatomy of Urban Crisis’, American Economic Review, Vol. 57, No. 3, pp. 415-426. Behrman, J.R. (1984), ‘The Analytics of International Commodity Agreements’, in: C.K. Eicher and J.M. Staatz (eds.) Agricultural Developments in the Third World, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, pp. 241-252. Bell, D. (1973), The Coming of the Post-Industrial Society: A Venture in Social Forecasting, New York: Basic Books. Bertocchi, G. (1994), ‘Colonialism in the Theory of Growth’, Working Paper, Brown University, no. 94-14. Bertocchi, G. and F. Canova (2002), ‘Did Colonization Matter for Growth? An Empirical Exploration into the Historical Causes of Africa’s Underdevelopment’, European Economic Review, Vol. 46, pp. 1851-1871. Bhagwati, J. and T.N. Srinivasan (2002), ‘Trade and Poverty in the Poor Countries’, American Economic Review, Vol. 92, No. 2, pp. 180-183. Bird, K. and C. Manning (2003), ‘Economic Reform, Labour, Markets and Poverty: The Indonesian Experience’, in: K. Sharma (ed.) Trade Policy, Growth and Poverty in Asian Developing Countries, London/New York: Routledge, pp. 74-94. Boeke, J.H. (1953), Economics and Economic Policy of Dual Societies: As Exemplified by Indonesia, Haarlem: Tjeenk Willink. Boediono and Marie Pangestu (1986), ‘Indonesia: The Structure and Causes of Manufacturing Protection’, in: C. Findlay and Ross Garnaut (eds.) The Political Economy of Manufacturing Protection: Experiences of asean and Australia, Sydney: Allen and Unwin, pp. 1-47. Boer, M.G. de and J.C. Westermann (1941), Een Halve Eeuw Paketvaart, 1891-1941 [Half a Century of Packetboat Shipping, 1891-1941], Amsterdam: DeBussy. Booth, A. (1988), ‘The State and Economic Development in Indonesia: The Ethical and
323
| References
New Order Eras Compared’, in: R.J. May and W.J. O’Malley (eds.) Observing Change in Asia: Essays in Honour of J.A.C. Mackie, Bathurst: Crawford House Press, pp. 111-126. Booth, A. (1989), ‘Exports and Growth in the Colonial Economy, 1830-1940’, in: A. Maddison and G. Prince (eds.) Economic Growth in Indonesia, 1820-1940, Dordrecht: Foris Publications, pp. 67-96. Booth, A. (1990), ‘Foreign Trade and Domestic Development in the Colonial Economy’, in: A. Booth, W.J. O’Malley and A. Weidemann (eds.) Indonesian Economic History in the Dutch Colonial Era, New Haven: Yale University Southeast Asia Studies, pp. 267-295. Booth, A. (1998), The Indonesian Economy in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries: A History of Missed Opportunities, London: MacMillan. Booth, A. (1999), ‘The Historical Development of the Indonesian Statistical System’, Asian Historical Statistics Project, Hitotsubashi University, Discussion Paper, D 99-39. Booth, A. (2000), ‘Poverty and Inequality in the Soeharto Era: An Assessment’, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. 36, No. 1, pp. 73-104. Bos, F. (2003), The National Accounts as a Tool for Analysis and Policy; Past, Present and Future, PhD thesis, Twente University, Enschede. bps (1965), Sensus Penduduk 1961, Seri sp2 [Population Census 1961], Jakarta: Biro Pusat Statistik. bps (1966), Pendapatan Nasional Indonesia, 19581962 [National Income of Indonesia, 19581962], Jakarta: Biro Pusat Statistik. bps (1967), Pendapatan Nasional Indonesia, 19601964 [National Income of Indonesia, 19581962], Jakarta: Biro Pusat Statistik. bps (1970), Pendapatan Nasional Indonesia, 19601968 [National Income of Indonesia, 19601968], Jakarta: Biro Pusat Statistik. bps (1973), Sensus Penduduk 1971, Seri D (Population Census 1971], Jakarta: Biro Pusat Statistik. bps (1978), Tabel Input-Output Indonesia, 1975, Jakarta: Biro Pusat Statistik (3 volumes). bps (1982), Hasil Sensus Penduduk 1980, Seri S [Results of the Population Census 1980], Jakarta: Biro Pusat Statistik.
bps (1984), Tabel Input-Output Indonesia, 1980, Jakarta: Biro Pusat Statistik (4 volumes). bps (1989), Tabel Input-Output Indonesia, 1980, Jakarta: Biro Pusat Statistik (2 volumes). bps (1993), Hasil Sensus Penduduk 1990, Seri S [Results of the Population Census 1980], Jakarta: Biro Pusat Statistik. bps (1994), Tabel Input-Output Indonesia, 1990, Jakarta: Biro Pusat Statistik (3 volumes). bps (1995), Statistik Dalam 50 Tahun Indonesia Merdeka [Statistics in 50 Years Independent Indonesia], Jakarta : Biro Pusat Statistik. bps (1998), Tabel Input-Output Indonesia, 1995, Jakarta Biro Pusat Statistik (2 volumes). bps (2003), Tabel Input-Output Indonesia, 2000, Jakarta Biro Pusat Statistik (3 volumes). Braun, J. von, Teklu, T. and P. Webb (1999), Famine in Africa: Causes, Responses, and Prevention, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Broadberry, S. (2007), Market services and the productivity race, 1850-2000: British performance in international perspective, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Broeke, M.C. van den (1920), De Autodiensten Bringin-Toentang-Salatiga en Parakan-WonosoboNgadirejo der nis [Automobile Services of nis in Bringin-Toentang-Salatiga and ParakanWonosobo-Ngadirejo], Batavia. Butzer, R., Y. Mundlak and D.F. Larson (2003), ‘Intersectoral Migration in Southeast Asia: Evidence from Indonesia, Thailand, and the Philippines’, World Bank Policy Research Paper Series No. 2949. Cameron R. (1967), Banking in the Early Stages of Industrialization: A Study in Comparative Economic History, London: Oxford University Press. Cameron, R. (1972), Banking and Economic Development: Some Lessons of History, New York: Oxford University Press. Campo, J.N.F.M. à (1992), Koninklijke Paketvaart Maatschappij: Stoomvaart en staatsvorming in de Indonesische Archipel, 1888-1914 [Translated as: Engines of Empire: Steamshipping and State Formation in Colonial Indonesia (2002)], Hilversum: Verloren. Campo, J.N.F.M. à (1998), ‘Business Not as Usual. Dutch Shipping in Independent Indonesia,
324
| Accounting for Services
1945-1958’, International Journal of Maritime History, Vol. 10, No. 2, pp. 1-39. cei ii (1976), Changing Economy in Indonesia: A Selection of Statistical Source Material From the Early 19th Century Up to 1940, Volume 2: Public Finance 1816-1939 (Inititated by W.M.F. Mansvelt. Re-edited and continued by P. Creutzberg), The Hague: Nijhoff. cei iv (1978), Changing Economy in Indonesia: A Selection of Statistical Source Material From the Early 19th Century Up to 1940, Volume 4: Rice Prices (Initiated by W.M.F. Mansvelt. Re-edited and continued by P. Creutzberg), The Hague: Nijhoff. cei v (1979), Changing Economy in Indonesia: A Selection of Statistical Source Material From the Early 19th Century Up to 1940, Volume 5: National Income (Initiated by W.M.F. Mansvelt. Re-edited and continued by P. Creutzberg), The Hague: Nijhoff. cei vi (1980), Changing Economy in Indonesia: A Selection of Statistical Source Material From the Early 19th Century Up to 1940, Volume 6: Money and Banking 1816-1940 by J. T. M. van Laanen (Edited by P. Creutzberg and J.T.M. van Laanen), Amsterdam: Royal Tropical Institute. cei ix (1989), Changing Economy in Indonesia: A Selection of Statistical Source Material From the Early 19th Century Up to 1940, Volume 9: Transport 1819-1940 by G. J. Knaap (Edited by P. Boomgaard), Amsterdam: Royal Tropical Institute. cei xi (1991), Changing Economy in Indonesia: A Selection of Statistical Source Material From the Early 19th Century Up to 1940, Volume 11: Population Trends 1795-1942 by P. Boomgaard and A. J. Gooszen (Edited by P. Boomgaard), Amsterdam: Royal Tropical Institute. cei xiia (1991), Changing Economy in Indonesia: A Selection of Statistical Source Material From the Early 19th Century Up to 1940, Volume 12a: General Trade Statistics 1822-1940 by W.L. Korthals Altes (Edited by P. Boomgaard), Amsterdam: Royal Tropical Institute. cei xiii (1992), Changing Economy in Indonesia: A Selection of Statistical Source Material From the Early 19th Century Up to 1940, Volume 13: Wages, 1820-1940 by N. Dros (Edited by P. Boomgaard), Amsterdam: Royal Tropical Institute.
cks (1928), ‘Onderzoek naar Gezinsuitgaven in Nederlandsch-Indie gedurende Augustus 1925 en het jaar 1926’ [Study on Household Expenditure in the Netherlands Indies during August 1925 and the year 1926], Mededeelingen van het Centraal Kantoor van de Statistiek, no. 60, Batavia: Landsdrukkerij. cks (1935), Het Verloop der Huishuren in Nederlandsch-Indië in de Periode Januari 1929Januari 1934 [Development of House Rents in the Netherlands-Indies in the Period January 1929–January 1934], Korte Mededeelingen Centraal Kantoor voor de Statistiek No. 5, Batavia: Landsdrukkerij cks (1938), Prijzen, Indexcijfers en Wisselkoersen op Java, 1913-1939 [Prices, Indexnumber and Exchange Rates on Java, 1913-1939], Mededeelingen Centraal Kantoor voor de Statistiek No. 146, Batavia: Landsdrukkerij. cks (1939), ‘Een Onderzoek naar de Levenswijze der Gemeentekoelies te Batavia in 1937’ [A Study on the Lifestyle of Municipal Coolies in Batavia in 1937], Mededeelingen van het Centraal Kantoor van de Statistiek, no. 177, Batavia: Landsdrukkerij. Clark, C. (1940), The Conditions of Economic Progress, London: MacMillan. Colombijn, F. and M. Barwegen (2005), ‘Renting Houses in Indonesian Cities’, in: F. Colombijn (ed.) Kota Lama, Kota Baru: Sejarah Kota-Kota di Indonesia sebelum dan setelah Kemerdekaan, Yogyakarta: Ombak, pp. 521-536. Creightney, C.D. (1993), Transport and Economic Performance: A Survey of Developing Countries, Washington dc: World Bank. Creutzberg, P. (1974), Het Ekonomisch Beleid in Nederlandsch-Indië. Capita Selecta. Een Bronnenpublikatie [Economic Policy in the Netherlands-Indies. Capita Selecta. A Publication of Sources]. Groningen: WoltersNoordhoff. Cribb, R. and C. Brown (1995), Modern Indonesia: A History since 1945, London: Longman. Cummings, R.W. (1967), Pricing Efficiency in the Indian Wheat Market, New Delhi: Impex. Dawe, D. (1996), ‘A New Look at the Effects of Export Instability on Investment and Growth’, World Development, Vol. 24, No. 12, pp. 19051914.
325
| References
Dawe, D. (1997), ‘Should Asia Move to Free Trade in Rice?’, in: C. Silitonga et al. (ed.) 30 Tahun Peran Bulog dalam Ketahanan Pangan, Jakarta: Bulog, pp. 399-424. Dawson, P.J. and P.K. Dey (2002), ‘Testing for the Law of One Price: Rice Market Integration in Bangadesh’, Journal of International Development, Vol. 14, No. 4, pp. 473-484. Department of Communications (1999), Indonesia Transport, Jakarta: Department of Communications. Dercon, S. (1995), ‘On Market Integration and Liberalisation: Method and Application to Ethiopia’, Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 32, No.1, pp. 112-143. Dick, H.W. (1975), ‘Prahu Shipping in Eastern Indonesia, Part i’, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. 11, No. 2, pp. 69-107. Dick, H.W. (1985), ‘Interisland Shipping: Progress, Problems and Prospects’, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. 21, No. 2, pp. 95-114. Dick, H.W. (1987a), The Indonesian Interisland Shipping Industry; An Analysis of Competition and Regulation, Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies. Dick, H.W. (1987b), ‘Prahu Shipping in Eastern Indonesia in the Interwar Period’, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. 23, No. 1, pp. 104-121. Dick, H.W. (2000), ‘Representations of Development in 19th and 20th Century Indonesia’, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. 36, No. 1, pp. 185-207. Dick, H.W. and D. Forbes (1992), ‘Transport and Communications: A Quiet Revolution’, in: Anne Booth (ed.) The Oil Boom and After: Indonesian Economic Policy and the Performance in the Soeharto Era, Singapore: Oxford University Press, pp. 258-282. Dick, H.W., V.J.H. Houben, J.Th. Lindblad and Thee Kian Wie (2002), The Emergence of a National Economy: An Economic History of Indonesia, 1800-2000, Crown West, nsw: Allen & Unwin. Djojosoedarman (1941), ‘Taxi-chauffeurs te Batavia’ [Taxi-drivers in Batavia], Koloniaal Tijdschrift, Vol. 30, pp. 606-632.
Edmundson, W.C. and P.V. Sukhatme (1990), ‘Food and Work: Poverty and Hunger?’, Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 38, No. 2, pp. 263-280. Elfring, T. (1989), ‘New Evidence on the Expansion of Service Employment in Advanced Economies’, Review of Income and Wealth, Vol. 35, No. 4, pp. 409-440. Ellis, F. (1993), ‘Private Trade and Public Role in Staple Food Marketing: The Case of Rice in Indonesia’, Food Policy, Vol. 18, No. 5, pp. 428438. Elson, R.E. (2007), ‘Clifford Geertz, 1926-2006: Meaning, Method and Indonesian Economic History’, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. 43, No. 2, pp. 251-263. Eng, P. van der (1992), ‘The Real Domestic Product of Indonesia, 1880-1989’, Explorations in Economic History, Vol. 29, No. 3, pp. 343-373. Eng, P. van der (1996a), ‘Historical Statistics in Indonesia: Continuity and Change’, Historical Statistics Project, Hitotsubashi University Newsletter, No. 3, pp. 12-15. Eng, P. van der (1996b), Agricultural Growth in Indonesia: Productivity Change and Policy Impact since 1880, London: MacMillan Press. Eng, P. van der (2002), ‘Indonesia’s Growth Performance in the Twentieth Century’, in: A. Maddison, D.S.P. Rao and W.F. Shepherd (eds.) The Asian Economies in the Twentieth Century, Cheltenham/Northampton: Edward Elgar, pp. 143-179. Eng, P. van der (2005), ‘Indonesia’s New National Accounts’, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. 41, No. 2, pp. 243-252. Engle, R.F. and C.W.J. Granger (1987), ‘Cointegration and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation, and Testing’, Econometrica, Vol. 55, No. 2, pp. 251-276. Eswaran, M. and A. Kotwal (2002), ‘The Role of the Service Sector in the Process of Industrialization’, Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 68, No. 2, pp. 401-420. Fabricant, S. (1942), Employment in Manufacturing, 1899-1939, New York: nber. Falvey, R.E. and N. Gemmell (1996), ‘Are Services Income-Elastic? Some New Evidence’, Review of Income and Wealth, Vol. 42, No. 3, pp. 257-269.
326
| Accounting for Services
Fane, G. and T. Condon (1996), ‘Trade Reform in Indonesia, 1987-1995’, Bulletin of Indonesia Economic Studies, Vol. 32, No. 3, pp. 33-54. Fasseur, C. (1978), ‘Some Remarks on the Cultivation System in Java’, Acta Historiae Neerlandicae, Vol. 10, pp. 130-162. Feinstein, C.H. (1972), National Income, Expenditure and Output of the United Kingdom 1855-1965, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Fernando, M.R. (1989), ‘Javanese Peasants and ByEmployment at the Turn of the Century’, in: R.J. May and W.J. O’Malley (eds.) Observing Change in Asia: Essays in Honour of J.A.C. Mackie, Bathurst: Crawford House Press, pp. 155-169. Fisher, A.G.B. (1935), The Clash of Progress and Security, London: MacMillan. Fisher, A.G.B. (1939), ‘Production, Primary, Secondary, and Tertiary’, Economic Record, Vol. 15, pp. 24-38. Fogel, R.W., (1964) Railroads and American Economic Growth: Essays in Econometric History, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press. Fogel, Robert W. (1979), ‘Notes on the Social Saving Controversy’, Journal of Economic History, Vol. 39, No. 1, pp. 1-54. Food and Agriculture Organization (fao) (1991), ‘Demand Prospects for Rice and Other Foodgrains in Selected Asian Countries’, United Nations fao Economic Social Development Paper. Fourastié, J. (1949), Le Grand Espoir du xx Siècle, Paris: Presses Universitaires de France. Frankema, E. (2008), The Historical Evolution of Inequality in Latin America: A Comparative Analysis, 1870-2000, PhD thesis, University of Groningen. Fremdling, R. (1975), Eisenbahnen und Deutsches Wirtschafswachstum, 1840-1879 [Railways and German Economic Development], Dortmund: Gesellschaft für Westfälische Wirtschaftsgeschichte. Fuchs, V.R. (1968), The Service Economy, New York: National Bureau of Economic Research. Fujita, M. (1989), Urban Economic Theory: Land Use and City Size, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Gani, A. and M.D. Clemes (2002), ‘Services and Economic Growth in asean Economies’, asean Economic Bulletin, Vol. 19, No. 2, pp. 155-169.
Garcia Garcia, J. (2000), ‘Indonesia’s Trade and Price Interventions: Pro-Java and Pro-Urban’, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. 36, No. 3, pp. 93-112. Gauthier, H. (1970), ‘Geography, Transportation and Regional Development’, Economic Geography, Vol. 46, pp. 612-619. Geertz, C. (1963), Agricultural Involution: The Process of Ecological Change in Indonesia, Berkeley/Los Angeles: University of California Press. Gershuny, J.I. (1978), After Industrial Society? The Emerging Self-Service Economy, London/ Basingstoke: MacMillan. Gershuny, J.I., and I.D. Miles (1983), The New Service Economy. The Transformation of Employment in Industrial Societies, London: Pinter. Gilbert, E.H. (1969), Marketing of Staple Foods in Northern Nigeria: A Study op Staple Food Marketing Systems Serving Kano City, PhD thesis, Stanford University. Ginkel, H. van (1926), Verslag van den Economischen Toestand der Inlandsche Bevolking in 1924 [Report of the Economic Situation of the Indigenous Population in 1924], Weltevreden: Kolff. Goldenweiser, A. (1936), ‘Loose Ends of Theory on the Individual Pattern, and Involution in Primitive Society’, in: R. Lowie (ed.) Essays in Anthropology Presented to A.L. Kroeber, Berkeley: University of California Press, pp. 99-104. Gonggrijp, G. (1948), De Sociaal-Economische Betekenis van Nederlands-Indië voor Nederland [The Social-Economic Significance of the Netherlands Indies for the Netherlands], Utrecht: Het Spectrum. Gonzales-Rivera, G. and S.M. Helfand (2001), ‘The Extent, Pattern, and Degree of Market Integration: A Multivariate Approach for the Brazilian Rice Market’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 83, No. 3, pp. 576592. Götzen, L. (1933), ‘Volksinkomen en Belasting’ [National Income and Taxation], Koloniale Studiën, Vol. 17, No. 2 pp. 449-484. Graaff, E.A. van de (1955), De Statistiek in Indonesië, [Statistics in Indonesia], ’s-Gravenhage: W. van Hoeve. Granger, C.W. (1981), ‘Some Properties of Times Series Data and Their Use in Econometric
327
| References
Model Specification’, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 16, No. 1, pp. 121-130. Granger, C.W. and C.M. Elliot (1967), ‘A Fresh Look at Wheat Prices and Markets in the Eigteenth Century’, Economic History Review, Vol. 20, No. 2, pp. 257-265. Griliches, Z. (1992), Output Measurement in the Service Sector, Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Haarman, W.C.D. (1930), ‘De Depressie in de Transportbedrijven’ [The Depression in Transportation Companies], Koloniale Studiën, Vol. 14, No. 1, pp. 203-222. Hanson, J.R. (1980), Trade in Transition: Exports from the Third World, 1840-1900, New York: Academic Press. Harriss, B. (1979), ‘There is Method in My Madness: Or Is It Vice-Versa? Measuring Agricultural Market Performance’, Food Research Institute Studies, Vol. 17, pp. 197-218. Hart, H.M. (1932), ‘De Personeelsuitgaven van het Land’ [Expenditure on Government Personnel], Koloniale Studiën, Vol. 16, No. 1, pp. 312-335. Hartwell, R.M. (1973), ‘The Service Revolution: The Growth of Services in Modern Economy’, in: C.M. Cipolla (ed.) The Fontana Economic History of Europe, dl. 3: The Industrial Revolution, London: Fontana/Collins, pp. 358-396. Hasselman, C.J. (1914), Algemeen Overzicht van de Uitkomsten van het Welvaart-Onderzoek Gehouden op Java en Madoera in 1904-1905 [General Overview of the Results of the Prosperity Investigation Held in Java and Madura in 19041905] The Hague: Martinus Nijhoff. Hetler, C.B. (1989), ‘The Impact of Circular Migration on a Village Economy, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. 25, No. 1, pp. 53-76. Hidayat (1978), ‘Peranan Sektor Informal dalam Perekonomian Indonesia’ [The Role of the Informal Sector in the Indonesian Economy], Ekonomi dan Keuangan Indonesia, Vol. 26, No. 4, pp. 415-445. Hill, H. (2000), The Indonesian Economy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Hill, T.P. (1977), ‘On Goods and Services’, Review of Income and Wealth, Vol. 23, No. 4, pp. 315-338. Hilling, D. (1996), Transport and Developing Countries, London: Routledge.
Hine, J.L., J.H. Ebden and P. Swan (1997), ‘A Comparison of Freight Transport in Operations in Tanzania and Indonesia’, Transport Research Laboratory Report no. 267. Hollinger, W.C. and A.D. Tan (1956/57), ‘The National Income of Indonesia, 1951-1952: A Critical Commentary on the Neumark Estimates,’ Ekonomi dan Keuangan Indonesia, Vol. 9, pp. 785-798; Vol. 10, pp. 2-33. Horlings, E. (1995), The Economic Development of the Dutch Service Sector 1800-1850. Trade and Transport in a Premodern Economy, Amsterdam: neha. Hutabarat, P.M. (1992), The Role of International Trade in Economic Growth in Developing Countries: The Case of Indonesia, PhD dissertation, Michigan State University. Ibrahim, A.M. and W.F. Weinreb (1957), ‘Penjelidikan Biaja Hidup di Djakarta’ [A Study on Cost of Living in Jakarta], Ekonomi dan Keuangan Indonesia, Vol. 10, pp. 738-795. ide (1977), Input-Output Table Indonesia, 1971, Tokyo: Institute of Developing Economies (2 volumes). Illori, C. (1968), Economic Study of Production and Distribution of Staple Foodcrops in Western Nigeria, PhD thesis, Stanford University. ilo (1993), Statistics of Employment in the Informal Sector: Report of the xvth International Conference of Labour Statisticians, 19-28 January, Geneva. Ishihara, Y and D. Marks (2005), ‘Capacity Utilization in Indonesia: Time to Invest’, Ekonomi dan Keuangan Indonesia, Vol. 53, No. 3, pp. 279-292. Ismet, M., A.P. Barkley, and R.V. Llewelyn (1998), ‘Government Intervention and Market Integration in Indonesian Rice Markets’, Agricultural Economics, Vol. 19, No. 3, pp. 293295. Johansen, S. (1991), ‘Estimation and Hypothesis Testing of Cointegration Vectors in Gaussian Vector Autoregressive Models’, Econometrica, Vol. 59, No. 6, pp. 1551-1580. Johansen, S. (1995), ‘Identifying Restrictions of Linear Equations with Applications to Simultaneous Equations and Cointegration’, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 69, No. 1, pp. 111132.
328
| Accounting for Services
Johansen, S. and K. Juselius (1990), ‘Maximum Likelihood Estimation and Inference on Cointegration – with Application to the Demand for Money’, Oxford Bulletin of Economic Statistics, Vol. 52, No. 2, pp. 169-210. Jones, W.O. (1972), Marketing Staple Food Crops in Tropical Africa, Ithaca, ny: Cornell University Press. Jong, P. de (1995), Handel en Wandel in de Kolonie [Trading in the Colony], ma thesis, Leiden University. Jonker, J. and K. Sluyterman (2000), At Home on the World Markets: Dutch International Trading Companies from the 16th Century until the Present, The Hague: Sdu. Kasryno, Faisal (1986), ‘Impact of Off-Farm Employment on Agircultural Labour Absorption and Wages in Indonesia’, in: R.T. Shand (ed.) Off-Farm Employment in the Development of Rural Asia, Canberra: Australian National University, pp. 273-308. Kindleberger, C.P. (1958), Economic Development, New York: McGraw-Hill. Kögel, M.T. (1999), Services and Economic Growth, PhD thesis, Erasmus University, Rotterdam. Koopmans, R., M. Sonnenberg, and J. van der Winden (1994), Uittocht. Het Einde van de Koninklijke Paketvaart-Maatschappij in Indonesië [Exodus. The End of the Koninklijke PaketvaartMaatschappij in Indonesia]. Krantz, O. (1983), ‘Historical Accounts – Some Methodological Notes’, Scandinavian Economic History Review, Vol. 31, pp. 109-131. Krantz, O. (1994), ‘Service Production in Historical National Accounts’, Review of Income and Wealth, Vol. 40, pp. 19-41. Krantz, O. (2000), ‘The Transport and Communications Sector in Economic Development: Views from the Historical National Accounts’, Scandinavian Economic History Review, Vol. 48, No. 2, pp. 5-29. Kravis, I.B., A.W. Heston, R. Summers (1983), ‘The Share of Services in Economic Growth’, in: F.G. Adams and B.G. Hickman (eds.) Global Econometrics: Essays in Honor of Lawrence R. Klein, Cambridge: mit Press, pp. 188-218. Kuznets, S. (1955), ‘Introduction’, Income and Wealth, Series v, pp. vii-viii. Kuznets, S. (1966), Modern Economic Growth, New Haven: Yale University Press.
Kuznets, S. (1971), Economic Growth of Nations: Total Output and Production, Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Kuznets, S. (1973), ‘Modern Economic Growth: Findings and Reflections’, in: American Economic Review, Vol. 63, No. 3, pp. 247-258. Lains, P. (2004), ‘Structural Change and Economic Growth in Portugal, 1950-1990’, in: S. Heikkinen and J.L. van Zanden (eds.) Explorations in Economic Growth, Amsterdam: Aksant, pp. 321-340. Lakshmanan, R.T., P. Nijkamp, P. Rietveld and E.T. Verhoef (2001), ‘Benefits and Costs of Transport: Classification, Methodologies and Policies’, Papers in Regional Science, Vol. 80, No. 2, pp. 139-164. Leeuwen, B. van (2007), Human Capital and Economic Growth in India, Indonesia and Japan: A Quantitative Analysis, 1890-2000, PhD thesis, Utrecht University. Lehrman, C. (1983), ‘Sex Differential Patterns of Circular Migration: A Case Study of Semarang, Indonesia’, Peasant Studies, Vol. 10, No. 4, pp. 251-269. Leinbach, Th.R. (1986), ‘Transport Development in Indonesia: Progress, Problems and Policies under the New Order’, in: Colin Mac Andrew (ed.) Central Government and Local Development in Indonesia, Singapore: Oxford University Press, pp. 190-220. Leinbach, Th.R. (1989), ‘Transport Policies in Conflict: Deregulation, Subsidies, and Regional Development in Indonesia’, Transportation Research, Vol. 23A, No. 6, pp. 467-475. Leinbach, Th.R. and Chia Lin Sien (1989), SouthEast Asian Transport: Issues in Development, Singapore: Oxford University Press. leknas (1973a), Input-Output Table of Indonesia, 1969: Inter-industrial Transaction Studies, Jakarta: Lembaga Ekonomi dan Kemasyarakatan Nasional. leknas (1973b), The Structure of the Indonesian Economy in 1969: Inter-industrial Transactions Studies, Jakarta: Lembaga Ekonomi dan Kemasyarakatan Nasional. Lele, U.J. (1967), ‘Market Integration: A Study of Sorghum Prices in Western India’, Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. 49, No. 1, pp. 147-159.
329
| References
Lele, U.J. (1971), Food Grain Marketing in India, Private Performance and Public Policy, Ithaca, ny: Cornell University Press. Leunig, Timothy (2006), ‘Time is Money: A ReAssessment of the Passenger Social Savings from Victorian British Railways’, Journal of Economic History, Vol. 66, No. 3, pp. 635-673. Leur, J.C. van (1955, 1934), Indonesian Trade and Society: Essays in Asian Social and Economic History, The Hague: W. van Hoeve. Lindblad, J.Th. (1994), ‘The Contribution of Foreign Trade to Colonial State Formation in Indonesia, 1900-1930’, in: R. Cribb (ed.) The Late Colonial State in Indonesia: Political and Economic Foundations of the Netherlands Indies, 1880-1942, Leiden: kitlv Press, pp. 93-116. Lindblad, J. Th. (2002), ‘Politieke economie en de dekolonisatie van Indonesië’ [Political Economy and the decolonisation of Indonesia], in: J. Thomas Lindblad and Willem van der Molen (eds.) Macht en majesteit; Opstellen voor Cees Fasseur, Leiden: Opleiding Talen en Culturen van Zuidoost-Azië en Oceanië, pp. 132-146. Lindblad, J.Th. (2006), ‘Macroeconomic Consequences of Decolonization in Indonesia’, paper presented at the xivth conference of the International Economic History Association, Helsinki 21-25 August 2006. Lindblad, J.Th. (2008), Bridges to New Business: The Economic Decolonization of Indonesia, Leiden: kitlv Press. Lynch, Robin (1998), ‘What is fisim’, sna News and Notes 8, , accessed July 2, 2008. Maddison (1980), ‘Economic Growth and Structural Change in the Advanced Countries’, in: I. Leveson and J.W. Wheeler (eds.) Western Economies in Transition: Structural Change and Adjustment Policies in Industrial Countries, Colorado: Westview Press. Maddison, A. (1989a), ‘Dutch Income in and from Indonesia’, in: A. Maddison and G. Prince (eds.) Economic Growth in Indonesia, Dordrecht: Foris Publications, pp. 15-41. Maddison, A. (1989b), The World Economy in the 20th Century, Paris: oecd. Maddison, A. (2003), The World Economy: Historical Statistics, Paris: oecd.
Manning, Chris (1998), Indonesian Labour in Transition: An East Asian Success Story?, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Marks, D. (forthcoming), ‘The Economic Consequences of Decolonization: The ‘Special’ Case of Indonesia’, in: J.Th. Lindblad and P. Post (eds.) Economic Decolonization in Indonesia in Regional Perspective, Leiden: kitlv Press. Marx, K. (1909), Capital: A Critique of Political Economy. Edited by F. Engels, Chicago: Charles Kerr. McCulloch, N. and C.P. Timmer (2008), ‘Rice Policy in Indonesia: A Special Issue’, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. 44, No. 1, pp. 33-44. Mears, L.A. (1961), Rice Marketing in the Republic of Indonesia. Jakarta: Institute of Economic and Social Research. Meijer, H. (1987), De Deli Spoorweg Maatschappij: Driekwart Eeuw Koloniaal Spoor [The Deli Railway Company: 75 Years of Colonial Railways], Zutphen: De Walburg Pers. Mudge, James L. (1972), Growth and Development in Indonesian Freight Transportation: the Case of Highway Common Carriers, PhD Thesis, University of Colorado. Mulder, N. (1999), The Economic Performance of the Service Sector in Brazil, Mexico and the usa, Groningen Growth and Development Centre Monographs Series, No. 4, Groningen. Muljatno (1957), ‘Persoalan Pendapatan Nasional di Indonesia’ [Problems of National Income in Indonesia], Ekonomi dan Keuangan Indonesia, Vol. 10, pp. 527-542. Muljatno (1960), ‘Perhitungan Pendapatan Nasional Indonesia untuk Tahun 1953 dan 1954’ [The Calculation of National Income of Indonesia for 1953 and 1954], Ekonomi dan Keuangan Indonesia, Vol. 13, pp. 162-211. Nas, J. and Pratiwo (2002), ‘Java and de Groote Postweg, la Grande Route, the Great Mail Road, Jalan Raya Pos’, Bijdragen tot de Taal-, Land- en Volkenkunde, Vol. 158, No. 4, pp. 707-725. Natawidjaja, R.S. (2001), ‘Dinamika Pasar Beras Domestik’ [Domestic Rice Market Dynamics], in: A. Suryana & S. Madianto (eds.) Bunga Rampai Ekonomi Beras [Antology of the Rice Economy], Jakarta: lpem-feui, pp. 59-81.
330
| Accounting for Services
Neumark, S.D. (1954), ‘The National Income of Indonesia 1951-1952’, Ekonomi dan Keuangan Indonesia, Vol. 7, pp. 348-391. Newbery, D.M.G. and J.E. Stiglitz (1979), ‘The Theory of Commodity Price Stabilization Rules: Welfare Impacts and Supply Responses’, Economic Journal, Vol. 89, pp. 799-817. Newbery, D.M.G. and J.E. Stiglitz (1981), The Theory of Commodity Price Stabilization: A Study in the Economics of Risk, New York: Oxford University Press. North, D.C. (1981), Structure and Change in Economic History. New York: Norton. North, D.C. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Nus, J. van (1935), ‘De Staatsspoorwegen in Nederlandsch-Indië gedurende de Crisisjaren 1930 t/m 1934’ [The State Railways Company in the Netherlands Indies during the Crisis Years 1930-1934], Koloniale Studiën, Vol. 19, No. 1, pp. 1-29. O’Brien, P.K. (1977), The New Economic History of Railways, London: Croom Helm. O’Brien, P.K. (1983), Railways and the Economic Development of Western Europe, 1830-1914, New York: St Martin’s Press. Oegema, J.J.G. (1982), Een Stoomtractie op Java en Sumatra [Steamtraction on Java and Sumatra], Deventer: Kluwer Technische Boeken. Ohkawa, K. (1993), Growth Mechanism of Developing Countries: Investment, Productivity, and Employment, Panama: International Centre for Economic Growth. Orrt, C. (1933), ‘Het Wegverkeer in Indië gedurende de Laatste Jaren’ [Road Transport in the Netherlands Indies during the Last Few Years], Koloniale Studiën, Vol. 17, No. 2, pp. 485-513. Osterwald-Lenum, M. (1992), ‘A Note with Quantiles of the Asymptotic Distribution of the Maximum Likelihood Cointegration Rank Test Statistics: Four Cases’, Oxford Bulletin of Economic Statistics, vol. 54, No. 3, pp. 461-471. Owen, W. (1964), Strategy for Mobility, Washington: The Brookings Institute. Owen, W. (1987), Transportation and World Development, London: Hutchinson.
Paauw, D.S. (1963), ‘From Colonial to Guided Economy’, in: R. McVey (ed.) Indonesia, New Haven: Hraf Press, pp. 155--247. Palaskas, T.B. and B. Harriss-White (1993), ‘Testing Market Integration: New Approaches with Case Material from the West Bengal Food Economy’, Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 30, No. 1, pp. 1-57. Panglaykim, J. (1968), ‘Marketing Organisation in Transition’, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. 4, No. 9, pp. 35-59. Panglaykim, J. and I. Palmer (1969), State Trading Corporations in Developing Countries, Rotterdam: Rotterdam University Press. Pearsson, S., W. Falcon, P. Heytens, E. Monke and R. Naylor (1991), Rice Policy in Indonesia. Ithaca, ny: Cornell University Press. Persson, K.G. (1999), Grain Markets in Europe, 1500-1900: Integration and Deregulation, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Petit, P. (1986), Slow Growth and the Service Economy, London: Pinter. Piggot, R.R., K.A. Parton, E.M. Treadgold and B. Hutabarat (1993), Food Price Policy in Indonesia, ACIAR Monograph No. 22, Canberra: Australian Centre for International Agricultural Research. Polak, J.J. (1943), The National Income of the Netherlands Indies, 1921-1939, New York: Netherlands and Netherlands-Indies Council of the Institute of Pacific Relations (Reprinted in cei v: 25-102). Portes, A. and Benton, L. (1984), ‘Industrial Development and Labor Absorption: A Reinterpretation’, Population and Development Review, Vol. 19, No. 1, pp. 33-61. Prawiro, R. (1998), Indonesia’s Struggle for Economic Development: Pragmatism in Action, Kuala Lumpur: Oxford University Press. prealc (1982), Mercado de Trabajo en Cifras,19501980 [Labour Market in Numbers, 1950-1980], Santiago de Chile: ilo, eclac. Pugel, Th.A. (2004), International Economics, 12th edition, Boston: McGraw-Hill. Ravallion, M. (1986), ‘Testing Market Integration’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 68, No. 1, pp. 102-109. Ravallion, M. (1987), Markets and Famines, Oxford: Clarendon Press.
331
| References
Reitsma, S.A. (1928), Korte Geschiedenis der Nederlandsch-Indische Spoor- en Tramwegen [A Concise History of the Rail- and Tramways in the Netherlands-Indies], Weltevreden: Kolff & Co. Richter, H.V. (1970), ‘Problems of Assessing Unrecorded Trade’, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. 6, No. 1, pp. 45-60. Ricklefs, M.C. (2001), A History of Modern Indonesia Since c. 1200, Houndmills: Palgrave. Riddle, D.I. (1986), Service-Led Growth: The Role of the Service Sector in World Development, New York: Praeger. Rodriguez, F. and D. Rodrik (2000), ‘Trade Policy and Economic Growth: a Skeptic’s Guide to the Crossnational Evidence’, in: B. Bernanke and K. Rogoff (eds.) Macroeconomics Annual 2000, Cambridge, ma: mit Press. Rosendale, P. (1975), ‘The Indonesian Terms of Trade 1950-1973’, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. 11, No. 3, pp 50-80. Rouwendal, J. and P. Rietveld (1994), ‘Changes in Commuting Distances of Dutch Households’, Urban Studies, Vol. 31, No. 9, pp. 1445-1457. Rutgers, S. (1947), Indonesië: Het Koloniale Systeem in de Periode tussen de Eerste en de Tweede Wereldoorlog [Indonesia: The Colonial System in the Period between the First and Second World War], Amsterdam: Pegasus. Saifullah, A. (2001), ‘Peran Bulog Dalam Kebijakan Perberasan Nasional’ [The Role of Bulog in National Rice Policy], in: A. Suryana and S. Mardianto (eds.) Bunga Rampai Ekonomi Beras [Anthology of the Rice Economy], Jakarta: lpem-feui, pp. 83-101. Samuelson, P.A. (1952), ‘Spatial Price Equilibrium and Linear Programming’, American Economic Review, Vol. 42, No. 3, pp. 283-303. Schumpeter, J.A. (1954), History of Economic Analysis, New York: Oxford University Press. Sen, A. (1981), Poverty and Famines: An Essay on Entitlement and Deprivation, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Shelp, R.K., J.C. Stephenson, N.S. Truitt and B. Wasow (1984), Service Industries and Economic Development: Case Studies in Technology Transfer, New York: Preager Publishers. Simkin, C.G.G. (1970), ‘Indonesia’s Unrecorded Trade’, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. 6, No. 1, pp. 17-44.
Singelmann, J. (1978), From Agriculture to Services: The Transformation of Industrial Employment, Beverly Hills: Sage Publications. Sivasubramonian, S. (2000), The National Income of India in the Twentieth Century, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Smith, A. (1910, 1776), The Wealth of Nations, London: Dent & Sons. Smits, J.P. (1990), ‘The Size and Structure of the Dutch Service Sector in International Perspective, 1850-1914’, Economic and Social History in the Netherlands, Vol. 2, pp. 81-98. Smits, J.P. (1995), Economische Groei en Structuurveranderingen in de Nederlandse Dienstensector, 1850-1913. De Bijdrage van Handel en Transport aan het Proces van ‘Moderne Economische Groei [Economic Growth and Structural Change in the Dutch Service Sector, 1850-1913. The Contribution of Trade and Transport to the Process of Modern Economic Growth], PhD thesis, Free University, Amsterdam. Squires, D. and S.T. Tabor (1987), ‘Integration of Staple Food Commodity Markets in Java’, Singapore Economic Review, Vol. 32, No. 2, pp. 1-15. Srinivasan, T.N. and J. Bhagwati (1999), ‘OutwardOrientation and Development: Are Revisionists Right?’, Center Discussion Paper No. 806, Yale University. Staargaard, W.F. (1929), Een Zelfstandig Staatsspoorbedrijf in Nederlandsch Indië [An Independent State Railway Company in the Netherlands-Indies], Bandung: Van Dorp & Co. Statistiek van het Taxi-verkeer in de Stad Soerabaja [Statistics on Taxi Traffic in the City of Surabaya] (1929), Soerabaja: Bureau van Statistiek. Stibora, J.J. and A. de Vaal (1995), Services and Services Trade, PhD thesis, Erasmus University, Rotterdam. Studenski, P. (1958), The Income of Nations. Theory, Measurement, and Analysis: Past and Present: A Study in Applied Economics and Statistics, New York: New York University Press. Sulistiyono, Singgih Tri (2001), ‘Prahu Shipping around the Java Sea and its Role in the Interregional Connection during the Late Colonial State of Indonesia, 1900-1942’, in: E. Sedyawati and S. Zuhdi (eds.) Arung Samudera: Persembahan Memperingati Sembilan Windu
332
| Accounting for Services
A.B. Lapian, Depok: Lembaga Penelitian Universitas Indonesia, pp. 202-228. Sulistyono, Singgih Tri (2003), The Java Sea Network: Patterns in the Development of Interregional Shipping and Trade in the Process of National Economic Integration in Indonesia, 1870s-1970s, Leiden: kitlv Press. Sulistiyono, Singgih Tri (2006), ‘The Expulsion of kpm and its Impact on the Inter-island Shipping and Trade in Indonesia, 1957-1964’, Itinerario, Vol. 30, No. 2, pp. 104-128. Summerhill, W.R. (2005), ‘Big Social Savings in a Small Laggard Economy: Railroad-Led Growth in Brazil’, Journal of Economic History, Vol. 65, No. 1, pp. 72-102. Sundrum, R.M. (1986), ‘Indonesia’s Rapid Economic Growth: 1968–81’, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. 22, No. 3, pp. 40-69. Suprapto, P. (1995), Growth and Import Dependence: The Case of Indonesia, 1970-1990, PhD dissertation, University of Notre Dame. Sutter, J.O. (1959), Indonesianisasi; A Historical Survey of the Role of Politics in the Institutions of a Changing Economy from the Second World War to the Eve of the General Election (1940-1955), PhD thesis, Cornell University, Ithaca, ny. Syrquin, M. (1984), ‘Resource Allocation and Productivity Growth’, in: M. Syrquin, L. Taylor and L.E. Westphal (eds.) Economic Structure Performance: Essays in Honor of Hollis B. Chenery, New York: Academic Press. Syrquin, M. (1986), ‘Productivity Growth and Factor Reallocation’, in: H.B. Chenery, S. Robinson, and M. Syrquin (eds.) Industrialization and Growth: A Comparative Study, New York: Oxford University Press. Szirmai, A. (2005), The Dynamism of SocioEconomic Development: An Introduction, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Taaffe, E.J., R.L. Morill and P.R. Gould (1963), ‘Transport Expansion in Underdeveloped Countries: A Comparative Analysis’, Geographical Review, Vol. 53, No. 4, pp. 503-529. Tabor, S.T. (1992), ‘Agriculture in Transition’ in Booth A. (ed.) The Oil Boom and After: Indonesian Economic Policy and Performance in the Suharto Era. Singapore: Oxford University Press, pp. 161-196.
Takayama, T. and G.G. Judge (1971), Spatial and Temporal Price and Allocation Models, Amsterdam: North-Holland. Takayama, T. and W.C. Labys (1986), ‘Spatial Equilibrium Analysis’, in: P. Nijkamp (ed.) Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers. Thorbecke, E. (1991), ‘Adjustment, Growth and Income Distribution in Indonesia’, World Development, Vol. 19, No. 11, pp. 1595-1614. Tim Telaga Bakti Nusantara (1997), Sejarah Perkeretaapian Indonesia [A History of Railways in Indonesia], Bandung: Angkasa Timmer, C.P. (1974), ‘A Model of Rice Marketing Margins in Indonesia’, Food Policy Reserach Institute Studies, Vol. 13, No. 2, pp. 145-167. Timmer, C.P. (1989a), ‘Food Price Policy. The Rationale for Government Intervention’, Food Policy, Vol. 14, No. 1, pp. 17-27. Timmer, C.P (1989b), ‘Indonesia: Transition from Food Importer to Exporter’, in: T. Sicular (ed.) Food Price Policy in Asia: A Comparative Study, Ithaca: Cornell University Press, pp. 22-62. Timmer, C.P. (1991), ‘Food Price Stabilization: Rationale, Design, and Implementation’, in: D.H. Perkins and M. Roemer (eds.) Reforming Economic Systems, Cambridge: Harvard University Press, pp. 219-248. Timmer, C.P. (1996), ‘Does Bulog Stabilise Rice Prices in Indonesia? Should it Try?’ Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. 32, No. 2, pp. 45-74. Timmer, C.P. (2004), ‘Food Security and Economic Growth: An Asian Perspective’, Center for Global Development Working Paper No. 51. Timmer, M. and A. Szirmai (2000), ‘Productivity Growth in Asian Manufacturing: The Structural Bonus Hypothesis Examined’, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics Vol. 11, pp. 371-392. Timmer, M. and G. de Vries (2007), ‘A CrossCountry Database for Sectoral Employment and Productivity in Asia and Latin America, 19502005’, ggdc-Research Memorandum gd-94, University of Groningen. Tokman, V.E. (1984), ‘Employment Crisis in Latin America’, International Labour Review, Vol. 125, No. 5, pp. 587-595. Touwen, J. (2001), Extremes in the Archipelago: Trade and economic development in the Outer Islands of Indonesia, 1900-1942, Leiden: kitlv Press.
333
| References
Touwen, J. (2008), ‘The Economic History of Indonesia’, eh.Net Encyclopedia, edited by Robert Whaples, March 16 2008. url: http:// eh.net/encyclopedia/?article=touwen.indonesia Uemura, Y. (2002), ‘Inter-Regional Trade of Rice and Paddy in Java and Madura, late-19th to early-20th Century’, Annual Report of Research Center for Regional Geography, Vol. 11, pp. 1-31. United Nations (1964), Review of Long-Term Economic Projections for Selected Countries in the Ecafe Region, Bangkok: United Nations Economic Commission for Asia and the Far East. United Nations (1993), A System of National Accounts, 1993, New York: United Nations. United Nations (1999), A Pilot Study on the Alleviation of Poverty in Remote Island Communities in Indonesia, New York: United Nations. Veenendaal, G. (2004), ‘De Locomotief van de Moderniteit: Aanleg van het Net van Spoor- en Tramwegen’ [The Locomotive of Modernity: Construction of the Rail- and Tramways], in: W. Ravesteijn en J. Kop (eds.) Bouwen in de Archipel: Burgerlijke Openbare Werken in NederlandschIndië 1800-2000 [Building in the Archipelago: Public Works in the Netherlands-Indies, 18002000]. Zutphen: Walburg Pers, pp. 63-92. Vries, E. de and H. Cohen (1937), ‘On Village Shopkeeping in Java and Madura’, Koloniale Studien, Vol. 21, No. 4, pp. 263-273. Weisfelt, J. (1972), De Deli Spoorweg Maatschappij als Factor in de Economische Ontwikkeling van de Oostkust van Sumatra [The Deli Railway Company as a Factor in the Economic Development of Sumatra’s Eastcoast], PhD dissertation, Netherlands School of Economics, Rotterdam. White, B. (1983), ‘Agricultural Involution and its Critics: Twenty Years Later’, Bulletin of Concerned Asian Scholars, Vol. 15, No. 2, pp. 18-31. White, B. (1991), ‘Economic Diversification and Agrarian Change in Rural Java, 1900-1990’, in: P. Alexander, P. Boomgaard and B. White (eds.) In the Shadow of Agriculture: Non-Farm Activities in the Javanese Economy, Past and Present, Amsterdam: Royal Tropical Institute, pp. 41-69.
Williams, J.C. and B.D. Wright (1991), Storage and Commodity Markets, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. World Bank (1987), Indonesia: Agriculture Incentives Policies, Issues and Options. Washington dc: World Bank. World Bank (1993), The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy. Oxford: World Bank /Oxford University Press. Yonekura, H. (2005), ‘Institutional Reform in Indonesia’s Food Security Sector: the Transformation of bulog into a Public Corporation’, Developing Economies, Vol. 43, No. 1, pp. 121-148.
334
| Accounting for Services
Zanden, J.L. van (1993), ‘Historical National Accounts’, in: The Value Added of National Accounting: Commemorating 50 Years of National Accounts in the Netherlands, Voorburg/Heerlen: cbs, pp. 243-255. Zanden, J.L. van (2004), ‘On the Efficiency of Markets for Agricultural Products: Rice Prices and Capital Markets in Java, 1823-1853’, Journal of Economic History, Vol. 64, No. 4, pp. 10281055. Zimmerman, L.J. (1967), ‘De Toekomstige Verhoudingen Tussen Ontwikkelde en Onderontwikkelde Gebieden op Lange Termijn’ [The Future Relations Between Developed and Underdeveloped Regions in the Long Run], De Economist, Vol. 115, No. 5, pp. 701-717.